View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The R e v i e w is published 10 times per year by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis. Single-copy subscriptions are available to the public free of charge. Mail requests
for subscriptions, back issues, or address changes to: Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis, P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166.
Articles herein may be reprinted provided the source is credited. Please provide the Bank’s Re­
search Department with a copy of reprinted material.


http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
2
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

T he Lag From Money To Prices
K E IT H M . C A R L S O N

^ E c o n o m i s t s generally agree that money affects
prices with a lag. Research conducted at this Bank
suggests that a change in the growth rate of money
is fully reflected in the inflation rate in about five
years. This conclusion was based on a statistical anal­
ysis of the relation between money and prices in the
U.S. from 1955 through the 1960s.1
The length of the lag between money and prices
represents important information that must be con­
sidered in the policy formulation process. The policy­
maker must allow for such lags when developing a
policy to control inflation; he must also consider pos­
sible future impacts of short-run policies designed to
combat recession. Given the historical presence of
lags between money and prices, a policy designed to
control inflation will not have immediate effects. The
possible short-run costs (benefits) of a restrictive
(stimulative) policy in terms of employment and
output must be assessed against its long-run benefits
(costs) in terms of the price level. The nature of the
lag enters importantly into the decision to adopt a
specific policy, whether it be short- or long-run in
character.
The purpose of this article is to examine the rela­
tion between money and prices in light of the U.S.
1Denis S. Kamosky, “ The Link Between Money and Prices,”
this Review (June 1976), pp. 17-23. Also see Albert E. Burger,
“ Is Inflation All Due to Money?” this Review (Decem ber
1978), pp. 8-12.




economic experience of the 1970s. Statistical results
are summarized first and the economics of informa­
tion and search are then summarized to provide a
theoretical rationale for the results.

Statistical Results
Kamosky’s original estimate of the price equation
was based on the sample period from 1955 through
mid-1971 and used what is now known as “old M l”
for the money variable. A version of this equation,
estimated by using the “new” M1B definition of
money, is summarized in table l .2 Compared to the
original results, using a different definition of money
and modifying the sample period affects the pattern
of the coefficients very little. The sum of the coeffi­
cients is one, as would be expected from economic
theory.3 The mean lag is estimated at 10.96 quarters
for the 1955-69 sample period.4
2In this article, money is defined as M1B ( currency plus check­
able deposits at financial institutions). See R. W . Hafer, “ The
New Monetary Aggregates,” this Review (February 1980),
pp. 25-32. The sample period differs slightly from Karnosky’s
for puiposes of balancing degrees of freedom, so that the
1970s can be compared with the “pre-1970s” .
3For a discussion of the theory, see Leonall C. Andersen and
Denis S. Kamosky, “ The Appropriate Time Frame for Con­
trolling Monetary Aggregates: The St. Louis Evidence,” in
Controlling Monetary Aggregates II: The Implementation,
Conference Series No. 9, Federal Reserve Bank o f Boston
(September 1972), pp. 147-77.
4The mean lag serves as a summary measure of the speed with
which prices respond to money. It is calculated as a sum of
roducts ( where each product is the coefficient times the numer of the lag) divided by the sum of the coefficients.

E

3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST . L O U I S

OCTOBER

1980

Table 1
Estimate of Money-Price Equation: Original Specification
Sam ple period: I/5 5 -IW 6 9 : m2i =

20

0

.

P = -.1 4 6 + Z m , M ,
(.3 9 5 ) i = 0
Coeff.

|t|

m0

.041

1.276

mi

.034

1.538

Coeff.

|t|

Coeff.

mg

.048

3.249

m 16

.069

3.943

m9

.054

3.783

m 17

.062

3.712

4.305

m is

.053

3.511

4.673

mig

.039

3.338

|t|

m2

.030

1.903

mio

.059

m3

.029

2.171

mn

.065

m4

.030

2.235

m 12

.069

4.795

m2o

.022

3.191

m5

.033

2.294

^13

.072

4.694

2m i

1.031

7.870

m6

.037

2.475

m 14

.073

4.468

Mean lag

10.959

5.634

m7

.042

2.798

mis

.072

4.202

R2

.525

S.E.

1.066

D.W.

2.00
•

Notation: P

•

com pounded annual rate of change of G NP deflator; M

To examine the nature of the money-price lag in
light of the experience of the 1970s, it is necessary
to consider other factors that influenced the price
level during this period. From August 1971 to April
1974, a government program of wage and price con­
trols disrupted the money-price level link. In addi­
tion, in late 1973 and early 1974, substantial increases
in energy prices occurred. At various times during
the 1970s, agricultural conditions also appeared to
affect movements in the price level or, more properly,
in the indexes that are used to measure changes in
aggregate prices.
Because of these factors, the basic price equation
in this article has been respecified to include prices
of food and energy relative to overall prices and
dummy variables to capture nonmonetary effects of
wage and price controls. Table 2 summarizes the re­
sults for the 1970-79 period (center columns) and,
for comparison purposes, also summarizes the results
of this same specification for the 1955-69 period (lefthand column). As implied in Karnosky’s specification,
food and energy prices did not play a statistically

http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
4
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

com pounded annual rate of change of M1B.

significant role in explaining inflation during the 195569 period.®
The results for 1970-79 indicate a number of
changes relative to those for 1955-69. The price con­
trol dummy is significant with a negative sign, and
the post-control dummy has the expected (positive)
sign but is not significant. The sum effect of energy
prices, as measured by the producer price of fuels
and related products and power, is positive and signifi­
cant. The food price variable has the expected sign
and is just short of being significant. More impor­
tantly, however, the pattern of coefficients on money
is substantially different from that estimated for 195569. No coefficients are significant after the eighth lag,
and the mean lag is 5.05 quarters. The sum of the
coefficients, although close to one in value, is not
significantly different from zero.
These results suggest that the 20-quarter lag struc­
ture is no longer appropriate for data from the 1970s.
5Throughout this article, “ statistical significance” refers to a
two-tailed test conducted at the 5 percent level. For large
samples, the critical “t” is ±1 .9 6 .

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BAN K O F ST. L O U IS

OCTOBER

1980

Table 2
Estimates of Money-Price Equation : Modified Specification
6
.
.
k
•
•
•
P = const. + Z mi M .i + d i D i + d2 D2 + Z e, (P b - P ) - i + f (P f - P )
i = 0
I= 0
1 /5 5 -IV /69: m2i = 0

I/7 0 -IV /7 9 : m2j = 0

I/7 0 -IV /7 9 : m 13 =

Coeff.

