View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
11 00 a m CDT(NoonEDT)
May 7, 1998

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
34th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition
of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
May 7,1998

Events in Asia over the past year reinforce once more the fact that, while our
burgeoning global system is efficient and makes a substantial contribution to standards of
living worldwide, that same efficiency exposes and punishes underlying economic imprudence
swiftly and decisively. These global financial markets, engendered by the rapid proliferation
of cross-border financial flows and products, have developed a capability of transmitting
mistakes at a far faster pace throughout the financial system in ways that were unknown a
generation ago Today's international financial system is sufficiently different, in so many
respects, from its predecessors that it can reasonably be characterized as new, as distinct from
being merely a continuing evolution from the past
As a consequence, it is urgent that we accelerate our efforts to develop a sophisticated
understanding of how this high-tech financial system works

Specifically, we need such an

understanding if we are to minimize the chances that we will experience a systemic disruption
beyond our degree of comprehension or our ability to respond effectively

We need it if we

are to continue to make progress in reducing settlement risk in foreign exchange markets and
to ensure a sound infrastructure for payments and settlement systems generally

And we need

it if we are to have confidence in our processes of supervision and regulation
In this regard, I intend to focus my remarks this morning on three related topics I
will start by examining the cnses in Asia, which, along with the one in Mexico just a few
years ago, provide the first evidence of how cnses anse in the new system, especially the
central role that banks play I will note that, while the support provided to banks by public
safety nets appears to be an element of stability in the new system, it has also been part of
the process that engendered recent cnses Next, I will consider why, if the existence of safety

-2nets can encourage crises, we continue to provide them Finally, I will consider possible
policy responses to some of the system's evident problems and tensions Put differently, can
we learn to stabilize our burgeoning, sometimes frenetic, new international financial system so
that we can realize its full potential?

Let me start with Asia In hindsight, it is evident that those leveraged economies
could not provide adequate profitable opportunities at reasonable risk in the 1990s to absorb
the surge in capital inflows That surge reflected in part the diversification of the western
equity markets' huge capital gains to a sector of the world which was perceived as offering
above average returns Together with distortions caused by a long-entrenched government
planning ethos, the flood of investment resulted-some would say inevitably-in massive
deadweight losses As activity slowed, burdened by fixed-cost obligations that were
undertaken on the presumption of continuing growth, business losses and nonperforming bank
loans surged The capital of banks in Asian economies—especially when properly accounted
for—eroded rapidly As a consequence, funding sources dried up as fears of defaults rose
dramatically
In an environment of weak financial systems, lax supervisory regimes, and vague
assurances about depositor or creditor protections, the state of confidence so necessary to the
functioning of any banking system was torn asunder Bank runs occurred in several countries
and reached crisis proportions in Indonesia Uncertainty and retrenchment escalated

-3 In short, the slowing in activity in Asia exposed the high fixed costs of a leveraged
economy, especially one with fixed obligations in foreign currencies Failures to make
payments induced vicious cycles of contagious, ever rising, and reinforcing fears
It is quite difficult to anticipate such crises Every borrower, whether a bank or a
nonbank company, presumably structures its balance sheet to provide a sufficient buffer
against the emergence of illiquidity or insolvency

The scramble by borrowers to protect their

balance sheets when this buffer is unexpectedly breached can lead to a surge in the demand
for liquidity that in turn produces a run on the financial system At one moment, an economy
appears stable, the next it is subject to an implosion of fear-induced contraction
In this context a preventive effort to lessen the probabilities of such crises arising—for
example, by bolstering the financial system's buffer through more capital or improved bank
supervision-may not in itself further insulate a country from crisis if financial institutions,
now faced with a lower cost of capital or lower spread on their debt, leverage away the
increased buffer

Indeed, one form of moral hazard is that an initially sound financial system

that attracts low risk premia could merely induce a ratcheting up of the risks that a nation's
borrowers choose to take on This is not to disparage endeavors to bolster financial systems
But we should keep in mind that some of the advantages of such initiatives could be drained
away by moral hazard
What is becoming increasingly clear, and what is particularly relevant to this
conference, is that, in virtually all cases, what turns otherwise seemingly minor imbalances
into a crisis is an actual or anticipated disruption to the liquidity or solvency of the banking
system, or at least of its major participants

That fact is of critical importance for

-4understanding both the Asian and the previous Latin American crises Depending on
circumstances, the original impulse for the crisis may begin in the banking system or it may
begin elsewhere and cause a problem in the banking system that converts a troubling event
into an implosive crisis
The aspects of the banking system that produce such outcomes are not particularly
opaque
First, exceptionally high leverage has often been a symptom of excessive risk-taking
that left financial systems and economies vulnerable to loss of confidence

