View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF ST. LOUIS
SEPTEMBER 1975

Explanation of the Growth of the
Money Stock: 1974-Early 1975
Real Money Balances: A Good
Forecasting Device and a Good
Policy Target? ..................................

Vol. 57, No. 9




5

11

Grain Exports and Inflation
CLIFTON B. LUTTRELL

f^ U V A T E grain exporters have notified the United
States Department of Agriculture (USDA) of their
intentions to sell more than 10 million tons of grain to
the Russians in the current marketing year. The sales
include 177 million bushels of com, 154 million bushels
of wheat, and 50.5 million bushels of barley.1 They
constitute about 3, 7, and 13 percent, respectively, of
the prospective corn, wheat, and barley crops and are
equivalent to 13, 18, and 84 percent, respectively, of
our average annual exports of these crops to all for­
eign purchasers for the past five years.
The grain sales to Russia this year are for cash.
They carry neither a Government price subsidy nor a
Government credit arrangement. Payments for the
shipments will be made with funds which can be
used immediately to purchase goods and services from
abroad.
This is in contrast to the 1972 sales which involved
substantial Government subsidies. The U.S. Govern­
ment at that time maintained a subsidy on all wheat
sold in foreign markets. The subsidy kept the interna­
tional price for U.S. wheat at a lower level than the
domestic price. These subsidies were a holdover from
the old farm programs which were designed to reduce
the domestic grain supply and increase domestic grain
prices. In addition to the price subsidies, the Russians
received a subsidized credit of $750 million that was
made available over a three-year period for purchas­
ing the grain.
This year, however, no export subsidies on wheat
are available and no subsidized credit is granted to
the purchaser. Consequently, most of the basic eco­
nomic arguments against the 1972 transactions are
missing.

contribute to higher meat and poultry prices which,
in turn, are believed to spill over into higher prices
for industrial raw materials. Hence, restrictions on
grain exports have been proposed in order to halt this
asserted inflationary impact.

Basic Issue is Free International Trade
In the controversy over the entry of Russia into the
domestic grain market, one major point has been
largely overlooked. Restrictions on grain exports to the
Russians will not prevent domestic grain prices from
rising unless restrictions are placed on all grain ex­
ports. If, for example, the Russians purchased grain
exclusively from Canada, prices there and in other
world trading centers would rise and U.S. grain deal­
ers would have the incentive to sell in those markets.
Grain markets are international and prices in these
markets reflect international supply and demand con­
ditions. Grain will flow to those locations where the
price is highest so long as the price differential ex­
ceeds transportation costs. Thus, as long as the United
States ships grain freely to any other nation, sales to
Russia by U.S. dealers will have no more of an impact
on domestic grain prices than the same amount of
sales by the Canadian Grain Commission or by Aus­
tralian dealers. Consequently, preventing a rise in

domestic grain prices involves the imposition of com­
prehensive controls on grain exports to all nations.

Total Export Controls Have Short-Run Appeal
Comprehensive export controls could be used in the
short run to limit the quantity of grain exports, reduce

1The W all Street Journal, July 24, 1975.

domestic grain prices, and raise world grain prices.
The Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries
(OPEC) is an example of an action where a minimum
price has been set on petroleum exports. This has
led to the accumulation of a surplus of oil in member
countries since the rest of the world has not been
willing to purchase all the oil produced by the cartel
at the prevailing fixed prices. The effect on the quan­
tity and price of goods exported is the same whether
the action is initiated by export controls or by artificial
price supports.

2For examples of such views, see “ Russia Feeds U.S. Infla­
tion,” Business W eek, August 11, 1975, pp. 14-15; “Prices: A
Rude Surprise,” Tim e Magazine, August 4, 1975, p. 59; and
Robert E. Grant, “ Mr. Butz and the Grain Sales to Russia,”
The W all Street Journal, July 28, 1975.

Some nations, by imposing such controls, are able
to increase their wealth since in the short run the
gains from higher prices more than offset the decline

Nevertheless, the recent sales to Russia, like the
earlier sales, have received considerable criticism.
Some analysts have argued that the exports will con­
tribute to higher food prices and to inflation.2 The
rising prices of grain and soybeans during recent
weeks are pointed to as evidence of the inflationary
effects of the sales. Higher grain and soybean prices


Page 2


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

in the quantity of their exports. The OPEC members
have received more foreign exchange for a smaller
amount of exported oil than formerly.
It does not appear that American wheat farmers are
in the same position as OPEC. While it may be true
that total world grain consumption does not fall
Sharply in response to higher prices, the United States
faces strong competition from other grain producing
nations. If we were to limit, through export controls,
the amount of grain we make available in the world
market, the effect would certainly be a somewhat
higher world price than otherwise would be the case,
since the United States supplies a major portion of the
world’s grain exports. But our restrictions would cause
other grain producing countries to increase their ex­
ports. Our competitors, instead of American grain
farmers, would surely gain. Small wonder, then, that
grain farmers are objecting vociferously to proposals
to restrict grain exports — domestic grain prices will
almost certainly be lower than world grain prices.
Historically, popular and political demands for in­
ternational trade restrictions generally have been for
limitations on imports, through the imposition of either
tariffs or quotas. These restrictions have penalized
consumers who have been forced to pay higher prices
for protected goods in order to benefit producers who
could not compete effectively in a free market. In
contrast, export restrictions initially hurt producers by
depriving them of access to free world markets, and
help consumers by increasing the domestic supply.
However, over the longer run it is not simply a case of
helping one group at the expense of another. Ac­
cepted economic theory implies that, in general, trade
restrictions make this country as well as the entire
world less well off.

Classical View of Free Trade Still Persuasive
Despite some occasional short-run gains from in­
ternational trade restrictions, the classical view of in­
ternational exchange remains persuasive. In 1776
Adam Smith outlined a system of free trade among
nations with arguments which are still held as valid
by most economic analysts.3 He pointed to the gains
from the specialization of labor and trade in a small
community. Through such specialization and exchange
of goods and services the total volume of real product
is increased and the costs of goods and services are
lower than if each person attempted to be selfsufficient.
3Adam Smith, T he W ealth o f Nations (New York: The Mod­
em Library, 1937), pp. 3-4.



