View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
12 30 p m E D T
June 6, 1996

Remarks byAlan Greenspan
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
40th Economic Conference
of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston
Chatham, Massachusetts
June 6, 1996

I regret that I was unable to join you for the earlier
portions of this conference

I know that you've had some

important explorations of the process through which technology
contributes to economic growth

What I'd like to do in this

session is perhaps augment these discussions by shifting gears a
bit

I would like to focus on the question of how people

perceive the benefits of recent technological change
Today a truly puzzling phenomenon confronts the American
economy

I refer to the pervasiveness of job insecurity in the

context of an economic recovery that has been running for more
than five years, inflation that has been contained, and a layoff
rate that is historically quite low

Yet, in the face of all

this seemingly good news, a sense persists that something is
fundamentally wrong
This afternoon I want to try to explain where I believe the
insecurity is coming from and, I hope, raise some suggestions as
to how it might be assuaged
The issue, as best I can judge, appears to be rooted in one
of those rare, perhaps once-in-a-century events--a structural
technological advance

The advent of the transistor and the

integrated circuit and, as a consequence, the emergence of modern
computer, telecommunication, and satellite technologies have
fundamentally changed the structure of the American economy
Since the beginning of the industrial revolution, our
economy and, to only a slightly lesser degree, the economies of

- 2 our industrial trading partners have been progressing toward a
regime in which abstract ideas and concepts are the dominant
element in the creation of economic value

A hundred years ago,

physical brawn was critical to value-added determination

People

who personally could lift rolled sheet steel and help haul it
from one part of the plant to another performed an activity that
was valuable in the marketplace

Today, several generations

later, the structure of production has become, to a remarkable
degree, idea-determined
On the output side, at the turn of the twentieth century, we
produced steel, industrial chemicals, and heavy fabrics in
abundance, what impressed was the very size and bulk of the
productive facilities and the output itself

Today, the products

that we find remarkable are those that are lighter, smaller, and
in some cases, almost invisible

Our radios used to be activated

by large vacuum tubes, today we have pocket-sized transistors to
perform the same function
huge tonnages of copper wire

Thin fiber optic cables have replaced
In the past, buildings were so

over-structured and sturdy that, when their time for replacement
arrived, demolition was a Herculean task

Owing to conceptual

advances in metallurgy, engineering, and architectural design, we
now can create as much or more space with fewer materials
Indeed, such advances have created an overall national
output whose physical weight probably is only modestly greater
than that of whatever we produced a hundred years ago

Real GDP,

- 3 that is price-adjusted value-added, of course, is much higher
today, and by far, ideas account for the difference

That trend

will doubtless continue because idea creation is irreversible
Knowledge, once acquired, does not disappear
If anything, this process has accelerated in recent years,
and that acceleration seems to have had two important side
effects

First, it has had a major influence on the distribution

of income in this country, and second, a related but different
concept, it has imparted a degree of insecurity, uncertainty, and
even fear to a vast segment of job holders

The consequence of

both effects, as I will explain shortly, has been to create a
sense that something in the economy is awry, which is wholly at
odds with what the macroeconomic data seemingly imply--economic
success, tranquility, and progress
The roots of this puzzling situation go back a few decades
As ideas became especially valuable relative to physical activity
in the creation of value-added, education and intellectual skill
became increasingly major determinants of income

Throughout the

1960s and 1970s, the rapid rise in the number of college
graduates apparently kept the supply of educated workers moving
up with the demand

However, by the latter 1970s and into the

1980s, demand seemed to have outstripped supply, the apparent
consequence was a fairly pronounced rise in compensation going to
college graduates relative to the compensation going to those who
had only high school diplomas

A similar disparity of earnings

- 4 developed between those who had graduated from high school and
those who had dropped out
After the mid -1970s, productivity slowed quite markedly,
for reasons that are not wholly apparent, and so did average real
incomes

As a consequence, the widening disparity also means

that a not insignificant portion of our work force--primarily
those whose work involves less conceptual activities--has been
experiencing either stagnant or falling real incomes in the past
ten or fifteen years

A substantial number of these people

understandably feel that they have been on a treadmill and are
barely able to make ends meet from their incomes

That feeling

has engendered significant concerns about economic and financial
well-being among this part of our work force
I suspect that other concerns affect an even larger
group--composed of those who have average or above incomes and
have been employed in their current jobs for a number of years
These are the people with higher skills, who interact closely day
by day with the high-tech part of our capital stock

Because

that stock, reflecting computer and telecommunications-based
technologies, is turning over very rapidly, the involved workers
have a high degree of uncertainty and insecurity about their
jobs

