View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

R
Vol. 76, No. 6




W
November/December 1994

Symposium on Mutual Funds and
Monetary Aggregates
An Alternative Monetary Aggregate: M2 Plus
Household Holdings of Bond and Equity
Mutual Funds
The Empirical Properties of a Monetary
Aggregate That Adds Bond and Stock
Funds to M2
Commentary

Replication and Scientific Standards in
Applied Economics a Decade After the
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking Project

THE
FEDERAL
^RESERVE
Jtk BANK of
A r ST. LOUIS

R E V I E W

President
T h o m a s C. M e lze r

Review is published six times per year by the Research Department of the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Single-copy subscriptions are available
free of charge. Send requests for subscriptions, back issues or address

Director of Research W illia m G. D e w a ld
Associate Director of Research
C le tu s C . C ou gh lin
Research Coordinator and
Review Editor
W illia m T. G avin

changes to:
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Public Information Department
P.O. Box 442
St. Louis, Missouri 63166
The views expressed are those of the individual authors and do not neces­
sarily reflect official positions of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, the
Federal Reserve System, or the Board of Governors. Articles may be reprinted

Banking
R. A lto n G ilb e rt
D avid C. W h e e lo c k
International
C h ris to p h e r J . N e e ly
M ic h a e l R. P a k k o
P a tric ia S. P o llard

or reproduced only if the source is credited. Please provide the Public
Information Department with a copy of the reprinted materials.

All nonproprietary and nonconfidential data and programs for the articles
published in Review are available to our readers. This information can be

Macroeconomics
D o n ald S. A llen
R ich ard G. A n d erson
J a m e s B. B u llard
M ic h a e l J . D u e k e r
Jo se p h A. R itte r
Jo h n A. T ato m
D a n ie l L. T h o rn to n
P e te r Yoo
Regional
M ic h e lle A. C la rk
K e vin L. K lie s e n
A d am M . Z a re ts k y

obtained from three sources:

1. FR ED (F e d e ra l R e s e rv e E c o n o m ic D a ta ), an e le c tr o n ic b u l­
le tin bo ard s e rv ic e . You can access FRED by dialing 314-621-1824
through a modem-equipped personal computer. Parameters should be
set to: no parity, word length = 8 bits, 1 stop bit, and the fastest baud rate
the modem supports (up to 14,400 bps). Information will be in directory
11 under the file name ST. LOUIS REVIEW DATA. For a free brochure on
FRED, please call 314-444-8809.

2 . T h e F e d e ra l R e s e rv e B a n k o f S t. L o uis. You can request
data and programs on either disk or hard copy by writing to: Research
Department, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Post Office Box 442,

Director of Editorial Services
D a n iel P. B ren nan
Managing Editor
C h a rle s B. H e n d erso n
Graphic Designer
Brian D. E b ert




St. Louis, MO 63166. Please include the author, title, issue date
and page numbers with your request.

3 . In te r-u n iv e rs ity C o n s o rtiu m fo r P o litic a l an d S o c ia l
R e s e a rc h (IC P S R ). Member institutions can request data through
the CDNet Order facility. Nonmembers should write to: ICPSR, Institute
for Social Research, P.O. Box 1248, Ann Arbor, Michigan 48106, or
call 313-763-5010.

1

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review
November/December 1994

In This Issue. . .
Symposium on Mutual Funds and Monetary Aggregates
During 1990-93, the Federal Reserve’s primary monetary aggregate, M2, grew much
more slowly than suggested by historical relationships to economic activity and
opportunity costs. This sluggish growth led some to question its usefulness as a
policy indicator. In July 1993, Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan Greenspan
told Congress that monetary aggregates, including M2, were being officially
de-emphasized as guides to policy.
During the same period, households’ holdings of bond and equity mutual fund
shares increased at a record pace. Responding to a sharp decrease in the overall
level of market interest rates and a record widening of maturity-related yield
spreads, households shifted unprecedented amounts of savings away from
traditional depository institutions.
In March 1994, the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis hosted a symposium to examine
the implications of the rapid growth of mutual funds for the role of M2 as an indicator
of the stance of monetary policy. Speakers included staff from the Division of
Monetary Affairs at the Board of Governors, executives from the banking and mutual
fund industry, and academic economists. Among the questions addressed were: To
what extent do households regard bank deposits and mutual fund shares as close
substitutes? Should M2 be replaced by a new monetary aggregate that includes
these mutual funds? Or, rather, does M 2’s apparently aberrant behavior only
confirm that broad monetary aggregates are generally not suitable as guides
for monetary policy?

Editor’s Introduction
Richard G. Anderson

An Alternative Monetary Aggregate: M2 Plus Household Holdings of Bond and
Equity Mutual Funds
Sean Collins and Cheryl L. Edwards

31




The Empirical Properties of a Monetary Aggregate That Adds Bond and Stock
Funds to M2
Athanasios Orphanides, Brian Reid, and David H. Small

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

2

53

Commentary

53

William A. Barnett and Ge Zhou

63

Jacob S. Dreyer

67

John V. Duca

71

Josh Feinman

75

George G. Pennacchi

79 Replication and Scientific Standards in Applied Economics a Decade After the
Journal of Money, Credit and Banking Project
Richard G. Anderson and William G. Dewald
Since early 1993, the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis has made data and programs for articles published in its R eview
available to the public. The files, developed during a pre-publication repli­
cation that assures the accuracy of an article’s empirical results, allow the
interested reader to delve into the details of the author’s research. The
R eview is one of only a few journals in economics that provides access to
the data used by its authors, and the only one to include the underlying
programming.
A decade ago, the Jou rn al o f M oney, Credit a n d B an kin g project was the
first attempt by an economics journal to furnish readers with the data and
programs used by its authors. The project affirmed that readers could not
obtain data and programs directly from authors. Further, the project sug­
gested a positive correlation between the journal’s furnishing data to read­
ers and the care with which authors completed their research. Finally, the
project demonstrated that professional journals are a low-cost way to dis­
tribute data to readers. The more recent experience at the Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis reaffirms these conclusions.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




3

Editor’s Introduction
On March 29, 1994, the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis hosted a symposium on the im plica­
tions of rapid mutual fund growth for monetary
policy. From 1990-93, household holdings of
shares in bond and equity mutual funds increased
at a record pace. During the same period, the
Federal Reserve’s primary monetary aggregate,
M2, grew much more slowly than suggested by
its historical relationships to economic activity
and opportunity costs. Does the confluence of
these events suggest that M2 has become less
useful as an indicator of the stance of monetary
policy? Should it be replaced with a new aggre­
gate that includes these mutual funds?
Financial innovation and advances in
technology change the structure of financial
markets, alter the indicator properties of monetary
aggregates, and give rise to pressures for their
redefinition. When Regulation Q capped deposit
offering rates during the 1970s, for example, many
households learned that money market mutual
funds provided an attractive alternative to holding
bank and thrift deposits. As a result, money
market funds were included in M2 when it was
redefined in 1980. During the 1980s, households
became increasingly familiar with financial
institutions other than banks and thrifts. Mortgage
loans were increasingly originated by mortgage
brokers, auto loans extended by finance compa­
nies, and retirement funds held in self-managed
IRA and Keogh accounts. At the same time, the
mutual fund industry benefited from technical
progress that reduced the cost of servicing large
customer lists and managing portfolios of mar­
ketable securities.
Thus, participants on both sides of the financial
markets seemed poised to react swiftly during
the 1990s to the combination of a sharp decrease
in the overall level of market interest rates and a
record widening of maturity-related yield spreads.
Available survey and anecdotal evidence, as well
as negative statistical correlations in the aggregate
data, suggest that households shifted savings
away from traditional depository institutions




toward bond and equity mutual funds. With
offering rates on deposits decreasing, prospective
returns on bond and equity funds often appeared
to be three- or four-fold greater.
The subsequent slow growth of M2 during a
period when many analysts perceived monetary
policy as becoming increasingly expansionary
led to doubts about its usefulness as a policy
indicator. The monetary aggregates were offi­
cially de-emphasized as policy guides in Federal
Reserve Board Chairman Greenspan’s July 1993
Humphrey-Hawkins Act testimony before
Congress. At about the same time, a group of
economists at the Board of Governors completed
two studies evaluating whether M2 might usefully
be replaced by a redefined aggregate that included
bond and equity mutual fund shares. These
studies, and the five commentaries that appear
here, were presented at the St. Louis symposium.
Written by economists closely involved in policy
analysis, the studies provide a unique perspective
on the range of issues that arise whenever it is
suggested that a monetary aggregate be redefined.
Before a monetary aggregate may be used, it
must be measured. In the first article, Sean Collins
and Cheryl Edwards discuss the measurement of
a monetary aggregate M2+ that includes both M2
and shares in bond and equity mutual funds.
They first describe how interest in redefining
an aggregate arises when its growth differs from
that suggested by its historical behavior. Although
necessary, such deviant behavior may not be
sufficient unless there also has been significant
innovation or technical progress in financial
markets since the previous redefinition of the
aggregates. The latter imparts an a priori reason­
ableness to suspicions that the array of money
substitutes available to households and firms
has expanded, or that the transaction costs of
substituting among various alternatives has
decreased.
The current M2 monetary aggregate is designed
to measure household and firm holdings of liquid
assets that are either available for spending now

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

4

or will become so in the near future. Retaining
this focus in a new monetary aggregate that
includes bond and equity mutual funds requires
separating institutional holdings of mutual fund
shares from those held by firms and households,
as Collins and Edwards discuss in the latter half
of their article. Further, data on several items
that are not included in the new aggregate, such
as the M2-type assets owned by the bond and
equity funds and the amount of mutual fund
shares held by households as illiquid retirement
balances, are also required. These amounts are
subtracted from the new aggregate.
Collins and Edwards discuss several unique
problems that arise while building M2+ that
have no direct parallel in the current monetary
aggregates. One is the inclusion of assets
denominated in foreign currencies. All compo­
nents of the current official monetary aggregates
(M l, M2, M3 and L) are denominated in U.S.
dollars. Mutual funds that invest in foreign
currency-denominated assets, however, have
been among the most rapidly growing type of
funds in recent years. Second, current M2
includes only assets that are capital-certain or,
in other words, only assets whose value does
not vary with the level of market interest rates.
Capital gains and losses are a significant factor
in changes in the value of bond and equity
funds, and present a thorny problem for both
the construction and interpretation of the
M2+ aggregate.
In the policy arena, monetary aggregates
may be valuable as either targets or indicators,
with requirements for the former generally
more stringent than for the latter. In both cases,
the aggregate must have a reliable empirical
relationship to future economic activity. In
addition, to be useful as a policy target, the
demand for the aggregate must be a stable func­
tion of a relatively small number of variables
and the Federal Reserve must be able to control
the aggregate’s growth. In the second article,
Athanasios Orphanides, Brian Reid and David
Small judge the M2+ monetary aggregate
relative to each of these criteria.
Modeling the demand for a monetary aggre­
gate requires identifying its close substitutes
and, in turn, the opportunity cost of holding the
components of the aggregate rather than alterna­
tive assets. The inclusion of capital-uncertain
assets in M2+ complicates calculation of its own
rate of return and identification of an appropriate

Digitized forFEDERAL
FRASER RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS


opportunity cost. The authors conclude that the
nonbank public’s holdings of bond and equity
fund shares seem to respond to both the spread
between the return on the mutual fund and the
Treasury bill yield, and the change during the
previous period in the overall level of market
rates or equity prices.
In the latter part of their article, Orphanides,
Reid and Small examine the stability of the
demand for M2+ and its value as a leading indi­
cator for nominal GDP. Working within the linear
error-correction framework developed by Board
staff in previous money demand studies, they find
a reasonably good overall fit to the data. Yet, the
estimated semi-elasticities of M2+ demand with
respect to market yields and various measures of
its opportunity cost appear highly sensitive to the
form in which these variables enter the regression.
Perhaps more disappointing, however, is their
conclusion that M2+ has not been a generally
better indicator than M2 of movements in
nominal GDP growth during the 1990s.
In their commentary, William Barnett and
Ge Zhou interpret the definition of M2+ as a
dynamic index number problem. When the
financial assets in an economy can be partitioned
into two non-overlapping groups—those that
provide monetary (transaction) services and those
that do not—the economy’s money stock is
correctly measured by summing the quantities
of the assets in the former group. It is the essence
of financial innovation, however, to blur the
distinction between these groups and allow assets
in the latter category to provide monetary as well
as non-monetary services. The authors show,
however, that sequentially redefining a broad
monetary aggregate may cause the aggregate to
move further away from, rather than closer to,
the economy’s true money stock. They laud the
authors of the symposium’s two major papers
for grappling with the difficult issue of including
capital-uncertain assets in a monetary aggregate.
Jacob Dreyer doubts, however, that a new
M2+ monetary aggregate would be useful to
policymakers. The necessity of estimating
expected holding period yields likely precludes
obtaining useful estimates of a demand equation
for the aggregate. He also argues that turnover
rates suggest that bond and equity mutual funds
lack the necessary degree of “moneyness” for
them to reasonably be included in a monetary
aggregate along with the current components of
M2. Although acknowledging that the transaction

5

costs of buying and selling bond and equity funds
have fallen sharply, he regards this change as
creating only the illusion, rather than the
substance, of moneyness.
In his commentary, John Duca attributes the
slower-than-anticipated growth of M2 during the
1990s to a combination of changes in banking
regulation and the pattern of market interest rates.
Duca notes that significant shifts in financial
intermediation also occurred in the 1970s and
1980s when government regulation interacted
with large movements in market interest rates.
Nevertheless, he concludes that the unprece­
dented steep slope of the yield curve during a
period when offering rates on bank and thrift
deposits fell to their lowest levels in decades
likely was the primary motivation for households
to substitute holdings of bond and equity funds
for M2-type assets during the 1990s. This
substitution does not, by itself, call for a
redefinition of M2, however.
Josh Feinman suggests that the dramatic
shrinkage of the federal subsidy to the depository
sector since 1990 seems to have played the larger
role in depressing M2 growth. He cites higher
deposit insurance premiums, new capital stan­
dards and stricter supervision as examples.
These changes reduced the incentive for deposi­
tories to pursue their traditional lending and
deposit-taking activities, resulting in an increasing
proportion of intermediation being conducted
through market instruments such as corporate
equity and commercial paper, popular investments
of bond and equity mutual funds. He doubts that
M2+ could ever be useful as a policy target or




indicator. In his view, the inverse correlation
between movements in market interest rates and
the value of the capital-uncertain assets included
in M2+ likely precludes formulating any policy
feedback rules based on M2+.
George Pennacchi suggests that households’
increased holdings of mutual fund shares might
be interpreted as a reaction to the narrower rate
spreads between liquid and time deposits at banks
during the 1990s. Reductions in transaction costs
and improvements in computer technology have
increased the liquidity of bond and equity mutual
funds, making them more competitive with liquid
deposits in such an environment. He suggests
that the lower turnover rates of bond and equity
fund shares should not be taken as evidence that
households have not responded to, and do not
value, the increased liquidity of the funds.
Moreover, although the funds are subject to
liquidity (interest rate) risk, economic theory
suggests that the expected holding period yields
of these mutual funds should not differ system­
atically, on balance, from other market returns.
Finally, I want to recognize the economic analysts
in the Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis who provided invaluable help
in reviewing references and data for the sympo­
sium papers: Heidi L. Beyer, Heather Deaton,
Kelly M. Morris and Richard D. Taylor.

Richard G. Anderson
St. Louis, Missouri
November 1 ,1 9 9 4

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994




7

Sean Collins and Cheryl L. Edwards
Sean Collins and Cheryl L. Edwards are staff economists with
the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Division of Monetary Affairs.

An Alternative Monetary
Aggregate: M2 Plus Household
Holdings of Bond and Equity
Mutual Funds
St a n d a r d m o n e y -d e m a n d m o d e l s
began to go off track in 1990, attesting to an
apparent shift in the velocity of M2. This shift
sparked debate about whether M2 velocity is
stable, an important property for an indicator of
monetary policy.1 It also raised questions about
the usefulness of money-demand models for
predicting the effects of Federal Reserve policy.
If velocity shifts in some unforeseeable way,
how is it possible for policymakers to exploit
the statistical relationship between M2 and
nominal income to attain their policy goals?
In mid-1993, the Federal Reserve responded
to the velocity shift by formally downgrading
M2 as an indicator of the state of the economy.
Meanwhile, interest has been rekindled in
defining “money” and searching for alternative
monetary aggregates.
One explanation for the velocity shift is the
increased importance of bond and equity mutual
funds, also called long-term funds. Over the
four-year period from 1990 to 1993, net purchases
of bond and equity mutual funds by investors

totaled about $655 billion, compared with about
$400 billion over the 1980s. The surge largely
reflected the yield-seeking behavior of retail
investors. Yields on M2-type assets fell to his­
torically low levels in the early 1990s, while
long-term market interest rates were unusually
high relative to short-term rates, and equity
prices were rising sharply. In this environment,
investors sought higher returns by investing in
bond and equity mutual funds. They may also
have been attracted by the enhanced liquidity
of long-term mutual fund shares. Most large
mutual fund complexes upgraded their share­
holder services during the late 1980s to permit
investors to write checks against their bond fund
balances. At the same time, banks entered the
mutual fund business as regulations that once
prevented banks from selling mutual funds
virtually evaporated. As a result, investors
could buy and sell mutual fund shares in a
familiar environment: the hank lobby.
Taken together, these two developments—the
recent case of missing M2 and the ascendant

1 In this context, stable is usually taken to mean that velocity
is a stationary stochastic process. For some recent evi­
dence on the stability of velocity, see Hallmann and
Anderson (1993).




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

8

Figure 1
M2 Velocity and its Opportunity Cost
Standardized value

Standardized by subtracting mean and dividing by standard deviation

mutual fund industry—raise the issue of whether
bond and equity mutual funds ought to be added
to M2. This paper proposes just that, but offers
some caveats. The first section reviews the recent
behavior of M2 and its deterioration as a predictor
of economic activity. The second section provides
historical background on the mutual fund indus­
try. The third section asks whether bond and
equity mutual funds meet the tests of “moneyness”
usually applied to assets considered for inclusion
in a monetary aggregate. The fourth section
discusses the data needed to construct a theoret­
ically sound monetary aggregate that includes
bond and equity mutual funds. The fifth section
describes how we constructed such an aggregate,
which we will refer to as M2+. The final section
concludes by pointing out some of the drawbacks
of this aggregate.

RECENT BEHAVIOR OF M2
The relationship between M2 and nominal
income was fairly stable for many years before
1990. M2 velocity, which is the ratio of gross
domestic product to the level of M2, fluctuated

Digitized for FEDERAL
FRASER RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS


around a constant level. Moreover, movements
away from this level were strongly positively
correlated with the opportunity cost of holding
M2, measured as the spread between the yield
on a short-term Treasury security and the
weighted-average return on M2. When short-term
Treasury rates rose, the opportunity cost of
holding M2 increased because the rates on the
components of M2 did not climb as fast as market
rates. As a result, M2 growth would slow relative
to the growth in income, and velocity would rise.
As the rates paid on M2 completed their adjust­
ment to the higher level of market rates, M 2’s
opportunity cost would narrow, M2 growth would
rise relative to income growth, and velocity would
return toward its trend level. This relationship
meant that M2 growth could serve as a guidepost
to current (but as yet unknown) income growth.
In m id-1990, however, the velocity of M2 rose
substantially above its long-run average, despite
a very considerable drop in the opportunity cost
of holding M2 (Figure 1). At the same time,
conventional demand equations for M2, which
are statistical representations of the relationship
between money and variables such as interest

9

Figure 2
Actual and Predicted Growth Rates of M2
Percent

rates and income, began to go off track (Figure 2).
Between the first quarter of 1990 and the fourth
quarter of 1993, the Board staffs quarterly model
of M2 demand overpredicted growth by an average
of 2.5 percentage points per quarter—m isesti­
mates that cumulated to nearly $380 billion by
the end of 1993.2
Several alternative hypotheses have been
advanced to explain the missing M2. Duca
(1993a) postulated that the resolution of thrifts
by the Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC) may
have been a factor. In short, he argued that
deposit rates were reset by depository institu­
tions that acquired the deposits of resolved
thrifts. More often than not, the new deposit
rates would be lower—typically much lower—
than the rates that thrift investors had enjoyed
earlier. This “sticker shock” led thrift deposi­
tors to reassess their portfolios in ways not cap­
tured by conventional money-demand models.
Duca’s explanation is an important one for 1990

and 1991, but cannot explain the subsequent
weakness in M2 because RTC funding and, thus,
resolution activity dried up in 1992. Wenninger
and Partlan (1992) focused on the weakness in
small time deposits. They noted that the phasing
out of Regulation Q (which limited the rates banks
could pay on deposits) encouraged banks to think
of small time deposits as managed liabilities.
Consequently, banks, which faced weak credit
demand, were rather unaggressive bidders for
small CDs. The authors also noted that, on the
demand side, consumers may have been surprised
by the substantial decline in deposit rates, and
they therefore sought the higher returns available
on mutual fund investments. Other explanations
advanced in the press and elsewhere attributed
the weakness in M2 to a number of sources: the
credit crunch; rising deposit insurance premiums;
the imposition of new, higher capital standards
for depositories; the downsizing of consumer
balance sheets (which was accomplished by
using M2 balances to pay off debt); the unusual

2 This model is described in Moore, Porter and Small (1990).




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

10

steepness of the yield curve; and, finally, the
especially strong flows into bond and equity
mutual funds over the 1991-93 period.
A common thread binds these stories: They
highlight some facet of household demand for
money not captured in conventional moneydemand models. For instance, if the demand
for money by households is influenced by returns
on capital market instruments, then this effect
would be reflected as an error in conventional
money-demand models, because such models
usually depend only on the spread between the
yield on a short-term Treasury security and the
weighted-average rate paid on M2 balances.
Similarly, to the extent that rising deposit insur­
ance premiums were not accurately reflected in
reported deposit rates, conventional models
could experience significant forecast errors.
The incompleteness of conventional
money-demand models sparked attempts to
revamp such models. Feinman and Porter (1992)
augmented the Board staffs model of the demand
for M2. Rather than defining the opportunity cost
of M2 as the spread between a short-term Treasury
rate and the rate of return on M2 balances, they
estimated the opportunity cost of holding M2
balances. Their model chose the opportunity
cost by selecting among rates of return on M2-type
balances and competing assets.3 In contrast to
conventional models, Feinman and Porter found
that yields on longer-term Treasury instruments
and consumer debt were significant factors in
determining money demand. A steep yield
curve tended to dampen money growth and
helped to explain weak M2 growth. Although
the Feinman-Porter model achieved some success
in predicting M2 growth out-of-sample, the model
had difficulty beginning in m id-1993, when
long-term interest rates fell sharply. In part, this
problem may have stemmed from an asymmetric
response of investors to changes in the slope of
the yield curve. If the yield curve flattens
because long-term interest rates have declined,
investors in mutual funds may enjoy temporary
capital gains, thus depressing their appetites for
M2 balances. In contrast, if the yield curve flattens
3 The rates of return included on M2-type balances were for
other checkable deposits, savings accounts (including
MMDAs), small time deposits with original maturities of
six months, small time deposits with original maturities
of two-and-a-half years or over, and the yield on money
market mutual funds. Yields on competing instruments
included those for three-month Treasury bills, five-year
Treasury notes, 30-year Treasury bonds and the
48-month auto loan rate.


