View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
8-40 A M
CDT
(9 40 A M
May 11. 19 95

E D T )

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
31st Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Chicago, Illinois
May 11, 1995

Financial Innovations and the Supervision of Financial
Institutions

Once again it is my pleasure to address the Chicago
Fed's Conference on Bank Structure and Competition, and I
would like to begin by thanking Chicago's new president.
Michael Moskow, for the opportunity to do so
Michael's
predecessors made this conference the single most important
annual gathering of its kind in the United States
I am
both pleased to be a part of it and to see that the new
president is continuing his predecessors' tradition of
excellence
The theme of this year's conference -- assessing
innovations in banking - - certainly continues two other
traditions of these meetings
relevance and timeliness
Innovations in data processing and telecommunications,
advances in the science and art of risk measurement and
management, the increasing globalization of financial
markets, and deregulation at home and abroad have permitted
and encouraged a blossoming of new financial products and
activities
As a result of these changes, competition in
the financial services industry has increased greatly, and
millions of consumers of such services have been made better
off
But we have also witnessed some spectacular failures,
such as the collapse of Barings Bank and the financial
crisis in Orange County, in which some of the new financial
instruments have played a highly visible role
I do not wish to downplay the controversies
generated by these new instruments and activities, but in
debates about the specifics we often tend to lose sight of
the larger picture
Thus, in my remarks this morning, I
intend to focus on four major implications of these new
developments in financial markets

-2• First, financial innovations have not changed the
substance of banking
The core functions of
banking remain the measurement, acceptance, and
management of risk
• Second, a critical result of the recent
innovations is further blurring of distinctions
between traditional forms of financial
intermediaries, such as commercial banks,
investment banks, insurance companies, and
specialized finance companies
• Third, viewed in the context of this blurring of
distinctions, repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act,
at least insofar as such repeal permitted mergers
between largely financial businesses, would not
be a major innovation in itself
Rather, such
legislation would constitute more of a
recognition of evolving market reality, much as
was true of the recent repeal of federal
restrictions on interstate banking and branching
• Finally, on the assumption that Glass-Steagall
will continue to be "repealed" by the marketplace, and will, hopefully in the very near
future, be repealed by the Congress, a critical
issue for supervisors is how to achieve our ongoing and unchanged supervisory goals in an
increasingly complex financial world, especially
a world in which it is more and more difficult to
make distinctions based on the functions of
particular financial entities
The Blurring of Distinctions Between Financial
Intermediaries
Last year I argued before this audience that a
crucial difference between the banks of today and those of

-3the not-too-distant past is that risk information processing
now lies closer to the core of the banking business
Yet,
the computer-driven risk management activities of today's
banks do not differ in purpose from those of earlier banks.
when credit officers made less formalized but equally
critical judgments, and portfolio managers had far fewer
types of financial instruments in which to invest and did so
with less rigorous analysis
In substance, banks have
always been measuring, taking, and managing risk
This morning I want to push this point a little
further, and to argue that it is becoming increasingly
difficult to distinguish the core functions of banking from
the core functions of other financial intermediaries
Each
of the various "types" of financial firm increasingly
engages in activities traditionally the province of the
others
And each of these types of financial business has
as its core functions the measurement, acceptance, and
management of risk
Examples abound that demonstrate this blurring of
distinctions
For instance, the economics of a typical loan
syndication, including the types of risks inherent in such a
syndication, do not differ essentially from the economics of
a best-efforts securities underwriting
The expertise
required to manage prudently the writing of OTC derivatives
is similar to that required for using exchange-traded
futures and options
Except for differences imposed by law
or regulation, it is difficult to identify substantive
differences between a guaranteed investment contract
provided by an insurance company, and a bank investment
contract provided by a bank
My list could go on
It is sufficient to say that,
in my judgment, a strong case can be made that the evolution
of financial technology has changed forever our ability to
place financial functions in neat little boxes
And, I
would emphasize, this is both logical and appropriate,