SEPTEMBER

1975

Smith postulated that the gains accruing from the
specialization of labor and other resources in a local
economy are not basically different from those accru­
ing from the specialization of resource use and ex­
change among nations.4 He contended that the bene­
fits stem directly from imports rather than from
exports. Gains accrue because the imported commodi­
ties can be acquired through trade at a lower cost
than similar or substitutable commodities can be pro­
duced domestically.
The mutual gains from trade can be demonstrated
with a simple example using only two countries and
two goods. Suppose we consider some hypothetical
cost of production figures for the United States and
West Germany, as in Table I.
Table I

C O S T O F P R O D U C T IO N
In the
United States

In W est
G erm any

W heat, per bushel

$ 2 .5 0

DM 5

W ine, per barrel

$5.0 0

DM 5

Product

In the United States, we must devote to the pro­
duction of every barrel of wine resources which could
otherwise produce two bushels of wheat, while West
Germany gives up only one bushel per barrel of wine.
Alternatively, we can say that the United States gets
two bushels of wheat for every barrel of wine we
give up in production, while West Germany gets
only one. Clearly, the U.S. is a more efficient (that is,
lower cost) producer of wheat, and West Germany is
a more efficient producer of wine.
Suppose with an exchange rate of 1.5 Deutschmarks
per dollar, we decide to export 100 bushels of wheat
for which we give up potential production of 50 bar­
rels of wine. In order to get the $250 to pay for the
wheat, West Germany gives us DM 375 (1.5 x $250)
which we in turn can use to buy 75 barrels of wine,
surely an improvement over the 50 we gave up. Notice
also that Germany’s DM 375, which purchased 100
bushels of wheat in the United States, would have
yielded only 75 bushels of domestically produced
wheat.
This example shows that countries engaging in trade
are able to get more goods and services from their
endowments of resources than they could by using
those resources to produce solely for their own con­
sumption. Each is encouraged to expand the produc­
tion of those goods which it produces more efficiently
and to trade them for goods which others can produce
4Ibid, p. 424.
Page 3

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

at lower cost. Conversely, any restriction which turns
a country back toward greater self-sufficiency attains
it at the cost of getting less from its resources — that
is, a lower standard of living.

The Case at Hand
Considering the nation as a whole, what might we
expect to result from the imposition of restrictions on
the amount of grain exported? Given an inelastic
demand for grain, a small decline in U.S. grain ex­
ports could cause a relatively large increase in the
world price of grain in the short run. Total receipts
derived from grain exports would then be greater than
in the absence of export restrictions. Depending on
the extent to which U.S. farmers participate in the
higher returns from the world grain market, both
farmers and consumers could gain relative to the free
market solution. On the other hand, if the world price
of grain did not rise sufficiently to offset the reduced
volume of grain exports (that is, if demand for grain
is elastic), total receipts derived from these sales
would be less than without the grain export limita­
tions. The dollar price of foreign currency would then
be higher, resulting in higher prices paid for the for­
eign goods and services we import. In this case the
farmer is obviously worse off and the consumer is
either better or worse off, depending on one’s pur­
chases of domestic food relative to imported goods
and services. So even immediately, the restrictions
which lead to lower domestic grain prices might not
provide an unmixed blessing for American consumers.
In the longer run, however, the effects of export
restrictions are more drastic (and we have learned
how difficult it is to escape from “temporary” gov­
ernment policies, once they are established). Grain
farmers, finding that they are not allowed to garner
the profits which they would receive from free trade
as a result of their superior efficiency as compared to
their foreign competitors, will reduce grain produc­
tion and turn to alternative forms of employment. In
short, resources which were previously used to pro­
duce goods which we could sell to other countries in
exchange for commodities which they produce more
cheaply are now used to produce those commodities
for ourselves — at a higher cost.

Will Unrestricted Grain Exports Cause
Inflation?
The belief that inflationary pressures arise from the
unrestricted export of grain stems from a basic con­
fusion between the forces which cause changes in

Page 4


SEPTEMBER

1975

relative prices and those which affect the general
price level. It is quite true that an increase in foreign
demand, if it is allowed to be effective, would raise
the price of grain and grain-related products. It is not
true, however, that this effect would spill over to
higher prices for other goods. The increased demand
for dollars to buy the grain would make imported
goods and services less costly to Americans — if not
now, then at some time in the future. This, in turn,
would exert a downward pressure on the prices of
domestic goods which compete with imports. Further,
the higher price of dollars to foreigners would induce
them to buy fewer American goods, leaving more
available for domestic consumption and making them
cheaper to us.
On the other hand, a rise in the price level (that
is, a rise in the average of prices of all goods)
occurs when we have more money to spend on an
unchanged stock of goods and services or if we were
to have the same amount of money to spend on a
smaller quantity. This would certainly occur if we
were to give our grain away, receiving nothing in
return. Since this is not the question in the recent
grain sales, there is no reason to expect that allowing
farmers to sell their output as profitably as they can
will contribute to inflation.
It is far more likely that a higher price level will
follow from a long-run policy of export restriction on
farm products. The resultant shift of resources out of
agriculture into other uses implies that we will have
fewer of all goods and services than we could other­
wise have. Without reduced money supply growth
and with a smaller commodity bundle available for
domestic purchase, aggravated inflation is to be
expected.

Summary
Export controls on grain shipments to Russia have
been proposed. It is contended that such exports lead
to higher food prices and further inflation. Restrictions
on exports to Russia, however, will not prevent do­
mestic grain prices from rising unless comprehensive
controls are placed on all grain exports.
Comprehensive export controls have appeal in the
short run since they tend to restrict current domestic
food prices. In the longer run the effects of export
controls are always harmful. They result in a decline
in the world value of the dollar, an increase in the
price of imported goods, less output from our pro­
ductive resources, a higher average price level, and
a lower standard of living.

Explanation of the Growth of the
Money Stock: 1974 -Early 1975
ALBERT E. BURGER

“THE GROWTH OF THE
MONEY STOCK DECELER­
ATED SHARPLY IN 1974 AND
EARLY 1975.” To many readers
such a headline would be re­
garded as something less than
spectacular, being greeted by
muffled yawns. But this devel­
opment is undeserving of such a
ho-hum response; the event is
actually noteworthy on several
counts. For one, the deceleration
in money growth accompanied
one of the worst periods of eco­
nomic attainment since World
War II. Second, the slowdown
in monetary expansion occurred
in spite of a continued expan­
sion in the monetary base — a
measure which historically has
been a precursor for movements
in the money stock. This second
point is the focus of discussion
in this article.

