View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
8:15pm C.D.T. (9:15pm E.D.T.)
October 19, 1995

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before
The Economic Club of Chicago
Chicago, Illinois
October 19, 1995

I appreciate this opportunity to address The Economic
Club of Chicago.

Your organization, founded nearly 70 years ago,

has a well-established reputation as a valuable forum for
discussion of some of the key economic issues facing the Midwest
and the Nation.

Tonight I hope to continue that tradition by

stepping back from the narrower concerns that occupy much of my
time to consider some of the fundamental factors that may shape
our nation's economic future, perhaps well into the first decade
of the twenty-first century.
Ancient soothsayers may have been able to penetrate the
future, but unfortunately they chose to vouchsafe precious few
tricks of their trade to today's central bankers.

The most

effective means we have for looking over the horizon is to try to
identify which of the forces currently driving our economy are
transitory and which are deep seated and likely to persist in the
longer term.
One major deep-seated force that we can identify with
some assurance is the trend toward an increasing conceptual
content of output—the substitution, in effect, of ideas for
physical matter in the creation of economic value. The roots of
this trend lie deep in human history, but the pace of such
substitution probably picked up in the early stages of the
industrial revolution, when science and machines created new
leverage for human energy.

Nonetheless, even as recently as the

middle of this century, the symbols of American economic strength

-2were our output of such products as steel, motor vehicles, and
heavy machinery—items for which sizable proportions of
production costs reflected the value of raw materials and the
sheer manual labor required to manipulate them.

Since then,

trends toward conceptualization have focused today's views of
economic leadership increasingly on downsized, smaller, less
palpable evidence of output, requiring more technologically
sophisticated labor input.

Our radios used to be activated by

large vacuum tubes; today we have elegantly designed pocket-sized
transistors to perform the same function—but with the higher
quality of sound and greater reliability that consumers now
expect.

Thin fiber optic cable has replaced huge tonnages of

copper wire.

Advances in architecture and engineering, as well

as the development of lighter but stronger materials, now give us
the same working space but in buildings with significantly less
concrete, glass, and steel tonnage than was required in an
earlier era.
The process is interactive.

The development of the

insights that brought us central heating enabled lighter-weight
apparel fabrics to displace the heavier cloths of the past'.

The

breakthroughs in medical research that have revolutionized health
care are only the beginning of a long and growing list of almost
wholly conceptual elements in our economic output.

Indeed, it is

perhaps the hallmark of our age that people are talking about
substituting computerized "virtual reality" for real-life
experiences!

-3These innovations are the extension of an established
and likely irreversible trend.

Over the past century, our

standard measure of output of goods and services, adjusted for
price change, has increased by approximately three percent per
year, but the actual physical tonnage of that output has gone up
significantly less.

The difference reflects the substitution of

impalpable concepts for physical volume.

The expanding

conceptualization of output has also led to a cumulative buildup
of productive capital, which has meant less labor input per unit
of output.

This is a key to increasing productivity and, with

it, our standard of living.
The process of conceptualization in output would seem
to have accelerated in recent decades with the advent of the
semiconductor, the microprocessor, the computer, and the
satellite.

Under the circumstances, it has puzzled many of us

that the growth of output as customarily measured has not
evidenced a corresponding pickup.

Of course, output may not be

measured correctly—a subject I shall return to later.

But it

also is possible that some of the frenetic pace of change is
wheel spinning—changing production inputs without increasing
output—rather than real advances in productivity.
A number of commentators, particularly Professor David
of Stanford University, have suggested that much of the wheel
spinning, if that is what it is, reflects the long time it
typically has taken to translate a major new technology into
increased productivity and higher standards of living.

For

-4example, electric power, an innovation of the late nineteenth
century, apparently did not fully show through in our
productivity data (and one must presume our productivity) until
the 1920s. Major infrastructure investments and other changes
were needed to realize the potential of the new technology.

