View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K
O F S T. L O U IS
NOVEMBER 1978


Vol. 60, No.


11

Movements in the Foreign Exchange Value of the
Dollar During the Current U.S. Expansion
DOUGLAS R. MUDD

F OR seven quarters following the severe U.S. eco­
nomic slowdown of 1973-75, the foreign exchange
value of the dollar rose substantially, increasing by
about 8 percent on a trade-weighted basis.1 The dol­
lar declined slightly only against the currencies of
Canada and Switzerland. The most dramatic increases
in the foreign exchange value of the dollar over
1975-76 were against the British pound and the Italian
lira. In terms of the British pound, the value of the
dollar rose by about 30 percent, and against the Italian
lira the dollar rose by about 26 percent.
In contrast, since late 1976, the trade-weighted for­
eign exchange value of the dollar has fallen about 13
percent. Over the past seven quarters the value of the
dollar has declined furthest against the Belgian franc
(16.7 percent), German mark (20 percent), Japanese
yen (52.5 percent), Dutch guilder (15.8 percent), and
Swiss franc (46.1 percent). Since fourth quarter 1976,
the dollar has appreciated against only one of the
world’s nine other major industrial countries’ curren­
cies, increasing 13.3 percent against the Canadian
dollar.2
Explanations of this sharp reversal in the trend of
the dollar’s foreign exchange value are often presented
in terms of economic growth rate differentials.3 Al­
though exchange rate movements can be influenced
r rhe trade-weighted value of the dollar is a weighted average
of the exchange rates between the dollar and the currencies of
the United States’ twenty major trading partners. The weights
take account of the size of the trade flows and are derived
from the International Monetary Fund’s ‘Multilateral Exchange
Rate Model’. See Jacques R. Artus and Rudolf R. Rhomberg,
“A Multilateral Exchange Rate Model,” International Monetary
Fund Staff Papers (November 1973), pp. 591-611.
2The ten major industrial countries considered here are Bel­
gium, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Netherlands,
Switzerland, United Kingdom, and United States.
3Of course, turning points in exchange rate movements differed
between currencies. However, by the end of 1976, the foreign
exchange value of the dollar was, or began, falling against
seven of the nine currencies considered here.

Page 2


by differences in economic growth rates, there is no
reason to expect the foreign exchange value of the
dollar to be dominated by the relatively rapid rate of
U.S. economic growth. Rather, the current downward
trend in the value of the dollar against most major
currencies can be attributed primarily to differential
excess money growth rates, as indicated by differ­
ential rates of inflation.4

EXCHANGE RATES AND ECONOMIC
GROWTH DIFFERENTIALS
A major factor sometimes cited as the cause of the
recent decline in the foreign exchange value of the dol­
lar is the vigorous growth of the U.S. economy rela­
tive to economic growth abroad. It has been asserted
that as the U.S. economy expanded and national in­
come increased, U.S. imports also rose; increased
amounts of imported raw and intermediate materials
were required to fuel the expanding U.S. economy,
and rising incomes allowed consumers to increase
their purchases of imported goods. At the same time,
economic growth abroad has been generally sluggish,
resulting in weak foreign demand (both business and
consumer) for U.S. exports. Thus, the recent U.S.
trade deficits (imports of goods and services have ex­
ceeded exports since early 1976) are viewed as having
resulted from international growth differentials. These
trade deficits, in turn, have been viewed as the pri­
mary cause of the downward slide in the foreign ex­
change value of the dollar.5
4For a critical discussion of both hypotheses, see Herbert Stein,
“The Mystery of the Declining Dollar,” T he A E I Economist
(American Enterprise Institute for Public Policy Research,
September 1978).
sThis argument ignores the possibility that both output growth
and exchange rate changes have a common cause. Thus, auton­
omous increases in output should result in a depreciating
currency. The argument also theoretically neglects the effects
of international capital flows on exchange rates. There is not
necessarily a causal link between a trade deficit and a depre-

N OVEMBER

FED ERA L R ESERVE B A N K OF ST. LOUIS

1978

Table I

OUTPUT GROW TH FOR SELECTED COUNTRIES*
Compounded Annual Rates of Change
Belgium

Canada
1 .0 %
2.0
4.3
4.1

France

Germany

Italy

Japan

U.K.

U.S.

