The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
CO 13 O GO o cu QQ c R e v i e w October 1982 Vol. 64, No. 8 CD > CD CO CD 01 3 Is It Tim e To Give Up the Fight Against Inflation? CD “O CD 7 The Mix of Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Conventional Wisdom Vs. Em pirical Reality 22 Simple Analytics of the Money Supply Process and Monetary Control The Review is published 10 times per year by the Research and Public Information Department o f the Federal Reserve Bank o f St. Louis. Single-copy subscriptions are available to the public fr e e o f charge. Mail requests f o r subscriptions, back issues, or address changes to: Research and Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank o f St. Louis, P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166. Articles herein may be reprinted provided the source is credited. Please provide the Bank’s Research and Public Information Department with a copy o f reprinted material. Is It Time To Give Up the Fight Against Inflation? Address by LA W REN C E K. ROOS, President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, before the Petroleum and Chemical Industry Conference of the Institute of Electrical and Electronic Engineers, St. Louis, Missouri, August 30, 1982 I AM pleased to have this opportunity to appear before you at a time when critical decisions concerning the future course of economic policy are being made. For almost 15 years, from the mid-60s to 1980, Americans endured accelerating inflation. During that period when prices rose from an annual rate of less than two percent to double-digit dimensions, our economy became afflicted by problems which increasingly weakened the industrial and commercial sinews of this nation. By the end of the 1970s, it became apparent that we were losing the war against inflation. Our losses consisted of more than just higher prices; we suffered significant declines in productivity, sizable reductions in investment and savings growth, rapidly rising interest rates, volatile financial markets, increas ing unemployment and a host of other social problems. Toward the end of 1979, the Federal Beserve took decisive steps to halt the rising growth in money that had spawned the inflation. Its goal became disinflation — a gradual reduction in the rate of inflation through a gradual reduction in the growth of the money supply. Today, after nearly three years of the new policy, we seem to be on the threshold of success. For the first time in several years, inflation has dropped substan tially. So far this year, on an annual basis, prices have risen only about 5 percent, a significant improvement over the double-digit figures of a few years ago. Unfortunately, however, at the very moment of meaningful progress, we are being besieged by a varie ty of economic ills that are severely testing our resolve to continue the fight. Among these are: increased un employment, high interest rates, sharply reduced housing and construction activity, falling commodity prices, low rates of saving and investment, and what some observers see as a declining competitive advan tage for our products in foreign markets. It is becoming increasingly popular in some circles to attribute our current economic ills to our disinflation efforts. Almost daily we are inundated by articles with titles like “How Disinflation Hurts Us All,” “The Costs of Disinflation, ” or, even more alarming, “The Curse of Disinflation.” Congressmen have been quoted as equating our current anti-inflation efforts to the PLO’s efforts in West Beirut, hinting that, if continued, our disinflation policies will reduce the nation’s economy to a pile of rubble. When the Chairman of the Federal Beserve System recently appeared before Congress, he was urged to “consider a major change in monetary policy before it is too late. ” Bills have been introduced in Congress to force the Federal Beserve to abandon its efforts to reduce monetary growth and to revert to interest rate targeting — the very same procedure that produced our past inflation. In the face of this sort of prodding, it is not surprising that more and more people are asking whether the time has indeed come for us to move away from disin flation and reinflate our way back to more “prosperous” times. It is this issue that I would like to discuss with you. 3 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Now, I am not going to tell you that disinflation is without its costs. It is not costless. To bring down and hold down inflation after 15 years of soaring prices requires a major overhauling of our economic system. And, as in any major overhaul, there will be a certain amount of “downtime” — a temporary reduction in output and a rise in unemployment — as we retool for a different economic environment. However, I want to stress that this downtime, for most sectors of the econ omy, is only temporary. It marks a necessary transition to a stable economic environment essential for longer term growth and prosperity. Also, it is important to recognize that not all indus tries will do well even if inflation is halted. Some will suffer permanent losses — especially those that, for a variety of reasons, benefit from inflation. Among these are speculative land and commodity firms, companies that produce and sell “collectibles” of all kinds, and, perhaps, even those publishing companies that market books on “how to beat inflation.” Reform is never without its costs, but in considering whether the time has really arrived to reinflate, I would like to pose two questions: First, is disinflation solely responsible for our current economic problems? Second, can we solve our problems by returning to our old “inflation as usual” policies? I will argue that the answer to both of these questions is “No. ” First, let’s consider why disinflation, per se, is not the sole cause of our current economic problems. Cer tainly disinflation is responsible for some temporary problems. However, some of our most serious prob lems would have occurred even if inflation had con tinued; they are the direct result of a new awareness on the part of the public of the pernicious nature of infla tion and people’s actions to attempt to protect them selves from some of its effects. In the early 1970s, when serious inflation was a new experience for most Americans, people tended to view rising prices as a temporary phenomenon that, like an old soldier, would somehow fade away. While no one in retrospect would question that the decade of the 1970s was one of rising inflation, many people at that time behaved as if inflation either didn’t exist or, at least, wouldn’t persist. Being unconditioned to infla tion, they totally failed to anticipate either the extent or the duration of the problem. As a result many people — perhaps you and I included— continued to save and lend money at interest rates that failed to compensate for our loss of future purchasing power that came about as a result of inflation. This was true even for 4 OCTOBER 1982 many sophisticated financiers whose activities in fluence interest rates. As a result, the real interest rate that savers and lenders received — the actual return after adjusting for the impact of inflation — was not only ridiculously low during the inflationary 70s, it was negative for much of the decade. Now, whenever the real rate of return on financial assets — such as bonds, savings accounts and the like — is unrealistically low — or even worse, when it is negative — people who hold financial assets — the savers — end up poorer and people who sell financial assets to them — the borrowers — end up wealthier. During the 1970s, people who borrowed funds to purchase tangible assets — houses, cars, land, gold, etc. — did well; those who lent funds did badly. Of course, nobody planned it that way. It was, however, a predictable result of the public’s failure to recognize the true nature and extent of inflation. To illustrate how this works, let’s take a simple ex ample. Consider two individuals, each of whom ex pects the rate of inflation to average 5 percent per year over the next ten years. Let’s further assume that the competitive real rate of interest at that time (i.e., the actual return above the rate of inflation) is 3 percent per year. If one borrows $100,000 from the other to purchase a house, the borrower would be willing to pay (and the lender would expect to receive) an 8 percent interest rate on the loan — 5 percent to compensate for expected inflation and 3 percent to provide a desired real return. Suppose, however, that the actual rate of inflation over the ten year period turned out to be 9 percent per year, instead of the 5 percent that was originally ex pected and factored into the loan. If this happened, the lender would be the loser. He would be receiving 8 percent each year on an investment that was eroding in value, due to inflation, at 9 percent per year. Instead of a positive real rate of return of 3 percent, he would be losing one percent in terms of his annual real rate of return. On the other hand, the borrower would be doing unexpectedly well. He would be paying 8 percent annual interest on a house that was appreciating in value at 9 percent per year — and getting a real return from living in it as well. In times of unexpected infla tion, the lender’s loss is the borrower’s gain. And many people failed to compensate for this factor during the inflationary 1970s. However, as this disparity between individual rates of return on real versus financial assets became in FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 creasingly noticeable over tim e, people becam e attuned to the meaning of inflation and took steps to protect themselves against it. They did this by pur chasing tangible assets such as houses, land, commod ities of all kinds — and by refraining from purchasing financial assets that were depreciating in value. process of disinflation itself, that accounts for current relatively high interest rates and most of the disloca tions that have occurred in the economy. And it is that adjustment process that has important implications for assessing whether reinflation would provide any relief from our current problems. It was simply a situation of people awakening to what was happening and adjusting their investments to com pensate for some of the effects of inflation. As a con sequence, land values increased dramatically. Hous ing prices, on average, rose 2.5 percent per year faster than the rate of inflation. Inventories became one of the best ways to hold corporate wealth. Commodity prices soared — the price of gold alone rose nearly 21 percent per year above the rate of inflation. Even if OPEC had not existed, petroleum products would have been a boom industry. On the other hand, finan cial markets foundered. Investors in bonds and money market instruments earned negative real rates of re turn ranging from -0.2 to -0.5 percent per year. The issue, therefore, is what will we gain if we abandon our disinflation efforts? Can we reinflate our way back to more prosperous times? The consequences were inevitable: savers got poor er and the supply of credit declined; borrowers got wealthier and the demand for credit rose. As a result, real interest rates began to rise. Moreover, the public got smarter; after 15 years of living with inflation, people finally came to realize the extent and persist ence of the problem and adjusted their economic deci sions so as to reduce, as much as possible, the disloca tions that inflation produces. Both savers and lenders learned to insist on a return that would preserve their purchasing power as well as compensate them for the greater risk of lending during a period of uncertain inflation. And all of this, of course, put even further upward pressure on real interest rates. By the beginning of the 1980s, inflation awareness, not inflation naivete, dictated the direction of financial dealings. Real interest rates became positive and the benefits people had previously enjoyed from borrow ing to acquire real assets evaporated. As a result, cer tain sectors of the economy such as housing, land spec ulation, commodity purchases, etc., that had previous ly been subsidized by invalid and erroneous infla tionary anticipations began to experience a decline. Similarly, gold prices fell, while bonds and money market instruments finally began yielding positive real rates of return. What happened, in a nutshell, was that the public learned to recognize and anticipate the effects of changes in the rate of inflation and, as a result, is now better prepared to adjust its economic decisions ac cordingly. It is that adjustment process, and not the To some extent, advocates of reinflation are simply victims of misplaced nostalgia or selective amnesia. Critics of today’s disinflation policies seem to have forgotten that the 1970s were not good years for this nation. During the inflationary 1970s real economic growth fell about 25 percent below what it had been during the 1960s; the unemployment rate, which had averaged less than 4 percent in the last half of the 60s, averaged 7 percent from 1975 to 1979. Long-term interest rates, which had averaged less than six percent during the late 60s, reached double-digit levels by the end of the 1970s. It was precisely these problems that led us to embark on the struggle against inflation. It is precisely these long-run consequences of higher infla tion that we can expect to return to if we do opt to reinflate. O f course, there are some who feel that a return to reinflation is necessary to bring relief to certain indus tries that have severely suffered during the disinflation effort, such as the housing and construction industries. That reinflation would accomplish this is wishful think ing! As I’ve explained, the gains that inflation produced for housing and similarly affected sectors during the 1970s arose from the fact that interest rates did not correctly reflect the full impact of inflation. Today, however, the public has developed an infla tion awareness that would prevent this from happening again. The public is now fully aware that it can protect the value of its assets only by anticipating changes in the future rate of inflation. Consequently, if the public were to believe that reinflation was imminent, interest rates would increase to protect investors’ real return. Any anticipated reinflationary gains to the housing in dustry, or to any other interest-sensitive sectors of the economy, would be doomed by upward adjustments in interest rates resulting from heightened inflationary expectations. This is why I find the current clamor for reinflation so disturbing. It is not just that there is no evidence that excessive monetary expansion would bring the results its advocates seek; it is rather that pressure for 5 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS reinflation raises doubts in people’s minds as to whether inflation will continue to decline. In view of the rising sentiment for reinflation, it is not surprising that people remain skeptical as to the extent of our current commitment to disinflation. Many of the sav ers and lenders who were so badly burned in the 1970s understandably are sensitive to what they read and hear that implies a potential weakening of our resolve to continue the struggle against inflation. Just recently, the American Bankers Association re leased a long-range inflation forecast predicting an average inflation rate of more than 9 percent per year over the next ten years. The latest Harris poll of busi ness executives shows that many of those polled expect inflation to begin rising within one year. If bankers and business executives aren’t convinced that disinflation will continue, we can hardly expect to convince lend ers and savers that this will happen. 