View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Fiscal Ease and Monetary Growth
CONTENTS

m
Page

Fiscal Ease and M onetary
G r o i v th ...........................

1

Interest Rates, 1914-1965

4

Farm Land P r ic e s ...........

9

J lHE ECONOMY has continued to expand through the sum­
mer and early fall and is operating at a high level. Monetary
growth has continued at a moderate pace, while the fiscal situa­
tion has become more expansionary. These developments prom­
ise further stimulation of aggregate demand for goods and
services.
Increased Federal borrowing and expanding business activity
appear to be putting upward pressures on interest rates. Rising
interest rates may be helping both to bring about balance be­
tween domestic saving and investment without inflationary pres­
sures and to restrain net capital outflows, one of the causes of a
chronic deficit in the balance of payments.

Monetary Developments
Money supply growth accelerated in September, after being
moderate since last winter. Bank credit has continued to expand
rapidly through the summer and early fall but at a more moder­
ate rate than during last winter. Total reserves of member banks
have changed little on balance since spring, and interest rates
have risen.
Volume 47

•

Number 10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF ST. LOUIS
P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, Mo. 63166




The money supply increased markedly from August to Septem­
ber, after growing at a 3 per cent annual rate from last November
to August. Comparatively, the money supply increased at a 4 per
cent rate from September 1962 to November 1964 and at a 2 per
cent average annual rate from 1951 to 1962.

M o n e y S u p p ly
Billions of

Weekly A ve rage s of Daily Figures
Dollars ____________ Seasonally Adjusted____________ Billions

of D ollars

Annual rates of change, four
w eeks e n d in g Se ptem ber 29,196'
from four weeks ending:
Aug. 4, 1965 + 7 . 2 %
July 7, 1965 +6.1%
June 9, 1965 + 7 .9 %
Dec.

165.1

, 1964 + 4 .0 7

vV

J

/■"
VV/
\l
V

1

\ I

I I I ! J _ U I 1 i.l -1 1 1 ! lLLL L 1 1 1 J 1_Ul iL L L L 111
J _ L L , i J_l u 111 !
J A N . FEB. M A R . APR. M A Y J U N E JULY A U G . SEPT. O C T . N O V . DEC.
Seasonal adjustment computed using 1959 through June 1965 data.
Latest data plotted: Week ending S e p te m b e r 29 ,196 5 p r e lim in a r y

This year the money supply has been influenced by
large shifts between Government demand deposits
(not a component of the money supply) and private
demand deposits (the major component of the money
supply). A large build-up in Government deposits in
M ay depressed the money supply in that month. A
large reduction in Government deposits in August
and September was a factor tending to increase the
money supply.
Bank credit expansion moderated after April as a
rapid growth in higher yielding bank loans and hold­
ings of “other” securities (mainly municipals) was fi­
nanced partly by substantial decreases in the holdings
of Government securities. Bank credit increased at a
9 per cent annual rate from April to September, com­
pared with a 12 per cent rate from November to
April and a 5 per cent rate since 1948.
Total reserves of member banks, which support
bank deposits and make bank credit expansion possi­
ble, increased steadily from January to June and sub­
sequently declined slightly. These reserves averaged
$21.8 billion in September, little changed from their
April level. Since April large net purchases of G ov­
ernment securities by the Federal Reserve, which
add to bank reserves, have been offset by gold sales
abroad and increases in currency in circulation. M em ­
ber bank borrowing from Federal Reserve Banks has
averaged about $540 million since June, up from an
average $420 million earlier this year. This greater
borrowing probably reflects the decline in nonbor­
rowed reserves, strong credit demands, and an edging
up in interest rates.
Despite little change in total reserves since April,
reserves available for private demand deposits have
risen moderately. A decline in U. S. Government
deposits and therefore a drop in the amount of re­
serves required to support these deposits provided
reserves for private deposits.
Page 2



Interest rates have risen gradually since June, re­
flecting an increase in the demand for funds relative
to the supply. Yields on long-term U. S. Government
securities rose from 4.15 per cent in early July to
4.25 per cent in late September, after remaining al­
most unchanged earlier this year. D uring the same
period yields on corporate Aaa bonds moved up from
4.46 per cent to 4.52 per cent. The three-month
Treasury bill rate rose from 3.81 per cent in early
July to 3.94 per cent in late September.
Demand for funds has increased as fiscal develop­
ments have turned more stimulative and as business
has turned to outside sources to a greater extent in
obtaining funds to finance inventory growth and
large plant and equipment expenditures.1 Public offer­
ings of securities have risen to finance the Federal
deficit and increased expenditures by state and local
governments. O n the supply side, bank credit expan­
sion has moderated, and the flow of saving has prob­
ably not grown so fast as the demand for investment
funds.2 The voluntary restriction of loans to foreign­
ers has been a factor in keeping loanable funds at
home and may have kept interest rates from rising
further.
A rise in interest rates is appropriate for an advanc­
ing economy operating near capacity and experienc­
ing an outflow of private capital which is causing a
balance-of-payments problem. The higher rates not
only reflect the tendency for planned investment to
outpace desired saving, but they also provide the
means for balancing these two flows without infla­
tionary pressures. A rise in rates—both short-term
and long-term—also encourages capital flows into the
United States from abroad or reduces capital out­
flows. Interest rates in the United States remain be­
low those of most other countries.

