View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF ST. L O U IS
may 1971

o l. 5 3 , N o .
Digitized for V
FRASER


5

The Economy: A Moderate Recovery

I OTAL SPENDING on goods and services rose at
a 7.3 per cent annual rate from the third quarter of
1970 to the first quarter of 1971, compared with a 4.6
per cent increase in the preceding year. A consider­
able first quarter spurt in the pace of overall economic
activity can be attributed largely to a reversal of
those forces accompanying work stoppages in the
automobile industry late last year. First quarter gains
in the auto sector accounted for about two-thirds of
the $30.8 billion increase in GNP.
Monetary growth, as measured by the narrowly
defined money supply, accelerated sharply in early
1971. Most interest rates are currently higher than
their February or March lows, though still well below
the 1969-70 peaks. Federal Government expenditures,
which have a short-run stimulative effect on total
spending, rose more rapidly in early 1971 than in the
previous two quarters.
Some progress in combating inflation has become
apparent this year, while unemployment has remained
at about 6 per cent of the labor force. Cutbacks in
Demand and Production
R a tio S c a le
Q uarterly Totals at Annual Rates
R a tio S ea l#
T rillio n s o f D o lla rs ___________________Seasonally Adjusted__________________ T rillio n s o f D o lla rs

Total Spending n

Real Product £

1963

1964

1965

1966

1967

1 968

12GNP in current dollors.
[2 GNP in 1958 dollars.
Percentages are a nnual rates of c h a n g e lo r perio d s indicated.
Latest d a ta plotted: 1st quarter

Page 2



1969

1970

1971

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce

defense spending have led to significant unemploy­
ment in defense-related industries. Continuation of
rapid monetary expansion, however, probably would
be reflected in considerable gains in total spending,
but would entail the risk of re-enforcing still formida­
ble inflationary pressures.

Stabilization Actions
The recent monetary ease evidenced in the growth
of the money stock is an extension of the expansive
policies undertaken last year. The Federal budget, on
a national income accounts basis, has been in sub­
stantial deficit since early 1970, compared with a
large surplus in 1969. On a high-employment basis,
which provides a better measure of fiscal stimulus,
the budget has been in surplus and has changed
little in recent quarters.

Monetary Actions
The monetary base, the prime determinant of
growth in the money supply,1 increased at a 10.5 per
cent rate from November to April, compared with a
6.2 per cent rate from February 1970 to November
and a 2.9 per cent rate in the preceding eleven
months. The growth pattern of Federal Reserve credit,
the principal source component of the monetary base,
has been similar to that of the base. Federal Reserve
credit rose at a 13.6 per cent rate from November to
April, compared with a 6.5 per cent rate from Febru­
ary 1970 to November and a 3 per cent rate in the
preceding eleven months. Money increased at a 12.5
per cent annual rate in the three months from January
to April, after rising 4.7 per cent in the year ending
in January.
The growth of the money supply over the past
three months was greater than any other consecutive
three-month period since January 1950. The growth
of the monetary base and Federal Reserve credit
'See “Elements of Money Stock Determination,” this Review
(October 1969), pp. 10-19, for an explanation of the linkages
between the monetary base and the money supply.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

MAY 1971

M o n e y Stock a n d M o n e t a r y B a se
Sea onolly Adj sted

250

+3.0%

Mon y Stock

200

+2.5%
+ 55% , ^ 2 2 1 .2

+ 6.37
■3.8%_____
- 0 5%

150

?0
c
Jt

58

s

1

<
t

i

100

5
c

£
11
t

90

Monetary Base*
80

100
+6 £ % , ^ 8 6 .0

+2.2%

90
80

6 J% ^^
+1.2%

70

+ 5 .1%

3

3

■R

t
1963

1964

1965

1966

R

5
a

5

2

2

«

- i—

t

t

1967

1968

1969

1970

50

(
1971

•Uses of the monetary base are member bank reserves and currency held by the public and
nonmember banks. Adjustments are made for reserve requirement changes and shifts in deposits
among classes of banks. Data are computed by this bank.
Percentages are annual rates of change for periods indicated.
Latest data plotted: April

the first quarter, compared with an average surplus of
$7 billion in calendar year 1970 and $9.7 billion in
calendar year 1969. The high-employment budget
averaged a $7.2 billion rate of deficit from 1966 to
1968.
According to research at this Bank, fiscal actions
alone, regardless of the method of measurement, have
little long-run influence on total spending for goods
and services, but these actions affect the transfer of
goods from one sector of the economy to another.2 For
example, expenditures associated with the award of a
large Government defense contract require the trans­
fer of funds from some individuals or businesses to
others, when the funds are provided through taxes
or bond purchases. If the Federal Reserve, rather
than the public, finances the award, the end result
may be an expansion of the money stock and further
inflation. If the Government does not wish to enlarge
its overall control of resources, the defense award
could be paid for through the elimination of some
other Government project.
Composition of Federal O u tlays*
Per Cent

ranked in the 98th and 71st percentiles, respectively,
for the same three-month period. Such rapid growth
rates of the monetary aggregates, if continued much
longer, suggest future increases in total spending at
rates far in excess of the growth rate of potential
real output.