6 OCTOBER 1982 The solution to this problem, and the challenge facing us for the future, is to make our anti-inflation policies credible to a disbelieving public. There are several things that would contribute mightily to this effort. First, our current monetary policy stance must be maintained; there must be no, even temporary, reinflation “relapse. ” Second, federal deficits must be reduced significantly. I say this not because I believe that deficits by themselves cause inflation — they do not. I say it because smaller federal deficits would reduce the “temptation” facing monetary authorities to monetize a portion of the deficit. Finally, the American public must be prepared to resist pressures for policy makers to revert to reinflation in order to alleviate the temporary pain of the process of disinflation. Only when people become convinced that our anti-inflation fight is “for real” and will be pursued over a long period of time, will inflation finally be eliminated and stabil ity, so necessary for economic growth, be restored. The Mix of Monetary and Fiscal Policies: Conventional Wisdom Vs. Empirical Reality K EIT H M. CARLSON T HE current economic situation of high interest ..Irates, high unemployment and large federal deficits has prompted a call for a change in the mix of stabiliza tion policies. The current mix seems to be one of “easy” fiscal policy and “tight” monetary policy. Many analysts feel the mix should be shifted toward “tighter” fiscal policy and “easier” monetary policy, ostensibly for purposes of putting the economy on the path to recovery. James Tobin, for example, recently stated that: . . . the mix o f policies is unhealthy. To achieve a solid reco v ery , such as th e adm inistration p rojects, and to achieve it w ithout astronom ical in terest rates and se rious crow ding out, w e n eed an easier m onetary policy com b in ed w ith a tig h ter fiscal p o licy .1 Economists at the Brookings Institution have ex pressed a similar view: Beyond 198 2 , th e key to an im p roved econ om ic situ ation m ust lie in a realign m en t of econ om ic policy— a shift in th e mix o f fiscal and m o n etary policy, by m atch in g red u ctio n s o f fu tu re b u d get deficits with an easier m onetary policy. As p resen tly con stitu ted , fiscal and m o n etary policies ap pear to b e on a collision cou rse . . .2 The Congressional Budget Office talks of the clash between monetary and fiscal policy: S tatem en ts from th e F e d e ra l R eserv e suggest that m o n e ta ry p o licy will co n tin u e its an ti-in flatio n ary ^ames Tobin, “The Wrong Mix for Recovery,” Challenge (MayJune 1982), p. 25. 2Joseph A. Pechman and Barry P. Bosworth, “The Budget and the Economy,” in Joseph A. Pechman, ed., Setting National Priorities: The 1983 Budget (The Brookings Institution, 1982), p. 43. stance in the com ing years . . . By con trast, th e budget m easures en acted last su m m er will provide con sid er able stim ulus to econ om ic activity ov er th e n ext few years. This suggests th e possibility o f a clash b etw een m onetary and fiscal policy unless the C ongress en acts fu rth er sp en d in g cu ts and tax in creases to red u ce federal borrow ing o r th e F e d e ra l R eserv e adopts a less restrictive m o n etary policy. If th e clash m aterializes, it will be reflected in high real in terest rates that crow d out p rivate in v estm en t.3 The notion of policy mix is well-known and has been a part of the macroeconomics literature for a number of years, but seldom has it generated controversy as it has now. Despite its recognition, however, little is known about the exact terms of the mix or what indicators of monetary and fiscal policy are most appropriate to use in defining it. For example, neither Tobin, the Brook ings economists, nor the Congressional Budget Office state by how much fiscal policy should be tightened and to what extent monetary policy should be eased. The gravity of the current economic situation re quires that the notion of “policy mix” be given a more precise interpretation. Is current policy what it seems? How does one measure the ease and tightness of monetary and fiscal policies? What measures of eco nomic performance are relevant to the mix argu ment— interest rates, GNP, the ratio of investment to GNP? What horizon is pertinent— short-run, longrun, a specific number of years? Can policies really be traded off to achieve a specific economic objective? These are the types of questions that are given short shrift when the mix of policies is discussed. Congressional Budget Office, The Prospects fo r Economic Recov ery (U.S. Government Printing Office, 1982), p. 27. 7 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS The purpose of this article is to provide some spec ificity to the policy mix question. As a point of de parture, some indicators of monetary and fiscal policy are examined, and a historical classification of policy mix is developed. A conventional macroeconomic treatment of policy mix is then presented, providing the basis for development of testable hypotheses. These hypotheses are tested, and some policy implica tions are derived. D EFIN IN G EASE AND TIGHTNESS OF POLICY Many summary measures of monetary and fiscal policy have been developed over the years. The main reason for seeking such a measure is to provide a quick interpretation of current policy stance. The criteria for selection are that the measure primarily reflect move ments in the instruments of policy and that it not be influenced greatly by the pace of economic activity.4 In other words, the indicator should reflect the thrust of the policy on the economy rather than the reverse. Measurement of Monetary Actions Measuring the stance of monetary policy revives many controversial issues, one of the oldest of which centers on the choice between interest rates and monetary aggregates. Although the level of interest rates is often alluded to as an indicator of monetary policy, most analysts have found it to be unreliable as a policy measure, since a great many forces influence interest rates besides monetary actions. The monetary aggregates, on the other hand, tend to reflect more accurately changes in the policy instruments— open market operations, reserve requirements and the dis count rate— without being influenced unduly by out side forces.5 Chief among the candidates for a monetary policy indicator are the money stock (M l) and the monetary base. The monetary base has appeal because it reflects more accurately changes in the instruments of policy than does M l. The M l measure, however, tends to be more closely related to GNP.6 4See, for example, Albert E. Burger, “The Implementation Prob lem of Monetary Policy,” this Review (March 1971), pp. 20-30. 5See R. W. Hafer, “Selecting a Monetary Indicator: A Test of the New Monetary Aggregates,” this Review (February 1981), pp. 12-18. 6For references to the literature, along with a contrasting inter pretation, see William E. Cullison, “Money, the Monetary Base, and Nominal GNP,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review (May/Iune 1982), pp. 3-13. 8 OCTOBER 1982 Labeling monetary policy as easy or tight is, of course, quite arbitrary. The procedure followed here is to examine the historical record of M l and develop a classification of relatively easy and relatively tight policy on the basis of this record. To make this classifi cation meaningful, one must account for changes in the trend of monetary growth, particularly if one intends to focus on the impact of monetary policy on real vari ables. Consumers and investors come to expect certain growth rates of the monetary aggregates, basing such expectations on past experience. It is the deviation of the monetary aggregate around this expected growth rate that affiects real economic activity. Table 1 summarizes monetary policy since 1956. The first column shows the four-quarter rate of change of M l minus its trend (20-quarter rate of change) for the period ending in the fourth quarter of each year (except for 1982).7 The second column, which classifies monetary policy as easy, tight or neutral, follows from a three-part division of the observations in the first col umn. The mean plus or minus Vi standard deviation serve as points of demarcation. The classification is relative and also approximate. Rigidly adhering to the four-quarter rate of change can mask changes in policy that occur within the year. A more exhaustive study would not be tied to periods of fixed length. Nonethe less, the classification seems to accord with common interpretation of economic experience; for example, all of the observations labeled as “tight” occurred near recession periods. Measurement o f Fiscal Actions The measurement of fiscal actions also has been researched extensively over the years.8 The chief con clusion from this research is that recorded surpluses or deficits do not provide an accurate measure of fiscal actions. The reason is that a considerable amount of the movement of receipts and expenditures reflects an automatic response to the pace of economic activity rather than policy actions. Consequently, only fiscal m easures on a high-em ploym ent basis are con sidered.9 These high-employment budget measures justification for a 20-quarter rate of change as a measure of trend is found in Denis S. Karnosky, “The Link Between Money and Prices,” this Review (June 1976), pp. 17-23. See also Keith M. Carlson, “The Lag from Money to Prices,” this Review (October 1980), pp. 3-10. 8Alan S. Blinder and Robert M. Solow, “Analytical Foundations of Fiscal Policy,” in Alan S. Blinder and Robert M. Solow, eds., The Economics o f Public Finance (The Brookings Institution, 1974), pp. 3-115. 9Frank de L eeuw and Thomas M. Holloway, “ The HighEmployment Budget: Revised Estimates and Automatic Inflation Effects,” Survey o f C urrent Business (April 1982), pp. 21-33. OCTOBER 1982 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Table 1 Classification of Ease and Tightness of Monetary and Fiscal Policy Monetary Measure1 Fiscal Measure1 A(S/D) H -4 M1 _4 - M1 -2 0 EH< - FH2 0 c Value yh _4 R e EH4 Year2 Value Class 1956 -1 .1 9 T 5.84 E 2.15 N 0.52 T 1957 -1 .6 7 T 6.83 E -4 .6 3 E -0 .6 9 E Class value Class Value Class 1958 1.49 E 10.12 E -1 0 .0 5 E -1 .7 3 E 1959 0.33 N -6 .7 1 T 9.46 T 1.72 T 1960 -0 .7 9 T -2 .8 9 T 5.47 T 1.07 T 1961 1.19 E 2.68 N -6 .3 4 E -1 .0 2 E 1962 -0 .3 0 N 1.75 N -2 .0 2 N -0 .3 2 N 1963 1.75 E -1 .2 2 T 1.51 N 0.33 N 1964 1.71 E -3 .8 2 T -1 .9 6 N -0 .3 8 N 1965 0.91 N 4.35 E -8 .3 4 E -1 .4 8 E 1966 -0 .6 9 T 8.46 E -2.01 N -0 .4 8 N 1967 1.98 E 2.49 N -3 .4 6 E -0 .7 9 E 1968 2.31 E -0 .0 8 N 7.89 T 1.31 T 1969 -1 .0 8 T -6 .3 3 T 5.69 T 1.14 T 1970 -0 .1 6 N -1 .9 8 T -6 .5 9 E -1 .3 2 E 1971 0.87 N -1 .2 8 T -1 .2 9 N -0 .2 9 N 1972 2.26 E 6.83 E -5 .3 4 E -1 .1 5 E 1973 -0 .1 7 N -2 .7 3 T 7.60 T 1.35 T T 1974 -1 .3 5 T 6.32 E 3.43 T 0.58 1975 -1 .1 6 T 2.93 N -8 .1 9 E -1 .6 7 E 1976 0.16 N -4 .0 2 T 2.09 N 0.30 N 1977 2.21 E 0.22 N -1 .6 2 N -0 .4 5 N 1978 1.77 E -1 .5 8 T 4.82 T 0.81 T 1979 0.41 N 0.88 N 0.21 N -0 .0 2 N 1980 -0 .1 4 N 5.56 E 0.62 N 0.05 N 1981 -2 .2 0 T 0.31 N -1 .3 4 N -0 .3 3 N 1982 -2 .1 1 T -3 .1 4 T -4 .8 2 E -1 .0 0 E Mean Mean - Vkr Mean + '/2a 0.23 -0 .4 5 0.92 1.27 -1 .0 6 3.54 -0 .4 7 -3 .1 4 2.20 -0 .1 1 -0 .6 0 0.38 E: Easy N: Neutral T: Tight 1For definitions of variables, see text. Ease is associated with relatively large positive values except for the right-hand pair of fiscal measures. For these measures, ease is associated with relatively large negative values. 2AII values are for year ending fourth quarter, except for 1982 which is for year ending second quarter. can be assembled in different ways, however. Three high-employment measures are examined: the rate of change of expenditures minus its trend, the rate of change of receipts minus the rate of change of expendi tures, and the change of the surplus or deficit scaled by the size of the economy as measured by potential GNP. The latter two measures were tested for the presence of trend, but none was apparent. 9 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 Table 2 The Mix of Policy, 1956-82 Monetary Fiscal Tight Tight 1956, 1960, 1969, 1974 Neutral 1966, 1981 Easy 1957,1975, 1982 Neutral 1973 1959,1962,1971, 1965,1970 1976, 1979, 1980 Easy 1968, 1978 1963, 1964, 1977 1958,1961, 1967,1972 NOTE: Monetary policy is measured by four-quarter rate of change of M1 minus 20-quarter rate of change. Fiscal policy is measured by change in high-employment surplus/deficit over four quarters divided by high-employment GNP at the beginning of the period. The right-hand portion of table 1 summarizes these three fiscal measures over the 1956-to-1982 period. The rate of change of high-employment expenditures is included because previous studies have used it as a summary fiscal measure even though it does not re flect changes in tax policy.10 The other two highemployment measures— the rate of change of receipts minus the rate of change of expenditures and the change in the surplus/deficit scaled by potential GNP— reflect changes in both tax policy and expendi t u r e policy. In general, these latter two measures yield the same classification of easy, tight and neutral. Historical Record of Policy Mix The measures of monetary and fiscal policy can be combined to give a classification of each year in terms of the mix of those policies. Table 2 provides this summary on the basis of detrended M l and the highemployment surplus/deficit measure of fiscal action. The years shown in the corners of this matrix are most revealing. Periods when both policies were tight clear ly were associated with recessions; those when both were easy were associated with economic expansion. The periods of contrasting policies, though few in num ber, are interesting nonetheless. Easy monetary policy and tight fiscal policy occurred only in 1968 and 1978, both expansion years before business cycle peaks. The 10See Leonall C. Andersen and Jerry L. Jordan, “Monetary and Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their Relative Importance in Economic Stabilization,” this Review (November 1968), pp. 11-24. 10 other extreme of tight monetary policy and easy fiscal policy occurred in 1957, 1975 and 1982; these were recession years, although all of 1975 is not classified so according to the National Bureau of Economic Research. The current situation (note that 1982 refers to the four quarters ending in second quarter 1982) clearly falls into the classification of tight monetary policy and easy fiscal policy. According to the detrended measure of monetary policy as shown in table 1, 1981 and 1982 are the tightest years for monetary policy for the 195682 period. The measures of fiscal policy, however, do not indicate unusual ease. The expenditure measure does not indicate ease at all, and the other two, although suggesting ease, do not indicate that the de gree of ease is unusual. There have been six or seven of the last 27 years (depending on which measure is used) when fiscal policy has been easier than in 1982. The current concern about the mix of policies, however, is not focused entirely on the recent past (note, in particular, the quotations by Brookings and the Congressional Budget Office above). There is con cern about the near future. In other words, given current trends, analysts seem to be most concerned about developing trends in the mix. Consequently, a full assessment of policy mix requires an extrapolation of trends to determine if the mix of policies appears to be worsening, that is, that monetary policy is tighten ing further or at least remaining tight, and that expen diture and tax policies are leading to a further easing of fiscal policy. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 Figure 1 D e te rm in a tio n of R eal In c o m e , In te re s t R a te an d In v e s tm e n t-S a v in g Interest rate Interest ra te (i) R a t io (') rve Real in c o m e IS curve depicts equilibrium in goods and services market. LM curve depicts equilibrium in money market. DEVELOPMENT OF THE MIX HYPOTHESIS: A FRAM EW ORK OF ANALYSIS The question of policy mix is broad, encompassing a large body of macroeconomic theory and empirical support for the theory. Since a broad review of the theory is thus prohibitive, a typical example from mac roeconomic textbooks is summarized to represent the policy-mix literature.11 The Basic IS-LM Model The notion of policy mix usually is explained by using the well-known Hicksian IS-LM framework. According to this framework, the level of economic activity (real income) and the level of interest rates are determined by the conjunction of conditions in two n See, for example, Robert J. Gordon, Macroeconomics, 2nd ed. (Little, Brown and Company, 1981), pp. 140-42; or William H. Branson and James M. Litvack, Macroeconomics, 2nd ed. (Har per and Row Publishers, 1981), pp. 86-90. (l/X , S / X ) In v e s tm e n t, S a v i n g ratio (l /X , S / X ) Investment and saving curves are drawn for given level of real income (X). aggregate markets: the market for goods and services and the market for money.12 Fiscal policy, that is, changes in federal expenditures and tax rates, in fluence the economy through the market for goods and services, while monetary policy works through the money market. The IS-LM model is summarized in figure 1. The IS curve is the locus of combinations of interest rate and real economic activity consistent with equilibrium in the goods and services market. The curve is downward-sloping because lower interest rates induce high er levels of investment, which increase real income through the multiplier. Including the federal govern ment in the analysis broadens the equilibrium condi tion to investment plus government purchases equals savings plus taxes. The right-hand panel shows explic itly the situation in the goods and services market that underlies the IS curve in the left-hand panel. Although in reality both savings and investment depend on real 12In the simplest version of the IS-LM model, there is no distinction made between nominal and real interest rates because the price level and price expectations are held constant. 