View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
1:00 p.m. (EST)
November 19, 2002

International Financial Risk Management
Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
at the
Council on Foreign Relations
Washington, D.C.
November 19, 2002

Today I would like to share with you some of the evolving international financial issues
that have so engaged us at the Federal Reserve over the past year. I, particularly, have been
focusing on innovations in the management of risk and some of the implications of those
innovations for our global economic and financial system.
Fostered by a lowering of trade barriers, cross-border exchange of goods and services over
the past half century has increased far faster than world gross domestic product. But what is even
more remarkable is how large the scale of cross-border finance has become, relative to the value
of the trade that it finances. To be sure, much global finance reflects growing investment
portfolios, some doubtless with a speculative component. But, at bottom, such finance is a central
element of the systems that support the efficient international movement of goods and services.
We strongly suspect, though we do not know for sure, that the accelerating expansion of global
finance may be indispensable to the continued rapid growth of world trade in goods and services.
It appears increasingly evident that many forms and layers of financial intermediation will be
required if we are to capture the full benefit of our advances in technology and trade. Indeed, the
seemingly outsized implicit compensation for risk associated with many investments worldwide
suggests the potential for a far larger world financial system than currently exists.
Among most of the large world trading economies the bias against investment in foreign
assets is apparent in the still-high correlation between domestic savings and domestic investment.
In decades past, risk was perceived to increase with distance. A paucity of information and
surplus of regulation discouraged the cross-border movement of funds. Even today, with
regulatory bars lowered and information and access much enhanced, bias against

-2cross-border investment remains high. However, the continuous probing for enhanced returns,
unless inhibited by governments, seems poised to create a much larger global presence of
financial linkages in all our economies.
As in all aspects of life, expansion of one's activities beyond previously explored territory
involves taking risks. And risk by its nature has earned, and always will carry with it, the
possibility of adverse outcomes. Accordingly, for globalization to continue to foster expanding
living standards, risk must be managed ever more effectively as the century unfolds.
The development of our paradigms for containing risk has emphasized dispersion of risk
to those willing, and presumably able, to bear it. If risk is properly dispersed, shocks to the
overall economic system will be better absorbed and less likely to create cascading failures that
could threaten financial stability.
The broad success of that paradigm seemed to be most evident in the United States over
the past two and one-half years. Despite the draining impact of a loss of $8 trillion of stock
market wealth, a sharp contraction in capital investment and, of course, the tragic events of
September 11, 2001, our economy is still growing. Importantly, despite significant losses, no
major U.S. financial institution has been driven to default. Similar observations pertain to much
of the rest of the world but to a somewhat lesser extent than to the United States.
These episodes suggest a marked increase over the past two or three decades in the ability
of modern economies to absorb unanticipated shocks. To be sure, the recent weakened pace of
world economic activity has raised concerns that the full cycle of the past decade has yet to be
definitively concluded. But the already clearly evident increased resiliency arguably supports the
view that the world economy already has become more flexible irrespective of how events unfold
in the weeks and months ahead. This favorable turn of events has doubtless been materially

-3assisted by the recent financial innovations that have afforded lenders the opportunity to become
considerably more diversified and borrowers to become far less dependent on specific institutions
or markets for funds.
The wide-ranging development of markets in securitized bank loans, credit card
receivables, and commercial and residential mortgages has been a major contributor to the
dispersion of risk in recent decades both domestically and internationally. These markets have
tailored the risks associated with such assets to the preferences of a broader spectrum of investors.
Especially important in the United States have been the flexibility and the size of the
secondary mortgage market. Since early 2000, this market has facilitated the large debt-financed
extraction of home equity that, in turn, has been so critical in supporting consumer outlays in the
United States throughout the recent period of cyclical stress. This market's flexibility has been
particularly enhanced by extensive use of interest rate swaps and options to hedge maturity
mismatches and prepayment risk.
Financial derivatives, more generally, have grown at a phenomenal pace over the past
fifteen years. Conceptual advances in pricing options and other complex financial products, along
with improvements in computer and telecommunications technologies, have significantly lowered
the costs of, and expanded the opportunities for, hedging risks that were not readily deflected in
earlier decades. Moreover, the counterparty credit risk associated with the use of derivative
instruments has been mitigated by legally enforceable netting and through the growing use of
collateral agreements. These increasingly complex financial instruments have especially
contributed, particularly over the past couple of stressful years, to the development of a far more
flexible, efficient, and resilient financial system than existed just a quarter-century ago.

