View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
12 15 p m EST
November 5, 1998

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Annual Meeting
of the
Secunties Industry Association
Boca Raton, Florida
November 5, 1998

This afternoon I intend to address a subject that ten years ago would have been sleep
inducing Today it is a cage rattler the structure of the international financial system
Functioning well, most participants take it for granted Functioning poorly, it becomes a vehicle
for financial contagion and a threat to the franchises of many in this room
Dramatic advances in computer and telecommunications technologies in recent years
have enabled a broad unbundling of risks through innovative financial engineering The
financial instruments of a bygone era, common stocks and debt obligations, have been
augmented by a vast array of complex hybrid financial products, which allow risks to be isolated,
but which, in many cases, seemingly challenge human understanding
The consequence doubtless has been a far more efficient financial system The
price-setting functions of the market economy in the United States, for example, have become
increasingly sensitive to subtle changes in consumer choice and capital efficiencies, and the
resulting set of product and asset market prices and interest rates have enabled producers to direct
scarce capital to those productive facilities that most effectively cater to consumer preferences
Thus, despite a rate of capital investment far short of that of many other advanced industrial
countries, the efficiency of that capital has facilitated the creation of an economy whose vitality
is unmatched throughout the world
These same new technologies and financial products have challenged the ability of
inward looking and protectionist economies to maintain effective barriers, which, along with the
superior performance of their more open trading partners, has led over the past decade to a major
dismantling of impediments to the free flow of trade and capital The new international financial
system that has evolved as a consequence has been, despite recent setbacks, a major factor in the
marked increase in living standards for those economies that have chosen to participate in it

-2It has done so by facilitating cross-border trade in goods and services that has enhanced
competition and expanded the benefits of the international division of labor Indeed, the growing
importance of finance in fostering those rising living standards, especially in the United States, is
the major reason the share of national incomes accruing to finance has been increasing since the
mid-1970s
Notwithstanding the demonstrable advantages of the new international financial system,
the Mexican financial breakdown in late 1994 and, of course, the most recent episodes in East
Asia and elsewhere have raised questions about the inherent stability of this new system
The Mexican crisis had many of the characteristics of earlier financial disorders,
primarily a very large current account deficit, but the intensity of the disruption, and certainly the
size of official financing employed to quell it, seemed larger relative to the underlying causes
than comparable previous episodes
Many of the more recent crises, from Thailand to Russia, have the conventional
causes-fiscal and trade imbalances, and/or imprudent borrowing denominated in foreign
currencies But again the size of the breakdowns and required official finance to counter them is
of a different order of magnitude than in the past This is especially the case when we consider
how outsized the distortions were in Latin America in the early 1980s, relative to the remedies
that were employed
But why did a relatively conventional slowdown in capital investments and capital
outflows to East Asia over the past year and a half induce such a wrenching adjustment in
individual economies and why has the degree of contagion been so large?

-3The answer appears to lie in the very same technologies that have brought so marked an
increase in the efficiency of our new international financial structure That financial structure,
which has induced such dramatic increases in productive capital flows, has also exhibited
significantly improved capacities to transmit ill-advised investments One can scarcely imagine
the size of losses of a single trader employing modern techniques that contributed to the demise
of Barings in 1995 being accomplished in the paper-trade environment of earlier decades
Clearly, our productivity to create losses has improved measurably in recent years
The system is thus both productive of increased standards of living and more sensitive to
capital misuse It is a system more calibrated than before to not only reward innovation but also
to discipline the mistakes of private investment or public policy-once they become evident As I
have pointed out before, the huge flows of capital into debt and equity markets, premised on
overly optimistic assessments of risk or returns, drove asset prices to unsustainable levels that
only worsened the subsequent correction
Hence, the recent crises, while sharing many, if not most, of the characteristics of past
episodes, nonetheless, appear different Market discipline today is clearly far more draconian
and less forgiving than twenty or thirty years ago Owing to greater information and more
opportunities, capital now shifts more readily and increasingly to those ventures or economies
that appear to excel
A measure of the broader sensitivity of current technologies relative to those of a bygone
era is reflected, for example, in the impact of "collars" on program trading on the New York
Stock Exchange In the aftermath of the October 1987 crash, electronic submission of index