11 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 Fig u re 2 Policy Mix and the IS-LM Framework In t e r e s t rate st X Real incom e (X) © Tight monetary policy ( M ^ M ) and easy fiscal policy (G, G). © Easy monetary policy (M2>M ) and tight fiscal policy (G2<G). income, the curves are drawn here only with reference to the equilibrium level of income. The LM curve, as shown in figure 1, is the locus of combinations of interest rate and real economic activ ity consistent with equilibrium in the money market. Money is defined as currency plus checkable deposits. The curve is upward-sloping because the demand for real balances is assumed to be negatively related to interest rates and positively related to real income. Consequently, in order for the demand for real bal ances to be equal to a fixed supply, an increased de mand for money balances as real income increases must be offset by reduced demand for money balances via higher interest rates. Real income and interest rates are determined simultaneously by the intersection of the IS and LM curves. Only this combination of interest rate and real income is consistent with equilibrium in both the goods and services and money markets. The way that this equilibrium combination changes in response to monetary and fiscal actions is of interest here. Fiscal actions affect equilibrium by shifting the IS curve, while monetary actions shift the LM curve. Consequently, a given level of real income can be 12 achieved with different combinations, or mixes, of monetary and fiscal actions. For example, in figure 2, the combination of IS j and LM X represents “easy” fiscal policy and “tight” monetary policy, and a given level of real income is achieved with a higher interest rate than at the original equilibrium. Similarly, the intersection of IS2 and LM2 reflects “tight” fiscal policy and “easy monetary policy. “High” interest rates imply a lower rate of private investment (see righthand panel) and thus signify slower economic growth over the long term than a set of policies that yields “low” interest rates. Within the context of the current economic situa tion, the implication seems to be that the U.S. econ omy is operating at a point corresponding to the in tersection of IS j and LM i. This interpretation, how ever, is not obvious. Rather, Tobin and Brookings economists seem to draw the conclusion that the eco nomic recovery cannot be started or sustained unless interest rates are reduced by changing the mix of poli cies. This interpretation suggests that they view the IS-LM framework in dynamic rather than in static terms. In other words, the level of real income and interest rates are being moved over time by a combina tion of policies in such a way that interest rates are rising— or at least being sustained at high levels. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 F ig u re 3 In fla tio n a r y E x p e c ta tio n s and the IS-LM Fram ew ork (X ) Inflationary expectations (P E> 0 ) push up nominal interest rate (i), but by less than PE. Expected Inflation and the IS-LM Model The version of the IS-LM model discussed above is based on a number of simplifying assumptions. One of the most important simplifications is that inflation and expectations of inflation can be ignored. It would seem that any discussion of current economic developments should be based on a framework that allows for the effect of expected inflation. The effect of introducing expectations into the ISLM model is shown in figure 3. The interest rate axis now represents both nominal and real interest rates. ISo represents equilibrium in the goods and services market with expected inflation equal to zero (implying nominal and real interest rates are the same). The effect of introducing expected inflation of some posi tive amount is to shift the IS curve upward and to the right with respect to nominal rates, but leave it un changed in terms of real rates. The reason for this is that consumption and investm ent decisions are assumed to be based on real rather than nominal rates of interest. This means that IS Xis raised above IS0 by the amount of expected inflation. The effect on the LM curve of introducing expected inflation is somewhat more complicated. If, for exam ple, the demand for real balances depends on the difference between rates of return on money and all other assets, then expected inflation will affect all of these rates of return equally, including the return on real balances, and the LM curve will not be affected when drawn in terms of the nominal interest rate. If the assumption of equal effects of expected inflation on all asset returns is relaxed, however, the results will differ. An increase in expected inflation generally can be expected to increase the nominal return on capital relative to bonds and money. Wealth-holders will attempt to rearrange their portfolios to hold more capital and less money and bonds. Prices of capital will rise as those on bonds fall; that is, interest rates will rise. This means the LM curve will shift upward when drawn with reference to the nominal rate of interest. Because all wealth is not affected by a change in ex pectations, however, the upward shift of the LM curve will be less than the change in expected inflation. The effect on policy mix of introducing expectations into the IS-LM model depends on the response of expectations to any change in policy. If expectations do not change in response to a shift in policy, the mix can be changed as in the basic model. A given level of income can be achieved with different combinations of policies and different interest rates. On the other hand, if expectations are responsive to either monetary or fiscal actions, a larger number of possibilities is introduced, depending on the nature of the expecta tions response. In general, the faster expectations react to actual changes in monetary or fiscal policy, the less the effect of policy changes on the real variables, that is, real income, real interest rates and the invest ment ratio. TESTING THE M IX HYPOTHESIS The IS-LM framework provides a rationale for assigning the mix of policy an important role in plan ning the course of economic activity. Though there are many problems involved in moving from the classroom blackboard to economic reality, the general framework can still serve as a guide in formulating a test of the mix hypothesis. Testing Procedure The question of policy mix focuses on the aggrega tive effects of monetary and fiscal actions and thus lends itself to a reduced-form approach to hypothesis testing.13 The details of the transmission mechanism 13See Andersen and Jordan, “Monetary and Fiscal Actions.” 13 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 Table 3 Variables Used in Regressions Dependent variable Monetary Fiscal Aaa: corporate Aaa bond rate M1: compounded annual rate of change of money stock narrowly defined EH: compounded annual rate of change of highemployment federal expenditures Aaa - P 16: Aaa rate minus 4-year rate of change of GNP deflator X: compounded annual rate of change of real GNP a (^): change in the ratio of fixed investment to GNP RH- E H: compounded annual rate of change of high-employment federal receipts minus the rate of change of high-employment expenditures A(S/D)H . H : change in the Y _i high-employment federal surplus/ deficit divided by high-employment GNP NOTE: All variables are expressed in percent terms from a policy action to economic activity are of second ary interest, as is the process by which inflationary expectations are formed. Rather, the chief concern is whether certain values of key economic variables can be achieved with different combinations of monetary and fiscal actions. The variables used in the analysis and summarized in table 3 are restricted to those implicit in the IS-LM framework. The dependent variables are real GNP, real and nominal interest rates, and the ratio of fixed investment to GNP. These variables were regressed on current and lagged values of the monetary and fiscal variables.14 The regressions involving interest rates demonstrated substantial autocorrelation in the re siduals, so these equations were adjusted using the Cochrane-Oreutt procedure. All other equations were estimated with ordinary least squares. Lag length was 14Although M l minus trend was used in table 1 in defining the stance of monetary policy. M l without trend adjustment was used in the regressions, mainly because of its simple interpretation. Explaining the quarter-to-quarter variation of a variable is little affected by this choice, except for the value of the constant term. Digitized for14 FRASER determined by varying the lag by multiples of four and choosing from these regressions on the basis of max imum adjusted R2. The Almon lag technique was used, with the coefficients constrained to lie on a thirddegree polynominal with a tail constraint. These esti mates were tested against the unrestricted leastsquares estimates to ensure that the smoothness assumption could not be rejected by the data. Regression Results Tables 4 -7 summarize the statistical results. The effects of the policy variables on the relevant depen dent variable are summarized as one-year effect, twoyear effect and full effect. The final column, labeled “mix effect, ” of tables 4 -7 is of particular interest here. The mix effect is defined as the percentage change in \11 that would be required to offset a tighter fiscal policy and keep the dependent variable constant. A tighter fiscal policy is defined as a decrease in federal spending that would increase the change in the highemployment budget by $5 billion for 1980 and 1981. An appendix provides the specifics of how this tighter fiscal policy is defined. OCTOBER 1982 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Table 4 Effects of Monetary and Fiscal Actions on the Aaa Bond Rate Sample Period; 11/1959— IV/1981 Monetary Effect Dependent variable Aaa Aaa Aaa Variable Lags M1 3 7 20 M1 M1 Sum of coefficients1 Fiscal Effect Sum of coefficients1 Variable Lags .114 .394* 1.395* (4.49) EH 3 7 16 .010 .030 .098 (1.24) 3 7 24 .118* .401* 1.750* (4.92) RH- EH 3 7 16 .017 .054 .101 (1.40) 3 7 24 .108 .363* 1.725* (4.96) 3 7 16 .541 1.617 2.931 (1.80) A(S/D)H Y -i Constant 1.539 (.51) 1.103 (.36) 1.178 (.40) R2 .17 .18 .20 DW 1.74 1.74 1.77 Rho Mix effect2 .99 Undef. 0 0 .99 0 0 0 .99 Undef. 0 0 'Sums are cumulative for number of lags indicated. Absolute value of t-statistic in parentheses. * indicates sum is significant at 5 percent level. 2Mix effect is the change in M1 (in percentage points) required to offset a tightening of fiscal policy in the form of an increase in A(S/D)H of $5 billion. To offset means to keep the dependent variable unchanged. See appendix for details. “ Undef." means the mix effect is undefined; neither the monetary or fiscal effect is significantly different from zero (5 percent level). N om inal in terest rates and policy mix— Many analysts consider the level of nominal interest rates to be the primary cause for the current economic malaise. Yet the IS-LM model depicts the interest rate as a dependent variable. So, the first question investigated here is whether the nominal interest rate is systemati cally related to monetary-fiscal actions. The rela tionship of the corporate Aaa bond rate to the selected measures of monetary and fiscal policy is summarized in table 4. Three regressions were run, corresponding to the three measures of fiscal action. The number of lags that maximized the adjusted R2 of the equation ranged from 20 to 24 for M l and was 16 for the fiscal variable. The results are summarized as one-year effects (current and three lags), two-year effects (current and seven lags), and the full effect, which takes into account all of the lags. Relevant summary statistics also are shown. According to the simple IS-LM interpretation as shown in figure 2, a tighter fiscal policy should be accompanied by a tighter monetary policy in order to keep interest rates unchanged. Remember that the model of figure 2 ignores the influence of price ex pectations. A tightening of fiscal policy with no change in monetary policy shifts the IS curve to the left, lead ing to a fall in interest rates. To keep interest rates unchanged, monetary policy would have to be tight ened, shifting the LM curve to the left. Consequently, the implication of the simple IS-LM model is that the “mix effect” would be negative. The results in table 4 are clear-cut. The mix effect is either zero or undefined. The effect of E H on interest rates is of the expected sign, but not significantly dif ferent from zero. In the case of both RH — E H and AS/DH , . r i —v j'i , the effect on interest rates is not of the exi-i pected sign, but is also not significant. A tightening of AS/Dh fiscal policy, that is, an increase of R h — E Hor vH > i ) is associated with an increase in interest rates. The effect of monetary policy on interest rates in all cases is positive, running contrary to the implication of the simple IS-LM model. In general, fiscal policy has no effect on the Aaa bond rate; thus, there is no mix effect. The effect of monetary expansion, on the other hand, builds up over time and appears to be permanent. These results suggest that it is necessary to augment the IS-LM model with price 15 OCTOBER 1982 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Table 5 Effects of Monetary and Fiscal Actions on a Proxy for the Real Interest Rate Sample Period: 11/1959-IV/1981 Monetary Effect Dependent variable Aaa - P .16 M1 .114 .330* .698* (3.13) 3 7 20 .116* .321* .846* (2.90) 3 7 20 .111 .299* .798* (2.78) Sum of Variable coefficients1 Lags EH I M1 3 7 16 Variable X LU A a a -P .16 M1 Sum of coefficients1 I C C A a a - P 16 Lags Fiscal Effect A(S/D)H 3 7 16 .010 .022 .009 (.11) 3 7 16 .009 .016 -.0 1 5 (.21) 3 7 16 .202 .604 .385 (.24) Constant - .1 0 5 (.06) -.5 5 9 (.27) -.3 9 3 (.21) R2 .04 .06 .06 DW 1.79 1.82 1.81 Rho Mix effect2 .98 Undef. 0 0 .99 0 0 0 .98 Undef. 0 0 1Sums are cumulative for number of lags indicated. Absolute value of t-statistic in parentheses. * indicates sum is significant at 5 percent level. 