View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:00 a.m., E.D.T
July 13, 1988

Statement by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs
of the
U.S. Senate

July 13, 1988

Mr. Chairman, and members of the Committee, I appreciate this opportunity to review with you recent and prospective
monetary policy and the economic outlook.

I would also like to

provide a broader perspective by discussing in some detail our
nation's longer-term economic objectives, the overall strategy
for fiscal and monetary policies needed to reach those objectives, and the appropriate tactics for implementing monetary
policy within that strategic framework.
The economic setting and monetary policy so far in 1988.
The macroeconomic setting for monetary policy has
changed in some notable respects since I testified last
February.

At that time, the full after-effects of the stock

market plunge on spending and financial markets were still
unclear.

While most Federal Open Market Committee members were

forecasting moderate growth, in view of rapid inventory building
and some signs of a weakening of labor demand, the possibility
of a decline in economic activity could not be ruled out.

To

guard against this outcome, in the context of a firmer dollar
on exchange markets, the Federal Reserve undertook a further
modest easing of reserve pressures in late January, which
augmented the more substantial easing following October 19.
Short-term interest rates came down another notch, and with a
delay helped to push the monetary aggregates higher within their
targeted annual ranges.

-2In the event, the economy proved remarkably resilient
to the loss of stock market wealth.

Economic growth remained

vigorous through the first half of the year.

Continuing brisk

advances in exports, together with moderating growth in imports,
supported expansion in output, especially in manufacturing.
Some strengthening also was evident in business outlays for
equipment, especially computers, and consumer purchases of
durables, including autos.
Financial markets also returned to more normal functioning.

Although trading volumes did not regain pre-crash

levels in many markets, price volatility diminished somewhat and
quality differentials stayed considerably narrower than in the
immediate aftermath of the stock market plunge.

In response,

the Federal Reserve gradually was able to restore its standard
procedure of gearing open market operations to the intended
pressure on reserve positions of depository institutions.

We

thereby discontinued the procedure of reacting primarily to dayto-day variations in money market interest rates that had been
adopted,right after the stock market break.
As the risks of faltering economic expansion and
further financial market disruptions diminished, the dangers of
intensified inflationary pressures reemerged.

Utilization of

labor and capital reached the highest levels in many years, and
hints of acceleration began to crop up in wage and price data
Strong gains in payroll employment that continued through the
spring combined with slower growth in the labor force to lower

-3the unemployment rate by about 1/4 percentage point, even before
the strong labor market report for June; the industrial capacity
utilization rate moved up as well.

In part reflecting the

payroll tax increase, broad measures of hourly compensation
picked up somewhat in the first quarter.

Prices for a wide

range of domestic and imported industrial materials and supplies
rose even more steeply than last year.

Finished goods price

inflation has not reflected this step-up in price increases for
intermediate goods, in part as productivity gains kept unit
labor costs under control.

Even so, continued increases in

materials prices at the recent pace were seen as pointing to a
potential intensification in inflation more generally, since
based on historical experience, such increases have tended to
show through to finished good prices.
In these circumstances, the Federal Reserve was well
aware that it should not fall behind in establishing enough
monetary restraint to effectively resist these inflationary
tendencies.

The System took a succession of restraining steps

from late March through late June.

The shortest-term interest

rates gradually rose to levels now around highs reached last
fall.

Responding as well to the unwinding of a tax-related

buildup in liquid balances, M2 and M3 growth slowed noticeably
after April.
In contrast to the shortest-maturity interest rates,
long-term bond and mortgage rates, though also above February
lows, still remain well below last fall's peaks

The timely

-4tightening of monetary policy this spring, along with perceptions of better prospects for the dollar in foreign exchange
markets in light of the narrowing in our trade deficit, seemed
to improve market confidence that inflationary excesses would be
avoided.