As one affected employee commented to a Wall Street

Journal reporter a couple of weeks ago, "Is

somebody getting

- 5ready to change my whole life for me?" 1

These workers perceive

the job skills that they have acquired through high school or
college to be increasingly open to competitive challenge One
must wonder how highly skilled, turn-of-the-century telegraphers
felt with the onset of the telephone or the skilled buggy-whip
craftsman with the advent of the automobile

Today, large

numbers of people have become so demonstrably insecure about
whether their skills will still be relevant in, say, five years
that they fear for their jobs
This insecurity is evidenced by the fact that they have
increasingly forgone wage hikes for job security

As a

consequence, the past few years have been a period of
extraordinary labor peace

In fact, 1995 had the lowest strike

record for a half-century

Moreover, labor contracts, which

historically almost never extended beyond thirty-six months, are
now sometimes going out five and six years, as people try to lock
in job security, often willing to forgo significant wage
increases in the process
This sense of job insecurity is so deep that many workers
are truly scared

Some fear that their skills will no longer be

appropriate for the future
meet in the future

Some fear their ability to make ends

Many appear truly concerned about a

prospective decline in their standard of living

Wall Street

Journal,

May 16, 1996, page A 16

- 6 This development is startling considering the overall state
of the economy suggested by the macroeconomic data

It is

certainly the case that average real income has slowed and that
the disparity in real incomes has widened

After reaching a

postwar low in the late 1960s, income disparities, as measured by
Gini coefficients, climbed steadily through 1994--the most recent
year for which data are available

Moreover, disparities in the

distribution of wealth (net worth) as measured by the Federal
Reserve's Survey of Consumer Finances also widened significantly
between the surveys taken in 1963 and 1992, with much of that
increase in Gini coefficients occurring during the 1980s
Doubtless, that disparity has widened further in recent years in
the wake of major increases in stock and bond prices

But the

notion that the economic well-being of the lower-income segments
of our workforce has deteriorated as much as might be suggested
by the widening disparities in the income and wealth statistics
is open to question
I say this because there is a surprising difference between
trends in the dispersion of holdings of claims to goods and
services (that is, income and wealth) and trends in the
dispersion of actual consumption, which is, of course, the
ultimate determinant of material or economic well-being

Put

another way, well-being is determined by things people consume,
either directly from their incomes and accumulated savings or
indirectly from the stock of household goods they already
own--automobiles, telephones, TVs, VCRs, and so forth, not to

- 7 mention the homes themselves

And disparities in consumption and

ownership of hard goods don't appear to have widened nearly as
much as income disparities
I do not wish to disparage income as a partial antidote to
insecurity

Nevertheless, some aspects of economic well-being

may be more accurately discerned by examining consumption
A number of researchers have compared trends in the
distribution of consumption with the distribution of income
Many of these studies rely on data from the Consumer Expenditure
Survey that the Bureau of Labor Statistics conducts, and much of
the analytical research on distributional issues has been carried
out by BLS economists

A recent study by David Johnson and

Stephanie Shipp of the BLS finds that "income inequality is more
volatile than consumption and the level is about 3 0 percent more
than that of consumption inequality "2
These findings are not surprising

As is well known,

consumers tend to maintain their levels of consumption in the
face of temporary changes in income

Variations in asset

holdings and debt buffer changes in income

In short,

consumption patterns tend to look more like patterns in income
that has been averaged over several years, rather than the oneyear convention of our statistics

2

David Johnson and Stephanie Shipp, "Changing Inequality in the U S
from 1980-1994 A Consumption Viewpoint," manuscript, Bureau of Labor
Statistics, January 1996, and U S Department of Labor, Report on the American
Workforce, 1995

But, besides finding differences in the levels of
consumption and income inequality, Johnson and Shipp find
differences in the inequality trends

In particular, although

consumption inequality has increased, on average, since 1981, the
rise has been only three-fourths as large as that of income
inequality (see table 1)

3

An evaluation that views consumption not in terms of outlays
but, rather, in terms of the flow of services that come from
purchases indicates an additional qualification

The reason, of

course, for examining the flow of services from spending, and not
just current-period spending alone, is that while outlays for
food and haircuts, for example, are consumed immediately, a
television set that is purchased today provides entertainment
over its entire service life

Thus, unless ownership of

household appliances and other consumer durables is brought into
the evaluation, the story of the dispersion of material wellbeing is incomplete
What do the numbers

show?