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS


because short-term rates have risen, investors
would garner no capital gains (and might even
confront capital losses on short-term securities),
and they would see an erosion of the yield
advantage of mutual funds over M2-type balances.
However, the Feinman-Porter model treats the
two kinds of flattening the same.
A different approach advocated by Hendry
and Ericsson (1990) for the United Kingdom,
and recently employed by the Board staff, is
to introduce an “error-learning” term into the
conventional M2 demand equation. The errorlearning term attempts to capture changes in
preferences as investors “learn” about mutual
funds and their potentially higher yields.
Nonetheless, as suggested by Higgins (1992),
if the slowdown in M2 was to some extent a
permanent phenomenon related to restructuring
(both regulatory and technical) in the financial
industry, then error-learning models might even­
tually go off track as well. Indeed, this appears to
be the case, as the Board’s error-learning model
has recently been overpredicting money growth.
The standard model has been modified by
adding other variables as well. Carlson and
Byrne (1992) and Duca (1993a) both included
variables that accounted for the impact of thrift
closings. Duca (1993b) further modified the
model by changing the dependent variable to
be M2 plus various measures of households’
holdings of bond mutual funds. He found that
both the assets of bond mutual funds and RTC
activity helped explain the missing M2.
Instead of reworking conventional moneydemand models, many economists have suggested
abandoning M2 as an aggregate and replacing
it with another, more predictable (they hope)
aggregate. The search for a replacement to M2
has given rise to a cottage industry of constructing
and testing alternative aggregates. Among the
proposed successors to M2 are M l, M l A, liquid
M2 (M2 less small time deposits), MZM (M2 less
small time deposits plus assets of institution-only
money market mutual funds), M2E (M2 plus assets
of institution-only money funds), household M2

11

(M2 less demand deposits, and overnight RPs
and Eurodollars), M2BF (M2 plus bond mutual
funds) and, most recently, M2+ (M2 plus
household holdings of bond and equity
mutual funds).4
To date, none of these proposed aggregates
has been particularly well-received because all
are plagued by theoretical or empirical difficulties.
With respect to M l and M lA , recent history
clearly demonstrates that they are too highly
interest elastic to serve as a useful indicator
of income growth. Liquid M2, considered by
Wenninger and Partlan (1992), among others,
seems appealing on the theoretical grounds
that small CDs are neither very liquid nor trans­
action balances; liquid M2, however, suffers
from the same interest-elasticity problem as M l.
Moreover, the velocity of liquid M2 has been
less predictable than that of M2 itself. Poole’s
proposed aggregate, MZM, is subject to the same
criticism and would additionally include a com­
ponent (institution-only money funds) that is
extremely sensitive to money market pressures
and thus is highly volatile. Institutional investors
will make large adjustments in their holdings of
money funds in response to very small differen­
tials between market rates and those on money
funds. This sensitivity was demonstrated in
February 1994, when nearly $16 billion flowed
out of institution-only money funds following a
0.25 percentage point increase in the federal
funds rate.
M2BF and M2+ are not trouble-free, either on
empirical or theoretical grounds. Each attempts
to internalize some of the observed substitution
between M2 and long-term mutual funds. These
aggregates therefore should have a more stable
relationship to nominal income than M2 alone.
The empirical evidence, however, suggests that
these aggregates may not be much more stable
than M2. For instance, Orphanides, Reid and
Small (1994) point out that the velocity of M2+,
although perhaps more predictable than that of
M2, would have led to substantial overpredictions
4 Monetary economists in other industrialized countries have
grappled with similar problems as their official monetary
aggregates have succumbed to financial innovation and
deregulation. In Canada, McPhail (1993) proposed an M2+
aggregate consisting of M2 balances plus savings bonds
and short-term Treasury securities. Arestis and others
(1993) discussed the difficulties faced by the Bank of
England in defining and controlling monetary aggregates
during the 1980s. They concluded that “trying to target the
growth rate of broad monetary aggregates in the UK...has
always been problematic because of the weak and some­




of GDP growth during the past few years, just
like M2 (indeed, the velocity of M2+ grew quite
rapidly in early 1994). In part, these overpredic­
tions may not stem from the definition of the
augmented aggregate but rather from an inappro­
priate measuring of the opportunity cost variable.
The authors use the slope of the yield curve as a
proxy for the yield advantage of holding bond and
equity funds; however, there is no necessary reason
why the yield on long-term bonds should be a
good proxy for the return on equities. Moreover,
one can argue that if the expectations hypothesis
is true, the yield on short-term Treasury securities
should adequately measure the opportunity cost.5
Difficult issues arise on the theoretical side
as well. For instance, should we add just bond
funds to M2, or should equity funds be included
as well? Duca (1993) focused mainly on bond
funds on the grounds that equity funds carry
substantial principal risk and therefore are less
substitutable for M2 balances. The liquidity of
equity funds, however, suggests that there may
be some benefit to including these funds in an
augmented aggregate. A thornier issue is the
treatment of capital gains. Orphanides, Reid
and Small (1994) note that excluding capital
gains from net assets could lead to substantial
misestimates of potential balances and introduce
an element of arbitrariness into measuring the
aggregates, but including capital gains may permit
changes in interest rates or equity prices to intro­
duce excessive volatility into the aggregate. As
a consequence, the M2+ aggregate, although it
has the advantage of internalizing portfolio shifts
between mutual funds and M2, will be quite
sensitive to movements in bond and equity prices.
This problem poses difficulties, but the difficulties
may be somewhat less severe than the problems
affecting the alternative aggregates discussed
earlier. Nonetheless, in order to better interpret
the movements in M2+, one must track capital
gains and losses.
In this paper, we focus on issues related to
the construction of M2+. These issues include
times perverse relationships between the level of absolute
rates and the relative rates which form the key to [money
targeting].” To our knowledge, though, economists in the
United States were the first to propose incorporating bond
and equity mutual funds into a monetary aggregate.
5 This point is a matter of debate. For a contrary view, see
Feinman and Porter (1992).

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

12

Figure 3
Net Assets of Bond and Equity Mutual Funds
Billions of dollars
1600 '
1400 '
1200

'

1000

-

800 600 400 200

-

0 1980 81

“ I-----------i---------- r —

82

83

84

85

i---------- i---------- i---------- i---------- i---------- i-----------i---------- i---------- r - 1

86

the following: Should we exclude from M2+
the assets of mutual funds devoted to retirement
accounts? Should we exclude the liquid assets
held by mutual funds on the grounds that such
assets are “money” and have already been
counted in M2? Should we exclude the assets
of international funds, whose underlying invest­
ments are denominated in currencies other than
dollars and thus may not reflect purchasing power
within the United States? More pragmatically,
do the data exist to make such adjustments?

RECENT HISTORY OF THE M U T U A L
FUND INDUSTRY
Net assets of stock and bond mutual funds
were nearly $1.5 trillion at the end of 1993,
about 24 times higher than in 1980 (Figure 3).
Most of this dramatic growth reflected heavy
purchases of fund shares by investors, as
opposed to revaluations of fund investments.
6 A mutual fund is a type of investment company. It sells
shares representing an interest in a pool of securities. The
minimum initial investment for many long-term funds is
around $2,500, in contrast to, say, the $10,000 minimum
investment needed to purchase a Treasury bill. For a more

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



87

88

89

90

91

92

93 1994

During the 1980s, net purchases of bond and
equity mutual funds averaged $54 billion per year.
The upswing during the 1980s was prompted,
in part, by rising stock and bond prices. With
incomes and wealth rising, investors were inter­
ested in taking advantage of potential gains in
equity and bond markets, and mutual funds
permitted small investors to invest in a diversified
portfolio at low cost.6 Investor interest may also
have been spurred between 1982 and 1986 by
the incentives to invest in individual retirement
accounts (IRA) and Keogh accounts.7
The popularity of bond and equity mutual
funds soared in the early 1990s. Two record
years were reported in 1992 and 1993, when
investors made net purchases of $202 billion
and $266 billion, respectively (Figure 4). The
increased pace of purchases stemmed, in large
part, from the low-interest rate environment and
the steepness of the yield curve. In early 1989,
complete discussion of recent trends in the mutual fund
industry, see Mack (1993).
7 IRAs and Keogh accounts are two types of tax-sheltered
accounts that are used to save for retirement.

13

Figure 4
Net Flows into Long-Term Bond and Equity Mutual Funds
Billions of dollars, 12-month sum

Net flow equals total sales less redemptions.

Figure 5
Yields on Treasury Bills and Bonds
Yield in percent




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

14

Table 1
Bond and Equity Bank-Related Mutual Funds

1989

1990

1991

Total assets of bank-related funds

9.8

13.1

26.4

Percent of industry assets

1.7

2.3

3.3

Number of funds

1989

1990

1991

Total bank-related mutual funds

213

271

359

Percent of all mutual funds

9.5

11.5

13.8

Dollar Value of Assets1

1992

1993

19942

46.7

85.5

96.4

4.4

5.7

6.3

1992

1993

1994

502

954

1211

16.8

26.2

31.1

Source: Upper Analytical Services and Investment Company Institute.
1 Billions of dollars
2 Observation for 1994 is June.

the yield curve was essentially flat. Between
March 1989 and December 1993, the yield on
three-month Treasury bills fell by about 6 per­
centage points to around 3 percent, while the
yield on 30-year bonds fell by 3 percentage
points to about 6.25 percent (Figure 5). At the
same time, equity prices were rising. Over the
24 months from January 1992 to December 1993,
the stock market advanced just over 20 percent.
In this rate environment, investors sought the
higher returns available in long-term mutual
funds. Equity funds were also apparently boosted
by households substituting out of direct purchases
of equities. The flow-of-funds accounts show
that households’ direct holdings of equities fell
$21 billion in 1993, in contrast with the $140
billion of inflows into equity mutual funds.
Faced with a loss of deposits to mutual
funds, many banks began entering the mutual
fund business in the late 1980s. Since 1989,
the assets of bank-related mutual funds have
increased tremendously, relative to the total
assets of the mutual fund industry. As shown in
the top panel of Table 1, long-term bank-related
mutual funds accounted for only about 2 percent
of total assets of long-term funds in 1989, but this
figure had more than tripled by mid-1994. As
the bottom panel of Table 1 shows, the number
of long-term funds offered by banks climbed
even faster, experiencing more than a fivefold
increase from 1989 to mid-1994. In contrast,
for the industry as a whole, the number of long­
term funds less than doubled over the same

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



period (from 2,242 funds to 3,894 funds). As a
result, the banking sector created nearly 60 per­
cent of all new long-term funds over this period.
The watershed year for bank-related long-term
funds was 1992, when the average number of
funds sold per bank jumped sharply. In that
year, Nationsbank started 55 new long-term
funds, and many other banks plunged into
the business as well.

ARE MUTUAL FUND SHARES MONEY?
Economists have typically asked two questions
when designing monetary aggregates: Do the assets
in question serve as a transaction balance or a
medium of exchange, and is the asset readily
convertible into a transaction balance? For our
purposes, we consider to what extent shares held
in long-term mutual funds may be used as payment
for goods, services or other assets. We also explore
whether individuals consider fund shares to be
readily convertible into transaction balances.
Investments in bond and equity mutual
funds cannot generally be used as a medium
of exchange or as a transaction balance. Some
bond funds are exceptions. Bond funds some­
times offer a check-writing option that permits
investors to make purchases by writing a check
directly against their bond fund assets. Thus,
there is good reason to consider some portion
of the assets of bond funds to be transaction
balances. Indeed, check writing is nearly uni­
versal among money market mutual funds,
whose assets are included in M2. On the other

15

hand, although both money market funds and
bond funds typically impose minimum dollar
amounts on checks written against them (often
$500), the check-writing feature of bond funds
is usually less flexible, because they sometimes
impose maximum dollar amounts (often 50 per­
cent of an investor’s total bond fund assets).8
Irrespective of the check-writing features they
offer, mutual funds can be quite liquid. Investors
can usually redeem assets by telephone and have
the proceeds wired to their checking or money
market fund the same day.9 Moreover, the vast
majority of fund complexes (a group of funds
managed by the same advisor) routinely offer
exchange privileges at nominal cost or no cost.
Exchange privileges allow investors to shift assets
between long-term funds and money market funds
(or other long-term funds) within their complex.
Thus, a telephone call again allows fund investors
to shift in and out of M2-type accounts (that is,
retail money market mutual funds). Figure 6
shows the cumulative sum of net exchanges out
of money market funds into long-term funds for
the years 1989 to 1993. This sum rose during the
1990-93 period, when the M2 forecasting equation
went off track. Although the cumulative sum is
not particularly large, relative to the $380 billion
of missing M2, it does suggest that there is a
quantitatively important, and technologically
direct, substitution between a component of M2
and long-term mutual funds. One factor that
tempers this argument is that some mutual funds
charge exit fees (back-end loads). By raising
transaction costs, back-end loads reduce substi­
tutability between long-term mutual funds and
M2 balances.
Another way to decide whether an asset is
“money” is to look at its turnover rate, measured
as total withdrawals divided by outstanding
balances. Spindt (1985) argued that transaction
accounts have high turnover rates; therefore, the
higher the transaction balance, the greater the
degree of “moneyness.” Figure 7 shows turnover
rates for some of the components of M2, along
with turnover rates for equity and bond funds.
Turnover rates for checkable deposits are quite
high, reflecting their use as the primary transaction
account for most households. Turnover rates
on savings accounts and money market mutual
funds are somewhat lower. Turnover ratios on

8 Maximums are imposed to prevent an investor from incurring an overdraft if bond prices fell sharply on the day that
the check clears.




long-term funds are quite low, an indication that
individuals regard these accounts mainly as sav­
ings vehicles, rather than transaction balances.
Figure 7 lacks one important series: the turnover
ratio for small time deposits. Unfortunately, the
Federal Reserve does not collect this information.
Staff at the Federal Reserve Board, however, have
estimated that the turnover ratio for small time
deposits is on the order to 1 percent to 1.5 percent
at an annual rate, which is reasonably close to
the estimated turnover ratio for long-term funds.
In summary, there are some reasons to think
of the assets of bond and equity mutual funds as
“money,” or at least close substitutes for money.
Although the reasons for believing mutual fund
assets to be money are not overwhelmingly strong,
they are about as favorable as the case for calling
small time deposits money. Both small time
deposits and long-term mutual fund assets are
mainly savings balances, as opposed to transaction
balances. Both have a high degree of substi­
tutability (or potential substitutability) with other
kinds of M2 balances. In addition, investors in
these instruments may face some penalty for
withdrawing their balances.

DESIRED DATA
The current monetary aggregates measure the
public’s holdings of money first by summing the
total outstanding amounts of instruments deemed
to be money and then subtracting money holdings
of the U.S. government, foreign governments,
depository institutions, and money market mutual
funds. (Table 2 shows the construction of M2.)
The current aggregates also attempt to distinguish
between individual (retail) and institutional
holdings of money market mutual funds. This
distinction is based on the belief that individuals’
holdings of money market mutual funds are more
closely related to consumption and income than
are institutions’ holdings, which are more tightly
linked to financial market conditions. In practice,
however, making such a distinction is difficult
because data on money funds are available only
by type of fund, not by type of holder. Conse­
quently, the distinction between retail and
institutional money funds is not clear cut: Funds
deemed to be institution-only funds accept
investments from individuals as long as those
individuals meet the sizable minimum investment

9 Proceeds can also be mailed by check, but this option would
reduce liquidity relative to the wire transfer option,

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

16

Figure 6
Net Exchanges Into Long-Term Funds from Money Market
Mutual Funds
Billions of dollars

Figure 7
Turnover Ratios of Selected Financial Assets
Turnover ratio (annualized)/log scale

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



17

requirements, and institutions can invest in
retail funds.10
The guiding principle we followed when
constructing M2+ was to parallel the current
construction of M2. The data needed to add bond
and equity mutual funds to M2 are in many ways
similar to those that were needed to incorporate
money market mutual funds into M2. We must
be able to measure the total net assets of long-term
mutual funds and, for netting purposes, the
monetary investments of such funds, as well
as balances held by institutions or invested in
retirement accounts. Table 3 summarizes the
series necessary for the construction of M2+.
The first requirement for building M2+ is an
accurate measure of total net assets of bond and
equity mutual funds. Total net assets of a mutual
fund are simply its total assets— essentially the
market value of its securities portfolio—less its
total liabilities, which include such items as
accounts payable (for investments purchased or
shares redeemed), accrued management fees,
and other accrued expenses." We included
reinvested dividends and capital gains in order
to treat these items like interest credited on
deposits, which is included in M2.
The second requirement is to distinguish
between mutual fund holdings of individual
and institutional investors. In order to parallel
the current treatment of money market mutual
funds, we would split bond and equity mutual
funds into retail and institution-only funds; we
cannot do so, however, because long-term funds
typically accept investments from both individual
and institutional investors. Therefore, we need
data on holdings of long-term mutual funds by
type of investor, with individual holdings
appearing in M2+.
Bond and equity mutual funds invest in
instruments included in the monetary aggregates.
If the total net assets of these funds were simply
added to M2, the funds’ holdings of monetary
instruments would be counted twice because
their holdings already would be included in the
outstanding amounts of monetary instruments,
such as overnight RPs with banks. To avoid this

Table 2
Current Definitions of the Monetary
Aggregates_______________________
M1 =

currency (public holdings)
+ travelers checks of nonbank issuers
+ demand deposits at all commercial banks
(less cash items in the process of collection and
Federal Reserve float)
- demand deposits due to depository institutions,
the U.S. government, foreign banks, and foreign
official institutions
+ other checkable deposits

M2 =

M1
+ overnight and continuing contract RPs issued by
all depository institutions
+ overnight Eurodollars issued to U.S. residents by
foreign branches of U.S. banks worldwide
+ savings deposits (including money market
deposit accounts)
+ small-denomination time deposits
+ balances at retail money market mutual funds
- U.S. commercial bank, U.S. government, foreign
government, foreign commercial bank, and retail
money market mutual fund holdings of all non-M1
components
- IRA/Keogh balances at depository institutions
and money market mutual funds

double counting, monetary investments of long­
term funds should be excluded from M2+, just
as holdings of monetary instruments by money
funds and depository institutions are excluded
from M2. Therefore, we need data on bond and
equity fund holdings of overnight Eurodollars
and overnight RPs with depository institutions.
Moreover, the data ideally would allow us to
apportion these so-called netting items between
those due to retail investors and those due to
institutional investors.
Finally, paralleling the current aggregates
requires us to exclude from the M2+ aggregate
IRA and Keogh balances held as bond and equity

10 Institution-only money funds are funds that impose high min­
imum balances on shareholders. These minimums— usually
$50,000— are prohibitively high for the great majority of retail
customers.
11 The value of a share in a long-term fund is calculated each
day by dividing the total net assets of the fund by the num­
ber of shares outstanding.




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

18

mutual fund shares. IRA/Keogh accounts are
savings vehicles and typically are not used for
transaction purposes. Indeed, these accounts
are extremely illiquid because federal law imposes
stiff penalties for withdrawals before retirement.
Of course, for individuals of retirement age (59and-a-half or older), IRA/Keogh balances are
liquid. As a practical matter, though, it would
be nearly impossible to estimate the percentage
of IRA/Keogh balances that might be considered
liquid. As a result, instead of making an arbitrary
assumption about the proportion of IRA/Keogh
balances that are liquid, M2 simply excludes all
IRA/Keogh balances held in deposit accounts
and money market funds, and we follow that
approach for M2+ by removing balances held in
IRA/Keogh accounts from the measure of total
net assets of long-term funds.

ACTUAL CONSTRUCTION OF M2+
Not all of the desired data set forth in the
previous section are available. This section
therefore discusses data availability and gives
the technical details on how the augmented
aggregate M2+ was constructed. (Table 4
provides a summary.)
The Investment Company Institute (ICI) is
a prominent source of mutual fund data. It is
funded by contributions from its members, which
comprise the vast majority of investment compa­
nies. On behalf of the Federal Reserve, ICI has
been collecting data on money funds for over 12
years, including data on their assets, their invest­
ments and their IRA/Keogh balances. These
s e r ie s a re u s e d in th e c o n s tr u c tio n o f M 2 , M 3

and L. We have used ICI’s data on long-term
funds to construct M2+.

Net Asset Data
Monthly data on the total net assets of bond
and equity mutual funds are drawn from ICI’s
Trends in M utual F u n d Activity. This release
publishes (with a lag of about one month) data on
total net assets held by long-term funds measured
as of month-end. In 1993, ICI collected data from
over 3,000 long-term funds. From the Trends
releases, we compiled a monthly series on the
total net assets of bond and equity mutual funds
back to 1959.
We deviated from our guiding principle of
constructing M2+ like M2 in only one area: net
assets of global and international mutual funds.
These funds invest in debt and equity instruments

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




Table 3
Theoretical Definition of M2+
M2+ =

current M2
+ net assets of bond funds held by individual
investors
+ net assets of equity funds held by individual
investors
- bond and equity fund holdings of overnight RPs
attributable to individuals
- bond and equity fund holdings of overnight
Eurodollars attributable to individuals
- IRA and Keogh holdings at bond and equity
mutual funds

denominated in foreign currencies, as well as
those denominated in dollars. Although M2
excludes deposits denominated in foreign cur­
rencies, we incorporated the assets of these types
of funds in M2+. This treatment seems justified
by the following considerations. First, doing so
permits M2+ to internalize substitutions between
non-dollar-denominated and dollar-denominated funds. Second, the foreign currency deposits
netted from M2 have been quite small, amounting
to only a few billion dollars. Moreover, these
assets are thought to be held by institutions,
mainly for clearing purposes. Thus, the netting
of these assets has little impact on the monetary
aggregates, and doing so skirts a difficult theo­
retical issue: Are non-dollar-denominated
assets money in the United States? This issue
cannot be swept aside when considering long­
term mutual funds. The assets of international
mutual funds are thought to be held mainly by
retail investors and are growing rapidly.
Although
the underlying investments of these funds are
denominated in foreign currencies, these funds’
net asset values (share prices) are reported in
dollars and thus may be viewed by retail
investors as liquid investments that are highly
substitutable for assets in M2 or for other kinds
of mutual funds whose underlying investments
are denominated in dollars. Finally, because of
data limitations, it would be very difficult to
extract only the dollar-denominated holdings
of these funds for inclusion in M2+.

Institutional Holdings
In order to apportion the total net assets of

19

Table 4
Actual Construction of M2+

holdings on a monthly basis. Nonetheless,
analyses of the long-run behavior of M2+ likely
would not be impaired much because, by con­
struction, the interpolated series is tied to ICI’s
year-end observations.

M2+ = current M2
+ net assets of bond funds

Liquid Investments

+ net assets of equity funds

The current monetary aggregates, M2 and M3,
are constructed to avoid double-counting of assets.
For example, the RP and Eurodollar investments
of money market mutual funds are excluded from
the monetary aggregates to avoid counting them
twice: once in the money fund component of M2,
and again in the RP and Eurodollar components
of M2. To avoid double-counting when con­
structing M2+, we needed data on long-term
mutual fund holdings of M2 instruments, such as
overnight RPs and Eurodollars. Most bond and
equity mutual funds hold a portion of their port­
folios in liquid investments to meet investors’
demands for share redemption. ICI has collected
monthly data on the total liquid investments of
long-term funds since 1960, with a detailed break­
down of such investments into short-term
Treasury securities, short-term municipal secu­
rities, and “cash and other receivables” beginning
in 1991. Nonetheless, this breakdown is still too
aggregated for our purposes. Rather than arbitrarily
create a series on long-term mutual funds holdings
of M2-type assets, which would consist principally
of overnight RPs and Eurodollars, we chose to
make no adjustment at all. Our view was that these
holdings would be a relatively small portion of
M2+ and that any assumption we might make to
remove them could well introduce greater error into
M2+ than that caused by double-counting them.

- institutional holdings of bond and equity funds
- IRA and Keogh assets at bond and equity funds

long-term mutual funds between retail and insti­
tutional holdings, we made use of the ICI’s survey
of institutional holdings of long-term mutual
funds. ICI first surveyed such holdings in 1954
and did so biennially until 1980. Since that time,
its survey has been conducted annually. In the
survey, mutual funds report the percent of their
assets held by various institutions on the last
day of the calendar year. Among the largest
institutional holders are fiduciaries (bank trust
departments) and retirement plans. The data are
disaggregated enough to permit us to apportion
institutional holdings of mutual funds between
long-term funds and money market funds for
survey dates back to 1974. For earlier years, we
have assumed that the assets of money market
mutual funds were zero; thus, any institutional
holdings in these years are allocated to long­
term funds.
We had to make several adjustments to the raw
data in order to derive a monthly series on insti­
tutional holdings. First, we adjusted for the
changes in the format of ICI’s survey by making
several ad hoc adjustments to remove the breaks
in the series. Second, we converted the breakadjusted series into monthly observations. We
did so by linearly interpolating between surveys
the end-of-year ratio of institutional assets to total
net assets of long-term funds. Third, we multi­
plied each of the resulting monthly ratios by
total net assets in the corresponding month to
derive the series on institutional holdings. We
could then construct a series on retail holdings
of long-term mutual funds by subtracting our
institutional series from total net assets. The
resulting series therefore may be subject to con­
siderable month-to-month error because of the
assumptions required to estimate institutional
12 Only year-end figures on these assets are available for
1981 and 1982. Quarter-end figures are available for IRA
accounts from 1975 to 1980 and from 1964 to 1980 for




IRA/Keogh Assets
Retirement account balances are thought to be
too illiquid to be used as transaction balances.
Consequently, the monetary aggregates exclude
balances in IRA and Keogh accounts. To parallel
this treatment, we used ICI’s data on IRA/Keogh
balances in long-term mutual funds to exclude
such holdings from M2+. Month-end data on the
assets of bond and equity mutual funds that are
held in IRA and Keogh accounts balances begin in
January 1983. Data for earlier periods are avail­
able either quarterly or annually.12 For years prior
to 1983, we constructed monthly observations on
Keogh accounts. Earlier data for IRA accounts are not avail­
able, but balances in these accounts were essentially nil
before 1977.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

20

IRA/Keogh balances of long-term funds by linearly
interpolating the ratio of IRA/Keogh assets to total
net assets of long-term funds between the quarterly
or annual observations. We then multiplied this
interpolated ratio by the total net assets of long­
term funds for the corresponding month.13

Deriving Monthly Averages
ICI’s long-term mutual fund data are monthend observations. M2 is a monthly average
derived from either daily or weekly data,
depending on the component. In order to add the
mutual fund data to M2, items related to mutual
funds had to be converted to a month-average
basis. We approximated monthly averages for
ICI’s data by taking two-month moving averages
of the month-end figures for total net assets,
institutional holdings and IRA/Keogh balances.