Coeff

|t|

Coeff.

|t|
.440
1.454

|t|

0

m0

.048

1.215

.035

.680

.038

mi

.041

1.484

.070

1.881

.065

ITI2

.036

1.875

.096

3.168

.087

2.800

m3

.034

2.217

.115

3.821

.104

2.963

m4

.034

2.307

.125

3.777

.116

3.005

m5
m6

.036

2.310

.129

3.458

.123

3.222

.039

2.407

.128

3.789

.124

3.443

m7

.044

2.641

.121

2.692

.121

3.324

m8

.049

3.007

.111

2.308

.113

2.804

mg

.054

3.470

.097

1.926

.100

2.213

mio

.059

3.946

.081

1.549

.082

1.744

mu
m i2

.063

4.293

.064

1.182

.056

1.404

.067

4.396

.046

.833

.032

1.159

™13
nrii4

.069

4.268

.028

.508

—

—

.070

4.014

.011

.210

—

—

m is

.069

3.728

-.0 0 3

.058

—

—

rtiie

.065

3.459

-.0 1 5

.296

—

—

m 17

.059

3.224

-.0 2 3

.506

—

—

m 18
mi9

.050

3.026

-.0 2 6

.690

—

—

.037

2.858

-.0 2 4

.850

—

—

m2o
Zm i

.020

2.717

-.0 1 6

.990

—

—

1.044

7.457

1.150

1.631

1.164

3.297

10.542

5.201

5.047

.756

5.908

3.279

e0

.002

.089

.001

.076

.003

.314

ei

.004

.216

.013

1.652

.014

1.755

e2
e3
e4

.007
.010

.370

.018

2.097

.017

2.089
2.465

.018

.574

.017

2.602

.013

.706

.013

2.233

.013

2.892

e5

.013

.674

.008

1.123

.007

1.386

e6
Zei

.009

.595

.002

.407

.002

.444

.058

.580

.073

2.086

.075

2.586

-.1 0 9

.281

-.6 8 8

.174

-.7 7 0

.356

dx

—

—

-1 .7 2 4

3.010

-1 .7 3 5

2.801

d2

—

—

1.619

1.134

1.772

1.168

-.0 3 2

.536

.131

1.941

.129

1.969

Mean lag

Const.

f
R2

.495

•

Notation: P =

=

.728

1.264

1.294

1.94

D.W.

Di =

.741

1.099

S.E.

2.27
•
com pounded annual rate of change of GNP deflator; M =

price control dummy ( III /7 1 - I/ 7 4 =

1 , 0 elsew h ere); D2 =

2.18
com pounded annual rate of change of M1B;

decontrol dummy ( II/7 4 - IV /7 4 =

1 , 0 elsew h ere); PE

com pounded annual rate of change of producer price index of fuels and related products and power; and PF =

com­

pounded annual rate of change of food deflator.




5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BAN K O F ST. L O U IS

OCTOBER

1980

C hart 1

C um ulative Effect on Rate of Price Increase of
a Perm anent Increase in the Rate of G row th of M oney
Percent of Total Effect
Perceat

Percent

100

100

\

\
\

75

75

1 7 -7
90 9

50

50

^ 1 5 -6
95 9

25

25

...................

i

i

i

i

i
10
Q enrters

The results of shortening the lag structure to 12 quar­
ters (with the thirteenth constrained to equal zero)
are shown in the right-hand columns of table 2. With
this specification, the effect of money on prices equals
slightly more than one after 12 quarters. The mean
lag for the specification is 5.91 quarters, which is
significantly different from the 10.54-quarter mean lag
obtained for the 1955-69 period.
Chart 1 portrays the results from the left- and
right-hand columns of table 2 and indicates that
prices apparently responded more rapidly to changes
in money during the 1970s than previously. Why did
this happen and what does it imply in terms of for­
mulating a policy to combat inflation?

Theoretical Rationale for Lags
Questions about the lag between prices and money
can be analyzed within the framework of information
and search theory.6 To facilitate an understanding of
lags and of the reasons they change, this article de­
velops a theory of lag determination.7
6Most of the literature on information and search theory is in
the context of labor markets. For a survey, see Steven A.
Lippman and John J. McCall, “ The Economics of Job
Search: A Survey,” Economic Inquiry (June and September
1976), pp. 155-89, 347-68. For a discussion of the moneyprice lag within the context of rational expectations, see
Bennett T. McCallum, “ Price Level Adjustments and the
Rational Expectations Approach to Macroeconomic Stabiliza-




i

i

i

i
15

i

i

i
20

Consider a typical firm that is a price-setter in an
economic environment in which information regarding equilibrium prices and quantities is costly to ob­
tain on both sides of the market.8 Firms do not pos­
sess full information about the prices or the quality
of their competitors’ products. Similarly, customers
do not possess full information about the prices that
all sellers are charging. Firms must determine whether
a change in demand for their products is caused by a
switch in consumer preferences or by a general shift
in aggregate demand. Moreover, they have to decide
whether such a shift is permanent or temporary.
For purposes of illustration, assume that the typical
firm obtains information about the demand for its
product by observing its sales at the current “posted”
price. Given the fact that the firm possesses accumu­
lated information on quantities sold at a given price
and assuming that the firm knows its own cost struc­
ture, it will eventually learn which price is optimal
for its operations.
tion Policy,” Journal of M oney, Credit and Banking (N ovem ­
ber 1978), pp. 418-36.
7Although the economics of information and search is not neces­
sarily a theory of lag determination, this is a common implica­
tion of the analysis, as it is usually applied.
8The classic article which develops this point is Kenneth J.
Arrow, “ Toward a Theory of Price Adjustment,” in Moses
Abramovitz, ed., The Allocation of Economic Resources (Stan­
ford: Stanford University Press, 1959), pp. 41-51.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BAN K O F ST. L O U IS

Figure 1

E cono m ics of the Firm F a cin g U n ce rtain Dem and

OCTOBER

1980

riod, the firm realizes sales of Q, at price P0; will it
change its price? If demand shifts so that Qi is the
mean of the new distribution, the profit-maximizing
price would be Pi (and the distribution as drawn
with respect to Pi will be slightly to the right of Q0).9
However, the firm will not change its price to Pi
unless its subjective assessment of the distribution
has shifted accordingly; that is, the firm will change
its price to Pi only if the solid line shifts to coincide
with the Qi distribution (drawn with respect to P0).
In the absence of other information, it is reasonable
to assume that the firm’s subjective distribution will
shift only slightly with a single observation, depending
on past experience. Continued sales around Qi for a
number of periods, however, would eventually shift
the subjective distribution so that it would be cen­
tered over Qj. Furthermore, the speed with which
the firm will move to Pi depends on the nature of
the distribution around Q,. If sales are distributed
narrowly around Qi, the firm will have greater confi­
dence in the new distribution than if sales are dis­
tributed broadly. Over an extended period of time,
the magnitude of price response will be the same
but the speed of response will vary.