Per Cent

60

60

50

50

Defense
—

40

40

Human Resoiirces
30

30

Fiscal Actions
Federal Government expenditures rose at an 8.4
per cent annual rate from the fourth quarter of 1970
to the first quarter of 1971, a slightly faster rate than
the 5.9 per cent annual rate of increase over the
preceding two years. On a national income accounts
basis, the Federal budget was in deficit at a $13.3
billion annual rate in the first quarter of 1971, com­
pared with an $11.5 billion average rate of deficit
in calendar year 1970. The large current deficit re­
flects more a shortfall in tax receipts, caused by the
slowing in overall economic activity, than accelerating
growth of Government expenditures. The rate of in­
crease of Government expenditures has slowed since
mid-1968. Expenditures rose at a 14.5 per cent rate
from mid-1965 to mid-1968 and have risen at a 6.4
per cent rate since mid-1968.
The hypothetical high-employment budget, which
reflects presumed income and expenditure patterns
of the Government at a 4 per cent rate of unemploy­
ment, was in surplus at a $6.6 billion annual rate in



20

20
Physical Resources

10

10

----Inte est Payments

1
1963

1964

1965

1966

1967

1968

1969

1970

1971

1972

Sources: O ffic e o f M a n a g e m en! a n d B u d g e t a n d F e d e ra l Reserve Bank of Si. Louis
‘ U n ified B udget basis; outlays include net lending.
Latest d a ta plotted: 1971 a n d 19 72 from 1 9 7 2 F e d e ra l b u d g e t

The Government allocated a greater share of its
spending to human resources than to defense expendi­
tures in the first quarter of this year. Prior to 1971,
defense spending exceeded expenditures on human
resources. Both defense expenditures and total Fed­
eral outlays as a per cent of total spending peaked in
mid-1968. Since then the Government has allocated a
declining share of its expenditures to defense. Some
effects of this shift in national priorities are evidenced
by the large number of defense workers currently
2See “The ‘Crowding Out’ of Private Expenditures by Fiscal
Policy Actions,” this Review (October 1970), pp. 12-24.
Page 3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

MAY 1971

Federal Outlays a as a Per Cent of Total Spending

Real Product*
A d j u s t e d a n d U n a d ju st e d for 1970
A uto m o b ile W o r k S t o p p a g e s
Billions of D o lla r s

I tal Oull ays

B illion s of D o lla r s

\
\
1
1

Adjusted
Monde! nse

/

Unadjusted
Real Produc ---

1

1969

'

/
V

-L

O1—
tlense

\

1970

1971

S ources: U.S. D e p a rtm e n t o f C o m m e rce a n d E conom ic R e p o rt o f the
P re sid e n t, 1971
’ G ro ss n a tio n a l p ro d u c t in 1958 d o lla rs .
U Real p ro d u c t w a s a d ju s te d fo r the e ffe c ts o f a u to m o b ile in d u s try strikes
in the fo llo w in g e le m e n ta ry w a y; N o m in a l G N P w a s in c re a s e d b y
$ 2 b illio n fo r 111/1970, b a s e d on d a ta fro m the U.S. C o m m e rce
D e p a rtm e n t N e w s R elease o f O c to b e r 2 2 ,1 9 7 0 , a n d $14 b illio n fo r

1963

1964

1965

1966

1967

1968

1969

1970

1971

1972

Sources: O ffic e o f M a n a g e m e n t a n d B u d g e t a n d F ed e ral Reserve Bank of St. Louis
[^ U n ifie d Budget basis; outlays in clu d e n e t le n din g.
£ Total Spending is Gross N a tio n a l P roduct in current dollars.

IV /1 9 7 0 , b a s e d on the E con o m ic R e p o rt o f the P re side n t, 1971, a n d
d iv id e d b y the G N P p ric e d e fla to r in b o th q u a rte rs.
Latest d a ta p lo tte d : 1st q u a r te r 1971

Latest d a ta plotted: 1971 a n d 1 9 72 o u tlays from 1 9 72 F e d e ra l b u d g e t; 1971 a n d 1972 to tal
s p e n d in g es tim ate d by F ed e ral Reserve Bonk of St. Louis.

among the unemployed. Defense Department-gener­
ated employment declined at an estimated 7.9 per
cent annual rate from 1968 to 1971, after rising at a
12.2 per cent rate from 1965 to 1968.3

Output, Prices and Employment
Recent output, employment and price trends have
been obscured somewhat by the automobile work
stoppages last year and preparations for a possible
steel strike this summer. Allowance for these irregular
fluctuations in activity, particularly the automobile
strike, suggests that real output has risen slightly
since the middle of last year. Rates of price increase
have slowed somewhat, and the level of employment
has remained about unchanged since last summer.
None of these developments is necessarily inconsis­
tent with those of the early recovery stages following
other postwar recessions.
The addition (to adjust for auto strike influences)
of about $2 billion to nominal GNP in the third quar­
ter of last year and $14 billion in the fourth quarter
indicates that a slow recovery from a mild recession
probably began in the third quarter of 1970. The ac­
companying chart presents an approximation of the
changes in real output with and without adjustment
for auto strike influences over the past year and a
half. The adjusted data indicate that three quarters
3Economic Report of the President, 1971, p. 44.

Page 4


of negative or negligible growth from IV/1969 to
11/1970 were followed by three quarters of moderate
gains in real output from III/1970 to 1/1971.
The transitory influence of the auto strike on em­
ployment, industrial output and prices does not seri­
ously hamper the comparison of these economic
variables with past recession-recovery periods. The
following chart indicates the relative mildness of
the current recession-recovery in terms of payroll em­
ployment and industrial production, and the relative
severity of the current inflation. Industrial production
did not decline as steeply in the current recessionrecovery period as in previous comparable periods,
but it also has not rebounded as sharply. In fact,
industrial production in the first quarter of 1971 (six
quarters after the peak) was still below the third
quarter 1969 peak; industrial production on average
for the three comparable earlier periods had risen
above the earlier peak after six quarters. Recent data
indicate that industrial production increased at a 3.7
per cent annual rate from March to April 1971, but it
continued at a rate below the 1969 peak.