Fiscal Position
Government actions have become more expansion­
ary than earlier this year. The “full employment sur­
plus” has been reduced from a $7 billion annual rate
in the first half to an estimated $3 billion rate in the
second half. Barring any large changes in Govern­
ment expenditures or in tax rates, fiscal developments
1Business expenditures on plant and equipment are expected to
rise to a $53.0 billion annual rate in the fourth quarter, up
from an estimated $51.2 billion rate in the third quarter and a
$50.4 billion rate in the second quarter.
2 Gross private saving—including personal saving, undistributed
corporate profits, capital consumption allowances, and inven­
tory valuation adjustments—fell from the first to the second
quarter of this year. Personal saving as a per cent of dispos­
able income was 5 per cent in the second quarter, compared
with a 6 per cent average since 1954.

are apt to become less expansionary in the first half
of 1966, when higher social security taxes will more
than offset additional decreases in excise taxes.
For purposes of determining the impact of the bud­
get on the economy, it is desirable to separate the
effects of changed tax rates, Government expenditure
programs, and other actions of the Government affect­
ing the budget from the effect on the budget of
changing levels of economic activity. The “full em­
ployment budget” provides an estimate of what G ov­
ernment surplus or deficit would occur if the economy
were at full employment, given the prevailing set of
tax rates and spending programs. It indicates the
net effects of Government actions such as changes in
tax rates and Federal expenditure programs by as­
suming a certain level of economic activity, namely,
full employment; it abstracts from influences on the
budget which result from fluctuations in economic
activity and isolates and measures effects of changes
in policy. Fiscal developments are said to be more
expansionary the smaller the full employment surplus
or the greater the full employment deficit.

The Economy
The appropriateness of any combination of mon­
etary and fiscal policy can be judged by reference to
levels of production, employment, prices, and the con­
dition of the balance of payments.
The level of economic activity has continued to
increase during the late summer and early fall. The
U. S. balance of payments has continued to be basic­
ally a deficit problem, though there was a surplus in
the second quarter of the year.
Industrial production, buoyed by high retail sales,
rising defense expenditures, and large investment in
plant and equipment, rose rapidly during the spring
and midsummer but increased little from July to
August as steel production declined. After increasing
at an 8 per cent annual rate from January to July,
production rose at a 1.7 per cent rate from July to
August. Preliminary data suggests that production
changed little from August to September. By com­
parison, industrial production has risen at a 5 per cent
rate since 1960. The large expenditures on plant and
equipment, while helping to lift the economy toward
capacity this year, w ill add significantly to future
capacity.
The rapid increase in production this year has not
only maintained but substantially increased invento­
ries in the face of increased sales. The inventories of




all businesses rose to $116 billion in July, up $0.8
billion from June and $5 billion from last December.
Inventory build-up was especially strong in steel,
where users increased inventories from about 11 mil­
lion tons at the turn of the year to over 17 million
tons in August. It has been estimated that steel inven­
tories will decline at a $2 billion annual rate during
the fourth quarter.3 However, inventories in general
do not appear excessive relative to current sales and
new and unfilled orders.
Use of the labor force has intensified rapidly dur­
ing the past year. Payroll employment is estimated to
have grown 4 per cent, and total civilian employment,
3 per cent since last August. D uring the same time
period the number of persons of approximate working
age (18 to 64) is estimated to have increased 1.9 per
cent.
Wholesale and consumer prices have leveled off
since June, after rising rapidly earlier this year. From
January to June wholesale prices rose at a 4.3 per
cent annual rate, accelerating a rise which began in
mid-1964. Increases in the prices of farm products
and processed foods were primarily responsible for
the wholesale price rise earlier this year, but indus­
trial prices also rose. Since June a decline in the
prices of farm products has offset a slight rise in in­
dustrial and processed food prices. Consumer prices
rose at a 2.7 per cent annual rate from January to
June but have been about unchanged since midyear
as food costs have leveled and declines in the prices
of nonfood commodities have offset increases in the
price of services. Recent declines in durable goods
prices reflect cuts in excise taxes.

Conclusion
The economy continues to advance and is using its
resources more fully than in recent years. Reflecting
a leveling off of the prices of farm products and the
reductions in excise taxes, there has been a pause in
the rise of the general price indexes, which was so
marked last spring. In this context, monetary devel­
opments have continued moderately expansionary,
and the fiscal situation has become more stimulative.
Increasing interest rates accompanying these develop­
ments may be beneficial in curbing capital outflows
and in bringing about balance between saving and
investment.
3Gardner Ackley, Chairman of the Council of Economic Ad­
visers, in a speech before the American Statistical Association
in Philadelphia on September 9, 1965.

