View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
8:00 a.m. EDT
October 11, 1999

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
Before the
American Bankers Association
Phoenix, Arizona
October 11, 1999

I appreciate once again being invited to participate in your annual convention.
The convention theme, "Creating Sustainable Competitive Advantage," is well chosen for
an industry that continues to be characterized by dramatic change.
This morning I should like to address one aspect of response to change—the
evolution of bank supervision.
As the theme of your convention suggests, the economic landscape is continually
evolving. To remain competitive, individual banks must adapt, and they have. It is no
less natural to expect that supervisory policies and practices also would evolve and adapt
over time. Banking supervision is responding, though admittedly not as rapidly as the
industry itself. This is not necessarily all bad. The physician's admonition "First do no
harm" is a desirable starting point for bank supervisors as well.
Nevertheless, significant changes are in the pipeline. Today I would like to
sketch the framework that is now being developed, growing out of work at the Federal
Reserve, at other U.S. banking agencies, and by our colleagues abroad. The outline of
this framework was presented in a consultative document released by the Basel
Supervisors Committee in June. The details are preliminary, but the concepts are
beginning to congeal and deserve your close attention, especially if you wish to influence
the eventual outcome of the deliberations.
The first concept I would highlight is that the scope and complexity of prudential
policies should conform to the scope and complexity of the bank entities to which they
are applied. This means, in practice, that few changes to the present system are necessary
for the vast majority of banks in the United States. More broadly, however, a one-sizefits-all approach to regulation and supervision is inefficient and, frankly, untenable in a
world in which banks vary dramatically in terms of size, business mix, and appetite for
risk. Even among the largest banks, no two institutions have exactly the same risk
profiles, risk controls, or organizational and management structure. Accordingly,

prudential policies need to be customized for each institution: The more complex an
institution's business activities, the more sophisticated must be our approach to prudential
oversight.
The need for a multi-track approach to prudential oversight is particularly evident
as we face the reality that the megabanks being formed by growth and consolidation are
increasingly complex entities that create the potential for unusually large systemic risks
in the national and international economy should they fail. No central bank can fulfill its
ultimate responsibilities without endeavoring to ensure that the oversight of such entities
is consistent with those potential risks. At the same time, policymakers must be sensitive
to the tradeoffs between more detailed supervision and regulation, on the one hand, and
moral hazard and the smothering of innovation and competitive response, on the other.
Heavier supervision and regulation designed to reduce systemic risk would likely lead to
the virtual abdication of risk evaluation by creditors of such entities, who could—in such
an environment—rely almost totally on the authorities to discipline and protect the bank.
The resultant reduction in market discipline would, in turn, increase the risks in the
banking system, quite the opposite of what is intended. Such a heavier hand would also
blunt the ability of U.S. banks to respond to crisis events. Increased government
regulation is inconsistent with a banking system that can respond to the kinds of changes
that have characterized recent years, changes that are expected to accelerate in the years
ahead.
The desirability of limiting moral hazard, and of minimizing the risks of overly
burdensome supervision and regulation, has motivated those of us associated with the
Basel exercise to propose a three-pillared approach to prudential oversight. This
approach emphasizes, and seeks to strengthen, market discipline, supervision, and
minimum capital regulation.
Market Discipline. In trying to balance the necessary tradeoffs, and in
contemplating the growing complexity of our largest banking organizations, it seems to

us that the supervisors have little choice but to try to rely more—not less—on market
discipline—augmented by more effective public disclosures—to carry an increasing
share of the oversight load. This is, of course, only feasible for those, primarily large,
banking organizations that rely on uninsured liabilities in a significant way. To be sure,
these organizations already disclose a considerable volume of information to market
participants, and, indeed, there is ample evidence that market discipline now plays a role
in banking behavior. Nonetheless, the scale and clarity of disclosures is better at some
institutions than at others and, on average, could be considerably improved. With more
than a third of large-bank assets funded by noninsured liabilities, the potential for
oversight through market discipline is significant, and success in this area may well
reduce the need to rely on more stringent governmental supervision and regulation.
The channels through which market discipline works are, of course, changes in
access to funds and/or changes in risk premia as banks take on or shed risk or engage in
certain types of transactions. The changing cost and availability of bank funding affect
ex ante risk appetites of bank management and serve as market signals of a bank's
condition to market participants and to examiners. But the prerequisite to the
enhancement of market discipline in conjunction with supervision and regulation is
improvement in the amount and kind of public disclosure that uninsured claimants need
about bank activities and on- and off-balance-sheet assets in order to make informed
judgments and to act on those judgments. Information on loans by risk category and
information on residual risk retained in securitization are examples. The best way to
encourage more disclosures is not yet clear. Our intent is to consult with the industry
regarding the establishment of new disclosure standards and ways to evaluate their
application.
Supervision. Improved public disclosure will, we believe, not only enhance
market discipline but also create further incentives for improvements in banks'