-4arbitrage trades was suspended when the Dow Jones Industnal Average moved inordinately in a
day
Analyses of trading when that collar was in effect indicated that S&P futures and cash
indices converged far more slowly than when electronic order submission was permitted In
effect, we had an expenment in the comparative market responsiveness of a modern technology
and an older paper-based system that was used pnor to 1976, when electronic order routing was
first introduced The collar was revised in 1988 to allow electronic order submission, but another
anachronism, the requirement that these orders be executed only on stabilizing upticks or
downticks, now has the same effect
The faster reaction time has not only accelerated the pace of domestic capital flows to
ferret out the increasingly more subtle differences among investments, it has also markedly
accelerated international capital flows Cross-border bank lending, for example, has doubled in
the past decade Daily foreign exchange transactions have more than doubled and now stand at
$1 5 trillion
The cnses seem to reflect, arguably, an inability of people to come to gnps with the
vastly accelerated pace of financial activity-its complexity and its volume In the throes of the
1990s' virtuous cycle that propelled asset pnces higher and nsk premiums lower, the accelerated
pace of competitive pressures, until the cnses struck, was hardly likely to appear threatening
But the inevitable reversal engendered fear and retrenchment While this was evident in Asia a
year ago, it became particularly pronounced in the remarkable increase in nsk aversion and an
increased propensity for liquidity protection in both the United States and Europe in recent

-5months without significant signs of underlying erosion in our real economies, tightened monetary
policy, or higher inflation This is virtually unprecedented in our post World War II experience
In the wake of the Russian debt moratorium on August 17, demand for risky assets,
which had already declined somewhat, suddenly dned up This, in the United States, induced
dramatic increases in yield spreads across the risk matrix In Europe spreads have moved less,
apparently owing to widespread reliance on relationship finance Volumes in risk markets,
however, have declined sharply Even more startling is the surge for liquidity protection that has
manifested itself through significant differentiation in yields among riskless assets according to
their degree of liquidity We are all familiar with the dramatic rise in late September in the
illiquidity premium for off-the-run Treasury securities, or the spreads on government sponsored
agency issues
The surge toward less risky assets reflected dramatic increases in uncertainty, but still a
risk differentiation judgment among various assets The surge toward liquidity protection,
however, is a step beyond, since it implies that any commitment is perceived as so tentative that
the ability to easily reverse the decision is accorded a high premium Risk differentiation,
despite its recent abruptness, is, of course, a straight-forward feature of well-functioning capital
markets The enhanced demand for liquidity protection, however, reflected a markedly
decreased willingness to deal with uncertainty—that is a tendency to disengage from risk-taking
to a highly unusual degree
It is, of course, plausible that the current episode of investor fright will dissipate, and
yield spreads and liquidity premiums will soon fall into more normal ranges Indeed we are

-6already seeing significant signs of some reversals But that leaves unanswered the question of
why such episodes erupted in the first place
It has become evident time and again that when events become too complex and move
too rapidly as appears to be the case today, human beings become demonstrably less able to
cope The failure of the ability to comprehend external events almost invariably induces
disengagement from an activity, whether it be fear of entenng a dark room, or of market
volatility And disengagement from markets that are net long, the most general case, means bids
are hit and prices fall
Over the long run, perhaps, people can adjust to a state of frenetic change with
equanimity Certainly our teenagers seem far more adaptive to the newer technologies than their
parents and grandparents But I have my doubts that newer generations' human response to
change will differ in any matenal way from earlier ones That leaves us with the challenge how
can we harness burgeoning international financial flows in a manner that does not strain human
evaluation capacities?
First let me stipulate that capital controls, which worked in part to contain international
flows earlier in this post war period, are unlikely to be effective over the longer run given the
vast increase in technical capabilities to evade them But more importantly, should controls
nonetheless succeed, they would cut off capital investment inflow to an economy, and the higher
level of technology and standards of living that normally accompany access to such flows
Restricting controls to short-term capital inflows, as is often recommended, is not a solution
They will invariably also restrict direct investment that requires short-term capital to facilitate it

-7Clearly, to live with enhanced global finance, it has become necessary to find ways to
buttress our financial institutions to be able to weather the dramatic increase in capital flows,
both domestic and cross-border, before they strain human capacities
It has taken the longstanding participants in the international financial community many
decades to build sophisticated financial and legal infrastructures that can buffer the shocks of
such flows But even they, on rare occasions, run into trouble (for example, Sweden in 1992)
Those advanced infrastructures generally have been able to discourage speculative attacks
against a well-entrenched currency because their financial systems are robust and are able to
withstand large and rapid capital outflows of foreign currency instruments, and the often
vigorous policy responses required to stem such attacks For the more recent participants in
global finance, their institutions, had not yet been tested against the rigors of major league
pitching, to use a baseball analogy
Many emerging market economies have tried to fix their exchange rates against the dollar
and, in recent years, many borrowed dollars excessively, unhedged, to finance unproductive
capital projects Eventually their currencies became overvalued and their financial systems,
under the increasing strain of the unhedged debt, broke down
But such behavior need not undermine financial systems that are otherwise sound Last
month's unprecedented three-day weakening in the dollar, relative to the yen, reportedly as a
consequence of a large scale unwinding of the so-called yen carry trade, has not induced spasms
in the U S financial markets, nor for that matter in Japan, despite its severe banking problems
The heightened sensitivity of exchange rates of emerging market economies under stress
would be of less concern if banks and other financial institutions in those economies were strong