Prices
An inspection of the consumer and wholesale price
indexes suggests that some progress has been made
in slowing price rises. Consumer prices rose at a 4
per cent rate from July 1970 to March 1971, compared
with a 5.9 per cent increase the previous year. Whole­
sale prices of industrial commodities rose at a 4 per
cent rate in the July-to-April period, about the same as

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

MAY 1971

C o m p arison of Three Economic Indicators
Re ce ssion — Re co ve ry P e rio d s
P e a k s - 100
115

P e a k s - 100
115

Industrial Production
3 R D Q T R .5 3
3R D Q T R ’5 7
2 N D QTR. 6 0
3 R D G TR.69

110

110
105

105
J

1968-71

100

100

95

95
A v e r a g e o f 1 9 5 2 -5 4 ,

'

a n d 1959-61

90
85

9 5 6 - 5 8 ,V

i

i

i

I

90

---- 1---------i-------------------1---------1----

i

Payroll Employment

105

85
105

1968-71

/

100

t

A v e r a g e o f 1 9 5 2 - 5 4 ,1 9 5 6 - 5 8 , _________
a n d 1959-61

95

90

GNP Price Deflator

110

110
— i—

i

A v e r a g e o f 1 9 5 2 - 5 4 ,1 9 5 6 - 5 8 ,
a n d 1959-61

100

^

-

105

100

8-71

95
90

95

_L_

90

105

100

" .............'

---- i---------1--------- i--------- i---------i-------- --------- L--------1---------1---------1--------- 1--------4

-

3 - 2 - 1 0
1
2
3
QUARTERS T O A N D FRO M PEAK

95
90

S o u rc e s : U.S. D e p a rtm e n t o f L a b o r , B o a rd o f G o v e rn o rs o f th e
F e d e ra l R e serve S y s te m , a n d U .S . D e p a rtm e n t o f C o m m e rc e

1969-71 period as in the average of the three earlier
periods. Six quarters after the peak, however, payroll
employment was at about the level of the peaks in
both the recent and the earlier periods. The fact that
payroll employment did not decline or rebound as
much as the average of the earlier comparable periods
suggests the mildness of the latest economic slow­
down and recovery.
The current employment situation is similar to the
1961 recession-recovery period in terms of the gap
between real and potential output, as estimated by
the Council of Economic Advisers. A fairly reliable
relation between real output, potential output and
the unemployment rate has been established.4 The
greater the gap between actual and potential output,
the higher the unemployment rate. The gap between
real and potential output at the end of 1961 (three
quarters after the trough of the recession) was about
6.3 per cent of potential output, not substantially dif­
ferent from the 5.9 per cent in early 1971. Elimination
of the gap between real and potential output, which
did not occur until four years after late 1961, was
accompanied by a fall in unemployment to 4 per cent
of the labor force or less.
The composition of the unemployed has changed
since past recession-recovery periods. The trough
years, 1954, 1958, and 1961, were marked by substan­
tial unemployment among full-time, blue-collar, mar­
ried male workers. The trough year 1970 was charact­
erized by marked unemployment among part-time
workers (all workers other than full-time workers),
teenagers, and women. This changed nature of un­
employment carried over into early 1971.

L a te s t d a t a p lo tte d : 1st q u a r t e r 1971

T a b le I

the increase in the preceding year. Wholesale prices
of farm products and processed foods and feeds, a
more volatile price index than most others, was about
unchanged from July to April after rising 3.3 per cent
the previous year.
The accompanying chart indicates that price in­
creases began to slow a few quarters after the peak
in the three comparable earlier periods, but have con­
tinued to rise rapidly since the most recent peak. The
upward momentum of prices generated over the
decade of the 1960’s has been difficult to halt.

Employment
Both payroll and total civilian employment have
been about unchanged since late last summer. Pay­
roll employment was not cut back as much in the



Ratio of the Unemployment Rate of Selected
Workers to the Overall Unemployment Rate
A ll
W o rk e rs

F u ll­
tim e

Blue
C o lla r

M a rrie d
M en

Teen­
agers
(1 6 -1 9 )

W om en
( 2 0 and
ov e r)
100%

1954

100%

73%

229%

100

95%
1 06

131%

1 95 8

150

75

234

90

1961

100

1 00

137

69

251

94

1970

1 00

92

127

53

312

98

The number of employed as a proportion of the
population of labor force age (16-64) was higher in
1970 than in earlier trough years, reflecting a stronger
job market and higher labor force participation rates.
This ratio was 64.2 per cent in 1970, compared with
61.8 per cent in 1961, 61.4 per cent in 1958 and 60.5
per cent in 1954.
'See “A Monetarist Model for Economic Stabilization,” this
Review (April 1970), pp. 7-25.
Page 5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

Secular increases in the labor force participation
rate of women are one probable cause for their higher
unemployment, and the 1947-55 baby boom has been
a strong force increasing the number of young-adult
entrants into the labor force. A changing attitude
toward the role of women in society, growing numbers
of young workers, and an increasing supply of mili­
tary veterans (whose unemployment rate is consid­
erably higher than their civilian counterparts) will
tend to assure continued rapid growth of the labor
force in the near future.