-4Economists long ago observed that, over time, competition
erodes the economic "rents" associated with new products
This process also leads to the evolution of what we might
term "generic" products for older, established goods and
services
At the same time, it causes firms to continually
innovate in an attempt to establish new market niches
This
intense competitive pressure is a primary reason for the
tremendous variety of products and services that
characterize a market economy, and that meet the specialized
needs of millions of consumers
Financial services,
including various types of risk and risk management, are
subject to the same forces as any other sector of our
economy
Indeed, financial derivatives are particularly good
examples of the innovative process I am describing
Derivatives allow the unbundling of the total risk of more
generic products into that risk's component parts, and
facilitate the transfer of the individual risk components to
those most willing and able to bear them
In addition, the
decomposing of risk allows financial engineers to recombine
the pieces in ways that mimic the risk profiles of other
activities which were once thought of as separate and
unique
The end result is a set of financial instruments
and strategies that make it increasingly possible for all
financial institutions to do essentially the same thing
All of this is not to say that the blending of
financial institutions is anywhere near complete
There
remain key products and services, such as the provision of
small business loans, insured deposits, and certain payments
services, that are likely to remain uniquely, or nearly
uniquely, associated with banks for some time to come
This
is especially true for many community and regional banks
that are not yet as extensively affected by financial
innovation as larger institutions

-5Nor, in my judgment, should the vast majority of
banks of any size be intimidated, either by the pace of
financial innovation, or by the blurring of functional
distinctions that has accompanied the innovations
In
particular, community banks have repeatedly demonstrated
their competitive resilience in the face of larger rivals
History has also shown that smaller, more locally oriented
banks can profit from innovations that occur at their larger
bank and nonbank brethren
For example, community banks now
profit from the brokering of nonbank financial products
supplied by others
Similarly, community banks are finding
it increasingly to their advantage to participate in the
activities of the securitization markets, either as the
originators of assets to be securitized or as the purchasers
of senior asset-backed securities
However, these examples
illustrate that, as the basic trends of innovation and
change continue, it will become ever more important for
banks of all sizes to plan carefully how they can continue
to profit from market innovations
Viewed in this broader context of the evolution of
financial institutions and markets, repeal of Glass-Steagall
would appear to constitute not so much a major reform as a
recognition of market realities
Certainly, legislative
reform would improve the efficiency of financial markets by
removing artificial barriers to the realization of
production economies
Equally important, competition would
be increased by the lowering of entry barriers to both the
investment and commercial banking businesses
All of these
effects would provide real benefits to both financial
customers and most financial institutions, and for these
reasons alone Glass-Steagall should be repealed as soon as
is possible
But the changes brought about by GlassSteagall repeal would not, I submit, be radical
Rather,
they would constitute the next logical step in the on-going
evolution of the financial system

Regardless of whether legislative reform of GlassSteagall occurs this year or at some future date, financial
supervisors will have to deal with the implications of
rapidly evolving financial institutions
In particular, we
must decide how, and with what tools, to supervise the
evolving financial services organizations of the 21st
century
Supervising Financial Services Organizations
When thinking about how to supervise a multiproduct financial firm, I believe it is important to begin
by stating clearly the primary goals of the supervision and
regulation of financial institutions
These goals, I think
we would all agree, are to maintain the stability of the
financial system, to enhance the efficiency and
competitiveness of U S banking and financial markets, to
protect consumers of financial services from fraud and
deceptive business practices, and to protect taxpayers from
the risk of loss associated with the federal safety net
provided to insured depositories
Today, these goals are pursued by a variety of
entities, including the federal and state banking and thrift
agencies, the SEC and the CFTC, and the state insurance
regulatory bodies
This system, while certainly subject to
a number of inefficiencies and capable of being improved, in
principle could work reasonably well in a world in which
financial institutions and their supervisors could be
identified with particular financial functions
But how
should we supervise financial institutions, with or without
Glass-Steagall reform, in a world in which all financial
organizations perform essentially the same functions and use
many of the same tools? In particular, how can we achieve
our supervisory goals without extending the too often

