View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:15 P.M., EST
February 8, 1994

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

at the
National Community Reinvestment Coalition
1994 Annual Meeting and Conference
Washington, D.C.

February 8, 1994

Good afternoon.

In dealing with the Community

Reinvestment Act, the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act,
discrimination in lending and other consumer issues, the National
Community Reinvestment Coalition plays a vital role in many of
the most pressing concerns facing financial institutions and
their communities.

Consequently, I particularly appreciate the

opportunity to discuss a few of the many issues surrounding the
provision of credit to low- and moderate-income people.
I have little doubt there are many in this audience who
have profoundly differing views from those of us at the Federal
Reserve on the way CRA should be interpreted and implemented.

To

be sure, I do not think we disagree on the central objective of
CRA:

to expand profit-making lending to all elements of the

community—including those that have been overlooked in the past.
I do believe, however, that we have significant
differences in certain of our approaches.

These are

disagreements mainly of process and effect.

By nature community

groups may be less inclined to trust market forces than we do.
You may view our caution with regard to the CRA reform proposal
as hostility, while we see it as prudent decision making.

You

may tend to see issues appropriately from your vantage point of
community development, while we are required to be looking at the
same questions in a somewhat broader economic context.

What you

may view as ultimately critical short term gains, we may often
see as counter-productive in the long run to our common goal.
grant we at the Fed may be wrong on some of this, but so may a
number of you.

The appropriate approach is debate in a

I

2
democracy, before Congress and in open forum.

I hope that my

remarks today will contribute to that process.
Let me first dwell on the Community Reinvestment Act.
As an economist, I suspect I approach CRA a bit differently than
many of you.

We economists tend to think that what makes good

market sense makes good long term social sense as well.

CRA can

be good business, and can meet that market test.
When conducted properly by banks who are knowledgeable
about their local markets, who use this knowledge to develop
suitable products, and have adequately promoted those products to
the low- and moderate-income segments of the community, CRA can
be a safe, sound, and profitable business.

This seems to have

been proven over the years of our experience since the law was
enacted in 1977.

CRA has helped financial institutions to

discover new markets that may have been underserved before.

That

has been its great strength.
We at the Federal Reserve have stressed this market
aspect of CRA and will continue to do so.

Activities developed

by banks to meet credit needs in low- and moderate-income
neighborhoods should be well-planned and thoughtfully implemented
within their overall business plan.

Banks should not try to

throw money at a problem or "just write the check"—that's not
using the market to anyone's advantage.

The latter type of

activity will not be sustainable over the long haul.

If CRA is

perceived by banks as a tax or credit allocation, it will fail in
the long run.

Banks are not philanthropic institutions, and if

3
approached with this in mind, they are unlikely to be substantial
reliable partners over time.

They are for-profit entities with

obligations to their stockholders, and subject to a regulatory
apparatus which protects their depositors from losses due to
unsound practices.
This is surely evident to most of you, but I think it
bears repeating, for CRA must meet the test of the market if it
is to provide the long-term benefits of revitalization that we
all desire.

It's worth reminding all of us—community groups,

policy makers and even bankers—of this fact from time to time,
since it's sometimes tempting to emphasize short term benefits at
the expense of long term commitments.
Nowhere have the benefits of sound community
development lending practices been more evident to me than on a
recent community tour which I took in southeast Washington, D.C.
There I witnessed low-income multifamily housing and retail
projects which have been financed by a local institution with a
professional, experienced community development lending group.
This bank has forged productive partnerships with local nonprofit and for-profit entrepreneurial developers.

The result has

been an impressive array of projects which provide housing and
retail services to large segments of a previously underserved
low- and moderate-income community in Washington.
the bank has been twofold.

The result for

It has attained a high degree of

visibility for these projects and they have realized a profitable
portfolio.

Yes, some of this was accomplished with the aid of

4
special government programs to fill gaps.

But on the whole, the

role of government was rather inconsequential.
What is uppermost in people's minds these days about
the Community Reinvestment Act is the proposal for revised
regulations.

