View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 a.m. E.D.T.
July 20, 2000

Statement of
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs
United States Senate
July 20, 2000

Mr. Chairman and other members of the Committee, I appreciate this opportunity
to present the Federal Reserve's report on monetary policy.
The Federal Reserve has been confronting a complex set of challenges in judging the
stance of policy that will best contribute to sustaining the strong and long-running expansion of
our economy. The challenges will be no less in coming months as we judge whether ongoing
adjustments in supply and demand will be sufficient to prevent distortions that would undermine
the economy's extraordinary performance.
For some time now, the growth of aggregate demand has exceeded the expansion of
production potential. Technological innovations have boosted the growth rate of potential, but as
I noted in my testimony last February, the effects of this process also have spurred aggregate
demand. It has been clear to us that, with labor markets already quite tight, a continuing disparity
between the growth of demand and potential supply would produce disruptive imbalances.
A key element in this disparity has been the very rapid growth of consumption resulting
from the effects on spending of the remarkable rise in household wealth. However, the growth in
household spending has slowed noticeably this spring from the unusually rapid pace observed
late in 1999 and early this year. Some argue that this slowing is a pause following the surge in
demand through the warmer-than-normal winter months and hence a reacceleration can be
expected later this year. Certainly, we have seen slowdowns in spending during this neardecade-long expansion that have proven temporary, with aggregate demand growth subsequently
rebounding to an unsustainable pace.
But other analysts point to a number of factors that may be exerting more persistent
restraint on spending. One they cite is the flattening in equity prices, on net, this year. They
attribute much of the slowing of consumer spending to this diminution of the wealth effect

2
through the spring and early summer. This view looks to equity markets as a key influence on
the trend in consumer spending over the rest of this year and next.
Another factor said by some to account for the spending slowdown is the rising debt
burden of households. Interest and amortization as a percent of disposable income have risen
materially during the past six years, as consumer and especially mortgage debt has climbed and,
more recently, as interest rates have moved higher.
In addition, the past year's rise in the price of oil has amounted to an annual $75 billion
levy by foreign producers on domestic consumers of imported oil, the equivalent of a tax of
roughly 1 percent of disposable income. This burden is another likely source of the slowed
growth in real consumption outlays in recent months, though one that may prove to be largely
transitory.
Mentioned less prominently have been the effects of the faster increase in the stock of
consumer durable assets-both household durable goods and houses-in the last several years, a
rate of increase that history tells us is usually followed by a pause. Stocks of household durable
goods, including motor vehicles, are estimated to have increased at nearly a 6 percent annual rate
over the past three years, a marked acceleration from the growth rate of the previous ten years.
The number of cars and light trucks owned or leased by households, for example, apparently has
continued to rise in recent years despite having reached nearly 1-3/4 vehicles per household by
the mid-1990s. Notwithstanding their recent slowing, sales of new homes continue at
extraordinarily high levels relative to new household formations. While we will not know for
sure until the 2000 census is tabulated, the surge in new home sales is strong evidence that the
growth of owner-occupied homes has accelerated during the past five years.

3
Those who focus on the high and rising stocks of durable assets point out that even
without the rise in interest rates, an eventual leveling out or some tapering off of purchases of
durable goods and construction of single-family housing would be expected. Reflecting both
higher interest rates and higher stocks of housing, starts of new housing units have fallen off of
late. If that slowing were to persist, some reduction in the rapid pace of accumulation of
household appliances across our more than hundred million households would not come as a
surprise, nor would a slowdown in vehicle demand so often historically associated with declines
in housing demand.
Inventories of durable assets in households are just as formidable a factor in new
production as inventories at manufacturing and trade establishments. The notion that consumer
spending and housing construction may be slowing because the stock of consumer durables and
houses may be running into upside resistance is a credible addition to the possible explanations
of current consumer trends. This effect on spending would be reinforced by the waning effects of
gains in wealth.
Because the softness in outlay growth is so recent, all of the aforementioned hypotheses,
of course, must be provisional. It is certainly premature to make a definitive assessment of either
the recent trends in household spending or what they mean. But it is clear that, for the time being
at least, the increase in spending on consumer goods and houses has come down several notches,
albeit from very high levels.
In one sense, the more important question for the longer-term economic outlook is the
extent of any productivity slowdown that might accompany a more subdued pace of production
and consumer spending, should it persist. The behavior of productivity under such circumstances