Seasonal Adjustment
As Figure 8 shows, some of the components
of the monetary aggregates have large seasonal
regularities. Seasonality in the aggregates arises
primarily from their transaction nature; for
instance, currency demand is seasonally high
in December because of Christmas shopping.
Tax payments, other holidays and interest cred­
iting also occur seasonally. If the monetary
aggregates were not adjusted for seasonal varia­
tion, it would be hard to discern changes in
money demand related to movements in interest
rates and income. Because it is these latter effects
that are of primary interest to policymakers,
seasonal adjustment of the monetary aggregates
is imperative.
As a rule, seasonality is strongest within the
components of M l and less so for those in nonM l M2 because the components of non-M l M2
are not used as extensively as M l for transaction
purposes (Figure 9). With respect to long-term
mutual fund assets, which we have suggested may
be driven less by transaction motives than by
savings motives, one might expect to find weak,
or nonexistent, seasonality. If so, it would obviate
13 There are many other types of retirement vehicles, such as
employer-sponsored retirement plans and annuities; however,
only IRA/Keogh balances are subtracted from M2. The
measure of M2+ that we constructed did not include balances
in retirement accounts other than IRA and Keogh accounts
because these accounts are included in ICI’s measure of
institutional holdings. Thus, subtracting institutional holdings
from total net assets removes these balances from M2+.
Strictly speaking, we have again deviated from our practice
of paralleling the construction of M2, but we do not feel that
the deviation impairs the usefulness of the M2+ aggregate.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




the need for us to seasonally adjust such assets
before adding them to M2. Figure 10 indicates
that there is indeed little apparent seasonality
in the assets of mutual funds.
Nevertheless, our guiding principle of paral­
leling the current construction of M2 dictates
that mutual fund assets should be seasonally
adjusted before adding them to M2. Accordingly,
we used the following seasonal adjustment pro­
cedure. We constructed a not-seasonally adjusted
(NSA) measure of household holdings of mutual
fund assets, called the “plus” portion of M2+, as
shown in Table 4. This component is the assets
of bond and equity funds less institutional hold­
ings and IRA/Keogh balances. The “plus” portion
is then seasonally adjusted using Census X - l l ,
assuming multiplicative seasonality.14 Seasonally
adjusted M2+ is constructed by adding the sea­
sonally adjusted “plus” portion to seasonally
adjusted M2. A comparison of M2 and M2+ is
shown in Figure 11, and Appendix 1 provides
estimates of M2+ for recent years.15

CONCLUDING REMARKS
This paper has detailed construction of an
alternative monetary aggregate that adds house­
hold holdings of bond and equity mutual funds
to M2. This aggregate has the advantage of
internalizing some of the observed substitution
between long-term mutual funds and M2 bal­
ances. The empirical evidence discussed by
Orphanides, Reid and Small (1994) suggests
that M2+ does have some advantages over M2,
in that its velocity appears to have been more
“sensible” over the past few years. Consequently,
the predictability of GDP is improved. A major
drawback of this aggregate, however, is that it is
very sensitive to movements in bond and equity
prices. For example, in early 1994, the velocity
of M2+ rose sharply, in large part reflecting
declines in bond and equity prices, and it remains
to be seen whether the velocity of M2+ will return
to its trend level. In fact, the only sure test of a
monetary aggregate is the test of time. If financial

14 This algorithm is essentially the same one used to seasonally
adjust the current monetary aggregates. For a complete
description of that algorithm, see Farley and O’Brien (1987).
15 The reader is referred to Orphanides, Reid and Small (1994)
for a discussion of the empirical properties of M2+.

Figure 8
Seasonality in Selected Components of M2 (billions of dollars)
First Differences in Currency
6

First Differences in Demand Deposits
15

to

First Differences in Savings (including MMDAs)
25

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER
1994

1990
1991




1992
1993

First Differences in Small Time Deposits

10

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Figure 9
Seasonality in Selected Monetary Aggregates (billions of dollars)
First Differences in M1

First Differences in M2

30

30

20

20
10

10

0
0
-10

-10

-20

-20

-30

hJ
N>
First Differences in Non-M1 M2
20

15 10-

5-

o-5 -

10-

-15 -

20-

-25 -

1990
1991




First Differences in Non-M2 M3
15

-

1992
1993

23

Figure 10
Seasonality in Assets of Long-Term Mutual Funds
Growth rate of assets of bond and equity mutual funds (annualized)

Figure 11
M2, and M2 Plus Household Holdings of Bond and Equity Mutual Funds
Billions of dollars




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

24

innovation continues at a rapid pace in the 1990s
and depositories continue to lose their share of
credit intermediation, then the usefulness of
M2+ as an indicator of economic activity may
grow as intermediation continues to shift to
mutual funds.

REFERENCES
Arestis, Philip, I. Mariscal Biefang-Frisancho, and P.G.A.
Howells. “UK Monetary Aggregates— Definition and Control,”
in Philip Arestis, ed., Money and Banking, Issues for the
Twenty-First Century, Essays in Honour o f Stephen F.
Frowen. St. Martin’s Press, pp. 163-91.
Carlson, John B., and Susan M. Byrne. “Recent Behavior of
Velocity: Alternative Measures of Money” , Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland Quarterly Review (second quarter 1992),
pp. 2-10.
Duca, John. “Should Bond Funds be Included in M2” , Journal
o f Banking and Finance (forthcoming).
_____ . “RTC Activity and the ‘Missing M2,’ Economics Letters
(No. 1, 1993), pp. 67-71.
Farley, Dennis, and Yuch-Yun C. O’Brien. “Seasonal
Adjustment of the Money Stock in the United States,”
Journal of Official Statistics, vol. 3 (No. 3, 1987), pp. 223-33.
Feinman, Joshua, and Richard Porter. ‘T he Continuing
Weakness in M2” , Federal Reserve Board FEDS Paper
#209 (September 1992).
Hallman, Jeffrey J., and Richard G. Anderson. “Has the Longrun Velocity of M2 Shifted? Evidence from the P* Model,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland Economic Review (first
quarter 1993), pp. 14-26.
Hendry, David F., and Neil R. Ericsson. “Modeling the Demand
for Narrow Money in the U.K. and the United States,”

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




Federal Reserve Board International Finance Discussion
Papers #383 (1990).
Higgins, Bryon. “Policy Implications of Recent M2 Behavior,”
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review
(third quarter 1992), pp. 21-36.
Investment Company Institute. Trends in Mutual Fund Activity.
October 1994.
Mack, Philip R. “Recent Trends in the Mutual Fund Industry,”
Federal Reserve Bulletin (November 1993), pp. 1001-12.
McPhail, Kim. “The Demand for M2+, Canada Savings Bonds,
and Treasury Bills,” Bank of Canada Working Paper 93-8
(September 1993).
Moore, George, Richard Porter, and David H. Small. “Modeling
the Disaggregated Demands for M2 and M1: The U.S.
Experience in the 1980s”, in Peter Hooper and others, eds.,
Financial Sectors in Open Economies: Empirical Analysis
and Policy Issues. Federal Reserve Board of Governors,
1990, pp. 21-105.
Orphanides, Athanasios, Brian Reid, and David H. Small “The
Empirical Properties of a Monetary Aggregate That Adds
Bond and Stock Funds to M2”, this Review
(November/December 1994), pp. 31-51.
Poole, William. Statement Before the Subcommittee on
Domestic Monetary Policy of the Committee on Banking,
Finance and Urban Affairs, U.S. House of Representatives.
November 6, 1991.
Spindt, Paul A. “Money is What Money Does: Monetary
Aggregation and the Equation of Exchange,” Journal of
Political Economy (No. 1, 1985), pp. 175-204.
Wenninger, John, and John Partlan. “Small Time Deposits and
the Recent Weakness in M2”, Federal Reserve Bank of New
York Quarterly Review (spring 1992), pp. 21-35.

25

Appendix 1
M2 and M2 Plus Bond and Stock Mutual Funds (M2+)
Levels
(billions of $)
M2
(1)

Growth rates
M2+
(2)

M2
(3)

M2+
(4)

Difference
(4)-(3)

Monthly
1993
1993
1993
1993
1993
1993
1993
1993
1993
1993
1993
1993
1994
1994
1994
1994
1994
1994

1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
1
2
3
4
5
6

$ 3502.8
3494.2
3494.8
3498
3521.9
3528.7
3533.7
3536
3544.2
3547.8
3560.1
3567.6
3572.8
3568.9
3582.9
3589.9
3590.9
3581.3

$ 4046.7
4063.6
4066.2
4072.8
4108.1
4128.5
4148.3
4169.2
4201.8
4225.6
4252.3
4265.1
4278.9
4280
4276.7
4277.1
4278
4263.8

-2.1
-2.9
.2
1.0
8.1
2.3
1.6
.7
2.7
1.2
4.1
2.5
1.7
-1.2
4.6
2.3
.3
-3.1

3.5
5.0
.7
1.9
10.4
5.9
5.7
6.0
9.3
6.8
7.5
3.6
3.8
.3
-.9
.1
.2
-3.9

-5.6
-7.9
-.5
-.8
-2.2
-3.6
-4.0
-5.2
-6.6
-5.5
-3.4
-1.0
-2.1
-1.6
5.6
2.2
.0
.7

1991
1991
1991
1991
1992
1992
1992
1992
1993
1993
1993
1993
1994
1994

1
2
3
4
1
2
3
4
1
2
3
4
1
2

3380.6
3418.2
3427.1
3444.3
3478
3480.6
3488.9
3509
3497.3
3516.2
3538
3558.5
3574.9
3587.4

3702.5
3765.8
3796.3
3851.2
3912.6
3935.7
3974
4022
4058.8
4103.1
4173.1
4247.7
4278.5
4273

3.8
4.4
1.0
2.0
3.9
.2
.9
2.3
1.3
2.1
2.4
2.3
1.8
1.3

5.5
6.8
3.2
5.7
6.3
2.3
3.8
4.8
3.6
4.3
6.8
7.1
2.9
-.5

-1.7
-2.3
-2.1
-3.7
-2.4
-2.0
-2.9
-2.5
-5.0
-2.2
-4.3
-4.8
-1.0
1.9

2916.6
3070.6
3219.2
3348.5
3444.3
3509
3558.5

3197.4
3353.9
3535.3
3651.6
3851.2
4022
4247.7

4.3
5.2
4.8
4.0
2.8
1.8
1.4

4.9
4.8
5.4
3.2
5.4
4.4
5.6

-.6
.3
-.5
.7
-2.6
-2.5
-4.2

Quarterly

Annual (Q4/Q4)
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993

1 The market value of mutual funds balances added to M2 excludes balances in IRA/Keogh accounts and institutional holdings of
long-term mutual funds. Data are seasonally adjusted.




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

26

Appendix 2
Levels of the Augmented Aggregate M2+
T h e ta b le p r e s e n ts le v e ls f o r t h e a u g m e n te d a g g re g a te , M 2 + , as w e l l as M 2 . M 2 + w a s c o n s t r u c t e d
u s in g t h e f o r m u la s i n T a b le 4 a n d s e a s o n a lly a d ju s te d as d e s c r ib e d i n t h e t e x t.

Month

M2+

M2

Month

M2+

M2

Month

M2+

M2

1959

1

299.3

286.6

1964

1

419.2

395.4

1969

1

615.5

569.3

1959

2

300.5

287.7

1964

2

421.6

397.6

1969

2

617.2

571.5

1959

3

302.0

289.0

1964

3

424.0

399.5

1969

3

618.9

573.9

1959

4

303.4

290.1

1964

4

426.3

401.7

1969

4

621.0

575.9

1959

5

305.9

292.2

1964

5

429.0

404.2

1969

5

622.2

576.5

1959

6

307.8

293.9

1964

6

432.2

406.8

1969

6

623.3

578.4

1959

7

309.6

295.3

1964

7

436.4

410.1

1969

7

623.2

579.8

1959

8

310.8

296.4

1964

8

439.7

413.3

1969

8

623.5

580.5

1959

9

310.7

296.4

1964

9

443.1

416.5

1969

9

625.5

582.2

1959

10

310.9

296.5

1964

10

446.1

419.2

1969

10

627.8

583.8

1959

11

311.5

297.1

1964

11

448.9

422.2

1969

11

630.8

586.9

1959

12

312.1

297.7

1964

12

451.4

424.7

1969

12

631.9

589.5

1960

1

312.4

298.2

1965

1

454.7

427.8

1970

1

631.1

591.1

1960

2

312.4

298.5

1965

2

457.8

430.4

1970

2

628.8

588.5

1960

3

313.2

299.2

1965

3

460.5

433.0

1970

3

630.9

589.3

1960

4

314.1

300.0

1965

4

463.1

435.5

1970

4

629.0

590.4

1960

5

315.2

300.9

1965

5

465.0

437.0

1970

5

628.8

593.5

1960

6

316.9

302.1

1965

6

467.5

439.8

1970

6

631.0

597.1

1960

7

319.2

304.2

1965

7

470.7

442.8

1970

7

635.8

600.4

1960

8

321.9

306.8

1965

8

474.3

445.6

1970

8

643.0

606.1

1960

9

323.3

308.2

1965

9

478.6

449.1

1970

9

650.2

612.4

1960

10

324.6

309.5

1965

10

483.1

452.7

1970

10

656.0

617.6

1960

11

326.1

311.0

1965

11

486.8

455.9

1970

11

660.8

622.3

1960

12

327.7

312.3

1965

12

490.7

459.3

1970

12

668.1

628.1

1961

1

330.3

314.1

1966

1

494.2

462.3

1971

1

675.5

634.0

1961

2

333.5

316.6

1966

2

496.6

464.5

1971

2

685.8

642.6

1961

3

335.6

318.1

1966

3

499.1

466.9

1971

3

695.9

651.2

1961

4

337.9

319.9

1966

4

501.5

469.3

1971

4

706.5

660.5

1961

5

340.8

322.2

1966

5

501.7

469.9

1971

5

715.1

668.7

1961

6

342.9

324.1

1966

6

502.4

470.9

1971

6

720.8

674.8

1961

7

344.7

325.6

1966

7

502.8

470.8

1971

7

727.6

681.3

1961

8

347.1

327.5

1966

8

503.2

472.6

1971

8

733.5

687.4

1961

9

349.1

329.3

1966

9

504.4

475.2

1971

9

740.5

694.4

1961

10

351.5

331.2

1966

10

505.4

476.0

1971

10

745.6

700.4

1961

11

354.3

333.4

1966

11

507.6

477.4

1971

11

750.7

706.9

1961

12

356.4

335.4

1966

12

510.6

479.9

1971

12

757.9

712.6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



27

M2+

Month

M2

Month

M2+

M2

Month

M2+

M2

1972

1

766.3

719.6

1975

1

940.1

912.2

1978

1

1328

1296.2

1972

2

776.1

728.1

1975

2

949.6

920.1

1978

2

1332.2

1301.3

1972

3

784.6

735.8

1975

3

962.0

931.3

1978

3

1341.4

1308.6

1972

4

789.8

741.2

1975

4

973.4

941.5

1978

4

1350.7

1317.1

1972

5

795.3

745.9

1975

5

987.4

954.1

1978

5

1360.7

1326

1972

6

801.9

752.6

1975

6

1003.5

969.2

1978

6

1367.6

1333.3

1972

7

811.3

762.3

1975

7

1015.1

981.0

1978

7

1376.3

1341.8

1972

8

820.9

771.8

1975

8

1023

989.7

1978

8

1385.5

1350

1972

9

829.4

780.9

1975

9

1030.6

998.5

1978

9

1399

1363.3

1972

10

838.3

789.5

1975

10

1037.5

1004.7

1978

10

1407.2

1372.6

1972

11

846.2

796.6

1975

11

1048.3

1014.8

1978

11

1412.7

1379.5

1056.5

1023.2

1972

12

855.7

805.1

1975

12

1978

12

1421.8

1388.6

1973

1

861.7

813.5

1976

1

1068.2

1033.9

1979

1

1429

1395.2

1973

2

863.1

817.8

1976

2

1083.2

1047.8

1979

2

1435.7

1401.8
1412.2

1973

3

862.3

818.7

1976

3

1092.6

1057

1979

3

1446.3

1973

4

865.1

823.2

1976

4

1103.6

1068.4

1979

4

1460.6

1426.5

1973

5

870.6

830.3

1976

5

1116.3

1081.8

1979

5

1467.8

1434

1973

6

876.7

837.2

1976

6

1120.9

1086.2

1979

6

1482.2

1448.4

1973

7

882.0

841.0

1976

7

1129.4

1095.2

1979

7

1495.1

1460.9

1973

8

885.5

843.6

1976

8

1143

1109

1979

8

1505.9

1471

1973

9

886.6

844.6

1976

9

1155.6

1120.9

1979

9

1517.7

1482.8

1973

10

892.1

848.5

1976

10

1171.4

1136

1979

10

1522.4

1488.4

1973

11

894.9

854.4

1976

11

1183.8

1148.7

1979

11

1523.9

1490.5

1973

12

899.0

860.9

1976

12

1199.4

1163.6

1979

12

1530.7

1497

1974

1

902.7

865.4

1977

1

1212.6

1177.1

1980

1

1542.3

1507.8

1974

2

906.6

870.3

1977

2

1222.5

1188.3

1980

1555.8

1520.7

1974

3

911.9

876.5

1977

3

1233.3

1199.4

1980

3

1559.8

1527.3

1974

4

913.2

879.1

1977

4

1244.7

1211.2

1980

4

1554.9

1524.1

1974

5

914.1

881.2

1977

5

1254.9

1221.5

1980

5

1565.2

1532.7

1974

6

916.2

884.6

1977

6

1263.9

1230.1

1980

6

1586.6

1552.5

1974

7

918.5

888.0

1977

7

1275

1240.9

1980

7

1609.2

1573.6

1974

8

919.8

891.1

1977

8

1284.1

1250.3

1980

8

1627.9

1590.3

1974

9

921.2

895.1

1977

9

1293.9

1260.3

1980

9

1642.4

1604.5

1974

10

927.3

900.2

1977

10

1302.8

1269.9

1980

10

1654.9

1616.8

1974

11

933.7

905.4

1977

11

1311.2

1278.2

1980

11

1667

1628.9

1974

12

935.9

908.4

1977

12

1320.8

1286.5

1980

12

1667.6

1629.3




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

28

Month

M2+

M2

Month

M2+

M2

Month

M2+

M2

1981

1

1677.6

1640

1984

1

2278.5

2202.4

1987

1

3105.7

2836.8

1981

2

1689.8

1652

1984

2

2296.6

2221.2

1987

2

3121.6

2837

1981

3

1709.7

1670.8

1984

3

2311.4

2236.8

1987

3

3136.3

2841.4

1981

4

1730.5

1691.7

1984

4

2327.9

2252.8

1987

4

3152.7

2855.8

1981

5

1736.3

1697

1984

5

2341.4

2267.7

1987

5

3155.2

2860.7

1981

6

1745.4

1705.5

1984

6

2352.9

2279.8

1987

6

3159.6

2862.6

1981

7

1757.9

1718.7

1984

7

2364.7

2290.3

1987

7

3173.8

2868.8

1981

8

1773.1

1734.9

1984

8

2378.8

2299.9

1987

8

3195.2

2882.7

1981

9

1782

1745.8

1984

9

2399.7

2316.3

1987

9

3211.9

2898

1981

10

1797.1

1760.5

1984

10

2413.6

2328.7

1987

10

3207.4

2913.8

1981

11

1814.7

1776.8

1984

11

2438.1

2353.1

1987

11

3189.5

2915.8

1981

12

1831.4

1793.3

1984

12

2464.1

2377.8

1987

12

3195.4

2920.1

1982

1

1850.3

1812.6

1985

1

2495.5

2403.5

1988

1

3223.4

2944.6

1982

2

1853.2

1815.9

1985

2

2524.4

2427.2

1988

2

3245

2963.3

1982

3

1865.4

1828.5

1985

3

2536.6

2438.7

1988

3

3262.3

2981.1

1982

4

1879.8

1842.6

1985

4

2541.8

2442.2

1988

4

3282.5

3003.7

1985

5

2564.4

3021.5

1982

5

1892.2

1854.4

2457.8

1988

5

3299.4

1982

6

1902.6

1865.3

1985

6

2597.9

2484.2

1988

6

3312.3

3033.9

1982

7

1914.4

1877.1

1985

7

2619.8

2500.4

1988

7

3319.9

3041.2

1982

8

1936.2

1895.8

1985

8

2643.1

2518

1988

8

3319.2

3044.6

1982

9

1954.2

1910.7

1985

9

2661.9

2533.3

1988

9

3325.7

3047.6

1982

10

1972.8

1926

1985

10

2678.9

2543.8

1988

10

3341.5

3056.9

1982

11

1988.7

1939.2

1985

11

2702.6

2557.2

1988

11

3356.7

3073.6

1982

12

2004.3

1953.2

1985

12

2731.3

2575

1988

12

3363.5

3081.4

1983

1

2062.6

2009

1986

1

2744.3

2580

1989

1

3368.4

3085.5

1983

2

2103.9

2046.8

1986

2

2764.1

2590

1989

2

3365.6

3085.4

1983

3

2126.2

2066.1

1986

3

2798.2

2611.2

1989

3

3371.7

3093

1983

4

2146

2082.4

1986

4

2833.7

2637.6

1989

4

3380.3

3097.1

1983

5

2166.9

2099.6

1986

5

2868

2663.7

1989

5

3388.7

3099

1983

6

2181.4

2111.2

1986

6

2895.4

2684.5

1989

6

3409.5

3116.3

1983

7

2194.8

2123.6

1986

7

2926.6

2711.7

1989

7

3441.9

3143.4

1983

8

2203.1

2132.1

1986

8

2959

2734

1989

8

3466

3161.4

1983

9

2216.7

2144.2

1986

9

2987.4

2753.5

1989

9

3488.7

3178.9

1983

10

2238.9

2165.2

1986

10

3017.6

2777

1989

10

3509.5

3199

1983

11

2250.8

2177.1

1986

11

3043.6

2793

1989

11

3534.5

3218.9

1983

12

2263

2187.6

1986

12

3075.5

2818.2

1989

12

3561.9

3239.8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



29

Month

M2+

M2

Month

M2+

M2

1990

1

3563.4

3252.9

1993

1

4046.7

3502.8

1990

2

3567.3

3267.3

1993

2

4063.6

3494.2

1990

3

3582.7

3279.5

1993

3

4066.2

3494.8

1990

4

3594.4

3291.1

1993

4

4072.8

3498

1990

5

3600.4

3294

1993

5

4108.1

3521.9

1990

6

3619.8

3305.5

1993

6

4128.5

3528.7

1990

7

3631.5

3315.3

1993

7

4148.3

3533.7

1990

8

3640

3330.9

1993

8

4169.2

3536

1990

9

3644.6

3345

1993

9

4201.8

3544.2

1990

10

3644.1

3347.3

1993

10

4225.6

3547.8

1990

11

3648

3345.1

1993

11

4252.3

3560.1

1990

12

3662.8

3353

1993

12

4265.1

3567.6

1991

1

3676.6

3363.5

1994

1

4278.9

3572.8

1991

2

3700.7

3380

1994

2

4280

3568.9

1991

3

3730.3

3398.1

1994

3

4276.7

3582.9

1991

4

3750.9

3409

1994

4

4277.1

3589.9

1991

5

3767.6

3418.9

1994

5

4278

3590.9

1991

6

3778.8

3426.6

1994

6

4263.8

3581.3

1991

7

3783.3

3426.4

1991

8

3794.8

3427.4

1991

9

3810.7

3427.5

1991

10

3828.9

3432.3

1991

11

3850.8

3445.4

1991

12

3873.9

3455.3

1992

1

3892.4

3464.1

1992

2

3918

3483.6

1992

3

3927.4

3486.3

1992

4

3929.8

3481.9

1992

5

3936.3

3482.1

1992

6

3941.1

3477.8

1992

7

3956.8

3480.7

1992

8

3973.7

3489.4

1992

9

3991.7

3496.6

1992

10

4008.7

3507.5

1992

11

4022.5

3510.5

1992

12

4034.8

3509




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994




31

Athanasios Orphanides, Brian Reid and David H. Small
Athanasios Orphanides, Brian Reid and David H. Small are staff economists with the Board
of Governors o f the Federal Reserve System, Division o f Monetary Affairs.