Both bond prices and the dollar rallied in June

despite increases in interest rates in several major foreign
countries and jumps in some agricultural prices resulting from
the drought in important growing areas.
The economic outlook and monetary policy through 1989.
The monetary actions of the first half of the year were
undertaken so that economic expansion could be maintained,
recognizing that to do so, additional price pressures could
not be permitted to build and progress toward external balance
had to be sustained.

The projections of FOMC members and

nonvoting presidents indicate that they do expect economic
growth to continue, and inflation to be contained.
The 2-3/4 to 3 percent central tendency of FOMC members' expectations for real GNP growth over the four quarters of
this year implies a deceleration over the rest of the year to a
pace more in line with their expected 2 to 2-1/2 percent real
growth over 1989 and with the long-run potential of the economy.
The drought will reduce farm output for a time, and it is
important that nonfarm inventory accumulation slow before long,
if we are to avoid a troublesome imbalance.

Still, further

gains in our international trade position should continue to
provide a major stimulus to real GNP growth through next year,

-5reflecting the lagged effects of the decline in the exchange
value of the dollar through the end of last year.

Although the

month-to-month pattern in our trade deficit can be expected to
be erratic, the improvement in the external sector on balance
over time is expected to replace much of the reduced expansion
in domestic final demands from our consumer, business, and
government sectors.
Employment growth is anticipated to be substantial,
though some updrift in the unemployment rate may occur over the
next year and a half.

Capacity utilization could well top out

soon, as growth in demands for manufactured goods slows to match
that of capacity.
Considering the already limited slack in available
labor and capital resources, a leveling of the unemployment and
capacity utilization rates is essential if more intense inflationary pressures are to be avoided in the period ahead.

Other-

wise, aggregate demand would continue growing at an unsustainable pace and would soon begin to create a destabilizing
inflationary climate.

Supply conditions for materials and labor

would tighten further and costs would start to rise more
rapidly; businesses would attempt to recoup profit margins with
further price hikes on final goods and services.

These faster

price rises would, in turn, foster an inflationary psychology,
cut into workers' real purchasing power, and prompt an attempted
further catchup of wages, setting in motion a dynamic process in

-6which neither workers nor businesses would benefit.

The hard-

won gains in our international competitiveness would be eroded,
with feedback effects depressing the exchange value of the
dollar.

Excessive domestic demands and inflation pressures in

this country, with its sizable external deficit, would be
disruptive to the ongoing international adjustment of trade and
payments imbalances.
Not only the reduced slack in the economy but also
several prospective adjustments in relative prices have
accentuated inflation dangers.

One is the upward movement of

import prices relative to domestic prices, which is a necessary
part of the process of adjustment to large imbalances in international trade and payments.

Another is the recent drought-

related increases in grain and soybean prices.

It is essential

that we keep these processes confined to a one-time adjustment
in the level of prices and not let them spill over to a sustained higher rate of increase in wages and prices.

Elevated

import and farm prices must be prevented from engendering
expectations of higher general inflation, with feedback effects
on labor costs.

A more serious long-run threat to price

stability could come from government actions that introduced
structural rigidities and increased costs of production.
Protectionist legislation, inordinate hikes in the minimum wage,
and other mandated programs that would impose costs on U.S
producers would adversely affect their efficiency and
international competitiveness

-7The costs to our economy and society of allowing a more
intense inflationary process to become entrenched are serious.
As the experience in the past two decades has clearly shown,
accelerating wages and prices would have to be countered later
by quite restrictive policies, with unavoidably adverse implications for production and employment.

The financial health of

many individual and business debtors, as well as of some of
their creditors, then would be threatened.

The long-run costs

of a return to higher inflation and the risks of this occurring
under current circumstances are sufficiently great, that Federal
Reserve policy at this juncture might be well advised to err
more on the side of restrictiveness rather than of stimulus.
We believe that monetary policy actions to date, together with the fiscal restraint embodied in last fall's agreement between the Congress and the administration, have set the
stage for containing inflation through next year.

