View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
11:30 a.m. CST (12:30 p.m. EST)
December 11,2003

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
World Affairs Council of Greater Dallas
Dallas, Texas
December 11,2003

Interest in issues of trade, tariffs, and protectionism has ebbed and flowed in this country
since our founding. The widened trade deficit of recent years, in the context of a prolonged bout
of job loss, has again elevated cries of distress to special prominence.
The sensitivity of our economy to foreign competition does appear to have intensified
recently as technological obsolescence has continued to foreshorten the expected profitable life
of the nation's capital stock. The more rapid turnover of our equipment and plant, as one might
expect, is mirrored in an increased turnover of jobs. A million workers leave their jobs every
week, two-fifths involuntarily, often in association with facilities that have been displaced or
abandoned. A million, more or less, are also newly hired or returned from layoffs every week, in
part as new facilities come on stream.
Related to this process, jobs in the United States have been perceived as migrating over
the years, to low-wage Japan in the 1950s and 1960s, to low-wage Mexico in the 1990s, and
most recently to low-wage China. Japan, of course, is no longer characterized by a low-wage
workforce, and many in Mexico are now complaining of job losses to low-wage China.
In the United States, conceptual jobs, fostered by cutting-edge technologies, especially
information technologies, are occupying an ever increasing share of the workforce and are
gradually replacing work requiring manual skills. Those industries in which labor costs are a
significant part of overall costs have been under increasing competition from foreign producers
with labor costs, adjusted for productivity, less than ours.
This process is not new. For generations American ingenuity has been creating industries
and jobs that never existed before, from vehicle assemblers to computer software engineers.
With those jobs come new opportunities for workers with the necessary skills. In recent years,
competition from abroad has risen to a point at which our lowest skilled workers are being priced

-2out of the global labor market. This diminishing of opportunities for such workers is why
retraining for new job skills that meet the evolving opportunities created by our economy has
become so urgent in this country. A major source of such retraining has been our community
colleges, which have proliferated over the past two decades.
We can usually identify somewhat in advance which tasks are most vulnerable to being
displaced by foreign or domestic competition. But in economies on the forefront of technology,
most new jobs are the consequence of innovation, which by its nature is not easily predictable.
What we do know is that over the years, more than 94 percent of the workforce, on average, has
been employed as markets matched idled workers seeking employment to new jobs. We can thus
be confident that new jobs will displace old ones as they always have, but not without a high
degree of pain for those in the job-losing segment of our massive job turnover.
The American economy has been in the forefront of what Joseph Schumpeter, the
renowned Harvard professor, called "creative destruction," the continuous scrapping of old
technologies to make way for the new. Standards of living rise because the depreciation and
other cash flows of industries employing older, increasingly obsolescent, technologies are
marshaled, along with new savings, to finance the production of capital assets that almost always
embody cutting-edge technologies. Workers migrate with the capital. This is the process by
which wealth is created, incremental step by incremental step. It presupposes a continuous
churning of an economy in which the new displaces the old, a process that brings both progress
and stress.
Disoriented by the quickened pace of today's competition, some in our society look back
with nostalgia to the seemingly more tranquil years of the early post-World War II period, when

-3tariff walls were perceived as providing job security from imports. Were we to yield to such
selective nostalgia and shut out a large part, or all, of imports of manufactured goods and
produce them ourselves, our overall standards of living would fall. In today's flexible markets,
our large, but finite, capital and labor resources are generally employed most effectively. Any
diversion of resources from the market-guided activities would, of necessity, engender a less
productive mix.
For the most part, we as a nation have not engaged in significant and widespread
protectionism for more than five decades. The consequences of moving in that direction in
today's far more globalized financial world could be unexpectedly destabilizing. A likely fall in
wage incomes and profits could lead, ironically, to a fall in jobs and job security in the shorter
term. So, yes, we can shut out part or all foreign competition, but we would pay a price for doing
so—perhaps a rather large price.
***
I do not doubt that the vast majority of us would prefer to work in a less stressful, less
competitive environment. Yet, in our roles as consumers, we seem to relentlessly seek the low
product prices and high quality that are prominent features of our current frenetic economic
structure. In particular, America's discount retailers have responded by learning to profit as
intermediaries between consumers and low-cost producers, whether located in Guangdong
province in China or Peoria, Illinois.
Retailers who do not choose their suppliers with price and quality uppermost in mind risk
finding themselves in liquidation. If a producer can offer quality at a lower price than the

