View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
4:10 p.m. local time (11:10 a.m. EST)
December 2, 2005

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Advancing Enterprise Conference
London, England
December 2, 2005

In November 2003, I noted that we saw little evidence of stress in funding the
U.S. current account deficit even though the real exchange rate for the dollar, on net, had
declined more than 10 percent since early 2002. Inflation and inflation premiums embedded in
long-term interestrates— the typical symptoms of a weak currency-appeared subdued, and the
vast international savings transfer to finance U.S. investment had occurred without measurable
disruption to international financial markets. Two years later, little has changed except that our
current account deficit has grown still larger. Most policy makers marvel at the seeming ease
with which the United States continues to finance its current account deficit.
Of course, deficits that cumulate to ever-increasing net external debt, with its attendant
rise in servicing costs, cannot persist indefinitely. At some point, foreign investors will balk at a
growing concentration of claims against U.S. residents, even if rates of return on investment in
the United States remain competitively high, and will begin to alter their portfolios. In addition,
efforts by U.S. residents to address their domestic imbalances will presumably contribute to a
move away from current account imbalance.
In all instances, a current account balance essentially results from a wide-ranging
interactive process that involves the production and allocation of goods, services, and incomes
among the residents of a country and those of the rest of the world. The outcome of the process
is reflected in the full array of domestic and international product and asset prices, including
interest rates.
The array of bilateral exchange rates between the dollar and foreign currencies appears to
be particularly important to the current account balance, although, of course, exchange rates, like
all other prices, are determined interactively and simultaneously. As I note later, to the extent
that an economy harbors elements of inflexibility, so that prices and quantities are slow to

-2respond to new developments, the process of current account adjustment, besides affecting prices
of goods and financial assets, is also more likely to adversely affect the levels of output and
employment as well.
* **
The rise of the U.S. current account deficit over the past decade appears to have
coincided with a pronounced new phase of globalization that is characterized by a major
acceleration in U.S. productivity growth and the decline in what economists call home bias. In
brief, home bias is the parochial tendency of persons, though faced with comparable or superior
foreign opportunities, to invest domestic savings in the home country. The decline in home bias
is reflected in savers increasingly reaching across national borders to invest in foreign assets.
The rise in U.S. productivity growth attracted much of those savings toward investments in the
United States. The greater rates of productivity growth in the United States, compared with
still-subdued rates abroad, have apparently engendered corresponding differences in
risk-adjusted expected rates of return and hence in the demand for U.S.-based assets.
Home bias implies that lower risk compensation is required for geographically proximate
investment opportunities; when investors are familiar with the environment, they perceive less
risk than they do for objectively comparable investment opportunities in far distant, less familiar
environments.
Home bias was very much in evidence for a half century following World War II.
Domestic saving was directed predominantly toward domestic investment. Because the

-3difference between a nation's domestic saving and domestic investment is the near-algebraic
equivalent of that nation's current account balance, external imbalances were small.1
However, starting in the 1990s, home bias began to decline discernibly, the consequence
of a dismantling of restrictions on capital flows and the advance of information and
communication technologies that has effectively shrunk the time and distance that separate
markets around the world. The vast improvements in these technologies have broadened
investors' vision to the point that foreign investment appears less risky than it did in earlier
times.
Accordingly, the weighted correlation between national saving rates and domestic
investment rates for countries representing four-fifths of world gross domestic product (GDP)
declined from a coefficient of around 0.97 in 1992, where it had hovered since 1970, to an
estimated low of 0.68 last year.2
To be sure, international trade has been expanding as a share of world GDP since the end
of World War II. Yet, through the mid-1990s, the expansion was largely a grossing up of
individual countries' exports and imports. Only in the past decade has expanding trade been
associated with the emergence of ever-larger U.S. trade and current account deficits, matched by
a corresponding widening of the aggregate external surpluses of many of our trading partners,
most recently including China and the OPEC countries.