Framework of Analysis
This article analyzes the
growth of the money stock in
1974 and early 1975 using the
framework of a money supply
hypothesis in which the money
stock (M ) is expressed as the
product of the monetary base
(B ) and a multiplier (m ). In
the expression M = mB, the
term “m” ’incorporates the effects
of all factors which operate to
change the stock of money other
than those summarized in the
monetary base.



Table I

A n n u a l G row th Rates o f M o n e ta ry Base
a n d M o n e y : 1974 through e a rly 1 9 7 5 1
Three-Month Periods
Growth Rate
of
M one tary Base

Growth Rate
of M o ne y

Difference Between
the Growth Rate
of Base and M o n e y 2

12/73 -

3/74

7 .7 %

5 .6 %

2 .1 %

1/74-

4/74

9.3

8.7

0.6

2/74 -

5/74

8.8

6.8

2.0

3/74-

6/74

9.6

7.2

2.4

4/74-

7/74

7.5

5.6

1.9

5/74 -

8/74

7.3

4.2

3.1

6/74-

9/74

7.5

1.0

6.5 *

7 /7 4 - 10/74

7.2

1.7

5 .5 *

8/7 4 - 11/74

9.3

4.5

4.8 *

9/74 - 12/74
1 0 / 7 4 - 1 /7 5

9.8

5.4

4.4

0.9

4.0

11/74-

2/75

4.9
4.4

-0.1

12/74-

3/75

4.3

2.4

1.9

Mean

3.36

Standard Deviation

1.72

4 .5 *

Six-M onth Periods
12/73 1/742/74 -

6/74
7/74
8/74

3/74 -

8 .6 %

6 .4 %

2 .2 %

8.4
8.1

7.1
5.5

1.3
2.6

9/74

8.5

4.0

4 .5 *

4/74 - 10/74

7.3

3 .7 *

5/74 - 11/74

8.3

3.6
4.4

6/7 4 - 12/74
7 / 7 4 - 1 /7 5

8.7
6.0

3.2

5 .5 *

1.3

4 .7 *

8/74 -

2 /7 5

6.8

2.2

4 .6 *

9/74 -

3/75

7.0

3.9
M ean

3.1

Standard Deviation

1.30

3.9 *

3.61

Twelve-Month Periods
12/73 - 1 2/74

8 .6 %

4 .8 %

3 .8 % *

1/ 7 4 -

1/ 7 5

7.2

4.2

3.0*

2/74-

2/75

7.5

3.8

3 .7 *

3/74 -

3/75

7.8

4.0

3 .8 *

M e an

3.58

Standard Deviation

0.39

1A11 data are seasonally adjusted, The results are based upon m oney stock and related data as
available in late A ugust 1975.
2A n asterisk indicates that the difference exceeds tw o standard deviations, based on the sample
period 1954-1973.

Page 5

SEPTEMBER

FEDERAL. RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

1975

M o n e ta ry Multiplier

The monetary base summarizes the effects of actions
by the monetary authorities on the money stock and
is the basic factor limiting the growth of the stock of
money. Movements of the monetary base are dom­
inated by changes in Federal Reserve open market
purchases of Government securities, lending to mem­
ber banks, and changes in required reserve ratios.
These Federal Reserve actions determine the total of
bank reserves and currency in circulation, which com­
prises the “base” upon which the money stock rests.
The Federal Reserve, if it is willing to accept the
corresponding movement of interest rates, can set
the monetary base at any value it desires over a
period of as short as a month.
Historically, the growth rates of money and mone­
tary base have been, on average, about the same. How­
ever, from about mid-1974 into early 1975 there was
a progressive widening between the growth rates of
base and money, as shown in Table I on p. 5. By the
end of 1974 this divergence had increased to almost 4
percentage points, which is very unusual by historical
standards. The sharply reduced growth rate of money,
while the growth of the monetary base was little
changed, reflected a substantial decline in the money
multiplier. As shown in the accompanying chart, the
fall in the multiplier from early 1974 to early 1975 was
the sharpest of any one-year period in the past 25
years.
The money multiplier is affected by a number of
factors not under the control of the monetary authori­

Page 6


ties. Among these are the following: decisions of the
public as to the amount of currency it wishes to hold
relative to the amount of demand deposits it holds,
summarized in the k-ratio; decisions of the public
as to the amount of time deposits it wishes to hold
relative to demand deposits, summarized in the t-ratio;
the amount of U. S. Government demand deposits
relative to private demand deposits, summarized in
the g-ratio; and the amount of reserves relative to
total deposits, summarized in the r-ratio.
These ratios are the “proximate” determinants of the
multiplier. Combined with the monetary base, they
constitute the proximate determinants of the money
stock. They describe the actual behavior of the pub­
lic, banks, and the Treasury. This behavior, in turn,
reflects responses to basic economic factors such as
interest rates, growth of income, wealth, price expec­
tations, and regulatory actions such as Regulation Q
ceiling rates on time deposits. This article does not
examine the factors influencing changes in the proxi­
mate determinants of money growth.1 In terms of its
proximate determinants, the multiplier (m) may be
expressed in the following manner:
m

1+k
r(l+t+g)+k

Since factors other than the growth of the monetary
base substantially affected the growth of the money
1For an explanation of the dependence of the multiplier ratios
on these ultimate determinants, see Albert E. Burger, The
Money Supply Process (Belmont, California: Wadsworth
Publishing Co., 1971), pp. 45-111.