4
will be a revealing test of just how much of the rapid growth of productivity in recent years has
represented structural change as distinct from cyclical aberrations and, hence, how truly different
the developments of the past five years have been. At issue is how much of the current
downshift in our overall economic growth rate can be accounted for by reduced growth in output
per hour and how much by slowed increases in hours.
So far there is little evidence to undermine the notion that most of the productivity
increase of recent years has been structural and that structural productivity may still be
accelerating. New orders for capital equipment continue quite strong--so strong that the rise in
unfilled orders has actually steepened in recent months. Capital-deepening investment in a broad
range of equipment embodying the newer productivity-enhancing technologies remains brisk.
To be sure, if current personal consumption outlays slow significantly further than the
pattern now in train suggests, profit and sales expectations might be scaled back, possibly
inducing some hesitancy in moving forward even with capital projects that appear quite
profitable over the longer run. In addition, the direct negative effects of the sharp recent runup in
energy prices on profits as well as on sales expectations may temporarily damp capital spending.
Despite the marked decline over the past decades in the energy requirements per dollar of GDP,
energy inputs are still a significant element in the cost structure of many American businesses.

For the moment, the dropoff in overall economic growth to date appears about matched
by reduced growth in hours, suggesting continued strength in growth in output per hour. The
increase of production worker hours from March through June, for example, was at an annual
rate of 1/2 percent compared with 3-1/4 percent the previous three months. Of course, we do not

5
have comprehensive measures of output on a monthly basis, but available data suggest a roughly
comparable deceleration.
A lower overall rate of economic growth that did not carry with it a significant
deterioration in productivity growth obviously would be a desirable outcome. It could
conceivably slow or even bring to a halt the deterioration in the balance of overall demand and
potential supply in our economy.
As I testified before this committee in February, domestic demand growth, influenced
importantly by the wealth effect on consumer spending, has been running 1-1/2 to 2 percentage
points at an annual rate in excess of even the higher, productivity-driven, growth in potential
supply since late 1997. That gap has been filled both by a marked rise in imports as a percent of
GDP and by a marked increase in domestic production resulting both from significant
immigration and from the employment of previously unutilized labor resources.
I also pointed out in February that there are limits to how far net imports-or the broader
measure, our current account deficit-can rise, or our pool of unemployed labor resources can
fall. As a consequence, the excess of the growth of domestic demand over potential supply must
be closed before the resulting strains and imbalances undermine the economic expansion that
now has reached 112 months, a record for peace or war.
The current account deficit is a proxy for the increase in net claims against U.S. residents
held by foreigners, mainly as debt, but increasingly as equities. So long as foreigners continue to
seek to hold ever-increasing quantities of dollar investments in their portfolios, as they obviously
have been, the exchange rate for the dollar will remain firm. Indeed, the same sharp rise in
potential rates of return on new American investments that has been driving capital accumulation

6
and accelerating productivity in the United States has also been inducing foreigners to expand
their portfolios of American securities and direct investment. The latest data published by the
Department of Commerce indicate that the annual pace of direct plus portfolio investment by
foreigners in the U.S. economy during the first quarter was more than two and one-half times its
rate in 1995.
There has to be a limit as to how much of the world's savings our residents can borrow at
close to prevailing interest and exchange rates. And a narrowing of disparities among global
growth rates could induce a narrowing of rates of return here relative to those abroad that could
adversely affect the propensity of foreigners to invest in the United States. But obviously, so
long as our rates of return appear to be unusually high, if not rising, balance of payments trends
are less likely to pose a threat to our prosperity. In addition, our burgeoning budget surpluses
have clearly contributed to a fending off, if only temporarily, of some of the pressures on our
balance of payments. The stresses on the global savings pool resulting from the excess of
domestic private investment demands over domestic private saving have been mitigated by the
large federal budget surpluses that have developed of late.
In addition, by substantially augmenting national saving, these budget surpluses have kept
real interest rates at levels lower than they would have been otherwise. This development has
helped foster the investment boom that in recent years has contributed greatly to the
strengthening of U.S. productivity and economic growth. The Congress and the Administration
have wisely avoided steps that would materially reduce these budget surpluses. Continued fiscal
discipline will contribute to maintaining robust expansion of the American economy in the
future.