Spending in Major Sectors
Among those economic sectors usually considered
cyclically sensitive, residential construction activity is
one of the few which has displayed strong signs of
recovery in recent months. Consumer spending on
durable goods has shown little strength apart from
first quarter automobile sales. Spending (on inventory
and on plant and equipment) has also remained
sluggish.

G N P S p e n d in g C om p onents
C yc lic a lly S e n sitiv e Sectors
B i ll i o n s of D o l l a r s

B ill io n s of D o l l a r s

MAY 1971

Housing and Consumer Expenditures
Residential construction continued at a brisk pace
in the first quarter. From the second quarter of last
year to the first quarter of 1971, nominal spending on
residential structures rose at a 36.2 per cent rate, com­
pared with a 16.2 per cent decline in the preceding
year. Falling mortgage interest rates, increased avail­
ability of funds from savings institutions, and continu­
ing Federal housing subsidies have stimulated build­
ing activity in recent months.
New housing starts and new building permits, both
of which lead actual home construction, were at a
higher level in the first quarter of this year than at
any quarter in more than a decade. The outlook for
business structures, however, is not so favorable for
the near future. Commercial and industrial construc­
tion contracts, which normally lead business construc­
tion, were at a six-year low in the first quarter.
Consumer spending, which constitutes more than
60 per cent of total spending, increased at a 7 per
cent annual rate from the second quarter of last year
to the first quarter of 1971, after rising 7.2 per cent
in the previous year. Consumer spending on durable
goods, which is more cyclically oriented than spend­
ing on services or nondurable goods, has not re­
bounded strongly from a 1969-70 slump. Such spend­
ing increased at an 8.2 per cent rate from the second
quarter of last year to the first quarter of 1971, com­
pared with a 9.6 per cent annual rate of increase from
1961 to 1968.
Much of the drop in fourth quarter automobile
sales was offset by first quarter post-strike purchases.
A rapidly expanding money stock, a March-April surge
in all retail sales (an estimated 7 per cent higher than
a year earlier), improved credit conditions, and high
stock market prices suggest possible future consumer
spending strength. Unfavorable price and unemploy­
ment developments, however, would tend to counter
a strongly optimistic consumer spending outlook.

Business Spending

S o u rc e : U.S. D e p a rtm e n t o f C o m m e rc e
Latest d a ta p lo tte d : 1st q u a r t e r 1971


Page 6


Spending on producers’ durable equipment and
structures slowed to a 3 per cent annual rate of in­
crease from the second quarter of 1970 to the first
quarter of 1971, down from a 5.4 per cent rise the
previous year. Possibly contributing to the slowing in
investment has been a fall in manufacturing capacity
utilization from 79.8 per cent in the first quarter of
1970 to 73.1 per cent in the first quarter of 1971.
After-tax corporate profits, which often lead invest­

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

ment activity, increased at an 11.1 per cent rate from
11/1970 to 1/1971, after falling 11.7 per cent the pre­
vious year. Continued profit recovery, lower interest
rates, and a sustained surge in consumer spending
would, if realized, spur investment spending later
this year. Lengthy work stoppages and continued
excess capacity would tend to restrain such spending.
Inventory spending was not strong in any quarter
of 1970 nor in the first quarter of 1971. The increase
of business inventories was $3.5 billion in 1970 and
$1.4 billion (annual rate) in the first quarter of 1971,
compared with an average $9.7 billion increase from
1965 to 1969. The inventory-to-sales ratio did not in­
crease so much in early 1970 as in past recessionary
periods. Consequently, inventory liquidation need not
be so great as in past recovery periods. Steel inven­
tories (as well as steel production) are expected to
rise rapidly before the possible mid-summer steel
strike. Steel inventories would be worked off later
this year with a strike (as in 1959) or without one"
(as in 1968).

Summary
Total spending rose rapidly in the first quarter of
this year, with much of the increase attributable to a
post-strike automobile rebound. Residential construc­
tion spending has expanded rapidly in the current
recovery period, but consumer, business and Federal
Government spending have declined or expanded
only moderately through the first quarter of this year.
Partial elimination of work stoppage influences sug­
gests that a mild recovery from a mild recession has
been underway since last summer. The declines in
payroll employment and industrial production were




MAY 1971

not as steep as the average of three comparable
earlier periods, nor has the recovery been as sharp.
Monetary actions have been very stimulative in re­
cent months. The money supply grew at a 12.5 per
cent rate from January to April, a rate greater than
any other consecutive three-month period since Jan­
uary 1950. The monetary base and Federal Reserve
credit have also risen at extremely high rates in early
1971.
Some slight signs of progress in slowing the rate of
inflation emerged in the first part of 1971. Inflationary
pressures, as evidenced by continuing high wage set­
tlements, are far from being erased. Prices, preceded
by monetary expansion, rose virtually unabated
through the second half of the decade of the 1960’s,
in contrast to the 1950’s when they were slowed by
policy actions on several occasions. The momentum
of price increases has been much stronger recently
than in the 1950’s.
Policies of moderate restraint and moderate expan­
sion were undertaken in 1969 and 1970, respectively,
to slow price increases gradually. These policies of
gradualism may be in jeopardy of being abandoned
prematurely at the first signs of progress in arresting
inflation. A repeat of the excessively stimulative poli­
cies of 1967-68 risks reversal of the modest progress
achieved thus far in curbing inflation. The moderate
economic slowdown of 1969-70 will have served no
useful purpose if the battle against inflation is termi­
nated short of success. In addition, the costs of slow­
ing prices in terms of lost employment and production
will be far higher in subsequent years if the current
inflation and inflationary expectations are permitted
to continue.