2Mix effect is the change in M1 (in percentage points) required to offset a tightening of fiscal policy in the form of an increase in A(S/D)H of $5 billion. To offset means to keep the dependent variable unchanged. See appendix for details. “ Undef." means the mix effect is undefined; neither the monetary or fiscal effect is significantly different from zero (5 percent level). expectations, when those expectations seem to depend on the rate of monetary expansion. The explanatory power of each of the three equations is dominated by the rate of change of money. Real interest rates and policy mix— Recent concern about the level of interest rates also has been couched in terms of the real rate.15 Many consider the current high level of real rates an obstacle to economic recov ery. Since real rates are not observable, however, proxies have to be developed. Although much work has been done, the simple proxy of a nominal rate minus the recent rate of inflation is still most common ly used. For this analysis, the real rate is proxied by the Aaa bond rate minus the rate of change of the GNP deflator over the four previous years. The results are summarized in table 5, following the same format as before. The explanatory power of each equation is very low, although the monetary effect is significant in each case. The fiscal effect is not signifi 15See, in particular, the study by the Congressional Budget Office cited in footnote 3. Digitized for16 FRASER cant for any of the three measures. As with nominal rates, there is no mix effect applicable to the real rate. In general, monetary and fiscal actions do little to explain the movement of the real rate as measured by the Aaa bond rate minus past inflation. To the extent that the equation has explanatory power, it comes from the monetary variable. Even that effect runs counter to the conventional wisdom, as might be implied by an expectations-augmented IS-LM model. More expan sionary monetary policy is associated with increases in the real rate. Such an effect should probably not be taken too seriously, however, because of the problems inherent in measuring the real rate. Output growth and policy mix— Another interpreta tion of the mix problem is that output growth is being retarded by the particular combination of policies in effect. The next set of regressions examines the rate of output growth as a function of the monetary and fiscal variables. These results are summarized in table 6. The monetary and fiscal variables explain between 35 and 40 percent of the movement of output growth, and no correction for serial correlation is necessary. What is apparent from these regressions is the impor FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 Table 6 Effects of Monetary and Fiscal Actions on the Rate of Output Growth Sample Period: 11/1959-IV/1981___________________________________ Monetary Effect Dependent variable X X X Variable Lags M1 3 7 20 M1 M1 Sum of coefficients1 Fiscal Effect Sum of coefficients1 Variable Lags 1.010* .434 .001 (.01) EH 3 7 12 .030 -.0 9 2 -.3 0 7 (1.70) 3 7 20 1.008* .520 -.3 0 1 (1.61) RH- E H 3 7 12 -.0 8 2 -.0 8 2 .020 (.12) 3 7 20 1.076* .670 -.2 7 8 (1.56) 3 7 12 -2 .7 7 6 -3 .1 2 9 -.9 4 6 (.24) A(S/D)H Y -, Constant 6.055 (4.83) 4.506 (4.61) 4.279 (4.51) R2 .39 .37 .39 DW 2.28 2.20 2.25 Rho Mix effect2 N.A. 0 Undef. Undef. N.A. 0 Undef. Undef. N.A. 0 Undef. Undef. 1Sums are cumulative for number of lags indicated. Absolute value of t-statistic in parentheses. * indicates sum is significant at 5 percent level. 2Mix effect is the change in M1 (in percentage points) required to offset a tightening of fiscal policy in the form of an increase in A(S/D)H of $5 billion. To offset means to keep the dependent variable unchanged. See appendix for details. “ Undef.” means the mix effect is undefined; neither the monetary or fiscal effect is significantly different from zero (5 percent level). tance of the length of horizon. Money growth stimu lates output growth in the short run, but this stimulus fades after a year. Consequently, any potential mix effect is applicable only in the short run, but none is found because the fiscal effect on output is not signifi cantly different from zero. The conventional wisdom indicates that a tightening of fiscal policy should be accompanied by an expansion ary monetary policy in order to achieve a given rate of output growth. The directions of the effects are gener ally found, but, because the fiscal effect is not signifi cantly different from zero, there is no mix effect. And, for the long term, the mix effect is undefined because neither the effects of monetary or fiscal actions are significantly different from zero. Investment ratio and policy mix—A final variable of interest to those concerned with the current mix of policies is the investment ratio. Easy fiscal policy is thought to discourage private investment because the federal government preempts the use of loanable funds (see figure 2). To investigate this effect, the change in the ratio of fixed investment to GNP is run against the monetary and fiscal variables. Table 7 summarizes the results. The striking feature of these regressions is that the explanatory power of these equations is quite high, with about 55 percent of the movement in the invest ment ratio explained by the monetary and fiscal vari ables. Also, no correction for serial correlation is neces sary. The effect of monetary policy on the investment ratio is first positive, then negative (shown by a decline in the sum of coefficients as the horizon is lengthened); only in combination with E H is the effect significant after 20 quarters. The fiscal effect, on the other hand, builds up over time and is significant at the 95 per cent level after 16 quarters for each of the three fiscal variables. The mix effect for the investment ratio, according to conventional wisdom, should be negative. A tighten ing of fiscal policy should be accompanied by a tighten ing of monetary policy in order to keep the investment ratio constant. That is, a tightening of fiscal policy is supposed to encourage investment; if that is to be offset, monetary policy also should be tightened. For all cases in table 7, the conventional wisdom is upheld. But, as the horizon is lengthened, there really is no mix effect, because monetary actions do not have a perma 17 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 Table 7 Effects of Monetary and Fiscal Actions on the Investment Ratio Sample Period: 11/1959-IV/1981 Monetary Effect Dependent variable A(l/Y) A(l/Y) A(l/Y) Variable Lags M1 3 7 20 M1 M1 Fiscal Effect Sum of coefficients1 Sum of coefficients1 Variable Lags .085* .045 .048* (2.82) EH 3 7 12 -.0 1 6 * - .024* - .032* (2.91) 3 7 20 .096* .050 - .0 0 0 (.02) RH- E H 3 7 12 .009* .020* .034* (3.40) 3 7 20 .099* .051 .009 (.82) 3 7 12 .177 .412* .699* (2.88) A(S/D)h wH Y -i Constant R2 DW Rho Mix effect2 -0 .7 0 0 .080 (1.04) -.0 1 7 (.30) -.0 4 2 (.71) .55 .56 .55 2.36 2.36 2.28 N.A. -2 .2 N.A. -0 .4 0 0 0 0 N.A. 0 0 0 0 0 1Sums are cumulative for number of lags indicated. Absolute value of t-statistic in parentheses. * indicates sum is significant at 5 percent level. 2Mix effect is the change in M1 (in percentage points) required to offset a tightening of fiscal policy in the form of an increase in A(S/D)H of $5 billion. To offset means to keep the dependent variable unchanged. See appendix for details. °c means the mix effect is infinite, that is, a nonzero effect is divided by zero; the fiscal effect is significant but the monetary effect is not (5 percent level). nent effect on the investment ratio, while fiscal actions do (this result is shown as °o). IMPLICATIONS OF THE RESULTS These regression results carry certain implications for economic policy that are at variance with the con ventional wisdom on policy mix. The general policy implications of the statistical results require further discussion. To give some indication of the magnitude of effect, some different policy mixes are simulated for the period from 1981 to 1985. higher, not lower. The implication for real rates is not clear; even though real rates were positively related to money growth, the regressions were not significant. To the extent that interest rates can be explained, money growth, not fiscal actions, provides the explanation. An easing of fiscal policy alone does not guarantee a fall in interest rates. The effect of fiscal actions on interest rates was not found to be significant. These regression results can be pulled together into a general conclusion. Consider Tobin’s recommenda tion, cited at the beginning of this paper: The idea of a solid recovery is that real output growth could be stimulated by shifting the mix toward tighter fiscal policy and easier monetary policy. The regres sion results indicate that this desired effect could be achieved, but only temporarily. Easier monetary pol icy stimulates output growth initially, but this effect dissipates after a year. Furthermore, the regression results indicate that fiscal effects on output growth are not significant, either in the short or long run. To achieve a solid recovery, such as the administration projects, and to achieve it without astronomical interest rates and serious crowding out, we need an easier monetary policy combined with a tighter fiscal policy. Tobin’s recommendation has some validity in its assertion that the mix should be changed to avoid “serious crowding out. ” According to the regression 16 What light do these regression results shed on this recommendation? First, if easier monetary policy means faster money growth, following Tobin’s recom mendation will yield nominal interest rates that are 16For a survey article on "crowding out, see Keith M. Carlson and Roger W. Spencer, “Crowding Out and Its Critics,” this Review (December 1975), pp. 2-17. General Policy Implications Digitized for18 FRASER OCTOBER 1982 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Table 8 Simulation of Alternative Policy Mixes Easy Fiscal Policy and Tight Monetary Policy Tight Fiscal Policy and Tight Monetary Policy Tight Fiscal Policy and Easy Monetary Policy Corporate Aaa Bond Rate 1981 Actual 1982 1983 1984 1985 14.17% 14.26 13.01 11.37 9.99 14.17% 14.28 13.26 12.00 10.87 14.17% 14.39 13.78 13.16 12.82 Growth Rate of Real GNP 1981 Actual 1982 1983 1984 1985 0.80% -0 .1 3 2.16 3.10 3.67 0.80% -0 .3 5 1.10 2.14 3.41 0.80% 1.36 2.84 2.54 2.83 15.36% 14.62 13.96 13.43 12.95 15.36% 14.64 14.19 14.16 14.52 15.36% 15.00 15.24 15.48 15.73 Investment Ratio 1981 Actual 1982 1983 1984 1985 NOTE: Easy Tight Easy Tight fiscal policy is a fiscal policy is a monetary policy monetary policy steady increase of the high-employment deficit to $150 billion in fiscal 1985. steady movement toward a balanced high-employment budget in fiscal 1985. is 6.5 percent growth rate of M1. is 4.5 percent growth rate of M1. results, tighter fiscal policy would indeed encourage a rise in the investment ratio, but interest rates would be minimally affected. This shift to tighter fiscal policy, however, need not be accompanied by easier monetary policy. There is a positive effect of monetary actions on the investment ratio, but it appears to be temporary, whereas the fiscal effect appears to be permanent. Simulation of Alternative Policy Mixes To provide some specific indication of the magni tudes involved in the policy mix controversy, the re gression results were used to simulate three different mixes of policy for the 1982-85 period. Point estimates of the coefficients were used even if they were not significantly different from zero.1' Two fiscal scenarios were chosen; one is based on fiscal actions that lead to a $150 billion deficit in the high-employment budget by 1985, the other a tighter 17Real interest rates were not simulated because none of the regres sions was significant. fiscal policy that yields a balanced high-employment budget by 1985. The easy policy conforms roughly with the prospective course of fiscal action as it appeared to be developing in early 1982. The tight policy is consis tent with a recommendation by the Brookings Institu tion in their annual report on the federal budget.18 Two monetary policies were simulated: one is a steady expansion of M l at a 4.5 percent rate, the other is expansion at a 6.5 percent rate. The first policy is labeled “tight” and would be within the 1982 target range announced by the Federal Reserve. The 6.5 percent scenario for money is called “easy,” and would be above the upper end of the 1982 target range. Table 8 gives the results of these simulations. The result of tightening fiscal policy and easing monetary policy (compare the first and third columns) is to push up nominal interest rates. The growth of output is 18See Charles L. Schultze, “Long-Term Budget Strategies,” in Joseph A. Pechman, ed., Setting National Priorities: The 1983 Budget (The Brookings Institution, 1982), pp. 187-220. Their recommendation was made before passage of the Tax Equity and Fiscal Responsibility Act of 1982. 19 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS actually worsened by the change in the mix, the reason being that inflation accelerates with easier monetary policy. The investment ratio, however, is increased by changing the mix of policy. As the middle column of table 8 shows, there is little to be gained by expanding money more rapidly when fiscal policy is tightened. Although easing monetary policy appears desirable because of its beneficial effects on fixed investment, recall that the long-run effects of money growth on the investment ratio were not statistically different from zero. SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS The notion of policy mix has been presented in textbooks and discussed by eminent analysts almost as if it were a self-evident truth. A recommended change in policy mix seems to be based on the well-known IS-LM model. When scrutinized more closely, the question of the appropriate mix of monetary-fiscal poli cies is not as clear-cut as the simple IS-LM model implies. The lagged effects of policy actions must be taken into account, as well as the empirical realities of certain economic relationships. This paper examined four dependent variables that seem relevant in any discussion of policy mix— nomi nal interest rates, real interest rates, the rate of output 20 OCTOBER 1982 growth, and the investment ratio. The conclusions are as follows: (1) M ovem ents o f nom inal in terest rates and, to a lesser exten t, real rates are dom in ated by m o n etary actions. The effect of fiscal actions on in terest rates is not statisti cally significant. (2) T h ere is a short-ru n effect o f m o n etary actions on output grow th, b u t it is only tem p orary . O v er the long run, m ovem en ts in ou tp ut grow th are unaffected by eith er m onetary o r fiscal actions. (3) T h e in vestm en t ratio is influenced tem p orarily by m onetary actions, b u t th e effect appears to be p erm a n ent for fiscal actions. These conclusions imply that the IS-LM framework must be carefully interpreted when used as a guide for policy analysis, and that current recommendations for a change in the mix are only partly valid. Fiscal policy should indeed be tightened in order to stimulate an increase in the investment ratio, if long-term economic growth and/or housing investment is a national goal. There is little evidence, however, to support the no tion that interest rates would be affected greatly. There is no basis for thinking that a tightening of fiscal policy should be accompanied by an easing of monetary policy. The effect of easier monetary policy would be higher nominal interest rates and only a temporary surge of output growth. FEDERAL RESERVE Receipts Level Expenditures Change Level Change Tighter Fiscal Policy (High-Employment Values) Surplus/Deficit Receipts Level Change Level Expenditures Change Level Level Change $20.1 -$ 1 3 .3 -$ 5 .6 13.7 -1 1 .7 1.6 589.4 20.1 - 9 .2 2.5 610.3 20.9 3.2 12.4 626.4 16.1 23.7 20.5 622.8 -3 .6 40.6 16.9 645.4 22.6 39.3 - 1 .3 672.2 26.8 16.0 -2 3 .3 1980:1 $542.3 $14.5 $560.6 $25.1 -$ 1 8 .3 -$ 1 0 .6 $542.3 $14.5 $555.6 II 557.5 15.2 579.3 18.7 -2 1 .7 -3 .4 557.5 15.2 569.3 III 580.1 22.6 604.4 25.1 -2 4 .2 -2 .5 580.1 22.6 IV 613.5 33.4 630.3 25.9 -1 6 .8 7.4 613.5 33.4 1981:1 650.2 36.7 651.4 21.1 -1 .3 15.5 650.2 36.7 II 663.3 13.1 652.8 1.4 10.6 11.9 663.3 13.1 III 684.7 21.4 680.4 27.6 4.3 -6 .3 684.7 21.4 IV 688.3 3.6 712.2 31.8 -2 4 .0 -2 8 .3 688.3 3.6 no change Change Surplus/Deficit O ST. LOUIS F ___________ Actual Fiscal Policy (High-Employment Values) BANK Appendix Change in Fiscal Policy Used in Calculating Mix Effect $5 billion difference For the fiscal variables used in the regressions, this change in policy translates as follows: RH- E H YH, 1st year -3 .7 4 + 3.74 + .19 2nd year -3 .2 8 + 3.28 + .18 Beyond 2nd year -3 .2 8 + 3.28 + .18 OCTOBER 1982 A(S/D)H EH Simple Analytics of the Money Supply Process and Monetary Control D ANIEL L. TH O RN TO N O n O C TO BER 6, 1979, the Federal Reserve adopted a new procedure for implementing monetary policy that would place more emphasis on controlling the money supply and less on controlling the level of the federal funds rate. This procedure has been im plemented by establishing an intermediate target for nonborrowed reserves.1 While the Federal Reserve has succeeded in slowing the rate of growth in the basic monetary aggregate (M l) since adopting the new pro cedure, it has failed to smooth the erratic short-run movements in M l. ernors is now committed to implementing the last of these recommendations.3 Analysts have suggested a number of changes to the Federal Reserve’s operating procedure to achieve more stable short-run monetary growth. Among the most frequently cited proposals are: adopting a mone tary base target, tying the discount rate to a market interest rate and adopting a system of contempora neous reserve accounting (CRA).2 The Board of Gov A M O D EL OF THE MONEY STOCK 'F o r a discussion of the new operating procedures, see Fred J. Levin and Paul Meek, “Implementing the New Operating Proce dures: The View from the Trading Desk,” New Monetary Control Procedures, Volume I, Federal Reserve Staff Study (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February 1981); Stephen Axilrod and David E. Lindsey, “Federal Reserve System Implementation of Monetary Policy: Analytical Foundations of the New Approach,” American Economic Review (May 1981), pp. 2 46-52; and R. Alton Gilbert and Michael E . Trebing, “The FOMC in 1980: A Year of Reserve Targeting,” this Review (August/ September 1981), pp. 2-22. 