-4 .8 %
5.4
-1 .2
13.1

-5 .6 %
-0 .2
3.9
8.1

-3 .1 %
-3 .8
-1 .4
11.1

-8 .5 %
9.7
4.5
8.2

2 .0 %
-6 .0
-7 .6
3.7

-9 .0 %
6.4
10.5
2.6

1975 1
II
III
IV

-4 .8 %
-6 .8
-2 .7
0.4

1976 1
II
III
IV

7.1
15.6
8.7
2.9

13.7
4.6
-1 .8
2.5

7.7
5.8
2.1
0.4

9.3
5.0
1.6
3.9

10.0
6.6
0.4
9.6

7.7
5.7
3.5
3.3

16.0
-3 .3
2.3
5.5

9.3
4.0
2.7
2.4

1977 1
II
III
IV

-1 .8
2.5
-3 .9
-1.1

5.5
1.4
1.2
6.1

8.6
-5 .2
2.0
2.0

3.2
0.4
1.0
6.0

7.0
-10.1
-2 .0
-0 .5

7.6
7.6
0.5
6.3

-5 .4
2.9
1.1
-0 .7

7.3
5.9
5.7
3.2

6.2
NA

2.9
4.5

7.4
NA

-0 .6
8.8

10.4
4.4

3.2
NA

-0.1
8.7

1975 1 - 1976 IV

3.4

4.1

4.7

4.5

4.4

6.1

1.3

5.4

1976 IV - present

0.4

3.6

2.9

3.1

0.5e

6.1

0.2

5.1

1978 1
II

7.2e
1,5e

♦Real G N P was used fo r Belgium, Canada, Germany, Japan, and the United States while real GD P was used for Italy, France, and the
United Kingdom. Quarterly data fo r the Netherlands and Switzerland are not available. Quarter-to-quarter growth rates are shown fo r the
I/1975-II/1978 time span.
N A — Data not available
e — Estimate
Sources: Bank o f Canada, Bank o f England. Bank o f Japan. Deutsche Bundesbank, International Monetary Fund, Organization fo r Economic
Cooperation and Development, U . S. Departm ent o f Commerce, Universite Libre de Bruxelles.

Table I shows output growth rates since 1975 in
the United States and seven other industrialized econ­
omies. With the exception of Japan, U.S. output
growth over the 1975-76 period was stronger than
output growth abroad. Yet, during that period, the
trade-weighted foreign exchange value of the dollar
rose.
Since late 1976, U.S. output growth has significantly
accelerated relative to that of Belgium, France, Ger­
many, Italy, and the United Kingdom. These five cases
are consistent with the hypothesis that accelerating
U.S. output growth relative to output growth abroad
has caused the depreciation of the dollar.
Two cases presented in Table I contradict the
argument that the foreign exchange value of the dol­
lar should decrease (increase) when the U.S. econ­
omy expands more (less) rapidly than foreign econ­
ciating currency. For example, suppose an autonomous in­
crease in U.S. output results from a technological innovation
raising U.S. productivity. Even if a trade deficit results from
this autonomous increase in U.S. real income, capital inflows
would be induced by the now higher real rate of return on
investment in the United States. There is no clear indication
of the direction of change in the foreign exchange value of
the dollar. Therefore, higher real income growth in the United
States than abroad does not, by itself, produce a deprecia­
tion of the dollar.



omies. Although output growth in Japan since late
1976 has been substantially higher than in the United
States, the value of the dollar in terms of the yen
has fallen sharply and steadily. Further, although
the value of the dollar in terms of the Canadian dollar
has risen steadily since fourth quarter 1976, U.S. out­
put growth has been significantly faster than that in
Canada. In the cases of both Japan and Canada (the
United States’ major trading partners), the view that
recent movements in the foreign exchange value of
the dollar have been in response to relatively more
rapid economic growth in the United States than
abroad is inconsistent with experience.
Thus, the hypothesis that exchange rates adjust to
offset differences in economic growth is not clearly
supported by the data. One limiting factor of this
hypothesis is that it overlooks the importance of the
impact of price differentials on international trade.
For example, a U.S. resident might buy a new car
if his real income increases. However, the choice be­
tween a domestically or foreign produced car depends
upon, among other things, price differentials. The al­
ternative hypothesis which incorporates these price
effects explains movements in the foreign exchange
value of the dollar over the 1975-78 period better than
Page 3

FE D E R A L R ESERVE B A N K OF ST. LOUIS

the one which relies solely on differential rates of
growth.

AN ALTERNATIVE VIEW OF
EXCHANGE RATE MOVEMENTS
Another explanation of the primary cause of changes
in the foreign exchange value of the dollar, which
takes account of the association between exchange
rates and inflation differentials, views exchange rate
movements as essentially monetary phenomena, in­
fluenced strongly by such factors as money stock
growth.6 Real factors, such as output growth, also are
recognized as affecting exchange rate movements, but
through monetary channels.7 When exchange rate
movements are viewed within a monetary framework,
changes in exchange rates reflect relative changes in
excess money stock growth.

