View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Informal Remarks
of

Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before a
dinner meeting of
The Trilateral Commission
Washington, D.C.
June 23, 1988

Thank you very much, David, those were really very
kind remarks.
As I think I mentioned to a number of you who were at
the Council on Foreign Relations meeting a few weeks ago, since
I became a central banker I have learned to mumble with great
incoherence.

That's something which I learned from Paul who did

that in a manner which was approaching a work of art.

I might

add that on the issues of foreign exchange and interest rates
this evening, if you think what I said was clear and
unmistakable, I can assure you you've probably misunderstood me.
At that Council on Foreign Relations meeting the other
week, I spent a good deal of time discussing what central
bankers usually talk about -- focuses on short-term movements in
output, interest rates, inflation, foreign exchange, trade
balances, international trade adjustment.

On this occasion,

however, I think it would be useful to step back and try to
discern the more deep-seated, longer-term forces that are
driving the world economy.

I'd like specifically to focus on

two of them this evening -- first, the economic forces which
have shaped and are shaping the structure of activity in the
industrial world and in recent years the developing world as
well.

Secondly, I'd like to touch on the political forces which

have governed and will govern the outcome of the economic
forces.

During the 20th century and in fact I suspect probably
all the way back to the beginning of the industrial revolution,
we have experienced increasingly, impressively, a rise in the
part of the value of economic output which, for want of a better
term, I would designate as conceptual, as distinct from the
physical.

A half century ago, for example, our radios were

bulky and activated by large vacuum tubes while today the same
function is served by pocket-sized transistor packs with a small
fraction of the weight.

The insights that developed into modern

electronics are of course at the base of the dramatic change.
We also used to construct office buildings with excess bulk.

In

fact I remember reading once that a building that had originally
been built at the turn of the century or shortly before had been
tagged for demolition and it had been so over-engineered and
built that they had great difficulty knocking

it down.

Obviously, with advances in engineering and the development of
lighter but stronger materials we now get the same working space
in newly constructed buildings with a lot less concrete, steel
and glass.
Modern aircraft and the extension of new insights into
the behavior of nature have sharply improved the speed and the
convenience of long distance travel.

And medical breakthroughs

that have revolutionized the provision of health care are
illustrative of a long list of examples underscoring the rise in
the ratio of ideas to physical effort and bulk as the source of
economic value creation.

Once the bushels of grain and tons of iron ore, coal
and steel, cement, were added up, I suspect that we would find
that the growth in the physical components of the GNP, measured
strictly in terms of their bulk, would probably represent a
relatively flat trend in recent decades.

In fact, I would

suspect that we, on a tonnage basis, have got very much the same
volume of output as we did at the turn of the century in the
United States, in Europe and elsewhere.

This means that the

conceptual components of GNP -- that is, those elements in
economic output which are ideas and advancing ideas -- have
essentially accounted for virtually the entire rise in the
industrial world's GNP since the turn of the century.
Even the concepts of manufacturing are being altered
by the structural changes that are going on in the way we add
value.

At the turn of the century, I would suspect in a typical

steel rolling mill one would find that the rolls that would come
off, the coils that would come off the rolling mills, would be
moved by four or five journeymen hefting the coil over to the
next set of rolls and continue from there.

Today's mills

probably are run by some young clerk weighing 150 pounds with no
muscles, working on a computer and clearly being capable of
doing very much the same physical brawn effort that was
accomplished 50 to 100 years ago.

In short, what we are seeing

is ideas substituting for bulk and for the structure of the type
of production which we used to be so much enamored with.

It's no longer clear what in fact is the distinction
between manufacturing and service and trade.

Historically,

those are very clear distinctions, but in today's environment
what is a production worker is in fact the person working on the
computer off a rolling mill and that is scarcely our view of
what blue collar employment used to be a couple of generations
ago.

What we are essentially beginning to see is a concept of

manufacturing which was so thing- or physical-volume oriented
that it is gradually dissolving into impalpable conceptual
issues.
In recent years the intellectual contribution largely
has reflected the explosive growth in information gathering and
processing techniques, which have greatly extended our
analytical capabilities and had enormous consequences for
virtually all facets of our economic lives.

These trends almost

surely are irreversible and will continue into the 21st century.
Once knowledge is gained, it is never lost.

Perhaps the dark

ages may be the one exception to that proposition.
In the years and the decades ahead, telecommunications
and advance computing will take on an increasingly greater role.
By facilitating the transfer of ideas, they create value by
changing the location of intellectual property, much like the
railroads at the turn of this century created value by
transferring physical goods to geographic locations were they
were of greater worth.

At the turn of the century we created

economic value by moving ore from the Mesabi range over the
lakes down to the Pittsburgh district where we joined it with

coking coal from that area and produced steel.