2There have been a number of suggestions for these reforms. For example, Economic Report o f the President (1982); Anatol B. Balbach, “How Controllable is Money Growth?” this Review (April 1981), pp. 3-12; James M. Johannes and Robert H. Rasche, “Pre dicting the Money Multiplier,” Journal o f Monetary Economics 22 The purpose of this paper is to analyze the effects of adopting each of these proposals. Since each of these recommendations, in some way, are linked to the others, the analysis will proceed serially, beginning with the effects of base targeting and ending with the effects of CRA. These proposed reforms are analyzed within the context of a simple linear stochastic model of the money stock.4 The model used here is complete enough to provide useful insights into the effects of each of these propos als, yet simple enough to be readily understood. The reader need not follow each step in the development of the model in order to understand its implications. All (July 1979), pp. 301-26, and “Can the Reserves Approach to Monetary Control Really Work?” Journal o f Money, Credit and Banking (August 1981), pp. 298-313; William Poole, “Federal Reserve Operating Procedures: A Survey and Evaluation of the Historical Record Since October 1979,” presented at the Confer ence on Current Issues in the Conduct of Monetary Policy, Amer ican Enterprise Institute (February 1982). "The Federal Reserve will implement CRA on February 2, 1984. ‘‘The model is a more complicated version of linear stochastic mod els recently considered by Poole and LeRoy. See Poole, “Federal Reserve Operating Procedures: A Survey and Evaluation of the Historical Record Since October 1979;” and Stephen F . LeRoy, “Monetary Control Under Lagged Reserve Accounting, ” Southern Economic Journal (October 1979), pp. 460-70. OCTOBER 1982 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Table 1 A Simple Linear Model of the Money Stock Equations: Definitions o f Variables: Money Supply Equations Mf = D, + C, Ms the supply of nominal money, composed of checkable deposits and currency D checkable deposits of depository institutions B, = RR, + Ct + ER, C the currency component of money C, = kD, + pi, + Uc, k > 0, p < 0 B the monetary base TDt = + p,it + uTl, t > 0, p. ^ 0 RR required reserves of depository institutions ER, = eD, + 5i, + uet, e > 0, 8 < 0 TD time and savings deposits of depository institutions RR, * r(D, + TD,) ER excess reserves of depository institutions RR, + ER, = NBR, + BR, NBR nonborrowed reserves: total reserves of depository institutions less depository institutions’ borrowing from the Federal Reserve BR depository institutions’ borrowing from the Federal Reserve i the nominal market interest rate id the discount rate Y nominal GNP Md the demand for nominal money M the equilibrium nominal money stock t D, BR, = a(id, — i,) + Ub,, a < 0 Money Demand Equations M,d = ($Y, + Xi, + umt, 0 > 0, X < 0 Market Equilibrium Condition M f = M? =M , Uc, uT ,, uet, ubt, um , random variables with zero means and constant variances. Descriptions of Equations: The first two equations are the definitions of money stock and the monetary base, respectively. The next three equations are parametric equations relating currency held by the nonbank pub lic, time deposits and excess reserves to checkable deposits and the market interest rate. These equations also contain random components that represent both purely stochastic elements and the effects of omitted variables. The sixth is an identity relating required reserves to total deposits and the seventh is an equilib rium condition requiring the demand for reserves to equal the supply of reserves. The eighth equation makes depository institu tions’ demand for borrowed reserves a function of the spread between the Federal Reserve discount rate and the market in terest rate, and the random error.1 The model is completed by including a simple demand for money equation and a money equilibrium condition. The demand for nominal money is assumed to depend on nominal income and the market interest rate.2 Infla tion and, hence, expectations of inflation are ignored. 1This borrowing equation differs from the usual one. The usual borrowing equation would relate borrowing to bank deposits para metrically, say BR, = bD, t a (id, — it). This practice is not adopted here for the following reasons. First, there is little theoretical justification for parametrically relating borrowing to the level of deposits. Second, this practice results in including the b-term in the multiplier. This gives the erroneous impression that the link between money and the base will change with changes in b, even under base targeting, but this is not the case. This point will be made clear later in the paper. It is true that there would be some frictional level of borrowing even if id, = i,. Thus, it might be appropriate to include a constant term in equation 8. Third, it is possible to obtain a nonborrowed reserve multiplier by completely ignoring equation 2 when the borrowing equation is written in the above form. This encourages one to ignore the fact that nonborrowed reserves are linked to money only via their link to the base or total reserves. 2That is, we follow common practice in assuming the absence of a “ money illusion” on the part of money holders. 23 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 of the results presented are derived in the appendix. Nevertheless, the complete model along with a de scription of the equations and variables is presented in table 1 for the reader’s convenience. Wherever possi ble, the analysis is presented graphically. [ (,^ + s + p) — p fra + T ^ + c + k ) ] (X — p) (r(l + (2) M t = +e+k> + (n * + s + Specifically, we assume that Yt = Yt + E t , where E(et) = 0. Thus, E(Yt) = Yt, i.e., the Federal Reserve correctly forecasts nominal income on average. This forecast introduces another source of error into the model which is ignored in this paper for convenience; however, this does not affect the qualitative conclusions. The Federal Reserve has to forecast the parameters of the model as well. This problem is usually ignored. Digitized for24 FRASER p )(r(l + t) + e) + k) Yt + (rp. + 8 + p) NBRt + (rp, + 8 + a) + P (X - p )(r(l + T) + e) 1 + k + Yt 4- (rp. + 8 + a) aX (X - p )(r(l + 1+ k T) + e) idt + (rp, + 8 + a) (3) M , = p f t + Xit The expected value of the equilibrium money stock under interest rate targeting (equation 3) is simply the demand for money. This reflects the well-known fact that the quantity of money is completely demanddetermined if the Federal Reserve chooses an interest rate target.6 While these equations appear somewhat compli cated, they merely represent expressions for the ex pected value of the equilibrium money stock, repre sented graphically by M* in figure 1. For example, both the base and income appear in the equilibrium equation 1, because the money supply is conditional on the level of the base under base targeting and the demand for money is conditional on the income level. This is illustrated in figure la. Therefore, the equilib rium money stock depends both on the level of income and the base under a monetary base target. Control of the money stock through each of these targets can be analyzed by evaluating the expressions for the expected value of the equilibrium money stock obtained by treating each of these variables as exoge nous. (The Federal Reserve must forecast the level of income Yt in order to control the money stock. Thus, the forecasted value Yt replaces Yt in the model.)5 The expected value of the equations for the equilibrium money stock under monetary base, nonborrowed re serve and interest rate targeting, respectively, are: t (X - 1 + k The model requires that three variables be exoge nous. Two of the exogenous variables are the discount rate (idt) and nominal income (Yt). The remaining ex ogenous variable is determined by the operating pro cedure. If the Federal Reserve chooses to target on the market interest rate (it), it would be treated as exoge nous; in this case, the monetary base (Bt) and nonbor rowed reserves (NBRt) would change to whatever levels are necessary to achieve the interest rate target. If the Federal Reserve targets on nonborrowed re serves, the monetary base and the interest rate would move endogenously to achieve levels consistent with the nonborrowed reserve target. The same would be true of the interest rate and nonborrowed reserves if the Federal Reserve chose a monetary base target. ( x ~ p )(r ^ e 1 + k The model initially assumes CRA. This assumption will be changed later to analyze the implications of lagged reserve accounting (LRA) for short-run mone tary control and to analyze the effects of the Board’s proposal for CRA. Initially, the deterministic form of the model is considered. This is achieved by taking the expected value of the endogenous variables (the ex pected value is denoted with a hat, e.g., E(X) = X). The full model is taken up in the final section, which deals with the variance of money and interest rates under CRA and LRA. (1) M ' T) + The discount rate appears in the money stock equa tion when nonborrowed reserves are exogenous, but not when the monetary base is exogenous. The reason for this is simple. Changes in the discount rate alter the spread between it and the market interest rate and, p 6In this case, the money supply curve would be perfectly horizontal, as the Federal Reserve simply accommodated the public’s demand for ) B| money at some nominal rate. Of course, it is well-known and widely accepted that the Federal Reserve cannot “peg” the nomi nal rate in an inflationary environment without continuously accelerating the growth rate of money. See Milton Friedman, “The Role of Monetary Policy,” American Economic Review (March 1968), pp. 1-17. More recently, however, McCallum has shown that the price level is determinant if the Federal Reserve smoothes rather than pegs interest rates. See Bennett T. McCallum, “Price Level Determinancy with an Interest Rate Policy Rule and Ration al Expectations,” Journal o f Monetary Economics (November 1981), pp. 319-29. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 Figure l E q u ilib riu m M o n e y Stock U n d e r Base and N o n b o rr o w e d R e serve T a rg e tin g In te re s t rate Ms |N B R t = N B R ,id t = id M dlY,=Y A * s tock (a) thus, the level of bank borrowing.7 If the monetary base were the control variable, changes in borrowings would be offset through open market operations in order to maintain the base at its target level. Changes in the discount rate would have no effect on the equilibrium money stock under monetary base target ing. Thus, the discount rate does not appear as an exogenous variable in equation 1. This is not the case for nonborrowed reserve target ing. Changes in the discount rate would produce changes in depository institutions’ borrowing, the monetary base and the money supply unless the Federal Reserve simultaneously changes its target level of nonborrowed reserves.8 Thus, the money there were a significant “announcement effect” of a discount rate change on market interest rates, there would be an endogenous movement in the money stock even under base targeting. For more details on the relationship between the discount rate and market interest rates, see Daniel L. Thornton, “The Discount Rate and Market Interest Rates: What’s the Connection?” this Review (June/July 1982), pp. 3-14. 7I f 8If the Federal Reserve changed its nonborrowed reserve target in light of these changes, it would, ipso facto, be targeting on the base M Money s to ck (b) supply schedule is conditional on both nonborrowed reserves and the discount rate under nonborrowed reserve targeting, as illustrated in figure lb. MONETARY BASE VS. NONBORROW ED RESERVE TARGETING The controversy over base versus nonborrowed re serve targeting depends critically on the stability of the link between each of these reserve aggregates and nominal money. The stability of this link, in turn, or total reserves, not nonborrowed reserves. It is sometimes argued that the Federal Reserve is essentially base or total reserve targeting because it first determines a total reserve path and, from that, its nonborrowed reserve path given an initial borrowing assumption. It would be total reserve targeting, however, only if it changed its nonborrowed reserves every time it recognized it was off its total reserve path. Recently, Gilbert and Trebing have shown that the Fed often knowingly stuck with its nonborrowed reserve path despite the fact that it correctly projected it would be off the total reserve path necessary to hit its short-run money target. R. Alton Gilbert and Michael E. Trebing, “The FOMC in 1980: A Year of Reserve Targeting,” this Review (August/September 1981), pp. 2-16. 25 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS depends on (a) the exogeneity of the respective reserve aggregate multiplier and (b) the exogeneity of the re serve aggregate. The first of these issues can be dealt with by considering the extent to which the money stock is exogenous under each target.9 The Exogeneity o f Money under Base and Nonborrowed Reserve Targeting Consider the extent to which the money stock is exogenous under nonborrowed reserves and monetary base targeting— that is, determined only by the Feder al Reserve’s control over the target variable and the parameters of the model. This can be accomplished by observing the conditions required to make the money supply schedule vertical under the two regimes. Equa tion 1 indicates that the money stock is exogenously determined by the base if the public’s demand for currency and time deposits and depository institutions’ demand for excess reserves are unresponsive to in terest rate changes (|x = 8 = p = 0). If these condi tions hold, equation 1 reduces to «■> M- = K 1 + ‘) t ! l + k B- The less interest-sensitive these factors are, the less interest-sensitive will be the money supply. If these factors are completely insensitive to the interest rate, 9In a recent Board study dealing with the observed historical stabil ity of the monetary base multiplier, David Lindsey and others discuss two types of multiplier endogeneity. First, they argue that the variability of the observed multipliers may be biased downward because they do not account for the possibility that the targeted level of the reserve aggregate may have changed in response to an unanticipated change in some other factor. If, for example, the money supply took an unanticipated jump (because of an unantici pated jump in the demand for money) at the beginning of the intermeeting targeting period, the Federal Reserve might reduce its target for nonborrowed reserves (or the monetary base under base targeting). The result might be a larger observed multiplier if the reduction in the reserve aggregate were larger than the reduc tion in the money supply from its unanticipated level (of course, it could be smaller if the money supply response was greater). This type of reserve aggregate endogeneity error applies to all potential reserve aggregates, but only if the Federal Reserve is actually targeting on it. Moreover, this type of reserve endogeneity is concerned only with the question of the observed stability of the multiplier; it has nothing to do with the issue of monetary control. The second type of reserve endogeneity is the traditional type, in which factors that make up the various multipliers change with changes in other endogenous variables (e.g ., interest rates) in the system, as considered here. See, David Lindsey, et. al., ‘Mone tary Control Experience Under the New Operating Procedures,” New Monetary Control Procedures, Federal Reserve Staff Study, Volume II (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, July 1981); Balbach, “How Controllable is Money Growth?” Johan nes and Rasche, “Can the Reserves Approach to Monetary Control Really Work?” and “Predicting the Money Multiplier.” Digitized for 26 FRASER OCTOBER 1982 the money supply schedule becomes perfectly verti cal, and the equilibrium money stock is exogenously controlled. In contrast, the money stock is exogenous under nonborrowed reserve targeting only if the above condi tions hold and if, simultaneously, a, the interest re sponsiveness of borrowing from the Federal Reserve to the rate spread between the discount rate and the market interest rate, is zero. Under these conditions, equation 2 reduces to Thus, the conditions necessary for the Federal Re serve to control the money stock are more restrictive under nonborrowed reserve than under base target ing. Indeed, it is commonly accepted that excess re serves are interest-insensitive, and Johannes and Rasche recently have argued that the currency and time deposit ratios are fairly interest-insensitive as well.10 This is not the case, however, for depository institutions’ borrowing. Casual observation shows a strong relationship between borrowing and the dis count rate/market interest rate spread. Thus, the sup ply of money might exhibit greater interest sensitivity under nonborrowed reserve targeting than under base targeting.11 The importance of this for monetary control can be seen by noting that the less interest-sensitive the 10See Johannes and Rasche, “Predicting the Money Multiplier” for details. 