1

National income accounting establishes that the gap between domestic saving and domestic investment is
equivalent to net foreign saving; net foreign saving is a close approximation of the current account balance.
2
Doubtless, part of the increasing ex post gap between nations' domestic saving and their domestic
investment reflects the exogenous rise of competitive risk-adjusted rates of return in the United States, which would
have attracted cross-border investments even without a change in ex ante home bias. Nevertheless, even excluding
the United States, the correlation coefficient declined from 0.96 in 1992 to 0.58 last year. Of course, excluding the
United States from the calculation does not also exclude the growing ex post non-U.S. surpluses, which were drawn
to high U.S. rates of return.

-4Indeed, the increasing dispersion of current account balances is closely tied to the
shrinking degree of correlation of country shares of saving and investment.3 Obviously, if
domestic saving exactly equaled domestic investment for every country, all current accounts
would be in balance, and the dispersion of such balances would be zero. Thus, current account
imbalances require the correlation between domestic saving andinvestment—

which

reflects the

ex post degree of home bias—to be less than 1.0.
Home bias, of course, is only one of several factors that determine how much a nation
actually saves and what part of that saving, or of foreign saving, is attracted to fund domestic
investment. Aside from the ex ante average inclination of global investors toward home bias, the
difference between domestic saving and domestic investment—that is, the current account
balance-is determined by the anticipated rate of return on foreign investments relative to
domestic investments as well as the underlying propensity to save of one nation relative to that
of other nations.
Indeed, all these factors working simultaneously determine the extent to which domestic
savers reach beyond their borders to, on net, invest in foreign assets and thereby facilitate current
account surpluses and the financing of other countries' current account deficits.
***
This afternoon, I should like to raise the hypothesis that the reason the historically large
U.S. current account deficit has not been placing persistent pressure on the exchange rate of the

Because domestic saving less domestic investment is equal, with small adjustments, to the current account
balance, the dispersion of domestic saving less domestic investment among nations is a very close approximation to
the dispersion of current account balances.

-5U.S. dollar, at least to date, is that the deficit is a reflection of a far broader and long-standing
financial development in the United States and elsewhere.
An ever-growing proportion of U.S. households, nonfinancial businesses, and
governments, both national and local, fund their capital investments from external sources, rather
than, for example, household self-finance or corporations' internal funds. Early on, almost all of
that financing originated with U.S. financial institutions, and the debt of U.S. residents to
foreigners was small.
The uptrend in unconsolidated deficits of individual U.S. economic entities relative to
GDP has been evident for decades, possibly even emerging during the nineteenth century. For
most of that period, those deficits were almost fully matched by surpluses of other
U.S. economic entities. What is special about the past decade is that the decline in home bias,
along with the rise in U.S. productivity growth and the rise in the dollar, has engendered a large
increase by U.S. residents in purchases of goods and services from foreign producers. The
increased purchases have been willingly financed by foreign investors with implications that are
not as yet clear.
Typically, current account balances, saving, and investment are measured for a specific
geographic area bounded by sovereign borders. Were we to measure current account balances of
much smaller geographic divisions, such as American states or Canadian provinces, or of much
larger groupings of nations, such as South America or Asia, the trends in these measures and
their seeming implications could be quite different than those extracted from the conventional
national measures of the current account balance.

-6The choice of appropriate geographical units for measurement depends on what we are
trying to ascertain. I presume that in most instances, we seek to judge the degree of economic
stress that could augur significantly adverse economic outcomes. To make the best judgment in
this case would require current account measures obtained at the level of detail at which
economic decisions are made: individual households, businesses, and governments. That level
is where stress is experienced and hence where actions that may destabilize economies could
originate. Debts usually represent individual obligations that are not guaranteed by other parties.
Consolidated national balance sheets, by aggregating together net debtors and net creditors,
accordingly can mask individual stress as well as individual strength.
Indeed, measures of stress of the most narrowly defined economic units would be
unambiguously the most informative if we lived in a world where sovereign or other borders did
not affect transactions in goods, services, and assets. Of course, national borders do matter and
continue to have some economic significance, an issue to which I shall return.
The process of growing trade and financing imbalances has been developing within the
borders of the United States for some time. The dispersion of unconsolidated current account
balances of individual economic entities relative to nominal GDP may be expected to exhibit
similar trends to the dispersion of saving-investment imbalances among the seven consolidated
nonfinancial sectors measured in U.S. macroeconomic statistics: households, corporations,
nonfarm noncorporate business, farms, state and local governments, the federal government, and
the rest of the world.4 This measure exhibits a rise over the past half-century in the absolute sum