The value that

was produced essentially reflected the changing of the location
of the physical volume of things.
As we move into the 1990's and into the 21st Century,
the equivalent of the creation of value through location is
going to clearly be telecommunications where what has moved is
not the ore or the coal, but data and concepts and impalpable
elements in our system through communication satellites and a
variety of other elements which are at the moment probably not
even foreseen.

But the concept of the production of economic

value and wealth for the purposes of human survival and human
life, that process will significantly change but it will remain
what it always has been, namely those material elements which
enhance the capability of the human race to function, to live,
to achieve values, to embark upon many of the things which they
could not do in earlier ages.
This is extraordinarily important when one views the
international economy because one of the things which we are
acutely aware of in the data is the extraordinary continued rise
in the amount of goods and, increasingly recently, services
which move across international boundaries.

In fact, what we

are all aware of obviously is that trade per se has been rising
at a much faster pace than has domestic demand, and clearly that
has been even more so the case in the movement of services and,
increasingly recently, intellectual property.

This means

necessarily, algebraically in fact, that the average ratio of

imports to domestic demand must be rising.

And indeed when we

talk about the necessity of coordination in the international
economy, and in fact coordination in a mechanism that is
developing in many different forms, what we are doing is trying
to coordinate this economic phenomenon which is creating more
and more exchange of goods amongst countries.

And since goods

are increasingly impalpable, then the capability of moving them
has become, obviously, substantially easier than at any time in
human history.

And what that has obviously meant is that the

facility of moving goods, moving economic values and their
associated services, has necessitated almost inevitably a rise
in trade as a proportion of aggregate world output.

And it's

fairly apparent, I would think, that when one looks at the
economic internationalization of the world, what we are looking
at is this process, this irreversible process of an increasing
conceptualization of the physical output of what it is we
produce.
However, while knowledge and conceptual advances are
irreversible, it is nonetheless possible to place barriers to
trade to prevent expansion.

Fundamental to the 1980's is a

quiet revolution to market-oriented policies throughout the
world and this is the second issue which I would like to address
this evening.

In effect, it requires a political framework to

adjust to this ever-changing environment of the production of
economic value.

When one looks at the movement toward market

economics and market policies -- free market policies as

distinct from the collectivist, socialist forms of economic
production which prevailed for so long a period and to such an
extraordinary extent in the world after World War II -- it
really is extraordinary how far we have come in the last decade.
I say it is a quiet revolution because very little has
been made of it.

We do in peripheral conversations discuss the

changes in the United States.

I mean it's obvious that the

Reagan years, whatever one may think of them in a number of
respects, are years m

the United States in which there has been

a very dramatic shift toward market-oriented open-trade
concepts.

It's not President Reagan only.

It is essentially

the fact that he represents a fundamental change that has been
occurring in the international political environment,
necessitated by the change in economics.

One can find the

change merely by looking at the democratic Congress, because
it's not that many years ago that I recall, as David pointed
out, having earlier stints here and subjected to Congressional
hearings on very similar economic matters as I would be
subjected to today.

And the one thing that I find utterly

fascinating is that the democrats in today's Congress, or more
specifically in those committees related to economic affairs,
both domestic and international, are more market-oriented than
the average republican was back in the mid 1970's.
The shift has occurred largely because the technology
in the world is forcing it.

Margaret Thatcher would not have

been in the position she has been in Britain 20 years ago and

8
accomplished what she has done in the United Kingdom because
there was no political way m

which anything she did was even

remotely feasible in the political philosophy of earlier in the
post-World War II period.

One can say much the same for Canada

and when one looks onto the continent there is an extraordinary
change that occurs as one goes from Willi Brandt to Helmut
Schmidt and then onto Helmut Kohl.
fractious.

The changes are not

There is not a confrontation of great moment that

grabs the headlines.

It's an inevitable shift that seems to be

going on.
The one time the confrontation has happened in recent
years is when President Mitterand, when coming into office in
1981, endeavored to place into position some of the old
economics in an environment of dramatically changing
international trade and freedom of markets.

He rapidly changed

and joined, in effect, the total swing that has been occurring
in recent years.

The same is true in Italy and one can argue in

the Iberian Peninsula.
One of the most interesting aspects in recent weeks is
something I must say to you I would never have imagined and that
is the acceleration that is going on in the Economic Community
toward the 1992 deadline.

They have clearly created a critical

mass on the European continent to move toward the full notions
of a free-trade Economic Community.

Once they agreed to

eliminating capital controls, very recently, in a sense the dye
was cast because if you eliminate controls that maintain the

sovereign economic structures of the various different
continental European economies, then you find that unless
monetary policies are closely coordinated you will have -- as I
think the London Economist indicated this week -- the currency
of the week or the currency of the month.