-7excessively complex bank-like supervision over a wider range
of activities?
We can pose this question in another, but equally
critical way
That is, how can we supervise a wide-ranging
financial institution that has, as part of its array of
services, the offering of insured deposit products, without
a de facto expansion of the federal safety net subsidy?
Indeed, as I look back over my presentations to this
Conference in recent years, a recurring and central theme
has been how to limit the safety net and mitigate its moral
hazard problems
Despite progress in this area, such as
substantially improved bank capital ratios and the
implementation of prompt corrective action, the problems
inherent to the safety net remain and cannot be ignored
Traditionally, the management of important
tradeoffs among possibly conflicting supervisory goals has
employed so-called functional regulation
To most
observers, functional regulation is thought of as a system
in which each separate "function" -- such as commercial
banking, investment banking, or mortgage banking -- is
supervised by the same regulatory body, regardless of the
function's location within a particular financial
institution
Practically, this means that a single
financial organization would have several functional
regulators, and that different functions would be somehow
separated, most likely through the creation of legally
separate subsidiaries, within the broad financial
organization
Functional regulation is likely to remain a
cornerstone of our supervisory theory and practice for the
foreseeable future, since it is extremely unlikely that all
federal, much less state regulators, would be -- nor should
be, in my view --rolled into one
Indeed, as I have argued
in other contexts, I believe that the creation of a monopoly
regulator would be highly undesirable on both political and

economic grounds. In any event, it seems reasonable to
assume that in the future, as today, financial institutions
will be regulated by multiple agencies, each with specific
responsibility for one or more functions
But if we are to
make functional regulation work as effectively as is
possible, we would be remiss if we did not, at the very
beginning, incorporate into our supervisory practice the
recognition that it is becoming increasingly difficult to
define separate financial functions
The need for such recognition and action is
reinforced by the fact that evolving risk management
practices, quite apart from the economics of risk taking,
are making the identification of separate functions even
more difficult and even less meaningful for supervisory
purposes
Today, the largest and most sophisticated
financial institutions are increasingly conducting their
risk measurement and management on a centralized basis with
respect to the entire financial organization
This is as it
should be, for such "macro" risk management is highly
desirable and has long been the rational goal
Advances in management information systems are
beginning to permit a more integrated approach to the
application of the insights of modern finance, and it is
only natural that financial organizations should utilize
these conceptual advances
While still in its embryonic
stage, a few institutions are measuring major categories of
risk, such as credit risk, with an eye toward the covariance
of losses across product types, regions, and customers
Moreover, I believe it likely that, in the future,
institutions will produce integrated measurements of firmwide risk, including credit, market, liquidity and other
risks
In such a world, attempts to pigeonhole financial
functions into narrowly defined roles traditionally ascribed
to a particular type of financial institution would severely
curtail some of the risk-reduction benefits of consolidated

-9risk management, and could reduce the overall effectiveness
of firm-wide risk management
Enlightened functional
regulation must strive to avoid such results
There are other reasons why we cannot rely solely
on a decentralized form of functional regulation of the
financial supermarket
First, perhaps in recognition of the
trends I have been discussing, but also for other reasons,
the customers, creditors, and the general market view
today's evolving financial institutions as essentially
single entities
Moreover, it seems likely that this view
would survive any legislative reform
True, judging by debt
ratings and risk premiums, market participants make
significant distinctions between the insured and noninsured
portions of a bank holding company, and these distinctions
give important support to the view that functional
regulation can be effective
But the critical point for
bank supervisors remains
Trouble in the nonbank portion of
the financial firm cannot be expected to leave completely
unscathed the market's view of the bank subsidiary
In the
worst scenarios, runs on a healthy bank may result
In
addition, legal barriers to the transfer of risk between the
insured depository and the rest of the financial
organization -- the much discussed firewalls -- may not be
as effective as desired precisely when they are needed the
most
What, then, is the solution to the difficult
supervisory puzzles I have raised? In my judgment, prudent
functional regulation must include some type of umbrella
supervision of the entire financial institution
In short,
someone must be responsible for assessing how the behavior
of the entire organization, viewed as an organic whole, is
consistent with our supervisory goals
Indeed, most
industrial nations now subscribe to the need for
consolidated banking supervision