The Empirical Properties of a
Monetary Aggregate That Adds
Bond and Stock Funds to M2
R THE PAST FEW YEARS, the unexpected
slowdown of M2 growth and strength in its
velocity have coincided with a surge in out­
standing balances in bond and stock mutual funds.
Although this surge partly reflects capital gains
from rising prices in stock and bond markets, it
also is due to record inflows of new balances.
Indeed, anecdotal and statistical evidence suggests
that a significant portion of these inflows have
come from M2, contributing to the unexpected
weakness in this aggregate. Consequently, aug­
menting M2 with bond and stock funds in order
to internalize these flows offers the prospect of an
aggregate that is more stably related to income
and prices than M2 has been of late.
This article examines empirical issues associ­
ated with whether such an augmented aggregate,
called M2+, would be useful in the conduct of
monetary policy. The three main issues examined
are the stability of its demand function, its infor­
mation content as an indicator of spending, and
its controllability. To assess these characteristics
of M2+, demand functions and reduced-form
relationships between M2+ and income have been
estimated. The M2+ series used in this empirical
work includes capital gains and losses on bond
and stock funds. M2+ was defined in this manner
on the presumption that meaningful behavioral
distinctions cannot be made between balances




generated in the past by capital gains and balances
originally brought into stock and bond funds
from outside sources.
Specifying a demand function for M2+ requires
identifying its close substitutes. One broad class
of substitutes includes real assets such as com­
modities and durable goods, while alternative
financial assets may include direct holdings of
short-term market instruments, bonds and stocks.
The estimated demand functions posit direct
holdings of Treasury bonds and bills as the sole
substitutes for M2+ because of difficulties in
finding plausible measures of expected ex ante
returns on real assets and equities. Using rough
proxies for ex ante financial returns, including
those on stock and bond funds themselves, the
estimated demand functions have reasonable
behavioral properties. But perhaps because of the
problems with measuring ex ante returns, as well
as the difficulty in distinguishing between returns
on direct and mutual-fund holdings of the same
assets, the estimated demand functions are not
very stable. Hence, the usefulness of these equa­
tions in interpreting and forecasting movements
in M2+ may prove to be limited. Moreover, these
relationships have been estimated over a period
of major innovation and growth of the bond and
stock fund industry, raising further questions
about the stability of the specification.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

32

In terms of information content, M2+ and M2
do not appear to have differed significantly. The
velocity of M2+ may have been more “sensible”
than that of M2 over the past three years, given
the anomalous behavior of V2, which was rising
while the opportunity cost of M2 was declining.
As a consequence, in reduced-form relations,
forecasts of nominal GDP growth for 1992 are
somewhat stronger and more accurate when based
on M2+ rather than M2. But leading into the past
recession and continuing to the end of 1991, both
aggregates yielded substantial overpredictions of
nominal GDP growth. Within M2+, the volatile
monthly swings in M2 are modestly offset by
changes in net inflows to stock and bond funds,
but capital gains and losses cause growth of M2+
to be more volatile than that of M2. Moreover,
the capital gains and losses in M2+ may cause
movements in the aggregate that neither reflect
shifts in the stance of monetary policy nor provide
appropriate signals for changes in policy.
The remainder of the paper addresses these
issues in more detail. Section two explains why
the inclusion of capital gains and losses in M2+
seems necessary and highlights some of the
problems that result from their inclusion. The
section also briefly describes the data used to
create a bond and stock mutual fund series that
is comparable to M 2.1 Section three provides a
broad empirical overview of the growth of bond
and stock mutual funds over the past decade.
The section then goes on to describe the recent
behavior of M2+ and compares its behavior with
that of M2. In the final section, we conduct an
econometric investigation of M2+ demand, noting
several of the difficulties associated with speci­
fying a demand function for M2+ and with the
stability and controlability of the aggregate. Also
in this section, the indicator properties of M2+
are formally examined and contrasted with
those of M2.

DEFINING M2+ AND ASSOCIATED
DATA LIMITATIONS
Because stock and bond funds are revalued
daily to reflect realized capital gains and losses
(unlike the deposit components of the current
1 For a more complete discussion of the issues associated
with constructing the bond and stock fund component of
M2+, see Collins and Edwards (1994).
2 Defining an aggregate by adding only bond funds to M2
would mitigate some of the problems associated with capital
gains because such gains are more volatile for stock funds
than for bond funds. However, such an aggregate suffers

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



monetary aggregates whose values are fixed at
par), questions arise as to the proper treatment
of these changes in value. One option is to
exclude capital gains by selecting a value of
outstanding balances on a specific historical
date to which subsequent inflows (net of capital
gains) are added. However, both the selection
of this date and the assumption that net capital
gains before this date, but not after, constitute
money are arbitrary. Presumably after some
period of time, mutual fund shareholders cease
to distinguish between balances generated by
capital gains and those that stem from new
investments of funds.
A second problem with excluding net capital
gains is that, at least conceptually, M2+ balances
(or at least the mutual fund component) could
become negative. For example, if an individual
starts with no M2+ and then adds $100 to a bond
fund, the M2+ holdings would then equal $100.
If capital gains add $50 to the value of the bond
fund account, M2+ will still equal $100 if capital
gains are excluded from M2+. If the individual
then withdraws all $150 from the bond fund,
net inflows would equal minus $150, and M2+
would equal minus $50 for this individual. To
avoid such problems, M2+ is defined to include
capital gains.2
But the inclusion of capital gains and losses
raises issues about the signals that M2+ can
convey about the stance and proper course of
monetary policy. For example, a decline in the
stock market that reflected lower profit expecta­
tions and slower business activity would lower
M2+, ceteris paribus, and may appropriately be
calling for a more stimulative monetary policy.
But, if capital losses and lower M2+ result from
an increase in long-term interest rates in response
to rising inflation, a monetary ease is not likely
to be the appropriate response. With bond
and stock funds currently amounting to about
15 percent of M2+, and likely to increase further,
capital gains and losses can have noticeable
short-run effects on the growth of the
expanded aggregate.
Data used to measure bond and stock fund
balances are provided to the Federal Reserve by
from the data limitation that a large number of mutual funds
invest in both bonds and stocks, and therefore separating
mutual funds into these two categories is problematic. An
aggregate consisting of M2 plus bond funds has been exam­
ined by Duca (forthcoming).

33

the Investment Company Institute (ICI). As
received from ICI, the bond and stock fund
balances include IRA/Keogh and institutional
holdings.3 Because IRA/Keogh and institutional
holdings of M2-type accounts are netted from M2,
such holdings of bond and stock funds need to
be netted out in constructing the bond and stock
fund component of M2+. Such netted bond and
stock fund series will be referred to as M 2-type
series. For M2-type bond and stock funds, it
would be useful to have data on inflows excluding
capital gains as a direct measure of portfolio shifts,
but this series is not reported by ICI and cannot
be constructed from available data.4 To proxy
for this missing series, we rely on total inflows
excluding capital gains.5

This growth may be attributed, in part, to
declining transaction costs when investing in
mutual funds. Between 1970 and 1992, load
fees on mutual funds fell from an average of
8.5 percent to 4.5 percent. In addition, during
the past decade, no-load mutual funds have
become more widely available, further reducing
the transaction costs involved in shifting in and
out of mutual funds.8

Historical Trends o f Bond and Stock
Mutual Funds

In reducing transaction costs associated with
moving into mutual funds, banks have also been
playing a role. Large domestic banks sampled for
the Federal Reserve System’s March 1993 Senior
Financial Officer Survey reported significant
increases during the past few years in their overall
sales staffs for mutual funds, as well as in the
share of branch offices with sales representatives
located at them.9 These developments suggest
that investment balances that previously had
been held in M2 can now be moved more readily
into bond and stock funds, and may be more
likely to be switched back and forth between
these two lodgings as relative yields shift.

Although bond and stock mutual funds
have existed in the United States since 1924,
most of their growth has been quite recent. In
the early 1970s, there were about 400 such funds
with total assets of about $40 billion. Today, there
are more than 3,000 funds with total assets of
about $1.4 trillion (see Figure 1, top panel).6
The bottom panel of Figure 1 shows that holdings
of aggregate bond and stock mutual funds have
grown roughly in parallel and are about equal.7

Another innovation that may have contributed
to the growth of the industry is that the balances
held in such funds can be used more readily as a
means of payment in the purchase of goods and
services, in part because many funds now allow
withdrawals to be made by checks. However, the
writing of a check means that mutual fund shares
must be sold, so there is a potential capital gain
or loss associated with each check. Anecdotal
evidence suggests that the inconvenience of

GROWTH OF THE MUTUAL FUND
INDUSTRY AND THE BROAD EMPIRI­
CAL PROPERTIES OF M2+

3 See ICI (1994, Appendix A) for the type of funds classified
as stock and bond funds.
4 Inflows to M2-type bond and stock funds can be estimated
by starting with the change in the market value of M2-type
bond and stock funds and subtracting estimated capital
gains. These capital gains and losses can be estimated
from capital gains and losses on total bond and stock funds,
which are available. We have made these estimates by tak­
ing total capital gains and losses and multiplying them by the
lagged ratio of M2-type outstandings to total outstandings of
bond and stock funds.
Although we show such estimates of M2-type capital
gains and losses in Figure 10, these estimates and the
associated estimates of M2-type inflows do not seem reli­
able enough to use throughout the analysis.
5 Reinvested earnings are included in both the M2-type and
total inflows. This treatment is conceptually similar to the
interest crediting of M2 balances. According to ICI data,
about 75 percent of shareholders automatically reinvest their
earnings in the mutual fund.
6 For an overview of the growth of the mutual fund industry
and how mutual funds operate and compete, see Sirri and
Tufano (1993).

types of funds offered, and much of the growth has occurred
in specialized funds. For example, municipal bond funds,
which were introduced in 1976, had total assets of $50 bil­
lion by 1985, and had grown to $225 billion by 1993.
Government income and Ginnie Mae funds, which had a
total of about $2.5 billion under management at the start of
1984, had $175 billion by 1993.
8 See Mack (1993) for a more extended discussion of the
decline in load fees.
9 The percentage of sampled banks with more than 50 repre­
sentatives selling retail mutual funds increased from less
than 10 percent three years ago to more than 40 percent
currently; and nearly all sampled banks currently have some
retail sales force. Also, banks have made mutual funds
more accessible through their branches. Over half the sam­
pled banks have personnel selling retail mutual funds on a
part-time basis or by appointment at 90 percent or more of
their branches, a significant increase from three years ago,
when only 20 percent of the banks had sales representa­
tives available part-time at 90 percent or more of their
branches. The results of the March 1993 Senior Financial
Officer Survey and the growth of bank-related mutual funds
more generally is discussed by Reid and Small (1993).

7 This growth of the bond and stock fund industry has been
associated with increased diversity and specialization of the




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

34

Figure 1A
Number and Market Value of Bond and Stock Mutual Funds
Number of funds

Billions of dollars

- 600
- 400

-

200

-

100

- 50

Figure 1B
Market Value of Aggregate Bond and Stock Mutual Funds
Billions of dollars

Aggregate bond and stock mutual fund balances include IRA/Keogh balances
and institutional holdings. These aggregate mutual fund data are not
seasonally adjusted.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



35

tabulating capital gains and losses for the purpose
of income taxes significantly limits the frequency
of the writing of checks on stock and bond fund
accounts.10
The transaction activity in bond and stock
funds is presented in Figure 2, which plots
gross outflows from total bond and stock funds
measured as a share of outstanding balances.11
Contrary to what would be expected if transaction
activity had increased, there is no discernible
secular trend in the ratio of gross outflows to the
value of shares, and the most recent value of the
ratio seems rather modest.12
Consequently, the rationale that we explore
for adding such funds to M2 is based on the
substitutability of bond and stock funds for
small time deposits or other M2 balances as
savings vehicles, and not on the transactability
of bond and stock funds.

R ecent Behavior ofM 2+
Figure 3 displays the levels of M2 and M2+,
with M2+ defined to include capital gains
and losses, but excluding IRA/Keogh accounts
and institutional holdings. The upper panel
of Figure 4 shows the GDP velocities of the two
aggregates and the bottom panel shows the growth
rates of M2 and M2+. Three distinct episodes
are evident: (1) From 1984 through 1986, the gap
between the two velocity measures increased as
growth in M2+ outpaced that of M2 (lower panel);
(2) From 1986 through 1990, the velocities moved
roughly parallel to each other; (3) From 1990 to
the present, the velocity of M2 rose sharply
while that of M2+ is about unchanged.

changes in the value of bond and stock funds and
changes in M2— such as from 1990:Q4-1991:Q3.
As a consequence, M2+ is slightly more variable
than M2, including the most recent years. In terms
of deviations from trend, and as shown in the top
panel of Table 1, the mean absolute deviation of
M2+ growth over the period from March 1984
through September 1993 is 3.07 percentage
points — somewhat greater than that for M2
growth at 2.46 percentage points. However,
during the recent sub-sample of January 1989
to September 1993, the difference in variability
is much smaller. The middle panel of the table
indicates that these differences persist using
quarterly data. The bottom panel of the table
examines the variability of velocity growth about
its mean. The variability of V2+ has been close
to that of V2 in recent years, but V2+ was con­
siderably more variable in the mid-1980s.

MODELING BOND AND STOCK
FUNDS AND M2+
Modeling the demand for any monetary
asset requires identifying alternative uses for
the balances held in the aggregate. Bond and
stock funds compete with M2 for balances, and
a potential advantage of considering M2+ is that
this competition need not be addressed in mod­
eling M2+. But bond and stock funds compete
with many more assets than just M2— such as
commodities or other real assets. Because rea­
sonable proxies for the expected rates of return
on real assets are not available, these assets will
not be included in the models developed below.

Figure 5 shows the monthly growth rates of
M2 and M2+. As shown in the top panel, much
of the monthly variability of M2 growth shows
through to M2+ growth. Monthly net inflows to
stock and bond funds apparently are negatively
correlated with changes in M2, but offset only
a small portion of the change in M2, as shown
in the middle panel.13 However, as shown in
the bottom panel, capital gains and losses can
induce positive co-movements between the

The only alternatives to M2+ that are included
in the models below are direct holdings of Treasury
bonds and bills. As a result, analyzing M2+ entails
the measurement of own-rates that determine the
flows among the following five assets: M2, bond
funds, stock funds, and direct holdings both of
bonds and bills. The own-rate for M2 can be
calculated from posted rates on M2 deposits.
Proxies for ex ante returns on bond and stock
funds are examined immediately below.

10 Although mutual funds could compute the capital gains on
the checks written by each shareholder, this does not seem
to be a widespread practice as yet. See Clements (1993).

savings accounts is 4.7. See Collins and Edwards (1994)
for a further discussion.

11 Gross outflows are the value of all balances withdrawn,
whether or not the balances are reinvested in another fund.

13 The modest offset is only apparent because the inflows
shown are aggregate inflows that include flows to
IRA/Keogh and institutional balances.

12 As shown in the figure, recently this ratio has averaged
about 2.5 percent, which at an annual rate yields a turnover
rate of 0.3. In comparison, the turnover ratio for traditional




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

36

Figure 2
Aggregate Bond and Stock Mutual Fund Outflows
(as a percentage of total market value)
Percent

Aggregate bond and stock mutual fund outflows include flows from
IRA/Keogh accounts and institutional holdings.

Figure 3
M2 and M2+
Billions of Dollars

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




37

Figure 4A
Velocities of M2 and M2+

Figure 4B
Growth Rates of M2 and M2+
Percent




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

38

Figure 5
Variability of M2 and M2+
Billions of dollars

Billions of dollars

Billions of dollars

* Aggregate bond and stock mutual fund net inflows include flows to IRA/Keogh
accounts and institutional holdings.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



39

Table 1
Variability of Money and Velocity
About Trend* (percent annual rates)
Monthly money growth
Mean absolute
deviation
Sample period

Standard
deviation

M2

M2+

M2

M2+

2.46

3.07

3.04

3.81

1984:M3 - 1988:M12

2.72

3.37

3.25

4.15

1989:M1 - 1993:M9

2.23

2.38

2.82

3.05

1984:M3 - 1993:M9

Quarterly money growth
Mean absolute
deviation

Standard
deviation

Sample period

M2

M2+

M2

1984:Q3 - 1993:Q3

1.80

2.43

2.10

M2+
2.91

1984:Q3 - 1988:Q4

1.99

2.46

2.33

3.09

1989:Q1 - 1993:Q3

1.56

1.80

1.88

2.15

Quarterly velocity growth
Mean absolute
Standard
deviation
deviation
Sample period

M2

M2+

M2

M2+

1984:Q3 - 1993:Q3

2.89

3.40

3.60

4.25

1984:Q3 - 1988:Q4

3.04

4.06

3.91

5.12

1989:Q1 - 1993:Q3

2.45

2.61

2.98

3.10

* For money growth rates, regressions were used to esti­
mate separate time trends for each sub-period. The time
trends pick up the general slowing of money growth since
1984. For velocity growth, for each sub-period the summary
statistics refer to the growth of velocity about its mean for
that sub-period. No trend in the growth of velocity (that is,
acceleration of velocity) was removed before calculating the
summary statistics.
Some of the additional variability in M2+ may be because
the monthly figures for mutual funds represent averages of
end-of-month figures, while M2 data represent averages of
daily data.

Proxies fo r E x Ante Returns and their
Effects on Changes in M2-Type Bond
and Stock Funds
This sub-section attempts to identify determi­
nants of the demands for bond and stock mutual
14 Increases in these proxies would be expected to increase
demands for the relevant type of mutual funds, but may also
raise demands for direct holdings.
15 Decreases in aggregate bond and stock fund inflows in 1987
were related in part to changes in the tax exemption for IRA
contributions, which were liberalized in 1981 and tightened
in 1987. The latter change in the tax law does not seem to
be the dominant reason for the dropoff in aggregate inflows
in 1987. Net inflows went from $144 billion in 1986 to $49
billion in 1987, but data on IRAs indicate that a drop in their
flows account for no more than $7 billion of this slowing.




funds. In particular, proxies are needed for the
ex ante returns on mutual funds.
For bond funds, two alternative proxies are
available. One approach relies on contempora­
neously observable market rates and the other
employs lags of ex post realized returns.14 The
first approach uses the slope of the Treasury yield
curve and recent changes in the Treasury bond
rate. The yield curve captures the difference
between quoted yields to maturity on long-term
bonds and posted returns on short-term assets
including small time deposits or money market
mutual funds (MMMFs) in M2 as well as money
market instruments. As such, increases in the
spread will make bond mutual funds (as well as
direct holdings) look more attractive. Recent bond
rate changes may affect investors’ expectations
of prospective capital gains or losses if investors
have extrapolative expectations.
The top panel of Figure 6 shows that both net
aggregate inflows to bond funds and the change
in market value of M2-type bond funds surged
from 1984 through the first quarter of 1987. This
surge may well have reflected the relatively steep
yield curve going into that period (middle panel)
and capital gains caused by falling bond rates
throughout most of the period (lower panel).15
But then with the upturn in bond rates in the
second quarter of 1987, bond funds initially
experienced modest average outflows during the
last half of 1987, and then grew moderately over
the next two years as long rates leveled off and
the slope of the yield curve fell because of rising
short-term rates. More recently, aggregate bond
inflows surged as bond rates started to drift down
again (although more slowly than during the
1984-1986 period) and as the slope of the yield
curve rose to record heights.
A quarterly regression that examines the
effects of the slope of the yield curve and recent
capital gains and losses is given in equation 1.
The change in market value of M2-type bond
funds is scaled by the lagged value of M 2+.16
16 Bond funds are scaled by M2+ to avoid placing undue
weight on the early years of the regression. Such overem­
phasis could result if bond fund changes were scaled by
lagged bond funds (that is, if we modeled the growth rate of
bond funds) because during the early years when bond
funds were modest, a small shift from M2 would represent a
large percentage change in bond funds.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

40

Figure 6
Changes in Bond Fund Balances
Billions of dollars

Spread Between the 30-Year Treasury Bond and the 3-Month
Treasury Bill Rates
Percentage points

30-Year Treasury Bond Rate
Percent

* Aggregate bond fund net inflows include flows to IRA/Keogh accounts and
institutional holdings.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



41

(1) ABFUND = .00019 + .000025 TIME
M 2+ ,
(.25)
(.75)
+ .00047 (RT30Y - RTBE)_,
(1.97)
- .0022 ART5Y .0014 ART5Y,
(3.71)
(2.28)

four-quarter moving average of the realized
returns is given in equation 2.17
(2) ABFUND = .0012 M 2+4
(2.03)

- .00036 (RTBE - RETBND4)_1
(7.47)

- .0017 ART5Y, - .0018 ART5Y,,.
(3.04)
(3.14)
R2 = .735
R 2 = .676
D.W. statistic = 1.22
Estimation period: 1985:Q2 - 1993:Q3,
where:

ABFUND is the change
in the market value of M2-type
bond funds;
RT30Y is the 30-year Treasury
bond rate;
RT5Y is the five-year Treasury
note rate;
RTBE is the three-month Treasury
bill rate;

and the absolute values of t-statistics are
in parentheses.
The positive coefficient on the spread vari­
able indicates that a steep yield curve draws
balances into bond mutual funds. The negative
coefficients on the changes in the five-year
Treasury note show that recent capital losses
reduce bond fund inflows. The contemporaneous
change in the note rate also captures the direct
effect of changes in the market values.
While the top panel of Figure 7 repeats that of
Figure 6, the lower panel of 7 uses the realized
returns on bond funds to proxy for expected
returns. Comparisons across the two panels
show a rough relation between the changes in
bond fund balances and the spread of realized
returns over Treasury bill rates. A regression
relating the change in market value of M2-type
bond funds to the opportunity cost that uses the

.000098 TIME
(.34)

- .0017 ART5Y.
(3.14)
R2 = .758
R 2 = .733
D.W. statistic = 1.33
Estimation period = 1985:Q2 —1993:Q3,
where:

ABFUND is the change in
market value of M2-type
bond funds;
RETBND4 is a four-quarter
moving average of the ex post
realized return on bond funds;
RTBE is the three-month Treasury
rate;

and the absolute values of t-statistics are
in parentheses.
These results are similar to those reported in
equation 1, with both equations having R2s of
about .75.
For stock funds, the upper panel of Figure 8
shows two measures of changes in balances and
the lower shows the spread of the realized returns
over the Treasury bill rate. Comparing the two
panels, the surge in balances prior to the stock
market crash of 1987, the subsequent falloff, and
then the resurgence in balances in 1989 are all
tracked by the movements in realized returns
minus the Treasury bill rate. The latest spurt in
balances seems anomalous, but some of this rise
is lessened when the changes in market values
are scaled by M2+ as in the following regression,
which explains the change in the market value
of M2-type stock funds:

17 The four-quarter moving average is used for realized returns
to save on the number of freely estimated parameters, in
comparison to using four lags of realized returns. When the
spread between the quarterly realized return and the
Treasury bill rate is entered with four lags, the four individual
coefficients are roughly of the same magnitude and the sum
of the coefficients is statistically insignificantly different from
the estimated coefficient on the four-quarter moving average
reported in equation 2.
Also, the realized return is entered in the form of the
spread of the Treasury bill rate over the realized return in
keeping with standard usage of entering opportunity costs.




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

42

Figure 7A
Changes in Bond Fund Balances
Billions of dollars

Figure 7B
Realized Returns on Bond Funds Minus the 3-Month T-Bill Rate
Percent

* Aggregate bond fund net inflows include flows to IRA/Keogh accounts and
institutional holdings.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



43

Figure 8A
Changes in Stock Fund Balances
Billions of dollars

Figure 8B
Realized Returns on Stock Funds Minus the 3-Month T-Bill Rate
Percent

* Aggregate bond fund net inflows include flows to IRA/Keogh accounts and
institutional holdings.