-8and well capitalized Developed countries' banks are, to be sure, highly leveraged, but subject to
sufficiently effective supervision that local banking problems do not generally escalate into
international financial crises Most banks in emerging market economies are also highly
leveraged, but their supervision often has not proved adequate to forestall failures and general
financial crisis The failure of some banks is highly contagious to other banks and businesses,
both domestic and international, that deal with them
This weakness in banking supervision in emerging market economies was not a major
problem for the rest of the world prior to those economies' growing participation in the
international finance system over the past decade or so Exposure of an economy to short-term
foreign currency capital inflows, before its financial system is sufficiently sturdy to handle a
large unanticipated withdrawal, is a highly nsky venture
A key conclusion stemming from our most recent crises is that economies cannot enjoy
the advantages of a sophisticated international financial system without the internal discipline
that enables such economies to adjust without crisis to changing circumstances
Between our Civil War and World War I when international capital flows were, as they
are today, largely uninhibited, that discipline was more or less automatic Where gold standard
rules were tight and liquidity constrained, adverse flows were quickly reflected in rapid increases
in interest rates and the cost of capital generally This tended to delimit the misuse of capital and
its consequences Imbalances were generally aborted before they got out of hand But following
World War I, such tight restraints on economies were seen as too inflexible to meet the economic
policy goals of the twentieth century

-9From the 1930s through the 1960s and beyond, capital controls in many countnes,
including most industnal countnes, inhibited international capital flows and to some extent the
associated financial instability-presumably, however, at the cost of significant shortfalls in
economic growth and misallocated resources There were innumerable episodes, of course,
where individual economies expenenced severe exchange rate cnses Contagion, however, was
generally limited by the existence of restnctions on capital movements that were at least
marginally effective, in that penod of paper-based transactions
In the 1970s and 1980s, recognition of the inefficiencies associated with controls, along
with newer technologies and the deregulation they fostered, gradually restored the free flow of
international capital prevalent a century earlier In the late twentieth century, however, fiat
currency regimes have replaced the rigid automaticity of the gold standard in its heyday More
elastic currencies and markets, arguably, have augmented the scale of potential capital
misallocation It takes discretionary countervailing--and often unpopular-policy actions by
fiscal and monetary authonties to make needed adjustments Where those are delayed,
imbalances build and market contagion across national borders has consequently been more
prevalent and faster in today's international financial markets than appears to have been the case
a century ago under comparable circumstances
The international financial system was not as technologically responsive then as now
Contagion cannot fester where financial interconnectiveness is weak or lacking
Moreover, contagion is clearly enhanced by leverage, and while leverage is not
demonstrably greater today than in earlier post World War II decades, the degree of leverage that
was viable then apparently no longer appears appropnate in today's more volatile financial

-10environment If financial asset prices are more variable, firms need to protect themselves against
unexpected adverse market conditions by having more robust financial structures New
instruments, like derivatives, afford the opportunity to reduce risk, but they also afford
opportunities to become more vulnerable Borrowers, lenders, and regulators need to improve
their understanding of the nsk characteristics of the new instruments under a variety of
circumstances--some extreme
As the financial system becomes ever more sensitive to change, consideration needs to be
given to discourage excess leverage by financial intermediaries worldwide The events of the
past year have doubtless already induced a readjustment in optimum debt-equity balance on the
part of all investors and borrowers Nonfinancial corporate leverage in Asia especially urgently
needs to be addressed Higher nonfinancial debt levels have significantly increased inflexible
debt service requirements, especially those denominated in foreign currencies Such trends have
been particularly instrumental in inducing financial system breakdowns in East Asia
Presumably, Asian borrowers will be less inclined to high leverage in the future Perhaps the
most effective tool to reduce leverage in emerging market economies is to remove the debt
guarantees, both explicit and implicit, by central banks and governments
Another challenge confronting the international financial system is establishing and
retaining more robust currency regimes
The defining characteristic of the latest set of crises is the extraordinary collapse of
exchange rates among emerging market economies Those adjustments brought such havoc to
balance sheets of both financial and nonfinancial entities in those economies that deep recessions