During the 1960s and 1970s, the

real net stock of consumer durables per household increased an
average of 3 1 percent per year

The average growth rate has

slowed slightly since then--to a pace of 2-1/2 percent--but all
of that slowing occurred during the recessions of 1980 and
1981-82

Indeed, since 1982 households have been adding to their

3
The Gini coefficients for consumption and income that are reported on
table 1 are based on annual average data

- 9 stock of durables at an annual rate per household of 3 3
percent--slightly faster than in the 'sixties and 'seventies

4

Moreover, we have apparently not had a widening disparity in
holdings of hard assets like the one that appears in the income
and wealth data

Stephanie Shipp and her colleagues in the

Division of Consumer Expenditure Surveys at the BLS generously
provided the Board's staff with detailed tabulations of the
ownership of consumer goods and vehicles by income decile

To be

sure, these data show that ownership rates for consumer durables
clearly rise with income

But the data also show that for motor

vehicles and a number of appliances--for example, dishwashers,
clothes dryers, microwave ovens, and even garbage disposals--the
distribution of ownership rates by income decile moved toward
greater equality between 1980 and 1994 (see table 2 ) 5
For some consumer goods we are moving toward greater
equality because the proportion of households with access to
these items is moving close to saturation

For example, nearly

all poor families have access to a refrigerator, stove, and color

4
The growth rate of the net stock of owner-occupied housing (measured
in 1992 dollars) per household was 2 3 percent annually from 1959 to 1979,
1 3 percent from 1979 to 1994, and 1 8 percent from 1982 to 1994
5

The calculation of the measure of distributional inequality used to
support this statement is described in the attached technical note

- 10 TV

In addition, three-fourths of poor households have

telephones, and nearly two-thirds have microwave ovens and VCRs

6

These encouraging findings are not without qualification,
however

As an example, for personal computers, which nowadays

are critical for economic success, the disparity in ownership
rates is quite large--around 10 percent for lower-income
households in 1994 compared with more than 50 percent for the
highest-income decile

And, even when most families own a

durable good or vehicle, the number owned by the low-income group
typically is less than that owned by the upper-income groups
For example, in 1994 lower-income families owned slightly more
than one color television set, on average, whereas high-income
families tended to own more than two

The figures for motor

vehicles are similar--slightly under one per household at the
lower end of the income distribution and slightly more than two
at the upper end

Nonetheless, even though the inequality in the

number of units owned per household is often greater than that in
the ownership rate, the degree of inequality measured on this
basis narrowed between 1984 and 1994 in a manner similar to the
shifts for ownership rates (compare tables 2 and 3 ) 7

6
Some of these data are taken from Kathleen Short and Martina Shea,
"Beyond Poverty, Extended Measures of Weil-Being 1992," U S Bureau of the
Census, Current Population Reports, P70-50RV, November 1995
7

Collection of data in the Consumer Expenditure Survey on the average
number of units owned per household did not begin until 1984

- 11 But, even if the number of hard assets per family were the
same for rich and poor, it is not evident how much this would
assuage the current deep-seated sense of insecurity that pervades
such a large segment of our workforce

Clearly, there is more to

economic security than owning consumer durables

In fact, the

very forces that load our households with every sort of gadget
come from an economy that apparently is changing too quickly for
many Americans to absorb readily
fear in all walks of life

Accelerated change fosters

It is a rational human response to

such an imperative
Finding a solution to such insecurity is not simple

If 30b

insecurity is largely a fear of skill obsolescence, real or
imagined, some way must be found to enhance skills

People who

believe that their skills are up to date and readily marketable
do not inordinately fear job layoffs
Bolstered by signals from the marketplace, education is
clearly increasingly becoming a lifetime activity

Resting on

one's skills as the world rapidly goes by will only intensify a
sense of job insecurity

Ongoing schooling and training are

becoming ever more relevant for the average worker
Fortunately, developing human capital is rapidly being
perceived by many corporations as adding to shareholder value
If ideas are increasingly the factor that engenders value-added,
then training and education are crucial to the expansion of
company value-added and profitability

- 12 As a consequence, corporate universities are emerging as a
growth industry in this country

A significant and expanding

number of companies require that employees attend class, say,
twice a week, at company expense, to augment their on-the-job
techniques

Moreover, there is a growing peripheral industry

whose basic product is to train company employees in the latest
technologies

Such trends should decidedly be encouraged

Hopefully, in that environment efforts to increase the
competitive skills of workers in the lower half of the income
distribution will succeed in narrowing income disparities
* * *
At this point it is unclear whether the particular current
surge of technology is peaking and will eventually slow down or
whether we are in its early stages