Page 3

Interest Rates, 1914-1965
In t r o d u c t io n
I n T E R E S T R A T E S play a strategic role in the econ­
omy. They represent a cost to the borrower and, as
such, may influence decisions to invest or to spend
on goods or services. They represent a return to the
saver and may influence saving decisions. To wealth
holders and to managers of investment flows, interest
rates or yields are the common denominator for eval­
uating alternative forms of holding wealth and alter­
native avenues for placing funds.
Interest rates are believed to have an effect on eco­
nomic activity. Other things equal, a rise in interest
rates has a dampening effect on investment decisions
and increases the incentive to save. Conversely, a de­
cline in interest rates is usually interpreted as expan­
sionary.
There is a great deal of uncertainty concerning
what causes interest rates to be what they are. A most
popular interpretation emphasizes the role of changes
in the supply of and demand for credit in various mar­
kets. There are questions, however, about why inter­
est rates in general reach the level they do. Issues
such as the role of productivity of capital as a basic
determinant of rates, the impact of fiscal actions of the
Government on rates, and the influence of rates in one
country on those in another have not been resolved.
There are also unanswered questions concerning why
debt instruments of different maturities have different
interest rates.
In addition to the other forces bearing on interest
rates, it is widely agreed that monetary actions have an
influence. Transactions in the Government securities
market are a chief means by which the Federal Re­
serve System conducts monetary policy.1 These trans­
actions directly affect the prices—and, hence, the
yields or interest rates—of the securities bought or sold.
They also affect interest rates through their impact on
1These transactions, called “open market operations,” add to or
reduce member bank reserves and have a major impact on the
money supply and interest rates. See Chapters III and IV of
The Federal Reserve System: Purposes and Functions (5th ed.,
Washington, D. C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Re­
serve System, 1963), which discuss instruments of monetary
regulation and the function of bank reserves.
Page 4




commercial bank credit expansion or contraction.2
Indirectly, transactions in the Government securities
market influence the prices, or interest rates, on vir­
tually all marketable securities. Other monetary ac­
tions, e.g., changes in reserve requirements and in the
discount rate, also have an effect on interest rates.
Because of the role interest rates play in our eco­
nomic system and because System actions play a part
in interest rate behavior, levels and changes in interest
rates have been used as a convenient measure of mon­
etary actions. W hen interest rates are high and rising,
analysts using this measure describe monetary policy
as restrictive; when rates are low and declining, they
say policy is easy.
The following discussion and accompanying chart
( see pages 6 and 7) summarize movements in interest
rates on marketable securities since the Federal Re­
serve System began operations in 1914. From the host
of available market rates, a major money market rate
(four- to six-month prime commercial paper until
1937 and three-month Treasury bills thereafter) and
a leading capital market rate (highest grade railway
bonds until December 1919 and highest grade corpo­
rate bonds thereafter) have been selected. Although
other rates give somewhat different results, these prob­
ably were typical of rates in the short-term and long­
term markets.
This discussion is intended as a short resume of
background information on this key financial variable,3
tracing the course of interest rates since 1914 and
noting some of the chief economic developments which
may have had an influence on rates. Although the
analysis is not designed to form the basis for conclu­
sions regarding the proper level of interest rates or
the desirability of using interest rates as a guide for
2Open market transactions add to or absorb member bank re­
serves, which affect the volume of commercial bank credit,
bank deposits, money supply, and other financial variables.
The main effect of System actions on interest rates may not be
through the increase or reduction of Federal Reserve assets
but through the resultant increase or decrease of assets held
by the commercial banks.
3For a detailed examination of rates covering a much longer
time span, see Sidney Homer, A History of Interest Rates
(New Brunswick, N. J.: Rutgers University Press, 1963).

future public policy, such a review does provide back­
ground for these important issues.
This 50-year period may be divided roughly into
three parts: before 1930, when interest rates on high­
est grade securities averaged about 5 per cent; 1930 to
1946, when, in the depression of the 1930’s and in
W orld W ar II, interest rates were low; and since 1946,
when interest rates have generally worked higher.
Today, both short- and long-term rates are still much
lower than in some extensive earlier periods and are
somewhat below the average levels of 1914 through
1929. Short-term rates averaged about the same as
long-term rates during the 1914-29 period. In re­
cent months short-term rates have been only slightly
below long-term rates.
T h e C o u r s e o f In t e r e s t R a t e s