Page 7

Social Priorities and
The Market Allocation of Credit
Speech by DARRYL R. FRANCIS, President, Federal Reserve Rank
of St. Louis, to the College of Rusiness and Industry,
Mississippi State University, February 23, 1971

I n RECEN T YEARS there has been much discus­
sion concerning financial responsibility for the alloca­
tion of resources for social goals. Some contend that
there is a widening gap between the performance of
our financial institutions and the desires of society.
They assert that society is concerned primarily with
the relative shares of total expenditure in individual
sectors of the economy, and that this is inconsistent
with the concern of national monetary policymakers
for aggregate activity and the profit motive governing
the private financial community.
For several decades many economic sectors have
allegedly fared unfavorably from the market alloca­
tion of resources, especially the allocation of credit.
Such sectors include housing, state and local govern­
ments, small business, low income groups, -and agricul­
ture. A natural consequence of this alleged inefficient
allocation of credit has been a number of proposals
designed to improve the system of credit allocation.
In a world of scarce resources the allocation of
credit is an important function. It is a major deter­
minant of the type and quantity of goods and services
available to consumers. This function can be per­
formed either through competitive markets or on the
basis of social priorities administered by the govern­
ment. Allocations through the marketplace are the
result of individual decision-making in the daily pur­
chasing of goods and services. Such purchases indi°The issues discussed in this speech have been presented to
other groups recently by President Darryl R. Francis.
Page 8



cate to producers the type and quantity of goods and
services desired by consumers. Producers in turn pur­
chase resources such as labor and capital to provide
a level of production necessary to meet consumer de­
mands at market prices. In contrast, social priorities
are actually restrictions imposed on the community
by delegated authority. In making the choice between
these systems of resource allocation, we are faced with
issues concerning both economic welfare and freedom.
In this discussion I shall contend that the main­
tenance of maximum welfare in individual sectors is
consistent with both a monetary policy concerned
primarily with aggregates and the profit motive of
private financial firms. Most shortcomings in financial
market performance in recent years were the result of
impediments to the operation of free markets. Credit
controls designed to alleviate alleged hardships often
do not alter resource flows in the socially desired di­
rection. If aid to low income groups is the social ob­
jective, cash payments are a more efficient means of
providing assistance than credit reallocations.
I
believe that the market system of credit alloca­
tion is superior to any other system. It provides
greater economic welfare and more individual free­
dom of choice. Rather than attempting to improve
welfare in specific sectors, the monetary authorities
can make a greater contribution to overall welfare by
concentrating on the maintenance of national eco­
nomic stability. Given the appropriate actions for
overall stability, market forces will assure that indi­
vidual sectors are treated equitably in a competitive

MAY 1971

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

enterprise economy free from excessive restrictions.
Consumer preferences as reflected by demands for
goods and services will provide the incentive for pro­
ducers in each sector to acquire necessary resources,
including credit, for a level of output consistent with
maximum satisfaction.

Case for Social Priorities Overstated
Most of the impetus for setting social priorities on
credit flows or on goods and services produced has
occurred during periods of great depressions or of high
nominal interest rates (notably agriculture in the
1930’s and housing more recently). When market
rates exceed limits established by usury laws, Regula­
tion Q and other restrictions on savings yields, credit
flows are diverted from normal patterns. These market
barriers have tended to starve some sectors, while
other sectors not subject to the regulations have paid
the market rates and obtained more funds than would
have been available under free market conditions.
Such restrictions, however, probably have little effect
on the total volume of credit or savings.
In order to correct the assumed defects of capital
and credit markets, proposals have been made to es­
tablish priorities on credit flows through various finan­
cial agencies, including the Federal Reserve System.1
Variable reserve requirements against bank assets,
selective open market purchases, the discount mech­
anism, moral suasion, quotas, margin requirements,
and direct controls have been suggested as means for
altering credit flows to specific sectors. If reserves
were required against assets rather than liabilities,
and it was desired, for example, to increase invest­
ment in housing relative to other investments, re­
quired reserves could be increased on other invest­
ments and reduced on residential mortgages. This
would provide incentive for banks to make more
residential mortgage loans. It has also been suggested
that Federal Reserve Open Market purchases include
FNMA securities, thereby increasing the volume of
funds available for home mortgages.

Credit Priorities Included in
Federal Reserve Act
A number of credit priorities were included in the
discount provisions of the original Federal Reserve
1See Tom Connors, “Variable Reserve Requirement Imposi­
tion Opposed by Burns,” New York Journal of Commerce,
April 1, 1971, and “Bunting Opposes Fed on Credit Alloca­
tion,” American Banker, April 19, 1971, for discussions of this
subject.



Act. Agricultural paper, for example, was given the
special consideration that maturities of such paper not
exceeding six months (later extended to nine months)
were eligible for discount. Short-term paper, or real
bills, arising from commercial transactions was like­
wise given preference over most other instruments in
the credit market. Maturity requirements were more
stringent for other paper.
With the decline of the discount mechanism as a
major monetary policy instrument in the 1930’s, this
means of channeling credit to areas with high priori­
ties declined. Other restrictions on credit, however,
tended to offset this move toward free market alloca­
tion. Margin requirements placed on stock market
credit may have channeled a small amount of funds
to other areas. At the beginning of World War II, the
buildup of defense industries was given high priority
and received aid through the V loan program admin­
istered by the Federal Reserve. Consumer credit con­
trols were instituted about this time, and both con­
sumer and real estate credit controls were used dur­
ing the Korean conflict to reduce credit and demand
for resources in these sectors.2 Following World War
II and the Korean buildup, the central bank reverted
to its pre-war position with respect to credit allocation.
As market interest rates increased in recent years,
Regulation Q and other restrictions reduced credit
flows through normal bank channels. These restric­
tions probably resulted in a loss of funds to the hous­
ing industry and a gain to other sectors which could
pay market rates for the diverted funds.
Since credit flows are an important determinant of
production, the problem of credit allocation is similar
to that of allocating other resources. The solution de­
pends upon whether the individual should be given
freedom of choice in the marketplace to decide what
goods and services will be available for consumption,
or whether this decision should be imposed on the
individual through social action. It is my belief that
such rights to choose goods and services for consump­
tion should be left to the individual.

