View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan
Federal Reserve Board's semiannual monetary policy report to the Congress
Before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate
February 11, 2003
Chairman Greenspan presented identical testimony before the Committee on Financial
Services, U.S. House of Representatives, on February 12, 2003
Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am pleased this morning to present the
Federal Reserve's semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress. I will begin by
reviewing the state of the U.S. economy and the conduct of monetary policy and then turn to
some key issues related to the federal budget.
When I testified before this committee last July, I noted that, while the growth of economic
activity over the first half of the year had been spurred importantly by a swing from rapid
inventory drawdown to modest inventory accumulation, that source of impetus would surely
wind down in subsequent quarters, as it did. We at the Federal Reserve recognized that a
strengthening of final sales was an essential element of putting the expansion on a firm and
sustainable track. To support such a strengthening, monetary policy was set to continue its
accommodative stance.
In the event, final sales continued to grow only modestly, and business outlays remained
soft. Concerns about corporate governance, which intensified for a time, were compounded
over the late summer and into the fall by growing geopolitical tensions. In particular,
worries about the situation in Iraq contributed to an appreciable increase in oil prices. These
uncertainties, coupled with ongoing concerns surrounding macroeconomic prospects,
heightened investors' perception of risk and, perhaps, their aversion to such risk. Equity
prices weakened further, the expected volatility of equity prices rose to unusually high
levels, spreads on corporate debt and credit default swaps deteriorated, and liquidity in
corporate debt markets declined. The economic data and the anecdotal information
suggested that firms were tightly limiting hiring and capital spending and keeping an
unusually short leash on inventories. With capital markets inhospitable and commercial
banks firming terms and standards on business loans, corporations relied to an unusual
extent on a drawdown of their liquid assets rather than on borrowing to fund their limited
expenditures.
By early November, conditions in financial markets had firmed somewhat on reports of
improved corporate profitability. But on November 6, with economic performance
remaining subpar, the Federal Open Market Committee chose to ease the stance of monetary
policy, reducing the federal funds rate 50 basis points, to 1¼ percent. We viewed that action
as insurance against the possibility that the still widespread weakness would become
entrenched. With inflation expectations well contained, this additional monetary stimulus
seemed to offer worthwhile insurance against the threat of persistent economic weakness

and unwelcome substantial declines in inflation from already low levels.
In the weeks that followed, financial market conditions continued to improve, but only
haltingly. The additional monetary stimulus and the absence of further revelations of major
corporate wrongdoing seemed to provide some reassurance to investors. Equity prices rose,
volatility declined, risk spreads narrowed, and market liquidity increased, albeit not to levels
that might be associated with robust economic conditions. At the same time, mounting
concerns about geopolitical risks and energy supplies, amplified by the turmoil in
Venezuela, were mirrored by the worrisome surge in oil prices, continued skittishness in
financial markets, and substantial uncertainty among businesses about the outlook.
Partly as a result, growth of economic activity slowed markedly late in the summer and in
the fourth quarter, continuing the choppy pattern that prevailed over the past year.
According to the advance estimate, real GDP expanded at an annual rate of only ¾ percent
last quarter after surging 4 percent in the third quarter. Much of that deceleration reflected a
falloff in the production of motor vehicles from the near-record level that had been reached
in the third quarter when low financing rates and other incentive programs sparked a jump in
sales. The slowing in aggregate output also reflected aggressive attempts by businesses more
generally to ensure that inventories remained under control. Thus far, those efforts have
proven successful in that business inventories, with only a few exceptions, have stayed lean-a circumstance that should help support production this year. Indeed, after dropping back a
bit in the fall, manufacturing activity turned up in December, and reports from purchasing
managers suggest that improvement has continued into this year. Excluding both the swings
in auto and truck production and the fluctuations in non-motor-vehicle inventories,
economic activity has been moving up in a considerably smoother fashion than has overall
real GDP: Final sales excluding motor vehicles are estimated to have risen at a 2¼ percent
annual rate in the fourth quarter after a similar 1¾ percent advance in the previous quarter
and an average of 2 percent in the first half.
Thus, apart from these quarterly fluctuations, the economy has largely extended the broad
patterns of performance that were evident at the time of my July testimony. Most notably,
output has continued to expand, but only modestly. As previously, overall growth has
simultaneously been supported by relatively strong spending by households and weighed
down by weak expenditures by businesses. Importantly, the favorable underlying trends in
productivity have continued; despite little change last quarter, output per hour in the
nonfarm business sector rose 3¾ percent over the four quarters of 2002, an impressive gain
for a period of generally lackluster economic performance. One consequence of the
combination of sluggish output growth and rapid productivity gains has been that the labor
market has remained quite soft. Employment turned down in the final months of last year,
and the unemployment rate moved up, but the report for January was somewhat more
encouraging.
Another consequence of the strong performance of productivity has been its support of
household incomes despite the softness of labor markets. Those gains in income, combined
with very low interest rates and reduced taxes, have permitted relatively robust advances in
residential construction and household expenditures. Indeed, residential construction activity
moved up steadily over the year. And despite large swings in sales, underlying demand for
motor vehicles appears to have been well maintained. Other consumer outlays, financed
partly by the large extraction of built-up equity in homes, have continued to trend up. Most
equity extraction--reflecting the realized capital gains on home sales--usually occurs as a