World War t
D uring 1913 and 1914 the economy was in reces­
sion, and, although there was some quickening of
activity during 1915, the average level of output dur­
ing that year was only slightly changed from the pre­
vious two years. From early 1914 to November 1915
short-term interest rates declined, except for a period
of uncertainty and tension in the summer and early
fall of 1914, at the outbreak of W orld W ar I. The
yield on prime four- to six-month commercial paper
decreased from roughly 4.50 per cent in early 1914 to
3.45 per cent in November 1915. The yield on highest
grade railroad bonds showed little net change during
this period, averaging about 4.50 per cent.
From the end of 1915 to the late summer of 1918
a large volume of European securities were sold here,
and the U. S. Government borrowed heavily. Eco­
nomic activity, stimulated by a strong wartime de­
mand for goods, rose vigorously. Reflecting these
developments, interest rates increased, particularly
during 1917. Yields on commercial paper jumped
from 3.45 per cent in November 1915 to 6.22 per cent
in August 1918. Rates on railroad bonds went up from
about 4.50 per cent in late 1915 and 1916 to 5.41 per
cent in September 1918.
Immediately after the war interest rates declined.
Short-term rates decreased about one percentage point
from August 1918 to M a y 1919, and long-term rates
moved down about one-half of one percentage point
in late 1918. D uring this period demand for credit
slackened, and economic activity was either slowing
or at a reduced level as the war drew to a close.

to rise in the first half of 1920, reaching record levels.
Demands for credit may have slackened somewhat
with the start of the 1920-21 recession, but, if so, the
decreases were more than matched by declines in the
supply of funds, since bank credit, bank deposits, and
money grew at a slower rate.4 By July 1920 interest
rates on commercial paper averaged 8.13 per cent
and on highest grade corporate bonds averaged 6.34
per cent.
The 1920-21 recession was particularly severe. In
late 1920 short-term rates remained relatively high;
an apparent slackening in the demand for credit was
nearly matched by a contraction in outstanding com­
mercial bank credit. Interest rates declined markedly
during 1921 and drifted still lower in the first half of
1922. Commercial paper, which was yielding 8.13
per cent in the fall of 1920, was bringing only 4.13
per cent in the late summer of 1922. Interest rates on
corporate bonds fell from 6.34 per cent to 4.93 per
cent.
O n balance, from the early twenties to the end of
1927 interest rates declined, even though corporations,
real estate owners, and state and local governments
were large net borrowers. There was a large volume
of saving, but part of the explanation for the down­
ward drift in rates may have been in the mix of public
policy actions adopted. The Federal Government was
operating at a surplus and retiring debt, and there was
a rapid expansion of bank credit and money during
much of this period.
D uring the economic boom lasting from the fall
of 1927 to the fall of 1929, interest rates again moved
higher. Yields on four- to six-month commercial paper
rose from 4.00 per cent to 6.25 per cent, and interest
rates on highest grade corporate bonds increased from
4.50 per cent to 4.80 per cent.

The Depression
In the initial stages of the great depression, begin­
ning in late 1929, interest rates declined. From a level
of 6.25 per cent in the fall of 1929, commercial paper
yields dropped to 2.00 per cent in the summer and
early fall of 1931. Likewise, highest grade corporate
bond yields decreased, from 4.80 per cent to 4.36 per
cent.
Despite the continued contraction in economic ac­
tivity, interest rates rose markedly in late 1931. For­
eign crises and devaluations, the large number of bank

The Twenties
Economic activity rose during most of 1919, and
interest rates moved up moderately. They continued




4An examination of the rates of change in money since 1914 is
presented in this Bank’s September 1964 Review in an article
entitled “Money Supply and Time Deposits, 1914-1964.”
Page 5

In te re st R a te

* C h a n g e in se r ie s.

failures, and distrust of the dollar brought a large gold
outflow. The Federal Reserve met this crisis in the
traditional fashion by taking actions designed to raise
interest rates.5 Short-term rates doubled to a level of
4.00 per cent, and long-term rates went up about 1
percentage point to 5.32 per cent.
Except for another sharp jump for a brief period
around the “bank holiday” in early 1933, interest rates
generally worked lower until early 1937. The supply
of short-term Government securities and other highgrade money market paper was severely limited. By
early 1937 prime commercial paper was yielding only
0.75 per cent, and highest grade corporate bonds were
5See pages 1-13 of the Eighteenth Annual Report of the Fed­
eral Reserve Board, Covering Operations for the Year 1931
(Washington, D. C.: Government Printing Office, 1932).
Page 0



bringing 3.10 per cent. D uring the first quarter of
1937 interest rates jumped higher briefly but declined
late in the year (during the 1937-38 recession) and
continued at an unusually low level until early 1941.

World War II and the Im m ediate
Postwar Period
D uring 1941 and early 1942 economic activity was
quickening, and short-term interest rates worked up
somewhat. In early 1942 the Federal Reserve began
pegging the prices of Government securities to help
finance the war effort, thereby keeping interest rates
down. From April 1942 to July 1947, when the peg
was relaxed, yields on three-month Treasury bills re­
mained at three-eighths of one per cent, and yields on

s, 1 9 1 4 - 1 9 6 5
"I

|

|

P er C en t
I

I ;■

I

I

I

i

I

I

I

I

T "------- ----1---------------- 1
---------------- 1---------------- T ~ -----------1---------------- 1---------------- T --------------1---------------- 1---------------- 1---------------- T

7

6

940

1942

1944

1946

1948

1950

1952

1954

1956

1958

1960

1962

1964

S h o d e d a re as represent p eriod s of b usin e ss recessio n a s defined b y the N a tio n a l Bureau of Econom ic Research.

highest grade corporate bonds drifted from 2.85 per
cent to 2.55 per cent.

generally drifted lower throughout the year, although
the decline was sharpest around midyear.