11This question is more complicated in a nonlinear model. In the nonlinear case, the relative interest sensitivity of the money sup ply under base and NBR targeting depends on the relative magni tude of these reserve aggregates and their multipliers. To illus trate this, let the money supply under base and NBR targeting be given by the expressions below. M s = m(i; B) • B M s = m(i; N B R ) • N B R Here, m(i; B) and m(i; NBR) denote multipliers that are functions of the interest rate, given either a base or NBR target. The difference in the interest responsiveness of the money supply under base or NBR targeting is given by flm (i; B) • B - 3m(i; N B R ) • N B R di di This expression is less than or equal to zero if B _ 3m(i; N B R ) NBR ~ 3i , dm(i; B) . di Since the base is about four times as large as NBR, the base multiplier must be about one-fourth as interest-responsive as the NBR multiplier if the money supply under base targeting is to be less interest-sensitive than under NBR targeting. Whether this condition holds depends on the relative magnitude of the struc tural parameters as discussed above. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 Figure 2 The Effect of U n a n tic ip a te d Shifts in M o n e y D e m a n d and S upply money supply, the less responsive the equilibrium money stock will be to unanticipated shifts in money demand. This is illustrated in figure 2a, which shows the effect of an unanticipated increase in the demand for money. While it is more difficult to illustrate, the less in terest-sensitive the supply of money, the more sensi tive equilibrium money stock may be to unanticipated changes in factors that affect the supply of money. (The exact relationship depends on the relative magnitude of certain parameters of the model.) This is illustrated in figure 2b. An unanticipated decrease, say, in excess reserves, shifts both M | and M s Br to the right. N Although the latter curve shifts further, the resulting change in the money stock may be smaller. This is the result of the effect of a reduction in depository institu tions’ borrowing associated with the declining interest rate on the quantity of money supplied. The above result depends on the source of the supply-side shock. If the supply-side shock comes from an unanticipated change in currency, the effect on the money stock will be larger than if it comes from excess reserves or time deposits. The absolute magnitude of the differential effect of supply-side shocks under base and NBR targeting de pends on the relative magnitude of the interest sensi tivity of borrowing (a) and the demand for money (\). The less interest-sensitive is borrowing and the more interest sensitive the demand for money, the smaller will be this differential effect. If a is sufficiently small relative to X, the money supply would be less respon sive to supply-side shocks under base targeting.12 Given the above analysis, we would expect base targeting to result in more stable money growth if most of the exogenous shocks come from the demand side. If most shocks come from the supply side, however, base targeting may result in less stable growth. This last 12The required condition for smaller effects of supply-side shocks under base targeting is (\k + p)/(l + k) < a. Since it is commonly assumed that p is small, this condition will hold only if IXI is large relative to Ia I Most empirical evidence on the demand for money . suggests XI is very small. Some recent estimates, however, sug gest a much larger value of I\ I See Daniel L. Thornton, “The . Long-Run and Short-Run Demand for Money: Additional Evi dence, ’’Journal o f Macroeconomics (Summer 1982), pp. 325-38. 27 OCTOBER 1982 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS statement must be tempered by the fact that supplyside shocks resulting from exogenous changes in de pository institutions’ borrowing will not affect money under base targeting, but will affect it under NBR targeting. Thus, if borrowing is unstable, money may be less responsive to supply-side shocks from all sources under base targeting.13 Endogeneity of the Monetary Base The above analysis explicitly assumes that both non borrowed reserves and the monetary base can be con trolled exogenously at any desired level. This is gener ally accepted to be true for nonborrowed reserves, though not for the monetary base. In fact, a principal objection to monetary base targeting is that the mone tary base is endogenous. In its most basic form, this objection argues that depository institutions’ borrowing is functionally re lated to the level of open market operations. Thus, any attempt at hitting a monetary base target, by offsetting uncontrolled borrowing through open market opera tions, necessarily changes the level of borrowing that the system must offset. The problem of base en dogeneity, while important, could be handled in part by tying the discount rate to the market interest rate. TYING THE DISCOUNT RATE TO MARKET RATES The interest responsiveness of borrowing could be substantially reduced by tying the discount rate to a market interest rate (i.e., idt = it + A, where A is a positive or negative constant).14 If this were done, borrowing would be unresponsive to interest rate 13The error term in the borrowings equation is not present in the error term for the reduced-form money stock equation under base targeting. This, of course, assumes that information on depository institution borrowing is available very quickly (it is currently available the next day). If the borrowing equation is unstable, as reported by a recent Board study, then base targeting may still be less sensitive to supply-side shocks. See “Impact of Discount Policy Procedures on the Effectiveness of Reserve Targeting,” New Monetary Control Procedures, Federal Reserve Staff Study, Volume I (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, February 1981). 14W e do not say “eliminated” because it is unlikely that tying the discount rate to any one market rate would eliminate all interestresponsive borrowing. This is due to the fact that different deposi tory institutions may have portfolios of different assets that reflect their opportunity cost of borrowing. Hence, tying the discount rate to one asset may not suffice for every institution. Tying the discount rate to the federal funds rate, however, would probably reduce the interest responsiveness of borrowing for most deposi tory institutions. Digitized for 28 FRASER changes. This would substantially reduce the en dogeneity of the base and, to this extent, make it much easier to hit and maintain a monetary base target. Some have argued that the discount rate should be a penalty rate, that is, A > 0. This concern is probably overstated. The problem with depository institutions’ borrowing is their interest sensitivity, not their level. Given the administration of the discount window, the level of aggregate borrowing will move inversely with A. The value of the spread between the market rates and the discount rate will have little impact on its interest sensitivity.15 Tying the discount rate to market rates also has implications for nonborrowed reserve targeting. Under a tied discount rate, equation 2 could be rewrit ten as (2") Mt = f li ~ P)(r(l + 1 + T) + k (X - p)(r(l + 1 + k t) NBRt + (r|jL + 8) p ( r ( l + T) + e P(i> + 8)+ e) 1+ k + e) + (rp . + Yt. 8) The multiplier in this equation is similar to the mone tary base multiplier of equation 1. Thus, one might be tempted to conclude that controlling the money supply by targeting on the base or nonborrowed reserves essentially would be the same if the discount rate were tied to market interest rates. This is not the case. Changes in depository institutions’ borrowing unre lated to interest rate changes will continue to affect the money supply under nonborrowed reserve targeting. This would not be true under base targeting since all changes in borrowing would be offset through open market operations.16 15The word “little” is used here because Polakoff has shown that borrowing increases at a decreasing rate as the rate spread widens. Making the discount rate a penalty rate might be a consideration if one believes Polakoff s “reluctance elasticity” is strong or if one believes that the administration of the discount window is highly variable. See M. E . Polakoff, “Reluctance Elasticity, Least-Cost and Member-Bank Borrowing: A Suggested Integration, "Journal o f Finance (March 1960), pp. 1-18. For a recent discussion of the role of the discount rate as a penalty rate, see Economic Report o f the President (1982), pp. 67-68; and Bryon Higgins and Gordon H. Sellon, Jr., “Should the Discount Rate be a Penalty Rate?” Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City (January 1981), pp. 3-10. 16In this regard, if borrowing is unstable, tying the discount rate may not produce greater control under NBR targeting. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS Furthermore, this argument fails to take account of the likely response by depository institutions to a monetary base operating procedure. A policy of offset ting all changes in borrowing to maintain a monetary base target may, at times, result in high levels of the federal funds rate; however, there is an upper limit to the federal funds rate that is established by depository institutions’ credit demand. These institutions would be unwilling to pay an interest rate on short-term reserve adjustment funds in excess of the rate on mar ginal short-term loans for any extended period. Thus, depository institutions might increase their holdings of excess reserves if the Federal Reserve adopted a base targeting procedure. This response might permit the Federal Reserve to hit a base target, but would not guarantee better short-run monetary control. Any im provement in short-run monetary control in this in stance depends critically on the volatility of excess reserves under a base targeting procedure. Thus, If the time subscript, t, is understood to be the end of a reserve maintenance week, the explicit effects of CRA and LRA for monetary control can be seen by comparing the model with the following required re serve equations: CRA (4) RRt = r(Dt + T D t) (5) RR, (6) RRt Q This argument is important; however, it has implica tions for short-run monetary control under both base and nonborrowed reserve targeting. If the target level for nonborrowed reserves is inconsistent with deposi tory institutions’ required reserves, it produces a short-run change in borrowing, total reserves and, hence, money. LAGGED VS. CONTEMPORANEOUS RESERVE ACCOUNTING AND MONETARY CONTROL II While tying the discount rate to the market interest rate will reduce the endogeneity of the base under a system of CRA, this need not be the case under LRA. Under the present system of LRA, required reserves in the current week are determined by the level of deposits held two weeks previously. Thus, any dis crepancy between the amount of reserves supplied by the Federal Reserve and the amount of reserves that depository institutions are required to hold must be made up either at the discount window or through changes in desired levels of excess reserves. Since historically excess reserves are relatively interestinsensitive, the discrepancy between the amount of reserves supplied and the amount of reserves required will likely be made up at the discount window. If the Federal Reserve attempted to hit a level of the mone tary base that was inconsistent with the level of re quired reserves (given by deposit levels from the pre vious two weeks), the result would be an immediate change in the level of depository institutions’ borrow ing and a movement of the monetary base from its target level. Thus, it is argued, LRA precludes the Federal Reserve from hitting a short-run monetary base target. rather than being an objection to base targeting, this argument is simply an indictment of monetary control under LRA. ll it C A Tied Discount Rate and Lagged Reserve Accounting OCTOBER 1982 LRA -2 + T D t_ Federal Reserve’s proposal for CRA + T D t_ 2) These equations represent simplified versions of pure CRA, pure LRA (the present system) and the Federal Reserve’s proposal for CRA, respectively.17 The analy sis begins with a comparison of the model using equa tion 4 with the model using equation 5, and ends with an analysis of the likely implications of the Federal Reserve’s proposal. To this point, the analysis has assumed equation 4, so the effects of LRA can be seen by substituting equa tion 5 into the model. This modification affects the model in two ways: it weakens the contemporaneous link between the reserve aggregate and the equilib rium money stock, and it makes the model dynamic.18 These changes are illustrated by the following equa tions for the equilibrium money stock under base and NBR targeting when equation 5 replaces equation 4: (7) Mt = (X - p) (k + e) + (8 + p) 1+ k r(l + t )A (\ -p )(k + e) (1 + k) B, Dt 2 (8 + P) 17For a discussion of CRA and LRA as implemented, see R. Alton Gilbert, “Lagged Reserve Requirements: Implications for Mone tary Control and Bank Reserve Management,” this Review (May 1980), pp. 7-20. The Board’s proposal for CRA has a lag of two days. The reserve maintenance period ends on Monday, two days prior to the end of the reserve settlement week. 18Actually, the excess reserve equation may change with CRA or LRA as well. Current levels of excess reserves would be related to deposits of the previous two weeks and the current market in terest rate. This change is ignored for convenience. 29 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS rpA (\ -p )(k + e) (1 + k) + (8 + p) (\ -p )(k + e) + (8 + p) 1+ k (8) Mt = Yt X — NBR, (X -p )e + (8 + a) 1+ k r(l + t)X pi ~ p)e + (8 + a) 1+ k D t_ 2 rpA Pi~p)e + (8 + a) It — 2 1+ k + a\ Pi~p)e + (8 + a) id, 1+ k [ ( 8 + a) - + P i~p)e + (8 + a) 1+ k Yt The first of these changes can be seen by noting that neither the reserve ratio (r) nor the time deposit ratio (t ) appears in the contemporaneous multipliers for the base and NBR. Indeed, NBR are contemporaneously linked to money, through non-interest-rate effects, only via excess reserves and borrowings. The reserve aggregates provide a link to current money creation primarily through their link to current deposits. LRA severs part of this link. (It should be noted, however, that LRA does not eliminate completely the contem poraneous link between the money stock and either \1Q reserve aggregate.) 