consequence of house turnover. But during the past year, an almost equal amount reflected
the debt-financed cash-outs associated with an unprecedented surge in mortgage
refinancings. Such refinancing activity is bound to contract at some point, as average
interest rates on outstanding home mortgages converge to interest rates on new mortgages.
However, fixed mortgage rates remain extraordinarily low, and applications for refinancing
are not far off their peaks. Simply processing the backlog of earlier applications will take
some time, and this factor alone suggests that refinancing originations and cash-outs will be
significant at least through the early part of this year.
To be sure, the mortgage debt of homeowners relative to their income is high by historical
norms. But as a consequence of low interest rates, the servicing requirement for the
mortgage debt of homeowners relative to the corresponding disposable income of that group
is well below the high levels of the early 1990s. Moreover, owing to continued large gains
in residential real estate values, equity in homes has continued to rise despite sizable debtfinanced extractions. Adding in the fixed costs associated with other financial obligations,
such as rental payments of tenants, consumer installment credit, and auto leases, the total
servicing costs faced by households relative to their incomes are below previous peaks and
do not appear to be a significant cause for concern at this time.
While household spending has been reasonably vigorous, we have yet to see convincing
signs of a rebound in business outlays. After having fallen sharply over the preceding two
years, new orders for capital equipment stabilized and, for some categories, turned up in
nominal terms in 2002. Investment in equipment and software is estimated to have risen at a
5 percent rate in real terms in the fourth quarter and a subpar 3 percent over the four quarters
of the year.
However, the emergence of a sustained and broad-based pickup in capital spending will
almost surely require the resumption of substantial gains in corporate profits. Profit margins
apparently did improve a bit last year, aided importantly by the strong growth in labor
productivity.
Of course, the path of capital investment will depend not only on market conditions and the
prospects for profits and cash flow but also on the resolution of the uncertainties
surrounding the business outlook. Indeed, the heightening of geopolitical tensions has only
added to the marked uncertainties that have piled up over the past three years, creating
formidable barriers to new investment and thus to a resumption of vigorous expansion of
overall economic activity.
The intensification of geopolitical risks makes discerning the economic path ahead
especially difficult. If these uncertainties diminish considerably in the near term, we should
be able to tell far better whether we are dealing with a business sector and an economy
poised to grow more rapidly--our more probable expectation--or one that is still laboring
under persisting strains and imbalances that have been misidentified as transitory. Certainly,
financial conditions would not seem to impose a significant hurdle to a turnaround in
business spending. Yields on risk-free Treasury securities have fallen, risk spreads are
narrower on corporate bonds, premiums on credit default swaps have retraced most of their
summer spike, and liquidity conditions have improved in capital markets. These factors, if
maintained, should eventually facilitate more-vigorous corporate outlays.
If instead, contrary to our expectations, we find that, despite the removal of the Iraq-related