-4Greater resilience has been evident in many segments of the financial markets. One
prominent example is the response of financial markets to a burgeoning and then deflating
telecommunications sector. Worldwide borrowing by telecommunications firms in all currencies
amounted to more than the equivalent of one trillion U.S. dollars during the years 1998 to 2001.
The financing of the massive expansion of fiber-optic networks and heavy investments in
third-generation mobile-phone licenses by European firms strained debt markets.
At the time, the financing of these investments was widely seen as prudent because the
telecommunication borrowers had very high valuations in equity markets, which could facilitate a
stock issuance, if needed, to take down bank loans and other debt. In the event, of course, prices
of telecommunication stocks collapsed, and many firms went bankrupt. In decades past, such a
sequence would have been a recipe for creating severe distress in the wider financial system.
However, compared with decades past, banks now have significantly more capital with which to
absorb shocks, and they employ improved systems for managing credit risk. In conjunction with
this improvement, both as cause and effect, banks have more tools at their disposal with which to
transfer credit risk and, in so doing, to disperse credit risk more broadly through the financial
system. Some of these tools, such as loan syndications, loan sales, and pooled asset
securitizations, are relatively straightforward and transparent. More recently, instruments that are
more complex and less transparent-such as credit default swaps, collateralized debt obligations,
and credit-linked notes-have been developed and their use has grown very rapidly in recent
years. The result? Improved credit-risk management together with more and better riskmanagement tools appear to have significantly reduced loan concentrations in
telecommunications and, indeed, other areas and the associated stress on banks and other financial
institutions.

-5More generally, such instruments appear to have effectively spread losses from defaults by
Enron, Global Crossing, Railtrack, WorldCom, Swissair, and sovereign Argentinian credits over
the past year to a wider set of banks than might previously have been the case in the past, and
from banks, which have largely short-term leverage, to insurance firms, pension funds, or others
with diffuse long-term liabilities or no liabilities at all. Many sellers of risk protection, as one
might presume, have experienced large losses, but because of significant capital, they were able to
avoid the widespread defaults of earlier periods of stress. It is noteworthy that payouts in the still
relatively small but rapidly growing market in credit derivatives have been proceeding smoothly
for the most part. Obviously, this market is still too new to have been tested in a widespread
down-cycle for credit, but, to date, it appears to have functioned well.
The market for credit derivatives has grown in prominence not only because of its ability
to disperse risk but also because of the information it contributes to enhanced risk management by
banks and other financial intermediaries. Credit default swaps, for example, are priced to reflect
the probability of the net loss from the default of an ever-broadening array of borrowers, both
financial and nonfinancial.
As the market for credit default swaps expands and deepens, the collective knowledge
held by market participants is exactly reflected in the prices of these derivative instruments. They
offer significant supplementary information about credit risk to a bank's loan officer, for example,
who heretofore had to rely mainly on in-house credit analysis. To be sure, loan officers have
always looked to the market prices of the stocks and bonds of a potential borrower for guidance,
but none directly answered the key question for any prospective loan: What is the probable net
loss in a given time frame? Credit default swaps, of course, do just that and presumably in the

-6process embody all relevant market prices of the financial instruments issued by potential
borrowers.
Price trends of default swaps have been particularly sensitive to concerns about corporate
governance in recent months. The perceived risk of default of both financial and nonfinancial
firms has risen markedly in the wake of company-threatening scandals, though levels remain
moderate for most.
* * *
Derivatives, by construction, are highly leveraged, a condition that is both a large benefit
and an Achilles' heel. The benefits of risk dispersion are accomplished without holding massive
positions in the underlying financial instruments. Yet, too often in our financially checkered past,
the access to such leverage has induced speculative excesses that have led to financial grief. We
are scarcely likely to reform the underlying human traits that lead to excess, but we do need to
buttress our risk-management capabilities as best we can to delimit such detours from the path of
balanced growth.
More fundamentally, we should recognize that if we choose to enjoy the advantages of a
system of leveraged financial intermediaries, the burden of managing risk in the financial system
will not lie with the private sector alone. Leveraging always carries with it the remote possibility
of a chain reaction, a cascading sequence of defaults that will culminate in financial implosion if
it proceeds unchecked. Only a central bank, with its unlimited power to create money, can with a
high probability thwart such a process before it becomes destructive. Hence, central banks have,
of necessity, been drawn into becoming lenders of last resort.