SEPTEMBER

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

1975

Table II

Relative Contributions o f the C o m po ne nts of
the M o n e y M ultiplier to the G row th Rate o f M o n e y 1
1 95 4 - 1973

t-ratio2
M ean
Standard Deviation

O n e Month

Three Months

Six Months

Nine Months

Twelve Months

-1 .3 3 8 %
1.694

-1 .3 4 9 %

-1 .3 4 8 %

-1 .3 4 4 %

-1 .3 3 7 %

1.388

1.213

1.130

1.058

-2 .6 4 7 %

-2 .7 1 2 %

December 1973 - March 1975
M ean
Standard Deviation

-2 .6 9 0 %

-2 .7 9 9 %

2.560

0.723

-2 .6 8 0 %
0.3 8 0

0.2 5 7

0.071

195 4 - 1973
k-ratio3
M ean
Standard Deviation

-0 .1 0 7 %

-0 .1 2 0 %

-0 .1 2 1 %

-0 .1 3 2 %

-0 .1 4 3 %

1.803

1.132

0.9 1 4

0.805

0.715

M ean

-2 .5 5 4 %

-2 .5 9 4 %

-2 .5 7 8 %

-2 .6 3 0 %

December 1 97 3 - March 1975

Standard Deviation

2.153

-2 .5 1 3 %
1.010

1.301

0.4 6 7

0.0 9 5

195 4 - 1973
r-ratio4
M e an

1.395%

1.373%

1 .373%

1 .377%

1.373%

Standard Deviation

2.381

1.166

0.8 9 7

0.7 7 7

0.708

M ean

2 .0 1 3 %
3.705

2 .1 0 6 %

1.681 %

1 .5 7 8 %

1.873%

1.455

0.843

0.375

0.3 6 7

December 1 97 3 - March 1 97 5
Standard Deviation

1 95 4 - 1973
g-ratio5
M ean

0 .0 3 4 %

0 .0 1 9 %

0 .0 1 2 %

0 .0 0 8 %

0 .0 0 8 %

Standard Deviation

1.556

0.662

0.3 7 0

0.255

0.2 0 7

December 1 97 3 - March 1975
M ean

0 .0 9 7 %

0 .1 7 4 %

0 .1 6 5 %

0 .1 5 8 %

0.1 6 7 %

Standard Deviation

0.708

0.1 5 0

0.1 12

0.0 8 0

0 .0 5 7

1A11 the ratios are com puted using seasonally adjusted data. These results are based upon m oney stock and related data as available in late
A ugust 1975.
2t-ratio — Tim e d ep osits/p riva te demand deposits.
3k-ratio =

Currency held by the p u b lic/p riv a te demand deposits.

4r-ratio = Bank reserves/private demand deposits + tim e deposits + governm ent demand deposits. Bank reserves are defined as m ember bank
deposits at the F. R. Banks in the current period plus vault cash o f all com m ercial banks in the current period, and the ratio is adjusted for
reserve requirem ent ratio changes and shifts in the same type o f deposits between banks where different reserve requirem ent ratios apply.
5g-ratio = Governm ent demand d ep osits/p riva te demand deposits.

stock in 1974 and early 1975, this formulation of the
money multiplier is used to isolate the relative con­
tribution of each of the components of the multiplier
to the growth rate of money. The sum of the contribu­
tions of the components of the multiplier equals the
contribution of the multiplier to the growth of the
money stock.

tiplier, the mean value and standard deviation of its
contribution to the growth of the money stock are
given. The standard deviation is a measure of the
variability of the contribution of each of the ratios. In
general, the larger the standard deviation, the more
the contribution of the ratio has fluctuated away from
its mean value.-

Historical Perspective on the
Money Multiplier

Table II yields some interesting implications about
the relative importance of these different ratios ap­
pearing in the money multiplier for the growth rate

Table II presents the contribution of each of the
proximate determinants in the multiplier to the growth
of money for different length time periods from 1954
to 1973. For each of the ratios included in the mul­

-A useful statistical criterion for assessing the variability of a
set of data is that approximately 68 percent of the observa­
tions lie within plus or minus one standard deviation, and 95
percent of the observations lie within plus or minus two stand­
ard deviations of the mean value.




Page 7

SEPTEMBER

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

1975

M o n e ta ry Multiplier Ratios

of money over different length time periods. For ex­
ample, the mean contribution of the Government
deposit ratio (g-ratio) was very small for all time pe­
riods. This indicates that shifts between U. S. Govern­
ment demand deposits and private demand deposits
at commercial banks had very little influence, on aver­
age, on the growth of the money stock.
However, the standard deviation of the relative con­
tribution of the g-ratio declines markedly as the time
period is lengthened. For one-month periods the
standard deviation is quite large — about 1.6 percent­
age points. This is reflected in the very jagged pattern
of the g-ratio shown in the accompanying chart. The
standard deviation falls to about 0.4 percentage points
for consecutive six-month periods, and then falls to
about 0.2 percentage points for twelve-month periods.
These statistical results indicate that, on a very
short-run basis, variations in U. S. Government de­
mand deposits at commercial banks exerted a substan­
tial influence on the growth of the money stock. Over
periods of six months or longer these effects cancelled
out, and the relative contribution was negligible. This
extreme short-run variability of the g-ratio explains a
substantial part of the observed large divergence be­

Page 8


tween the growth rates of money and base on a very
short-run basis.
The reserve ratio (r-ratio) has, on average, exerted
a positive influence on the growth of money equal to
about 1.4 percentage points per year. This ratio de­
creased from 0.137 in early 1954 to 0.073 in late
1973. The decline in the reserve ratio primarily re­
flects the effects of the rising proportion of time de­
posits in total deposits. Average reserve requirement
ratios are substantially lower on time deposits than on
demand deposits.3 Consequently, a given volume of
reserves can support a larger volume of time deposits
than demand deposits.
Beginning in the early 1960s commercial banks be­
gan to bid aggressively for time deposits, primarily
through issuing certificates of deposit. Consequently,
there has been a major rise in the proportion of bank
deposits held in the form of time deposits. The t-ratio
has risen from about 0.6 in the late 1950s to about 2.0
3When the monetary base is used in a multiplier-base frame­
work for analyzing movements in the money stock, the re­
serve ratio which appears in the multiplier is adjusted for
changes in reserve requirement ratios. Therefore, changes in
reserve requirement ratios do not affect the multiplier.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