firm. If costs and demand are known perfectly, P0 and
Q0 represent the profit-maximizing price and quantity.
More realistically, perhaps, the demand curve can be
viewed as the average rate of sales for given prices
based on experience, with some “normally expected”
variation around this average. For the sake of exposi­
tion, this demand curve is shown in the top half of fig­
ure 1 as a band rather than a line, with the additional
assumption being made that quantity sold at a par­
ticular price is distributed normally about the mean.
The bottom half of figure 1 summarizes the nature
of this demand curve in terms of a probability distri­
bution. The solid line in the bottom half of figure 1
is a subjectively determined distribution that is based
on sales experience, as well as other informational
factors, when the price of the product is equal to P0.
Each additional observation of quantity sold at P0
will affect the firm’s assessment of the nature of the
distribution it faces. Suppose that, in a particular pe­



Even with a new subjective distribution, the firm
will not immediately change its price. The fact that
the process of adjusting price is costly will influence
the firm’s decision to change price. Changing price
tags, making up new price lists, notifying salesmen,
and/or reprogramming computers all involve costs.
In addition, because firms do not know precisely what
their competitors will do, a premature decision to in­
crease price could result in a loss of customers. There
is also a possible loss of customer goodwill if a firm
changes price frequently, thereby shifting additional
search costs to consumers. The change in sales must
be both sufficiently large and perceived as relatively
permanent before the firm will adjust its price.

The Money-Price Lag in an
Aggregate Context
In a growing economy, firms will experience in­
creasing sales over time and/or the number of firms
will change. However, expansion of quantities sold
need not imply rising prices. Prices will rise only if
aggregate demand is shifting outward more rapidly
9Note that nominal resource costs are assumed to be unchanged.
In a general inflation, resource costs will also rise. The focus
here is on the firm’s response to a shift in aggregate demand.
Recognition of such a shift before resource costs increase
represents exploitable profit opportunities for the firm.

7

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BAN K O F ST. L O U IS

than aggregate supply (which can be interpreted as
a “suitable” aggregation of individual firms’ marginal
cost curves). If the position of the demand curve is
dominated by movements in the stock of money,
firms’ assessments of demand will depend on their
expectations of monetary growth.1
0
This reinterpretation of the money-price lag in an
aggregate context can be illustrated in terms of figure
1. Q0 represents an average level of sales for a given
planning period and is associated with a given rate
of monetary growth. The price will equal P0 if this
expected monetary growth is realized.1 However, if
1
the rate of monetary growth is higher than expected,
sales averaging Qi ( at price P0) could be consistently
realized. Firms will have to determine whether this
change in monetary growth is permanent or tempo­
rary. Ultimately, firms must decide whether a price
change is necessary. As explained earlier, a change
in monetary growth will not necessarily lead to an
immediate pricing response by firms. Profit-maximiz­
ing considerations will still determine whether the
decision to change price should be made immediately
or postponed until further information is obtained.
Reinterpretation of the analysis demonstrates how
additional information influences the pricing process.
Firms derive information about the state of demand
by observing their sales. In an aggregate context,
however, some connection between monetary growth
and firms’ sales will also apply. For example, if firms
have observed a close relation between sales and
monetary growth, their subjective distributions might
shift significantly in anticipation of a change in mone­
tary growth. In other words, firms’ prices might be
changed in anticipation of an increase in sales.1 In­
2
formation about changes in monetary growth will
reduce the lagged impact of money on prices. The
whole process of determining price changes involves
both sides of the market. If firms’ customers have
similar perceptions about monetary growth, they will
expect prices to change, and firms’ loss of customer
goodwill, as a result of changing prices sooner, will be
reduced.
10See Leonall C. Andersen and Jerry L. Jordan, “ Monetary and
Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their Relative Importance in
Economic Stabilization,” this Review (November 1968), pp.
11-24.
11Different rates of expected monetary growth will, of course,
imply different P0 but costs will also be different so that
s,
Qo need not differ. The emphasis here, however, is on the
decision to change price.
12See Charles Pigott, “ Expectations, Money, and the Forecast­
ing of Inflation,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Economic Review (Spring 1980), pp. 30-49.


http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
8
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

OCTOBER

1980

A Suggested Explanation of the
Statistical Results
The analysis suggests that when sales deviate from
expected levels, price changes will eventually result.
The length of the time interval between sales devia­
tions and price changes will depend on the firm’s per­
ception that demand has shifted. This perception
is conditioned by (1 ) the past history of inflation
and monetary growth and (2 ) the distribution of re­
cently observed deviations.
First, as shown by the results summarized in table
2, firms and their customers have developed a greater
sensitivity to inflation and monetary growth during
the 1970s. During the 1955-69 period, the response
of prices to money was quite slow because the early
part of the period was dominated by relatively slow
inflation. As a result, during the latter part of the
period, there was a tendency to consider higher rates
of inflation and monetary growth as temporary.1
3
During the 1970s, however, economic units began
placing more emphasis on recent experience when
forming their expectations; they learned from their
past errors.
Second, during the 1970s, the nature of the distribu­
tion of deviations of money growth from what was
expected ( and, consequently, deviations of sales from
what was expected) appears to have changed con­
siderably. Some summary statistics are presented in
table 3. Quarter-to-quarter rates of change are ex­
amined for 20- and 12-quarter periods during the full
1955-79 period. These measures are examined to de­
termine if the pattern of monetary growth has changed
from the pattern observed for 1955-69.
The summary statistics that appear at the bottom
of table 3 indicate that the results are mixed. The
mean standard deviation, for example, changed little
between the 1955-69 and the 1970-79 periods. How­
ever, the standard deviation of the means dropped
sharply in the latter period, suggesting that the vari­
ation in monetary growth became more regular in
the 1970s. This movement toward regularity suggests
— although it does not necessarily imply — greater
predictability. Nonetheless, tentative evidence appears
to support the notion that monetary growth became
more predictable in the 1970s.1
4
13This has been labeled the “ retum-to-normality” hypothesis.
For discussion and statistical results, see David H. Resler,
“ The Formation of Inflation Expectations,” this Review
(April 1980), pp. 2-12.
14The pattern of mohetary growth would have to be examined
more thoroughly, and probably in conjunction with a formal