-10But precisely what should the umbrella supervisor
be responsible for? Virtually as we speak this issue is
being debated in the Congress, in the financial industry, in
the regulatory agencies, in the press, at this Conference,
and, I am sure, in many other places
This morning I would
like to suggest some basic principles that, in my
estimation, should guide this debate, and offer a few ideas
for implementing these principles
A core function of the umbrella supervisor must be
to monitor and assess the risks that the nonbank portions of
the financial institution impose on the insured depository
subsidiary, and on the safety net in general
But knowledge
alone is not enough
It is equally important that the
umbrella supervisor be able to take actions that reduce to
acceptable levels the risks to taxpayers and to the
financial system
While achieving these objectives, the
umbrella supervisor must be careful to maintain a delicate
balance
The supervisor must know enough and do enough to
protect the insured depositories and the safety net, but
must not be so involved in the affairs of the nonbank
affiliates and the parent that regulatory costs are
excessive, or that the market perceives that the safety net
has been expanded to the nonbank activities of the
organization
Achieving this balance will be difficult and, given
the nature of financial innovation, will inevitably be a
dynamic process. One promising area for minimizing
regulatory costs with few, if any, risks to financial
stability or the safety net, is the area of applications
procedures
Today, banks and bank holding companies must
apply to their supervisors for a wide variety of things -from opening a new branch to engaging in securities
underwriting
Surely we can reduce, hopefully by a
substantial degree, the need for financial institutions to
make such applications in the future
In this regard, the

-11Board is attracted to an approach embodied in recent
legislative proposals
That approach would eliminate the
current applications procedure for holding company
acquisitions by well-capitalized and well-managed
organizations whose proposed acquisitions, or de novo entry,
are both authorized and pass some reasonable test of scale
The bills would also streamline the process for evaluating
the permissibility of new financial activities
It may also be possible to target supervisory
examinations and inspections more narrowly on the bank, and
on the implications for the bank of activity in the rest of
the holding company
Bank exams would be conducted much as
they are today
But it might be feasible to concentrate
inspections of the rest of the financial firm on its risk
management practices, reporting systems, and internal
controls, perhaps reducing the frequency of exams or
inspections in some cases
Less intensive on-site reviews
of nonbank activities would be even more feasible and
appropriate if the insured depositories of a larger
organization were well capitalized and in otherwise
outstanding condition
Less intensive nonbank reviews - perhaps, for most affiliates, only reports -- might be
especially appropriate if the insured entity were neither
unusually large, nor a significant portion of the entire
organization
The current supervisory regime uses
procedures for bank holding companies in which the insured
bank typically has constituted virtually all of the
organization
As the insured bank becomes a smaller
proportion of the entire entity -- and assuming the
organization is under an obligation to maintain the capital
adequacy of the bank - - we might well reconsider the
necessity, let alone the desirability, of bank-like
supervision for the nonbank affiliates
This list of possibilities is obviously not meant
to be either exhaustive or sufficiently detailed to be

-12operational
Rather, it is meant to suggest that the proper
balancing of supervisory goals will require substantial
creativity and hard thinking by all parties involved
It is
my hope that the current round of debate will resolve these
difficult and complex issues in a way that allows for the
repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act, and the establishment of a
viable and durable institutional and supervisory framework
for the continuing evolution of our financial system
In conclusion, the forces shaping our banking and
financial system are fundamental and on-going
Through it
all, the core functions of banks and bank supervisors remain
unchanged
In addition, while the blurring of traditional
distinctions between the institutional forms of financial
intermediation makes repeal of the Glass-Steagall Act seem
ever more natural, nonstop innovation raises new challenges
for both the public and private sectors
Critical aspects
of these challenges are how to design and implement a system
of financial supervision that addresses evolving realities
and balances the inevitable tradeoffs in a realistic manner
*****