The central

tendency of FOMC members' expectations for inflation in the GNP
deflator ranges from 3 to 3-3/4 percent over this year and 3 to
4-1/2 percent next year.

But in one sense the GNP deflator

understates this year's rate of inflation, and the comparison
with next year overstates the pick-up.

The deflator represents

the average price of final goods and services produced in the
United States, or equivalently domestic value added, using
current quantity weights

This measure was artificially held

down in the first quarter by a shift in the composition of
output, especially by the surge in sales of computers whose

-8prices have dropped sharply since the 1982 base year used for
constructing the deflator.

Indeed, if the deflator were indexed

with a 1987 base year, it would have risen appreciably faster in
the first quarter.
Another understatement of inflation in the deflator
this year arises from its exclusion of imported goods, which are
not directly encompassed because they are produced abroad.

In

part because import prices have continued to rise significantly
faster than prices of domestically produced goods, consumer
price indexes have increased more than the GNP deflator.
The FOMC believes that efforts to contain inflation
pressures and sustain the economic expansion would be fostered
by growth of the monetary aggregates over 1988 well within their
reaffirmed 4 to 8 percent annual ranges, followed by some slowing in money growth over the course of next year.

M2 should

move close to the midpoint of its range by late 1988, if
depositors react as expected to the greater attractiveness of
market instruments compared with liquid money balances that was
brought about by recent increases in short-term market rates
relative to deposit rates

M3 could end the year somewhat above

its midpoint, though comfortably within its range, if depository
institutions retain their recent share of overall credit expansion.

The debt of nonfinancial sectors, which so far this year

has been near the midpoint of its reaffirmed 7 to 11 percent
monitoring range, is anticipated to post similar growth through
year-end.

-9For 1989, the FOMC has underscored its intention to
encourage progress toward price stability over time by lowering
its tentative ranges for money and debt.

We have preliminarily

reduced the growth range for M2 by 1 full percentage point, to
3 to 7 percent; last February, the FOMC also had reduced the
midpoint of the 1988 range for M2 by 1 percentage point from
that for 1987.

We have adjusted the tentative 1989 range for M3

downward by 1/2 percentage point, to 3-1/2 to 7-1/2 percent.
This configuration is consistent with the observed tendency for
M3 velocity over time to fall relative to the velocity of M2;
over the last decade, the Federal Reserve's ranges frequently
allowed for faster growth of M3 than of M2.

The monitoring

range for domestic nonfinancial debt for 1989 also has been
lowered 1/2 percentage point to a tentative 6-1/2 to 10-1/2
percent.
The specific ranges chosen for 1989 are, as usual, provisional, and the FOMC will review them carefully next February,
in light of intervening developments.

Anticipating today how

the outlook for the economy in 1989 will appear next February is
difficult, and a major reassessment of that outlook would have
implications for appropriate money growth ranges for that year
Unexpectedly strong or weak economic expansion or inflation
pressures over the next six months also could have implications
for the behavior of interest rates and their prospects for 198 9
The sensitivity of the monetary aggregates to movements in market interest rates means that the appropriate growth next year

-10in M2, M3, and debt could seem different next February than now,
necessitating a revision in the annual growth ranges.

As the

aggregates have become more responsive to interest rate changes
in the 1980s, judgments about possible ranges for the next year
necessarily have become even more tentative and subject to
revision.
The persistent U.S, external and fiscal imbalances.
Despite the changes in the economic setting over the
last six months, other features of the macroeconomic landscape
remain much the same.

Most notable are the continuing massive

deficits in our external payments and internal fiscal accounts
As a nation, we still are living well beyond our means; we
consume much more of the world's goods and services each year
than we produce.

Our current account deficit indicates how much

more deeply in debt to the rest of the world we are sliding each
year.
The consequence of this external imbalance will be a
steady expansion in our external debt burden in the years ahead.
No household or business can expect to have an inexhaustible
credit line with borrowing terms that stay the same as its debt
mounts relative to its wealth and income.