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BAN K O F ST. L O U IS

OCTOBER

1980

Table 3
Summary of Monetary Growth: 1955-1979
12-quarter periods

20-quarter periods

Mean

Standard
deviation

Mean

Standard
deviation

3.14

1.88

2.23

1.54

IV /5 6

2.56

1.95

1.88

1.50

IV /5 7

1.54

1.66

1.31

1.78

I V / 58

1.74

1.97

1.33

2.09

IV /5 9

1.85

2.36

1.74

2.77

IV /6 0

1.34

2.41

1.68

3.01

IV /61

1.71

2.47

2.06

2.59

I V / 62

1.92

2.47

1.34

2.20

I V / 63

2.38

2.24

2.65

1.45

IV /6 4

2.42

2.34

3.43

1.65

End of
period
IV /5 5

I V / 65

3.31

1.81

4.11

1.55

IV /6 6

3.49

2.17

3.86

2.47

IV /6 7

4.28

2.38

4.55

2.87

5.65

3.06

IV /6 8

5.01

2.66

IV /6 9

4.95

2.79

5.48

2.77

IV /7 0

5.15

2.71

5.42

2.15

IV /7 1

5.59

2.51

5.38

2.52

IV /7 2

6.25

2.38

6.37

2.45

IV /7 3

6.05

2.45

6.92

2.15

IV /7 4

5.94

2.24

6.07

2.31

IV /7 5

6.12

2.24

5.50

2.18

IV /7 6

5.85

2.12

5.18

1.71

IV /7 7

6.09

2.14

6.25

2.05

I V / 78

6.31

2.09

7.11

1.92

IV /7 9

6.89

2.20

7.97

1.80

M ean (19 5 5 -6 9)

2.78

2.24

2.89

2.22

Mean (19 7 0 -7 9)

6.02

2.31

6.22

2.12

Standard deviation
(19 5 5 -6 9)

1.21

1.51

Standard deviation
(19 7 0 -7 9)

.46

.90

prediction model, before more definitive conclusions could
be developed. Expectations formation is a complex process
and the modeling o f this process is probably still in its in­
fancy. More refined explanations of the shortening of the lag




await further research. See, however, Robert J. Barro,
“ Unanticipated Money, Output, and the Price Level in the
United States,” Journal o f Political Economy (August 1978),
pp. 549-80.

9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BANK O F ST. L O U IS

Implications of the Analysis
The lag in the effect of money on prices appears
to have shortened during the 1970s, but the reasons
for this contraction are unclear. One interpretation is
that recent experience now receives more weight in
the formation of expectations. Such a situation would
be beneficial for the policymaker, because it indicates
that there is less inertia to be overcome in designing
a policy to reduce inflation. On the other hand, a
policy of short-run economic stimulus can give rise to
a burst of inflation expectations, with little realized
positive effect on output.
A second interpretation of the shortened lag be­

Digitized for 10
FRASER


OCTOBER

1980

tween money and prices is that it occurred because of
the pattern of monetary growth. Although conclusions
about the nature of the distribution of realized mone­
tary growth are not definite, this interpretation implies
that a steady reduction in monetary growth will re­
sult in less output loss than an erratic reduction. If
both expected and actual monetary growth can be
reduced simultaneously, the effect on output need
not be severe or prolonged.15
15Past relationships based on an environment of uncertainty
and continuing deviation of expected and realized monetary
growth are misleading in assessing the costs of reducing
inflation. See Laurence H. Meyer and Robert H. Rasche, “ On
the Costs and Renefits of Anti-Inflation Policies,” this Review
(February 1980), pp. 3-14.

Our “Shrinking” Farmland: Mirage
or Potential Crisis?
C L IF T O N B . L U T T R E L L

K a CH year, more American farmland is being con­
verted to nonfarm uses such as highways, houses, air­
ports, and shopping centers. This development has
engendered fear that the decline in farmland will
eventually produce a severe crisis for U.S. food
production.
A recent study, in which 11 U.S. government agen­
cies participated, stated: “Every day in the United
States, four square miles of our nation’s prime farm
lands are shifted to uses other than agriculture. The
thief is urban sprawl. . . . Ten years from now,
Americans could be as concerned over the loss of the
nation’s prime and important farm lands as they are
today over shortages of oil and gasoline.” 1
Leading proponents of the shrinking farmland thesis
contend that decisions to convert agricultural land to
1W here Have the Farmlands Gone? (Washington, D .C.: Na­
tional Agricultural Land Studies, September 1979), pp. 1-2.
Similar views were expressed in The Farm and The City (The
American Assembly, Columbia University, April 10-13, 1980),
and in Erick P. Eckholm, Losing Ground: Environmental
Stress and W orld Food Prospects (N ew York: W . W . Norton
and Company, Inc., 1976), pp. 183-86.




nonagricultural uses should be transferred from the
private to the public sector. Michael Brewer states:
“Each choice [by individual farmers to sell farmland
to developers] may be sensible in its own context.
But, collectively, they reduce the country’s capacity
to produce food, fiber, and wood.” He argues: “The
first step is to ‘find out’ . . . what tools are available
to local, state and Federal governments to deal with
it.”2 Lester Brown concludes: “ . . . it [cropland] can
be protected from competing nonfarm demands only
through land use planning.”3
In contrast to these views, this article asserts that
the arguments for social planning of land use are
erroneous. First, there is no evidence that the quan­
tity of cropland is shrinking or that shortages of food
are imminent. Furthermore, even if the alleged prob­
lem did exist, there is no evidence that it could be
solved more efficiently by social planning than by
market participants.
2W here Have the Farmlands Gone?, p. 6.
3lbid., p. 14.