by the end of 1974 (see chart). The major variations
in the upward trend of the t-ratio have been related
to movements of market interest rates relative to Reg­
ulation Q ceiling rates. As shown in the chart, the tratio declined during 1969. During this period market
interest rates rose very rapidly while the rates banks
could pay to attract and hold time deposits were held
fixed at Regulation Q ceilings which were set in April
1968.4
A movement from demand deposits to time de­
posits, after all portfolio adjustments are completed,
does not result in a one-for-one decrease in demand
deposits. Initially, demand deposits decrease by the
amount of the increase in time deposits. However, be­
cause required reserve ratios are lower for time de­
posits than for demand deposits, the result of this
action is that commercial banks’ excess reserves rise
above the amount they desire to hold, given their
structure of deposits. In the process by which banks
attempt to reduce excess reserves, demand deposits
rise. At the end of the process, time deposits are
greater, demand deposits somewhat lower, total de­
posits higher, and the reserve ratio lower than before
the process began. As shown by the historical data
(Table II), the rise in the t-ratio, which has exerted
a negative effect on the growth of money, has been
partly offset by the positive effect on the growth of
money resulting from the fall in the reserve ratio.
The mean of the relative contribution of the cur­
rency ratio (k-ratio) for all periods was less than -0.15
percentage points. This indicates that, on average, the
growth of currency relative to demand deposits exer­
cised only a very minor influence on the growth of the
money stock. The standard deviation of the contribu­
tion of the k-ratio, however, is fairly large for all time
periods. This indicates that, at times, the currency
behavior of the public has exerted a substantial influ­
ence on the growth rate of the money stock.
In summary, the historical evidence indicates that
fluctuations in Treasury deposits at commercial banks
have not had any significant effect on the growth rate
of the money stock over periods of six months or
longer. The decision of the public to hold a substan­
tially larger amount of time deposits relative to their
holdings of demand deposits has imparted a substan­
tial downward trend to the level of the multiplier
4For example, the market yield on Treasury bills rose from
5.45 percent in November 1968 to 6.43 percent by June 1969,
and then rose to 7.81 percent in December. During this period
the Regulation Q rate on passbook savings deposits was held
at 4 percent. In 1970 market interest rates fell sharply, with
the yield on Treasury bills reaching an average of 4.87 per­
cent in December 1970.



SEPTEMBER

1975

since the early 1960s. Shifts between demand de­
posits and time deposits have resulted in divergences
between the growth rates of money and base. How­
ever, a large part of these divergences have been off­
set by an opposite movement in the average reserve
requirement ratio. The remaining factor, and the one
which appears to have been quite important in pe­
riods when substantial divergences between the
growth rates of money and base occurred, is the cur­
rency ratio.

Factors Influencing Money Growth:
1974 to Early 1975
Let us now compare the contribution of the key
ratios of the multiplier to the growth of money in 1974
and early 1975 to their behavior over the 1954-73
period. For each of the ratios, the 1974-75 results are
given below those for the 1954-73 period in Table II.5
The t-ratio, by itself, exerted a substantial negative
influence of about 2.7 percentage points on the
growth of the money stock over the 1974-75 period.
However, this impact was partially offset by a posi­
tive influence from the reserve ratio which ranged be­
tween about 1.5 and 2.0 percentage points. As dis­
cussed earlier, the time deposit ratio and reserve ratio
tend to move together, but in opposite directions. This
reflects the fact that a rise in the ratio of time deposits
to demand deposits lowers the average reserve ratio.
The combined influence of the public’s decision to
hold more time deposits relative to demand deposits
( summarized in the t-ratio and the r-ratio) would have
resulted in about a one percent rate of decrease in
the money stock, holding other factors constant. For
example, an 8.6 percent growth of the monetary base
for December 1973 to December 1974 would have
resulted in about a 7.6 percent rate of growth of
money. If the growth in time deposits had been the
only other factor affecting the longer-run growth of
money, the growth of money and base would have
remained relatively close together.
Throughout much of the period from late 1973 to
early 1975, the currency behavior of the public was
the major factor restraining the growth rate of money
below the growth rate of the monetary base. As shown
in Table II, movements in the currency ratio con­
tributed about a 2.6 percent rate of decrease to the
money stock. The size of this effect was very large by
historical standards. For example, it was more than
°All empirical results are based upon money stock and re­
lated data as reported in late August 1975.
Page 9

SEPTEMBER

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Table III

G ro w th Rates o f M o n e ta ry A g g r e g a t e s :
Selected Periods1
I/ 7 2 -IV / 7 3

IV /73-1/75
4.4 %

M o n e y Stock

7 .2 %

M onetary Base

7.8

7.6

Currency Held by the Public

8.1

10.1

Adjusted Bank Reserves2

7.4

4.0

Dem and Deposits

7.0

2.7

60.9

78.8

C h a n ge in Currency/Change in
M onetary Base

1Annual rates o f change w ere com puted using quarterly averages o f
seasonally adjusted m onthly data. These results are based upon
m oney stock and related data as available in late A ugust 1975.
2A djusted bank reserves consist o f m em ber bank deposits a t Federal
Reserve Banks in the current period, plus vault cash o f all com ­
m ercial banks in the current period, plus an adjustment fo r reserve
requirem ent ratio changes and shifts in the same type o f deposits
between banks where different reserve requirem ent ratios apply.

two standard deviations away from the mean effect
over all consecutive periods of 12, 9, 6, or 3 months
between 1954 and 1973. Under this criterion the de­
cision by the public to add to its holdings of currency,
relative to the growth of its holdings of demand de­
posits, was very unusual. Since the growth of the
monetary base was not much changed until the end
of the period, the growth of bank reserves fell sharply
and, consequently, the growth of demand deposits
also fell sharply.
As shown in Table III the growth rate of the mone­
tary base, on a quarterly basis, was about the same
over the period from the fourth quarter of 1973 to the
first quarter of 1975 as over the previous seven
quarters. During the earlier period the money stock,
on a quarterly basis, grew at a 7.2 percent annual rate,
about the same as the monetary base. In the 1974early 1975 period the growth of money dropped to a
4.4 percent rate, while the monetary base grew at a
7.6 percent rate.


Page 10


1975

In this recent period the growth of currency held
by the public increased to an average rate of 10
percent, compared to an 8 percent rate in the earlier
period. Consequently, even though the growth rate
of the monetary base remained essentially unchanged,
the proportion of the change in the base being used
as currency rose from about 61 percent in the earlier
period to about 79 percent in the 1974-early 1975
period. If an additional dollar of monetary base is
used as currency, then the money stock rises by one
dollar. However, if the additional dollar of base is
used as bank reserves, then a “multiple” expansion
of demand deposits results and the money stock ex­
pands by more than one dollar. Hence, the result
of an increased amount of each new dollar of base
flowing into currency was that member bank reserves,
even after being adjusted for a series of reductions
in reserve requirement ratios, grew at a much slower
rate than in the previous period. The growth of de­
mand deposits was sharply reduced, and the growth
of money fell substantially below the growth of the
monetary base.