Excess Money Stock Growth
When the U.S. money stock, for example, is greater
than the amount people desire to hold (given the
prevailing levels of real income, interest rates, prices,
and price expectations) an excess supply of money
exists in the United States. As people attempt to re­
duce their holdings of money to desired levels, spend­
ing will rise. The increase in spending will be dis­
tributed among goods and services, including both
real and financial assets. If the increased spending is
not accompanied by a similar rise in the supply of
goods and services, U.S. prices will rise. Although
price increases temporarily stimulate output growth,
the long-term pattern of output growth is limited by
resource growth. If the U.S. money stock continues
to exceed the amount of money people are willing
to hold, total spending will continue rising, but only
in the form of rising prices. In this framework, excess
money stock growth is the primary cause of inflation,
and changes in excess money stock growth are mani­
fested by changes in the rate of inflation.
The dollar “price” of foreign currencies will also
rise — that is, the foreign exchange value of the dollar
will fall — if there is excess money growth in the
United States, but not abroad. The rise in spending re­
6See Harry G. Johnson, “The Monetary Approach to Balanceof-Payments Theory,” Further Essays in Monetary Econom ics
(Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 1973), pp. 229-49,
and Jacob A. Frenkel, “A Monetary Approach to the Exchange
Rate: Doctrinal Aspects and Empirical Evidence,” Scandi­
navian Journal o f Econom ics, no. 2 (1 9 7 6 ), pp. 200-24.
7See Michael Mussa, “The Exchange Rate, the Balance of Pay­
ments and Monetary and Fiscal Policy Under a Regime of
Controlled Floating,” Scandinavian Journal o f Economics, no.
2 (1976) pp. 237-38.

Page 4


NO VEM B ER

1978

suiting from an excess supply of money in the United
States will result in increased purchases of both do­
mestic and foreign goods, services, and financial as­
sets. If there is no excess money growth abroad, for­
eign demand for U.S. goods, services and financial
assets will not rise immediately. Similarly, if excess
money stock growth exists both in the United States
and abroad, but that growth in the U.S. is more rapid
than abroad, then U.S. spending on foreign goods,
services and financial assets will rise relative to foreign
purchases in the United States. At the original ex­
change rate, the quantity of dollars which U.S. resi­
dents will want to spend to purchase foreign goods
and services will be larger than the quantity of dol­
lars foreigners want to buy to make purchases in the
United States. As a result, the “prices” of foreign cur­
rencies in terms of the U.S. dollar will rise. In other
words, the value of the dollar in foreign exchange
markets will fall.
As this discussion indicates, exchange rate move­
ments are not caused by relative changes in money
stock growth rates, but by relative excesses of money
growth above the amount demanded in each country.
In attempting to determine if money growth has had
an impact upon exchange rate movements, changes
in the amount of money that people are willing to
hold (that is, the demand for money) are critical.
For example, the amount of money people are will­
ing to hold will increase if real income rises, if in­
terest rates fall, or if future inflation is expected to
decline. There is no reason to expect that the amount
of money that people are willing to hold will be the
same in all countries or that it changes at the same
rate in all countries.8 Therefore, there is no reason
to expect relative money stock growth rates to equal
relative excess money stock growth rates.
As shown in Table II, money stock growth abroad
has been generally faster than that in the United
States since late 1976. For example, between fourth
quarter 1976 and mid-1978, the money stock has
grown at a 12.1 percent annual rate in Germany and
a 9.3 percent rate in Switzerland. Over the same pe­
riod, the U.S. money stock increased at an 8.1 percent
rate. Yet between fourth quarter 1976 and second
quarter 1978, the value of the dollar in terms of the
German mark and Swiss franc declined 16 and 27.5
percent, respectively. While changes in the demand
for money are difficult to measure, the monetary in8See, for example, Michael J. Hamburger, “The Demand for
Money in an Open Economy: Germany and the United King­
dom,” Journal o f M onetary Econom ics (January 1977), pp.
25-40.

NO VEMBER

FEDE RAL RESERVE B AN K OF ST. LOUIS

1978

Table II

M O N EY STOCK ( M l ) GROW TH
Two-Quarter Compounded Annual Rates of Change

1976 IV

Belgium

Canada

France

Germany

Italy

Japan

Netherlands

Switzerland

U.K.

U.S.

6 .0 %

6 .6 %

6 .9 %

4 .1 %

1 6 .6 %

1 1 .4 %

4.6 %

7 .4 %

8.2%

5 .7 %

1977 1
II
III
IV

8.3
5.4
10.3
13.6

6.6
9.4
10.7
12.1

7.6
10.8
10.9

7.3
9.2
9.3
11.5

20.7
22.0
21.2
18.9

7.0
0.6
6.5
11.9

19.7
20.5
21.7
8.5

7.4
4.7
1.4
-0 .7

5.6
14.6
22.5
29.5

7.4
7.9
8.4
8.0

1978 1
II
III

8.6
3.7
NA

9.3
6.4
11.6

9.4
9.7
NA

17.6
15.5
NA

NA
NA
NA

8.4
11.4
15.2

0.4
3.0
NA

14.9
25.7
NA

23.6
11.6
NA

7.0
8.3
9.1

5.4

N A — Data not available
Sources: Bank o f Canada, Bank o f England, Bank o f Japan, Board o f Governors o f the Federal Reserve System, Deutsche Bundesbank,
International Monetary Fund, Organization fo r Economic Cooperation and Development.

terpretation of price determination implies that the
rate of inflation in each country can be used to indi­
cate the rate of excess money growth.9