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

44

(3) ASFUND = - .00093 + .000072 TIME
M2+.J
(1.68)
(2.96)
- .000054 (RTBE - RETEQ4).!
(2.59)
+ .00017 Alog(NYSE).
(6.98)
R2 = .661
R 2 = .628
D.W. statistic = 2.15
Estimation period = 1985:Q2 - 1993:Q3,
where:

ASFUND is the change in market
value of M2-type stock funds;
RETEQ4 is a four-quarter moving
average of the ex post realized
return on stock funds;
NYSE is the New York Stock
Exchange price index;

and the absolute values of t-statistics are in
parentheses.
As with the bond inflow equations, the spread
of the three-month Treasury bill rate over the
realized return has a significant, negative impact.
Moreover, the overall fit of the equation is quite
high, as the capital gains reflected in the con­
temporaneous change of stock prices explain
most of the variation in the market value of
stock fund balances.
An unattractive aspect of equations 1-3 is
the absence of a scale variable such as income
or wealth and, consequently, the absence of
well-defined, long-run equilibrium levels of bond
and stock funds relative to income or wealth, or
even to M2+. Specifications of such relations
were unsuccessful, apparently because innovation
and growth of the bond and stock fund industry
have caused bond and stock fund balances to
grow relative to other nominal quantities. As
a result, in what follows we do not attempt to
provide a model of the components of M2+ but
only of M2+ as a whole, which can be modeled
with such a scale variable.
18 These are error-correction models. To derive the long-run
properties of the model, let nominal GDP and all interest
rates be constant. Then M2+ will also be constant and the
left-hand side of the regression model can be set to zero.
The logarithm of velocity can then be solved for as a linear
function of the opportunity costs and the Treasury yield
curve spread.
19 Recent models that estimate significant yield-curve effects
on M2 demand were developed by Hess(1990). Subsequently,
Feinman and Porter (1992) found the same effect, and Mehra
(1992) obtained similar results.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



M odeling the D em and fo r M2+
This section presents and evaluates simple
models of the demand for M2+. The models are
similar to earlier specifications for the demand
for M2 that posit a long-run demand in which
velocity is a linear function of opportunity costs.
The regression models are of the general form:18
Alog(M2+) = cO + c l Time + c2 log(M2+/GDP).1
+ c3 (opportunity cost variables).!
+ c4 (RT30Y - RTBE).! + error.
Opportunity costs are defined as the difference
between the yield on the three-month Treasury
bill and the own-rate of return on monetary assets.
For own-rates we use the own-rate on M2 (RM2E),
and as proxies for the own-rates of return on bond
and stock mutual funds, we use the four-quarter
moving averages of realized returns on bond and
stock mutual funds (RETBND4 and RETEQ4), as
in equations 2 and 3. Because we assume direct
holdings of bonds and bills are the primary com­
peting asset for M2+ balances, the opportunity
cost variables all incorporate Treasury rates as
the competing rate. For this, the three-month
Treasury bill rate is used.
Because longer-maturity Treasury securities
may also be competing assets for M2+, especially
for the M2 balances in M2+, all specifications
considered below include the slope of the term
structure. This variable has been found to have
a significant, negative impact on M2 in recent
years and above we found that it had a positive
impact on bond-fund inflows.19 If the substitution
away from M2 that this variable captures is
towards bond and stock funds only, there would
be no net impact on M2+.20 Indeed, it is the
internalization of just such substitutions that
makes M2+ a potentially useful aggregate.
However, if the slope of the term structure cap­
tures some substitution of M2 into direct hold­
ings of stocks and bonds, then it would have a
negative impact on M2+.
20 Indeed, such substitution is consistent with the findings of
equation 1, which showed a positive impact of the yield
curve on bond fund balances.

45

Table 2
Estimated Demand Equations for M2+
(2)
-0.031
(2.85)

(3)
-0.026
(2.61)

Constant

(1)
-0.0038
(.30)

Time

-0.00066
(6.67)

log(M2+/GDP2)_,

-0.069
(2.24)

-0.232
(6.36)

-0.215
(6.65)

S30Y ,

-0.000079
(.10)

-0.0047
(5.76)

-0.005
(6.86)

OCM2+.,

-0.0000043
(4.31)

OCM2.,

-0.014
(5.89)

-0.013
(6.35)

OCMB.,

-0.00020
(1.18)

OCMS.,

-0.000025
(.35)

-0.00069
(10.38)

-0.00088
(13.07)

W *OCMB.,

-0.0041
(2.23)

W 'O C M S.,

-0.00037
(.50)

R2

0.614

0.857

0.880

R2

0.566

0.828

0.856

D.W. statistic

1.56

1.69

1.88

Estimation period = 1984:Q3 through 1993:03,
where:
the dependent variable = log(M2+t) -log(M2+,).,
S30Y

= RT30Y -R T B E

slope of the yield curve

OCM2+ = RTBE -R M 2 +

opportunity cost of M2+

OCM2 = R TBE--RM2

opportunity cost of M2

OCMB = RTBE-- RETBND4

opportunity cost of
bond funds

OCMS = RTBE-- RETEQ4

opportunity cost of
stock funds

w

a proxy for the availability
of mutual funds

: NETMF/(M2 + NETMF)

NETMF = Market value of M2-type bond and stock funds
GDP2

= Two-quarter moving average of nominal GDP

a n d a b s o lu te v a lu e s o f t-s ta tis tic s are in p a re n th e s e s .

Within this general specification, we fit three
alternative M2+ demand functions. In the first
alternative (shown in column one of Table 2), we
used the slope of the yield curve and one oppor­
tunity cost that incorporates a weighted-average
own-rate on M2+.21 The regression in column
one im plicitly contains the restriction that the
responses of M2+ to the opportunity costs of the
three components (M2, bond funds and stock
funds) after being weighted by dollar shares are
equal. To allow for different responses to changes
in the individual opportunity costs, column two
of Table 2 shows a regression in which the un­
weighted opportunity cost for each of the three
components of M2+ (OCM2, OCMB and OCMS)
is entered separately.22 As can be seen, the adjusted
R2 rises significantly when the constraint is
relaxed. However, the opportunity costs of bond
and stock funds are statistically insignificant.
As a final specification, an attempt is made to
incorporate the effects of the increasing access
of retail customers to bond and stock funds. In
column three of Table 2, the bond and stock fund
opportunity costs are weighted by the ratio of
bond and stock fund balances to the value of
M2+.23 As can be seen, the fit of the equation
improves modestly with the incorporation
of these weights. In addition, the statistical
significance of the opportunity cost of bond
funds improves noticeably. The opportunity
cost of stock funds remains insignificant, which
may not be surprising because the highly volatile
ex post returns on stock funds may be little used
by investors in forming expectations of future
movements in the market.

Stability ofM 2+ D em and and the
Controllability o f M2+
The stability of the above estimated demand
functions for M2+ is generally suspect for a

21 In this setting, the M2+ own-rate, RM2+, is constructed as
the weighted average of RM2E, RETBND4 and RETEQ4,
weighted by the quantities of M2, bond funds and stock funds
held in the previous quarter relative to M2+. The opportunity
cost of M2+ is defined as OCM2+ = RTBE - RM2+, where
RTBE is the yield on three-month Treasury bills.
22 There are several reasons to believe that separating the two
opportunity costs will produce better estimates. First, given
the likely error in measuring expected ex ante own-rates for
bond and stock mutual funds, the aggregation of those two
rates with the better-measured M2 own-rate will contaminate
the estimated response to all three own-rates, in general
lowering the estimated coefficient from its true value.
Second, and equally important, since the relevant alternative
assets for stock and bond mutual funds outside M2+ are
likely to include assets other than three-month Treasury
bills, the opportunity cost relative to the three-month




Treasury bill may be more important for M2 than for stock
and bond mutual funds.
23 As a proxy for the availability of mutual fund accounts, these
weights suffer from being determined in part by the other
factors driving demand for M2+. A better, but unavailable,
proxy would be one based on transaction costs.
The weight grows from about 3 percent in 1984 to around
8 percent in 1988 and then to 15 percent currently.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

46

Figure 9
Growth of Actual and Simulated M2+
Percent

The estimation period of 1986:Q3 through 1991:Q2 is marked off by the
vertical lines. The simulation begins in 1985:Q1.

number of reasons. First, 10 years is a very short
sample period. Second, within that period there
was considerable innovation in the bond and stock
fund industry. The weights used in the model of
column three of Table 2 are likely at best to capture
only broadly the effects on M2+ of such innova­
tions. Third, there are the obvious limitations
of the opportunity cost variables in terms of
identifying competing rates of return when the
aggregate is as broad as M2+ and in terms of
proxying ex ante expected rates of return on
bond and stock funds.
Indeed, all three equations in Table 2 fail Chow
tests, strongly suggesting a lack of stability. Under
these tests, the estimation period is split into two
sub-periods, and the estimation results over the
two sub-periods are compared statistically. In a
less formal check, the model of column three in
Table 2 was estimated over a sub-period that
starts in 1986:Q3 and ends in 1991:Q2, allowing
for an examination of the model’s forecasting
performance both before and after this period.
The simulation shown in Figure 9 shows fairly

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



substantial errors over the pre-estimation period,
but reasonable accuracy starting by 1988 and
carrying through nearly to the present.
Figure 10 provides some evidence on the his­
torical contribution of capital gains and losses
to the growth of M2+. These can be a guide to
the size of the shocks to the growth of M2+ that
might need to be offset if fairly close control of
M2+ were taken seriously. Although these esti­
mates likely are somewhat imprecise, they do
show the effects of the stock market crash of 1987
and major market swings. However, since stock
and bond funds are becoming a larger proportion
of M2+, the aggregate is probably becoming
increasingly vulnerable to swings in capital
gains and losses.

THE INDICATOR PROPERTIES OF M2
AND M2+
As a final set of statistical comparisons of
the behavior of M2 and M2+, the ability of these
aggregates to predict changes in nominal GDP

47

Figure 10A
Quarterly Growth of M2+ Accounted for by Capital Gains*
Percentage Points

Figure 10B
Annual (Q4/Q4) Growth of M2+ Accounted for by Capital Gains*
Capital gains over the year divided by M2+ of Q4 of previous year
Percentage Points

* Capital gains and losses for M2-type bond and stock funds are estimated
taking capital gains and losses for all bond and stock funds and multiplying
that series by the ratio of M2-type to total bond and stock outstandings
— la g g e d o n e p e rio d — a n d ta k in g a tw o -m o n th m o v in g a v e ra g e .

is examined. Each test regresses one-quarter
nominal GDP growth on lagged nominal GDP
growth, lagged growth in one of the monetary
aggregates, and lagged changes in the three-month
Treasury bill rate.24 The regression models are
of the general form:
Alog(GDPNt) = B0 + T n=1 fin Alog(GDPNtJ
+ r , 1=1 ?„ Alog(M,n) + r n=] An A(RTBE,n) + e t ,
where

GDPN = nominal GDP,
M = monetary aggregate, and
RTBE = three-month Treasury bill.
The top panel of Figure 11 presents in-sample
measures of the statistical significance of the
lagged money measures for a rolling 15-year
estimation window. The measure of significance
at an indicated date is the significance level when
the estimation period includes 15 years of data
ending at that date. By this measure, the two
aggregates performed equally well in predicting

24 The observation for 1980:Q2, during which credit controls
were imposed, was omitted from the data.




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

48

Figure 11A
Significance Levels for the Predictive Impact of M2 and M2+
on Nominal GDP Growth* (15-year window)
Significance level

Figure 11B
Significance Levels for the Predictive Impact of M2 and M2+
on Nominal GDP Growth* (71/2-year window)
Significance level

* Likelihood of falsely rejecting the monetary variable from the regression.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



49

Figure 12A
One-Quarter-Ahead Forecast Errors for Nominal GDP Growth*
(15-year window)
Percentage points

Figure 12B
One-Quarter-Ahead Forecast Errors for Nominal GDP Growth*
(71/2-year window)
Percentage points

* Forecast errors are calculated as actual minus predicted GDP growth.




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

50

Figure 13A
Four-Quarter-Ahead Forecast Errors for Nominal GDP Growth*
(15-year window)
Percentage points

* Forecast errors are calculated as actual minus predicted GDP growth.

Figure 13B
Four-Quarter-Ahead Forecast Errors for Nominal GDP Growth*
(71/2-year window)
Percentage points

* Forecast errors are calculated as actual minus predicted GDP growth.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




51

nominal GDP growth until the mid-1980s. In
1986, inflows to bond and stock funds were
heavy in response to falling interest rates, and
in 1987 there were modest net outflows when
interest rates reversed course early in the year
and the stock market crashed late in the year.
The resulting swings in M2+ growth were not
subsequently reflected in nominal GDP growth
and, thus, the rise in significance levels. In the
past couple of years, the significance levels of
the two aggregates moved closer together.
The lower panel of the figure presents the
statistical significance levels for the same speci­
fication using a shorter, seven-and-a-half-year,
rolling estimation window. With a shorter
estimation horizon, the ill behavior of M2 over
the past few years becomes clear with the large
significance level since 1991. This increase is
not accompanied by the corresponding increase
in the significance level of M2+.25
Figure 12 shows the results of out-of-sample
experiments that compute one-period-ahead
forecast errors based on the regressions used in
the previous exercise. Again, the time horizons
over which the forecasting equations are estimated
are 15 and seven-and-a-half years prior to the
forecast date. Figure 13 presents results for
four-period-ahead forecasts. The forecast errors
in both figures are calculated as actual minus
forecasted growth— a positive error indicates
an underprediction. Comparing the results for
M2 and M2+, these figures indicate that the
forecast errors for the two aggregates are about
the same over the whole period shown, as would
be expected given that both aggregates are

marginally useful in explaining future nominal
GDP growth in-sample. Both aggregates tended
to overpredict GDP growth in late 1990. Reasonably
strong money growth in the second half of 1989
was not consistent with the subsequent recession
at the end of 1990. Both aggregates generally
underpredicted nominal GDP growth in 1992,
with M2+ forecast errors being smaller than
those of M2.

REFERENCES
Clements, Jonathan. “Wait! Don’t Write That Mutual Fund
Check,” Wall Street Journal (November 1993), p. C14.
Collins, Sean, and Cheryl Edwards. “An Alternative Monetary
Aggregate: M2 Plus Household Holdings of Bond and Equity
Funds,” this Review (November/December 1994), pp. 7-29.
Duca, John V. “Should Bond Funds Be Included in M2?”
Journal o f Banking and Finance (forthcoming).
Feinman, Joshua, and Richard D. Porter. “The Continuing
Weakness in M2," Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, Finance and Economics Discussion Series
Paper #209 (September 1992).
Investment Company Institute. Trends in Mutual Fund Activity.
October 1994.
Mack, Phillip R. “Recent Trends in the Mutual Fund Industry,”
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Federal Reserve Bulletin (November 1993), pp. 1001-12.
Mehra, Yash. “Has M2 Demand Become Unstable?” Federal
Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review
(September/October 1992), pp. 27-35.
Reid, Brian, and David H. Small. “Bank Involvement in the
Mutual Fund Industry,” Board of Governors of the Federal
Resen/e System, mimeo (September 1993).
Sirri, Eirk K., and Peter Tufano. “Competition and Change in
the Mutual Funds Industry,” in Samuel L. Hayes, ed.,
Financial Services: Perspectives and Challenges. Harvard
Business School Press, 1993, pp. 181-214.

25 The results are little changed when interest rates are omitted
from the equations, although significance levels are lower
(money is more important) since money picks up some of
the variability of nominal GDP growth explained by interest
rates in the broader model.




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994




53

William A. Barnett and Ge Zhou
William A. Barnett is professor of economics at Washington
University, St. Louis. Ge Zhou recently received a doctorate in
economics from Washington University, St. Louis. The authors
benefitted from useful discussions with Athanasios Orphanides.
Research on the project was partially supported by NSF grant
SES 9223557.

Commentary
W,

E ARE VERY PLEASED to be invited
to comment on the new M2+ index, recently
proposed in interesting papers by some Federal
Reserve Board staff members (Collins and
Edwards, 1994; and Orphanides, Reid and
Small, 1994). The two papers presented at this
conference by those Board staff members raise
important and challenging questions that we
believe should motivate much research in future
years. In addition, we wish to commend those
Board staff economists for their courage and
integrity in pushing past barriers that have
intimidated prior researchers and thereby pre­
cluded prior research on these difficult matters.
The basic issue is whether riskiness of the
investment rate of return on an asset is a charac­
teristic that rules out the possibility of an asset’s
contribution to the economy’s liquidity. Oddly,
that issue has largely precluded prior considera­
tion of risky assets as components of central bank
monetary aggregates. Yet clearly the position is
groundless. While it is clear that risky assets are
not good candidates for legal means of payment,
monetary aggregates now contain many assets
that are not legal means of payment. It has long

been recognized that currency and demand
deposits provide much, but by no means all, of
the economy’s monetary service flow.
No one has suggested that bond or stock mutual
funds should be made legal means of payment.
In addition, stock and bond mutual funds currently
are bundled by companies into packages of funds
that include money market funds within the
bundle. Hence, it often is as easy as a telephone
call to transfer funds from stock and bond funds
into checkable money market funds. Although
stock and bond funds certainly should not be
made legal means of payment, it simply makes
no sense to exclude bond and stock mutual
funds from consideration as assets contributing
monetary liquidity to the economy.
There is no necessary conflict between the
existence of r i s k y r e tu r n and the c o n t r i b u t i o n
of liquidity to the economy. The two are not
mutually exclusive.1 Yet prior researchers have
excluded assets having substantial principle risk
from consideration as components of monetary
aggregates. It indeed is odd that such an obviously
groundless prejudice has precluded research by
the entire economics profession on an important

1 Formally, the correct method used to determine the cluster­
ing of components within an aggregation-theoretic monetary
aggregate is testing for blockwise weak separability. An
innovative new approach to testing for weak separability was
recently proposed by Swofford and Whitney (1994). Although
risky return complicates testing for weak separability, risk in
no way precludes acceptance of that hypothesis. In fact, a
successful test of weak separability with random rates of
return is included in Barnett and Zhou (1994).




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

54

topic. The authors of the two Board staff papers
are right. The authors have done a service to the
profession by exploring the topic for the first time.

CHALLENGES PRESENTED TO
ECONOMIC THEORY
Riskiness of the rate of return simply does
not preclude the production of monetary services
by an asset. Riskiness of the rate of return, how­
ever, certainly does make life more difficult for
index number theorists and aggregation theorists.
Most of the literature in those fields is produced
under the assumption of perfect certainty or risk
neutrality. Extensions of that literature to risk
aversion were begun recently by Poterba and
Rotemberg (1987), Barnett and Yue (1991), Barnett,
Hinich and Yue (1989) and Barnett and Zhou
(1994). We believe that the important issues raised
by Collins and Edwards (1994) and Orphanides,
Reid and Small (1994) at this conference should
serve as motivation for further research on index
number theory and aggregation theory under
risk aversion. We do indeed welcome the
increased motivation in that area provided by
the work of those Board staff researchers.
But there is an even more fundamental
problem. The existence of an investment rate
of return, even a perfectly certain one, raises
questions about how an asset should be incorpo­
rated into an aggregate. While the existence of
such a rate of return does not prevent an asset
from producing monetary services, the share
of the asset’s services that can be viewed as
“monetary” is strongly affected. This comment
is directed towards an investigation of that share.

HISTORICAL BACKGROUND
At one time, money was cash plus demand
deposits. No controversy existed on that topic.
But a sequence of technological changes and
innovations occurred, and continued to occur,
such that an increasingly large number of substi­
tutes for money produced an increasingly large
share of the economy’s monetary services. The
result was the Bach Commission, the Gurley and
Shaw (1960) book, the Pesek and Saving (1967)
book, and many other important contributions
that influenced the growing movement towards
the construction of increasingly broad monetary
aggregates. The response of most central banks,
however, has been to accept one aspect of that
research while conveniently overlooking another
closely related aspect.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



In particular, the researchers who first worked
in that area were very clear on one simple, ele­
mentary fact: Investment yield is not a m onetary
service. There was a reason that all monetary
economists once agreed that money included only
cash and non-interest-bearing demand deposits.
If investment yield were a monetary service,
then coal mines would be money. Land would
be money. The entire capital stock of the United
States would be money.
This is not to deny that assets that produce
an investment rate of return, whether risky or
not, can produce monetary services. Interest
yielding monetary assets, however, are joint
products. Some of their services are monetary.
Some are not. This fact seems to have escaped
many of the world’s central banks. To the degree
that the economy equates marginal utilities per
dollar across assets, the marginal utility of mon­
etary services produced by an asset must decrease
as its marginal non-monetary services increase—
and investment return is very clearly not a
monetary service.
To underscore our point, we bring up the
famous diamonds-versus-water paradox. The
total utility of water exceeds that of diamonds,
even though the marginal utility of diamonds
exceeds that of water. In fact, as one moves
along a concave utility function, marginal utility
varies inversely with total utility. Hence, the
statements made above about marginal utilities
should not be confused with the total or average
monetary service flow produced by an asset.
But it is the marginal utilities that are relevant
to measuring the prices in index numbers, such
as the Divisia, Fisher ideal, Paasche or Laspeyres
quantity indexes. We hope that we also do not
have to remind this audience that the prices
(user costs) in such indexes are not the weights.
We nevertheless find that this literature contains
many misunderstandings of monetary index
number theory, and most of those misunder­
standings are produced by confusing prices
with weights and marginal utilities with
total or average utilities.

FERRARI SPORTS CARS
It has been asked at this conference whether
stock funds or bond funds are “m oney,” or are
they not money. We would like to ask a differ­
ent question. Are Ferrari sports cars transporta­
tion machines or recreational machines? We
can imagine a Ferrari owner responding that a

55

Ferrari is strictly a transportation machine, and
that the high price is produced by the Ferrari’s
superior performance on highways and on
winding roads. Hence, the price of a Ferrari
is the discounted present value solely of the
transportation services. But I expect that most
of the rest of us would view the price of a Ferrari
as being the sum of the discounted present values
of two different flows: transportation services
and recreational services.
Ferraris are joint products, in terms of the
services produced. Interest-bearing monetary
assets similarly are joint products. Such assets
produce both monetary and non-monetary ser­
vices, whereby the interest yield unquestionably
is in the latter category. Hence, the correct answer
to the question asked by the Board’s staff econo­
mists at this conference is that such assets,
including stock and bond mutual funds, are
partially money and partially not money.

W HAT TO DO NEXT
We see that we are presented with a paradox.
More and more assets are contributing to the
economy’s monetary service flow. As made clear
by the authors of the two Board staff papers, stock
and bond funds now are among those assets. The
investment yields of that growing collection of
assets, however, are not monetary services. If we
do not add such assets into the monetary aggre­
gates, we overlook some of the economy’s mone­
tary service flow. If we do add those assets into
the aggregates, we contaminate the aggregates
with non-monetary services.
The answer should be obvious. We must
untangle the two discounted present values: the
discounted present value of the monetary service
flow and the discounted present value of the
investment yield. Indeed, it can be done.

THE THEORY
Barnett (1987) defined the economic stock
of money to be the discounted present value of
expenditure on the services of monetary assets.
Barnett (1991) derived that discounted present
value in the form that we display below. During
period s let p * = the true cost of living index, let
Mis be nominal balances of monetary asset i, let
rjs be the nominal expected holding period yield
on monetary asset i, and define mis = M J p * to
be real balances of monetary asset i. The current
period is defined to be period t so that s > t.
Define the discount rate for period s to be




1
fo r s = t
(1) p s =<! s-i
n (i + R u) f o r s > t .
By letting the planning horizon, 7, go to infinity
in the second term of Barnett (1978, eq. 2; 1980,
eq. 3.3; 1981, eq. 7.3), we immediately acquire
the following definition for the Economic Stock
of Money, first derived as definition 1 and
equation 2.2 in Barnett (1991):
Definition 1: Under risk neutrality, the economic
stock of money during period t is

(2K=XX

P's

Ps

P l i l + fj,

m,

Ps+1

The concept of economic stock used to produce
Definition 1 is the user-cost-evaluated expenditure
on the services of the n monetary assets that are its
components. It should be observed that the pro­
cedure used in Barnett (1978, eq. 2; 1980, eq. 3.3;
1981, eq. 7.3) to acquire that discounted present
value for finite T was just back substitution and
algebraic manipulation of the sequence of flowof-funds identities. Hence, our conclusion is
produced entirely from accounting identities.
If we now substitute equation 1 and mis =
M J p * into equation 2, we acquire the following
result:

M.

Unfortunately, this equation includes expected
future values of interest rates and of monetary
asset holdings. While it may be reasonable to
assume that interest rates are stationary, no such
easy simplification is available for the stochastic
process of future monetary asset holdings. We
believe that a useful way to proceed would be to
use VAR forecasts of the monetary asset hold­
ings and rates of return. We plan to produce
results using that approach. But considering the
time constraint that we faced with this confer­
ence, we had no choice but to make strongly
simplifying assumptions. In particular, we
make the assumption which causes equation 3
to collapse into the Rotemberg, Driscoll and
Poterba (1994) CE index, first interpreted to be a
stock index in Barnett (1991).

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

56

Definition 2: The CE index is
(4)

R,

-M ,

We seek to find conditions under which equa­
tion 4 will equal equation 3. To that end, sup­
pose that expectations are stationary in the
sense that ris = r„ and Ris = Rit for all s > t, and
consider the static portfolio, (Mjs, M2s, ..., Mns) =
Mnf), for all s > t . Equation 3 reduces
to

viewed the interest yield on monetary assets to
be a monetary service. In fact, that possibility
was considered carefully and rejected unequivo­
cally in Pesek and Saving (1967).
In the discussion that follows, we shall
use this result to decompose the simple-sum
aggregates into their investment share and
their monetary services share. In each case, the
share is produced by discounting the flow to the
present value, the interest yield in one and the
service flow in the other. The decomposition
then is into Vt and V * , which partition

Rt

( 5)

I M„

( i+Rt :

i= 1

into its two parts, in accordance with equation 9.
Observe, however, that
(6)S

R, - ri,

£li +Rty -,+1

Rt R,

since the left side of equation 6 is a convergent
geometric series (minus the first term in the
series). Substituting equation 6 into equation 5,
we acquire our result:

“AN CIEN T” HISTORY
There was a time— long, long ago—when
money was currency and demand deposits,
and demand deposits did not yield interest.
In those days, we see that
n

V* = 0, so that Vt = ^ Mit.
1= 1

Theorem 1: Under stationary expectations,
the CE index is equal to the Economic Money
Stock.
Under the stationary expectations assump­
tion, we easily can discount to present value the
expected investment yield flows, risMis = ritMit
for s > t to get the following capitalized value:

,

(7)

(i+r rm

Again, we have a convergent geometric series in
the summation over s at any given i, so that we
find
F“ M„

(8) Vt*
1= 1

llt

Adding equation 8 to equation 4, we find that
(9) Vt + Vt' = f^ M ir
1=1

The conclusion is clear. The simple-sum
monetary aggregates measure the stock of money
only if the investment (interest) yield of the
monetary components is treated as a monetary
service. Yet it is difficult to think of any macroeconomic school of thought which has ever

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



Those were the days when the simple-sum
monetary aggregates were created, and we see that
the people who created them knew what they
were doing. But that simpler world is long gone.
Many assets that contribute to the economy’s
monetary services also yield an investment
rate of return.

