View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:45 p.m. EDT
April 5, 2000

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
White House Conference on the New Economy
Washington, D.C.
April 5, 2000

It has become increasingly difficult to deny that something profoundly different from the
typical postwar business cycle has emerged in recent years. Not only has the expansion reached
record length, but it has done so with far stronger-than-expected economic growth. Most
remarkably, inflation has remained subdued in the face of labor markets tighter than any we have
experienced in a generation.
While there are various competing explanations for an economy that is in many respects
without precedent in our annals, the most compelling appears to be the extraordinary surge in
technological innovation that developed through the latter decades of the last century. In the
early 1990s, with little advance notice, those innovations began to offer sharply higher
prospective returns on investment than had prevailed in earlier decades.
The first sign of the shift was the sharp rise in capital investment orders, especially for
high-tech equipment, in 1993. This was unusual for a cyclical expansion because it occurred a
full two years after the trough of the 1991 recession.
By 1995, the investment boom had gathered momentum, suggesting that earlier
expectations of elevated profitability had not been disappointed. In that year, with inflation
falling, domestic operating profit margins started to rise, indicating that increases in unit costs
were slowing. These developments signaled that productivity growth was probably beginning to
move higher, even though official data, hobbled by statistical problems, failed to provide any
confirmation. Now, five years later, there can be little doubt that not only has productivity
growth picked up from its rather tepid pace during the preceding quarter century but that the
growth rate has continued to rise, with scant evidence that it is about to crest.

-2-

The acceleration of productivity stemming from the investment boom has held cost
increases in check. Despite the surge in demand, unit labor costs over the past year have barely
budged, and pricing power has remained well contained. Apparently, firms hesitate to raise prices
for fear that their competitors will be able to wrest market share from them by employing new
investments to produce at lower costs.
Indeed, the increasing availability of labor-saving equipment and software, at declining
relative prices and with improving delivery lead times, is arguably at the root of the loss of
business pricing power in recent years. To be sure, marked increases in available global capacity
and the deregulation of key industries have removed bottlenecks and increased the competitive
supply response of many economies, especially ours, and these developments have been
influential in suppressing price increases.
It would be an exaggeration to imply that, whenever a potential cost increase emerges on
the horizon, a capital investment is available to quell it. Yet the veritable explosion of spending
on high-tech equipment and software, which has raised the growth of the capital stock
dramatically over the past five years, could hardly have occurred without a large increase in the
pool of profitable projects available to business planners.
As our experience over the past century and more attests, such surges in prospective
investment profitability carry with them consequences for interest rates, which ultimately are part
of the process that balances saving and investment in a noninflationary economy. In these
circumstances, rising credit demand is almost always reflected in an increase in corporate
borrowing costs and that has, indeed, been our recent experience, especially in longer-dated debt
issues. Real interest rates on corporate bonds have risen more than a percentage point in the past

-3couple of years. Home mortgage rates have risen comparably. The Federal Reserve has
responded in a similar manner, by gradually raising the federal funds rate over the past year.
Certainly, to have done otherwise—to have held the federal funds rate at last year's level even as
credit demands and market interest rates rose—would have required an inappropriately
inflationary expansion of liquidity. It is difficult to imagine product price levels remaining tame
over the longer haul had there been such an expansion of liquidity. In the event, of course,
inflation has remained largely contained.
To be sure, the tripling of crude oil prices has left its mark on "headline" inflation rates
and inflicted considerable pain on some sectors of our economy. However, there is little
evidence, at least to date, to suggest that oil price increases have started to embed themselves
more broadly in the underlying cost structure of American business—that is, beyond the direct
effects of the higher energy costs themselves. Nevertheless, despite the very recent declines in
the price of oil, there are risks here that need to be monitored closely.
Given the persistent strength of private credit demands, market interest rates would have
risen even more were it not for the emergence of a sizable unified budget surplus following a
long period of chronic deficits. More recently, the Administration and the Congress have wisely
chosen to wall off the surplus in the social security trust fund and to allow it to pay down
Treasury debt held by the public. This action will surely contribute to sustaining the rapid private
capital formation we have experienced in recent years.
I see no reason that productivity growth cannot remain elevated, or even increase further,
to the undeniable benefit of American businesses and workers.