The

same may well be true of modern information technologies: New
ways of doing business may be necessary to fully exploit the
computing and communications tools now at our disposal.
In any event, realizing the full potential of these
powerful new technologies is going to depend on the prevalence of
another fundamental of economic growth—competition.

We seem to

have learned in recent years that growth can be hobbled by
unnecessary or poorly designed regulation and by protection of
business through barriers to free trade within a country and with
other countries.

Indeed, the unquestioned lesson of the failures

of economic development in Eastern Europe after World War II is
that government central planning, was incompatible with a vibrant
economy.

It suppressed the forces of competition and, almost

surely as a consequence, stifled economic progress and growth as
well.

Virtually all of those countries are now endeavoring to

build free-market, competitive economies as rapidly as possible.
The incentives associated with a competitive market are
critical in determining the degree to which our endowments of
natural resources and human skills are turned into wealth.

If

market forces are inhibited, wealth creation is almost certain to
be disappointing.

-5It is almost surely the case that the development of
the computer industry has done more to enhance the efficiency of
American business generally than any other recent phenomenon.
While the early development of mainframe computers was heavily
concentrated in large corporate enterprises, the industry as we
know it today owes much to the subsequent birth and growth of
many smaller and more dynamic firms.
It is hard to imagine a more competitive environment
than that which developed around the scores of small, "garage"
based firms that advanced PC and workstation technologies and
created the software that was needed to make computers more
useful and "user friendly."

These firms have created an industry

that is the envy of our trading partners.

Many of these garage

firms went down the wrong path and fell by the wayside.

Even the

most successful remain vulnerable to the next successful
innovation by a competitor.

Schumpeter's view of creative

destruction is nowhere more evident than in Silicon Valley.

Our

world leadership in computing doesn't reflect any government
industrial policy; and fortunately, there has been no
constraining set of regulations that might have stifled it.
If our superiority in producing computer-based
technologies persuasively demonstrates the continuing vitality of
our economy, why does such a large part of our populace seem
discontented and insecure?

There are doubtless many reasons, but

the very pace of the conceptualization process I described
earlier may provide at least a partial explanation.

-6-

As computers and various advanced telecommunications
technologies have begun to dominate what it is we produce and how
we produce it, the average age of our capital stock has undergone
a significant decline.

Our current capital stock is becoming

obsolete far more rapidly than in past years.
The rapid turnover of this capital stock, and the
concepts embodied in it, has important implications for the
persons working with that capital.

To keep up, to retain their

full usefulness as operators of capital, workers are having to
retool their knowledge and skills to match the accelerated pace
of change.

Job insecurity has grown as significant elements of

our work force are being rendered technologically obsolete.

This

is clearly much more the case for older workers than their
children who seem to have adjusted to the "computer age" much
more readily.
Expanding globalization with its attendant increasing share
of merchandise imports may also be adding to a sense of increased
competitiveness and insecurity.

But globalization directly

cannot be a big player because it affects only a relatively small
part of our work force—factory jobs, which account for fifteen
percent of total employment, and some service activities.
Job insecurity, of course, is not a new phenomenon.
has always been prevalent in free labor markets.

It

But it appears

to have become particularly pronounced in recent years, perhaps
because the rapid pace of technological change, has occurred
alongside, and been associated with, the highly publicized

-7downsizing of many large corporations.

Overall job growth has

remained substantial despite these layoffs, but that seems not to
have relieved the fear of displacement.

And that fear has

doubtless played a significant role in the slowdown in the growth
of labor compensation as workers have in effect sought to
preserve their jobs by accepting lesser increases in wages.
While disciplined monetary policy is largely responsible for the
disinflationary trends of the last fifteen years, subdued wage
pressures have doubtless facilitated those trends.
There will eventually come a point, however, when
workers will perceive that it no longer makes sense to trade off
wage progress for incremental gains in expected job security.
The concern about job loss will not have diminished, but there is
a limit to how far it can go and hence to its effect on wage
increases.

