View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

For release on delivery
8:30 a.m. EDT
October 12, 2005

Remarks by
Alan Greenspan
Chairman
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
before the
National Italian American Foundation
Washington, D.C.
October 12, 2005

It is a pleasure once again to speak before the National Italian American Foundation. I
have long since been awarded the status of honorary Italian, for which I am sincerely
appreciative.
In my more than eighteen years at the Federal Reserve, much has surprised me, but
nothing more than the remarkable ability of our economy to absorb and recover from the shocks
of stock market crashes, credit crunches, terrorism, and hurricanes—blows that would have
almost certainly precipitated deep recessions in decades past. This resilience, not evident except
in retrospect, owes to a remarkable increase in economic flexibility, partly the consequence of
deliberate economic policy and partly the consequence of innovations in information technology.
A couple of weeks ago, I outlined to a convention of fellow economists how I believe this
all came about. I should like to share some of those views with you this morning.
For this country's first century and a half, government was only peripherally engaged in
what we currently term the management of aggregate demand. Any endeavor to alter the path of
private economic activity through active intervention would have been deemed inappropriate
and, more important, unnecessary. In one of the more notable coincidences of history, our
Declaration of Independence was signed the same year in which Adam Smith published his
Wealth of Nations. Smith's prescription of letting markets prevail with minimal governmental
interference became the guiding philosophy of American leadership for much of our history.
With a masterful insight into the workings of the free-market institutions that were then
emerging, Smith postulated an "invisible hand" in which competitive behavior drove an
economy's resources toward their fullest and most efficient use. Economic growth and
prosperity, he argued, would emerge if governments stood aside and allowed markets to work.

-2Indeed, within a very few decades, free-market capitalism became the prevailing stance of
most governments' economic policy, even if it was often implemented imperfectly. This
framework withstood the conceptual onslaughts of Robert Owen's Utopians, Karl Marx's
communists and later, the Fabian socialists.
The free-market paradigm came under more-vigorous attack after the collapse of the
world's major economies in the 1930s. As the global depression deepened, the seeming failure
of competitive markets to restore full employment perplexed economists until
John Maynard Keynes offered an explanation that was to influence policy practitioners for
generations to come. He argued that, contrary to the tenets of Smith and his followers, market
systems did not always converge to full employment. They often appeared to settle at an
equilibrium in which significant segments of the workforce were unable to find jobs. In the place
of Smith's laissez-faire approach arose the view that government action was required to restore
full employment and to rectify what were seen as other deficiencies of market-driven outcomes.
A tidal wave of regulation soon swept over much of the American business community.
Labor relations, securities markets, banking, agricultural pricing, and many other segments of the
U.S. economy became subject to the oversight of government.
The apparent success of the economy during World War II, which operated at full
employment in contrast to the earlier frightening developments during the Depression years, led
to a considerable reluctance to fully dismantle wartime regulations when the hostilities came to
an end.
However, cracks in the facade of government economic management appeared early in
the post-World War II years, and those cracks continued to widen as time passed. At the macro

-3level, the system of wage and price controls imposed in the 1970s to deal with the problem of
inflation proved unworkable and ineffective. And at the micro level, heavy regulation of many
industries was increasingly seen as impeding efficiency and competitiveness. By the early 1980s,
the long-prevalent notion that the centrally planned economy of the Soviet Union was catching
up with the West had begun to be discredited, though it was not fully discarded until the collapse
of the Berlin Wall in 1989 exposed the economic ruin behind the Iron Curtain.
Starting in the 1970s, U.S. Presidents, supported by bipartisan majorities in the Congress,
responded to the growing recognition of the distortions created by regulation, by deregulating
large segments of the transportation, communications, energy, and financial services industries.
The stated purpose of this deregulation was to enhance competition, which had come to be seen
as a significant spur to productivity growth and elevated standards of living. Assisting in the
dismantling of economic restraints was the persistent, albeit slow, lowering of barriers to
cross-border trade and finance.
As a consequence, the United States, then widely seen as a once-great economic power
that had lost its way, gradually moved back to the forefront of what Joseph Schumpeter, the
renowned Harvard professor, had called "creative destruction"~the continual scrapping of old
technologies to make way for the innovative. In that paradigm, standards of living rise because
depreciation and other cash flows of industries employing older, increasingly obsolescent
technologies are marshaled, along with new savings, to finance the production of capital assets
that almost always embody cutting-edge technologies. Workers, of necessity, migrate with the
capital.

-4Through this process, wealth is created, incremental step by incremental step, as high
levels of productivity associated with innovative technologies displace less-efficient productive
capacity. The model presupposes the continuous churning of a flexible competitive economy in
which the new displaces the old.
As the 1980s progressed, the success of that strategy confirmed the earlier views that a
loosening of regulatory restraint on business would improve the flexibility of our economy. No
specific program encompassed and coordinated initiatives to enhance flexibility, but there was a
growing recognition that a market economy could best withstand and recover from shocks when
provided maximum flexibility.
Beyond deregulation, innovative technologies, especially information technologies, have
contributed critically to enhanced flexibility. A quarter-century ago, for example, companies
often required weeks to discover the emergence of inventory imbalances, allowing production to
continue to exacerbate the excess. Excessive stockbuilding, in turn, necessitated a deeper decline
in output than would have been necessary had the knowledge of the status of inventories been
fully current. The advent of innovative information technologies significantly shortened the
reporting lag, enabling flexible real-time responses to emerging imbalances.
Deregulation and the newer information technologies have joined, in the United States
and elsewhere, to advance flexibility in the financial sector. Financial stability may turn out to
have been the most important contributor to the evident significant gains in economic stability
over the past two decades.
Historically, banks have been at the forefront of financial intermediation, in part because
their ability to leverage offers an efficient source of funding. But in periods of severe financial