-4-

Achieving this outcome, however, requires that imbalances not arise to drive the
expansion off course. Only a balanced prosperity can continue indefinitely; one that is not will
eventually falter. A change in market interest rates is an important element of the balancing
mechanism of a market economy.
Some misalignments have arisen over the course of the expansion. Owing largely to the
increased rate of return on capital and a sizable wealth effect, overall demand for goods and
services for the past four years has been growing noticeably in excess of the enhanced growth in
potential supply, defined as the sum of the growth in the working-age population and
productivity. An increasing share of the goods and services required to meet this extra demand
has been supplied by net imports, with the remainder the result of an increase in domestic
production achieved by drawing down the pool of those we count as officially unemployed and
those otherwise available for work.
Short of a significant opening up of our borders to more immigration, an increase in
employment beyond the growth of the working-age population is limited to what remains of our
shrinking pool of available workers. Although the sum of the unemployed and those not in the
labor force but who nonetheless are available for work is still about ten million, the level has
been falling steadily. This year, the figure has been lower as a percentage of the population than
at any time in the history of this series, which goes back to 1970. Should the pool of available
workers continue to shrink, there is a point at which this safety valve for excess demand will
effectively close, even in the face of accelerating productivity. We do not know where that point
is, but presumably it would occur well before a full depletion of the pool of potential workers.
When we reach that point, short of a repeal of the law of supply and demand, the scarcity of labor

-5will almost surely induce a rise in hourly compensation gains that increasingly outpaces an even
faster productivity growth—a condition that would cause unit costs to accelerate over time.
Moreover, we do not know how long net imports and U.S. external debt can rise before
foreign investors become reluctant to continue to add to their portfolios of claims against the
United States. At that point, the safety valve of net imports could narrow or close.
It is conceivable that these two buffers can continue to absorb an excess growth of
demand over potential supply for quite a while longer. However, the significant uncertainties
surrounding these new economic forces counsel prudence. We need to be careful to keep
inflationary pressures contained: The evidence that inflation inhibits economic growth and job
creation is too credible to ignore. Consequently, maintaining an environment of low and stable
inflation provides the greatest opportunity for the dramatic increases in structural productivity to
show through fully into higher standards of living. In that regard, readings from financial
markets, despite their recent upheavals, suggest that participants perceive the most likely
outcome to be a gradual adjustment to more balanced noninflationary growth.
As I have argued previously, a substantial part of the excess growth of demand over
potential supply owes to a wealth effect, induced by the rising asset prices that have accompanied
the run-up in potential rates of return on new and existing capital. The rise in stock prices, as
well as in the capital gains on homes, has created a marked increase in purchasing power without
providing an equivalent and immediate expansion in the supply of goods and services. That
expansion in supply will occur only over time.
The persuasive evidence that the wealth effect is contributing to the risk of imbalances in
our economy, however, does not imply that the most straightforward way to restore balance in

-6financial and product markets is for monetary policy to target asset price levels. Leaving aside
the deeper question of whether asset price targeting is an appropriate governmental function,
there is little, if any, evidence that monetary policy aimed at achieving that goal would be
successful.
The risks of investing in equities come primarily from uncertainty about future earnings
and about the rates at which those future earnings should be discounted, and much less from
changes in overnight interest rates, the principal tool of the central bank. Consequently, even if
we were to foster somewhat larger movements in short-term rates to address changes in stock
prices, I doubt that investors' perceptions of equity risks would be much affected and thus that
equity prices would be meaningfully influenced.
In short, monetary policy should focus on the broader economy and on pending
inflationary or deflationary imbalances. Should changes in asset prices foster economic
imbalances, as they appear to have done in recent years, it is the latter we need address, not asset
prices.

In the economy overall, one result of the more-rapid pace of information technology
innovation has been a visible acceleration of the process of "creative destruction," a shifting of
capital from failing technologies into those technologies at the cutting edge. The process of
capital reallocation across the economy has been assisted by a significant unbundling of risks in
capital markets made possible by the development of innovative financial products, many of
which themselves owe their viability to advances in information technology.