uncertainties, constraints to expansion remain, various initiatives for conventional monetary
and fiscal stimulus will doubtless move higher on the policy agenda. But as part of that
process, the experience of recent years may be instructive. As I have testified before this
committee in the past, the most significant lesson to be learned from recent American
economic history is arguably the importance of structural flexibility and the resilience to
economic shocks that it imparts.
I do not claim to be able to judge the relative importance of conventional stimulus and
increased economic flexibility to our ability to weather the shocks of the past few years. But
the improved flexibility of our economy, no doubt, has played a key role. That increased
flexibility has been in part the result of the ongoing success in liberalizing global trade, a
quarter-century of bipartisan deregulation that has significantly reduced rigidities in our
markets for energy, transportation, communication, and financial services, and, of course,
the dramatic gains in information technology that have markedly enhanced the ability of
businesses to address festering economic imbalances before they inflict significant damage.
This improved ability has been facilitated further by the increasing willingness of our
workers to embrace innovation more generally.
It is reasonable to surmise that, not only have such measures contributed significantly to the
long-term growth potential of the economy this past decade, they also have enhanced its
short-term resistance to recession. That said, we have too little history to measure the extent
to which increasing flexibility has boosted the economy's potential and helped damp cyclical
fluctuations in activity.
Even so, the benefits appear sufficiently large that we should be placing special emphasis on
searching for policies that will engender still greater economic flexibility and dismantling
policies that contribute to unnecessary rigidity. The more flexible an economy, the greater
its ability to self-correct in response to inevitable, often unanticipated, disturbances, thus
reducing the size and consequences of cyclical imbalances. Enhanced flexibility has the
advantage of adjustments being automatic and not having to rest on the initiatives of
policymakers, which often come too late or are based on highly uncertain forecasts.
Policies intended to improve the flexibility of the economy seem to fall outside the sphere of
traditional monetary and fiscal policy. But decisions on the structure of the tax system and
spending programs surely influence flexibility and thus can have major consequences for
both the cyclical performance and long-run growth potential of our economy. Accordingly,
in view of the major budget issues now confronting the Congress and their potential
implications for the economy, I thought it appropriate to devote some of my remarks today
to fiscal policy. In that regard, I will not be emphasizing specific spending or revenue
programs. Rather, my focus will be on the goals and process determining the budget and on
the importance, despite our increasing national security requirements, of regaining discipline
in that process. These views are my own and are not necessarily shared by my colleagues at
the Federal Reserve.
***
One notable feature of the budget landscape over the past half century has been the limited
movement in the ratio of unified budget outlays to nominal GDP. Over the past five years,
that ratio has averaged a bit less than 19 percent, about where it was in the 1960s before it
moved up during the 1970s and 1980s. But that pattern of relative stability over the longer

term has masked a pronounced rise in the share of spending committed to retirement,
medical, and other entitlement programs. Conversely, the share of spending that is subject to
the annual appropriations process, and thus that comes under regular review by the
Congress, has been shrinking. Such so-called discretionary spending has fallen from twothirds of total outlays in the 1960s to one-third last year, with defense outlays accounting for
almost all of the decline.
The increase in the share of expenditures that is more or less on automatic pilot has
complicated the task of making fiscal policy by effectively necessitating an extension of the
budget horizon. The Presidents' budgets through the 1960s and into the 1970s mainly
provided information for the upcoming fiscal year. The legislation in 1974 that established a
new budget process and created the Congressional Budget Office required that organization
to provide five-year budget projections. And by the mid-1990s, CBO's projection horizon
had been pushed out to ten years. These longer time periods and the associated budget
projections, even granted their imprecision, are useful steps toward allowing the Congress to
balance budget priorities sensibly in the context of a cash-based accounting system.1 But
more can be done to clarify those priorities and thereby enhance the discipline on the fiscal
process.
A general difficulty concerns the very nature of the unified budget. As a cash accounting
system, it was adopted in 1968 to provide a comprehensive measure of the funds that move
in and out of federal coffers. With a few modifications, it correctly measures the direct
effect of federal transactions on national saving. But a cash accounting system is not
designed to track new commitments and their translation into future spending and
borrowing. For budgets that are largely discretionary, changes in forward commitments do
not enter significantly into budget deliberations, and hence the surplus or deficit in the
unified budget is a reasonably accurate indicator of the stance of fiscal policy and its effect
on saving. But as longer-term commitments have come to dominate tax and spending
decisions, such cash accounting has been rendered progressively less meaningful as the
principal indicator of the state of our fiscal affairs.
An accrual-based accounting system geared to the longer horizon could be constructed with
a reasonable amount of additional effort. In fact, many of the inputs on the outlay side are
already available. However, estimates of revenue accruals are not well developed. These
include deferred taxes on retirement accounts that are taxable on withdrawal, accrued taxes
on unrealized capital gains, and corporate tax accruals. An accrual system would allow us to
keep better track of the government's overall accrued obligations and deferred assets. Future
benefit obligations and taxes would be recognized as they are incurred rather than when they
are paid out by the government.2
Currently, accrued outlays very likely are much greater than those calculated under the cashbased approach. Under full accrual accounting, the social security program would be
showing a substantial deficit this year, rather than the surplus measured under our current
cash accounting regimen.3 Indeed, under most reasonable sets of actuarial assumptions, for
social security benefits alone past accruals cumulate to a liability that amounts to many
trillions of dollars. For the government as a whole, such liabilities are still growing.
Estimating the liabilities implicit in social security is relatively straightforward because that
program has many of the characteristics of a private defined-benefit retirement program.
Projections of Medicare outlays, however, are far more uncertain even though the rise in the