19It is sometimes argued that there is no contemporaneous link between deposit creation and reserves independent of its effect on market interest rates, because depository institutions are free to create all the deposits they wish in this period without any consid eration about the current level of reserves (e.g., LeRoy, “Mone tary Control Under Lagged Reserve Accounting”). This argument clearly ignores the role of currency and excess reserves in estab lishing a contemporaneous link between the reserve aggregate and the money stock. It is easy to show that current deposits are related to curren t base under LRA, even if the interestresponsiveness of currency and excess reserves are zero. From the appendix: if p = 8 = 0, then M, = (1 + k)/(k + e)Bt. Pesek and Saving have made this point in a simple money multiplier model when there were no reserve requirements. See Boris P. Pesek and Thomas R. Saving, The Foundations o f Money and Banking (Mac millan Co., 1968), pp. 76-78. Digitized for30 FRASER OCTOBER 1982 The explicit dynamics of the money stock under LRA are seen by noting that lagged deposits and in terest rates are included in the equilibrium money stock equations. NBR and the monetary base not only influence the level of money immediately, but have lagged effects via their influence on deposits and in terest rates. These variables, in turn, affect future money. It can be shown that if the dynamic system is stable, the long-run base multiplier is identical to the static base multiplier of equation 1. Thus, if the Feder al Reserve were to achieve and maintain some target level of the base, the expected value of the long-run equilibrium money stock would, ceteris paribus, be the same as that obtained under CRA.20 Short-Run Movements in Money and Interest Rates Despite the fact that the return to CRA has no consequences for long-run monetary control, it does have some implications for short-run movements in money and interest rates. The following analysis can be carried out in terms of either base or NBR targeting; however, the results are presented only for base targeting. The analysis begins with a simple graphic presenta tion of the model under base targeting in figure 3. M£ and Mf denote the money supply schedules under CRA and LRA, respectively. Under fairly reasonable conditions, the money supply schedule is flatter under LRA.21 Again, the money demand equation is drawn for a fixed income level. The curves are drawn to intersect for ease of illustration. 20This point has been made by Laufenberg, although in a slightly different context. See Daniel E. Laufenberg, “Contemporaneous Versus Lagged Reserve Accounting, ” Journal o f Money, Credit and Banking (May 1976), pp. 239-45. This result is more logical than it first appears. For example, one would not expect the introduction of LRA to have any impact on money creation if depository institutions had not previously adjusted their required reserves during the current week under CRA. Thus, we might expect LRA to affect interest rates and money only to the extent that it forces the system to follow a different aggregate reserve adjustment path than it would have followed under CRA. 21The condition is that > (1 + t) (e + (8 + p) < k) Since (1 + T )/ (e + k) is greater than one, this condition is likely to hold. If the interest sensitivity of time deposits, p., is sufficient ly negative, however, the LRA could be steeper than the CRA curve. If this were the case, the results of this section would be reversed. Because of the simplicity of his model, Laufenberg obtains the above result by ignoring this condition. See Laufen berg, “Contemporaneous Versus Lagged Reserve Accounting.” FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 Figure 3 Figure 4 Effect of an In c re a se in the R e se rv e A g greg a te Under LRA and CRA Effect of an In cre a se in M oney Demand Under LRA and CRA The effect of changes in Federal Reserve actions on the money stock can be illustrated via figure 3. For example, suppose that the monetary disturbance comes through an increase in the base. The increase in the base shifts both M* and Mt to the right. Because the s multiplier is larger under LRA than under CRA, the MJ curve shifts further and the new equilibrium level of money is larger.22 As a result, both the initial in crease in the money stock and the initial decrease in the interest rate are larger under LRA. A different result is obtained if the monetary dis turbance occurs through a change in the demand for money, as illustrated in figure 4. The increase in the demand for money results in a larger initial increase in the money stock and a smaller initial increase in the interest rate under LRA. If all money shocks are associ ated with changes in money demand due to unantici pated changes in the level of income, the move back to CRA would result in less short-run money stock and more interest-rate variability. If all money shocks are associated with changes in the policy control variable, 22The condition required for the equilibrium money stock to be larger is that The same condition is required for both base and NBR targeting. the return to CRA would reduce the short-run variabil ity of both money and interest rates. In either case, however, the short-run money stock initially overshoots its long-run equilibrium. In the former case, the overshoot is due to the fact that in terest rates fall too far in response to an increase in the policy aggregate, while in the latter, it is due to the fact that they do not rise enough in response to an increase in money demand. This initial overshooting of money may have repercussions in subsequent periods as de pository institutions attempt to obtain reserves to sup port the current overexpansion of deposits. The effect of this dynamic response on the variability of money and interest rates is an empirical question.23 23See Laufenberg, “Contemporaneous Versus Lagged Reserve Accounting. ” As noted, the introduction of LRA makes the model dynamic and, thus, the model with LRA follows an adjustment path toward the long-run equilibrium. This path differs with the dynamic structure of the model. A comparison of one dynamic adjustment path with another is relevant only if the dynamic structures are well-specified. In this regard, the conclusions con cerning the variability of money and interest rates reached by Laufenberg, based on a comparison of the dynamic adjustment of the CRA and LRA models, are misleading. See Daniel L. Thorn ton, “Lagged and Contemporaneous Reserve Accounting and the Variance of Money and Interest Rates,” unpublished paper, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (1982). The oscillatory nature of the adjustment of money and interest rates to their long-run equilibrium under LRA noted by Laufenberg is discussed in the appendix. 31 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS F igure 5 The Money Supply Under the Board's Proposal ior CRA OCTOBER 1982 money and may increase the variance of interest rates, depending on the relative magnitudes of the variances associated with the factors that affect supply and de mand. While the basic intuition that leads to this con clusion is correct, it fails to account for possible Federal Reserve reaction to random changes in time deposits. Under both CRA and LRA, random changes in time deposits, TD, affect the demand for required reserves and, hence, the equilibrium money stock and the in terest rate. Under LRA, however, the effect of a ran dom change in time deposits does not manifest itself for two periods. If such changes were identified with 100 percent accuracy and if the Federal Reserve made temporary, compensatory changes in the exogenous reserve aggregate, random fluctuations in time de posits two weeks previous would have no effect on either the current money stock or the current interest rate. If the variance of the time deposits is sufficiently large, the variance of money and interest rates may be less under LRA than under CRA. The critical issue is the extent to which the Federal Reserve correctly identifies and offsets random shifts in time deposits.24 This result is illustrated as follows: Let V(M^) and V(Mjj) denote the variance of the money stock under CRA and LRA, respectively. If the Federal Reserve correctly identifies random changes in time deposits, it is easy to show that The effect of the Federal Reserve’s proposal for CRA can be seen by noting that the money supply schedule under the Board s proposal, denoted Mb, lies between the CRA and LRA curves, as illustrated in figure 5. Furthermore, the curve will shift further than the CRA curve, but not as far as the LRA for a given change in the monetary base. If most money shocks are associ ated with changes in the policy control variable, the Federal Reserve’s proposal should improve the shortrun stability of both money and interest rates. If most shocks are associated with unanticipated changes in the demand for money, the result will be more stable money and less stable interest rates. V(Mf) = erf + a 2 T M and V(M{) = of, The Variance of Money and Interest Rates under CRA where cjmT is the variance in money associated with the demand for time deposits, e rf is the variance associated with the other random components of the money stock under CRA, and o f is the variance of money under LRA. It can be shown that o f > crf . Thus, the variance of the money stock would be larger under LRA, all other things constant. The loss of the variance of time deposits [omX does not appear in the expression for V(Ml )], however, makes the variance of money under t LRA smaller. The reduction in variance associated with the removal of this source of variation could more than offset the increase in variance due to other Given the above analysis, one might be tempted to conclude that random variations in the factors that affect the money supply will cause both money and interest rates to be more variable under LRA, while random variations in the demand for money will cause money to be more variable and interest rates to be less variable. Thus, one might suspect that the movement from CRA to LRA would increase the variance of ^Furtherm ore, if individual depository institutions anticipated the effects of their collective actions on interest rates, the systematic deposit overexpansions that we have noted need not occur; conse quently, the greater money and interest rate volatility associated with differences in the slopes of the short-run money schedule under LRA need not materialize. This point has been made by Edgar L. Feige and Robert T. McGee, “Federal Reserve Policy and Interest Rate Instability,” The Financial Review (May 1982), pp. 50-62. Digitized for32 FRASER OCTOBER 1982 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS factors.25 Thus, contrary to the common belief, no general conclusion can be reached about the relative variance of money under LRA and CRA. It is an empir ical issue.26 This analysis can be extended to the Federal Re serve’s proposal for CRA. If the variance of the money stock under the Board’s proposal is denoted as V(Mj’), it is easy to show that V(Mj’) < V(Mt).2' The question of the relative variance of interest rates under LRA or CRA has an ambiguous answer. If the reduction in variance associated with correctly iden tifying random changes in time deposits is ignored, the variance of interest rates will be smaller under CRA if the variance associated with money demand is small relative to the variance associated with the factors that 25This result is even stronger when it is recognized that variances of borrowings and excess reserves may be affected by the reserve accounting structure. There is evidence that both of these error structures changed with the move to LRA in 1968. See Albert E. Burger, “Lagged Reserve Requirements: Their Effects on Feder al Reserve Operations, Money Market Stability, Member Banks and the Money Supply Process,” unpublished paper for the Federal Beserve Bank of St. Louis (1971); and Board of Gov ernors, “Impact of Discount Policy Procedures on the Effective ness of Reserve Targeting. ” “ See Poole, “Federal Reserve Operating Procedures: A Survey and Evaluation of the Historical Record Since October 1979;” LeRoy, “Monetary Control Under Lagged Reserve Accounting;” and David S. Jones, “An Empirical Analysis of Monetary Control Under Contemporaneous and Lagged Reserve Accounting,” Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Working Paper 82-002 (March 1982). Furthermore, the empirical work to date does not provide an unambiguous answer to this question. Early empirical work by Burger, Coats, Poole and Lieberman suggested that the move ment to LRA in 1968 resulted in greater instability of the federal fiinds rate. Recent work by Feige and McGee, however, suggests that the movement to LRA actually reduced the funds rate variability. Poole and Lieberman report somewhat less stable money growth under LRA; however, in another study, Feige and McGee report slight increases in money and reserve predictabil ity under LRA during the reserve-targeting period, and a substan tial increase in the predictability of the federal funds rate. See Burger, “Lagged Reserve Requirements: Their Effects on Feder al Reserve Operations, Money Market Stability, Member Banks and the Money Supply Process;” Warren L. Coats, “Lagged Re serve Accounting and the Money Supply Mechanism, "Journal o f Money, Credit and Banking (May 1976), pp. 167-80; Feige and McGee, “Federal Reserve Policy and Interest Rate Instability,” pp. 50-61; Edgar L. Feige and Robert T. McGee, “Has the Federal Reserve Shifted From a Policy of Interest Rate Targets to a Policy of Monetary Aggregate Targets? An Application of E x ogeneity Test Procedures, "Journal o f Money, Credit and Bank ing (November 1979), pp. 381-404; Edgar L. Feige and Robert T. McGee, “Money Supply Control and Lagged Reserve Account ing,” Journal o f Money, Credit and Banking (November 1977), pp. 536-51. 27The reader is cautioned that this analysis of the variance of money and interest rates ignores variability through time associated with the dynamic structure of the model. affect the money supply.28 The same conclusion holds for a comparison of the Federal Reserve’s proposal for CRA with LRA. We have shown that if we account for a possible reduction in the variance of interest rates under LRA associated with correctly identifying random changes in time deposits, the variance of interest rates under LRA could be smaller than under CRA even if money demand were less variable than the money supply. This conclusion would not hold for the Federal Re serve’s proposal, however, since time deposits enter LRA and it in the same way. Thus, while an analysis of this model suggests that the Federal Reserve’s proposal for CRA may reduce the variance of money compared with the present system of LRA, its impact on the variance of interest rates is ambiguous.29 CONCLUSIONS This article reviews three frequently suggested changes in Federal Reserve operating procedures to achieve more stable short-run monetary control: monetary base targeting, tying the discount rate to the market interest rate and adopting a system of contem poraneous reserve accounting. Since the conditions necessary for money to be ex ogenous are less restrictive for base than for nonbor rowed reserve targeting, adopting a base targeting procedure would likely result in greater short-run monetary control if most of the shocks to the money supply come from the demand side. If most of the shocks come from the supply side, then base targeting “ In this regard, there has been a great deal of concern about the stability of money demand in recent years. See, for example, Michael J. Hamburger, “Behavior of the Money Stock: Is There a Puzzle?" Journal o f Monetary Economics (July 1977), pp. 265-88; G. S. Laumas and David E. Spencer, “The Stability of the De mand for Money: Evidence from the Post-1973 Period,” Review o f Economics and Statistics (August 1980), pp. 455-59; and R. W. Hafer and Scott E. Hein, “Evidence on the Temporal Stability of the Demand for Money Relationship in the United States,” this Review (December 1979), pp. 3-1 4 ; and “The Shift in Money Demand: What Really Happened?” this Review (February 1982), pp. 11-16. 29The Board has also considered a provision for staggered-reserve accounting. The effect of this controversial provision on short-run variability of money and interest rates remains a question. For a discussion of the effects of staggered-reserve accounting, see Michael L. Bagshaw and William T. Gavin, “Stability in a Model of Staggered-Reserve Accounting,” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Working Paper 8202 (August 1982); and William T. Gavin, “The Case for Staggered-Reserve Accounting,” Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review, (Spring 1982), pp. 30-36. 