I include the "rest of the world" sector because it measures surpluses or deficits of U.S. residents even
though they reflect the accumulation of net claims on, or of obligations to, foreigners. The other six sectors reflect
net claims on or obligations to domestic residents only.

-7of surpluses and deficits that is 1-1/4 percentage points per year faster than the rise of nominal
GDP.5
The increase in the dispersion of the balances of unconsolidated economic entities was
presumably even greater.6 Indeed, in a more detailed calculation employing more than
five thousand nonfinancial U.S. corporations, the absolute value of surpluses and deficits as a
ratio to a proxy for corporate value added exhibits an average annual increase of 3-1/2 percent
per year.7
The apparent increase in the dispersion of the imbalances of the economic entities within
our national borders appears to have flattened out over the past decade, according to calculations
using the balances of the six domestic sectors. The continued expansion of the dispersion of the
balances, relative to GDP, of individual households, nonfinancial businesses, and governments
during the past decade is arguably related to the shift in trade and financing from within the
borders of the United States to cross-border trade and finance.
In simple terms, some U.S. domestic businesses previously purchasing components from
domestic suppliers switched to foreign suppliers. These companies generally view domestic and
foreign suppliers as competitive in the same way that they view domestic suppliers as competing
with each other. Moving from a domestic to a foreign source altered international balance

5

Disregarding statistical discrepancies, the net of deficits and surpluses of these seven sectors is, of course,

zero.
6

Consolidationof any group of economic entities reduces dispersion. Full consolidation of the entities
eliminates it.
7

The surpluses (and deficits) are measured as income before extraordinary items, plus depreciation, minus
capital expenditures. The proxy for corporate value-added is gross margin, or sales less cost of goods sold.

-8bookkeeping but arguably not economic stress.8 Such transactions may, of course, take into
account exchange rates in the adjustment process, similar to the manner in which prices of
purchased components presumably are taken into account when one domestic supplier is
substituted for another.
Implicit in a widening dispersion of current account surpluses and deficits of individual
economic entities is the expectation of increasing cumulative deficits for some and, hence, a
possible rise in debt as a share of their income.9 Unconsolidated debt of private nonfinancial
U.S. entities as a ratio to GDP has, indeed, risen at nearly 3 percent per year, on average, over
the past half-century.10 From 1900 to 1939, nonfinancial private debt rose almost 1 percent
faster per year on average than GDP. The debt-to-GDP ratio fell in the wake of the inflation of
World War II and its aftermath, which inflated away the real burden of debt. The updrift in the
ratio, however, shortly resumed.
As I noted earlier, the trend toward intra-country dispersion is likely occurring not only
in the United States but in other countries as well. The existence of this trend is suggested by the
rise in unconsolidated nonfinancial debt of the major industrial economies, excluding the
United States, over the past three decades, which has exceeded the growth of GDP by
1.6 percentage points annually.
** *

8

Of course, domestic firms and workers that lose sales will be adversely affected, at least until they can be
reallocated to more competitive uses.
9

Cumulative deficits of individual economic entities will increase net debt, i.e., gross debt less financial
assets. But in the large majority of instances gross debt will rise with net debt.
10

Part of this rise possibly reflects a growing proportion of income generated by GDP accruing to debtors.
In recent decades, however, the proportion of economic units with no debt has been relatively small. Nominal GDP,
of course, is net value-added and is not affected by consolidations of accounts.

