View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
10:30 a.m. EDT
September 8, 2004

Statement of
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
Committee on the Budget
U.S. House of Representatives
September 8, 2004

Mr. Chairman and members of the committee, I am pleased to be here today to offer
my views on the state of the U.S. economy and current fiscal issues. I speak for myself and
not necessarily for the Federal Reserve.
As you know, economic activity hit a soft patch in late spring after having grown
briskly in the second half of 2003 and the first part of 2004. Consumer spending slowed
materially, and employment gains moderated notably after the marked step-up in early spring.
That softness in activity no doubt is related, in large measure, to this year's steep increase in
energy prices.
The most recent data suggest that, on the whole, the expansion has regained some
traction. Consumer spending and housing starts bounced back in July after weak
performances in June, although early readings on retail sales in August have been mixed. In
addition, business investment remains on a solid upward trend. In the manufacturing sector,
output has continued to move up in recent months, though part of that rise likely reflected an
increase in inventory investment. In the labor market, though job gains were smaller than
those of last spring, nonfarm payroll employment growth picked back up in August.
Despite the rise in oil prices through mid-August, inflation and inflation expectations
have eased in recent months. To be sure, unit labor costs rose in the second quarter as
productivity growth slowed from its extraordinary pace of the past two years and employee
compensation per hour remained on an upward trend. But, as best we can judge, the growth
in profit margins of non-energy, nonfinancial, corporations, which, at least from an
accounting perspective, had contributed significantly to price pressures earlier, has recently
slowed. Moreover, increases in non-oil import prices have lessened—a development that,
coupled with the slowing of profit-margin growth, has helped to lower core consumer price
inflation in recent months.

Movements in energy prices have been a major influence on overall inflation this year.
In the second quarter, gasoline prices rose rapidly as a marked pickup in gasoline demand
strained refinery capacity and resulted in sharply higher profit margins. In May and June,
refinery and marketing margins rose to levels that were 25 cents to 30 cents per gallon over
typical spreads going into the summer driving season.
As a consequence of the steep run-up in prices, demand for gasoline eased, and an
accompanying increase in inventories helped to reverse the bulge that had occurred in refinery
and marketing margins. That reduction in margins resulted in a decline in the price of regular
gasoline of about 20 cents per gallon despite the concurrent sharp rise in the price of crude
oil. With margins having returned to more-typical levels, prices of both gasoline and home
heating oil are likely to reflect changes in crude oil prices more directly.

Evaluating the impact of rising oil prices on economic activity in the United States has
long been a subject of dispute among economists. Most macroeconomic models treat an
increase in oil prices as a tax on U.S. residents that saps the purchasing power of households
and raises costs for businesses. But economists disagree about the size of the effects, in part
because of differences in the key assumptions employed in the statistical models that underlie
the analyses. Moreover, the models are typically based on average historical experience,
which is dominated by periods of only moderate fluctuations in oil prices and thus may not
adequately capture the adverse effects on the economy of oil price spikes. In addition to the
difficulties of measuring the impact of oil prices on economic growth, the oil price outlook
itself is uncertain.
Growing concerns about the long-term security of oil production in the Middle East,
along with heightened worries about the reliability of supply from other oil-producing
regions, led to a pronounced increase in the demand to hold inventory at a time when the
level of world commercial oil stocks was rising only modestly. Some of that increased

demand came from investors and speculators who took on larger net long positions in crude
oil futures, especially in distantly dated contracts. Crude oil prices accordingly rose sharply,
which, in turn, brought forth increased production from OPEC and induced some investors to
take profits on long inventory positions. The resulting reduction in the speculative demand
for inventories has, at least temporarily, reduced pressures in these markets, and crude prices
have come off from their highs of mid-August.
Nevertheless, the outlook for oil prices remains uncertain. Higher prices have
damped the consumption of oil—for example, U.S. gasoline consumption, seasonally
adjusted, fell about 200,000 barrels a day between April and July. But the growing concerns
about long-term supply, along with large prospective increases in demand from the rapidly
growing economies of China and India, both of which are expanding in ways that are
relatively energy intensive, have propelled prices of distant futures to levels well above their
ranges of recent years.
Meanwhile, despite the paucity of new discoveries of major oil fields, improving
technology has significantly increased the ultimate recovery of oil from already existing fields.
During the past decade, despite more than 250 billion barrels of oil extracted worldwide, net
proved reserves rose well in excess of 100 billion barrels. That is, gross additions to reserves
have significantly exceeded the extraction of oil the reserves replaced. Indeed, in fields
where, two decades ago, roughly one-third of the oil in place ultimately could be extracted,
almost half appears to be recoverable today. Gains in proved reserves have been
concentrated among OPEC members, though proved reserves in the United States, essentially
offshore, rose 3-1/2 percent during the past five years. The uptrend in proved reserves is
likely to continue at least for awhile. Oil service firms continue to report significant
involvement in reservoir extension and enhancement.
Nevertheless, future balances between supply and demand will remain precarious, and
incentives for oil consumers in developed economies to decrease the oil intensity of their