Public Action Appropriate for
Some Activities
I recognize that a number of functions can be per­
formed more efficiently in the public sector. Main­
tenance of social order, air pollution control, common
2Federal Reserve Bulletin, September 1941, p. 825-836; Oc­
tober 1950, p. 1314-1321; and December 1950, p. 1577-1581.
Page 9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. L O U IS

defense, and monetary controls provide general bene­
fits which cannot be completely captured by an indi­
vidual. For example, air pollution control, which may
require considerable expenditure by some sectors, pro­
vides substantial benefits to the entire community.
Some producers and consumers in minimizing costs
fail to control harmful waste products. Such polluting
activities which violate the rights of others to clean air
and water must be regulated by government action.
A lighthouse is a classic example of a service that
should be in the public sector. It provides equal
benefits to both owners and nonowners of ships in its
vicinity, and its use by one ship does not reduce its
services for other vessels. We justify expenses for
public education on the basis that all citizens receive
some benefits from the educated individuals. In order
for the public to gain the benefits of such public goods
and services, collective expenditures are necessary.
These expenditures may not provide benefits to tax­
payers in proportion to the taxes collected from each
individual, but the alternative may result in the elimi­
nation of services with a consequent reduction in
welfare to the entire community.

Private Action More Efficient
for Most Activities
In contrast to activities which are performed more
efficiently in the public sector, most economic benefits
readily accrue to the individual without specific com­
munity action. Given the premise that individuals
spend their funds so as to maximize satisfaction, in­
dividual expenditures for goods and services provide
a more efficient guide to producers than do priorities
established by legislative action. The establishment of
legal priorities is simply a method of substituting col­
lective for individual decision-making.
The establishment of priorities involves a tradeoff
of one type of activity or good for another. Total
volume of goods and services produced is not in­
creased. The diversion of resources to enhance output
in one sector, such as residential housing, with a re­
duction of resources in other areas, however, is not
neutral with respect to economic welfare. If marginal
expenditures by each person result in optimum satis­
faction prior to the diversion, the goods and services
foregone are of greater value to consumers than the
gains from the additional houses. In other words, given
the pattern of income distribution, the additional
houses provide less welfare than would have been
provided by the goods and services foregone, as indi­

Page 10


MAY 1971

cated by free market purchases prior to the arbitrary
diversion. Thus, such socially established priorities
force individuals into a pattern of expenditures which
provides less-than-optimum want satisfaction.
There is also a possible tradeoff between housing
and other forms of wealth, with no resultant decline
in current consumption. For example, given full use
of resources, more houses could be built at the expense
of investment elsewhere without reducing other types
of current consumption. The long-run impact of such
action would reduce national wealth and goods and
services available for consumption in future periods.
One prime example of the inefficiency of producing
under arbitrarily determined priorities in the United
States is our agricultural programs of the past several
decades. In the 1930’s and again in the 1950’s, farm
incomes were thought to be too low relative to in­
comes in nonfarm occupations. We first moved to
remedy the alleged problem by setting a floor under
farm commodity prices with the aid of a government
price support program. Price supports were generally
established above free market levels, thus providing
incentive for production of a surplus of farm products.
Our stocks of farm products, which were purchased
by the government in its price support operations,
soon rose to enormous levels. Numerous measures
have been taken to reduce these stocks, including
subsidized exports, subsidized school lunches, food
stamps to low income groups, a land rental program
to remove millions of acres of cropland from produc­
tion, and crop allotments which arbitrarily limit the
acreage planted to many crops. The alleged problem
and inefficient programs continue.
Fundamental economics tells us that the long-run
market price is the only price providing just enough
incentive for farmers to produce the quantity of farm
products that will clear the market. It is the only price
which will avoid an accumulation of excesses or short­
ages. The market price is also the only price that will
provide sufficient incentive for labor and other re­
sources to adjust between agriculture and other sec­
tors of the economy so as to maximize overall eco­
nomic output. Other resource combinations will tend
to reduce output and thus the volume of goods and
services available to consumers.
Agriculture, like other sectors of a competitive econ­
omy, is self-adjusting, provided that market forces
are permitted to operate freely. If incomes to farm
resources are too low relative to returns in other
areas, more farmers and farm youth will obtain em­