Exchange Rates and Inflation Differentials
As shown in Chart I, exchange rate movements
since the beginning of 1975 generally have been in
the appropriate direction to offset changes in relative
inflation rates.10 Over the 1975-76 period, U.S. infla­
tion, in general, decelerated relative to inflation abroad
and the foreign exchange value of the dollar generally
increased over this period. In the two cases where U.S.
inflation accelerated relative to that abroad, the for­
eign exchange value of the dollar behaved in the ex­
9For a discussion of the monetary interpretation of inflation,
see Denis S. Kamosky, “The Link Between Money and Prices
— 1971-76,” this R eview (June 1976), pp. 17-23.
Changes in the demand for money explain why money
growth abroad can exceed U.S. money growth without pro­
ducing an appreciation of the dollar. Expectations can signif­
icantly influence exchange rates in the short run. Suppose
inflation is expected to accelerate in the United States but not
in Germany and Switzerland. This could cause a decline in
the demand for dollars and a corresponding increase in the
demand for marks and francs. If the supply of dollars on
foreign exchange markets is not sufficiently reduced, the dollar
will depreciate against the mark and franc.
10For another discussion of this point and a critical look at
the monetary approach see Stein, “The Mystery of the De­
clining Dollar,” pp. 3-5.
The relationship between inflation differentials and exchange
rates is not exact, especially in the short run. For example,
the existence of nontradable goods and services, transporta­
tion and brokerage costs, barriers to trade and capital flows,
expectations, ana government intervention in foreign ex­
change markets prevent changes in rates of relative inflation
from being perfectly reflected in changes in exchange rates.
Further, turning points in exchange rate movements and
changes in relative rates of inflation can be expected to differ
somewhat; excess money growth affects inflation over time,
while exchange rates respond more quickly to monetary dis­
turbances. See Jacob A. Frenkel, “Purchasing Power Parity:
Doctrinal Perspective and Evidence from the 1920s,” Jour­
nal o f International Econom ics (May 1978), pp. 181-88.



pected manner. U.S. inflation was accelerating rela­
tive to Swiss inflation over the 1975-76 period and
the value of the dollar in terms of the Swiss franc
declined. U.S. inflation also accelerated relative to
Canadian inflation between mid-1975 and mid-1976
and the U.S. dollar depreciated in terms of the Ca­
nadian dollar during this period.
There is a case, however, in which changes in the
foreign exchange value of the dollar and the rate of
U.S. inflation relative to inflation abroad do not ap­
pear to be in offsetting directions. Over the 1975-76
period, U.S. inflation accelerated relative to inflation
in the United Kingdom; however, the value of the
dollar in terms of the British pound did not decline.
In this case, the actions of national governments ap­
pear to have had a significant impact upon exchange
rate movements over the 1975-76 period. During this
period, there were substantial sales of British pounds
by national governments, thereby contributing to sig­
nificant downward pressure on the foreign exchange
value of the British pound.11
Since late 1976, however, U.S. inflation has in gen­
eral accelerated relative to inflation abroad and the
foreign exchange value of the dollar has, on balance,
declined since then. In the one case where U.S. infla­
tion has decelerated relative to inflation abroad, Can­
ada, the foreign exchange value of the U.S. dollar has
steadily risen.
The pattern of relative rates of inflation, in most
cases, showed a reversal around late 1976. The most
obvious cases are those involving the European coun­
tries. For example, consumer prices in the United
u Official sterling claims on the United Kingdom declined
about 60 percent from 1974 to 1976. See International
Monetary Fund, Annual Report 1978, p. 53.
Page 5

NOVE M BER

F E D E R A L R ESERVE B A NK OF ST. LOUIS

1978

C h a rt I

Relative Rates of Inflation* a n d M o v e m e n ts in E xchange Rates
U.S. Cents Per
B e lg ia n Franc