economies will doubtless continue. Presumably similar developments will emerge in the large
oil-consuming developing economies.

The remainder of my remarks will address the federal budget, for which the incoming
data suggest that the unified deficit has recently leveled out. With the economy continuing to
improve, the deficit is more likely to decline than to increase in the year ahead.
Nonetheless, the prospects for the federal budget over the longer term remain
troubling. As yet, concerns about the budget do not appear to have left a noticeable imprint
on the financial markets. In recent years, even as fiscal discipline has eroded, implied oneyear forward Treasury rates at long horizons, which history suggests are sensitive to changes
in the fiscal outlook, have held fairly steady. Various measures of long-term real interest
rates have also remained at moderate levels over this period.
These developments, however, do not warrant complacency about the fiscal outlook.
With the baby boomers starting to retire in a few years and health spending continuing to
soar, our budget position will almost surely deteriorate substantially in coming years if
current policies remain in place.
The enormous improvement of the federal budget balance in the second half of the
1990s and early in the current decade was due importantly to the rapid growth in labor
productivity during that period, which led, both directly and indirectly, to a vast but, in
retrospect, temporary increase in revenues. The Budget Enforcement Act (BEA) of 1990,
and the later modifications and extensions of the act, almost surely contributed to the better
budget outcomes as well, before the brief emergence of surpluses eroded the will to adhere to
its deficit-containment rules. The key provisions of the BEA expired in 2002, and no
replacement has been adopted.
Reinstatement of a structure like the BEA would signal a renewed commitment to
fiscal restraint and would help restore discipline to the annual budgeting process. But it

would be only a part of any meaningful endeavor to establish a framework for fiscal policy
choices. The BEA was designed to constrain legislative actions on new initiatives. It
contained no provisions for dealing with unanticipated budgetary outcomes over time. It was
also not designed to be the centerpiece for longer-run budget policy; importantly, the BEA
did not set a clear objective toward which fiscal policy should aim.
Budget outcomes over the next decade will deviate, as they always have from
projections—perhaps, significantly. Accordingly, it would be quite helpful to have
mechanisms in place that assist the Congress in making mid-course corrections as needed.
Four or five decades ago, such mechanisms were unnecessary, in part because much of the
budget was determined on an annual basis. Indeed, in the 1960s, discretionary spending,
which is subject to the annual appropriations process and thus comes under regular review by
the Congress, accounted for about two-thirds of total outlays. That share dropped markedly
in the 1970s and 1980s as spending on retirement, medical, and other entitlement programs
rose sharply. In the early 1990s, it fell below 40 percent, where it has remained over the past
decade.
The rise in the share of expenditures that is not subject to annual review complicates
the task of making fiscal policy by effectively necessitating an extension of the budget
planning horizon. In the 1960s and early 1970s, the President's budgets provided
information mainly for the upcoming fiscal year. The 1974 legislation that established a new
budget process and created the Congressional Budget Office required that CBO provide fiveyear budget projections. By the mid-1990s, CBO's projection horizon had been pushed out
to ten years.
Given the changing composition of outlays, these longer planning horizons and the
associated budget projections were essential steps toward allowing the Congress to balance
budget priorities sensibly. Among other things, this change has made the budget process
more reliant on forecasting. To be sure, forecasting has become more sophisticated as