Nor can we as a

nation expect our foreign indebtedness to grow indefinitely
relative to our servicing capacity without additional inducements to foreigners to acquire dollar assets--either higher real
interest returns, or a cheaper real foreign exchange value for
dollar assets, or both.

To be sure, such changes in market

-11incentives would have self-correcting effects over time in
reducing the imbalance between our domestic spending and income.
Higher real interest rates would curtail domestic investment and
other spending.

A lower real value of the dollar would make

U.S. goods and services relatively less expensive to both U.S.
and foreign residents, damping our spending on imports out of
U.S. income and boosting our exports.
But simply sitting back and allowing such a selfcorrection to take place is not a workable policy alternative.
Trying to follow such a course could have severe drawbacks now
that our economy is operating close to effective capacity and
potential inflationary pressures are on the horizon.
is hardly propitious to discourage

The time

investment in needed plant

and equipment, to add further impulses for import price hikes on
top of the upward tendencies already in the making, or to push
our export industries as well as import-competing industries to
their capacity limits.
Fortunately, we have a better choice for righting the
imbalance between domestic spending and income--one over which
we have direct control.

That is to resume reducing substan-

tially the still massive federal budget deficit, which remains
the most important source of dissaving in our economy

The fall

in the dollar we have already experienced over the last few
years, even allowing for the dollar's appreciation from the lows
reached at the end of last year, has set in motion forces that
should continue to narrow our trade and current account deficits

-12in the years ahead.

The associated loss of foreign-funded

domestic investment is likely to adversely affect overall
investment unless it can be replaced by greater domestic
investment financed by domestic saving.

A sharp contraction in

the federal deficit appears to be the only assured source of
augmented domestic net saving.

Such a fiscal cutback should

help counter future tendencies for further increases in U.S.
interest rates and declines in the dollar, partly by instilling
confidence on the part of international investors in the resolve
of the United States to address its economic problems.
Fiscal restraint in the years ahead would assist in
making room for the needed diversion of more of our productive
resources to meeting demands from abroad.

Domestic demands will

have to continue growing more slowly than our productive capacity, as seems to have been the case so far this year, if net
exports are to expand further without resulting in an inflationary overheating of the economy.

Absent this fiscal restraint,

higher interest rates would become the only channel for damping
domestip demands if they were becoming excessive.

If a renewed

decline in the dollar were adding further inflationary stimulus
at the same time, upward pressures on interest rates would be
even more likely.

The restrictive impact would be felt most by

the interest-sensitive sectors--homebuilding, business fixed
investment, and consumer durables.
In terms of federal deficit reduction, the schedule
under the Gramm-Rudman-Hollings law is a good baseline for a

-13multi-year strategy, and I trust the Congress will stick with
it.

But we should go further.

Ideally, we should be aiming

ultimately at a federal budget surplus, so that government
saving could supplement private domestic saving in financing
additional domestic investment.

Historically, the United States

was not a low saving, low investing economy.

From the post-

Civil War period through the 1920s, the United States consistently saved more as a fraction of GNP than Japan and Germany,
and we saved much more as a share of GNP then than we have since
the end of World War II.

A turnaround in our current domestic

saving performance is essential to a smooth reduction in our
dependence on foreign saving, and the federal government should
take the lead.
It is also apparent that redressing our external imbalances must encompass cooperative policies with our trading
partners.

These include both the established industrial powers,

the newly industrialized economies, and the developing countries, whose debt problems must be worked through as part of the
international adjustment process.
This is the strategy that U.S. fiscal policy as well as
economic policies abroad should follow in most effectively promoting our shared economic objectives.

The strategic role of

U.S. monetary policy is implied by a clear statement of what
those ultimate objectives are.

We should not be satisfied

unless the U.S. economy is operating at high employment with a
sustainable external position and above all stable prices.

-14High employment is consistent with steadily rising
nominal wages and real wages growing in line with productivity
gains.

Some frictional unemployment will exist in a dynamic

labor market, reflecting the process of matching available
workers with available jobs.