Conclusions
Changes in the money stock can be analyzed in
terms of the movements in its proximate determi­
nants. The monetary base is the major proximate
determinant of the money stock. Usually the growth
rate of money is closely aligned to the growth rate of
the monetary base, especially over twelve-month pe­
riods. There are times, however, as in the last half of
1974 and early 1975, when changes in the factors that
influence the money multiplier exert a substantial in­
fluence on money growth. This paper has shown that
this recent experience can be explained primarily by
a surge in the growth of currency which markedly
reduced the growth of bank reserves, given the growth
in the monetary base.

Real Money Balances: A Good Forecasting
Device and A Good Policy Target?
A. B. BALBACH and DENIS S. KARNOSKY

OR the past two hundred years, economists have
debated the issue of the proper goals of monetary
policy. In times of strict adherence to the gold stand­
ard, the policy aspect of national money management
was of secondary importance. With fiat money and
loose or nonexistent ties to a commodity standard,
monetary policy became the ultimate determinant of
the quantity and quality of money stock. In a broad
sense, the goal that has emerged is to provide an
amount of money consistent with sustainable economic
growth and the avoidance of such undesirable eco­
nomic conditions as inflation or recession.
Conducting monetary policy in such a noninflationary and nonrecessionary manner, however, is some­
what more difficult than a casual investigation might
reveal. It is not simply the absolute quantity of money
in circulation that affects economic conditions; rather,
it is the relationship between the quantity of money
supplied and the quantity of money demanded.
The quantity of money supplied is controlled by the
Federal Reserve and can be measured, but an accept­
able measure of desired money balances is not yet in
the economist’s tool box. Money balances deflated by
some index of the general price level are often used
because they are supposed to reflect influences of both
money demand and supply. As a result, the concept
of real money balances has been advocated by some
analysts as a leading indicator of economic activity
and as an intermediate target of monetary policy. In
other words, it has been suggested that a decline in
observed real money balances leads to a decline in
economic activity and that monetary policy should
therefore be conducted so as to prevent such declines
in real balances.
Changes in observed real money balances, however,
do not necessarily indicate forthcoming changes in the
level of economic activity and, even if they frequently
have in the past, do not necessarily call for offsetting
changes in monetary policy. As a matter of fact,
changes in the nominal money stock designed to off­
set changes in real money balances can easily produce
procyclical effects and compound the very economic



problems which are supposedly being combatted. In
order to illustrate this point, a simplified theoretical
construct is described which utilizes real money bal­
ances in the decisionmaking process. Issues are raised
which pertain to the use of these balances as a target
of monetary policy and some evidence is presented
for the 1947-74 period.

What are Changes in Observed Real Money
Balances Supposed to Indicate?
All decisionmaking units in society hold their
wealth in inventories of various assets. Businesses
have stocks of raw materials, finished goods, build­
ings, and machinery. Banks hold inventories of loans,
bonds, and real estate. Individual households keep
their wealth in the form of land, homes, automobiles,
stocks of food, clothing, labor skills, and financial in­
struments. All of these economic units have inventor­
ies of money — cash and/or demand deposits.
Some of these inventories are held because they
provide current services (homes, automobiles, food,
raw materials), some because they are expected to
provide future services (stocks, bonds), but most pro­
vide a combination of the two. Since at any given
time these inventories are viewed as an investment
portfolio, the value of each item depends upon its
convertibility into other goods and services, that is,
upon its generalized purchasing power. Consequently,
the value of each asset is perceived as its nominal
value (its current price multiplied by quantity) di­
vided by a general price index. This is the foundation
of the assertion that economic decisions are made on
the basis of real balances.
The size of an individual’s portfolio is a measure
of an individual’s wealth. The distribution among
various assets is determined by subjective tastes
and preferences, existing relative prices, and ex­
pectations as to future relative prices and the price
level. At any point in time an individual attempts to
arrange this portfolio in such a way as to maximize
the satisfaction derived from wealth. Any change in
wealth, tastes, relative prices, or expectations will pro­

Page 11

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

duce a discrepancy between the desired and actual
portfolio and a reshuffling of assets will result so as to
achieve a new equilibrium.
For example, an unexpectedly bountiful wheat crop
would increase the actual wheat balances of some
individuals above the desired level. With everything
else remaining constant, this would increase the
wealth of owners of wheat, and thereby total wealth,
and increase their desired balances of most other
items. In order to reduce wheat stocks to the desired
level and increase other balances to their equilibrium
size, economic units will attempt to exchange wheat
for money and money for other assets. In the process,
both the relative price of wheat and the general price
level will fall (increased aggregate wealth has caused
an increase in desired real money balances and since
actual money balances cannot be increased by the
private sector, the general price level must fall in or­
der for real money balances to reach their desired
level). Changes in the relative prices of existing assets
will then induce changes in the rates of production
of new assets and corresponding changes in the prices
of new output.
Although this analysis applies to any asset in the
portfolio, real money balances are especially crucial.
Autonomous changes in all sorts of assets can affect
economic activity, but the nominal stock of money is
controlled by monetary authorities. In a money econ­
omy any portfolio shuffling will disturb the inventory
of money (people seldom barter) and until desired
and actual real money balances are equated, changes
will continue. Thus, policy tools can be used to con­
trol or induce these portfolio changes.
For instance, suppose that an increase in the
nominal money stock causes actual real money bal­
ances to be larger than desired. In attempting to
reduce their balances (relative to other assets in the
portfolio), people will try to acquire other assets,
whose prices will then be bid up. Exchanges of money
for assets will continue until the increase in the gen­
eral price level reduces real money balances to their
desired level.
A crude interpretation of this theory suggests that

any decline in observed real money balances implies
a fall below some desired level. In the process of at­
tempting to restore real money balances to the desired
level, economic units sell other assets bidding down
their prices. This induces a reduction in output, em­
ployment and prices of current output. If the goal of
monetary policy is to stabilize output, employment,
and prices, a correct policy prescription would be to

Page 12


SEPTEMBER

1975

increase the stock of money in order to reverse the
process. Thus, in this situation observed real money
balances become both a predictor of changes in eco­
nomic activity and a target of monetary policy.
Such an interpretation, however, is an example of
the crudest form of monetarist thought; it assumes
that changes in economic activity emanate solely from
changes in the money stock. Only under such an
assumption can decreases in observed real money
balances be invariably interpreted as indicative of
the process described in the paragraph above. But,
as shown in the wheat example, changes in observed
real money balances can easily occur when there are
unexpected changes in output or changes in expecta­
tions, each of which can be a result of many causes.