statistical techniques and economic models have evolved. But because of the increasing
complexity of our markets, the inaccuracy of forecasts—especially those that go beyond the
near term—is a large problem.
A well-designed set of measures for mid-course corrections would likely include
regular assessments of existing programs to verify that they continue to meet their stated
purposes and cost projections. Although the vast majority of existing programs would
doubtless be extended routinely, some that face appreciable opposition and offer limited
societal benefit might not clear hurdles set by the Congress unamended, if at all. More
generally, mechanisms, such as triggers, to bring the budget back into line if it goes off track
should be considered, particularly measures that force a mid-course correction when
estimated future costs for a program or tax provision exceed a specified threshold.
I do not mean to suggest that our budget problems will be solved simply by adopting
a set of budget rules that restrain new legislation—even if those rules are augmented by
effective mechanisms for making mid-course corrections. The fundamental challenge that we
face is to come to grips with the adverse budgetary implications of an aging population and
current health entitlements and with the limits on our ability to project the likely path of
medical outlays. The rapid increase in revenues during the 1990s significantly muted the
necessity of making choices between high-priority tax and spending initiatives. In the context
of an unprecedented increase in retirees, the need to make stark choices among budget
priorities will again become pressing. Federally funding access to advances in medical
technology, for example, likely will have to be weighed against other spending programs as
well as tax initiatives that foster increases in economic growth and the revenue base.
Because the baby boomers have not yet started to retire in force and accordingly the
ratio of retirees to workers remains relatively low, we are in a demographic lull. But short of
an outsized acceleration of structural productivity or a major expansion of immigration, this
state of relative tranquility will soon end.

8

In 2008—just four years from now—the leading edge of the baby-boom generation will
reach 62, the earliest age at which Social Security retirement benefits may be claimed and the
age at which about half of prospective beneficiaries have retired in recent years. In 2011,
these individuals will reach 65 and will thus be eligible for Medicare.
The pressures on the federal budget from these demographic changes will come on
top of those stemming from the relentless upward trend in expenditures on medical care.
Indeed, outlays for Medicare and Medicaid have grown much faster than has nominal GDP in
recent years, and no significant slowing seems to be in the offing.
In 2003, outlays for Social Security and Medicare amounted to about 7 percent of
GDP; according to the programs' trustees, by 2030 that ratio will nearly double. Moreover,
such projections are subject to considerable uncertainty, especially those for Medicare.
Unlike Social Security, where benefits are tied in a mechanical fashion to retirees' wage
histories and we have some useful tools for forecasting future benefits, the possible variance
in medical spending rises dramatically as we move into the next decade and beyond. As with
Social Security, forecasting the number of Medicare beneficiaries is reasonably
straightforward. But we know very little about how rapidly medical technology will continue
to advance and how those innovations will translate into future spending. Technological
innovations can greatly improve the quality of medical care and can, in some instances,
reduce the costs of existing treatments. But because technology expands the set of treatment
possibilities, it also has the potential to add to overall spending—in some cases, by a great
deal. Other sources of uncertainty—for example, about how longer life expectancies among
the elderly will affect medical spending—may also turn out to be important. As a result, the
range of future possible outlays per recipient is extremely wide.
Developing ways to deal with these uncertainties will be a major part of an effective
budget strategy for the longer run. Critical to that evaluation is the possibility that, as a
nation, we may have already made promises to coming generations of retirees that we will be

9

unable to fulfill. If, on further study, that possibility turns out to be the case, it is imperative
that we make clear what real resources will be available so that our citizens can properly plan
their retirements. This problem raises a more-general principle of public policy prudence. If,
as history strongly suggests, entitlement benefits and tax credits, once bestowed, are difficult
to repeal, consideration should be given to developing a framework that recognizes that
potential asymmetry.

Re-establishing an effective procedural framework for budgetary decisionmaking
should be a high priority. But it is only a start. As we prepare for the retirement of the babyboom generation and confront the implications of soaring expenditures for medical care, a
major effort by policymakers to set priorities for tax and spending programs and to start
making tradeoffs is long overdue.
The significant improvement in the budget in the 1990s reflected persistent efforts on
the part of this committee and others. If similar efforts are made now, they should assist in
preparing our economy for the fiscal challenges that we will face in the years ahead.