11

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BAN K O F ST. L O U IS

Some Arguments for Social Land Use Planning
A num ber o f individuals and groups have expressed
con cern about the quantity o f prim e farm land that is
bein g diverted from agricultural uses. Secretary o f
A griculture B ob Bergland stated: “ Failure to protect
our agriculture and the natural resources on w h ich it
depen ds w ill pu t us on a collision course w ith dis­
aster.” 1 F orm er Secretary o f Agriculture Earl Butz
w arned the nation that the loss o f farm land to urban­
ization uses cou ld spell trouble fo r our fo o d supplies:
“ I f U S D A ’s projections h old true, the consequences
o f failure to stem the shrinkage o f U.S. farm land w ill
b e om inous for the Am erican econ om y.” 2 T h e A m eri­
can Lan d Forum , in calling for action to protect farm
lands from further loss, stated:
. . . decisions about
agricultural lands are actually bein g m ade now , at a
tim e w hen the crucial im portance o f the resource is
practically invisible to the average citizen.” 3 In ad di­
tion to their con cern for fo o d production, critics o f
cro p land conversion to urban uses see other social
costs, including a degraded environm ent, im paired
w ater quality, lost w ildlife habitat, and dim inished
beauty o f landscapes.4 D av id Berry and Thom as Plaut
likew ise consider the loss o f scen ic qualities an ad di­
tional cost o f urbanization o f farm land.5
Bupert C u d er stated: “ M any otherw ise politically
aggressive Am ericans seem to ‘clam u p,’ look the other
w ay, or change the subject w henever it’s suggested
that the p u b lic’s stake in private land use decisions
has b een inadequately protected.
H asn’t the tim e com e for a com prehensive effort b y
local governm ents, aided b y state and Federal agen ­
cies, to preserve som e o f these traditions, in a d em o­
cratic w ay, through the use o f local land use plans
ap proved b y local p eop le?” 6
1W here Have the Farmlands Gone? (Washington, D.C.:
National Agricultural Land Studies, September 1979),
p. 3.
2Earl Butz, “ An Economic Analysis: U.S. Farmland
Shrinking,” N ew York Journal of Commerce (O ctober
16, 1979).
3W here Have the Farmlands Gone? p. 14.
*lbid., p. 10.
5David Berry and Thomas Plaut, “Retaining Agricultural
Activities Under Urban Pressure: A Review of Land Use
Conflicts and Policies,” in Policy Sciences ( Amsterdam,
Elseview Publishing Company, 1978), p. 160.

OCTOBER

1980

offset by other factors of production, a constant or
rising demand for food coupled with a declining quan­
tity of prime cropland would lead to declining farm
production and rising farm commodity and food prices
relative to prices of other products. Finally, if food is
becoming more scarce relative to nonfood products,
given a relatively inelastic demand for food (a one
percent change in the supply of farm products results
in a larger than one percent change in price), a ris­
ing proportion of disposable personal income (per­
sonal income after taxes) would be spent on food.
In other words, with a fixed relationship between land
and farm production, a reduction in the real quantity
of cropland with a constant or rising demand for food
leads to rising farm product and food prices, higher
real food costs, and a smaller percent of personal
income available for nonfood purchases. Although, all
of the above would be implied if a shrinking farmland
crisis actually existed, none of these events is consis­
tent with the data.

Quantity of Cropland Difficult to Measure
As Theodore W. Schultz noted, economic analysis
of land is not a simple matter. “Land as an economic
variable is exceedingly hard to get at. . . . The fact
that land is open and aboveboard, physical and con­
crete, and legally divided into neat, carefully de­
scribed parcels or lots . . . does not help one deter­
mine the supply of land.”4
In the early 1800s, economists such as Thomas Malthus and David Bicardo considered the contribution
of land to food production to be relatively fixed and
concluded that the real value of food would inevitably
rise along with population growth, eventually neces­
sitating the use of poorer land, more machines, and
more labor to produce additional food. Consequently,
food prices and rent would rise relative to other
prices.5 While this view recognized that cropland did
not refer to a fixed number of acres, the potential
real output of the land was assumed to be predeter­
mined and relatively fixed.8 It is now recognized that

eW here Have the Farmlands Gone? p. 20.

Implications of “Shrinking Farmland Problem”
Several implications are immediately suggested by
claims that there is a shrinking farmland crisis. First,
and most obvious, is the contention that the quantity
of farmland is declining. Second, if the amount of such
land actually is declining, this fact should be reflected
in the relative price of farm products and food. Unless
Digitized for 12
FRASER


4Theodore W . Schultz, The Economic Organization of Agri­
culture (N ew York: McGraw Hill Book Company, Inc., 1953),
p. 145.
5David Ricardo, The Principles of Political Economy and Tax­
ation, ed. Ernest Rhys (N ew York: E. P. Dutton and Co.,
Inc., 1948), p. 280; and Thomas Robert Malthus, On Popu­
lation (N ew York: The Modern Libraiy, published by Ran­
dom House, 1960), pp. 12, 13, 32, and 33.
6David Ricardo, The Principles of Political Economy and Tax­
ation, pp. 80-81. For a discussion of classical views, see
Harry G. Johnson, Theory of Income Distribution (London:
Gray-Mills Publishing Ltd., 1973), p. 74.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BANK O F ST. LO U IS

OCTOBER

1980

Table 1
Total U.S. Land Area, Farmland, Cropland, and Crop Yields
Millions of acres*
Date

Total land

Land in farms

Cropland
harvested

Yield per acre
1967 = 100

1910

1,934

879

317

56

1920

1,934

956

351

61

1930

1,934

990

360

53

1940

1,934

1,065

331

62

1950

1,934

1,161

336

69

1959

2,314

1,124

317

85

1964

2,314

1,110

292

95

1969

2,314

1,063

286

106

1974

2,316

1,017

322

104

1979

2,316

1,049

337

130

"Includes Alaska and Hawaii, beginning with 1959.
Source: Statistical Abstract of the United States (Washington, D .C.: U.S. Department of
Commerce, Bureau of the Census, 1979) 100th ed., p. 6; Agricultural Statistics
(Washington, D .C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture), 1978, p. 419; 1979, p. 417;
Changes in Farm Production and Efficiency (Washington, D .C.: U.S. Department
of Agriculture, 1978), p. 19; Agricultural Outlook (Washington, D .C.; U.S. Depart­
ment of Agriculture); Crop Production, 1979 Annual Survey (Washington, D.C.:
U.S. Department of Agriculture, January 1980).

the surface area that can be used for crops is more
variable than Malthus and Ricardo thought and that
output per unit of surface area is likewise more
variable.