It is not easy to

imagine the cumulative cascading of debt instruments seeking safety in a crisis when assets
are heavily funded with equity Moreover, financial (as well as nonfinancial) businesses have
employed high leverage to mask inadequate underlying profitability and did not have adequate
capital cushions to match their volatile environments
Second, banks, when confronted with a generally rising yield curve, which is more
often the case than not, have had a tendency to incur interest rate or liquidity risk by lending
long and funding short This has exposed banks, especially those that had inadequate capital
to begin with, to a collapse of confidence when interest rates spiked and capital was eroded
In addition, when financial intermediaries, in an environment of fixed exchange rates, but still
high inflation premiums and domestic currency interest rates, sought low-cost, unhedged,
foreign currency funding, the dangers of depositor runs, following a fall in the domestic
currency, escalated
Third, banks play a crucial role in the financial market infrastructure

A sound

institution can fend off unexpected shocks But when they are undercapitalized, have lax

-5lending standards, and are subjected to weak supervision and regulation, they have become a
source of systemic risk to both domestic and international financial systems.
Fourth, recent adverse banking experiences have emphasized the problems that can
arise if banks, especially vulnerable banks, are almost the sole source of intermediation
Their breakdown induces a marked weakening in economic growth A wider range of
nonbank institutions, including viable debt and equity markets, can provide important
safeguards of economic activity when the banking system fails.
Fifth, despite its importance for distributing savings to their most valued investment
use, excessive short-term interbank funding, especially cross border, may turn out to be the
Achilles' heel of an international financial system that is subject to wide variations in
financial confidence This phenomenon, which is all too common in our domestic expenence,
may be particularly dangerous in an international setting. I shall return to this issue later
Finally, an important contributor to past crises has been moral hazard, that is, a
distortion of incentives that occurs when the party that determines the level of risk receives
the gains from, but does not bear the full costs of, the risks taken. Interest rate and currency
risk-taking, excess leverage, weak financial systems, and interbank funding have all been
encouraged by the existence of a safety net The expectation that national monetary
authorities or international financial institutions will come to the rescue of failing financial
systems and unsound investments clearly has engendered a significant element of excessive
risk-taking The dividing line between public and private liabilities, too often, has become
blurred

-6-

• * •

Given that the existence of safety nets generates moral hazard, and moral hazard
distorts incentives, why do we continue to provide safety nets to support our financial
systems?
It is important to remember that, notwithstanding the possibility of excessive leverage,
many of the benefits banks provide modern societies derive from their willingness to take
risks and from their use of a relatively high degree of financial leverage Through leverage,
in the form principally of taking deposits, banks perform a critical role in the financial
intermediation process, they provide savers with additional investment choices and borrowers
with a greater range of sources of credit, thereby facilitating a more sophisticated allocation
of resources that appears to contribute importantly to greater economic growth Indeed, it has
been the evident value of intermediation and leverage that has shaped the development of our
financial systems from the earliest times—certainly since Renaissance goldsmiths discovered
that lending out deposited gold was both feasible and profitable
In addition, central bank provision of a mechanism for converting highly illiquid
portfolios into liquid ones, in extraordinary circumstances, has led to a greater degree of
leverage in banking than market forces alone would support Traditionally this has been
accomplished by making discount or Lombard facilities available, so that individual
depositories could turn illiquid assets into liquid resources and not exacerbate unsettled
market conditions by the forced selling of such assets or the calling of loans More broadly,
open market operations, in situations like that which followed the crash of stock markets

-7around the world in 1987, satisfy marked increased needs for liquidity for the system as a
whole that otherwise could feed cumulative, self-reinforcing, contractions across many
financial markets
To be sure, we should recognize that if we choose to have the advantages of a
leveraged system of financial intermediaries, the burden of managing risk in the financial
system will not be with the private sector alone As I noted, with leveraging there will
always exist a possibility, however remote, of a chain reaction, a cascading sequence of
defaults that will culminate in financial implosion if it proceeds unchecked Only a central
bank, with its unlimited power to create money, can with a high probability thwart such a
process before it becomes destructive Hence, central banks will of necessity be drawn into
becoming lenders of last resort But implicit in the existence of such a role is that there will
be some form of allocation between the public and private sectors of the burden of risk, with
central banks responsible for managing the most extreme, that is the most systemically
sensitive, outcomes Thus, central banks have been led to provide what essentially amounts
to catastrophic financial insurance coverage Such a public subsidy should be reserved for
only the rarest of disasters If the owners or managers of private financial institutions were to
anticipate being propped up frequently by government support, it would only encourage
reckless and irresponsible practices
In theory, the allocation of responsibility for risk-beanng between the private sector
and the central bank depends upon the private cost of capital In order to attract, or at least
retain, capital, a private financial institution must earn at minimum the overall economy's
marginal cost of riskless capital, adjusted for firm-specific risk In competitive financial