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

ployment in the nonfarm sector. Similarly, if incomes
rise higher in agriculture relative to other sectors, we
will have an expansion of farm workers until returns
to workers of equal ability are equal in all sectors of
the economy after allowance for nonmoney factors.
Our public housing is another example of the waste­
ful use of resources based on public ordering of pro­
duction. Despite the sizable subsidies provided oc­
cupants, a large proportion of public housing units are
often vacant, and the operations are in a constant
state of insolvency.
Such waste of resources resulting from public deci­
sions is not limited to our nation or our time. Modem
hotels built by governments of some underdeveloped
countries where few potential customers reside are
now largely vacant. The numerous edifices of the
Middle Ages and the very expensive royal mauso­
leums of ancient times are examples of resource di­
versions which were detrimental to most of the
people.
Social priorities which increase flows of some types
of goods and services, in addition to their inefficien­
cies, are extremely biased against those individuals
who already possess adequate amounts of these goods
and in favor of those who are in the process of pur­
chasing such goods. For example, those persons who
already have adequate homes are penalized when
resources are diverted from other areas through social
action to home building. With fewer resources allo­
cated to other areas, all consumers must pay a higher
price for nonhousing goods and services. In contrast,
only the prospective home purchaser gains from the
subsidy on home construction or home financing.
It is true that the private sector makes errors in re­
source use. Here, however, the decision-maker suffers
a financial loss when resources are used inefficiently,
giving him great incentive to avoid waste. Obviously,
all individuals and firms do not have equal access to
credit markets, as access is determined in part by the
assets of the borrower. Nevertheless, lending is deter­
mined in part by the anticipated productivity of
capital. Furthermore, the market system minimizes
waste of scarce credit resources and thereby provides
more funds to all productive uses. In contrast, other
methods of allocation offer no assurance that efficient
use of credit will be achieved.

MAY 1971

to lower income groups. The well-being of the lower
income groups would be enhanced more by money
income than by the same amount of income diverted
to them in the form of housing subsidies. The subsidy
forces a pattern of consumption on these groups which
conforms to the authorities’ tastes, not the individual’s.
The value of this forced spending pattern to the in­
dividual is not as high as the value of an equal
amount of funds. It is, therefore, my conclusion that
efforts to improve the welfare of lower income groups
should be limited to direct transfers of funds rather
than providing particular goods and services. The
supposedly wasteful consumption patterns on the part
of some households are not a sufficient reason for a
government or central bank to alter these patterns.
Our own spending patterns may appear similarly un­
wise to others; any government edict altering our
consumption patterns detracts from our personal well­
being.

Controlling Financial Flows Difficult
In addition to the inefficiencies created by arbitrary
credit allocation, attempts to alter financial flows in
the past have been less than satisfactory. The recent
period, in which Federal Reserve Regulation Q and
other interest rate restrictions limited the yield on sav­
ings accounts, shows the complex nature of credit
allocation.3 While an objective of the restrictions was
to maintain low interest rates to home purchasers,
the reverse was closer to the actual result. Supply and
demand forces in financial markets were not given
sufficient consideration. The flow of savings through
financial intermediaries was retarded, as many savers
invested their savings at higher rates in other assets
not subject to the restrictions. This tended to reduce
the supply of funds to savings institutions — the major
suppliers of home mortgage credit. Mortgage loan de­
mand, however, rose as a result of rising total demand
caused by excessive money creation, and the rates
charged on new mortgages rose sharply. The restric­
tions actually diverted funds away from home mort­
gages and caused higher rates to home purchasers
than would have been charged had banks and savings
and loan associations been free to compete for de­
posits through interest rate adjustments.

Cash Payments Most Efficient for Welfare

The proposed variable reserve requirements on
bank assets may likewise yield unexpected results. As
in the case of Regulation Q, if these restrictions lead
to inefficiencies in banking, savings will bypass the

The allocation of goods and services through social
priorities is an inefficient means of providing welfare

3Charlotte E. Ruebling, “The Administration of Regulation
Q,” this Review (February 1970), pp. 29-40.




Page 11

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

commercial banking system. The nation’s larger busi­
ness firms have direct access to money markets if
banking efficiency in meeting their demands is im­
paired. Other credit agencies can offset bank credit
diverted from low priority consumer uses.
Commercial banks are only one of several agencies
which channel funds from savers to investors. Esti­
mates published by Bankers Trust Company, New
York, indicate that commercial banks supplied less
than 20 per cent of all investment funds raised in
1969 and only about 25 per cent of all short-term
funds raised.4 Of the total investment funds supplied,
both the contractual-type and the deposit-type sav­
ings institutions exceeded the quantity raised by com­
mercial banks. The contractual institutions, which in­
clude life insurance companies and private and gov­
ernment pension funds, raised an estimated $23 billion
—more than double the amount of such funds raised
by commercial banks.
Commercial banks likewise supplied a relatively
small portion of the short-term funds raised — only
$9.5 billion of the $38.6 billion total. All other savings
institutions supplied $6.4 billion. Almost two-thirds of
the total raised, $24.4 billion, was supplied by other
business corporations. Other investor groups such as
brokers, consumer lenders, and foreign investors were
net users of $1.7 billion of short-term funds. These
nonbank sources of investment funds may completely
offset efforts by the monetary authorities to enhance
credit flows to specific sectors.

Federal Reserve Should Concentrate On
Economic Stabilization
Finally, and probably more important, is the fact
that attempts by the central bank to stimulate or re­
tard activity in specific sectors may not be consistent
with the maintenance of appropriate monetary poli­
cies for economic stabilization. The Federal Reserve
System is eminently qualified to stabilize overall eco­
nomic activity, provided it is not hampered by exces­
sive duties and restrictions which have little in com­
mon with this overall objective. Once the System be­
comes excessively concerned with activity in individ­
ual sectors rather than with the economy as a whole,
its usefulness will be greatly impaired.®
4Bankers Trust Company, The Investment Outlook for 1971,
New York, 1971, pp. 10-11.
5For further discussion of this point, see a statement by Arthur
F. Burns, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, before the Subcommittee on Financial In­
stitutions of the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban
Affairs, United States Senate, March 31, 1971.