Acres of Cropland Variable but Increasing
Despite the difficulty of estimating the amount of
cropland, it is now evident that the amount is not
fixed. Rather, the quantity actually in use at any
given time depends on a number of factors.
Because new technology reduces land development
costs and/or increases crop yields, thus providing
favorable returns on the investment, land areas cur­
rently used for other purposes can be developed into
profitable cropland. As Martin Bailey noted: “ . . .
mountainous land good only for grazing could be
leveled and made arable, and marshy lands, lake
bottom and the fringes of the ocean could be filled to
make arable land.”7 Examples of such conversion in
the U.S. include the Imperial Valley in California,
which was irrigated and developed into cropland,
7Martin J. Bailey, National Income and The Price Level ( New
York: McGraw Hill Book Company, Inc., 1962), p. 111.




and the Obion River Valley in Tennessee, much of
which was developed into cropland through con­
struction of a drainage system. Further, although
there is a vast amount of acreage (such as grazing,
range, or forest land) that is not currently used for
cropland at present prices, this acreage could be con­
verted to crop production within a short period of
time if it was profitable to do so. If the net return on
an acre of land is greater when used for crop produc­
tion than when used for grazing, it will be used
for crops. Conversely, if the expected net return on
land is greater when it is used for purposes such as
grazing, forestry, etc., the land will be used for these
purposes.
As shown in table 1, only a small portion of the
U.S. land area is currently used for crops. Of the 2.3
billion acres of land in the nation, only about 40 per­
cent is farmland and less than one third of this farm­
land has been actually used for crop production.
Hence, a large amount of land area is available for
conversion to or from crop production.
Data on cropland harvested indicate that sizable
changes have occurred during the past 80 years in
terms of the land area used for crop production. Acres

13

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BANK O F ST. L O U IS

OCTOBER

This relative increase in farm prices provided farmers
with sufficient incentive to convert additional land
to crop production.

Table 2
Changes in Cropland Harvested and
Selected Prices (Annual Rates)
1950-69

1969-79

-0 .8

1.7

Prices received by farmers

0.2

8.5

Price of industrial commodities

1.6

8.3

G NP price deflator

2.6

6.7

Consumer price index (all items)

2.2

7.1

Producer price index
(finished goods)

1.6

7.3

Acres harvested

Source: Economic Report of the President (Washington,
D.C.: United States Government Printing Office,
1980), pp. 208, 259, 265, 268, 312; Changes in
Farm Production and Efficiency, (Washington,
D .C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture, 1978), p. 19.

harvested rose from 317 million in 1910 to a peak of
360 million in 1930. By 1969, acres harvested had de­
clined to 286 million but increased again in the 1970s
and rose to 337 million in 1979. Although government
production control and crop diversion programs re­
duced the acreage of some crops harvested from 1934
through 1974, the effectiveness of these programs in
terms of total crops harvested can be overemphasized
since production of uncontrolled crops on diverted
acres was permitted in most years. Furthermore, the
impact of these production controls has been sharply
reduced since 1969.
The change in acres of crops harvested has been
positively correlated with the change in farm product
prices relative to other prices. For example, when the
cropland acreage was declining (0.8 percent per year
during the two decades, 1950-69), the index of prices
received by farmers declined relative to other prices
(table 2 ). During this same period, farm commodity
prices rose only 0.2 percent per year — 1.4 percentage
points less per year than the prices of industrial com­
modities or the producers price index, 2 percentage
points less than the consumer price index, and 2.4
percentage points less than the GNP price deflator.
During 1969-79, however, when the number of acres
of crops harvested was rising, prices received by
farmers rose at a slightly faster rate than most other
prices. For example, during the 1969-79 decade, farm
prices rose at an annual rate of 8.5 percent per year,
compared with 8.3 percent for industrial commodities
and less than 8 percent for each of the other series.

http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
14
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

1980

The increase in farm product prices relative to other
prices during 1969-79 is not an indication of potential
famine either in the U.S. or abroad. Bather, it repre­
sents a rise in export demand for U.S. farm products,
attributable primarily to a gradual reduction in for­
eign trade restrictions ( that began prior to W orld War
II) and to the large volume of U.S. currency accumu­
lations abroad (resulting from U.S. petroleum imports
following the sharp increase in petroleum prices).8 The
U.S. farm sector, having a comparative advantage in
production of farm products (it is relatively cheaper
in terms of resources used to produce farm products
in the U.S. than in other countries), exported an in­
creasing proportion of total farm output.

Yields Per Acre Rising
While output per acre of cropland varies from year
to year as a result of weather and other short-run
factors, the sharp increases in crop yields over the
longer run indicate that yields are sensitive to other
factors of production such as technology and prices.
The development of new technology and/or a change
in the price of crops relative to the cost of farm inputs
leads to a change in output per acre. For example,
new technology that reduces the real cost of ferti­
lizers, improves insect and plant disease control, and
provides improved seeds increases output per acre
and, consequently, has the same impact on output as
an increase in the acreage of farmland. In essence,
the increase in farmland “quality” produces the same
result as an increase in quantity. Similarly, an increase
in the price of crops relative to the returns on land
from alternative uses provides farmers with incentive
for using more yield-increasing factors (e.g., greater
quantities of fertilizer) per acre, as well as for using
more acres of land for crop production. With the
increase in the value of farm products in the early
1970s as a result of rising foreign demand, greater
quantities of yield-increasing inputs were added to
cropland; consequently, yields increased as did the
number of acres harvested.
The use of yield-increasing factors caused average
com yields to rise from 70 bushels per acre in the
three years, 1964-66, to 100 bushels per acre in 197779, despite the increase in acres harvested during the
8See Clifton B. Luttrell, “ Rising Farm Exports and Interna­
tional Trade Policies,” this Review (July 1979), pp. 3-10.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BANK O F ST. LO U IS

OCTOBER

1980

Table 3
Rates of Change of Selected Prices, Per Capita Personal Income, Percent of
Personal Income Spent on Food, and Percent of Farm Commodity Sales Exported
and Imported
1950-60

1960-70

1970-79

1950-79

Prices — rate of change:
Received by farm ers (U S D A )1

-0 .8

1.5

9.1

3.0

Food ( C P I) i

1.7

2.7

8.2

4.0

All com modities less food ( C P I) 1

1.4

1.9

6.3

3.1

All services ( C P I) 1

3.6

3.8

7.6

4.9

Industrial commodities ( P P I) 1

2.0

1.4

8.9

3.9

Disposable personal income per capita
(rate of c h a n g e )2

3.6

5.6

9.2

6.0

Percent spent on: total food2

22.4 — 20.2

20.2 — 17.3

17.3 — 16.6

22.4 — 16.6

17.8 — 16.1

1 6 .1 — 13.4

13.4 — 12.5

17.8 — 12.5

Exported3

10.1 — 14.1

14.1 — 14.6

14.6 — 24.8

10.1 — 24.8

Imported3

14.0 — 11.1

11.1 — 11.4

11.4 — 12.6

14.0 — 12.6

food at home2
Percent of total farm commodity sales:

iEconomic Report of the President (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979), pp. 240, 248, 290; Eco­
nomic Indicators (Washington, D .C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture, 1980); CPI (Consumer Price Index); and PPI
(Producer Price Index).
2National Food Review (Washington, D .C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture, Winter 1980), pp. 6, 56; and Economic
Indicators.
3Economic Report of the President (Washington, D .C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1979), pp. 287 and 296; U.S. Foreign
Agricultural Trade Statistical Report (Washington, D .C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture, 1970), p. 2; Agricultural Outlook
(Washington, D .C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture).