-9The apparent increase in the dispersion of the surpluses and deficits of U.S. economic
entities over the past half-century and more is likely an extension of the growing specialization
of the economy and the financial system within the United States. I suspect data would confirm
similar trends among many of the other developed economies as well.
Increasing specialization goes back to the beginnings of the Industrial Revolution.
Movement away from economic self-sufficiency of individuals and nations arose from the
division of labor, a process that continually subdivides tasks, creating ever-deeper levels of
specialization and improved productivity. Such specialization fosters trade.11
Trade, especially intertemporal trade—that is, the trade of goods and services today in
exchange for goods and services at some future date—tends to give rise to a range of surpluses
and deficits across individuals and nonfinancial businesses. And in all likelihood those
imbalances have been increasing faster than income. As a result, the dispersion of such
imbalances relative to incomes, or national product, can be expected to increase as the scope of
trade expands from within regions, then nation-wide, and finally across national borders.
That surpluses and deficits of residents of the United States have indeed been rising
relative to incomes over the past century is indicated by a similar rise in assets of financial
intermediaries relative to the total of nonfinancial assets and to nominal GDP. It is these
financial institutions that have largely intermediated the surpluses and deficits of U.S. residents,
and hence the size of these institutions can act as an alternative proxy for such surpluses and
deficits. Indeed, one can argue it has been the need to intermediate the surpluses and deficits
that has driven the development of our formidable financial system over the generations.
11

There is no necessary reason, of course, why such trade need be imbalanced.

-10Since 1946, the assets of U.S. financial intermediaries, even excluding the outsized
growth in mortgage pools, have risen 1.8 percent per year relative to nominal GDP. From 1896,
the earliest date of comprehensive data on bank assets, to 1941, assets of banks, by far the
predominant financial intermediaries in those years, rose 0.6 percent per year relative to GDP.
The increase in the ratio of deficits of individual economic entities to GDP, as I noted
earlier, is reflected in an ever-rising ratio of unconsolidated levels of debt to GDP. Facilitating
the ability of residents of the United States and, presumably, other economies to accumulate this
debt with limited stress has been the rising ratio of the market value of nonfinancial assets to
GDP. The rise in those asset values in the United States reflects, in part, an increasing ratio of
real capital assets to real GDP, which has helped to support the rise in U.S. productivity.
Hard data documenting these global developments at the appropriate microlevel are
regrettably sparse. Yet anecdotal, circumstantial, and some statistical evidence is suggestive that
the historically large current account deficit of the United States may be part of a broader set of
rising unconsolidated deficits and accumulated debt that is arguably more secular than cyclical.
The secular updrift in deficits and debt doubtless has been gradual. However, the component of
those broad measures that captures the share of net foreign financing of the balances of
individual unconsolidated U.S. economic entities—our current account deficit—has increased
from negligible in the early 1990s to more than 6 percent of our GDP today. The acceleration of
U.S. productivity, which dates from the mid-1990s, was an important factor in this process.
Accordingly, it is tempting to conclude that the U.S. current account deficit is essentially
a byproduct of long-term secular forces, and thus is largely benign. After all, we do seem to

-11have been able to finance our international current account deficit with relative ease in recent
years.
But does the apparent continued rise in the deficits of U.S. individual households and
nonfinancial businesses themselves reflect growing economic strain? (We do not think so.) And
does it matter how those deficits of individual economic entities are being financed?
Specifically, does the recent growing proportion of these deficits being financed, net, by
foreigners matter?
If economic decisions were made without regard to currency or cross-border risks, then
one could argue that current account imbalances were of no particular economic significance,
and the accumulation of debt would have few implications beyond the solvency of the debtors
themselves. Whether the debt was owed to domestic or foreign lenders would be of little
significance.
But national borders apparently do matter. Debt service payments on foreign loans, for
example, ultimately must be funded disproportionately from exports of tradable goods and
services, whereas domestic debt has a broader base from which it can be serviced. Moreover,
the market adjustment process seems to be less effective across borders than domestically.
Prices of identical goods at nearby locations, but across borders, for example, have been shown
to differ significantly even when denominated in the same currency.12 Thus cross-border current
account imbalances have implications for the market adjustment process and the degree of

12

The persistent divergence subsequent to the creation of the euro of many prices of identical goods among
member countries of the euro area is analyzed in John H. Rogers (2002), "Monetary Union, Price Level
Convergence, and Inflation: How Close is Europe to the United States?" Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System, International Finance Discussion Paper 740. For the case of U.S. and Canadian prices, see
Charles Engel and John H. Rogers (1996), "How Wide Is the Border?" American Economic Review, vol. 80,
pp. 1112-25.