elgium

U.S. Cents Per
C anad ian D olla r

Canada

Percent

U.S. Cents Per
fren ch Franc

France

Percent

-------------- 1 29

Exchange Rale

Exchange Rate

Relative Inflation Rate

Exchange Rate
I I

I I I

1977
ny

i 1 I

c

1978
U.S. Cents Per
G erm an Ma^rk

Percent

Percent

Relative Inflation Rate

Exchange Rate

Relative Inflation Rate

Relative Inflation Rate
Exchange Rate

Exchange Rate

2oi

1976

1977

Netherlands

Percent

U.S. Cents Per
Dutch Guilder

i

i

i

1975

1978

i

i

i

i

1976

i

i

i

1977

Switzerland

Percent

i

i

i

i

i

i

o

1978
U.S. Cents Per
S w is s Franc

Percent

Relative Inflation Rate

Relative Inflation Rate

Relative Inflation Rate
Exchange Rate

Exchange Rate

iii

i i

1-1 —L

i i i

1975

1976

1977

1978

-8

_L

_L

I I I
1976

I
I I
1977
1975 1978

_L

■20
1975

1976

I I
1977

J__ L

1978

S o u rc e s ; I n t e r n a t io n a l M o n e t a r y F u n d , U.S. D e p a rtm e n t o f C o m m e rc e , a n d B o a rd o f G o v e r n o r s o f th e F e d e r a l R e serve S yste m
♦ C o m p a r is o n o f ra te s o f c h a n g e in c o n s u m e r p r ic e in d e x o v e r c o r r e s p o n d in g f o u r - q u a r t e r p e r io d s . E x a m p le : th e U .S .- B e lg iu m r e la t iv e in f la t io n r a te f o r 1 /7 7 is
c o m p u te d b y s u b tr a c tin g th e p e r c e n ta g e c h a n g e in th e B e lg ia n CPI o v e r the 1 /7 6 - 1 /7 7 p e r io d fr o m th e p e r c e n t a g e c h a n g e in th e U.S. CPI o v e r th e s a m e
f o u r - q u a r t e r p e r io d . CPI d a t a a r e s e a s o n a lly a d ju s te d .
L a te s t d a t a p lo t t e d : E x c h a n g e ra te f o r a ll c o u n t r ie s - 3 r d q u a r t e r ; r e la t iv e in f la t io n r a te fo r F ra n c e , I t a ly , a n d J a p a n - 2 n d q u a rte r,- o t h e r c o u n t r ie s - 3 r d q u a r t e r .


Page 6


F E D E R A L RESERVE B ANK OF ST. LOUIS

States increased at a 5.9 percent rate between first
quarter 1975 and fourth quarter 1976. The correspond­
ing rates of inflation for six European countries were:
Belgium (9.1 percent), France (9.6 percent), Ger­
many (4.7 percent), Italy (15.7 percent), Nether­
lands (8.9 percent), Switzerland (2.1 percent), and
the United Kingdom (19.3 percent). Since fourth
quarter 1976, however, U.S. inflation has accelerated
to a 7.6 percent rate. In contrast, inflation in the Euro­
pean countries has decelerated: Belgium (5.3 percent),
France (9.2 percent), Germany (3.2 percent), Italy
(13.8 percent), Netherlands (5.0 percent), Switzer­
land (1.5 percent), and the United Kingdom (10.9
percent). In short, the monetary view of exchange rate
changes is consistent with the experience shown in
Chart I.

SUMMARY
When exchange rate movements are viewed as
basically monetary phenomena, the declining foreign
exchange value of the dollar can be attributed to an
excessive growth of the money stock in the United
States relative to the monetary actions of other coun­
tries. Belative rates of economic growth, operating
through the demand for money, do have an impact on
the foreign exchange market. As real income grows,
the quantity of money demanded increases. If the




NO VEM B ER

1978

quantity of money demanded in the United States
exceeds the amount supplied, all other factors con­
stant, the foreign exchange value of the dollar would
rise. Thus, a relatively rapid rate of U.S. economic
growth, if not resulting from monetary stimulus, con­
tributes to upward (rather than downward) pressure
on the foreign exchange value of the dollar.
However, other factors, such as expectations of
future accelerations in the rate of inflation, can cause
a reduction in the quantity of money demanded. The
interaction of money stock growth and changes in
the demand for money is indicated by changes in the
rate of inflation. The decline in the foreign exchange
value of the dollar since late 1976 corresponds with
an acceleration in U.S. inflation relative to inflation
abroad.
The cause of both the relative acceleration in U.S.
inflation and the corresponding decline in the foreign
exchange value of the dollar are responses to relatively
more expansionary (or less restrictive) monetary pol­
icies in the United States than abroad. The future
course of the foreign exchange value of the dollar
depends fundamentally upon the success of U.S. mone­
tary policy in reducing the rate of inflation in the
United States relative to the future performance of
inflation in other countries.

Page 7

Commentary on Monetary Economics:
An Interview with Karl Brunner
Professor Karl Brunner is a faculty member at both the University of Rochester,
New York, and the University of Bern, Switzerland, and is one of the foremost
scholars in the field of monetary theory and policy. He is also a periodic con­
tributor to this Review.
In the following interview, which originally appeared in the July 1978 issue
of The Banker, Professor Brunner outlines his interpretation of the monetarist
approach to economic analysis in response to comments and questions posed by
the publishers of The Banker. The interview is reprinted here because it repre­
sents a clear articulation o f modern monetarist thought and serves to further the
understanding of monetarist policy prescriptions.
For many years you have been regarded as one of
the leading advocates of a strict ‘monetary’ approach
to economic policy. Together with Professor Meltzer
you have played a leading part in bringing the
monetarist approach to a wider public, both through
the Shadow Open Market Committee in the United
States and in the past two years in Europe through
the Shadow European Economic Policy Committee
(SEEPC). How much progress has been made in
persuading public opinion of the merits of mone­
tarism?
Economic policy covers a wide range of measures
and the proper role of monetary policy should be
clearly recognised. Public opinion occasionally inter­
prets monetarism’ as a view attributing to money
and monetary policy an all-embracing power. This
involves a serious misconception. Monetarist analysis
essentially emphasises two aspects of the range of
policy problems: the relation between monetary
growth and the basic rate of inflation, and the rela­
tion between monetary acceleration ( or unanticipated
monetary growth) and temporary changes in output
and employment. The first relation determines mone­
tarist propositions about anti-inflationary policies. The
second relation determines, on the other hand, pro­
posals bearing on a stable and predictable course of
monetary policy. Monetarist analysis implies more­
over that monetary manipulation cannot raise the
trend of real growth. Neither is monetary expansion
a useful device under current circumstances to raise
investment expenditures. The falling trend of real
growth and investment expenditures is probably
dominated by the persistent erosion of the ‘rules of
the game’ required for a well-functioning market
8
Digitized for Page
FRASER