-11inevitably ensued The increasingly global character of investment--largely technologically
induced-spread contagion
Of course, at the end of the day the issue is not the stability of currencies, but the
underlying policies that engender stable currencies Open economies, governed by a rule of law
with sound monetary, trade, and fiscal policies, rarely experience exchange rate problems that
destabilize those economies to the degree we have seen in Asia Problems have ansen in recent
years when an economy without a history of sound finance endeavored to "rent it," so to speak,
by locking its domestic currency into one of the stable currencies of long-time participants in the
international financial system, such as the dollar and the DM There is nothing wrong with these
linkages provided the tied currency is set at a competitive level and is supported by sound
policies and flexible economies Too often they are not, with widespread consequences, as
recent history amply illustrates
In hoping to gain the benefits of sound economic systems without incurring the policy
costs, many emerging market economies have tried a number of technical devices the fixed rate
peg, varieties of crawling peg, currency boards, and even dollarization The success has been
mixed Where successful, they have been backed by sound policies
Even dollanzation, or its equivalent in other key currencies, is not a source of stability if
underlying policies are unsound It is questionable whether a sovereign nation, otherwise
inclined to economic policies that are "off the wagon," can force itself into "sobriety" by
dollanzation Dollanzation, fully adhered to, eliminates the possibility of costless pnnting of
money and restricts budget deficits to an economy's ability to borrow in dollars While dollar
currency circulating in such a country is credibly backed by the U S government, any domestic

-12dollar deposits or other claims are subject to the whim of the domestic government that could
with the stroke of a pen abolish their legal status Hence, dollar deposits in such a political
environment would tend to sell at a discount to dollar currency Dollar interest rates in that
economy could rise to debilitating levels, if fear of de-dollarization rose inordinately
Thus, there is no shortcut to sound fundamentals If we are going to have a sophisticated
high-tech international financial system, the lessons of recent years make it clear that all
participants must follow the policies that make it possible
There is already under way a number of initiatives that, if effectively implemented,
should significantly tighten international financial system discipline These initiatives include
endeavors to promulgate standards of bank supervision on a global basis, initiatives to markedly
increase transparency of central bank accounts, more prompt and detailed data on global lending,
compliance with codes for fiscal transparency, plus moves toward ensuring sound corporate
governance and accounting standards
Areas crucial to increased discipline, where consensus has yet to be reached, include
appropriate bankruptcy and workout procedures for defaulting private sector entities, new
arrangements for risk sharing between debtors and creditors, and ways to limit explicit and
implicit government guarantees of private debt
Central banks that fall short of the "best practice" requirements to be full participants in
the international financial system would doubtless be under exceptional pressure to improve
It is important to remember--when we contemplate the regulatory interface with the new
international financial system-the system that is relevant is not solely the one we confront today
There is no evidence of which I am aware that suggests that the transition to the new advanced

-13technology-based international financial system is now complete Doubtless, tomorrow's
complexities will dwarf even today's
It is, thus, all the more important to recognize that twenty-first century financial
regulation is going to increasingly have to rely on pnvate counterparty surveillance to achieve
safety and soundness There is no credible way to envision most government financial regulation
being other than oversight of process As the complexity of financial intermediation on a
worldwide scale continues to increase, the conventional regulatory examination process will
become progressively obsolescent—at least for the more complex banking systems
Overall, endeavors to stabilize the international financial system, and keep it that way,
will require perseverance
Until the current crisis is resolved, transition support by the international financial
community to emerging market economies in difficulty will, doubtless, be required But in
doing so we must remember that the major advances in technologically sophisticated financial
products in recent years have imparted a discipline on market participants, excluding a few
glaring exceptions, not seen in nearly a century Hence, the international financial assistance
provided must be carefully shaped not to undermine that discipline As a consequence, any
temporary financial assistance must be carefully tailored to be conditional and not encourage
undue moral hazard
Finally, there is somewhat of a silver lining, if one can call it that, in the debilitating set
of crises we have experienced in the past eighteen months First, while over the longer run, it
will be essential to have significantly improved systems to oversee lending and borrowing by
financial intermediaries, and incentives to dissuade excess leverage in general, in the short run,

-14there will be little need If anything, lenders are likely to be overcautious I remember at the
onset of the Amencan credit crunch of a decade ago, my joshing with one of my colleagues in
bank supervision and regulation about his going on a long overdue vacation I suggested he
could safely sail around the world since there was very little chance of bad bank loans being
made over the following year (I was concerned, however, whether anyone would make any
good loans either)
Secondly, some of the spectacular equity-driven Amencan and European capital gains of
the middle 1990s diversified as unproductive capital flows to some emerging market economies
Such capital flows, arguably a key factor in the crisis, are unlikely to be repeated in the near
future
That both excesses have likely descended into hibernation is fortunate since the type of
international financial restructunng that our new technologies require will take several years
Assuming we successfully resolve the current crisis, we will have time to restructure I fear only
that when available delay becomes evident, we will fall back into inaction, raising the stakes of
the next crisis