Interest rates rose from July 1947 until 1949; for
short-term rates the rise was sharp just after mid-1947.
The economy was expanding during most of this pe­
riod, although a mild economic adjustment began in
late 1948. In 1949 interest rates declined. Short-term
rates declined abruptly around the middle of the year,
following reduction of member bank reserve require­
ments and discontinuance of net sales of securities by
the Federal Reserve System to meet market demand
(which began early in the year).6 Long-term rates

Since 1950

6See pages 7-11 of the Thirty-Sixth Annual Report of the Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Covering Opera­
tions for the Year 1949.




From early 1950 to the spring of 1953 interest rates
rose. In March 1951, with the Treasury-Federal Re­
serve “accord,” rates were freed from die peg. Eco­
nomic activity in the early fifties, which included the
period of Korean conflict, was accelerating. In late
1953 and early 1954 rates declined rather sharply,
along with a contraction in economic activity.
Interest rates rose during the economic expansion
from the late summer of 1954 to the fall of 1957 to a
much higher level than during the previous period
of economic upswing. In late 1957 and the first few

months of 1958, a period of economic recession, inter­
est rates remained at their high level a few months,
and then they fell abruptly.
From mid-1958 through 1959 rates again moved
higher, surpassing the previous postwar peak levels.
At the end of 1959 three-month Treasury bills were
yielding about 4.50 per cent, and highest grade corpo­
rate bonds were yielding about 4.60 per cent. In
early 1960, while economic activity was still at a high
level, interest rates fell markedly.
Since the spring of 1960 interest rates have followed
different cyclical and seasonal patterns. The new pat­
terns may have reflected, in part, the rapid growth of
C.D.’s and the mix of policy actions designed both to
reduce the outflow of funds seeking higher yields
abroad and to stimulate domestic economic activity.
During the M a y 1960-February 1961 period of de­
clining economic activity, interest rates remained
about unchanged at a level down from the peak but
substantially higher than the lows of the three previous
recessions. Since early 1961 short-term interest rates
have moved higher, but at a slower rate than in pre­
vious postwar expansions. Long-term rates have shown
only small net increases. Also, the decline in short­
term rates early in the year and the rise in the late
summer and fall which was typical of the fifties has
virtually disappeared since mid-1960. In September
1965 rates on three-month bills averaged 3.92 per cent
and on highest grade corporate bonds averaged 4.52
per cent.
C o n c lu s io n s
Interest rates have generally been high and rising
during periods of rapid economic expansion and have
been low and declining during periods of economic
contraction. Exceptions have occurred, such as the un­
usually high rates during the first year of the 1920-21
economic contraction, the sharp upward movement of
rates during the depression in 1931, and the compar­
atively low rates during the period of heavy demand
for goods and services during and immediately fol­
lowing W orld W a r II.
According to a popular belief, proper economic sta­
bilization action calls for relatively high and rising
interest rates during periods of rapid expansion, es­
pecially when output is pressing the limits of produc­
tive capacity and prices are rising. Conversely, it is
generally thought that lower rates are desirable in
periods of insufficient and declining demand for goods
and services. According to this view, interest rates
have behaved in a stabilizing fashion during the past
half century, except for a few atypical periods.
Page 8



Proper interest rate policy, however, may be much
more complicated than merely determining that rates
are rising during periods of strong economic advance
and inflation or declining during periods of substan­
tial and rising unemployment. Questions arise as to
how much interest rates need to change under various
conditions, what should be the relation among rates
on loans of various maturities, the influence of factors
other than monetary actions, and lags in the effect of
changes in interest rates on economic activity.
This article does not purport to evaluate interest
rate policy over this 50-year period, but an examina­
tion of the data indicates a need for caution by those
who use interest rates alone as a measure of monetary
action. Economic activity itself has been the major
influence on rates. As activity quickens, demands for
funds for capital investment and other purposes rise
faster than the supplies of funds from saving, exerting
upward pressures on rates. Conversely, as activity
contracts, downward pressures on interest rates de­
velop. In the light of these observations, the apparent
countercyclical behavior of rates during the past 50
years may have been partially or entirely a reflection
of changing economic conditions rather than a reflec­
tion of monetary actions.
For example, with the advantage of hindsight, one
might conclude that the marked decline in interest
rates during the depression of the early thirties
resulted primarily from forces associated with the
economic contraction rather than from stimulative
monetary action. W hile interest rates were declining,
bank reserves, bank credit, bank deposits, and money
supply were also contracting.
Conversely, since the early fall of 1962 interest rates
on three-month Treasury bills have moved up in sev­
eral steps from about 2.75 per cent to about 4.00 per
cent, yet bank reserves, bank credit, total bank de­
posits, and money have each risen markedly. One
might conclude that interest rates have increased de­
spite expansionary monetary actions and that these
monetary actions have been a factor in the continued
economic expansion.
In some periods of recession, although interest rates
have declined, it may be that a greater decline would
have been appropriate. In some periods of boom,
while interest rates have risen, it may be that greater
increases would have been appropriate, and there may
have been times near the end of economic expansions
when rates were higher or rose more rapidly than was
appropriate.
(Continued on page 12)