latter period.9 As shown in table 1, the trend rise in
crop yields is not limited to com . Yields of all crop­
land harvested rose from an average index of 83 in
1957-59 to 123 in 1977-79, an increase of 48 percent.
Furthermore, there is no indication that a slowing
has occurred in the trend growth of crop yields. From
1967-69 to 1977-79, crop production per acre rose at
a 1.7 percent rate, well above the 1.1 percent rate of
increase from 1910 to 1969.1
0
9Agricultural Statistics (Washington, D .C.: U.S. Department
of Agriculture, 1979), p. 30; and Agricultural Outlook (W ash­
ington, D .C .: U.S. Department o f Agriculture, May 1980),
p. 33.
10A rate of yield growth higher than that of 1969-79 was
realized only in the decade of 1950-60, when output per
acre rose at a 2.6 percent rate. During the 1950-60 decade,
however, the number of acres harvested declined sharply
indicating that less fertile acres were taken out of crop
production.
A number of recent studies point to a possible decline in
the rate of growth in crop yields in the years ahead. Agrtcultural Production Efficiency (Washington, D .C .: National
Academy of Sciences, 1975), p. 195. This study concluded
that biological realities suggest a slowing of the rate of in­
crease in productivity for most crops. Yoa-chi Lu, Philip Cline,
and Leroy Quance, Prospects for Productivity Growth in U.S.
Agriculture (Washington, D .C.: U.S. Department of Agri-




Shrinkage Not Indicated b y Relative
Prices of Food
During the period, 1950-79, farm product prices
rose at a slower rate than other major price series
and only half as fast as disposable personal income
(table 3 ). Consequently, the proportion of disposable
personal income spent on food declined from 22.4 per­
cent in 1950 to 16.6 percent in 1979.
During the more recent decade, 1970-79, farm prod­
uct prices rose somewhat faster than prices of most
nonfarm products. Farm prices rose at a 9.1 percent
rate, slightly faster than the 8.9 percent rate for in­
culture, September 1979). The authors expressed doubt that
agricultural productivity growth through the year 2000 will
equal the historical rate unless research and extension invest­
ment increase and unprecedented technologies develop.
On the other hand, Glen L. Johnson contends that agri­
culture has a high long-run supply elasticity in The Over­
production Trap in Agriculture, ed. Glen L. Johnson and
Leroy Quance (Baltimore: The John Hopkins University
Press, 1972), pp. 20 and 183. Furthermore, he argues that
if demand (fo r farm products) was doubled or tripled, we
would have so much money invested in land that earnings
would not cover acquisition costs.

15

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BANK O F ST. L O U IS

OCTOBER

1980

Table 4
Rates of Change of Specified Prices, Per Capita Personal
Income, Percent of Personal Income Spent on Food,
and Percent of Farm Commodity Sales Exported and Imported
in the First and Second Half of the 1970s
1970-75

1975-79

Prices — rate of change:
Received by farmers (U S D A )

11.0

6.8

Food (C P I)

8.8

7.5

All com modities less food (C P I)

5.8

7.0

All services (C P I)

6.5

8.9

Industrial com modities (P P I)

9.3

8.3

8.7

9.7

17.3 — 17.0

17.0 — 16.6

13.4 — 13.0

13.0 — 12.5

Disposable personal income per capita
(rate of change)
Percent spent on: total food
food at home
Percent of total farm commodity sales:
Exported

14.6 — 25.2

25.2 — 24.8

Imported

11.4 — 10.6

10.6 — 12.6

dustrial commodities, and well above the rate of in­
crease for all commodities (less food ) and for all
services. The relative increase in farm product prices
during this decade, however, was related to a sharp
increase in demand for U.S. farm products, primarily
for export, rather than to a shrinkage in cropland.
(There is no evidence that farmland conversion to
urban uses was greater in 1970-79 than in any other
post-World War II decade.) Exports started rising in
the 1950s, rose moderately in the 1960s, and acceler­
ated sharply in the 1970s. For instance the rate of
increase was relatively low in the 1950s and the 1960s,
and exports totaled only 14.6 percent of sales in 1970.
However, exports accelerated from 14.6 percent of
total sales in 1970 to 25.2 percent in 1975 (table 4 ).
Furthermore, sharp increases in farm commodity ex­
ports were not offset by rising imports of farm com­
modities. Farm commodity imports declined from 11.4
to 10.6 percent of sales of farm products during the
period.
By 1975, farm commodity exports as a percent of
sales had leveled off, and farm commodity prices be­
gan to decline again relative to other prices (table
4 ). From 1975 to 1979, farm commodity prices rose
at the rate of 6.8 percent, 2.1 percentage points less
than the rate of increase in the price of all services
and 1.5 percentage points less than the price of in­
dustrial commodities. The price of food, which had

16


increased at about the same rate as disposable per­
sonal income in the first half of the 1970s, rose 2.2
percentage points slower in the second half of the
decade than did disposable personal income.
As indicated earlier, much of the increase in farm
exports since the mid-1950s can be attributed to a
gradual reduction in foreign trade restrictions, which
had been almost prohibitive following the SmootHawley Tariff Act of 1930. A number of major reduc­
tions in average ad valorem rates have been nego­
tiated since the 1947 General Agreement on Tariffs
and Trade; numerous studies show that these reduc­
tions have a major impact on trade.1 However, re­
1
ductions in tariff duties do not increase trade imme­
diately, as evidenced by the gradual rise in exports
during the 1950s and 1960s. Part of the sharp increase
in exports during the early 1970s may be attributed
to the implementation of monopolistic petroleum pol­
icies by the OPEC nations, which resulted in a sharp
increase in dollar accumulations abroad and the dol­
lar’s reduced value in terms of foreign currencies.
Despite the accelerating export demand for U.S.
farm products, however, the farm sector concurrently
produced enough food to maintain relatively stable
11See Clifton B. Luttrell, “ Rising Farm Exports and Interna­
tional Trade Policies,” pp. 6-7.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BANK O F ST. L O U IS

real prices for food in the U.S., further reducing the
proportion of disposable personal income spent on
food.