At that point, efforts to achieve real wage gains at

least commensurate with productivity improvements may exert
pressures toward faster nominal wage increases.
Obviously, if an acceleration is accompanied by stable
inflation and hence a growth in real earnings, that is all to the
good.

But we have to be careful not to lull ourselves into the

presumption that somehow the institutional structure of the
American economy and its increasing globalization is permanently
suppressing inflation, and that monetary policy, as we move into
the twenty-first century, need no longer be vigilant against
inflationary pressures.

-8Also contributing to the prevailing dissatisfaction
with our economic performance is the unevenness of wage gains in
recent years.

As output increasingly embodies ideas, labor force

adaptation requires education.

Not surprisingly, there has been

a trend toward rising relative wages for those with higher levels
of education.

During the past fifteen years, the earnings of

college graduates have increased relative to those who are high
school graduates and, in turn, high school graduates have
continued to open up their advantage over those who are high
school dropouts.

In fact, an increasing minority of our labor

force has experienced real wage decreases, and surely this fact
has accentuated unease, despite increases in living standards, on
average, for our populace.
Clearly, we must focus on ways to improve the skills
and earning power of those who appear to be falling behind.

We

need to raise the supply of better educated workers if the recent
trend toward rising wage dispersion is to be contained.

In the

long run, better child-rearing and better schools are essential.
But in the shorter run, on-the-job training is a critical
necessity—to overcome the educational deficiencies of all too
many of our young people, and to renew the skills of workers who
have fallen behind the rapidly rising curve of technological
change.

It has become quite apparent that many firms have

concluded that it makes more sense to invest in such training
than to bid up wage scales in a zero-sum competition for the
existing limited pool of well-qualified workers.

The bottom

-9line, though, as I indicated earlier, is that individuals are
going to have to be prepared to maintain skills as new procedures
and equipment become part of a rapidly evolving economy.
Finally, the changing nature of output also has
important effects on how good our statistical measures are in
capturing the reality of economic growth and thus our perceptions
of it.

If we do not know how we are doing as a society, we shall

not be able to devise appropriate policy responses to changing
environments.

The proliferation of cutting-edge technologies is

making it especially difficult to measure how well or poorly our
economy is performing overall.
We depend on signals from the marketplace to judge what
is adding value and providing utility and what is not:

The

structure of prices and quantities that derive from free-market
interactions is a reflection of the relative worth of various
goods and services.

If people like what they are offered, they

will buy, sales values will rise, and the market value of the
capital assets that produce those goods will rise as well.
The aggregate market value of goods and services, that
is the Gross Domestic Product, is an especially useful measure of
our productive capabilities.

Its major component, gross business

product, is in effect the consolidated net sales of the economy.
These measures are not meant to be definitive measures
of the general well-being of a society.

Increases in crime and

pollution, for example, tend to raise the outlays to combat them

-10and hence to raise the GDP.

Depletion of natural resources in

the production process adds to business output and GDP.
GDP is strictly a measure of economic output and, when
measured against labor and capital inputs, a measure of
productivity.

Whatever its shortcomings, it is by far the best

proxy that we have for the growth in our living standards.
Our conventional GDP measures for recent years exhibit
some indications of a step up in productivity growth.

But, in

December, the Department of Commerce will officially shift the
focus to a new measure of economic growth.

In so doing, it will

adjust for one bias in the current measure and—all other things
equal—the result will be that reported growth in output and
productivity in the last few years will be shown to be slower
than current measurement formulas have been indicating.

I should

point out that the new output index has been calculated for some
time as an experimental basis; consequently, it should hold no
surprises for policymakers.

But unless there are offsetting

changes in the data owing to other revisions, new figures will
accentuate the seeming conflict between the official statistics
and what is suggested by the rather compelling reports of
productivity improvement we hear from American businesses.
leads to a broader question.

This

Setting aside the narrow technical

issues of our formulas for aggregating diverse output, are we
measuring the output itself properly?

Have we been capturing the

new types of value added which do not fall into our conventional
accounting categories?