competition, retailers are pressed to respond because the consumer will otherwise shop at the
retailer who does. Retailers are afforded little leeway in product sourcing.
If consumers are stern taskmasters of their marketplace, business purchasers of capital
equipment and production materials inputs have taken the competitive paradigm a step further
and applied it on a global scale. Understandably, as a consequence, trade discussions under the
aegis of the World Trade Organization have become increasingly contentious. After four
decades of more or less successful negotiations, the "low-hanging trade agreement fruit," so to
speak, has already been picked. Current trade negotiators, accordingly, now must grapple with
the remaining, more difficult issues, such as intellectual property rights and agricultural
subsidies. Debates over trade restrictions have understandably become far more confrontational
than in earlier years.
For example, a strain of so-called conventional wisdom has attributed the weak labor
market in the United States to the widening trade deficit, and a loss of jobs since the beginning of
the recession of 2001 to low-priced competition from abroad (often deemed "unfair") and
increased foreign outsourcing on the part of corporate America. In fact, as Council of Economic
Advisers Chairman Greg Mankiw recently pointed out, U.S. "job losses are ... more closely
related to declines in domestic investment and weak exports than to import competition."1 In
addition, of course, increased productivity has enabled ongoing demand to be met with fewer
workers.
Noteworthy is the singling out of a particular exchange rate, the Chinese renminbi, as a
significant cause of American job loss. The renminbi is widely believed to be markedly

-5undervalued, and it is claimed that a rise in the renminbi will slow exports from China to the
United States, which according to some, will create increased job opportunities for Americans at
home.
The story on trade and jobs, in my judgment, is a bit more complex, especially with
respect to China, than this strain of conventional wisdom would lead one to believe. If the
renminbi were to rise, presumably U.S. imports from China would fall as China loses
competitive position to other low-wage economies. But would, for example, reduced imports of
textiles from China induce increased output in American factories? Far more likely is that our
imports from other low-wage countries would replace Chinese textiles.
Despite the very large surplus of China's trade with the United States, overall Chinese
trade is much closer to balance. Chinese exports, a majority of which are from foreign-owned
firms or affiliates, many American, depend on purchases from East Asian companies that supply
inputs to the products the Chinese sell to the United States and elsewhere. Emerging Asia used
to manufacture many goods that were then directly exported to the United States. However, a
growing fraction of these goods are now partially assembled with capital-intensive,
high-value-added manufacturing in the rest of emerging Asia; exported to China, where final
processing is done—typically with labor-intensive, lower-value-added manufacturing; and then
exported to the United States. This situation implies a deterioration in the Chinese trade balance
Statement to the Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives, October 30, 2003.

-6with the rest of emerging Asia, along with a growing surplus with the United States. In large
part, the increase in China's share of U.S. imports has come at the expense of other East Asian
exporters.
China's imports overall have risen dramatically over this year, from approximately
$25 billion per month a year ago to $33 billion per month more recently, as China has become a
major consumer of the world's commodities. Doubtless, part of the recent firmness in
non-high-tech commodity prices is attributable to China's voracious appetite for raw materials.
* **
A rise in the value of the renminbi would be unlikely to have much, if any, effect on
aggregate employment in the United States, but a misaligned Chinese currency, if that is indeed
the case, could have adverse effects on the global financial market and, hence, indirectly on
U.S. output and jobs.
In order to maintain the tight relationship with the dollar initiated in the 1990s, the
Chinese central bank has had to purchase large quantities of U.S. Treasury securities with
renminbi. What is not clear is how much of the unquestioned current upward pressure on the
renminbi results from underlying market forces, how much from capital inflows due to
speculation on potential revaluation, and how much from capital controls that suppress Chinese
residents' demand for dollars.
No one truly knows whether easing or ending of capital controls would ease pressure on
the currency without central bank intervention and, in the process, also eliminate inflows from
speculation on a revaluation. Many in China, however, fear that an immediate ending of controls

-7could induce capital outflows large enough to destabilize the nation's fragile banking system.
Others believe that decontrol, but at a gradual pace, could conceivably temper such concerns.
Central bank purchases of dollars, unless offset, threaten an excess of so-called
high-powered money expansion and consequent overheating of the Chinese economy. The
Chinese central bank this year has indeed offset, that is, sterilized, much of its heavy dollar
purchases by reducing its loans to commercial banks, by selling bonds, and by increasing reserve
requirements. But currency and commercial bank reserves have been rising enough to support a
growth of the money supply well in excess of a 20 percent annual rate so far this year. Should
this pattern continue, the central bank will be confronted with the choice of an overheated
economy, with its potential recessionary consequences, or a curtailing of dollar asset purchases.
The latter presumably would allow the renminbi to appreciate against the dollar.
China has become an important addition to the global trading system. A prosperous
China will bring substantial positive benefits to the rest of the trading world. It is, thus,
important to all of us that they succeed in navigating through their current economic and
financial imbalances.
***
The challenges represented by China's large surplus with the United States and the efforts
to repair a recent breach in the current round of trade negotiations have engaged the attention of
policymakers worldwide. But these are subplots in a much larger debate about the benefits and
costs of expanding globalization.
At the risk of oversimplification, I would separate the parties in that debate into three
groups. First, there are those who believe that relatively unfettered capitalism is the only