THE DATA
We computed the decomposition into Vt and V*
of the official simple-sum M l and M2 indexes
along with the corresponding decomposition into
Vt and V* of the newly proposed simple-sum M2+
index. We also computed the decomposition into
V, and V* of bond mutual funds and stock mutual
funds as a means of further investigating the
source of the difference in behavior of M2 versus
M2+. The attached figures provide the results.
The decomposition depends upon the
measurement of the benchmark rate of return
Rt. Clearly, Vt increases as Rt increases, and V*
decreases as Rt increases. Hence, the monetary
service share (versus the investment share) of
the simple-sum aggregate “joint product” increases
as R, increases. The results can be biased in the
direction favoring the inclusion of stock and
bond funds by choosing an artificially high
setting for Rt. For the purpose of biasing the

57

Figure 1
M1 Joint Product and Economic Capital Stock

M1= simple sum joint product
CEM1= economic capital stock part of the joint product

results in that direction intentionally, we chose
the highest possible setting for Rt that could be
connected in any way with the available data.
As shown by Rotemberg, Driscoll and Poterba
(1994), Vt has a very volatile growth rate and,
hence, they advocate smoothing the interest rates
to produce smoother growth of the aggregates.
This is not surprising, since Vt and V * are stock
aggregates which tend to have volatile growth
rates. We use the same smoothing method
advocated by Rotemberg, Driscoll and Poterba
(1994). In particular, we replaced all of the
interest rates in the index by 13-quarter centered
moving averages. Since the moving averages are
centered, they are not defined for the first six
quarters or the last few six quarters. We used
the method advocated by Rotemberg, Driscoll
and Poterba and phased in the centered moving
average from asymmetric averages computed
during the first six and last six observations.
Once the smoothed interest data had been
constructed, we searched over those series for
the highest smoothed interest rate ever attained
by any component asset during our sample.




That ex post rate of return was 24.2 percent,
which we selected to be the value of Rt for all t.
In general, there is no reason for the benchmark
rate to be a constant or to equal any ex post rate
of return, since ex post rates of return tend to be
much more volatile than ex ante expected rates
of return. Our selection for the benchmark rate,
however, produces the largest value that we
could connect with the data, and we wanted to
produce results that would be biased in favor of
the Board staff members’ proposal. In interpreting
our results, the division of the simple sum into
the components Vt and V,* should be understood
to be biased very strongly towards Vt and away
from V *. Hence, the monetary services share
in the joint product should be viewed as inten­
tionally exaggerated.

THE RESULTS
Figure 1 contains the partition of simple-sum
M l into its investment share and its monetary
services share. The solid line is the monetary
service share produced from the computed value
of Vj. The vertical gap between the solid line
and the dotted line is the investment-motivated

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

58

Figure 2
M2 Joint Product and Economic Capital Stock

M2= simple sum joint product
CEM2= economic capital stock part of the joint product

share, V,*, which could be interpreted as the
“error-in-the-variable” embedded in the simplesum index, M l. The height of the dotted line from
the horizontal axis is the simple-sum index,
equaling the sum of V, and V * . As is evident
from Figure 1, the error-in-the-variable gap is
relatively small and does not vary much over
the sample. With a relatively constant vertical
gap, the rate of growth of M l is not greatly
affected by the error-in-the-variable gap. For
most statistical inferences and for policy, the
growth rate of money is what matters. Hence,
we see that the existence of the V * error gap
produces little difficulty for M l.
Figure 2 contains the analogous plot and
decomposition for the official simple-sum M2
aggregate. Observe that the error-in-the-variable
gap is large (and would be much larger for a
more realistic choice of Rt). In addition, that
gap is variable and trends downward, especially
recently. Hence, the existence of the error gap
not only effects the short-run growth rate dynamics
of the aggregate, but also biases downward the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



long-term growth rate. Inferences and policy
are not invariant to the existence of this gap.
Figure 3 contains the decomposition for the
M2+ aggregate that has been proposed at this
conference by Collins and Edwards (1994) and
Orphanides, Reid and Small (1994). Observe that
while the error gap is even larger than for M2,
the size of the gap is less variable and no longer
trends downward. Hence, the growth rate of the
error-shifted dotted line approximately tracks
the growth rate of the “correct” solid line.
To see why M2+ stabilizes the size of the gap
and thereby improves on the aggregate’s growth
rate performance, see Figures 4 and 5, which
display the decomposition of the stock mutual
funds data and the bond mutual funds data into
their economic capital stock share and their
error-in-the-variable shift. Observe that in each
of those two cases, the size of the gap grew rapidly
during the past two years. This growing error
gap offsets the declining error gap in M2, when
the stock and bond fund data are added into M2.

59

Figure 3
M2+ Joint Product and Economic Capital Stock

M2+= simple sum joint product
CEM2+= economic capital stock part of the joint product

In short, we conclude that the authors of the two
papers presented at this conference are correct in
concluding that the growth rate behavior of M2
is improved by incorporating the stock and bond
mutual fund data into M2. Indeed, it does appear
that substitution from M2 components into stock
and bond mutual funds has become important.

W HERE IS A L L OF THIS GOING?
There is an underlying dynamic to this trend
in monetary theory. Stabilizing the size of the
error gap requires continually incorporating more
assets into the monetary aggregates. The size of
the gap keeps growing. The share of the monetary
aggregate representing discounted monetary ser­
vices continues to decrease, and the monetary
aggregates look increasingly like pure investment
capital rather than money. Even if stabilizing the
size of the gap offsets long-run errors in growth
rate paths, the short-run dynamics of the aggre­
gates are likely to become increasingly disjoint
from monetary services growth.




In this paper we use the CE index, equation 4,
to permit easy decomposition of the simple-sum
aggregate “joint product” into its monetary
service and investment shares. Using the formula
in equation 3 with forecasted variables, perhaps
by a VAR, would be better. But generating
data that depends upon forecasts is unpleasant
for data-producing governmental agencies.
Smoothing interest rates to decrease the volatility
of the resulting aggregate is also unpleasant for
governmental agencies. For this conference,
decomposition of the stocks in that manner was
revealing. But as a means to produce data for a
central bank, there is a better way. It is the Divisia
monetary aggregates long advocated by Barnett
(1980). See Barnett, Fisher and Serletis (1992) and
Belongia and Chalfant (1989) for an overview
and some of the relevant empirical results.
The Divisia monetary aggregates directly mea­
sure monetary service flows, not the discounted
stock levels. The Divisia monetary aggregates do
not require smoothing of interest rates to smooth
the index’s growth rate, and the Divisia monetary

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

60

Figure 4
Common Stock Mutual Funds Joint Product and Economic
Capital Stock

StockQ= simple sum joint product
CEstock= economic capital stock part of the joint product

Figure 5
Bond Mutual Funds Joint Product and Economic Capital Stock

BondQ= simple sum joint product
CEbond= economic capital stock part of the joint product

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




61

aggregates contain no variables that need fore­
casting.2 In addition, Barnett (1991) proved that
if we could do the forecasting needed to compute
the monetary capital stock (equation 3), the result
would be identical to that produced by discounting
to present value the future stochastic process of
the Divisia monetary aggregate.

_____ , and Piyu Yue. “Exact Monetary Aggregation Under
Risk,” Washington University (Department of Economics),
St. Louis, Working Paper #163 (December 1991).

REFERENCES

Belongia, Michael T., and James Chalfant. “The Changing
Empirical Definition of Money: Some Estimates From a
Model of the Demand for Money Substitutes,” Journal of
Political Economy (April 1989), pp. 387-97.

Barnett, William A. “Reply to Julio J. Rotemberg,” in Michael T.
Belongia, ed., Monetary Policy on the 75th Anniversary of
the Federal Reserve System: Proceedings of the
Fourteenth Annual Economic Policy Conference of the
Federal Reserve Bank o f St. Louis. Kluwer Academic
Publishers, 1991, pp. 232-43.
_____ . “The Microeconomic Theory of Monetary Aggregation,”
in William A. Barnett and Kenneth J. Singleton, eds.,
New Approaches to Monetary Economics, Proceedings
of the Second International Symposium in Economic Theory
and Econometrics. Cambridge University Press, 1987,
pp. 115-68.
_____ . “The Optimal Level of Monetary Aggregation,” Journal
of Money, Credit and Banking (February 1982), pp. 687-710.
_____ . Consumer Demand and Labor Supply: Goods,
Monetary Assets, and Time. North-Holland, 1981.
_____ . “Economic Monetary Aggregates: An Application
of Index Number and Aggregate Theory,” Journal of
Econometrics (summer 1980), pp. 11-48.
_____ . “The User Cost of Money," Economics Letters, vol. 1
(1978), pp. 145-9.
_____ , and Ge Zhou (1993), “Financial Firm’s Production and
Supply-Side Monetary Aggregation Under Dynamic
Uncertainty,” this Review (March/April 1994), pp. 133-65.
_____ , Douglas Fisher, and Apostolos Serletis. “Consumer
Theory and the Demand for Money.” Journal o f Economic
Literature (December 1992), pp. 2086-119.

2 It is necessary to measure the benchmark rate, R, to construct
the Divisia monetary aggregates, and we advocate the use
of the upper envelope of the yield-curve-adjusted, holdingperiod yields on all of the components in the broadest
aggregate. Obviously, we do not advocate the use of the
extreme, constant setting of 24.4 percent, chosen for an
illustrative purpose in this paper. However, it should be
observed that the behavior of the Divisia monetary aggre­
gate is much more robust to variations in the method of
measuring the benchmark rate than is the CE index, which
is very sensitive to that rate’s selection. The reason is that




_____ , Melvin Hinich, and Piyu Yue. “Monitoring Monetary
Aggregates Under Risk Aversion,” in Michael T. Belongia,
ed., Monetary Policy on the 75th Anniversary of the Federal
Resen/e System: Proceedings of the Fourteenth Annual
Economic Policy Conference o f the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis. Kluwer Academic Publishers, 1989, pp. 189-222.

Collins, Sean, and Cheryl L. Edwards. “An Alternative Monetary
Aggregate: M2 Plus Household Holdings of Bond and
Equity Mutual Funds,” this Review (November/December
1994), pp. 7-29.
Gurley, John, and Edward S. Shaw. Money in a Theory of
Finance. Brookings Institution, 1960.
Orphanides, Athanasios, Brian Reid, and David H. Small.
“The Empirical Properties of a Monetary Aggregate That
Adds Bond and Stock Funds to M2,” this Review
(November/December 1994), pp. 31-51.
Pesek, B.P., and T.R. Saving. Money, Wealth and Economic
Theory. Macmillan, 1967.
Poterba, James M., and Julio J. Rotemberg. “Money in the
Utility Function: an Empirical Implementation,” in William
Barnett and Kenneth Singleton, eds., New Approaches
to Monetary Economics, Proceedings of the Second
International Symposium in Economic Theory and
Econometrics. Cambridge University Press, 1987,
pp. 219-40.
Rotemberg, Julio J., John C. Driscoll, and James M. Poterba.
“Money, Output, and Prices: Evidence From a New
Monetary Aggregate,” Journal o f Business and Economic
Statistics (forthcoming).
Swofford, James L., and Gerald A. Whitney. “A Revealed
Preference Test For Weakly Separable Utility Maximization
With Incomplete Adjustment,” Journal o f Econometrics
(January/February 1994), pp. 235-49.

the benchmark rate appears symmetrically in both the
numerator and denominator of the share weights of the
Divisia index, which in turn is a growth-rate index. Since
the CE index is a level index, variations in any interest rate,
including the benchmark rate, produce jumps in the level of
the unsmoothed index. Jumps in levels produce spikes in
growth rates.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994




63

Jacob S. D reyer
Jacob S. Dreyer, former chief economist at the Investment
Company Institute, is president of JDA International, a consult­
ing firm.

Commentary

I PRESUME THAT I WAS ASKED to comment
on the papers by Collins and Edwards, and
Orphanides, Reid and Small because I spent a
good portion of the last six years looking at the
“+,” that is, on the assets, the desirability of whose
inclusion into a broadened monetary aggregate is
the subject of these deliberations. It is true that I
not only watched stock and bond fund assets, and
money market fund assets, but also had some
influence on their definition, methods of collec­
tion and aggregation, and similar mundane
matters. So, when the yield curve steepened a
few years ago and, consequently, the flow of
retail savings into longer-term debt instruments
intensified, those who were uncomfortable with
the apparent unresponsiveness of M2 to consec­
utive reductions in the Fed funds rate frequently
used me as a sounding board for all sorts of
p r o p o s a l s to r e d e f in e th i s m o n e t a r y aggregate.

In other words, I have been exposed to the alleged
problems and proposed solutions before and I
am pleased to discuss them once again.
However, since I was asked to specifically
comment on the presented papers, and duty comes
before pleasure, let me start with the papers and
then move on to the broader issue of re-definition
of monetary aggregates.
I will begin with the article examining empirical
properties of an expanded M2, M2+. The authors
of this article, Orphanides, Reid and Small, do an
excellent job of examining the stability, indicator
properties and, to some extent, controlability of
M2+ (that is, M2 plus assets of bond and equity
mutual funds) by trying to determine the demand




for M2+, including reduced-form relationships
that presumably would capture the determinants
of supply as well.
To specify the demand for M2+, they correctly
recognize the importance of specifying the ex ante
return on its close substitutes—real assets such
as commodities and durable goods, as well as
financial assets such as direct holdings of short­
term instruments, bonds and stocks. However,
they note the difficulty of measuring such returns.
They also note that M2+ would include the capital
gains and losses on stock and bond mutual funds,
because of the difficulty—I would say impossi­
bility— of removing such ex ante gains and losses
from the mutual fund component. Not inciden­
tally, they do not believe such gains and losses
should be removed, a subject to which I shall
return later.
It is important for me to summarize their
conclusions because I will be using them in
commenting on the other article. The authors
conclude from their analysis, and I agree with
their conclusions, that:
1.

On stability:
“...the estimated demand functions are
not very stable. Hence, the usefulness
of these equations in interpreting and
forecasting movements in M2+ may
prove to be limited.”

2.

On indicator properties:
“In terms of their information content, M2+
and M2 do not appear to have differed

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

64

significantly.” Both overpredicted nominal
GDP before and during the last recession.
“... capital gains and losses cause growth of
M2+ to be more volatile than that of M2.
Moreover, the capital gains and losses in
M2+ may cause movements in the aggregate
that neither reflect shifts in the stance of
monetary policy nor provide appropriate
signals for changes in policy.”
3.

On controllability:
The authors do not explicitly examine
this aspect but, based on their previous
statement just quoted, presumably would
agree that M2+ is far less controllable than
M2, which itself has not proven to be con­
trollable at all during the period when it
was the major monetary aggregate targeted
by the Federal Reserve.

On the basis of these conclusions, they doubt
that anything would be gained by expanding
M2 to include assets of stock and bond mutual
funds. I agree completely.
By contrast, the authors of the second paper,
Collins and Edwards, still consider M2+ (and its
companion, M3+) a worthwhile replacement for
M2. They argue that M2+ is less worse than any
other proposed replacement, first because the
added components, that is, assets of long-term
mutual funds, have enough moneyness—their
medium-of-exchange and liquidity attributes, and
second, because, as intermediation continues to
shift wealth from present components of M2 to
long-term mutual funds, M2+ should, in fact, grow
in value as an indicator of economic activity.
The authors of the paper recognize the poten­
tial pitfalls of using M2+. For example, some
of the components of M2+ will have to be inter­
polated from annual data to monthly series in
order to net out the institutional assets that
would otherwise lead to double counting. Such
interpolation drastically reduces the indicator
properties of an aggregate for short-term purposes.
Even if we leave the interpolation problem aside,
the usefulness of M2+ as a long-run indicator
also would be limited: For the demand for M2+
to be properly specified, one would n eed to

specify ex ante returns—a task bordering on
the im possible, as the authors o f both papers
seem to acknow ledge.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



The technical issue then appears to be, at
least in part, whether the moneyness attributes
of the “+” make its components so indistin­
guishable from the components of M2 proper
as to warrant the expansion of M2 despite the
deficiencies of the broader measure established
by Orphanides, Reid and Small, and pitfalls of
using it as recognized by Collins and Edwards.
A broader issue is, of course, what would be
gained, if anything, by including assets of stock
and bond funds into an expanded M2.
So now, as my principal assigned duty is
fulfilled, I feel I am entitled to express my other
thoughts on this matter. In order not to keep the
audience breathless, I shall state at the outset
that I disagree with the conclusions of the paper
by Collins and Edwards and think that nothing
would be gained by introducing yet another,
broader monetary aggregate.
First, if the demand for M2+ is neither
stable nor more informative than that for M2, as
Orphanides, Reid and Small show, then deciding
to adopt it because it is less worse than other
proposed aggregates is a most unusual criterion
for selection. I shall elaborate on this in a moment.
Second, it is fairly easy to show that the added
components making up M2+ lack moneyness,
contrary to what the authors of the second paper
claim. Table 1 gives the turnover of some of the
major components of M2 (those in columns one
through four, and six and seven of the table; small
time deposits, overnight repurchase agreements
and overnight Eurodollar deposits were not
available) and the turnover of bond and equity
funds (the last two columns).
The striking feature of the table is that the
turnover rates for the bond and equity funds are
so much lower than that for any other financial
assets. They are less than 10 percent of that of
general-purpose money market funds, and less
than 0.07 percent of that of demand deposits
outside of New York City hanks. Moreover, in
contradistinction to demand deposits and even
money market funds whose turnover ratios have
tended to drift upwards over the nine years por­
trayed in the table, turnover ratios on bond and
equity funds have declined or remained constant.
Thus, their relative moneyness, at least as mea­
sured by turnover ratios has, in fact, decreased.
I may add that the turnover ratio has in its
numerator the sum of debits, that is, it includes
exchanges out of these funds. These in most

65

Table 1
Turnover of Deposits, MMMFs and Bond & Equity Funds, 1984-92
Deposits at commercial banks
Demand deposits

Demand deposits

NYC banks

other banks

MMMFs

OCDs

Savings

Institution

Bond & equity funds

Broker/

General

Bond/

dealer

purpose

income

Equity

1984

1,843

269

15.8

5.0

4.2

3.0

2.2

0.4

0.3

1985

2,169

302

16.7

4.5

5.0

3.5

2.5

0.3

0.4
0.5

1986

2,461

327

16.8

3.0

4.6

3.4

2.9

0.3

1987

2,671

357

13.8

3.1

4.6

3.7

3.0

0.5

0.6

1988

2,897

333

13.2

2.9

4.6

3.5

2.4

0.3

0.5

1989

3,421

408

15.2

3.0

4.5

3.6

2.4

0.3

0.4

1990

3,820

465

16.5

6.2*

4.3

3.2

2.2

0.3

0.4

1991

4,271

448

16.2

5.3*

4.8

3.2

2.3

0.3

0.4

1992

4,798

436

14.4

4.7*

6.9

3.6

2.7

0.3

0.3

'Includes money market deposit accounts at banks for these years.
SOURCES: Federal Reserve Bulletin (various issues) and Investment Company Institute

cases represent changes in asset composition of
a shareholder’s overall portfolio rather than debit
to a checking account or a money market fund
which has for its counterpart acquisition of, say,
a new suit. Excluding exchanges out (that is,
redemption exchanges) from debits would make
the already low turnover ratios for long-term
funds considerably lower. In any event, the low
turnover of bond and equity funds indicates that
they probably have far less to do with the types
of transactions that might influence GDP over
the span of time normally adopted in framing
monetary policy. In fact, it seems plausible that
a switch of, say $1,000, from my money market
fund or bank account to a bond or stock fund,
suggests a decision to move a potential near-term
$1,000 purchase into the future, quite possibly
beyond the relevant time frame. Consequently,
it seems to me that, contrary to the claims of
Collins and Edwards, very little, if any, moneyness
resides in the bond and equity components of
M2+. I think that the extremely low transaction
cost of converting these assets into cash creates
this illusion of moneyness.
Third, adopting M2+ because it might eventu­
ally have better indicator properties and would, at
least, in the meantime, envelop close substitutes
for M2 assets, leads me to ask where will the
broadening end? Milton Friedman recognized




many years ago that the definition of money was
as much an empirical as a theoretical matter,
but deciding where to draw the line is not easy
and, under current law, the Federal Reserve must
decide where to draw it. Now, I don’t want to get
into a largely doctrinal argument over the wisdom
of the requirement to set targets for monetary
aggregates. However, because financial institu­
tions are able and willing to grant credit lines
collateralized by all types of assets, it does seem
to me that broadening the definition to envelop

close substitutes h as as its fea sib le upper limit
all o f hou seh old wealth i f not all o f national
wealth. I can get liquidity out of my home equity
by simply opening my desk drawer, grasping
my pen and writing out the amount I wish to
spend. Moreover, I don’t have to fear the tax
consequences of my decision because I don’t
have to compute and report any of the capital
gain on my home at the time I wrote the check.
By contrast, if I were to write a check on my
bond fund this would be a capital transaction
requiring relatively complex computations of
my cost basis for reporting short- or long-term
capital gains. In this sense, a home equity
line of credit has greater moneyness than a
stock or bond fund. Thus, rather than stopping
with including bond and equity mutual funds,
shouldn’t we go all the way and include home
equity, margin credit, other lines of credit,

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

66

including signature loans and, eventually,
as our experience with financial innovation
suggests, any assets that can be sold or
borrowed against?1
This third comment brings me to a question
that has been too easily dismissed by Collins
and Edwards. Has the definition of money gone
in the wrong direction? It seems to me that is a
conclusion a reasonable person could draw from
the experience of the past several decades as the
Federal Reserve tended to broaden the definition
of money. Despite the view of the authors that
the Federal Reserve now would be reluctant to
backtrack towards narrow measures of money,
it is my humble opinion that the movement
has been indeed in the wrong direction.
Although we all understand that monetary
aggregates are not the ultimate objectives of
policy— sustained growth and low inflation
are really the measures by which the Federal
Reserve policies will be judged—I have always
been struck by the fact that the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) has typically used
various components of bank reserves as internal
guides for its open market operations even as
it was proceeding in evolutionary steps from
narrow to broad definitions of money when
communicating its objectives to the public.

1 I can understand the tendency to resort to broader defini­
tions if the desire is to incorporate wealth effects into the for­
mation of monetary policy. However, such effects tend to
have little explanatory power from quarter to quarter, or from
year to year, in explaining movements in aggregate demand,
production, employment and especially inflation.
Furthermore, if this were the case, all assets that can easily
be liquified would have to be included into such a wealtheffect-capturing aggregate.


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS


Of course, I don’t want to give the impression
that the links between narrow aggregates like
reserves or the monetary base and the ultimate
policy objectives are any more precise than the
links between broader aggregates and those
objectives. Nevertheless, the place of such
narrow aggregates in the interplay of policy, ulti­
mate objectives and information variables (such
as commodity prices, interest rates, yield curves
and exchange rates) has been more “enduring”
in the conduct of monetary policy than any of
the publically targeted monetary aggregates.
To summarize both papers, I agree with
Orphanides and others and disagree for the same
reasons with Collins and Edwards that adding M2+
to the monetary zoo would not make monetary
policy more effective in achieving its ultimate
objectives or make the Fed’s stance more trans­
parent to the Congress and the public.
I have tried to put the work of the two papers
in the larger context of either being prepared to
draw the line at total wealth rather than repeat­
edly drawing the line, erasing it, and redrawing
it again and again at arbitrary segments of the
wealth spectrum or, on the other hand, of moving
back towards narrower aggregates which the
Federal Reserve uses and can control. To me
the choice is obvious.

67

John V. Duca
John V. Duca is a research officer at the Federal Reserve
Bank o f Dallas. The author thanks Anne King and Chih-Ping
Chang for their excellent research.