But every effort should be made

to minimize both impediments that contribute to structural
unemployment and deviations of real economic growth from the
economy's potential that cause cyclical unemployment.
By a sustainable external position, I am referring to a
situation in which our foreign indebtedness is not persistently
growing faster than our capacity to service it out of national
income.

Our international payments need not be in exact balance

from one year to the next, and the exchange value of the dollar
need not be perfectly stable, but wide swings in the dollar, and
boom and bust cycles in our export and import-competing industries, should be avoided.
By price stability, I mean a situation in which households and businesses in making their saving and investment
decisions can safely ignore the possibility of sustained, generalized price increases or decreases.

Prices of individual goods

and services, of course, would still vary to equilibrate the
various markets in our complex national and world economy, and
particular price indexes could still show transitory movements
A small persistent rise in some of the indexes would be tolerable, given the inadequate adjustment for trends in quality
improvement and the tendency for spending to shift toward goods

-15that have become relatively cheap.

But essentially the average

of all prices would exhibit no trend over time.

Price movements

in these circumstances would reflect relative scarcities of
goods, and private decision-makers could focus their concerns on
adjusting production and consumption patterns appropriately to
changing individual prices, without being misled by generalized
inflationary or deflationary price movements.
The strategy for monetary policy needs to be centered
on making further progress toward and ultimately reaching
stable prices.

Price stability is a prerequisite for achieving

the maximum economic expansion consistent with a sustainable
external balance at high employment.

Price stability reduces

uncertainty and risk in a critical area of economic decisionmaking by households and businesses.

In the process of foster-

ing price stability, monetary policy also would have to bear
much of the burden for countering any pronounced cyclical
instability in the economy, especially if fiscal policy is
following a program for multi-year reductions in the federal
budget deficit.

While recognizing the self-correcting nature of

some macroeconomic disturbances, monetary policy does have a
role to play over time in guiding aggregate demand into line
with the economy's potential to produce.

This may involve

providing a counterweight to major, sustained cyclical
tendencies in private spending, though we can not be overconfident in our ability to identify such tendencies and to
determine exactly the appropriate policy response.

In this

-16regard, it seems worthwhile for me to offer some thoughts on the
approach the Federal Reserve should take in implementing this
longer-term strategy for monetary policy.
The appropriate tactics for monetary policy.
For better or worse, our economy is enormously complex,
the relationships among macroeconomic variables are imperfectly
understood, and as a consequence economic forecasting is an
uncertain endeavor.

Nonetheless, the forecasting exercise can

aid policymaking by helping to refine the boundaries of the
likely economic consequences of our policy stance.

But fore-

casts will often go astray to a greater or lesser degree and
monetary policy has to remain flexible to respond to unexpected
developments.
A perfectly flexible monetary policy, however, without
any guideposts to steer by, can risk losing sight of the ultimate goal of price stability.

In this connection, the require-

ment under the Humphrey-Hawkins Act for the Federal Reserve to
announce its objectives and plans for growth of money and credit
aggregates is a very useful device for calibrating prospective
monetary policy.

The announcement of ranges for the monetary

aggregates represents a way for the Federal Reserve to
communicate its policy intentions to the Congress and the
public.

And the undisputed long-run relation between money

growth and inflation means that trend growth rates in the
monetary aggregates provide useful checks on the thrust of
monetary policy over time.

It is clear to all observers that

-17the monetary ranges will have to be brought down further in the
future if price stability is to be achieved and then maintained.
But, in a shorter-run countercyclical context, monetary
aggregates have drawbacks as rigid guides to monetary policy
implementation.

As I discussed in some detail in my February

testimony, financial innovation and deregulation in the 1980s
have altered the structure of deposits, lessened the predictability of the demands for the aggregates, and made the velocities of Ml and probably M2 over periods of a year or so more
sensitive to movements in market interest rates.