Under those

conditions, you would have cross-border movements of capital
which would be utterly devastating to the stability of the
system.

Once you fit into place a requirement that capital

flows, you have essentially first locked in a coordination of
monetary policy as a necessity, and eventually perhaps even that
will require the European Central Bank which I had originally
thought was just somebody's vague view of something that would
be nice in the 23rd Century.
But what's happening at the moment is a combination of
the telecommunications and computer structure.

We are driving

the underlying politics of our societies and not only democratic
societies.

It's inconceivable -- but it is, I guess, possible

-- that the Soviet Union is going to move in this direction.
know they are obviously trying.

I

In fact I seriously expect

that, on the basis of having spoken to several Soviet economists
of recent date, some of them talk in terms of market economics,
something that they subscribe to, and one merely waits for the
time in which the Soviets will announce that they have invented
capitalism.

But when you look at the People's Republic and the

extraordinary endeavors that are being pushed there, you come to

10
the conclusion that this is a phenomenon which crosses political
ideologies and is being driven by far more extraordinary forces.
One final fallout from this is what is happening to
the LDCs.

One extraordinary set of experiences I had when I was

here as Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers in the
mid-1970's, was meetings of the G-77 or its equivalent and
listening to the north-south debate which was essentially a
debate of capitalism versus socialism and never the twain shall
meet.

Today's environment in the same countries are really

quite extraordinarily different.

One finds through sub-Sahara

Africa an endeavor to move toward a good deal of market
economics strictly as a practical question being forced by the
practicality of necessity of constructing economic environments
which function.
This phenomenon may well be the economic and political
force which ultimately solves the LDC problem.

One obvious

characteristic, which is a fallout from the overall political
shift that one is perceiving, is that we no longer see the type
of populist economics in Latin America one would ordinarily have
expected under the politics of the 1960's and even the 1970's
that under conditions of debt which confronted much of the Latin
American major-country group that it would have been politically
so easy to move toward debt repudiation striking out at the
imperialist bankers of the north.
The fact is that has not happened.

Even Alan Garcia

who moved slightly in that direction has not moved very far.

11
The fact that when we look at somebody like Alfonsin -- who one
would presume would have been upended by the Peronista victory a
number of months ago and still functions -- or say Nelson
Obreiga -- the Finance Minister of Brazil who talks market
economics m

a way in which American economists would never even

approach 20-30 years ago -- what one senses is an acute
awareness that the only way to fundamentally resolve the debt
problem is for the debtor countries to create an economic
environment which is adequate growth to move them out from under
the burdensome debt service.
This is the reason why I am not, I shouldn't say
optimistic about a solution to the debt problem, but I am a good
deal more optimistic than I sense the overall gloom that seems
to cover this issue.

And I am because the debtor nations have

chosen not to succumb to really powerful pressures that would
seemingly make it so easy for them to cave in and take the road
of least resistance and listen to the siren songs of a number of
the debt facility issues.

They have chosen not to because I

think they recognize that if we are ultimately forced to go in
that direction -- and I certainly hope we do not -- that we are
presumably looking at the end of private financing of these
ma]or, these very large and very potentially productive
countries.

We're looking at the elimination of private

financing for a generation.

No one is going to go back into

those markets under those conditions.

It will also create a

large schism between the commercial banking system of the

12
international community and what is potentially some very
important customers who would, if they can resolve this
particular issue, move into an effective growth advance in the
21st Century.
I don't know how to come out of this.
difficult problem of which I am aware.

It's the most

It's a very tough one.

It's one that is involved in debtor fatigue, creditor fatigue,
general fatigue.

There is no really fundamental alternative

when you look at all of these various, different schemes that
come up.

The payoff is so terrific if in fact we manage to pull

this off, and I don't know what the probabilities are that we
will succeed.

But I certainly know in this context that it is

worth the effort that we're all putting in and hopefully we will
continue.
So let me say in ending that we who are involved in
international economy either on the private sector basis or
public basis have got an extraordinary complex set of economic,
social, financial problems ahead of us.

But what I think is

increasingly becoming clear is that these two basic forces, one
the economic and the other the political, are both working in a
way which is shedding a lot of potential problems and at least
creates the environment where one can look toward the future
with some degree of optimism, even though one necessarily sees
an extraordinarily large amount of short-term problems that
basically will confront us for the months ahead, probably the
years ahead.

But there is nothing fundamental to the evolution

13
of the world's economy which in any way suggests that we are at
some point where the expansion in economic growth and human
standards of living are about to come to a halt.
Thank you very much.