7
Just as there is a limit to our reliance on foreign saving, so is there a limit to the
continuing drain on our unused labor resources. Despite the ever-tightening labor market, as yet,
gains in compensation per hour are not significantly outstripping gains in productivity. But as I
have argued previously, should labor markets continue to tighten, short of a repeal of the law of
supply and demand, labor costs eventually would have to accelerate to levels threatening price
stability and our continuing economic expansion.
The more modest pace of increase in domestic final spending in recent months suggests
that aggregate demand may be moving closer into line with the rate of advance in the economy's
potential, given our continued impressive productivity growth. Should these trends toward
supply and demand balance persist, the ongoing need for ever-rising imports and for a further
draining of our limited labor resources should ease or perhaps even end. Should this favorable
outcome prevail, the immediate threat to our prosperity from growing imbalances in our
economy would abate.
But as I indicated earlier, it is much too soon to conclude that these concerns are behind
us. We cannot yet be sure that the slower expansion of domestic final demand, at a pace more in
line with potential supply, will persist. Even if the growth rates of demand and potential supply
move into better balance, there is still uncertainty about whether the current level of labor
resource utilization can be maintained without generating increased cost and price pressures.
As I have already noted, to date costs have been held in check by productivity gains. But
at the same time, inflation has picked up-even the core measures that do not include energy
prices directly. Higher rates of core inflation may mostly reflect the indirect effects of energy
prices, but the Federal Reserve will need to be alert to the risks that high levels of resource

8
utilization may put upward pressure on inflation.
Moreover, energy prices may pose a challenge to containing inflation. Energy price
changes represent a one-time shift in a set of important prices, but by themselves generally
cannot drive an ongoing inflation process. The key to whether such a process could get under
way is inflation expectations. To date, survey evidence, as well as readings from the Treasury's
inflation-indexed securities, suggests that households and investors do not view the current
energy price surge as affecting longer-term inflation. But any deterioration in such expectations
would pose a risk to the economic outlook.
As the financing requirements for our ever-rising capital investment needs mounted in
recent years-beyond forthcoming domestic saving-real long-term interest rates rose to address
this gap. We at the Federal Reserve, responding to the same economic forces, have moved the
overnight federal funds rate up 1-3/4 percentage points over the past year. To have held to the
federal funds rate of June 1999 would have required a massive increase in liquidity that would
presumably have underwritten an acceleration of prices and, hence, an eventual curbing of
economic growth.
By our meeting this June, the appraisal of all the foregoing issues led the Federal Open
Market Committee to conclude that, while some signs of slower growth were evident and
justified standing pat at least for the time being, they were not sufficiently compelling to alter our
view that the risks remained more on the side of higher inflation.
As indicated in their forecasts, FOMC members and nonvoting presidents expect that the
long period of continuous economic expansion will be extended over the next year and one-half,
but with growth at a somewhat slower pace than over the past several years. For the current year,

9
the central tendency of Board members' and Reserve Bank presidents' forecasts is for real GDP
to increase 4 to 4-1/2 percent, suggesting a noticeable deceleration over the second half of 2000
from its likely pace over the first half. The unemployment rate is projected to remain close to 4
percent. This outlook is a little stronger than anticipated last February, no doubt owing primarily
to the unexpectedly strong jump in output in the first quarter. Mainly reflecting higher prices of
energy products than had been foreseen, the central tendency for inflation this year in prices for
personal consumption expenditures also has been revised up somewhat, to the vicinity of 2-1/2 to
2-3/4 percent.
Given the firmer financial conditions that have developed over the past eighteen months,
the Committee expects economic growth to moderate somewhat next year. Real output is
anticipated to expand 3-1/4 to 3-3/4 percent, somewhat less rapidly than in recent years. The
unemployment rate is likely to remain close to its recent very low levels. Energy prices could
ease somewhat, helping to trim PCE inflation next year to around 2 to 2-1/2 percent, somewhat
above the average of recent years.
Conclusion
The last decade has been a remarkable period of expansion for our economy. Federal
Reserve policy through this period has been required to react to a constantly evolving set of
economic forces, often at variance with historical relationships, changing federal funds rates
when events appeared to threaten our prosperity, and refraining from action when that appeared
warranted. Early in the expansion, for example, we kept rates unusually low for an extended
period, when financial sector fragility held back the economy. Most recently we have needed to
raise rates to relatively high levels in real terms in response to the side effects of accelerating

10
growth and related demand-supply imbalances. Variations in the stance of policy-or keeping it
the same—in response to evolving forces are made in the framework of an unchanging objective—
to foster as best we can those financial conditions most likely to promote sustained economic
expansion at the highest rate possible. Maximum sustainable growth, as history so amply
demonstrates, requires price stability. Irrespective of the complexities of economic change, our
primary goal is to find those policies that best contribute to a noninflationary environment and
hence to growth. The Federal Reserve, I trust, will always remain vigilant in pursuit of that goal.