Farm Land Prices
M A R K E T P R IC E S of farm real estate in the
United States rose 6 per cent during the year ending
M arch 1, 1965 (Table I) . This was about the same
rate of increase as in the previous year but above the
4.6 per cent average for the five-year period 1960-65.1
Values per acre increased from $53 to $146 during
the period 1946-65, an average annual rate of increase
of 5.3 per cent. Since the general uptrend began in
1933, farm real estate prices have increased or re­
mained stable each year with the exception of three
years, 1939, 1950, and 1954.
In the Central Mississippi Valley2 farm real estate
prices increased about 7 per cent during the year
ending March 1, 1965.3 Such values in the area rose at
an average annual rate of 6 per cent during the five
1Years ending M arch 1.
2F o r purposes of this article the Central Mississippi Valley com­
prises five states, Arkansas, Kentucky, Mississippi, Missouri,
and Tennessee.
3Tables similar to Table I for the Central Mississippi Valley,
each of the five Central Mississippi Valley states, and Illinois
and Indiana can be obtained from the Research Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, P. O. Box 442, St. Louis,
Missouri 63166.

years 1960-65 and have increased at an annual rate of
5.6 per cent since 1946.
Land prices in Arkansas and Mississippi have ad­
vanced faster than in the other Valley states since
1946. The high rate of farm consolidations in these
states was probably an important factor in their rapid
price gains.
L a n d P r ic e T r e n d s

National Trends
Trends in farm real estate prices in the United States
may be divided into four periods: prior to 1900 prices
rose slowly; from 1900 to 1920 prices rose rapidly;
from 1920 to 1933 prices declined; and since 1933
prices have again risen rapidly (Table I I ) .
During the last half of the nineteenth century the
value of farm real estate increased slowly, from an av­
erage of $11.14 per acre in 1850 to $19.80 per acre in
1900. Most of the increase occurred during the 20
years from 1850 to 1870, when land prices rose from
$11.14 to $18.25 per acre, an average rate of 2.5 per
cent per year. Such values remained relatively stable
from 1870 to 1900, increasing an average of 0.3 per

Table I

CH A N G ES IN VALUE OF FARM REAL ESTATE
United States
Annual Rates
Terminal
Year

Initial Year
1946

1947

13.5

1947

1948

1949

1950

1951

1952

1953

1954

1955

1956

1957

1958

1959

1960

1961

1962

1948

10.1

1949

8.3

5.8

1950

5.7

3.3

1.6

1951

7.6

6.2

6.0

6.6

15.4

1952

7.9

6.8

6.8

7.5

12.3

9.3

1953

6.9

5.9

5.7

5.9

8.5

5.2

1.2

1954

5.9

4.8

4.5

4.4

6.0

3.0

0.0

1955

5.6

4.7

4.4

4.3

5.5

3.2

1.2

1.2

3.7

1956

5.5

4.7

4.4

4.4

5.4

3.5

2.1

2.4

4.2

4.7

1957

5.6

4.9

4.7

4.7

5.6

4.0

3.0

3.4

5.0

1958

5.5

4.8

4.6

4.6

5.4

4.1

3.2

3.6

4.8

5.7
5.2

5.5

1959

5.6

5.0

4.8

4.9

5.6

4.4

3.7

4.2

5.3

5.7

6.0

5.6

7.1

1960

5.6

5.0

4.8

4.8

5.5

4.5

3.9

4.2

5.2

5.5

5.7

5.3

5.9

1961

5.3

4.7

4.5

4.5

5.1

4.1

3.5

3.8

4.6

4.7

4.7

4.2

4.2

2.8

1962

5.3

4.7

4.6

4.6

5.1

4.2

3.7

4.0

4.7

4.8

4.8

4.4

4.5

3.6

3.1

5.4

1963

5.2

4.7

4.6

4.6

5.0

4.2

3.8

4.0

4.6

4.7

4.7

4.4

4.4

3.8

3.5

1964

5.3

4.8

4.7

4.7

5.1

4.4

4.0

4.2

4.8

4.9

5.0

4.7

4.8

4.3

4.2

4.8
5.4

4.2
5.4

1965

5.3

4.9

4.8

4.8

5.2

4.5

4.1

4.4

4.9

5.0

5.1

4.9

5.0

4.6

4.6

5.6

5.6

Source:

1963

1964

6.8
4.8
— 1.5

— 1.2

6.7
4.2
4.7
0.9

USDA.




Page 9

3.5 per cent from 1960 to 1963; however, during 1964
and 1965 the rate of increase was above the over-all
average for the 1946-65 period. From 1946 to 1965
land in farms declined at an average rate of 0.3 per
cent per year, while cropland harvested declined at
a rate of 0.2 per cent.

