View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
9 15 p in E D T.
Thursday, May 8, 1997

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
1997 Haskins Partners Dinner
of the
Stern School of Business
New York University
New York, New York
May 8, 1997

I am pleased to accept this year's Charles Waldo Haskins
Award and have the opportunity to address this distinguished
audience on current monetary policy
A central bank's raising interest rates is rarely popular
But the Federal Reserve's action on March 25, to tighten the
stance of monetary policy, seems to have attracted more than the
usual share of attention and criticism
our action deserve a response

I believe the critics of

So tonight, I would like to take

a few minutes to put this action in the broad context of the
Fed's mandate to promote the stable financial environment that
will encourage economic growth.
The Federal Open Market Committee raised rates as a form of
insurance

It was a small prudent step in the face of the

increasing possibility that excessive credit creation, spurred by
an overly accommodative monetary policy, might undermine the
sustained economic expansion.

That expansion has been fostered

by the maintenance of low lrflation

But the persisting—indeed

increasing—strength of nominal demand for goods and services
suggested to us that monetaiy policy might not be positioned
appropriately to avoid a buildup of inflationary pressures and
imbalances that would be incompatible with extending the current
expansion into 1998, and hopefully beyond

Even if it should

appear in retrospect that we could have skirted the dangers of
credit excesses without a modest tightening, the effect on the

-2expansion would be small, temporary, and like most insurance, its
purchase to protect against possible adverse outcomes would still
be eminently sensible
For the Federal Reserve to remain inactive against a
possible buildup of insidious inflationary pressures would be to
sanction a threat to the job security and standards of living of
too many Americans

As I pointed out in testimony before the

Congress in March, the type of economy that we are now
experiencing, with strong growth and tight labor markets, has the
special advantage of drawing hundreds of thousands of people onto
employment payrolls, where they can acquire permanent work
skills

Under less favorable conditions they would have remained

out of the labor force, or among the long-term unemployed
Moreover, the current more-than-six-year expansion has enabled us
to accelerate the modernization of our productive facilities
It has long been the goal of monetary policy to foster the
maximum sustainable growth in the American economy

I emphasize

sustainable because it is clear from our history that surges in
growth financed by excessive credit creation are, by their
nature, unsustainable, and, unless contained, threaten the
underlying stability of our economy

Such stability, in turn, is

necessary to nurture the sources of permanent growth
The Federal Reserve, of late, has been criticized as being
too focused on subduing nonexistent inflation and, in the

-3process, being willing to suppress economic growth, retard job
expansion, and inhibit real wage gains.

On the contrary, our

actions to tighten money market conditions in 1994, and again in

March of this year, were directed at sustaining and fostering
growth in economic activity, jobs, and real wages

Our goal has

never been to contain inflation as an end in itself
only signals of how the economy is functioning

Prices are

If inflation had

no effect on economic growth, we would be much less concerned
about inflationary pressures
But the evidence is compelling that low inflation is
necessary to the most favorable performance of the economy
Inflation, as is generally recognized throughout the world,
destroys jobs and undermines productivity gains, the foundation
for increases in real wages

Low inflation is being increasingly

viewed as a necessary condition for sustained growth.
It may be an old cliche, but you cannot have a vibrant
growing economy without sound money

History is unequivocal on

this .
The Federal Reserve has not always been successful at
maintaining sound money and sustained growth, and the lessons
have been costly

The Federal Reserve's policy actions, the

evidence demonstrates, affect the financial markets immediately,
but work with a significant lag of several quarters or more on
output and employment, and even longer on prices

Too often in

-4the past, policymakers responded late to unfolding economic
developments and found they were far behind the curve, so to
speak; as a result, their policy actions were creating or
accentuating business cycles, rather than sustaining expansion
Those who wish for us, in the current environment, to await
clearly visible signs of emerging inflation before acting are
recommending we return to a failed regime of monetary policy that
cost jobs and living standards.
I wish it were otherwise, but there is no alternative to
basing policy on what are, unavoidably, uncertain forecasts

As

I have indicated to the Congress, we do not base policy on a
single best-estimate forecast, but rather on a series of
potential outcomes and the possible effects of alternative
policies, including judgments of the consequences of taking a
policy action that might, in the end, have turned oat to be less
than optimal
I viewed our small increase in the federal funds rate on
March 25 as taken not so much as a consequence of a change in the
most probable forecast of moderate growth and low inflation for
later this year and next, but rather to address the probability
that being wrong had materially increased
In the same sense that it would be folly not to endure the
small immediate discomfort of a vaccination against the
possibility of getting a serious disease, it would have been

-5folly not to take this small prudent step last March to reduce
the probabilities that destabilizing inflation would re-emerge
The risk to the economy from inaction came to outweigh the risk
from action.
To be sure, 1997 is not 1994 when the Fed was forced to
tighten monetary conditions very substantially to avoid
accommodating rising inflation

Current financial conditions are

much less accommodative than they were in 1994
wary.