What Do Changes in Real Money
Balances Actually Indicate?
Again, real money balances are defined as the ratio
of nominal money balances to some generalized price
level. As Illustration I demonstrates, there can be sev­
eral causes for the decline in this ratio, indicating dif­
ferent forecasts and different policy implications.
Let us start with case I where nominal money bal­
ances decline and desired real money balances remain
constant. This is a case in which, clearly, an observed
reduction in real money balances implies an eco­
nomic contraction; the correct countercyclical policy
would be an expansion in the money stock.
In case II, nominal money balances remain con­
stant while a rising price level causes real money bal­
ances to decline. Here, these events would follow
from a decline in desired real money balances due to
an autonomous decline in wealth, the result, perhaps,
of a natural catastrophe. Since such a fall in wealth
must encompass a reduction in output, the observed
decrease in real money balances would correctly pre­
dict a recessionary tendency but would not call for
an expansionary monetary policy. With exogenous
events causing the contraction in wealth and output,
an increased money stock would only contribute to
the rising price level without countering the real
market contractive forces.
The third case is identical to II in terms of the
cause of falling real money balances except that here
desired real money balances decline because of an
expectation of accelerating inflation. Individual deci­
sionmakers would attempt to protect their real wealth
by reducing their holdings of monetary assets, includ­
ing real money balances, by buying other assets and
thus increasing the demand for output. In these cir­

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

SEPTEMBER

1975

Illustration I

SO U RCES A N D

C O N S E Q U E N C E S O F D E C L IN IN G

REAL M O N E Y

BALANCES

CASE 1

C A S E II

C A S E III

C A SE IV

CASE V

C A S E VI

Current
Decline in
N om inal M o n e y
Stock Growth

Current
Autonom ous
Decline
in W ealth

Current
Increase in
Expectations
of Inflation

Past
Autonom ous
Decline
in W ealth

Past
Increase in
Expectations
of Inflation

Past
Increase in
Nom inal M o n e y
Stock Growth

Declines

Unchanged

Unchanged

Unchanged

Unchanged

Unchanged

Price Level

Unchanged

Increases

Increases

Increases

Increases

Increases

Desired Real M o n e y Balances

Unchanged

Declines

Declines

Unchanged

Unchanged

Unchanged

Declines

Declines

Increases

Unchanged

Unchanged
or Increases

Unchanged
or Increases

Current O bservations
Nom inal M oney
Stock Growth

Output Growth

cumstances a decline in real money balances is as­
sociated with an increase rather than a decrease in
output; again, an increase in money stock would only
serve to reinforce anticipations of inflation and
strengthen the inflationary push.
Of these three cases, a decline in observed real
money balances gives a “correct” signal of an impend­
ing decline in output in two cases and an “incorrect”
signal in the other. In addition, only in case I is an
offsetting increase in the money supply appropriate.
These are not the only possible situations; considera­
tion of additional cases shows observed real money
balances to be an even more unreliable indicator and
target for monetary policy.
Empirical evidence strongly suggests that changes
in aggregate demand produce changes in output and
prices with a lag. Thus there are at least three addi­
tional ways in which falling real balances can produce
erroneous forecasts and damaging policy prescrip­
tions. Case IV shows a decrease in currently observed
real balances resulting from an increase in the price
level which, in turn, results not from a current de­
crease in desired real money balances (as in II and
III) but from a past decrease. This could be caused
by an autonomous wealth decrease in previous pe­
riods and would not indicate a decrease in output
now or in the future. In this case output would fall
at the time of the wealth decrease, but observed real
money balances would be unchanged initially. Real
money balances would fall only later. This case would
be expected in a situation where prices are relatively
inflexible in the short run — a situation not far from
reality. Thus, although this case is analogous to case
II, it would produce both a faulty forecast (in that
the prior decrease in output was missed) and a faulty
policy recommendation.
Case V is similar to IV except that a past decline
in desired real balances is caused by a past change



in expectations regarding the future level of prices.
The current price level is rising because of a lagged
adjustment to a past disequilibrium and observed
real money balances are falling. This again does not
indicate current or future reductions in output. On
the contrary, growth of aggregate demand actually
has accelerated. The decline in observed real money
balances again emits incorrect signals with respect
to forecasts and stabilization policy.
The final alternative VI is one in which the current
price level is rising due to a past expansion in the
nominal money stock, with current and past desired
real money balances remaining constant. The current
decrease in real balances represents an adjustment to
a past increase in those balances. The implication of
this observation is that output has risen already in re­
sponse to the initial discrepancy between desired and
actual real money balances and the current price level
is rising with a lag. There is no reason to expect cur­
rent or future contractions in output. Again, misleading
information is provided by the real money measure.
In addition to the above described alternatives,
there are numerous situations where different rates
of change may produce similar results. Their effects
are analogous.
In summary, there are three basic causes of de­
clining observed real money balances, each with dis­
tinct implications:1 case I, for which the forecast of
declining output and the recommendation for expan­
sive monetary policy would be correct; case II, for
which the forecast for declining output would be
correct but an expansive monetary policy would only
create or intensify inflationary pressures; and cases
'There is also the lingering problem of measurement. Ob­
served real money balances are dependent on price indexes
and thus suffer all of the problems peculiar to index num­
bers. Care must be taken lest the price index replace actual
prices in the analysis.
Page 13

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

SEPTEMBER

1975

C h a n g e s in R e a l G r o s s N a t io n a l P ro d u ct

-----------1...