Table II

CH A N G ES IN FARM LAND VALUES
United States
Annual Rates
Selected Periods, 1850-1965
Years
1850-1900 ............................

Source:

Change
1 .2 %

1900-1920 ............................

6.5

1920-1933 ............................

— 6.3

1933-1965 ............................

5.1

U SD A.

cent per year. The rate of increase for the entire half
century averaged 1.2 per cent per year. Total farming
area rose 2.1 per cent per year as additional land suit­
able for cultivation was brought into farms.
By the turn of the century most of the nation’s fer­
tile land had been settled, and the general price level,
as measured by the wholesale price index, had turned
up. Land prices began to rise rapidly, doubling from
1900 to 1910 and rising another 80 per cent from 1910
to 1920. Prices had risen to an average of $69 per
acre in 1920, an increase of 6.5 per cent per year for
the period 1900-20. D uring this 20-year period land
in farms continued to rise but at a reduced rate of
0.7 per cent per year. Cropland harvested rose 1.0
per cent per year.

Since 1946 farm real estate prices have increased at
a slower rate than prices of common stocks but faster
than wholesale commodity prices. Common stock
prices rose from 1946 to 1965 at an average annual rate
of 8.8 per cent, well above the rate for farm land, while
wholesale prices rose at an average rate of 2.3 per
cent, about half the rate of increase for farm real
estate.
B y contrast, from the 1910-14 average to 1946 the
relative prices of common stocks, wholesale commodi­
ties, and farm real estate had not changed significantly
on balance (Chart 1). D uring the period common
stock prices rose at an average annual rate of 1.9 per
cent, wholesale commodity prices, at a 1.7 per cent
rate, and farm real estate, at a 0.7 per cent rate.

Trends in the Central Mississippi Valley
Land prices in the Central Mississippi Valley have
generally followed the national trend. However, in
recent years the rate of increase for most states in this
area has been greater than the average for the nation.
From 1946 to 1965 land prices in the area rose at an
average annual rate of 5.6 per cent, slightly faster than

Following 1920, farm land prices began a decline
which continued throughout the twenties and into the
early thirties. Prices reached bottom in 1933 after a
13-year decline during which prices
C h a rt 1
per acre decreased from an average
P R IC E S
of $69 to $30, or at an annual rate
L
a
n
d
,
C
o
m
m
o
n
S
t
o
c
k
s
,
a n d W h o le s a le C o m m o d it ie s
of 6.3 per cent. Land in farms and
cropland harvested rose only slightly
during the period.
From the 1933 depression low,
farm real estate prices rose slightly
until the beginning of W orld W ar
I I and then turned sharply upward.
From 1933 to 1941 prices rose from
an average of $30 to $32 per acre,
an average rate of increase of 0.8
per cent. From 1941 to 1946 they
rose from $32 to $53 per acre, an
average rate of 10.8 per cent. Since
1946 land values have increased at a
rate of 5.3 per cent per year. For
the 32-year period 1933-65 the aver­
age annual rate of increase was 5.1
per cent. Such prices appeared to
be leveling off in the early 1960’s
as the rate of increase declined to
Page 10



1880

1890

1900

1910

1920

1930

J, S t a n d a r d & P o o r ’s stock prico in d o x, 3 0 0 com m on stocks.
(2 U.S. Do p artm on t of L a b o r, w h o lo sa lo p r ic * indox.
13 U SD A .

1940

1950

1960

1970

Table III

the average for the nation. In the five years 1960-65,
prices in the five states rose at an annual rate of 6.0
per cent, compared with 4.6 per cent for the nation.

LAND IN FARMS
United States
Year

Since 1946 land values have increased most rapidly
in Arkansas and Mississippi, with rates of 7.2 and 6.3
per cent, respectively (Chart 2). In Kentucky values
rose at the national average rate of 5.3 per cent, while
the rates in the remaining valley states, Tennessee and
Missouri, were slightly below the national average.
F a c to r s A ffe c tin g F a r m

L a n d V a lu e s

.................................

839

1940

.................................

1,061

1950 ..................................

1,158

1960

.................................

1,115

1965 ..................................

1,092

opm ents.”

Table IV

CROP YIELDS
United States
Year
1940

........................
.................................

82

1950

.................................

84

76

1955

.............................

91

1960

.................................

109
116

Source; U S D A .

land area is fixed, and the amount useful for agricul­
ture is also relatively inflexible. W hile substantially
higher prices for farm commodities might bring ad­
ditional acres into farms, such price increases would
give rise primarily to greater production on land al­
ready in farms.

C ha rt 2

P R IC E S
F a r m R e a l E s ta t e b y S t a t e s - E ig h t h D istrict
19 10-14=100

Output per Acre
(1957-59 = 100)

1945

1964

Supply of Farm Land

Land in farms is price inelastic, i.e., price changes
do not result in sizable changes in supply. The nation’s

294

1900

Source: C alculated from USD A data in “ F a rm R eal E state M arket D evel­

Numerous economic forces have contributed to the
increases in farm real estate values. The productivity
of farm real estate has increased rapidly in recent
years. Demand forces have been even more dynamic.
The remainder of this article outlines some of the
forces which affect the supply and demand for farm
real estate, with special attention to the variation in
real estate price trends in the Central Mississippi V al­
ley states.