-8 markets, the greater the leverage, the higher the rate of return, before adjustment for risk If
private financial institutions have to absorb all financial risk, then the degree to which they
can leverage will be restrained, the financial sector smaller, and its contribution to the
economy more limited

On the other hand, if central banks effectively insulate private

institutions from potential losses, however incurred, increased laxity could threaten a major
drain on taxpayers or produce inflationary instability as a consequence of excess money
creation
Once a private financial institution infers the amount of capital it must devote to
ensure against, first, illiquidity and, finally, insolvency, the size of its balance sheet for
maximum rate of return on equity, adjusted for risk, is determined That inference depends
on the institution's judgment of how much of the tail of its risk distribution requires a capital
provision The central bank is presumed to respond to the remainder of the risk tail by
lending freely and reducing the danger of illiquidity Protecting private financial institutions'
solvency through guarantees of liabilities risks significant moral hazard
In practice, the policy choice of how much, if any, of the extreme market risk that
government authorities should absorb is fraught with many complexities Yet we central
bankers make this decision every day, either explicitly or by default

Moreover, we can never

know for sure whether the decisions we made were appropnate The question is not whether
our actions are seen to have been necessary in retrospect, the absence of a fire does not mean
that we should not have paid for fire insurance Rather, the question is whether, ex ante, the
probability of a systemic collapse was sufficient to warrant intervention Often, we cannot

-9wait to see whether, in hindsight, the problem will be judged to have been an isolated event
and largely benign
Thus, governments, including central banks, have been given certain responsibilities
related to their banking and financial systems that must be balanced

We have the

responsibility to prevent major financial market disruptions through development and
enforcement of prudent regulatory standards and, if necessary in rare circumstances, through
direct intervention in market events But we also have the responsibility to ensure that
pnvate sector institutions have the capacity to take prudent and appropnate risks, even though
such risks will sometimes result in unanticipated bank losses or even bank failures.
Our goal as supervisors, therefore, should not be to prevent all bank failures, as I have
suggested to this conference many times, but to maintain sufficient prudential standards so
that banking problems that do occur do not become widespread

We try to achieve the proper

balance through official regulations, as well as through formal and informal supervisory
policies and procedures
To some extent, we do this over time by signalling to the market, through our actions,
the lands of circumstances in which we might be willing to intervene to quell financial
turmoil, and conversely, what levels of difficulties we expect pnvate institutions to resolve by
themselves The market, then, responds by adjusting the risk premium addition to the riskless
cost of capital available to banks
• •+

To return to the question I raised at the beginning Can we learn to stabilize our
burgeoning, sometimes frenetic, new international financial system so that we can realize its

- 10full potential? What types of regulatory initiatives appear fruitful in achieving the benefits
and minimizing the costs of the new system?
In addressing those questions, I will confine myself again to issues related more
narrowly to banks in particular, to bank supervision and to possible ways in which the
behavior of individual banks could be improved I will not discuss the important issues
concerning the need for efficient bankruptcy procedures or for alternative means for
coordinating debtors and creditors, both in the domestic context in many countries and in the
cross-border context, that may be requned in our new system
While failures will inevitably occur in a dynamic market, the safety net—not to
mention concerns over systemic risk—requires, to repeat, that regulators not be indifferent to
how banks manage their risks To avoid having to resort to numbing micromanagement,
regulators have increasingly insisted that banks put in place systems that allow management
to have both the information and procedures to be aware of their own true risk exposures on a
global basis and to be able to manage such exposures The better these risk information and
control systems, the more risk a bank can prudently assume In that context, an enhanced
regime of market incentives, involving greater sensitivity to market signals and more
information to make those signals more robust, is essential
In this rapidly expanding international financial system, the primary protection from
adverse financial disturbances is effective counterparty surveillance and, hence, government
regulation and supervision should seek to produce an environment in which counterparties can
most effectively oversee the credit risks of potential transactions

-11 Here a major improvement in transparency is essential To be sure, counterparties
often exchange otherwise confidential information as a condition of a transaction