33 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 may result in less stable monetary growth. This conclu sion depends critically on the relative interest sensitiv ity of the demand for money and depository institution borrowing. The more interest sensitive is the former and less interest sensitive is the latter, the more stable money growth will be under base targeting relative to NBR targeting. Furthermore, if depository institution borrowing is highly variable, base targeting may be more stable, even if the shocks come from the supply side, since money will be unresponsive to fluctuations in borrowing under base targeting. Monetary control under base targeting could be en hanced further by tying the discount rate to a market interest rate. This would reduce substantially the in terest sensitivity of borrowing and make it easier to hit a monetary base target. Adopting a system of contem poraneous reserve accounting also should make it easier to hit a base target, since it would no longer be necessary for borrowing to respond to differences be tween a predetermined level of required reserves and an amount of reserves consistent with the base target, as under the present system of LRA. It is not certain whether the return to a system of contemporaneous reserve accounting on all deposits would increase or reduce the variance of money and interest rates. The Federal Reserve’s proposal for con temporaneous reserve accounting, however, will like ly reduce the variability of money. Furthermore, it will likely reduce the variability of interest rates, if the variance of the money demand schedule is sufficiently small relative to the variance of the money supply schedule. APPENDIX The purpose of this appendix is fourfold. First, it presents the system of reduced-form equations for base and NBR targeting under CRA. Second, it pre sents the reduced-form equations under LRA. Third, the long-run base multiplier under LRA is derived and discussed. Finally, analytical results for the variance of the endogenous variables for base and NBR targeting and for CRA and LRA are presented and discussed. In what follows, we will denote the expected value of the variable with a hat, e.g., E(M t) = M .1 The Expected Value of the Reduced Form fo r Base Targeting under CRA ... M, n r / - x „ — Bt + AO 1 „ ** ~ A o I - p l > + 8 + p) ~ ------------- l + k ---------- I 1 (*-~ p )(r (l+ T ) + e) + (rjjL + 5 + a) ( l + k) N BR, B, A o ft[(r(l + T) + e) (a — p) + k(rp. + 8 + a)] l + k Y, A o aid t a _ Ut — (X —p)/(l + k) . A0 i w h e r e Ao = B, + ft(rp. + S + p)/(l + k) , I, Ao (X —p)(r(l + t ) + e + k) i+~k ^ + p) pW1 + t ) + e + k)l A0 J Y, , The Expected Value o f the Reduced Form fo r NBR Targeting under CRA P W l + T) + e + k)/(l + k),. ---------------A A o J rtl / i \ P(r(1+ T ) e) p| (rp + -8 i + a) --------- — +---- "I 'The symbol Y, is used here in explicit recognition that the Federal Reserve must forecast aggregate income in order to control the nominal money stock. 34 M, = ----- N B R , + A, A, Y, FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS OCTOBER 1982 f (X -a )k + (p -a )"| rtx L iT k— J P ((8 + a )( k + e ) (X — p ) ( r ( l + t ) + e + k) + (r|jL + 8 + = NBR, Ai e )(g — p) + (r p . + 8 + c t)k ] (1 + k ) A j T (X. a p )(r(l + t ) + e + k) I ---------------------------L+ k [_ + (rp, + 8 + . (A. — p ) / ( l + k ) + “i l + k p) ' id , 0 ( r jx + 8 + * a )/ (l+ k ) ~ Yt A i o t(X — p ) / ( l + k ) id , A, w h ere A! = ( X- p) [— ] + (rp , + 8 + a ). The Expected Value of the Reduced Form fo r Base Targeting under LRA X M , = — r (l + T )X A2 B, - (X -p )(k + e) where A2 = ----- — ;------- 1 8 + p ) Y, A, Ut - Several interesting observations should be made about the above. First, the discount rate enters the reduced-form under base targeting only in the NBR equation. This merely reflects the fact that if the Federal Reserve is to hit a base target, it must change NBR proportionally to the change in the discount rate. Thus, changes in the discount rate cannot alter policy with respect to either the money supply or interest rates independent of the base target. This would not be true of NBR targeting. Under NBR targeting, changes in the discount rate produce effects on money and interest rates independent of the target level of NBR. Second, it is easy to show the conditions under which the initial change in the equilibrium money stock is larger under LRA than under CRA. Note that A M , A M , D ,_ 2 A 2 Y, — a id , , p [ ( r ( l + T) + e ( 8 + p ))/ (l + k ) p) ( l + k) B, — A B, A B, LRA CRA > 0, implies rp.X . i t - 2 ------------------------------: ---------------------------Y , X > 0. (X — p ) ( e + k ) . D t (X -p )/ (l + k) - r(l + ^ Bt r p .(X -p )/ (l + k ) t )( X — p ) / ( l + k ) “ £ P (k + e )/ (l + k ) + a2 A T) ) + e + k) + (r p . + 8 + p) l + k 2 ^ A , r (1 t This condition will hold if . p ( p + 8 )/ (l + k ) J_ R _ A A9 1 8 + p K l+ k Dt p- lt — (X — p ) ( r ( l + + l^t-2 • »2 A *t-2 . < ~ (X p )(l + t ) ;------ ■ l + k The term on the right-hand side of this inequality will be positive on the reasonable assumption that I X I> I p I. . The condition for the change in the money stock under the Federal Reserve’s proposal to be less than under LRA is A2 p. < — (^ ~ P ) T l+ k N BR , = + (8 + a ) l + k v -------------------------------------- B , 'I . The Long-Run Monetary Base Multiplier ^ r(x _ a )k+(p_ a )i r(1+T L ) ------ITiT- J D ,- The above system based on LRA is dynamic in that lagged endogenous variables, Dt_ 2 and it~ 2>appear on 35 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS the right-hand side of the reduced-form .2 If we assume, for simplicity, that Yt = 0 for all t, then it is easy to show that Mt can be expressed as the following distributed lag by successive substitution. \ Xip M, = — B, + — Z2 A tA £ H 2 where tp = _ [~ + T)(^~p + r^(1 + k) ~ r(1 ^ | (1 + k ) J A, Now if we let the base be constant for all t (i.e., Bf = Bt - 2 = B t - 4 = • • • = B), we get M, = —— [l + ip + < 2 + < 3 + . . .] p p Using the formula for summing a geometric series, and taking the limit, we have M, = lim BA. BX A-2 Some Observations on the Variability of Money and Interest fo r Base vs NBR Targeting and LRA vs CRA The question naturally arises about the variability of the endogenous variables under alternative operating procedures and under different institutional arrange ments. Unfortunately, the model does not lead to con clusive answers to these questions. We begin by deal ing with the question of the variability of the money stock under base and NBR targeting. The error terms for the money stock under base and NBR targeting are, respectively: fell The sum on the right-hand side of the above equation is finite if cp n-»-0 as Under this condition, M, = slowly or rapidly depending on whether IcpI is close to one or zero. Furthermore, under the general condition that < < 0, the system will oscillate toward its long-run p equilibrium, as indicated by Laufenberg.3 Xtp2 + "7~ B,_4 + . . . b ,_ 2 L OCTOBER 1982 X (r(l+ x) + e - l ) BX + e + k) j X(r(l + T ) + e) “ T T T T T a-----(1 + k) A! U" X , u« + 7 “ Aj (u bt - rU rt - U et) 1 A2 | t i r(l + t)(X —p) + r p . ( l 1+ (1 + k) A2 + k) j A2 (1 + k) + r ( l + t )(X - p) + (rp,)(l + k) Substituting in for A2, we get M, = B T) (1 + k) A0 L l-ip . a n d = B X , 7“ (ruT + uet) t A0 (l + k)(rp, + 8 + p) — p(r(l + fed Substituting in for cp, we get Mt X , ----7T77T7 (1 + k) Ao (1 + k) (rp. + 8 + + a) - p(r(l + t ) + e) (1 + k) A, If we denote the variance of money under base and NBR targeting by V(Mt ) and \ (Mt ), respectively, B / N and if we assume the individual error terms are inde pendent of each other and through time, we get X (X —p ) [ r ( l + t ) + k + e] + - D l 2 ( 8 + p + r p .) 1 + k L Comparing this multiplier with the base multiplier under CRA, we see that they are identical. Thus, LRA makes the system explicitly dynamic but does not affect the long-run equilibrium. -----(1 + k) A,0 J 2 Vc [ “t ] (2?+ r< T <a j^(l + k)(rp, + 8 + p) —p(r(l + (1 + k ) The above solution, however, does require the sta bility condition I(pi < 1. The system may converge A0 t ) + e + k ) "1 " , --------------J Cn T and V(M, 2The inclusion ofit_ 2 in these equations is based on the assumption that changes in time deposits in period t —2 induced by changes in the market interest rate affect current required reserves. This is a highly questionable assumption (see below). Therefore, it might be more reasonable to use the reduced-form equations obtained by letting p. = 0. 36 3See Daniel E. Laufenberg, “Contemporaneous Versus Lagged Reserve Accounting, ’’Journal o f Money, Credit and Banking (May 1976), pp. 239-45. FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS T (1 + k)(rp. + 5 + a) - p(r(l + t ) + e) "I ~ L (1 + k) J C T n A, A number of interesting observations can be made from the above. First, random shocks to currency, uct, move money in opposite directions under base and NBR targeting if 0 < t( 1 + t) + e < 1. Under this condition, a random increase in currency will reduce the money stock under base targeting and increase it under NBR targeting. Furthermore, the magnitude of this shock on the money stock will be larger under base targeting. This can be seen by noting that the absolute value of the coefficient on uct under base targeting will be larger than under NBR targeting if r(l + t ) + e < 1/2 and if IAo I < IAj I. Thus, the variance of money associ ated with random changes in currency will be larger under base targeting. The variance of money associated with other supplyside shocks will be smaller under NBR targeting if IA0 1< IAx I. This condition requires (\k + p)/(l + k) > a. Standard estimates of these parameters suggest that this condition will hold. Thus, supply-side shocks will have a greater impact on the money supply under base targeting. Note, however, that if the discount rate were tied so that, effectively, a = 0, the above condi tion would not hold, and more stable monetary control could be achieved through base targeting. Second, the variance of money associated with ran dom shifts in money demand can be seen to be larger under NBR targeting if the money supply schedule is flatter. This can be seen by denoting the slopes of the money supply under base and NBR targeting by 1/iJjb and l/vJiN respectively, where , >B = I< p(r(l + t) Third, random shocks in depository institutions’ borrowing have no impact on money under base targeting, but they do under NBR targeting. If the variance of these shocks are larger— relative to the variances of currency, excess reserves and time de posits— the net effect of supply-side shocks from all sources could be larger under NBR targeting. Thus, no general conclusion about the variability of money under base and NBR targeting can be reached. (The outcome depends on the magnitudes of o f , o f ,and o f relative to o f , and on the magnitude of o f ,.) The Variance of Money and Interest Rates under CRA and LRA Now consider the variance of money and interest rates under CRA, LRA and the Board’s proposal for CRA. Only the case of base targeting will be dealt with; however, the results hold for NBR targeting as well. For simplicity, assume that the individual structural errors are independent (relaxing this assumption makes determining the relative variability under CRA and LRA more difficult). It is easy to show that the error terms for the equilibrium money stock under CRA and LRA, respectively, are \ (r(l + T) + e — 1) X ------,, , u . -------- U ct- ~7~ (rUrt + Uet) (1 + k) A0 A0 (1 + k)(rp, + 8 + p) —p(r(l + t ) + e + k) + (1 + k) A„ U" and X(e - i ) X Uct - ~ r (m T t-2 + Uet) (1 + k) A* ct + e + k) — (1 + k) (r[x + 5 + p) A. (1 + k)(8 + p) —p(e + k) r (l + T) + e + k (1 + k) A* If we let V(Mt) and V(Me denote the variance of t) money under CRA and LRA, respectively, we obtain and p (r(l+ T ) = OCTOBER 1982 + e) — ( l + k)(rp. r (l + t) + 8 + a) + e Now note that the money supply schedule is flatter under NBR targeting if i| < iJiN, which, in turn, iB p(r(l + t) + e) —k(r|x + 8) requires ----------------------------------> a. We now note r(l+ T ) + e + k that the coefficients on the <jfrl term of the above expressions are simply T (1 + k)(rp. + 8 + p) —p(r(l + I 2 ^ ^ ■ , i = B and N. It is j i easy to see that the general conclusion about the sensi tivity of the money stock to random changes in the demand for money hold if i)jb < viN. | [£] [ (1 + k) A0 t) + e + k) P. and + ca 37 FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS | ( l + k)(S + p ) ~ p(e + k)~| (1 + k) A , Jm - L It is easy to see that V(M,) < V(M|). This can be done by noting that (r(l + T ) + e - 1 ) 2 < (e —l)2 for (r(l + t ) + e) < 1, and that (A0)2 > (A2)2. Furthermore, it is clear from our previous analysis that the coefficient on the variance of money will be smaller under CRA if the money supply schedule is flatter under LRA than under CRA.4 Note that this conclusion depends on including u-rt — in the error term for the equilibrium money stock 2 under LRA. If the Federal Reserve could identify ran dom changes in time deposits and make corresponding compensatory changes in the reserve aggregate, changes in uTt_ 2 would not affect the current money stock. Thus, the variance of money under LRA would be smaller than indicated above by5 OCTOBER 1982 Clearly (A3)2 > (A2)2. Furthermore, [(1 + k)(8 + p) —p(r + e + k)]2 < [(l + k)(8 + p)-p(e + k)]2. Thus, V(M’’) < V(M{). The move from the current t system of LRA to the Board’s proposed system of CRA should reduce the variance of the money stock. This conclusion is true whether o f is included or excluded from these expressions. The Variance of the Interest Rate Denote the variances of the interest rate with re spect to CRA, LRA and the Board’s proposal as V(it), V(iJ) and V(iJJ), respectively. Then, r(r(l + T + e + k - l ) ] 2 , ) V/-1 V ■L ,"> L r In this instance, it is impossible to say whether V(M?) is larger or smaller than V(Mf). Furthermore, the structure of other equations might change with a change in reserve accounting.6 Ifwe denote the variance of money under the Feder al Reserve’s proposal as V(Mj), it is easily shown that J * + [ r r f i l + r [f]‘* 0 +1.4, v (i,'; ~ [r(l + ) + e + k]~| 2 , (1 + k)A0 J Cm T t ,i ,i2 (1 + k)A2J 1 r , t -(1 + k)A2- 2 < ?) T —(e + kfl r u, (1 + k)A2J1 u' r+e - l l r u. (1 + k)A3J i ° V(if> -d + k )A 3 x; + a,2) —(r + e + k) "I (1 + k)A3 V(M? M-) = [ t t t S x j ] ^ + [ i ] (r2a?+o;2 (1 + k) (S + p) —p(r + e + k) ~j ~ d + k )a, J L , (Jn ' where r (X —p)(r + k + e) = r+k— + (8+p)'This condition is simply that „ ^ As with the comparison of the variances of money, a comparison of V(iJ) and V(iJ) depends on whether the term (1 + t ) (8 + p) (e + k) V . T is included or excluded under LRA. With respect to the variance of interest rates, however, there is an additional complication; it is not immediately clear whether • 5While the general conclusion that V(MC need not be less than ,) V(M|) will remain valid under alternative specifications of this model, this specific result may change. For example, this expres sion would change if there were different reserve ratios on time and transactions deposits and if excess reserve holdings depended on both time and transactions deposits. 6This need not be the case, however. If there were sudden changes in reserves due to deposit shifts AD, the amount of market opera tions necessary to restore a bank’s reserve position would be (1 —r) AD under CRA and AD under LRA. This need for greater market activity under LRA could offset any effect on excess reserves associ ated with greater certainty of required reserves. 38 -r L (1+ k)A0 J ( l + k)Ao — (r (l + T) + e + L (1 + k)A„ k)~|2 > [ - ( e + k )]2 J < L (l + k)A2J A little algebra shows that the condition requires (1 + t ) (8 + p) (e + k) < > This is the condition required for the slope of the money supply schedule to be steeper or flatter under CRA than under LRA. This adds another element of ambiguity to the determination of the relative variance of interest rates under CRA and LRA. A similar problem makes the determination of the relative magnitudes of V(il> and V(i't) ambiguous. This t) is seen by noting that V(i[’) < V(it) if r-(r+ + )T . . r ~ +k i22 ek , (e ) ~ L (l + k)A3 J m L(l + k)A2J nr Following the same procedure as above, it can be shown that this condition will hold only if r ( 5 + p) > 0. Given the restrictions on the signs of these parameters, this cannot hold. Therefore, the last term in the ex pression for V(i^) is strictly larger than the last term in the expression for V(i*). Thus, it is indeterminate whether the Board’s proposal for CRA will increase or reduce the variability of interest rates from the present system. 39