The supply of farm real estate has declined in re­
cent years. Land in farms in the United States totaled
1,092 million acres in 1965, down about 2 per cent
from the 1960 level and 5 per cent less than in 1946
(Table III).

Millions of Acres

1850 ..................................

1910-14=100

The capacity of land to produce
farm products is quite flexible. The
consistency of yield gains during the
past 24 years points to advances in
production technology and its ap­
plication on farms (Table IV). Out­
put of farm products could be in­
creased substantially even within the
current constraints of production
technology. Furthermore, the rising
level of farm technology seems likely
to continue to boost potential output
per acre.

D emand fo r Farm
Real Estate

Source: U SD A .




The demand for farm land is de­
termined by its use for both agri­
cultural and nonagricultural purpos­
es. Nonagricultural uses for land
include urbanization, roads, parks,
recreation areas, public conservation
projects, etc. Although only a small
Page 11

share of the total land area in most states is set apart
for such purposes, these uses may have a substantial
impact on farm real estate prices. About 20 per cent
of all land in the continental United States is within
commuting distance of some metropolitan area, and
farm land within this range tends to take on higher
values than similar land further away. Metropolitan
areas continue to gain population, and this has an
impact on land values over an increasing area as bet­
ter roads improve transportation.
Demand for land for farming has been affected di­
versely by farm technology. Increased yields per acre,
brought about through improved fertilization, seed,
and disease control, have been an important factor
tending to reduce farm commodity prices and demand
for land. O n the other hand, improvements in mecha­
nization and weed control have permitted a major
increase in the number of acres that can be farmed by
one man, thus tending to increase farm consolidations
and demand for land for farm enlargement purposes.
The reduction in labor costs increases the returns to
other factors of production, including land.
Government land rental and crop allotment pro­
grams have also tended to increase the demand for
real estate. Land rental payments have directly in­
creased the returns accruing to land. The acreage
allotment program may also increase farm consolida­
tions and demand for farm land. If it decreases farm
output, as in the case of the rental program, returns
to all factors including land are increased in view of
an inelastic demand for farm commodities. Further­
more, if farming units of optimum size maximize re­
turns to the operator and the allotment program re­
duces the acreage that can be farmed on existing units,

^

=

additional acres are required to bring farms back up
to optimum size. Thus, demand for additional acreage
for farm consolidation or enlargement is enhanced.

Land Prices and Farm Consolidations in
the Central Mississippi Valley
Part of the difference in farm real estate price trends
among the Central Mississippi Valley states can be
traced to the varying rates of farm consolidations in
the area. For example, from 1945 to 1964 the annual
rate of change in acres per farm was greatest in A r­
kansas and Mississippi, with percentage increases of
4.7 and 4.2, respectively (Table V ). Land value in­
creases in these states were also greatest, with gains
of 7.1 and 6.8 per cent per year, respectively. Acres
table

v

C H A N G ES IN FARM SIZE A N D LAND VALUES
Central Mississippi Valley, 1945 to 1964
Annual Rates
Acres per Farm

Value per Acre

A rkansas ........................ ... 4 . 7 %

7 .1 %

Kentucky ........................ ... 2.0

5.8

M ississipp i
M issouri

.................... ... 4.2

6.8

........................ ... 2.0

5.5

Tennessee ...................... ... 1.7
Total

States

5 .7

............ ... 3.0

6.0

Illinois ........................... ... 1.6

5.4

Indiana ............................. 1.7

5.5

United States ................. ... 2.8

5.7

5

Source: Calculated from USDA data in “Farm Real Estate Market Devel­
opments.”

per farm in the five-state area rose at a slightly higher
rate than in the nation, and value of land per acre also
moved up at a higher rate.
C

l if t o n

B. L

u ttrell

3

Interest Rates , 1914-1965—(Continued from page 8)
Countercyclical policy in terms of interest rates, it
would seem, requires at a minimum some upward
pressures on rates from the monetary system in periods
of ebullience and some downward pressures in periods
of economic decline. Since many forces are at all
times impinging on rates, selection of the proper rate
or determining the impact of monetary actions on
rates at any given time is a difficult task. Because of
a desire for relatively stable money market conditions
in the short run, chances for error in selecting the
proper rates seem to be greatest around cyclical turn­
Page 12




ing points, when there is usually the most marked
change in other forces affecting interest rates.
The frequently stated conclusion that increasing
monetary restraint is being imposed as evidenced by
rising interest rates during a boom may not be valid,
since other forces, including the expansion of activity
itself, may be placing upward pressure on rates. Analy­
sis must go deeper and seek to determine in what
direction and to what extent the monetary system has
been pushing rates.
N

orm an

N. Bow

sher