Commentary
SOME BACKGROUND ON MONEYDEMAND INSTABILITY
PAST EPISODES OF MISSING money can
shed light on whether bond and/or equity funds
should be added to M2. My perspective on
how to analyze monetary aggregates can be char­
acterized as a dynamic market-share approach.
If financial aggregates have a stable relationship
to nominal GDP and if banks have a stable share
of the financial market, then bank-based mone­
tary aggregates like M2 will be helpful indica­
tors. The two most pronounced episodes of
missing money, M l in the mid-1970s and M2
in the early 1990s, occurred when the competi­
tiveness of the banking system declined.
In the mid-1970s, firms shifted away from
bank loans toward commercial paper at a time
when Regulation Q induced banks to ration credit
and banks were passing along the heightened
cost of reserve requirements when interest rates
were high. On the liability side, binding deposit
rate ceilings and high interest rates led firms and
households to adopt cash management and to use
money market funds which purchased commercial
paper and Treasury bills. In terms of flows, firms
used the proceeds from issuing paper to pay off
bank loans while banks used these funds to pay
off depositors who were shifting assets into money
funds. In Figure 1, the development of money
funds allows part of the flow of short-term
finance to bypass the banking system.
By comparison, the bypassing of the banking
system in the early 1990s occurred in the flow of
medium- to long-term finance (Figure 2). Higher




deposit insurance premiums and more costly
risk-based capital standards led banks to boost
the spread of prime over short-term rates, which
helped induce firms to shift toward bond and
equity financing. At the same time, wider net
interest margins stemming from regulatory
changes, coupled with a steep yield curve,
encouraged households to shift out of small
time deposits into bond and equity funds. In
terms of flows, firms paid off bank loans with
proceeds from issuing bonds and stocks bought
by mutual funds whose purchases, in turn, were
financed by assets that households shifted out
of bank deposits. Both episodes show how the
banking system is not a closed loop, because
agents innovate to circumvent banks when
banks become relatively more costly to use.

THE CEN TRAL EM PIRICAL ISSUE
If one could model the shocks to money
demand, then modified money-demand models
would work. However, if households have fun­
damentally changed their asset behavior, then it
may be better to broaden an aggregate. In assessing
the impact of Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC)
activity and the yield curve on M 2 , 1 have found
that M2 plus non-IRA/Keogh household bond
funds is more explainable than M2 using Federal
Reserve Board-style (circa 1990) M2 models
(Duca, forthcoming). This suggests that the
behavioral relationships have changed. However,
given that bond funds were negligible prior to the
mid-1980s, the analysis was effectively conducted
over a period when bond fund assets did not
suffer sizable capital losses. T he issu e o f

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

68

Figure 1
Short-Term Finance

w h eth er to a d d b o n d or b o n d an d s to ck fu n d s
to M2 is an em p irical on e an d b oils dow n to
w h eth er we lo s e m ore from m akin g M2 m ore
vu ln erable to c a p ita l gain s an d losses than
we gain from internalizin g p ortfo lio shifts
betw een M2, an d b o n d an d equ ity fu n ds.

A CO M M ENT ON COLLINS AND
EDWARDS
This is a good paper. The authors are very
careful in how they construct and describe the
data used in building M2+. This study will
be a helpful resource for many analysts.

SOME COMM ENTS ON ORPHANIDES,
REID AND S M A LL (ORS)
Overall, this is a very nice and careful study.
The only suggestion I have regards how the
authors assess the indicator properties of M2
and M2+. I have some reservations about using
only Granger regressions of GDP and money
growth rates to assess indicator properties in the
ORS study. This approach has the problem of
letting bygones-be-bygones. That is, variability
in money and GDP growth may obscure any


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS


information in long-run relationships between
money and nominal output, if such relationships
still exist. On this point, ORS could look into
a simple error-correction model of nominal GDP
that imposes a long-run velocity relationship.
They then could compare results using M2
versus M2+ as ad d itio n a l evidence about
indicator properties.
To shed some light on this point, consider
some forecasts of inflation using a framework that
imposes a long-run relationship between money
and nominal output. Namely, the (in)famous
P-star model. Figure 3 shows out-of-sample
forecasts of inflation, as measured by the implicit
GDP deflator. These extend recent research with
Zsolt Becsi (Becsi and Duca, forthcoming). As
we can see, the P-star model using M2 severely
under-predicts inflation to the point of forecasting
deflation in 1993. By contrast, M2 plus bond
funds (M2B) and M2+ do a good job of tracking
this inflation measure since 1991, with a slight
edge to M2B. Interestingly, M2 does a better job
in predicting inflation during the m id-1980s’
surge in bond and equity funds, whereas M2+
and M2B do better during the early-1990s’
surge in mutual funds. Why?

69

Figure 2
Long-Term Finance

W H Y THE MID-1980S’ SURGE IN
M U T U A L FUNDS DIFFERS FRO M
THE 1990s’ SURGE
I believe that the answer reflects differences
in the sources of inflows during these episodes.
The surge of the mid-1980s came shortly after
IRA, 401K and Keogh regulations were liberalized.
Given the incentives to use these retirement
vehicles, many households learned more about
mutual funds and likely applied this knowledge
to other asset holdings. This is consistent with
the fact that household holdings of IRA/Keogh
and non-IRA/Keogh bond and equity fund bal­
ances grew rapidly in the mid-1980s. It is also
consistent with flow-of-funds data, which sug­
gest that the assets that households shifted into
bond and equity funds came more from direct
holdings of bonds and equities than from M2
deposits. This finding is also consistent with
the relatively good fit of M2 demand models
in the mid-1980s.
By contrast, flow-of-funds data suggest that
more of the inflows into bond and equity funds
during the early-1990s reflected shifts out of M2
deposits rather than out of direct bond and equity




holdings. This is consistent with the missing
M2 phenomenon of recent years.
Four factors may explain why the inflows into
bond and equity funds came more from M2 in
the early-1990s relative to the mid-1980s. First,
compared to the m id-1980s, the yield curve was
steeper for a longer period of time in the early1990s. Thus, households had a greater incentive
to shift out of M2 deposits in recent years. Second,
because short-term rates fell much more in the
early 1990s than in the mid-1980s, there were
negative income effects on retirees holding small
time deposits that encouraged them to shift out
of bank CDs into higher-earning bond and equity
funds. Third, declines in loads and fees on
mutual funds (as shown by ORS) reduced the
cost of shifting into mutual funds. Milbourne’s
(1986) modified Miller-Orr model implies that
smaller loads will induce shifts from M2 into
bond and stock funds. The fourth factor reflects
the realization during the early-1990s that jobs
are less secure—especially for professionals. As
the world becomes more Schumpeterian, house­
holds will increasingly rely on portable, defined
contribution pensions. Such plans typically
require that households make investment

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

70

Figure 3
Actual and Forecasted Inflation from the P* Model
(Implicit GDP Deflator, SAAR)
Percent

decisions. As a result of being more active in
managing their retirement assets, households
are becoming increasingly aware of alternatives
to M2 and are becoming better managers of
their assets.
Differences between the mid-1980s and early
1990s imply that future research should examine
the substitutability of bond and equity funds not
only for M2, but also for direct holdings of bonds
and equity. In addition, future work that applies
learning models to bond and equity funds may
prove fruitful.

W HAT SHOULD THE FED DO?
I favor an eclectic approach to conducting
monetary policy because innovation by the
private sector at times causes breakdowns in
the relationship between financial variables
and the economy. That said, part of our job
at the Fed is to update financial indicators
in light of those innovations.
As for using monetary aggregates as indica­
tors, I have two positions. First, since recent
innovations are mainly affecting the non-M l
component of M2, narrow money measures,
net of currency, could be used as information

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS



variables within models that control for the high
sensitivity of narrow money to interest rates and
mortgage refinancing activity. Nevertheless, the
high rate sensitivity of narrow aggregates limits
their usefulness as monetary targets under the
Humphrey-Hawkins Act. Second, I would also
monitor M2 and M2 broadened to include bond
and/or equity mutual funds, keeping in mind
that capital gains and losses w ill have direct
price effects on M2+ and M2B balances and
will induce portfolio substitution between
M2 and these broader aggregates.

REFERENCES
Becsi, Zsolt, and John V. Duca. “Adding Bond Funds to M2 in
the P-Star Model of Inflation,” Economics Letters (forthcoming).
Collins, Sean and Cheryl L. Edwards. “An Alternative
Monetary Aggregate: M2 Plus Household Holdings of Bond
and Equity Mutual Funds,” this Review
(November/December 1994), pp. 7-29.
Duca, John V. “Should Bond Funds Be Included in M2?,”
Journal o f Banking and Finance (forthcoming).
Milbourne, Ross. “Financial Innovation and the Demand for
Liquid Assets,” Journal o f Money, Credit and Banking
(November 1986), pp. 506-11.
Orphanides, Athanasios, Brian Reid, and David H. Small.
‘The Empirical Properties of a Monetary Aggregate that
Adds Bond and Stock Funds to M2,” this Review,
(November/December 1994), pp. 31-51.

71

Joshua Feinm an
Joshua Feinman is vice president o f Banker’s Trust.

Commentary

L SYMPATHIZE WITH THE DIFFICULTIES
that the authors have had in trying to explain and
model the financial innovation intermediation that
has been occurring in recent years, and the ways
that these changes have affected the relationships
between monetary aggregates and GDP. In fact, I
grappled with some of these issues m yself when
I was at the Board of Governors. I certainly appre­
ciate the difficulties and potential pitfalls.
At the Board, I had it a bit easier than these
authors, since I was mainly working on modeling
M2. These authors have taken it a step further
by constructing and modeling a new aggregate,
M2+, that really goes in a very different direction
and takes us in ways that the traditional monetary
aggregates have not had to deal with.
A starting point for discussing the behavior
of any monetary aggregate—M2, M3 or M2+,
or any other—has to be the changes that have
occurred in our financial system in recent years.
Particularly important have been the shifts in
the patterns of financial intermediation and the
efforts by both borrowers and lenders to adopt a
more cautious approach to leverage. The most
important change in financial intermediation has
been the relative shrinkage of the depository sector.
At the same time, perhaps the most important
financial innovation has been the proliferation
of information about the accessibility and
liquidity of mutual funds.
Both of these changes reflect the effects of a
dramatic shrinkage of the government subsidy
to the depository system in recent years. This



shrinkage has manifested itself in a variety
of ways, including higher deposit insurance pre­
miums, more stringent capital standards, and
tighter supervision, regulation and examination.
All this has resulted in a smaller amount of
depository intermediation in the economy and
a smaller share of the economy’s overall credit
being recorded on the books of depositories. In
addition, we have seen a smaller share of that
smaller amount of depository credit being funded
through deposits, in part because of increases in
deposit insurance premiums.
The pie charts shown by Cheryl Edwards
and Sean Collins illustrate the decreasing impor­
tance of deposits as a share of total household
assets. This is obviously just the flip side of the
depository shrinkage. The banking system has
been less aggressive in pursuing deposits in
recent years, and households have reacted by
reducing their deposits accordingly. The larger
upshot of this, of course, has been major shifts
in the relationships between broad monetary
aggregates—composed primarily of the liabilities
of the depository sector— and GDP. This has
resulted in the recent record-high GDP velocities
of the broad monetary aggregates.
I believe this explains the major part of what
has been happening. Although the steepening
yield curve has certainly played a role, I never
thought that was the key thing. Even though I’ve
used yield curve spreads myself in modeling, I’ve
always had problems with it on theoretical grounds.
First, you have the theoretical problems arising
from the expectations view of the yield curve.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

72

Saying people simply pick the highest point
on the yield curve flies in the face of economic
theory. But even more to the point, I think there’s
nothing per se that prevents banks, if they want
to, from going out the yield curve and pursuing
longer-term CDs more aggressively. If you didn’t
have the shrinkage in the banking system going
on—which I think has been the fundamental
thing—banks could and probably would have
been more aggressive in pursuing longer-dated
CDs with more aggressive pricing.
The bottom line is, in my opinion, the
shrinkage of depository sector. This has been
accompanied by increases in the direct-placement
credit market and by the growth of new financial
intermediaries. Obviously, the most visible new
intermediary has been the mutual fund industry
that we are discussing. That is why, at a very
simple level, it is extremely appealing to want
to create an aggregate that adds in these mutual
funds to M2. The charts in the paper by
Athanasios Orphanides and his colleagues
show clearly that we have had outflows from
M2 and its components while we have had
strong inflows into these mutual funds; from
the surface it looks appealing to build a new
aggregate including these mutual funds.
Building a broad monetary aggregate that
internalizes substitution among alternative assets
also was the intent of the Federal Reserve Board
staff when they defined the current M2 in 1980.
At that time, the substitution was from M l to,
primarily, small CDs and money market mutual
funds (MMMFs). Including the close alternatives
to M l meant that the new broader aggregate was
much less sensitive to market interest rates. This
is for two reasons. First, the rates paid on the
deposits included in the non-M l component
of the new M2 aggregate tended to adjust much
more quickly to changes in market rates then
did rates paid on M l. This sharply reduced
the incentive to substitute away from M2, into
assets not included in M2, when market rates
changed. Second, the broader aggregate captured
internally the substitution from liquid deposits
into small time deposits when market rates
increased and vice versa.
When we look at the charts shown today,
it is very tempting to say that a new, broader
aggregate could capture some part of the substitu­
tion away from small time deposits and MMMFs
and into bond and equity mutual funds. Even
so, having stated that, I think the articles


FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS


suggest— and I agree—that we must be skeptical
about the usefulness of an aggregate that adds
these stock and bond funds to M2. To avoid get­
ting into a tremendous amount of detail, I would
just highlight a couple of points. Obviously,
the capital gains issues that both Athanasios
Orphanides and Cheryl Edwards mentioned is
critical. It’s hard to know what might be the
correct answer. It’s somewhat arbitrary to exclude
capital gains completely. If you exclude them
initially, however, you must decide when to
include them in the aggregate. At what point
do the capital gains start looking to households
just like regular money? That’s a problem. On
the other hand, when you include capital gains
as they do, you bring up another whole set of
other problems. The monetary aggregate is going
to be extremely responsive to moves in the stock
market, for example. Could you ever target such
an aggregate? Scenarios under this which could
lead to some pretty silly policy responses are
not too hard to concoct.
I believe that if you ever consider going oper­
ationally to such an aggregate, you would almost
have to begin with a Q4 base period and try to
differentiate over the course of the year what
is contributing to that growth, separating how
much is coming from capital gains, how much
is coming from net inflows, and so on. I don’t
know if you can do that in a timely enough way
for policy analysis, however. Once you start
following the components of an aggregate rather
than the aggregate itself, I’m not sure that you
gain a lot by defining the aggregate in the first
place. That’s an obvious problem, but really
the main reason we’re here.
The second problem is one with the modeling
exercise: Are there good, timely measures of the
expected returns on these stock and bond mutual
funds? These are the returns that belong in a
money-demand equation. If you try to form these
returns ex post in a backward-looking manner, you
have a lot of theoretical problems in trying to
justify it. If you try to look ahead, you have to
specify the processes generating the data and how
much people know about them. I know I’m not
saying anything new here, but I want to highlight
what I think is obviously a big problem.
Finally, I would say that (as Athanasios
pointed out) M2+ doesn’t really seem to have
been a better indicator of GDP than M2, except
perhaps during the last couple of years. We just
don’t have a very long history, and we know

73

things are obviously still evolving. There may
not, in fact, be stable demand function for M2+
that we can estimate. It doesn’t seem to have any
history of being a better indicator of GDP. It’s
more variable than M2, or at least not any less
variable. Finally, the kinds of institutional
changes that have affected the traditional rela­
tionships between M2 and nominal GDP are
continuing. These changes even today are
affecting the development of M2+. Their
strength likely makes any kind of historical
data not terribly useful for looking ahead.
We should keep in mind that when things settle
down—when the depository sector completes its
shrinkage and stabilizes—the velocities of our
current aggregates, particularly M2, might stabilize
again, albeit at a permanently higher level. In
addition, the short-run relationships between M2




and its opportunity cost that we relied on in the
past might well re-emerge. In fact, unnoticed by
many analysts, M2 velocity and its opportunity
cost have increased in a roughly parallel way
since early 1992, suggesting that this pattern
might already be emerging. Unfortunately, at
this point the jury is clearly still out and we
really can’t answer that question definitively.
The evidence that I’ve seen presented suggests
that there is no other monetary indicator that is
going to provide monetary policy with a long-term
nominal anchor the way we thought M2 did prior
to 1990. In the absence of such an anchor, it
seems to me that monetary policy w ill continue
to be made basically as it has been for some time
now, without a monetary aggregate, by adjusting
the nominal federal funds rate in response to
activity in the real economy.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994




75

G eorge G. Pennacchi
George G. Pennacchi is professor of economics in the
Department o f Finance at the University o f Illinois, UrbanaChampaign.

Commentary

INANCIAL INNOVATION CONTINUES
to obscure traditional measures of monetary
policy and efforts to find an improvement are
now underway. A new, potentially superior
monetary aggregate, M 2+, is carefully analyzed
in the complementary papers by Sean Collins
and Cheryl Edwards, and Athanasios Orphanides,
Brian Reid and David Small. The Collins-Edwards
(CE) paper provides a thoughtful discussion of
issues dealing with the construction of M2+, while
the Orphanides, Reid and Small (ORS) paper
considers the empirical qualities of this new
aggregate. I wish to complement both sets of
authors for their work. Given their research
objectives, these papers are professionally
executed and insightful.
As CE notes, M2 became uncoupled from
nominal income beginning in 1990. During
this period of slow M2 growth, funds invested in
bond and stock mutual funds increased dramati­
cally. However, before simply assuming that M2
can be resurrected by adding in bond and stock
mutual fund balances, CE sensibly investigate
whether flows from M2 into these mutual funds
were the only problems occurring with M2.
Bearing in mind CE’s warning that it is “tricky
business” to explain the weakness in M2 based
on an analysis of its components, I would like
to further discuss movements in the components
of M2. I believe that a great deal of information is
1 Interest rates are averages of a Federal Reserve Board sur­
vey of approximately 460 commercial banks. This lowering
of spreads between more competitive retail deposits (CDs)
and less competitive retail deposits (NOWs) typically occurs




present in the individual components of monetary
aggregates. Table 1 presents a very simple descrip­
tion of recent changes in these components.
The table confirms CE’s observation that the
small time deposit component of M2 declined
substantially during this period. Where did these
funds go? Based on the negative correlation
between small time deposits and liquid bank
deposits, CE believe it is likely that funds moved
into liquid liabilities such as demand deposits,
other checkable deposits (OCDs), savings deposits
and money market demand accounts (MMDAs).
The deposit turnover rates that I give in the table
provide additional evidence of this movement.
Deposit turnover in OCDs declined substantially
from 1990 to 1993, suggesting that these accounts
were increasingly being used for savings rather
than for transaction purposes. I believe that the
cause of this intrabank shift was the reduction in
the opportunity cost between small time deposits
(for example, CDs) and OCDs (for example,
NOWs). For instance, the average spread between
six-month consumer CDs and NOW accounts
was approximately 208 basis points in 1990.
By November of 1993, that margin was reduced
to approximately 103 basis points.1 Changes in
intrabank opportunity costs that lead to flows
from non-reservable to reservable deposits will
increase the demand for high-powered money
and thereby lead to monetary tightening, even
when market rates fall. See Hutchison and Pennacchi
(1992) for more discussion and empirical evidence.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

76

Table 1
Selected Components of Monetary Aggregates (in billions, seasonally adjusted)
Quantity
1989.12

Change
1989.121993.11

%
Change

222.7

97.2

44.6%

Traveler’s checkst

6.9

1.1

15.9%

Demand deposits*

279.9

105.4

Other checkable depositst

285.3

Savings and MMDAs*
Money market funds (GP-BD)t

Component
Currencyt

Turnover
1990

Turnover
1993'

37.7%

797.8

824.6

127.4

44.7%

16.5

11.7

891.0

323.6

36.3%

6.2

4.8

317.4

19

6.0%

3.02
3.02

Money market funds (IO )tt

108.8

87.9

80.8%

Overnight repos & Euro$*

77.5

7.8

10. 1%

Term repos & Euro$tt

178.4

Small time deposits*
Large time deposits**

1152.7
548.8

-32.9
-364.5
-216.1

-18.4%
-31.6%

1.0-1.53

1.0-1.53

-39.4%

t Component of M1, M2, and M3
* Component of M2 and M3
t t Component of M3
1 Turnover rates are seasonally adjusted. Figure for 1993 is for month of September.
2 Turnover figure is an average for all MMMFs. See Gorton and Pennacchi (1993).
3 Reported in Collins and Edwards (1994), based on Federal Reserve Board Staff estimate.

though the level of reported M2 (or M2+) may not
change. Hence, these intrabank opportunity costs,
in addition to the opportunity cost of holding M2
measured by the spread between the Treasury
bill rate and the average rate on M 2’s components
(see Figure 1 in CE), need to be considered.
As the table points out, the components of
current monetary aggregates have displayed
very different movements over the last few years.
However, a general observation that is consistent
with each of the component changes in the
table is that, on net, funds have flowed from
non-demandable/redeemable assets into demandable/redeemable assets. This observation is also
consistent with the net flow of funds into (openended) bond and stock mutual funds whose shares
are redeemable as well. Perhaps this represents
a permanent shift in investment behavior that is
unrelated to the current slope of the term structure.
Investments in money market and bond mutual
funds can provide investors with rates of return
that are nearly identical to investments in term
CDs (the funds can hold these CDs themselves),
but with the added convenience of mutual fund

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




redeemability. One might argue that bond mutual
funds now dominate a CD investment.
A caveat to the redemption feature of bond
and stock mutual funds is that liquidating shares
may not always be costless. As ORS points out,
redeeming bond and stock mutual fund shares can
have capital gains tax implications (in addition
to possible back-end loads). There are a number
of somewhat complicated methods for calculating
a mutual fund capital gain, each having possibly
different tax implications. This could be a
significant deterrent to frequent mutual fund
withdrawals. Of course, this is not a problem
affecting money market mutual funds, since
they are permitted to use an “amortized cost”
method of security valuation and the “penny
rounding” method of share pricing that enables
them to maintain a fixed share price.
Therefore, I would predict that withdrawals
from bond and stock funds would tend to be
significantly less volatile than those of money
market funds. For example, money market fund
assets declined by over 30 percent during the
13-month period from December of 1982 to

77

January of 1984, a time when bank deposit
interest rate ceilings were lifted. I doubt that
redemptions of that magnitude are likely for
bond and stock funds. However, as the empirical
work of ORS suggests, the share price volatility
of bond and stock funds, leading to capital gains
and losses, will undoubtedly add volatility to
M 2+, especially since these funds’ current 15
percent share of M 2+ is likely to grow.
ORS examine the demand for balances in stock
and bond mutual funds, as well as the demand
for M 2+ as a whole. Following previous money
demand formulations that include proxies for
the opportunity cost of various monetary com­
ponents, they experiment with various quarterly
measures of the “ex ante perceptions of returns”
on stock and bond mutual funds. In my opinion,
this is an exceedingly difficult empirical exercise
and theoretically suspect as well. The empirical
difficulty is that, unlike other components of
M 2+ which have nearly risk-free returns, stock
and bond funds have high rate-of-return volatility.
Even if one assumed that the expected rates of
return on these funds were constant, rather than
varying on a quarterly basis, it could take decades
of data before a reasonably accurate estimate
of their expected returns could be found. These
assets’ rates of return variances overwhelm their
expected rates of return; that is, there is too much
“noise” (variance) to be able to infer these assets’
desired “signal” (expected rate of return).2
Economic theory may also suggest that the
opportunity costs of stock and bond investments
will always be approximately zero. Unlike other
bank liabilities that are not necessarily competi­
tively priced (for example, demand deposits,
NOWs, MMDAs, small CDs), there is likely to
be little “opportunity cost” of holding stock
and bond investments, even via mutual funds.
Demands for these assets should not depend
on expected rates of return but risk-adjusted
expected rates of return. A number of general
equilibrium models predict that the best mea­
sure of this risk-adjusted return is the current
short-term, risk-free rate, for example, the cur­
rent Treasury bill rate. But, of course, this then
implies that the opportunity cost for competi­
tively priced assets will be zero. In the context
of bonds, it is well known that a steeper yield
curve will not necessarily indicate that (long­
term) bond funds are more attractive than when
the yield curve is flat or inverted. A higher

slope may simply reflect the expectation of rising
short-term interest rates or a risk premium on
more volatile long-maturity bonds. To justify
their proxies, I believe the authors would need
to argue that their measures reflect the actual
“perceptions” of relatively unsophisticated
mutual fund investors. But even if this were
the case, these “m isperceptions” are likely to
be temporary. Following a significant correction
in stock and bond markets, investors are apt to
quickly learn that recent stock performance or
the steepness of the yield curve have little pre­
dictive power for future investment returns.
Given the above difficulties in modeling and
estimating risky asset demands, it is not surprising
that ORS find evidence of instability in their
estimated demand curve for M2+. I would not
be surprised, however, if M 2+ turns out to better
predict nominal GDP than other monetary aggre­
gates. The reason for this is that changes in M 2+
may not proxy for changes in “money” but for
changes in nominal “wealth” due to the capital
gains on its stock and bond components. If one
views wealth as the capitalized value of future
income, then changes in wealth may indeed
be a good forecast of changes in nominal GDP.
Hence, M 2+ may be a good indicator, but for
the wrong reasons.
My last comment concerns the general
approach that is used to revise monetary aggre­
gates in response to financial innovation. CE is
explicit in desiring a relatively simple aggregate
that is constructed in a parallel fashion to previ­
ously existing aggregates. They imply that more
complicated monetary indicators are problematic,
because they make adjustments using a “modelbased procedure that the public (Congress in
particular) might have tr o u b le understanding
[quote from previous draft—Editor].” If this is
the case, perhaps the Federal Reserve should
(already does?) report an easily understood
aggregate to the public, but then use a more
complicated monetary measure for internal
decision-making.
In my opinion, if we truly wish to understand
the inherently complex effects that financial
innovation have on the conduct of monetary
policy, we need to abandon the simple approach
of merely adding new asset categories to old
aggregates. As indicated by the turnover rates
in the table and O RS’ estimated turnover rate of

2 See Merton (1980) on this point.




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

78

bond and stock funds of 0.3, these new asset
categories are very distant substitutes for highpowered money, the economy’s numeraire for
pricing goods and services.3 As noted by ORS,
the justification for adding bond and stock funds
to M2 should not be based on these “balances
having become a better transaction medium, but
rather will be based on their substitutability for
small time deposits or other M2 balances as
savings vehicles.” But, if small time deposits
are held for savings, rather than transaction
purposes (as indicated by the turnover rate of
1.0-1.5), would it not make more sense to lessen
the effects of small time deposits in a monetary
measure rather than adding another, even less
money-like asset? The approach represented
by M 2+, which simply adds new non-monetary
assets to correct problems with old non-monetary
assets, is not unlike curing a hangover by having
another drink. It may appear to be a good solution
in the short run, but (as financial innovation
continues) the ultimate consequence is a much
larger hangover— or the need for an even
larger drink.
Developing aggregates based on their (historical)
empirical fit is unlikely to be a successful endeavor
in an environment in which new financial
instruments continue to be developed. A more
Bayesian or “model-based” approach, such as
the work of Barnett (1980) and Spindt (1985)

3 Fama (1980) provides an insightful discussion of issues
involving monetary policy and price-level control.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




would seem to be more appropriate. A general
modeling of the demand for high-powered money
could also potentially consider the effect of
non-monetary transaction technologies, such
as credit cards, or the effect of dollar-currency
demand by foreigners. In other areas of economics,
we do not insist that multi-good demand relations
be a function of a linear combination of those
goods, each having a coefficient of unity. Why do
we continue this practice in monetary economics?