beneficiary populations is expected to be similar. The likelihood of continued dramatic
innovations in medical technology and procedures combined with largely inelastic demand
and a subsidized third-party payment system engenders virtually open-ended potential
federal outlays unless constrained by law.4 Liabilities for Medicare are probably about the
same order of magnitude as those for social security, and as is the case for social security,
the date is rapidly approaching when those liabilities will be converted into cash outlays.
Accrual-based accounts would lay out more clearly the true costs and benefits of changes to
various taxes and outlay programs and facilitate the development of a broad budget strategy.
In doing so, these accounts should help shift the national dialogue and consensus toward a
more realistic view of the limits of our national resources as we approach the next decade
and focus attention on the necessity to make difficult choices from among programs that, on
a stand-alone basis, appear very attractive.
Because the baby boomers have not yet started to retire in force and accordingly the ratio of
retirees to workers is still relatively low, we are in the midst of a demographic lull. But short
of an outsized acceleration of productivity to well beyond the average pace of the past seven
years or a major expansion of immigration, the aging of the population now in train will end
this state of relative budget tranquility in about a decade's time. It would be wise to address
this significant pending adjustment sooner rather than later. As the President's just-released
budget put it, "The longer the delay in enacting reforms, the greater the danger, and the
more drastic the remedies will have to be."5
Accrual-based revenue and outlay projections, tied to a credible set of economic
assumptions, tax rates, and programmatic spend-out rates, can provide important evidence
on the long-term sustainability of the overall budget and economic regimes under alternative
scenarios.6 Of course, those projections, useful as they might prove to be, would still be
subject to enormous uncertainty. The ability of economists to assess the effects of tax and
spending programs is hindered by an incomplete understanding of the forces influencing the
economy.
It is not surprising, therefore, that much controversy over basic questions surrounds the
current debate over budget policy. Do budget deficits and debt significantly affect interest
rates and, hence, economic activity? With political constraints on the size of acceptable
deficits, do tax cuts ultimately restrain spending increases, and do spending increases limit
tax cuts? To what extent do tax increases inhibit investment and economic growth or, by
raising national saving, have the opposite effect? And to what extent does government
spending raise the growth of GDP, or is its effect offset by a crowding out of private
spending?
Substantial efforts are being made to develop analytical tools that, one hopes, will enable us
to answer such questions with greater precision than we can now. Much progress has been
made in ascertaining the effects of certain policies, but many of the more critical questions
remain in dispute.
However, there should be little disagreement about the need to reestablish budget discipline.
The events of September 11 have placed demands on our budgetary resources that were
unanticipated a few years ago. In addition, with defense outlays having fallen in recent years
to their smallest share of GDP since before World War II, the restraint on overall spending
from the downtrend in military outlays has surely run its course--and likely would have

done so even without the tragedy of September 11.
The CBO and the Office of Management and Budget recently released updated budget
projections that are sobering. These projections, in conjunction with the looming
demographic pressures, underscore the urgency of extending the budget enforcement rules.
To be sure, in the end, it is policy, not process, that counts. But the statutory limits on
discretionary spending and the so-called PAYGO rules, which were promulgated in the
Budget Enforcement Act of 1990 and were backed by a sixty-vote point of order in the
Senate, served as useful tools for controlling deficits through much of the 1990s. These rules
expired in the House last September and have been partly extended in the Senate only
through mid-April.
The Budget Enforcement Act was intended to address the problem of huge unified deficits
and was enacted in the context of a major effort to bring the budget under control. In 1990,
the possibility that surpluses might emerge within the decade seemed remote indeed. When
they unexpectedly arrived, the problem that the budget control measures were designed to
address seemed to have been solved. Fiscal discipline became a less pressing priority and
was increasingly abandoned.
To make the budget process more effective, some have suggested amending the budget rules
to increase their robustness against the designation of certain spending items as "emergency"
and hence not subject to the caps. Others have proposed mechanisms, such as statutory
triggers and sunsets on legislation, that would allow the Congress to make mid-course
corrections more easily if budget projections go off-track--as they invariably will. These
ideas are helpful and they could strengthen the basic structure established a decade ago. But,
more important, a budget framework along the lines of the one that provided significant and
effective discipline in the past needs, in my judgment, to be reinstated without delay.
I am concerned that, should the enforcement mechanisms governing the budget process not
be restored, the resulting lack of clear direction and constructive goals would allow the
inbuilt political bias in favor of growing budget deficits to again become entrenched. We are
all too aware that government spending programs and tax preferences can be easy to initiate
or expand but extraordinarily difficult to trim or shut down once constituencies develop that
have a stake in maintaining the status quo.
In the Congress's review of the mechanisms governing the budget process, you may want to
reconsider whether the statutory limit on the public debt is a useful device. As a matter of
arithmetic, the debt ceiling is either redundant or inconsistent with the paths of revenues and
outlays you specify when you legislate a budget.
In addition, a technical correction in the procedure used to tie indexed benefits and
individual income tax brackets to changes in "the cost of living" as required by law is long
overdue. As you may be aware, the Bureau of Labor Statistics has recently introduced a new
price index--the so-called chained CPI. The new index is based on the same underlying data
as is the official CPI, but it combines the individual prices in a way that better measures
changes in the cost of living. In particular, the chained CPI captures more fully than does the
official CPI the way that consumers alter the mix of their expenditures in response to
changes in relative prices. Because it appears to offer a more accurate measure of the true
cost of living--the statutory intent--the chained CPI would be a more suitable series for the
indexation of federal programs. Had such indexing been in place during the past decade, the