-8economic organization consistent with individual and political freedom. In a second group are
those who accept capitalism as the only practical means to achieve higher standards of living but
who are disturbed by the seeming incivility of many market practices and outcomes. In very
broad terms, the prevalence with which one encounters allegations of incivility defines an
important difference in economic views that distinguishes the United States from continental
Europe-two peoples having deeply similar roots in political freedom and democracy.
A more pronounced distinction separates both of these groups from a third group, which
views societal organization based on the profit motive and corporate culture as fundamentally
immoral.
This group questions, in particular, whether the distribution of wealth that results from
greater economic interactions among countries is, in some sense, "fair." Here terms such as
"exploitation," "subversion of democratic choice," and other value-charged notions dominate the
debate. These terms too often substitute for a rigorous discussion of the difficult tradeoffs that
we confront in advancing the economic welfare of our nations. Such an antipathy to "corporate
culture" has sent tens of thousands into the streets to protest what they see as "exploitive
capitalism" in its most visible form—the increased globalization of our economies.
As solutions to these alleged failures of globalization, dissidents frequently appear to
favor politically imposed systems, employing the power of the state to override the outcomes
arrived at through voluntary exchange. The historical record of such approaches does not offer
much encouragement. One would be hard pressed to cite examples of free and prosperous
societies that suppressed the marketplace.
***

-9Setting aside the arguments of the protesters, even among those committed to
market-oriented economies, important differences remain about capitalism and the role of
globalization. These differences are captured most clearly for me in a soliloquy attributed to a
prominent European leader several years ago. He asked, "What is the market? It is the law of
the jungle, the law of nature. And what is civilization? It is the struggle against nature." While
acknowledging the ability of competition to promote growth, many such observers, nonetheless,
remain concerned that economic actors, to achieve that growth, are required to behave in a
manner governed by the law of the jungle.
In contrast to these skeptical views, others argue for the ethical merits of market-driven
outcomes posited on the value preferences of individuals as reflected in their choices in a free
marketplace. The ultimate arbiter of an economy's ethics is, or should be, the material welfare of
the individuals in a society. The crux of the largely laissez-faire argument is that, because
unencumbered competitive markets reflect the value preferences of consumers, the resulting
price signals direct a nation's savings into those capital assets that maximize the production of
goods and services most valued by consumers. Wages, profits, and other sources of income are
determined, for the most part, by how successfully the participants in an economy contribute to
the welfare of consumers.
Clearly not all activities undertaken in markets are civil. Many, though legal, are
decidedly unsavory. Violation of law and breaches of trust do undermine the efficiency of
markets. But the legal foundations and the discipline of the marketplace are sufficiently rooted in
a rule of law to limit these aberrations. It is instructive that despite the egregious breaches of

-10trust in recent years by a number of the nation's business and financial leaders, productivity, an
important metric of corporate efficiency, has accelerated.
On net, vigorous economic competition over the years has produced a significant rise in
the quality of life for the vast majority of the population in market-oriented economies, including
those at the bottom of the income distribution.
The highly competitive free market paradigm, however, is viewed by many at the other
end of the philosophical spectrum as obsessively materialistic and largely lacking in meaningful
cultural values. This view gained adherents with the recent uncovering of much scandalous
business behavior during the boom years of the 1990s.
But is there a simple tradeoff between civil conduct, as defined by those who find raw
competitive behavior demeaning, and the quality of material life they, nonetheless, seek? It is
not obvious that such a tradeoff exists in any meaningful sense when viewed from a longer-term
perspective.
During the past century, for example, economic growth created resources far in excess of
those required to maintain subsistence. That surplus in democratic capitalist societies has been,
in large measure, employed to improve the quality of life along many dimensions. To cite a short
list: (1) greater longevity, owing first to the widespread development of clean, potable water and
later to rapid advances in medical technology; (2) a universal system of education that enabled
greatly increased social mobility; (3) vastly improved conditions of work; and (4) the ability to
enhance our environment by setting aside natural resources rather than having to employ them to
sustain a minimum level of subsistence. At a fundamental level, Americans have used the

-11substantial increases in wealth generated by our market-driven economy to purchase what many
would view as greater civility.
* **
Debates on the pros and cons of market capitalism have waged for generations. The
collapse of the Soviet empire, and with it central planning, has left market capitalism as the
principal, but not universally revered, model of economic organization.
The vigorous debates on how economies should be organized and by what rules
individuals' trading should be governed surfaced most prominently in the latter part of the
eighteenth century. Those debates appear destined to continue through the twenty-first century
and presumably beyond.