REFERENCES
Barnett, William A. “Economic Monetary Aggregates: An
Application of Index Numbers and Aggregation Theory,”
Journal o f Econometrics (summer 1980), pp. 11-48.
Fama, Eugene F. “Banking in the Theory of Finance,” Journal
of Monetary Economics (January 1980), pp. 39-57.
Gorton, Gary B. and George G. Pennacchi. “Money Market
Funds and Finance Companies: Are They the Banks of the
Future?,” in Michael Klausner and Lawrence J. White, eds.,
Structural Change in Banking. Business One Inwin, 1993,
pp. 173-214.
Hutchison, David E., and George G. Pennacchi. “A
Framework for Estimating the Value and Interest Rate Risk
of Retail Bank Deposits,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Working Paper WP-92-30 (December 1992).
Merton, Robert C. “On Estimating the Expected Return on the
Market: An Exploratory Investigation,” Journal o f Financial
Economics (December 1980), pp. 323-61.
Spindt, Paul A. “Money Is What Money Does: Monetary
Aggregation and the Equation of Exchange,” Journal of
Political Economy (February 1985), pp. 175-204.

79

Richard G. A nderson and William G. Dewald
Richard G. Anderson is a research officer at the Federal Reserve Bank
o f St. Louis. William G. Dewald is director of research at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Replication and Scientific
Standards in A pplied Economics
a Decade A fter the Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking
Project
L J INCE EARLY 1993, the Research Department
of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis has made
the data and programs for articles published in
the Bank’s R eview available to the public on its
electronic bulletin board.1 During the first year,
files from articles in the R eview were downloaded
from the bulletin board more than 200 times.
More recently, about 30 files have been down­
loaded each month.
The Research Department of the Bank develops
the program and data files on our bulletin board
during a replication of each article prior to pub­
lication. A research analyst first checks the
author’s data against original sources. Because
databases may have been updated or revised
after the research began, this can require searching
for the original published data. In a few cases,
data errors have been corrected, fortunately with
only minor impact on the author’s results. Next,
The bulletin board is advertised as the Federal Reserve
Economic Database, or FRED. FRED’s phone number is
(314) 621-1824. (The Federal Reserve System does not
have a server on the Internet.) Dewald, Thursby and




an annotated version of the computer program
is prepared and all statistical results recalculated.
Finally, bibliographic and other references are
checked by the analyst against original source
documents. We believe this practice both assures
the accuracy of the empirical results and allows
the interested reader to delve into the details
o f th e a u th o r ’s re s e a r c h .

THE ROLE OF DATA IN ECONOMIC
EXPERIMENTS
Although empirical knowledge in both the
physical and social sciences arises from repeated
experiments, the role of data differs. In the physical
sciences, scientists control a relatively small number
of variables such as temperature, atmospheric
pressure, diet or family characteristics. Since
some variables are neither observed nor controlled,
no two repetitions of an experiment w ill be
Anderson (1986) summarized the Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking project mentioned in the title.

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

80

identical. Response surface analysis and the newer
field of research synthesis provide tools for ana­
lyzing the dependence of experimental results
on the settings of the conditioning variables.2
In economics, however, unlike the physical
sciences, researchers can only condition on the
observed values of the environmental variables,
not control them. Consider a simple model of
an economic experiment:
1. Form hypotheses.
2. Collect data.
3. Develop theoretical and econometric
framework.
4. Estimate.
5. Test hypotheses, draw conclusions.
The values of the conditioning variables are
collected in step 2. Published articles typically
describe steps 1, 3 and 5, but are most often silent
on step 2. In principle, a researcher armed with
the values of the conditioning variables and the
computer code for step 4 should be able to exactly
reproduce an economic experiment.3 Unlike the
physical sciences, the experiment is deterministic,
given the data.
Appraising the robustness of the results of
an economic experiment requires knowing the
values of the conditioning variables used by the
researcher. Obtaining the data may sometimes
be difficult. Datasets and programs may be mislaid
or lost during the interval between completion of
the research and publication of an article. Further,
re q u e sts to a u th o rs fo r d ata may ra is e s u s p ic io n s
that the reader hopes (or expects) to find errors
in the authors’ research. An individual researcher
has strong incentives not to share data and pro­
grams. If the materials are shared and results
confirmed, the confirmation provides little (if any)
reward to the researcher beyond the original
publication of his findings. If results are found
faulty, however, the researcher faces the likeli­
hood of some professional embarrassment.
2 See Cooper and Hedges (1994).
3 A complication not dealt with here are errors and inconsis­
tencies in econometric computer programs. In the Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking project (described further below),
we requested that authors provide the version, release date
and serial number of the computer program used for their
estimation. See Lovell and Selover (1994) for examples of
the variation in econometric packages.
4 Various classification schemes and nomenclatures have
been discussed by Kane (1984), Mittelstaedt and Zorn (1984),
Hubbard and Vetter (1991), Lindsay and Ehrenberg (1993),
and Fuess (1994).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




The trepidation of authors aside, scientific
progress depends on challenging received wisdom.
In applied economics, these challenges fall into
three categories: replication of published results
using the previous authors’ data and programs;
applying new statistical methods or techniques
to authors’ datasets; and application of existing
statistical methods (including those used by
previous authors) to new datasets.4 That most
applied economic research falls within the third
category is not surprising, since the first two
depend on access to previous authors’ datasets.
Only with the authors’ data may the reader
repeat, or replicate, all five steps of the scientific
experiment. Selecting a new set of values for the
conditioning variables from published sources
may yield results close to those obtained by
the author, or results that are quite different.
Unfortunately, it is difficult to predict the sensi­
tivity of authors’ results to variations in the values
of the conditioning variables. For an example
of the wide range of results that may arise when
mixing different sources and vintages of data, see
the computer simulation experiment reported in
Dewald, Thursby and Anderson (1986).

THE JMCB PROJECT AFTER 10 YEARS
The Jou rn al o f M oney, C redit a n d B an kin g
project, conducted from 1982-84 at the editorial
offices of the JMCB at The Ohio State University
in Columbus, was the first attempt by a profes­
sional journal to make authors’ programs and
data available to its readers.5 During the project,
the JMCB asked authors to submit data and pro­
grams to the journal’s office. Conceptually, we
regarded the research reported in each article
as the outcome of an experiment. A complete
understanding of the experiment required the
researchers’ data and computer programs, as
well as the published summary descriptions and
conclusions. For a subset of these submissions,
we attempted to repeat steps 2 and 4 by collecting
data from the sources cited by the authors and
re-running the authors’ computer programs.
5 The primary research team was William Dewald, Jerry
Thursby, Richard Anderson and Hashem Dezbaksh. The
project’s findings are summarized in Dewald, Thursby and
Anderson (1986). The project was supported in part by the
National Science Foundation.

81

concluded that it is important for journals to
request data from authors immediately following
completion of the research, and for the journal
to retain the data to avoid its loss during the
interval between completion of the research
and publication of the paper.

T a b le 1

Datasets for the JMCB Project
Datasets Requested by Month and Year
through May 1989
1983

84

85

86

87

88

89

Jan.

0

0

12

3

9

5

8

Feb.

2

1

1

4

9

5

1

1

April

14

1
2

8
4

6

March

0
0

2

6

0

1

1
2

May

1

0

14

1

1

5

June

1

2

6

5

2

July

0

0
4

5

2

3

2

4

3
3

2

Aug.

0

2

1
2

4

Sept.

9

4

4

2

Oct.

11

6

7

38

Nov.

1

2

6

4

3

4

Dec.

0

1

6

0

3

1

Datasets Available by Issue as of May 1989
1980

81

82

83

84

85

86

87

88

Feb.

2

4

6

4

2

5

5

6

Aug.

1

4

6

2

6

2

6

Nov.

4

0

3
3

5
8

3
3

2

1

5
5

2

May

3
3

7

7

5

7

1

3

Total

8

10

12

24

24

17

19

10

17

SOURCE: JMCB editorial office staff. No later data are
available from the JMCB staff.

We found during the JMCB project that many
authors could not furnish data and programs
following publication of their articles. We in i­
tially requested data from the authors of 62 articles
published during 1980-82, prior to the beginning
of the project on July 1, 1982. About one-third
of the authors did not respond to either a first or
second request for data. Among the responding
authors, one-half either could not locate their
data or chose not to submit them. Most of these
authors said that they could have done so if the
materials had been requested when the manu­
script was first submitted to the JMCB. Data and
programs were often apparently mislaid during
the relatively long delay between completion of
the research and publication of its findings.
We next requested data from the authors of
papers that either had only recently been accepted
for publication or were under editorial review.
More than three-fourths furnished their data. We




In the second part of the JMCB project, we
studied whether the materials submitted by
authors were in fact sufficient to allow another
researcher to repeat their experiment.
For many articles, repeating step 2—searching
for the authors’ data in their stated sources—was
impossible. Descriptions of sources were either
too vague to allow us to locate the data and/or
the data were not included in the cited sources.
Although 54 datasets were submitted to the
JMCB during the project, we judged only eight
as satisfactory and 14 as valueless in helping us
understand the authors’ published work. Others
were deficient in at least one important respect.
For a few articles, we discovered data errors
during comparison to published sources. In the
most severe case, we found that an author’s con­
clusions were reversed (prior to publication of
the article) when an error was corrected. Where
the data were adequate, we usually obtained
numerical results from authors’ programs very
close to those reported by the authors.
Beyond encouraging readers to explore authors’
methodology and the robustness of published
results, we believed that requesting data and
programs from authors would encourage them
to exercise added care during their research.
We also expected that other journals would adopt
similar requirements to increase the value of their
articles to readers. Although the JMCB project
stimulated discussion of the role of replication
in economics, no other journal adopted a policy
of requesting data from authors during the 1980s.
Some journals adopted editorial statements that
authors should stand ready to provide data and
programs to other researchers. Such statements,
in and of themselves, may not solve the two major
problems identified during the project: Data often
are mislaid prior to publication of the article, and
the author may be suspicious of the motives of a
researcher requesting his data and programs.
A decade after the JMCB project, the replication
of previous studies as a part of new research seems
an infrequent occurrence. During the last decade,
no papers or notes in the JMCB have focused
primarily on replication, and only about two
papers per year have included a direct compari­

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

82

son of the authors’ results to those in previous
studies, whether published in the JMCB or else­
where.6 The collection of data by professional
journals also remains rare. The JMCB discontin­
ued requesting data from authors in 1993. To
our knowledge, today only two journals—the
Jou rn al o f A p p lied E con om etrics and the Jou rn al
o f B u sin ess a n d E co n o m ic Statistics—routinely
request data from authors, and neither requests
their programming.
From January 1983 through mid-1989, the JMCB
received nearly 150 submitted datasets and about
300 requests, as shown in Table l . 7 Except for a
surge in requests following the publication of
Dewald, Thursby and Anderson (1986), on balance
only a few datasets were requested each month
even though the number of available datasets
increased significantly during the decade.
The higher request rate during the past two
years for data from the St. Louis bulletin board
may suggest that the modest costs of requesting
data from the JMCB still exceeded the marginal
value to an individual researcher of replicating
a previous study. To obtain data for a JMCB article,
a reader had to call the editorial office to ask the
price of the data, submit payment by mail, wait for
the data to be reproduced and mailed, and perhaps
re-enter the data into a computer. By contrast,
the St. Louis bulletin board is free, delivery is
immediate, and data are machine-readable.

THE ROLE OF THE NATIONAL
SCIENCE FOUNDATION
The economics program of the National
Science Foundation (NSF) has sought to build
a heightened awareness of the value of data
collection, archival and distribution among
economists during the last decade. Following
publication of Dewald, Thursby and Anderson
(1986), the NSF established an archive for the
storage and distribution of authors’ data at the
Inter-university Consortium for Political and
Social Research (ICPSR) at the University of
Michigan. Initially, some anticipated that the
N SF’s effort would extend the JMCB’s practice
of requesting and distributing authors’ data to
6 Replication also has been relatively rare even in journals
that encourage submission of such papers. See Fuess
(1994).
7 Recall that in 1982 we began requesting data for articles
that had been published as early as 1980.
8 Some authors have since proposed models of how such col­
lective disinterest among professional journals might arise
and be sustained. See Feigenbaum and Levy (1994, 1993).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




a much larger number of journals. The editors
of 22 journals, however, declined invitations
from N SF’s economics program to request that
their authors place data in the ICPSR archive.8
The National Science Foundation has also
adopted guidelines to reduce the cost of replica­
tions. The guidelines require that authors place
any data used and/or developed in conjunction
with an NSF-funded project in a public archive
not later than six months following the end of
the grant period. Applications for additional
NSF funds must contain a statement of how the
author has complied with this requirement.
The ICPSR accepts data from any author who
has received NSF funds.9
National Science Foundation initiatives have
also assisted users of copyrighted and confidential
data. Some data obtained by researchers from
commercial vendors are copyrighted and may
not be further distributed by the researcher
without the vendor’s permission. One such
vendor, the Center for Research in Security Prices
(CRISP), has agreed to maintain researchers’
datasets as part of its own database and make
them available to all licensed users of its data.
For confidential data, the Bureau of the Census
and the NSF are exploring opening regional
offices that would allow researchers access to
confidential data, including datasets used in
previously published studies. A pilot office
is operating in Boston.

REPLICATION OF THE JMCB PROJECT
IN ST. LOUIS
Our experience at the JMCB during 1982-84
was itself only one trial of an experiment. Would
another sample of authors also have difficulty
providing data following publication of their
articles? Or were our original findings anom­
alous, leading us to greatly exaggerate the
problem, as some critics have suggested?
During 1992-93, we repeated the JMCB experi­
ment at St. Louis, in part, by requesting data and
programs from the authors of papers presented
at the Bank’s annual economic policy conference
in October 1992. We did not tell authors prior
9 Materials should be submitted to User Support, ICPSR, P.O.
Box 1248, Ann Arbor, Ml 48106. Data may be retrieved
from ICPSR via an Internet server; see Goffe (summer
1994; March 1994).

83

to the conference that we would be requesting
their programs and data. Their responses were
very similar to those we had observed at the
JMCB a decade earlier. Authors who had com­
pleted their studies just prior to the conference
promptly submitted their data and programs,
while those who had largely completed their
research as much as several years earlier found
it costly to organize and submit data. The fol­
lowing year, we informed participants for our
1993 conference at the time their paper was
invited that we expected data to be submitted
with the manuscript. Authors generally found
it imposed little burden to submit data and
programs with their manuscripts so lon g as
th ey w ere aw are o f the requ irem en t in ad v an ce,
although the Bank’s staff had to make some
follow-up calls to clarify documentation.

THE FUTURE ROLE OF REPLICATION
How should economists, as scientists, interpret
their profession’s apparent, collective lack of
interest in replicating prior studies? Does the
failure of journals to request and distribute data
and programs reflect a lack of scientific discipline
in economics, as some have suggested? Do the
costs to a reader of obtaining data from authors
exceed the benefit?
The JMCB project demonstrated that profes­
sional journals could reduce the costs of replica­
tion and improve the quality of applied economic
research by collecting data and programs from
authors. For the first time, the reader of an
empirical article could obtain data and programs
anonymously (with respect to the author) from
the journal that published the article. Further,
collection of the authors’ data and programs
seemed to encourage additional care by authors
to avoid inadvertent errors during the conduct
of the research.
Since January 1994, the Jou rn al o f A p p lied
E conom etrics has accepted papers for publication
conditional on authors furnishing an acceptable
dataset. The publication reviews datasets for
completeness and then places them on an Internet
server at Queens University.10 The Jou rn al o f
B u sin ess a n d E co n o m ic Statistics requests, but
does not require, that authors submit data for

distribution via an Internet server at Duke
University. Tauchen (1993) argues, as we did in
1986, that readers of journals should be interested
in authors’ data and programs, and a journal’s
prestige (and circulation) should increase when
such data and programs are made readily available
to readers. We believe that published empirical
research generally would benefit if the practices
of the Jou rn al o f A p p lied E con om etrics, Jou rn al
o f B u sin ess a n d E con om ic Statistics, and the
St. Louis R eview w ere more widely adopted.

REFERENCES
Cooper, Harris, and Larry V. Hedges, eds. The Handbook of
Research Synthesis. New York, 1994.
Dewald, William G., Jerry G. Thursby, and Richard G. Anderson.
“Replication in Empirical Economics: The Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking Project,” American Economic Review
(September 1986).
Feigenbaum, Susan, and David M. Levy. T h e Self-Enforcement
Mechanism in Science,” mimeo, paper presented at the
American Economic Association Meetings, Boston,
Massachusetts, January 1994.
_____ , and_____ . “The Market for (Ir)Reproducible
Econometrics,” Social Epistemology (no. 3,1993), pp. 243-44.
Fuess, Scott M. “On Replication in Business and Economic
Research: The QJBE Case,” paper presented at the Eastern
Economic Association meetings, Boston Massachusetts,
March 1994 (mimeo, Department of Economics, University
of Nebraska, October 1993).
Goffe, William L. “Computer Network Resources for Economists,”
Journal of Economic Perspectives (summer 1994).
_____ . “Resources for Economists on the Internet,” electronic
document maintained on the Internet (March 1994 version).
Contact bgoffe@whale.st.usm.edu.
Hubbard, Raymond, and Daniel E. Vetter. “Replications in the
Finance Literature: An Empirical Study,” Quarterly Journal
o f Business and Economics (autumn 1991).
Kane, Edward J. “Why Journal Editors Should Encourage the
Replication of Applied Econometric Research,” Quarterly
Journal of Business and Economics (winter 1984).
Lindsay, Murray R., and A.S.C. Ehrenberg. ‘T he Design of
Replicated Studies,” The American Statistician (August
1993), pp. 217-28.
Lovell, Michael, and David Selover, “Econometric Software
Accidents,” The Economic Journal (May, 1994), pp. 713-25.
MacKinnon, James. “Guidelines for Users: Journal of Applied
Econometrics FTP Archive Site,” Journal of Applied
Econometrics (April-June 1994), pp. 229-30.
Mittelstaedt, Robert A., and Thomas S. Zorn. “Econometric
Replication: Lessons from the Experimental Sciences,”
Quarterly Journal o f Business and Economics (winter 1984).
Tauchen, George. “Remarks on My Term at JBES,” Journal of
Business & Economic Statistics (October 1993).

10 For discussion of the Journal of Applied Econometrics server,
see MacKinnon (1994).




NOVEMBER/DECEMBER 1994

84

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS
R E V IE W \UDEX 1994

JANUARY/FEBRUARY
R. Alton Gilbert, “Federal Reserve Lending to Banks
That Failed: Implications for the Bank Insurance Fund."

David C. Wheelock and Paul W. Wilson, “Can Deposit
Insurance Increase the Risk of Bank Failure? Some
Historical Evidence.”

James B. Bullard, “Measures of Money and the Quantity
Theory.”

JULY/AUGUST

Daniel L. Thornton, “Financial Innovation, Deregulation
and the “Credit View” of Monetary Policy.”

Sangkyun Park, “Explanations for the Increased
Riskiness of Banks in the 1980s.”

MARCH/APRIL

Patricia S. Pollard, “Trade Between the United States
and Eastern Europe.”

“Money Stock Measurement: History, Theory and
Implications.” Proceedings of the Eighteenth
Annual Economic Policy Conference. Richard G.
Anderson, ed.

John C. Weicher, “The New Structure of the Housing
Finance System.”

Richard G. Anderson and Kenneth A. Kavajecz, “A
Historical Perspective on the Federal Reserve’s
Monetary Aggregates: Definition, Construction
and Targeting.”
Kenneth A. Kavajecz, “The Evolution of the Federal
Reserve’s Monetary Aggregates: A Timeline.”
K. Alec Chrystai and Ronald MacDonald, “Empirical
Evidence on the Recent Behavior and Usefulness
of Simple-Sum and Weighted Measures of the
Money Stock.”
Douglas Fisher and Adrian Fleissig, “Money Demand
in a Flexible Dynamic Fourier Expenditure System.”
William A. Barnett and Ge Zhou, “Financial Firms’
Production and Supply-Side Monetary Aggregation
Under Dynamic Uncertainty.”
Jerome L. Stein, “Can the Central Bank Achieve
Price Stability?”
Michael J. Boskin, Philip H. Dybvig, and Bennett T.
McCallum, “A Conference Panel Discussion.”
(Commentaries by Charles W. Calomiris, Charles R.
Nelson, James L. Swofford, William C. Brainard, and
Frederic S. Mishkin.)

Alvin L. Marty, “The Inflation Tax and the Marginal
Welfare Cost in a World of Currency and Deposits.”

SEPTEMBER/OCTOBER
Joseph A. Ritter, “Job Creation and Destruction: The
Dominance of Manufacturing.”
Peter Yoo, “Boom or Bust? The Economic Effects of
the Baby Boom.”
Christopher J. Neely, “Realignments of Target Zone
Exchange Rate Systems: What Do We Know?”
R. Alton Gilbert, “A Case Study in Monetary Control:
1980-82.”

NOVEMBER/DECEMBER
“Mutual Funds and Monetary Indicators.”
Proceedings from a symposium at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
Sean Collins and Cheryl L. Edwards, “Redefining M2
to Include Bond and Equity Mutual Funds.”

MAY/JUNE

Athanasios Orphanides, Brian Reid, and David H.
Small, “The Empirical Properties of a Monetary
Aggregate That Adds Bond and Stock Mutual Funds
to M2.”

Helmut Schlesinger, “On the Way to a New Monetary
Union: The European Monetary Union” (the Eighth
Annual Homer Jones Memorial Lecture).

(Commentaries by William A. Barnett and Ge Zhou,
Jacob S. Dreyer, Josh Feinman, John V. Duca, and
George G. Pennacchi.)

Clemens J.M. Kool and John A. Tatom, “The P-Star
Model in Five Small Economies.”
Charles W. Calomiris, “Is the Discount Window
Necessary? A Penn-Central Perspective.”

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS




Richard G. Anderson and William G. Dewald,
“Replication and Scientific Standards in Applied
Economics A Decade After the Journal of Money,
Credit and Banking Project.”

Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Post Office Box 442
St. Louis, Missouri 63166