Yet we must be

While there is scant evidence of any imminent resurgence

of inflation at the moment, there also appears to be little
slack in our capacity to produce

Should the expected slowing in

the growth of demand fail to materialize, we would need to
address any emerging pressures xn product and credit markets
To understand the problems of capacity restraint, I should
like to spend a few moments on what we have learned over the
years about economic growth and the conditions necessary to
foster it
First it is useful to distinguish between two quite
different types of economic growth.
growth, the other is not

One is true, sustainable

True growth reflects the capacity of

the economic system to produce goods and services and is based on
the growth in productivity and in the labor force
That growth contrasts with the second type, what I would
call transitory growth

An economy producing near capacity can

-6expand faster for a short time through excess credit creation
But this is not growth in any meaningful sense of promoting
lasting increases in standards of living for our nation
it will detract from achieving our long-term goals

Indeed,

Temporary

fluctuations in output owing to say, inventory adjustments, but
not financed through excess credit, will quickly adjust on their
own and need not concern us as much, provided policy is
appropriately positioned to foster sustainable growth
When excessive credit fostered by the central bank finances
excess demand, history tells us destabilizing inflationary
pressures eventually emerge

For a considerable portion of the

nineteenth and early twentieth centuries, inflationary credit
excesses and prices were contained by a gold standard and
balanced budgets

Both, however, were deemed too constraining to

the achievement of wider social goals as well as for other
reasons, and instead the Federal Reserve was given the mandate of
maintaining the appropriate degree of liquidity in the system
Over the long haul, the economy's growth is effectively
limited to the expansion of capacity based on productivity and
labor force growth

To be sure, it is often difficult to judge

whether observed growth is soundly based on productivity or
arises from transitory surges in output financed in many cases by
excess credit, but this is in part what making monetary policy is
all about

-7In that regard and in the current context, how can we be
confident we at the Federal Reserve are not inhibiting the nation
reaching its full growth potential?
One way is to examine closely the recent economic record
Only two and a half years ago, rising commodity prices,
lengthening delivery times, and heavy overtime indicated that our
productive facilities were under some strain to meet demand

To

be sure, since early 1995, those pressures have eased off
However, given the good pace of economic expansion since then, it
would stretch credulity to believe that capacity growth has
accelerated at a sufficient pace to produce a large degree of
slack at this moment

Capacity utilization in industry is a

little below its level through much of 1994, and pressures in
product markets have remained tame

However, falling

unemployment rates and rising overtime hours--as well as
anecdotal reports--unambiguously point to growing tightness in
labor markets
With tight labor markets and little slack in product
markets, we are led to conclude that significant persistent
strength in the growth of nominal demand for goods and services,
outstripping the likely rate of increase in capacity, will
presumably be resisted by higher market interest rates

If,

instead, that demand is accommodated for a time by a step up in

credit expansion facilitated by monetary policy, increasing

-8pressures on productive resources would sow, as they have in the
past, the seeds of even higher interest rates and a consequent
subsequent economic retrenchment
This, then, was the context for our recent action

We saw a

significant risk that monetary policy was not positioned to
promote sustainable economic expansion, and we took a small step
to increase the odds that the good performance of the economy can
continue
There is another point of view of the current context that
merits consideration

It is the notion that, owing largely to

technological advance and to freer international trade, the
conventional notions of capacity are becoming increasingly
outmoded, and that domestic resources can be used much more
intensively than in the past without added price pressures
There is, no doubt, a substantial element of truth in these
observations, as I have often noted in the past

Computer and

telecommunication based technologies are truly revolutionizing
the way we produce goods and services

This has imparted a

substantially increased degree of flexibility into the workplace,
which in conjunction with just-in-time inventory strategies and
increased availability of products from around the world, has
kept costs in check through increased productivity
Our production system and the notion of capacity are far
more flexible than they were ten or twenty years ago

-9Nonetheless, any inference that our productive capacity is
essentially unlimited is clearly unwarranted

As I pointed out

earlier, judging from a number of tangible signs of strains on
facilities, we were producing near capacity in early 1995, and it
is just not credible that an economy as vast and complex as that
of the United States could have changed its underlying structure

in the short time since then
If we consider the current rate of true, sustainable growth
unsatisfactory, are there policies which could augment it?
In my view, improving productivity and standards of living
necessitates increasing incentives to risk taking

To encourage

people to take prudent risks, the potential rewards must be
perceived to exceed the possible losses

Maintaining low

inflation rates reduces the levels of future uncertainties and,
hence, increases the scope of investment opportunities.

It is

here that the Federal Reserve can most contribute to long-term
growth
Other government policies also can affect these perceptions
For example, lower marginal tax rates and capital gains taxes
would increase the return to successful investments and, thus,
the incentive to initiate them

In addition, coming to grips now

with the outsized projected growth in entitlement spending in the
early years of the next century could have a profound effect on
current expectations of stability

Early actions could bring

-10real long-term interest rates down, also increasing the scope of
investment opportunities

And, clearly, removing the federal

deficit's drain on private savings would help to finance such
private investment
Deregulation, by increasing the flexibility in the
deployment of our capital and management resources, can also make
a decided contribution to growth

The deregulation of

telecommunications, motor and rail transport, utilities, and
financial services, to name a few, may have done more to foster
America's competitive market efficiencies than we can readily
document
Finally, though not a function of government policies, is
the continued good pace of productivity growth this late in the
business expansion

This cyclical pattern is contrary to our

experience and it suggests there may be an undetected delayed
bonus from technical and managerial efficiencies coming from the
massive advances in computer and telecommunications technology
applications over the last two decades.

If so, it is important

that we nurture it with adequate incentives — at a minimum, eschew
regulations and taxation that reduce most incentives—for this
may well be one source of our low inflation environment
While productivity improvement through capital investment
and technological advance is clearly central to the process of
economic growth, the pace and quality of labor force expansion is

-11additive to productivity growth in achieving overall gains in
GDP

Hence, appropriate upgrading of skills through education

and training should go with any menu to expand economic growth
Looking ahead, there are many reasons to be optimistic about
the economy's prospects.
For a vast nation such as ours at the cutting edge of
technology, a large pickup in productivity growth is difficult to
envisage

But appropriate incentives advancing that cutting edge

can augment growth in a material way

And cumulatively, over

time even a modest acceleration in productivity would very
significantly improve the standards of living of our children
The twenty-first century will pose many challenges to our
ingenuity to develop new and sophisticated ways of creating
economic value

But with the competitive benefits of

increasingly open markets, I have little doubt we Americans will
meet the challenge admirably