---------------------------- -------------------------------

----------- ----------- -------- -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------- ----------------------------------- ----------- ■--------- o '" ----- ------------- ----------------------------------------------- ------------ -I

1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976
1_1_GNP at 1 958 prices.
[2 N o m in a l m o n e y b a la n c e s a re c urren cy p lu s p riva te d e m a n d d ep osits. R eal m o n e y b a la n c e s are the m o n e y stock d iv id e d b y the G N P im plicit p rice d eflator (1958=100).
S h a d e d a r e a s re p re se n t p e rio d s of b u sin e ss re c e ssio n s a s d e fin e d b y the N a t io n a l B u re a u of E con om ic R e se a rc h e xce p t the 1 9 7 3 -7 5 re ce ssion w hic h is a p re lim in a ry d efinition.
Latest d a ta plotted: 2 n d q u a rt e r 1975

III-VI, for which the forecast would be incorrect and
expansion of the money stock would be the wrong
policy action.

Historical Evaluation
The experience of the past gives several examples
of the inherent dangers of using observed real money
balances as both a forecasting device and as a target
for monetary policy. In most situations real money
balances have performed reasonably well as a pre­
cursor of declines in economic activity. The exceptions
are notable, however, and offer persuasive evidence
against the use of observed real money balances in
policy discussions.

Page 14


The accompanying chart depicts corresponding
quarterly changes in real GNP, the nominal money
stock ( M j ) , and real money balances ( Mi/ GNP price
deflator).2 Simple visual inspection clearly indicates
that most of the recessions since 1947 have been
preceded by declines in real money balances and cor­
responding decreases in the rate of growth of nominal
money stock. These episodes would fall into our case
I, where decreases in real money balances resulted
from a restriction in the rate of monetary expansion.
This observation ostensibly supports changes in real
2The chart reports the dollar change in each magnitude from
the corresponding quarter one year earlier. This procedure is
used in order to smooth the data and thus present a clearer
picture of the relationships.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

money balances as both a good forecasting device and
a good target for stabilization policy.
The 1950-51 period stands out as an exception,
and is more like case III. Although real money bal­
ances fell precipitously, the growth of nominal money
balances remained relatively constant and a recession
did not develop. The sudden outbreak of war in
Korea in 1950 apparently induced expectations of
commodity shortages resulting from anticipated
price controls and rationing programs. This mood of
speculation caused a shift in the desired portfolio of
assets that people held.3 Desired real money balances
were reduced, as an attempt was made to shift out
of money and into inventories of other assets. The
result was a rapid rise in the price level. Thus, while
observed real money balances fell sharply, aggregate
demand increased rapidly. The decline in real bal­
ances incorrectly forecast a recession and increased
growth of nominal money to offset the reduction in
real money balances would have served only to ag­
gravate the situation.
A second period in which real-balance-watching
yields faulty policy prescriptions encompasses 1973
and the first part of 1974, when the behavior of real
and nominal balances diverge sharply. It appears
that this period illustrates a combination of cases II
and VI. Although the decline in real money balances
correctly indicated the reduction of output in early
1974, expansionary monetary policy during that pe­
riod would have been powerless to stem it. The rate
of growth of nominal money did slow in 1973; but
since most, if not all, of the decline in output in the
first three quarters of 1974 was due to the wealthreducing effects of the energy situation, bad agri­
cultural harvests, and new government regulations,
the effect of slower money growth on economic activ­
ity is uncertain. This wealth loss would serve to re­
duce the domestic demand for real money balances.
The latter part of 1974, of course, exhibited all the
attributes of case I.4
:tThe mood was, “we had better get it now while we still
can.” Thus purchases of goods and services that, in normal
times, would have taken place over a period of several
years were attempted all at once. The sharp rise in the price
level in 1950-51 was followed by several years of price con­
trols and price level stability, and there is evidence that the
level of prices in 1955 was approximately the same as what
would have been achieved without the shock of the Korean
war. Instead of rising smoothly through the 1950-55 period,
prices rose very rapidly early in the period and then remained
stable. See Michael K. Evans, M acroeconom ic Activity ( New
York: Harper & Row, 1969), p. 301.
4Advocates of the analytical power of real money balances
also point to the rate of growth of output in 1973 as




SEPTEMBER

1975

Summary and Conclusion
There is a significant number of economists and
policymakers who assert that all changes in observed
real money balances precede corresponding changes
in economic activity and that monetary policy should
be geared to counter these changes. This article at­
tempts to explain that such a view assumes that all
changes in economic activity emanate solely from
changes in the nominal money stock — an assumption
which is warranted by neither existing monetary
theory nor empirical observations.
Although it is agreed that real money balances
play a crucial role in the determination and predic­
tion of economic activity, the assertion that observed
real money balances provide us with sufficient in­
formation to make accurate predictions and policy
decisions is unwarranted. We have enumerated sev­
eral instances where changes in observed real money
balances would produce incorrect predictions and sev­
eral where, even if predictions were correct, wrong
policy proposals would result. Empirical observations
indicate that since 1947, blind reliance on observed
real money balances would have compounded cyclical
functuations on at least two occasions.
Examination of logical constructs and economic his­
tory over the past 30 years implies that changes in
nominal money balances would be a preferable pre­
dictor and target of monetary policy. This should not
surprise even those who advocate the use of observed
real money balances since it limits the changes in
these balances to a set where the causal determinant
of the change is indeed a change in the nominal
money stock. Again, the use of real balances as a
pivotal variable in economic decisionmaking is not
rejected, but it is suggested that observed real money
balances have a lower probability of correct predic­
tion of changes in economic activity and correct policy
suggestions than nominal money balances.
offering supporting evidence. Observed real money balances
began to decline early in the year, just as the rate of growth
of real GNP slowed markedly. There is danger here,
however, in that the initial decline in real balances resulted
from the not unexpected burst of price increases which
followed the removal of most price controls. This was a case
where behavior of the price index may have been very
different from movements in the actual level of prices.
Both theory and evidence suggest that price controls are
effective in controlling only the price index but not actual
inflation, which is then only suppressed in the data. The
actual rate of inflation during the period of controls in 197172 was probably higher than reported in the indexes and was
somewhat lower in 1973. Thus actual real money balances
were probably somewhat lower than reported in 1971-72 and
somewhat higher in 1973. The decline in observed real
money balances in 1973 was, therefore, probably overstated.

Page 15