-11We never had any difficulty in recognizing that an
integrated steel mill complex was of economic value, and it was
appropriately categorized as capital investment in our gross
domestic product.

And we could see the addition of a steel mill

or similar large capital asset at individual companies reflected
in a comparable increment to the book value of the firm.

The

stock market values of the firm tended, to a greater or lesser
extent, to match the book value that standard accounting
procedures constructed.

In recent years, though, the ratios of

market to book values of American companies have risen
substantially, and at a pace that appears to be faster than can
be accounted for by declines in interest rates and equity risk
premiums.

What appears to be happening is that the increasingly

important additions to the nation's capacity to produce, in the
form of new wealth-creating ideas are by convention expensed
rather than capitalized.
As a consequence, book values underestimate the true
value of an apparently rising proportion of our companies.

And

because such outlays are also expensed in the construction of the
GDP, it, too, increasingly underestimates the market value of
goods and services.

For example, capitalizing that part of

corporate software outlays that are currently expensed would add-probably significantly—to measured capital investment.

The

same would be true of similar types of outlays that are currently
expensed, such as those for research and development, some
technical work force training, and other conceptual inputs.

To

-12be sure, the net domestic product would not increase by the full
amount of capitalization, because a substantial increase in
depreciation is also implicit in such changed accounting
procedures.
Clearly, we should allow market valuations, where they
exist, to dictate what is capitalized and what is not, rather
than leave it to accountants and accounting practices.

It is

market values that generally reflect what an economy believes is
of value to it.

In this context, it is reasonable to conjecture

that our productivity and output have been growing faster than
our existing data imply.
Even with such adjustments, we may still not be fully
capturing the improvements in economic value and well-being that
occur as a consequence of the extraordinary innovations in
technology of late.

Arthroscopic surgery has significantly

shortened hospital stays and the quality of recovery from such
surgical procedures.

Supermarket check-out lines have been

speeded, as have the accuracy of computation and payment.

These

types of value added, which enhance the quality of life, are not
captured by our conventional national income accounting.
Similarly, while mobile phones, cable TV, and satellite
transmission are included, in part, in many of our measurements,
the greater opportunities that they bring cannot be appropriately
embodied in current GDP measurements.

Moreover, the innumerable

conveniences that have enhanced leisure and made day-by-day
living less onerous are not captured either.

While such factors

-13have always been mismeasured in our GDP to an extent, and there
is the possibility that some elements of our GDP are
overestimates, one gets the impression that, with increased
conceptualization the relative bias has been increasing.

The

implication is that, properly measured, economic output has been
growing faster than conventional measures suggest.
Moreover, as we move into the twenty-first century,
there is scant evidence that the nature and pace of change is
likely to slow materially.

To be sure, the most visible force of

recent change, the continuous downsizing of microprocessors, and
hence computer and telecommunications equipment, may increasingly
encounter physical limits.

But almost as surely, new

technologies will emerge, not now visible.
What we do know is that, excluding the sorrowful period
of the Dark Ages, human knowledge has rarely been lost, nor
technology reversed, and so one can presume that we will evolve
in the twenty-first century and beyond in ways not now
foreseeable.

We can anticipate change to be pervasive and, if

competitive forces are allowed free rein, and our fiscal problems
resolved, we can expect ever higher living standards for all
Americans.
Will Americans adjust to a frenetic pace of change and
allow it to happen?

While we have in the past, and almost surely

will in the future, it is important that we recognize that
adjustment is not automatic.

We have episodes in recent human

history where, for example, pressures of change were not easily

-14absorbed and people chose what appeared to be a greater degree of
security rather than competitive challenge.

Competitive forces

create uncertainty and dislodgment, but they also bring with them
an enhanced quality of living and the increased economic
abundance so necessary to confront the problems that exist in
societies throughout the world.
The advent of the twenty-first century will certainly
not bring an end to the challenges we are facing in a rapidly
changing world.

From my viewpoint, however, there are a number

of positive things happening in our economy now, that make it
more likely that we shall be well positioned to meet those
challenges successfully.