-7-

But implicit in such a role is the assumption that the burden of risk arising from
extreme outcomes will in some way be allocated between the public and private sectors.
Thus, central banks are led to provide what essentially amounts to catastrophic financial
insurance coverage. Such a public subsidy should be reserved for only the rarest of
occasions. If the owners or managers of private financial institutions were to anticipate
being propped up frequently by government support, it would only encourage reckless
and irresponsible practices.
In theory, the allocation of responsibility for risk bearing between the private
sector and the central bank depends upon the private cost of capital. To attract capital, or
at least retain it, a private financial institution must earn at minimum the overall
economy's rate of return, adjusted for risk. In competitive financial markets, the greater
the leverage, the higher must be the rate of return on the invested capital before
adjustment for risk.
If private financial institutions have to absorb all financial risk, then the degree to
which they can leverage will be limited, the financial sector smaller, and its contribution
to the economy more limited. On the other hand, if central banks effectively insulate
private institutions from the largest potential losses, however incurred, increased laxity
could threaten a major drain on taxpayers, excess creation of money by the central bank,
or both. In the end, we would be faced with a severe misallocation of real capital. In
practice, the policy choice of how much, if any, extreme market risk should be absorbed
by government authorities is complex. Yet central bankers make this decision every day,
either explicitly, or implicitly through inadvertence. Moreover, we can never know for
sure whether the decisions we make are appropriate. The question is not whether our

actions are seen to have been necessary in retrospect; the absence of a fire does not mean
that we should not have paid for fire insurance. Rather, the question is whether, ex ante,
the probability of a systemic collapse was sufficient to warrant intervention. Often, we
cannot wait to see whether, in hindsight, the problem will be judged to have been an
isolated event and largely benign.
Thus, governments, including central banks, must balance the responsibilities they
have been given related to their banking and financial systems. We have the
responsibility to prevent major financial market disruptions through development and
enforcement of prudent regulatory standards and, if necessary in rare circumstances,
through direct intervention in market events. But we also have the responsibility to
ensure that the regulatory framework permits private-sector institutions to take prudent
and appropriate risks, even though such risks will sometimes result in unanticipated bank
losses or even bank failures.
The inevitable rise in potential systemic risks as the international financial system
inexorably expands can be contained by improvements in effective risk management in
the private sector, improvements in domestic bank supervision and regulation, continued
cooperation among financial authorities, and, should it be necessary, by central banks
acting as lenders of last resort. In the past two decades, bank supervisors in developed
countries have worked together, through the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision,
to improve bank supervision and regulation. This effort is ongoing and places priority on
encouraging banks to further improve their risk-management systems. Similar efforts
toward shared objectives among individual central banks should also improve protection
against systemic risk on an international level.

-9Endeavors to synchronize individual countries' regulatory systems are far more
than a technical exercise. Differences are more cultural than economic. They largely
reflect differing conventions of business behavior, especially attitudes toward
competition.

Competition, of course, is the facilitator of innovation. And creative destruction,
the process by which less-productive capital is displaced with innovative cutting-edge
technologies, is the driving force of wealth creation. Thus, from the perspective of
aggregate wealth creation, the more competition the better.
But unfettered competitive capitalism is by no means fully accepted as the
optimal economic paradigm, at least as yet. Some of those involved in public policy
often see competition as too frenetic. This different perspective is captured most clearly
for me in a soliloquy attributed to a prominent European leader several years ago. He
asked, "What is the market? It is the law of the jungle, the law of nature. And what is
civilization? It is the struggle against nature." A major determinant of regulatory
regimes is how a rule of law is applied to strike a balance between the perceived benefits
of wholly unfettered markets and the perceived societal costs of overly fierce
competition.
In most countries an uneasy balance remains between unleashing the forces of
competition and reining them in when they are perceived to threaten the social order.
With markets continuously evolving as technologies advance and the political
perceptions of the proper extent of regulation also changeable, it is no wonder that our
regulations always seem to be in flux.

-10While regulation must change as financial structures do, such regulatory change
must be kept to a minimum to avoid fostering uncertainty among innovators and
investors. Moreover, shifting regulatory schemes unavoidably leave obsolescent
regulations in their wake. Business people both here and abroad complain, perhaps with
some exaggeration, that so many regulations are on the books that they are probably at all
times unknowingly in violation of some of them. We at the Federal Reserve endeavor
periodically to review all our existing regulations in order to revise or rescind those that
are out-of-date. It has worked well for us, and is probably a good practice to apply to
regulatory systems in general and to the Basel supervisory process in particular.
* * *
The extent of government intervention in markets to control risk-taking beyond
the commonly practiced control of systemic risk is, at the end of the day, a trade off
between economic growth with its associated potential instability and a more civil and
less stressful way of life with a lower standard of living.
Those of us who support market capitalism in its more-competitive forms might
argue that unfettered markets create a degree of wealth that fosters a more civilized
existence. I have always found that insight compelling. But the resistance by many to
such arguments suggests a more deep-seated aversion to the distress that often
accompanies the process of creative destruction.
The choices that we make in our societies on these critical issues will importantly
shape the opportunities for the unforeseen, but inevitable, innovations that have the
capability to advance the economic well-being of the citizens of the United States and our
trading partners.