economy. The pervasive uncertainty about economic
policy and the gradual attrition of property rights
lower real growth and raise the normal level of un­
employment. This trend is reinforced by many gov­
ernmental measures which affect relative wages and
prices.
It often seems as if public opinion is largely on the
side of the monetarists now while public policy con­
tinues to be inflationary. How do you explain this?
I doubt that a major portion of ‘public opinion
fully accepts the monetarist perspective in matters
bearing on monetary policy and monetary events.
The English establishment, including the media,
cling, with a few exceptions, to the ancient Keynesian
story. But let us consider the position of the bureauc­
racies and officials involved in the formulation and
execution of monetary policy. They will find no
reason to change their accustomed conceptions and
procedures in the absence of serious costs or dangers
to their position. The bureaucracies and policy insti­
tutions have a strong incentive to persist with their
established pattern. The consequence of their misjudgments are usually borne by others. Changes in
the conceptions governing an established institution
usually require a major crisis, which encourages
probing questions and a wide-ranging public debate,
combined with a change in the management of the
bureaucracy.
How would you sum up the present state of the
debate?
Indeed, the discussion continues. It continues in
scholarly journals and in the arena of public debate.

F ED E R AL R ESERVE B A NK OF ST. LOUIS

But it is important to understand that the nature
of the discussion has gradually shifted over the years.
Substantial propositions originally advanced by mone­
tarist analysis have been incorporated into profes­
sional thinking in the United States. Keynesian
analysis still thrives on the other hand, even in archaic
forms, in Germany and England. The meshing of
ideas occurring between centres of active research
has, however, unavoidably shifted the focus of the
relevant issues over the past years. Three problems
have, in my judgment, emerged from recent debates
with a force requiring future attention by scholars.
These problems are:
(i) the possibility and usefulness of an activist ap­
proach to policy based on optimal control
techniques;
(ii) the relative stability of the private and govern­
ment sector;
(iii) the relevant perspective bearing on the be­
haviour of the government sector.
A neo-Keynesian position asserts the potential of
optimal control techniques and an activist approach
to policy-making. The Keynesian tradition also asserts
the need for a stabilising government sector to con­
tain or offset the inherent instability of the private
sector. Lastly, this tradition reflects a conception of
government expressed by the ‘public interest’ or ‘good­
will’ theory of government behaviour. This theory as­
sumes that bureaucracies and politicians in general
attempt to maximise social welfare. The alternative
position rejects this neo-Keynesian perspective. It
emphasises, in particular, that optimal control tech­
niques and activism are likely to create instabilities
in the economic process. It also stresses the basic
stability of the private sector confronting a de-stabilising public sector. This de-stabilisation is linked to
an analysis centered on the entrepreneurial behaviour
of bureaucracies and politicians. This analysis rejects
the ‘public interest’ theory of government frequently
used in discussions of stabilisation policy.
Why does it seem to have so strong a grip on policy­
makers? Or to put the question in other terms: Why
do governments inflate when there are no benefits to
be derived from such action?
Is it really so? We need to look more carefully.
The apparent intractability of inflation cannot be
explained in terms of the linkages and interactions
of the economic process. A radical and sustained
reduction of monetary growth below a critical bench­
mark level determined by a country’s institutional



NO VEMBER

1978

environment would effectively remove over time any
inflation. The relevant question should thus be ad­
dressed to central banks, treasuries and beyond to
the nature of the political process shaping the behav­
iour of these institutions.
Three major channels have unleashed over the past
12 years in various countries excessive rates of mone­
tary growth. One channel works via large and persis­
tent government deficits and corresponding pressures
on the central bank to finance the deficit. Italy offers
a classic example in this respect. Major groups, in­
cluding the bureaucracy, find it advantageous to
expand the budget. This behaviour is motivated by
the wealth transfers produced with the expansion of
the budget.
Another channel functions via large and increasing
loans made directly or indirectly by central banks to
commercial banks. Such loan expansion accelerates
the monetary base and ultimately raises monetary
growth rates. There emerges under the circumstances
an apparently uncontrollable monetary growth. But
this uncontrollability essentially results from the cen­
tral bank’s unwillingness, or political inability, to
adjust the interest rate charged on central bank ac­
commodation to the realities of the market place.
France and Belgium offer some useful illustration in
this context. The crucial link in the inflationary proc­
ess under the circumstances is the political liability
burdening the central bank’s interest rate policies.
And these liabilities reflect again implicit wealth
transfers motivating the political constraints.
Lastly, determined efforts to maintain an under­
valued exchange rate produce extensive interventions
on the foreign exchange markets. These interventions
are converted via an acceleration of the monetary
base into ‘uncontrollable’ rates of monetary growth.
Maintenance of an undervalued exchange rate in­
volves an abdication of monetary control. Domestic
monetary growth is necessarily tied in this case to
the inflationary policies of the leading nations. This
policy reflects usually, the evident interests of major
export industries. It involves again an implicit trans­
fer of wealth, and it is this which lies behind the
political pattern we observe.
So what are the fundamental mistakes made by
those with whom you disagree?
Let us take the OECD as an illustrative example.
The OECD vigorously preaches activist financial
expansionism as a solution to the major problems of
unemployment and low growth. It is caught in old
Page 9