But

broader dissemination of detailed disclosures of governments, financial institutions, and firms
is required if the risks inherent in our global financial structure are to be contained A market
system can approach an appropriate equilibrium only if the signals to which individual market
participants respond are accurate and adequate to the needs of the adjustment process
Among the important signals are product and asset prices, interest rates, debt by maturity, and
detailed accounts of central banks and private enterprises I find it difficult to believe, for
example, that the crises that arose in Thailand and Korea would have been nearly so virulent
had their central banks published data prior to the crises on net reserves instead of the not
very informative gross reserve positions only Some inappropriate capital inflows would
almost surely have been withheld and policymakers would have been forced to make difficult
choices more promptly if earlier evidences of difficulty had emerged
Increased transparency can expose the prevalence of pending problems, but it cannot
be expected to discourage all aberrant behavior It has not prevented reliance on real estate
for collateral from becoming problematic from time to time East Asia has been no
exception

When real estate values fall sharply, as they do from time to time, such collateral

tends to become highly illiquid Removal of legal impediments to more widespread forms of
collateral and to prompt access to collateral would be helpful in dealing with these problems
It is increasingly evident that nonperforming loans should be dealt with expeditiously
and not allowed to fester

The expected values of the losses on these loans are, of course, a

subtraction from capital But since these estimates are uncertain, they embody an additional

- 12risk premium that further reduces the market's best estimate of the size of effective equity
capital Funding becomes more difficult

Partly reflecting uncertainties with respect to their

nonperforming loans, Japanese banks in London, for example, are currently required to pay
about a 15 basis point add-on over what markets require for major western banks for shortterm deposits denominated in yen It is, hence, far better to remove these dubious assets and
their associated risk premium from bank balance sheets, and dispose of them separately,
preferably promptly
A predicate to addressing nonperforming loans expeditiously is better and more
forceful supervision, which requires more knowledgeable bank examiners than, unfortunately,
many economies enjoy In all countries, we need independent bank examiners who
understand banking and business risk, who could in effect, make sound loans themselves
because they understand the process Similarly, we need loan officers at banks that
understand their customers' business-loan officers that could, in effect, step into the shoes of
their customers Lack of a cadre of loan officers who have experience in judging lending risk
can produce debilitating losses even when lending is not directed by government inducement
or the need to support members of an associated group of companies Experienced bank
supervision cannot fully substitute for poor lending procedures, but presumably it could
encourage better practice Apparently even that has been lacking in many economies And
training personnel and developing adequate supervisory systems will take time
I pointed earlier to cross-border interbank funding as potentially the Achilles' heel of
the international financial system Creditor banks expect claims on banks, especially banks in
emerging economies, to be protected by a safety net and, consequently, consider them to be

- 13essentially sovereign claims Unless those expectations are substantially altered—as when
banks actually incur significant losses—governments can be faced with the choice either of
validating those expectations or of risking serious disruption to payments systems and to
financial markets in general
Arguably expectations of safety net support have increased the level of cross border
interbank lending from that which would be supported by unsubsidized markets themselves
This would suggest resource misallocation Accordingly, it might be useful to consider ways
in which some added discipline could be imposed on the interbank market

Such discipline,

in principle, could be imposed on either debtor or creditor banks For example, capital
requirements could be raised on borrowing banks by making the required level of capital
dependent not just on the nature of the banks' assets but also on the nature of their funding
An increase in required capital can be thought of as providing a larger cushion for the
sovereign guarantor in the event of a bank's failure

That is, it would shift more of the

burden of the failure onto the private sector Alternatively, the issue of moral hazard in
interbank markets could be addressed by charging banks for the existence of the sovereign
guarantee, particularly in more vulnerable countries where that guarantee is more likely to be
called upon and whose cost might deter some aberrant borrowing For example, sovereigns
could charge an explicit premium, or could impose reserve requirements, earning low or even
zero interest rates, on interbank liabilities
Increasing the capital charge on lending banks, instead of on borrowing banks, might
also be effective

Under the Basle capital accord, short-term claims on banks from any

country carry only a twenty percent risk weight The higher cost to the lending banks

- 14associated with a higher risk weight would presumably be passed on to the borrowing banks
Borrowing banks, at the margin, might reduce their total borrowing or shift their borrowing to
nonbank sources of funds, perhaps with the shift facilitated by the lending banks, who might
advert to secuntization of short-term interbank lending if regulatory capital charges exceeded
internal requirements In either case, there would tend to be a reduction in interbank
exposures, a significant source of systemic risk To be evaluated in any such initiative is
whether such regulation would disrupt liquidity in the interbank market to a point where such
costs exceed the benefits of reduced interbank exposure
***
We are interacting every day with an emerging new international financial structure,
one with great potential for facilitating the creation of wealth and rising standards of living
Our understanding of the new system continues to improve, as does our ability to gauge and
manage risks Still, the new system will doubtless at times appear threatening and unstable
But that is the price of progress In my judgment, at the end of the day, it will be a price
well worth paying