-12economic stress that are likely greater than those for domestic imbalances. Cross-border legal
and currency risks are important additions to normal domestic risks.
But how significant are those differences? Globalization is changing many of our
economic guideposts. It is probably reasonable to assume that the worldwide dispersion of the
balances of unconsolidated economic entities as a share of global GDP noted earlier, will
continue to rise as increasing specialization and the division of labor spread globally.
Whether the dispersion of world current account balances continues to increase as well is
more an open question. Such an increase would imply a problematic further decline in ex ante
home bias. Even in that event eventually the U.S. current account deficit would likely move
back toward balance.
Regrettably, we do not as yet have a firm grasp of the implications of cross-border
financial imbalances. If we did, our forecasting record on the international adjustment process
would have been better in recent years. I presume that with time we will learn.
In the interim, whatever the significance and possible negative implications of the current
account deficit, maintaining economic flexibility, as I have stressed before, may be the most
effective initiative to counter such risks.
Whether by intention or by happenstance, many, if not most, governments in recent
decades have been relying more and more on the forces of the marketplace and reducing their
intervention in market outcomes. We appear to be revisiting Adam Smith's notion that the more
flexible an economy the greater its ability to self-correct after inevitable, often unanticipated
disturbances. That greater tendency toward self-correction has made the cyclical stability of an

-13economy less dependent on the actions of macroeconomic policy makers, whose responses often
have come too late or have been misguided.
Being able to rely on markets to do the heavy lifting of adjustment is an exceptionally
valuable policy asset. The impressive performance of the U.S. economy over the past couple of
decades, despite shocks that in the past would have surely produced marked economic
disruption, offers clear evidence of the benefits of increased market flexibility. In the
United Kingdom, as well, a quarter-century of progress toward dismantling controls and
increasing reliance on market forces evidently has resulted in a stronger and more flexible
economy.
Although the business cycle has not disappeared, flexibility has made the United States
and the United Kingdom, and much of the remainder of the global economy more resilient to
shocks and more stable during the past couple of decades. Nonetheless, the piling up of dollar
claims against U.S. residents is already leading to concerns about concentration risk. Although
foreign investors have not as yet significantly slowed their financing of U.S. capital investments,
since early 2002, we have observed a decline in the value of the dollar and a reduction in the
share of dollars in global cross-border portfolios.13
If the currently disturbing drift toward protectionism is contained and markets remain
sufficiently flexible, changing terms of trade, interest rates, asset prices, and exchange rates will

Of the more than $30 trillion equivalents of cross-border banking and international bond claims reported
by the private sector to the Bank for International Settlements for the end of the first quarter of 2005, 41.8 percent
were in dollars and 39.8 percent were in euros. Adjusting for exchange rate changes, the dollar's share was
4 percentage points less than three years earlier, and the euro's share was more than 5 percentage points greater.
Monetary authorities have been somewhat more inclined to hold dollar obligations. At the end of the first quarter of
2005, of the $3.8 trillion equivalents held as foreign exchange reserves, more than three-fifths were held in dollars
and approximately one-quarter in euros. Since early 2002, the dollar's share has been little changed after adjusting
for movements in exchange rates.

-14cause U.S. saving to rise, reducing the need for foreign finance and reversing the trend of the
past decade toward increasing reliance on it. If, however, the pernicious drift toward fiscal
instability in the United States and elsewhere is not arrested and is compounded by a
protectionist reversal of globalization, the adjustment process could be quite painful for the
world economy.