FEDERAL. RESERVE B A N K OF ST. LOUIS

conceptions and its bureaucracy seems unable to
open a meaningful discussion of newer scientific
developments. The measured rates of unemployment
and sagging investment expenditures that have been
recorded in recent years do not reflect a ‘deficient
aggregate demand problem’ of the nature experienced
in the 1930s. The role of supply factors and the effect
of institutions and policies on incentives to work and
to invest, are basic factors not sufficiently recognised
in traditional ‘Keynesian’ conceptions of the world.
Do you think that price stability is the only eco­
nomic objective a government should have?
Hardly. It is an important objective, but the
government’s essential function should be to provide
a stable and predictable framework for the rules of
the social game. This will never satisfy the social
activist however. But I urge you to consider that
social activism tends to produce institutions which
lower our living standards and, ultimately, via
a persistent growth of government, endanger our
freedom.
Is it a fundamental assumption of your position
that the real economy is inherently self-stabilising?
Yes. The Keynesian tradition proceeded on the view
that the market system is inherently unstable or prone
to settle, whenever left alone, around activity levels
substantially below ‘potential output’. This perspec­
tive, supplemented with the public interest theory’
of government, explains the activist approach to
‘stabilisation policy’. We contend on the other hand
that the market system is a shock-absorbing and self­
regulating system with built-in stabilising properties.
We also contend that the problem can be approached
beyond metaphysics and ideology as an issue to
be assessed by proper procedures of empirical
examination.
A soft version of monetarism would allow the
authorities to use fiscal policy in a discretionary
manner, to offset swings in the business cycle, whilst
insisting that they finance any budget deficits in a
non-inflationary way. You, however, believe in
balanced budgets. Why?
This kind of ‘soft monetarism’ offers no adequate
solution. It encourages actually the bad patterns
inherited from the past. It implicitly assumes that
the ‘government’ attends to the public interest and
can be relied upon to adjust the budget according
to ‘the needs of stabilisation policies’. This seems to
be somewhat naive in our judgment. The political
process increasingly produces a persistent deficit and

Page 10


NOV EM BE R

1978

larger budgets in the absence of well understood
and widely accepted constitutional rules confining
the government’s fiscal operation. Moreover, a per­
sistent deficit lowers the likelihood of proper mone­
tary control.
It is often said that monetarists are good at laying
down the ground-rules for some ultimate state where
a monetary rule can be applied, but not at describing
how we get there from the present. Is there force in
this criticism?
None whatsoever. The assertion depends essentially
on a tacit constraint imposed on monetarist proposals
designed to move the economy towards a non-infla­
tionary growth path. Our opposition claims that no
anti-inflationary policies be admitted which lower
temporarily employment and output. Such a condition
rules out any meaningful anti-inflationary campaign.
This is not because we desire lower employment and
output. We desire to stabilise the economy around
a stable price level and this requires, at this stage,
a persistent reduction of monetary growth. This re­
duction, unfortunately, may produce a temporary
decline of employment and output. The likelihood of
this result increases with the length, magnitude and
variability of the inflationary episode. But the fact
remains that there is no other way to control infla­
tion. I should also mention that the Shadow Open
Market Committee in the United States and the
Shadow European Economic Committee have repeat­
edly stated the policies required for the transition
period.
A new term has recently crept into the discussion of
economic policy, after ‘crowding out’. This is ‘the
wedge’. Could you explain what this is?
‘The wedge’ refers to the widening gap between
the cost to the employer of employing a unit of
labour and the net wage received by the employee.
This wedge affects various aspects of unemployment
inaccessible to manipulation by aggregate demand.
It is remarkable how frequently governments, as
recently in England and Sweden, cope with labour
market or budget problems with measures which in­
crease the size of the wedge and thus intensify
labour market problems. An increase in the wedge
lowers employment and lengthens the average dura­
tion of unemployment.
Another common criticism of monetarism is that it
sacrifices all other objectives of policy to that of
achieving price stability. For instance, to attain price
stability interest rates might have to go to such a