risk-management practices and technologies. Such improvements will enhance the
supervisory pillar of prudential oversight. If supervisors are comfortable with a bank's
internal risk-management processes, the most cost-effective approach to prudential
oversight would have supervisors tap into that bank's internal risk assessments and other
management information. To be sure, some "transaction testing" of risk-management
systems by supervisors will necessarily remain. But as internal systems improve, the
basic thrust of the examination process should shift from largely duplicating many
activities already conducted within the bank to providing constructive feedback that the
bank can use to enhance further the quality of its risk-management systems. It is these
internal bank systems—coupled with public disclosure—that provide the first line of
defense against undue risk-taking. Indeed, it should be emphasized that the focus of
supervision and regulation—especially for the larger institutions—should be even less on
detail and more on the overall structure and operation of risk-management systems. That
is the most efficient way to address our interest in both the safety and soundness of the
banking system and the overall stability of financial markets.
Relying more extensively on banks' internal risk-management systems can also
be used to enhance prudential assessments of a bank's capital adequacy. As the Basel
consultative document suggests, over time our examination process for assessing bank
capital adequacy would try to use the same techniques that banks are, and will be, using
to evaluate their risk positions and the capital needed to support these risks. To spur this
process in the United States, the Federal Reserve in June issued new examination
guidance encouraging the largest and most complex banks to carry out self-assessments
of their capital adequacy in relation to objective and quantifiable measures of risk. These
self-assessments will be evaluated during on-site examinations and, eventually, are to be
a factor in assigning supervisory ratings.
A key component of these self-assessments will be each bank's internal risk
evaluations of the credit quality of its customers and counterparties. Currently, such

internal risk ratings are beginning to be used by a small number of banks in their riskmanagement, pricing, internal economic capital allocation, and loan loss reserve
determinations. Some banks are further along in the process than others. Virtually all
large banks are moving in that direction. The bank regulators already have begun
incorporating reviews of these internal risk-rating processes into their on-site
examinations, and last July the Federal Reserve issued examination guidance on this
subject, including a summary of emerging sound practices in this area.
The supervisory policies and procedures being contemplated will build on the
increasingly sophisticated management and control systems that are rapidly becoming
part of banks' best practice risk-management mechanisms. They will, as well, require
both good judgment and sophistication on the part of bank examiners in order to avoid a
cookie-cutter application of policies and to develop skills at evaluation that will match
those available to the banks. For each of about thirty large, complex banking
organizations—in Washington parlance, LCBOs—the Federal Reserve has already
established dedicated teams of examiners, supplemented by experts in areas ranging from
clearance and settlement to value-at-risk and credit-risk models. Each LCBO team is
directed by a senior Reserve Bank official. Both that "central point of contact" and his or
her supervisory team will be charged with following one LCBO and understanding its
strategy, controls, and risk profile. Jointly, these teams will represent the Federal
Reserve supervisory pillar as it applies to LCBOs.
Minimum Capital Regulation. In addition to emphasizing more effective market
discipline and making supervisory assessments of bank capital adequacy more riskfocused, the June consultative paper highlights the need to make regulatory capital
requirements—the third pillar of prudential oversight—more risk-focused as well. In
recent years, it has become clear that the largely arbitrary treatment of risks within the
current Basel Accord has distorted risk-management practices and encouraged massive
regulatory capital arbitrage. That is, our rules have induced bank transactions that have

the effect of reducing regulatory capital requirements more than they reduce a bank's risk
position. Consequently, the fundamental credibility of regulatory capital standards as a
tool for prudential oversight and prompt corrective action at the largest banking
organizations has been seriously undermined.
In reflection of the considerable differences among banks that I mentioned earlier,
U.S. supervisors are developing proposals for a multi-track approach to address
modifications to the regulatory capital rules, and this approach has been incorporated in
the Basel consultative document. Within the United States, consideration is being given
to a standardized capital treatment involving a quite simple regulatory capital ratio that
might become applicable to the vast majority of institutions that are not internationally
active. For another group of banks, change might involve such modest refinements to
current capital requirements as closing certain loopholes and basing some risk-weights on
available external credit ratings.
For those comparatively few banking organizations whose scale, complexity, and
diversity warrant a more sophisticated approach to capital adequacy, the Basel
Committee has proposed another track that, at least initially, would seek to link
regulatory capital requirements to the banks' internal risk ratings that I discussed earlier.
Under this approach, the risk-weight assigned to a particular credit position would be
based on the internal risk rating assigned by the bank holding that instrument.
Regulatory staffs in the United States and other countries are currently attempting to
work out the basic architecture of such an approach. Critical issues include how to
validate banks' internal risk ratings and how to link risk-weights to these internal ratings
so as to ensure economically meaningful and reasonably consistent capital treatment of
similar risks across banks. This is an extremely difficult undertaking, and its success will
require unprecedented collaboration between—and among—supervisors and the banking
industry.

The Framework. It is, I believe, important to reiterate my earlier comment that
bank supervision and regulation—especially capital regulation—are necessarily dynamic
and evolutionary. We are striving for a framework whose underlying goals and broad
strategies can remain relatively fixed, but within which changes in application can be
made as both bankers and supervisors learn more, as banking practices change, and as
individual banks grow and change their operations and risk-control techniques.
Operationally, this means that we should not view innovations in supervision and
regulation as one-off events. Rather, the underlying framework needs to be flexible and
to embody a workable process by which modest improvements in supervision and
regulation at the outset can be adjusted and further enhanced over time as experience and
operational feasibility dictate. In particular, we should avoid mechanical or formulaic
approaches that, whether intentionally or not, effectively "lock" us into particular
technologies long after they become outmoded. We should be planning for the long pull,
not developing near-term quick fixes. It is the framework that we must get right. The
application might initially be bare-boned but over time become more sophisticated. For
example, it could begin with a limited number of risk "buckets" and, over time, be
expanded to include not only more risk categories, but also the use of an individual
bank's full credit-risk model—all within the same supervisory framework and unique to
each bank.
The design of the improved oversight approach is a work in progress. We are
endeavoring to develop a program that is the least intrusive, most market based, and most
consistent with current and future sound risk-management practices possible, given our
responsibilities for financial market stability.
***