-7-

There are few, if any, indications in the marketplace that the reallocation process, pushed
forward by financial markets, is slowing.
While growth in companies' projected earnings has been revised up almost continuously
across many sectors of the economy in recent years, the gap in expected profit growth between
technology firms and others has persistently widened. As a result, security analysts' projected
five-year growth of earnings for technology companies now stands nearly double that for the
remaining S&P 500 firms.
To the extent that there is an element of prescience in these expectations, it would
reinforce the notion that technology synergies are still expanding and that expectations of
productivity growth are still rising. There are many who argue, of course, that it is not prescience
but wishful thinking. History will judge.

Before this revolution in information availability, most twentieth-century business
decisionmaking had been hampered by pervasive uncertainty. Owing to the paucity of timely
knowledge of customers' needs and of the location of inventories and materials flowing
throughout complex production systems, businesses required substantial programmed
redundancies to function effectively.
Doubling up on materials and people was essential as backup to the inevitable
misjudgments of the real-time state of play in a company. Decisions were made from
information that was hours, days, or even weeks old. Accordingly, production planning required
costly inventory safety stocks and backup teams of people to respond to the unanticipated and the
misjudged.

Clearly, the remarkable surge in the availability of more timely information in recent
years has enabled business management to remove large swaths of inventory safety stocks and
worker redundancies. That means fewer goods and worker hours are absorbed by activities that,
while perceived as necessary insurance to sustain valued output, in the end produce nothing of
value.
These developments emphasize the essence of information technology—the expansion of
knowledge and its obverse, the reduction of uncertainty. As a consequence, risk premiums that
were associated with many forms of business activities have declined.
In short, information technology raises output per hour in the total economy principally
by reducing hours worked on activities needed to guard productive processes against the
unknown and the unanticipated. Narrowing the uncertainties reduces the number of hours
required to maintain any given level of production readiness. Because knowledge is essentially
irreversible, much, if not most, of the recent gains in productivity appear permanent.
Expanding e-commerce is expected to significantly augment this trend. Already major
efforts have been announced in the auto industry to move purchasing operations to the Internet.
Similar developments are planned or are in operation in many other industries as well. It appears
to be only a matter of time before the Internet becomes a prime venue for the trillions of dollars
of business-to-business commerce conducted every year.
Not all technologies, information or otherwise, however, increase productivity—that is,
output per hour—by reducing the inputs necessary to produce existing or related products. Some
new technologies bring about new goods and services with above-average value added per

-9workhour. The dramatic advances in biotechnology, for example, are significantly increasing a
broad range of productivity-expanding efforts in areas from agriculture to medicine.
Indeed, in our dynamic labor markets, the resources made redundant by better
information are being drawn to the newer activities and newer products, many never before
contemplated. The recent biotech innovations are most especially of this type, particularly the
remarkable breadth of medical and pharmacological product development.
One less welcome byproduct of rapid economic and technological change that needs to be
addressed is the insecurity felt by many workers. This stems, I suspect, from fear of job skill
obsolescence. Despite the tightest labor markets in a generation, for example, more workers
currently report in a prominent survey that they are fearful of losing their jobs than was reported
in 1991, at the bottom of the last recession. The marked movement of capital from failing
technologies to those at the cutting edge has quickened the pace at which job skills become
obsolete. The completion of high school used to equip the average worker with sufficient
knowledge and skills to last a lifetime. That is no longer true, as evidenced by community
colleges being inundated with workers returning to school to acquire new skills and by on-the-job
training being expanded and upgraded by a large proportion of American business.
It is not enough to create a job market that has enabled those with few skills to finally be
able to grasp the first rung of the ladder to achievement. More generally, we must ensure that our
whole population receives an education that will allow full and continuing participation in this
dynamic period of American economic history.

-10In summary, we appear to be in the midst of a period of rapid innovation that is bringing
with it substantial and lasting benefits to our economy.
But policymakers must be alert to the full range of possible outcomes. In the end, I do
not believe we can go far wrong if we maintain a consistent, vigilant, noninflationary monetary
policy focused on achieving maximum sustainable economic growth, a fiscal policy that
produces substantial saving to accommodate investment in productive capital, a trade policy that
fosters international competition through broadened market access, and an education policy that
ensures that all Americans can acquire the skills needed to participate in what may well be the
most productive economy ever.