FE D ER AL RESERVE B A NK OF ST. LOUIS

level as to damage investment. How do you answer
that criticism?
The issue is simply this: the social cost of persis­
tent inflation exceeds, in our judgment, the social
cost of a once-and-for-all return to a stable price
level. Persistent inflation does not proceed in the
pleasing fashion of a smooth and fully anticipated
path involving fully-adjusted institutions and be­
haviour. It is an erratic process with large uncertain­
ties generating large variations in real growth and a
comparatively high level of normal unemployment.
The road leading out of inflation is cosdy and un­
pleasant indeed, but the alternative is much worse.
And as to interest rates, even politicians learn on
occasion that the best way to lower interest rates
permanently is to lower the rate of inflation. Of
course, the reversal of the inflationary trend induces
temporary increases in rates of interest. But accept­
ance of permanent inflation, in order to prevent a
temporary rise in interest rates, is a typical example
of the policies responsible for the contemporary mess.
Why have no central banks adopted a fixed mone­
tary rule?
What are a central bank’s incentives to do so? The
traditional procedures serve in general the established
bureaucracies much better. They offer more oppor­
tunities for evasive rhetoric. In particular, they permit
banks to claim credit for good conditions and allow
useful disclaimers of responsibility for bad develop­
ments (eg inflation). It is still remarkable to observe,
however, that some central banks are approaching
a policy of monetary control which need not involve
a fixed rule of rigidly constant growth.
Having monetary targets seems in some ways to
make it more difficult for a central bank to control
the money stock. For instance, when monetary
growth overshoots the target, institutions stop buy­
ing government debt because they anticipate higher
interest rates and this in turn boosts such monetary
expansion. What is your answer?
This involves two aspects. One bears on the insti­
tutions governing the quality of monetary control.
Many central banks (France, Belgium, Germany,
England and others) proceed under arrangements
which substantially lower the likelihood of pursuing
effective monetary control. Inappropriate institutions
may effectively obstruct any rational monetary man­
agement. Central banks frequently disregard this
issue and fail to recognise the importance of develop­
ing monetary arrangements which raise the degree



NOVEM BER

1978

of monetary control. Control will never be perfect
and the question about speculation induced by devia­
tions from the desired growth path continues to
attract attention. But such deviations hardly affect
securities with longer maturities. Given a credible
policy of monetary control, investors will know that
short-run errors in monetary growth will approxi­
mately wash out over time. Any short-run overshoot­
ing of monetary targets will not produce a decline
in bond prices under such circumstances. It is even
doubtful that very short-term rates would be seriously
destabilised. Interest rates seem much more prone to
fluctuate in response to policies geared to stabilise
interest rates.
Given international mobility of capital, an attempt
by a single country to control money by raising
interest rates may, it is argued, result simply in an
inflow of capital which will swell the money supply
further. Do not small open economies have to accept
the international inflation rate?
Most definitely not. Switzerland has not accepted
the prevailing international rate of inflation. A regime
of floating exchange rates offers each country an
opportunity to determine the monetary base to the
last cent in accordance with its wishes. This implies
approximate control of monetary growth, irrespective
of capital flows induced by relative interest rates or
relative movements of exchange rates and interest
rates.
Do we have to accept that exchange rates are,
bound to be volatile?
The volatility of exchange rates simply reflects the
uncertainty about the course of financial policy in
various countries. Substantial revisions in the markets’
evaluation of future policies are immediately im­
pounded into the current exchange rate. A stable
and reliable course of financial policies reduces the
fluctuations in exchange rates. No degree of inter­
vention can be a substitute for proper financial
policies. Intervention undermines monetary control
(Germany and Switzerland) and affects exchange
rates beyond the shortest horizon only in cases where
markets revise (in response to persistent interven­
tion) their expectations of the course of monetary
policy.
Nevertheless central banks seem to be intervening
on a larger and larger scale in the markets. Why
is this?
Whether the magnitude of intervention increases
remains to be seen. To some extent interventions are
Page 11

an instrument for controlling the monetary base
without operating on domestic credit markets or
manipulating advances to banks. But the major force
behind the massive intervention is probably concern
about the short-run effects on export industries.

Hardly. More likely is the expanding application
and use by sociologists of the analytic framework
developed over many decades in economics. This
development is visible in political science and also
in psychology.

Monetarist analysis has recently been applied to
many areas beyond its original and continuing con­
cern with monetary policy — for instance, to the
economics of bureaucracies.

Monetarism has the reputation of being a hard,
even heartless doctrine. How would you answer such
a charge?

The connection between monetarist analysis and
the emerging work on non-market institutions and
the political process is the systematic use of proper
economic analysis in both fields of research. There
is no monetarist analysis of bureaucracy but there
is indeed an analysis of bureaucracy. The motivation
of this work lies in the increasing range and impor­
tance of the phenomenon.
Is this new economic approach going to put the
sociologists out o f business?




What is more heartless than irresponsible and
foolish advice, or false promises? The hard problems
do not change under a deceitful rhetoric. We have
experienced rising and erratic inflation, increasing
‘unemployment’ and lower rates of real growth as a
result of ‘warm-hearted’ policies. It is time to pene­
trate beyond this cloud of verbalism. We cannot
expect to cope effectively with difficult problems
under an essentially immoral commitment to refuse
a hard and honest examination of the nature of the
issues.