fiscal 2002 deficit would have been $40 billion smaller, all else being equal.
At the present time, there seems to be a large and growing constituency for holding down
the deficit, but I sense less appetite to do what is required to achieve that outcome.
Reestablishing budget balance will require discipline on both revenue and spending actions,
but restraint on spending may prove the more difficult. Tax cuts are limited by the need for
the federal government to fund a basic level of services--for example, national defense. No
such binding limits constrain spending. If spending growth were to outpace nominal GDP,
maintaining budget balance would necessitate progressively higher tax rates that would
eventually inhibit the growth in the revenue base on which those rates are imposed. Deficits,
possibly ever widening, would be the inevitable outcome.
Faster economic growth, doubtless, would make deficits far easier to contain. But faster
economic growth alone is not likely to be the full solution to currently projected long-term
deficits. To be sure, underlying productivity has accelerated considerably in recent years.
Nevertheless, to assume that productivity can continue to accelerate to rates well above the
current underlying pace would be a stretch, even for our very dynamic economy.7 So, short
of a major increase in immigration, economic growth cannot be safely counted upon to
eliminate deficits and the difficult choices that will be required to restore fiscal discipline.
By the same token, in setting budget priorities and policies, attention must be paid to the
attendant consequences for the real economy. Achieving budget balance, for example,
through actions that hinder economic growth is scarcely a measure of success. We need to
develop policies that increase the real resources that will be available to meet our longer-run
needs. The greater the resources available--that is, the greater the output of goods and
services produced by our economy--the easier will be providing real benefits to retirees in
coming decades without unduly restraining the consumption of workers.
***
These are challenging times for all policymakers. Considerable uncertainties surround the
economic outlook, especially in the period immediately ahead. But the economy has shown
remarkable resilience in the face of a succession of substantial blows. Critical to our nation's
performance over the past few years has been the flexibility exhibited by our market-driven
economy and its ability to generate substantial increases in productivity. Going forward,
these same characteristics, in concert with sound economic policies, should help to foster a
return to vigorous growth of the U.S. economy to the benefit of all our citizens.

Footnotes
1. Unfortunately, they are incomplete steps because even a ten-year horizon ends
just as the baby boom generation is beginning to retire and the huge pressures on
social security and especially Medicare are about to show through. Return to text
2. In particular, a full set of accrual accounts would give the Congress, for the first
time in usable form, an aggregate tabulation of federal commitments under current
law, with various schedules of the translation of those commitments into receipts
and cash payouts. Return to text

3. However, accrued outlays should exhibit far less deterioration than the unified
budget outlays when the baby boomers retire because the appreciable rise in benefits
that is projected to cause spending to balloon after 2010 will have been accrued in
earlier years. Return to text
4. Constraining these outlays by any mechanism other than prices will involve some
form of rationing--an approach that in the past has not been popular in the United
States. Return to text
5. Office of Management and Budget, Budget of the United States Government,
Fiscal Year 2004, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, p. 32.
Return to text
6. In general, fiscal systems are presumed stable if the ratio of debt in the hands of
the public to nominal GDP (a proxy for the revenue base) is itself stable. A rapidly
rising ratio of debt to GDP, for example, implies an ever-increasing and possibly
accelerating ratio of interest payments to the revenue base. Conversely, once debt
has fallen to zero, budget surpluses generally require the accumulation of private
assets, an undesirable policy in the judgment of many. Return to text
7. In fact, we will need some further acceleration of productivity just to offset the
inevitable decline in net labor force, and associated overall economic, growth as the
baby boomers retire. Return to text
February 2003 Monetary policy report | 2003 Testimony
Home | News and events | Monetary policy
Accessibility | Contact Us
Last update: February 12, 2003, 10:00 AM