Movements in

short-term market rates relative to sluggishly adjusting deposit
rates can result in large percentage changes in the opportunity
costs of holding liquid monetary assets.

Depositor responses

can induce divergent growth between money and nominal GNP for a
time.

I might add that it was partly these considerations that

led the FOMC to retain the wider four percentage point ranges
for money and credit growth for this year and next.
Nonetheless, the demonstrated long-run connection of
money and prices overshadows the problems of interpreting
shorter-run swings in money growth.

I certainly don't want to

leave the impression that the aggregates have little utility in
implementing monetary policy.

They have an important role, and

it is quite possible that their importance will grow in the
years ahead.

Currently, the FOMC keeps M2 and M3 under careful

scrutiny, and judges their actual movements relative to
assessments of their appropriate growth at any particular time.

-18In this context, these aggregates are among the indicators
influencing adjustments to the stance of policy, both at regular
FOMC meetings and between meetings, as the FOMC's directive to
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York's Trading Desk indicates.
The FOMC also regularly monitors a variety of other monetary
aggregates.

At times in recent years, we have intensively

examined the properties of several alternative measures, and
reported the results to the Congress.

These measures have

included Ml, Ml-A (Ml less NOW accounts), monetary indexes, and
most recently the monetary base.
An analysis of the monetary base appears as an appendix
to the Board's Humphrey-Hawkins report.

This aggregate, essen-

tially the sum of currency and reserves, did not escape the
sharp velocity declines of other money measures earlier in the
1980s.

Its velocity behavior stemmed from relatively strong

growth in transactions deposits compared with GNP, which was
mirrored in the reserve component of the base.

In this sense,

some of the problems plaguing Ml also have shown through to the
base, though in somewhat muted form.

Moreover, the three-

quarters share of currency in the base raises some question
about the reliability of its link to spending.

The high level

of currency holdings—$825 per man, woman and child living in
the United States—suggests that vast, indeterminate amounts of
U S. currency circulate or are hoarded beyond our borders
Indeed, over the last year and one half, currency has grown

-19noticeably faster than would have been expected from its
historical relationships with U.S. spending and interest rates.
Although the monetary base has exhibited some useful
properties over the last three decades as a whole, the FOMC's
view is that its behavior has not consistently added to the
information provided by the broader aggregates, M2 and M3.

The

Committee accordingly has decided not to establish a range for
this aggregate, although it has requested staff to intensify
research into the ability of various monetary measures to
indicate long-run price trends.
Because the Federal Reserve cannot reliably take its
cue for shorter-run operations solely from the signals being
given by any or all of the monetary aggregates, we have little
alternative but to interpret the behavior of a variety of
economic and financial indicators.

They can suggest the likely

future course of the economy given the current stance of monetary policy.
Judgments about the balance of various risks to the
economic outlook need to adapt over time to the shifting weight
of incoming evidence; this point is well exemplified so far this
year, as noted earlier.

The Federal Reserve must be willing to

adjust its instruments fairly flexibly as these judgments
evolve; we must not hesitate to reverse course occasionally if
warranted by new developments.

To be sure, we should not

overreact to every bit of new information, because the frequent
observations for a variety of economic statistics are subject to

-20considerable transitory "noise".

But we need to be willing to

respond to indications of changing underlying economic trends,
without losing sight of the ultimate policy objectives.
To the extent that the underlying economic trends are
judged to be deviating from a path consistent with reaching the
ultimate objectives, the Federal Reserve would need to make
"mid-course" policy corrections.

Such deviations from the

appropriate direction for the economy will be inevitable, given
the delayed and imperfectly predictable nature of the effects of
previous policy actions.

Numerous unforeseen forces not related

to monetary policy will continue to buffet the economy.

The

limits of monetary policy in short-run stabilization need to be
borne in mind.

The business cycle cannot be repealed, but I

believe it can be significantly damped by appropriate policy
action.

Price stability cannot be dictated by fiat, but govern-

mental decision-makers can establish the conditions needed to
approach this goal over the next several years.