-5stress, such leverage too often brought down banking institutions and, in some cases, precipitated
financial crises that led to recession or worse. But recent regulatory reform, coupled with
innovative technologies, has stimulated the development of financial products, such as
asset-backed securities, collateral loan obligations, and credit default swaps, that facilitate the
dispersion of risk.
Conceptual advances in pricing options and other complex financial products, along with
improvements in computer and telecommunications technologies, have significantly lowered the
costs of, and expanded the opportunities for, hedging risks that were not readily deflected in
earlier decades. The new instruments of risk dispersal have enabled the largest and most
sophisticated banks, in their credit-granting role, to divest themselves of much credit risk by
passing it to institutions with far less leverage. Insurance companies, especially those in
reinsurance, pension funds, and hedge funds continue to be willing, at a price, to supply credit
protection.
These increasingly complex financial instruments have contributed to the development of
a far more flexible, efficient, and hence resilient financial system than the one that existed just a
quarter-century ago. After the bursting of the stock market bubble in 2000, unlike previous
periods following large financial shocks, no major financial institution defaulted, and the
economy held up far better than many had anticipated.
If we have attained a degree of flexibility that can mitigate most significantshocks—

a

proposition as yet not fully tested~the performance of the economy will be improved and the job
of macroeconomic policymakers will be made much simpler.

-6Governments today, although still far more activist than in the nineteenth and early
twentieth centuries, are rediscovering the benefits of competition and the resilience to economic
shocks that it fosters. We are also beginning to recognize an international version of Smith's
invisible hand in the globalization of economic forces.
Whether by intention or by happenstance, many, if not most, governments in recent
decades have been relying more and more on the forces of the marketplace and reducing their
intervention in market outcomes. We appear to be revisiting Adam Smith's notion that the more
flexible an economy, the greater its ability to self-correct after inevitable, often unanticipated
disturbances. That greater tendency toward self-correction has made the cyclical stability of the
economy less dependent on the actions of macroeconomic policymakers, whose responses often
have come too late or have been misguided.
It is important to remember that most adjustment of a market imbalance is well under way
before the imbalance becomes widely identified as a problem. Individual prices, exchange rates,
and interest rates, adjust incrementally in real time to restore balance. In contrast, administrative
or policy actions that await clear evidence of imbalance are of necessity late.
Being able to rely on markets to do the heavy lifting of adjustment is an exceptionally
valuable policy asset. The impressive performance of the U.S. economy over the past couple of
decades, despite shocks that in the past would have surely produced marked economic
contraction, offers the clearest evidence of the benefits of increased market flexibility.
We weathered a decline on October 19, 1987, of a fifth of the market value of
U.S. equities with little evidence of subsequent macroeconomic stress—an episode that hinted at a
change in adjustment dynamics. The credit crunch of the early 1990s and the bursting of the

-7stock market bubble in 2000 were absorbed with the shallowest recessions in the
post-World War II period. And the economic fallout from the tragic events of
September 11, 2001, was moderated by market forces, with severe economic weakness evident
for only a few weeks. Most recently, the flexibility of our market-driven economy has allowed
us, thus far, to weather reasonably well the steep rise in spot and futures prices for oil and natural
gas that we have experienced over the past two years. The consequence has been a far more
stable economy.
***
Flexibility is most readily achieved by fostering an environment of maximum
competition. A key element in creating this environment is flexible labor markets. Many
working people, regrettably, equate labor market flexibility with job insecurity.
Despite that perception, flexible labor policies appear to promote job creation, not destroy
it. An increased capacity of management to discharge workers without excessive cost, for
example, apparently increases companies' willingness to hire without fear of unremediable
mistakes. The net effect, to the surprise of most, has been what appears to be a decline in the
structural unemployment rate in the United States.
Protectionism in all its guises, both domestic and international, does not contribute to the
welfare of American workers. At best, it is a short-term fix at a cost of lower standards of living
for the nation as a whole. We need increased education and training for those displaced by
creative destruction, not a stifling of competition.
A consequence of our highly competitive, rapidly growing economy is that the average
American will hold many different jobs in a lifetime. Accordingly, education is no longer the

-8sole province of the young. Significant numbers of workers continue their education well beyond
their twenties. Millions enroll in community colleges in later life, for example, to upgrade their
skills or get new ones. It is a measure of the dynamism of the U.S. economy that community
colleges are one of the fastest growing segments of our educational system.
***
Moving forward, I trust that we have learned durable lessons about the benefits of
fostering and preserving a flexible economy. That flexibility has been the product of the
economic dynamism of our workers and firms that was unleashed, in part, by the efforts of
policymakers to remove rigidities and promote competition.
Although the business cycle has not disappeared, flexibility has made the economy more
resilient to shocks and more stable overall during the past couple of decades. To be sure, that
stability, by fostering speculative excesses, has created some new challenges for policymakers.
But more fundamentally, an environment of greater economic stability has been key to the
impressive growth in the standards of living and economic welfare so evident in the
United States.