Much of this surge may well

represent more wheel-spinning than real increases in production,
as our subdued national productivity data suggest

Nathan

Rosenberg in his paper for this conference points out that
organizational changes and further development of complementary
technologies likely will be required before we see the
productivity payoff to computer technology

If so, as the

infrastructure of the economy finally adjusts itself to the new
semiconductor-based revolution, the rapid changes are likely to
finally become more evident in increased measured productivity
and growth

- 13 In any event, a new world is emerging

The twenty-first

century will be different--much more rapidly paced and changing
than any of us who have been around for a while have experienced
in our lifetimes

There will be a different America out there

Fortunately, job insecurity does not appear to be a problem for a
21-year-old who has experienced nothing else, and even less for a
6-year-old who seems to be far more computer literate than
grandfather
As a consequence, with the inexorable turnover of the
population, people will adjust

When we go through a period of

transition, inevitable symptoms of friction, uncertainty, and
fear arise

They will pass

- 14 Technical Note
The raw data on the ownership rates of consumer durables by
income decile are not in a form that can be used directly to
calculate standard measures of inequality ( e g , Gini
coefficients or mean log deviations)
However, William Cleveland
of the Board's staff suggested a transformation of the raw data
that allows one to calculate a measure of inequality that looks
like a Gini coefficient
This note describes the procedure
The first step is to transform the raw data into a discrete
probability distribution
In the case of ownership rates for
consumer durables, the calculation for a given consumer good is

where p1 is the fraction of all households that own the consumer
good who are in income decile 1, and r1 is the actual ownership
rate for the 1th decile
By construction, the sum of the p1' s is
equal to one
For goods that have ownership rates that are
relatively equal across deciles (regardless of the level of the
ownership rate), these probability distributions are fairly flat,
with values of p1 close to 0 1
For goods that are more
concentrated among the affluent households, the probability
distributions tend to rise across income deciles
The next step is to take the probability distributions and
create cumulative probability distributions (CPD) (e g , the
value of the CPD for the second decile equals p1 + p2)
The CPDs
look like Lorenz curves
The standard formula for the Gini
coefficient is then used to construct a measure of the degree of
inequality implied by the CPDs 8 These are shown in table 2
The calculation of "Gini coefficients" for the average
number of units owned per household in each income decile (u1) is
the same, except u1 is substitued for r1 in equation 1
These
"Gini coefficients" are shown in table 3

8
The "Gini coefficient" is defined as one minus twice the area under
the CPD
Although this statistic looks like a Gini coefficient, it doesn't
have all the properties of a true Gini coefficient
For example, a true Gini
coefficient must fall between zero and one, but the "Gini coefficient"
calculated here could have turned out negative if, say, poor people had owned
more microwave ovens than rich people

- 15 -

TABLE 1
GINI COEFFICIENTS FOR CONSUMPTION AND INCOME
Year

Consumption

Income

1980

0 291

0 365

1981

0 286

0 369

1982

0 299

0 380

1983

0 298

0 382

1984

0 307

0 383

1985

0 315

0 389

1986

0 326

0 392

1987

0 322

0 393

1988

0 320

0 395

1989

0 325

0 401

1990

0 325

0 396

1991

0 321

0 397

1992

0 331

0 403

1993

0 321

0 429

1994

0317

0 426

Sources Consumption data are from the Consumer Expenditure Survey, income data are from the Census Bureau

- 16

-

TABLE 2
GINI COEFFICIENTS" FOR OWNERSHIP RATES OF
SELECTED CONSUMER DURABLES
(By income decile)

Microwave ovens
Dishwashers
Clothes dryers
Garbage disposals
Motor vehicles
Freezers
Clothes washers
Refrigerators
Stoves

1980

1994

28
29
17
26
09
06
08
01
01

08
22
12
19
07
07
09
01
01

Source Based on tabulations from the Consumer Expenditure Survey
See the technical note for a discussion of the method used to calculate
the Gini coefficients

TABLE 3
"GINI COEFFICIENTS" FOR NUMBER OF UNITS
OWNED PER HOUSEHOLD
OF SELECTED CONSUMER DURABLES
(By income decile)

Microwave ovens
Dishwashers
Clothes dryers
Garbage disposals
Motor vehicles
Freezers
Clothes washers
Refrigerators
Stoves

1984
24
27
15
23
14
06
08
03

1994
08
21
12
19
13
07
09
02
02

Source Based on tabulations from the Consumer Expenditure Survey
See the technical note for a discussion of the method used to calculate
the Gini coefficients