As you know, the four regulatory agencies were

asked by the President to rethink CRA by placing more emphasis on
performance, rather than process and documentation.

I believe

that few bankers or community groups thought that the current
system was working at an optimal level.

The ultimate goal,

according to the President's request, is to "replace paperwork
and uncertainty with greater performance, clarity and
objectivity."

We are in full accord with this objective.

The proposed changes represent a major overhaul of the
current procedures and need to be closely examined.

The public

comment period ends on March 24, and if you have not already done
so, I encourage you to submit comments to the regulators.

We

will be looking very closely at these comments as we draft the
final version of the regulation.

There is certainly a wealth of

CRA experience represented by those in this room and I urge you
to share your perspectives with us.

These public comments weigh

heavily in agency decision making.
Rather than dwell on the specific proposal that has
been published, I would like to make some points which I think
need to be considered when the agencies adopt a final rule.
First, although it's clear that actual performance, not
procedures, should be the major emphasis in CRA, the agencies

5
must not cross the line into credit allocation.

By this I mean

taking into their own hands the decisions about the best use of
credit to meet the needs of localities.

Certainly this is done

by the Congress from time to time—for example, through the tax
code and credit subsidies.

But this is not, and should not be,

the role of banking supervision.

Despite its problems, CRA has

had a unique strength in that it has not been a bureaucratic,
Washington driven, program that substitutes "inside the beltway"
decision making by non-elected officials for the give and take of
local community control.

Yet it does seem clear that some

greater direction from the regulators is needed, and the question
is how that guidance should be provided.
This has been one of the most difficult issues that we
have tackled in this revision process—trying to maintain some
flexibility, yet further quantifying what is required for good
performance.

Centrally directed credit allocation by

administrative agencies would interfere with the flow of credit
to a bank's market, and runs the great risk of misallocating
funds and underserving some of the unique and critical needs in
your own localities.

I don't think you'll find any argument on

this point from any of the agencies, but it will be important for
all of us to remain vigilant to the risk of defacto credit
allocation that is not sanctioned by the Congress, at the same
time we are disavowing any such intention.
Second, quantifying CRA may be viewed as an improvement
in some quarters in that it would add some certainty for bankers

6

on their rating, and better allow community groups to assess
performance.

It would also make our examiners' lives much easier

by removing the need for them to make judgments on "how much is
enough."

In the public hearings which were held on CRA reform,

many bankers requested that we "just tell them what they need to
do."

Many community groups echoed this theme.

understand the desire for a clearer road map.

And it's easy to
However, complete

quantification could do more harm than good by removing
incentives for creativity in the implementation of projects.

By

allowing some judgment to remain, it increases the chances that
banks will look more closely at the specific needs of their
communities, as they are influenced by local groups, and develop
innovative solutions for addressing those needs.

A laundry list

of allowable activities may preclude certain distinctive
projects. It may cause banks to concentrate all their resources
on the more common projects which are known to get so-called "CRA
credit".

It would be most unfortunate if unique and well thought

out projects remain unfunded because they aren't on some list
that we in Washington have devised.
Third, let me mention a positive aspect of the
reexamination of C R A — a more direct recognition that CRA is not
just about housing.

Initially when CRA was enacted the emphasis

was on housing for several reasons.

One, the statute was passed

as part of the Housing and Community Development Act of 1977.
Second, the major community organizations which lobbied
successfully for the passage of CRA were mainly housing advocacy

7
and development groups.

Third, with the existence of HMDA data,

housing was the only area for which the public had quantifiable
data on an institution's performance.

However, the importance of

small business financing and development to low- and moderateincome communities and to our economy as a whole, cannot be
minimized.

The 1990 census data shows that about half of the

jobs in our country were contained in small businesses with fewer
than 500 employees.

I am glad to see that business development

is being recognized as a major issue in bank lending under CRA,
and I believe the proposed CRA reforms will assure that this
important area receives proper consideration.
We have tough work ahead of us.