Little Basis for Cropland Preservation Plans
Considering the facts that cropland acreage is not
shrinking, crop yields have increased, and food costs
as a percent of personal income have declined, alle­
gations of a “shrinking” farmland appear to be un­
founded. Consequently, the arguments for develop­
ing comprehensive social plans to convert cropland to
urban uses have little validity. Moreover, it is impor­
tant to note that, even if the claims of reduced farm­
land had been substantiated, proponents of social
cropland control have not made a convincing case for
such action. There are certain circumstances that
might call for social land use planning: (1 ) if farmers
are not price conscious, i.e., they are not responsive
to current or expected future crop prices since they
do not recognize the real value of prime cropland;
(2 ) if farmland prices do not reflect the true value of
the product of the land; and (3 ) if social planners’
knowledge about future land values is superior to that
of current landowners and developers.
Existing evidence does not corroborate the validity
of these circumstances. Research clearly indicates that
farmers are highly responsive to current and expected
future prices.12 They sell their land to urban devel­
opers because its value is greater if used for urbaniza­
tion purposes than for cropland ( cropland value being
determined by the current and expected future prices
of the crops grown on it). When the value of land
converted to urban use exceeds the value obtained
from farming, the farm owner, land developer, and
the general public will profit from conversion.1 In
3
the absence of harmful neighborhood effects (hidden
costs), the costs and benefits of such shifts are care­
fully assessed by the transacting parties. In other
words, the cost to the individual and to society is the
foregone value of the land’s contribution to farm out­
put. Unless the gain in the new use exceeds the loss,
the individuals involved would have no incentive for
making the change.
12See Holbrook Working, “ The Theory of Price of Storage,” in
Selected Writing of Holbrook Working, ed. Dana Kellerman
(Board of Trade of the City of Chicago, 1977), pp. 28-30;
Marc Nerlove, The Dynamics of Supply: Estimation of Farm­
ers’ Response to Price (Baltimore: The John Hopkins Press,
1958), pp. 186-235; and Zvi Griliches, “ Estimates of the
Aggregate U.S. Farm Supply Function,” Journal of Farm
Economics (M ay 1960), p. 282-93.
13For a discussion, see Neil A. Stevens, “ Rising Farmland Prices
and Falling Farm Earnings: Is Agriculture in Trouble?” this
Review (M ay 1978), p. 16.




OCTOBER

1980

The second argument for social planning — that
prices alone do not reflect the true value of the prod­
uct — implies that neighborhood effects are an impor­
tant factor. Some external costs, such as reduced water
quality and impaired landscapes, have been mentioned
by the proponents of social control over cropland.
However, this argument is subjective because one can
easily visualize rural scenes that are quite the oppo­
site of the beautiful landscape ideally depicted by
advocates of social control. Cattle feeding pens, swine
producing areas, and other livestock facilities are often
sources of pollution. In addition, other “unsightly”
views associated with farming communities include
dilapidated buildings, fences, and equipment dumped
along the roadside.
In regard to water quality, most authorities contend
that both rural and urban uses may result in water
pollution. Those types of pollution that result from
farming activities include runoff from livestock hab­
itats and chemicals used for controlling crop diseases,
insects, and weeds. Allen Kneese contends that agri­
cultural chemicals present a special ( pollutants) prob­
lem “as they are delivered to streams in storm runoff
from the land and bypass waste treatment plants.”1
4
The third argument for social planning — that social
planners possess superior knowledge compared to that
of private individuals — implies that individual
farmers and urban land users distribute their resources
between the present and the future on a relatively
uninformed (o f true value) basis. In other words, indi­
vidual landowners are perceived to be somewhat
myopic in assessing the future value of cropland,
whereas social land use planners can clearly foresee
the “correct” future value of land in its various alter­
native uses. This argument fails to consider that such
vision would provide social planners with amazing
opportunities for personal investment gains so that
they would not be likely to remain “planners” when
they could become wealthy as “doers.”
Of even greater importance for the public welfare,
however, is the assumption by proponents of social
planning that such programs operate in the “public
interest” rather than in self-interest. There is little
justification for the view that self-interest is eliminated
when social groups are given monopoly power over
economic functions. As pointed out so cogently by
George Stigler, alleged market failures are not evi­
dence that social planners can provide more services
14Allen V. Kneese, The Economics of Regional W ater Quality
Management (Baltimore: The John Hopkins Press, 1964),
p. 11.

17

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BAN K O F ST. L O U IS

at reduced costs. “W e may tell the society to jump out
of the market frying pan, but we have no basis for
predicting whether it will land in the fire or a luxur­
ious bed.”15 Any impediment to the transfer of crop­
land to urban use will increase the cost of land for
housing, factories, hospitals, parking, and other uses
vital to the public well-being. There is no evidence
that social groups can more equitably resolve the
conflict between costs and benefits of land use than
can private markets.

SUMMARY
As prime farmland is converted into streets, shop­
ping centers, and residential areas, observers conclude
that the quantity of farmland is declining sharply and
that this decline should be controlled by social action.
Unobserved, however, are the less noticeable but dra­
15George F. Stigler, The Citizen and the State (Chicago: The
University o f Chicago Press, 1975), p. 113. For a further
discussion of this problem, see R. H. Coase, “ The Problem
of Social Cost,” The Journal of Law and Economics (O c­
tober 1960), pp. 1-49; and Roger Leroy Miller, Economics
Today (San Francisco: Canfield Press, 1976), pp. 615-23.


http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
18
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

OCTOBER

1980

matic increases in acres of cropland and in produc­
tion per acre. The number of acres from which crops
were harvested rose from the 1969 low point of 286
million to 337 million acres in 1979. Yields per acre
of cropland rose at a 1.1 percent rate from 1910 to
1969 and at a 1.7 percent rate during the period from
1967-69 to 1977-79.
As a consequence of the increase in acres harvested
and in yields per acre, farm product and food prices
have consistently declined relative to other prices, ex­
cept during the first half of the 1970s when export
demand rose sharply. Since 1950, consumers have
spent a declining proportion of their disposable per­
sonal income on food, even while a larger proportion
of domestic farm output was being exported.
Consequently, there is no justification for using
social action to preserve cropland as proposed by
critics of the current land market system. Further­
more, even if there was some shrinkage in cropland,
there is no evidence that the problem can be solved
more efficiently by social action than it can be in the
market place.