Although there seems

to be common agreement that reform of CRA is desirable, there are
difficult decisions to be made.

Although data based, the rating

system being proposed will still—properly in my view—depend on
considerable examiner judgment.

We should therefore not

entertain false hopes of curing the ambiguity problem that
engendered so many of the complaints that prompted the review
process.

The core question is whether the new complicated

evaluation system will better advance the cause of CRA for all
concerned.

We will need to rely heavily on the comment process

for this answer, and again I can only urge everyone to
participate in that process.
Closely related to changes in CRA are the various
proposals for funding community development financial
institutions.

Without taking a stance on any specific piece of

8

legislation, as a general principle I think it is very important
to utilize existing financial intermediaries and institutions as
much as possible.

There are hundreds of excellent community

development organizations actively operating in our communities,
and many more with the potential to substantially increase their
contributions if they were given a little assistance.

In

general, in my view, we should support the capacity building
efforts of these existing organizations rather than trying to
create a network of new institutions.

Such a system could easily

become a second class banking structure that serves low-income
people, thereby removing the pressure on mainstream depository
institutions to recognize the benefits from serving these
populations.
Let me turn briefly to a matter of serious concern to
us all.

That, of course, is the specter of racial discrimination

in the mortgage granting process raised by the HMDA data, our own
research and enforcement activity, and findings of the other
agencies.

I know of few issues that need such prompt and

decisive action—on behalf of both the regulators and the
industry—as do the questions that have arisen about the fairness
of the mortgage market.
We simply cannot as a nation tolerate unfair and
illegal activity that puts some of our citizens at a disadvantage
as they try to participate in the credit markets.

We all know

that the raw HMDA numbers are not a reliable gauge of whether
discrimination is at work or to what degree.

But the general

9

story they tell cannot be encouraging to anyone, and is a strong
signal that work needs to be done.

We can debate endlessly the

fine points of the Boston Federal Reserve Bank study that sought
to go beyond the HMDA information, but we must not let this
obscure the fundamental findings that race alone appears to be a
factor.

I know from our own experience that identifying the

"smoking gun" in the examination process is a most difficult
undertaking, but that problem, too, should not undermine our
resolve.

The cumulative evidence seems clear to me.

We have a

problem whose magnitude may be unknown, but whose presence is
undeniable.
To be sure, much discrimination, perhaps most, in
today's society is subconscious, the result of habit and culture.
But whether it is deliberate or not, the consequence is the same.
Free market capitalistic systems rooted in individual freedom
cannot and should not abide such unjust behavior.

To the extent

that individual contributions to the market place are judged, and
rewarded on any basis other than economic values, the system
suffers, and the nation's standard of living is impaired.

We may

never reach perfection in this regard, but we should never cease
to persevere.
Let me assure you of the commitment of the Federal
Reserve Board to doing our best to deal with the difficult
problem of discrimination.

We are augmenting our examination

procedures with new more sophisticated techniques—building on
some of the statistical procedures developed in the Boston study.

10
We have been aggressive in our educational efforts with banks,
and have reorganized our complaint processing to bring all our
best efforts to bear on investigating any allegations of unfair
treatment.

These independent efforts are being pursued at the

same time that we are coordinating activities with the Department
of Justice, HUD and the other agencies.
But the solution to these problems will depend on a
very significant commitment by the industry itself.

We have been

encouraged by efforts of individual institutions to review loan
processing procedures, reexamine credit granting criteria for
unintended unfair consequences, institute special training for
loan officers, and establish second review programs.

All of

these efforts deserve aggressive support, and I would urge each
and every institution to undertake a self examination.
In closing, let me say that the existence of the
National Community Reinvestment Coalition—conceived to largely
represent the views of grass roots organizations — i s a welcome
addition to the Washington scene.

In bringing the views of its

constituent organizations to the attention of the Federal Reserve
and others, it is playing a most crucial role in the formation
of our nation's policy on the critical issues of economic
development.

Despite our differences, I very much appreciate

having the opportunity to address you.