Page 12


MAY 1971

It is doubtful that the Federal Reserve can detect
the forces contributing to change in economic activity
in specific areas better than other market participants.
Some lines of activity decline because of changes in
basic supply or demand factors not associated with
financial impediments. Such factors are automatically
detected and acted upon in the marketplace, where
the appropriate resources are adjusted to meet the
changed conditions. Waste of resources is minimized
during the adjustment process. It has been my experi­
ence that the application of specific government pro­
grams to ease the burden of such adjustments has not
only been inefficient but has also prolonged the ad­
justment period unnecessarily. Our programs for agri­
culture are examples of such inefficiency. The Federal
Reserve is not likely to improve on this poor record
of other government agencies by attempting to alter
economic activity in specific sectors through credit
allocation.
The loss by some sectors of rights to equal access to
credit markets, like other restrictions on economic
activity, is a further unnecessary encroachment on
individual freedom. As indicated earlier, any social
action which channels funds to one sector of economic
activity reduces the volume of funds available for
other sectors. This loss of funds to sectors having
lower priority is an impingement on individual rights
to purchase savings at market prices.

Conclusion
In conclusion, the case for establishing high social
priorities for output in specific sectors of our competi­
tive private economy has been greatly overstated. The
use of legislative action to increase output in specific
sectors is a means of determining through collective
rather than individual decision-making what goods
and services will be produced. We can justify some
collective decision-making during national emergen­
cies on the basis that it is necessary for survival, but
the competitive market is a more efficient allocator of
resources most of the time.
Many suggestions for setting priorities on credit
flows have occurred during periods of high interest
rates or major depressions resulting from ill-advised
public policies. The maintenance of a fairly stable
rate of growth in the stock of money and removal of
useless regulations will permit the free-market system
to work effectively and alleviate most of the observed
problems.
This country’s record of performance in establishing
social priorities in the private sector has been less than

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

MAY 1971

successful. Our farm programs designed to correct the
alleged illness of income allocation are examples of
such failures. Earlier price support programs which
ignored basic supply and demand forces were fol­
lowed by more expanded programs to correct newly
observed problems. Like the proverbial punching bag
that expanded elsewhere when punched from the
front, each new regulation created another problem
that required new legislation. We still have not been
able to get the government out of agriculture, and
the expanded programs continue at great social cost.
Such regulations have been a factor in retarding our
farm export markets. They have reduced output in
both the farm and nonfarm sectors of the economy
and have been relatively ineffective in increasing re­
turns to individuals. Their proponents fail to recognize
that resources, including labor, adjust to income in­
centives in all sectors.

Finally, the Federal Reserve is not an appropriate
agency to be in charge of social priorities. The use of
such mechanisms as variable reserve rates on different
bank assets to alter credit flows increases the problem
of maintaining control over monetary aggregates. Con­
trol over these aggregates is essential for economic
stabilization. More important is the fact that attempts
to maintain economic health in specific sectors of the
economy will detract from the central bank’s overrid­
ing responsibility for appropriate stabilization policies
for the total economy.

To the extent that the authorities are successful in
altering credit flows and production patterns in the
private sector, they reduce national welfare. Produc­
tion based on collective decisions imposes a spending
pattern on the individual that is not compatible with
maximum want satisfaction. If an increase in the wel­
fare of the low income groups is the objective of such

If a stable rate of growth is achieved in total eco­
nomic activity, the freely functioning credit and cap­
ital markets will provide the most efficient allocation
of funds to specific sectors. It is through this route of
providing sufficient flows for an appropriate level of
total activity that the central bank can make its maxi­
mum contribution to national welfare.

actions, welfare can be purchased at a lower cost
through cash grants than through credit subsidies for
specific goods and services. With cash grants, each
person can obtain maximum want satisfaction for each
dollar spent. In contrast, subsidies of goods and serv­
ices impose the spending pattern of a group on the
individual.

REVIEW IN D EX — 1971
Month
of Issue

Title of Article

Jan.

Current Stabilization Policy
The Revised Money Stock: Explanation
and Illustrations
Expectations, Money, and the Stock Market

Feb.

Stabilization Policies and Employment
Operations o f the Federal Reserve Bank
o f St. Louis — 1970
Population, The Labor Force, and Potential
Output: Implications for the St. Louis
M odel

Mar.

Month
of Issue

Title of Article

Apr.

Monetary Aggregates and Recent
Economic Trends
Controlling Money in an Open
Economy: The German Case
Summary o f U.S. Balance o f Payments, 1970

May

The Economy: A Moderate Recovery
Social Priorities and the Market
Allocation o f Credit
The Year 1970: A Modest” Beginning
for Monetary Aggregates

Capital Markets and Interest Rates in 1970
T he 1971 National Economic Plan
The Implementation Problem o f Monetary
Policy




Page 13

The Year 1970 —A “Modest” Beginning
For Monetary Aggregates
by JERRY L. JORDAN and N EIL A. STEVENS

T

J AST YEAR marked a transition for the economy,
for the direction of monetary policies, and for the im­
plementation of these policies. At the beginning of
1970, the nation was suffering from the continuation
of inflation caused by the excesses of 1965 through
1968, as well as weakness in production resulting from
the corrective steps taken in 1969. Monetary policy­
makers were faced with the question of whether a
growth rate of total spending could be achieved
which would be conducive both to reduction of infla­
tion and to renewed growth in production.

In the first two meetings of 1970 the Federal Open
Market Committee,1 the primary monetary policy­
making group, decided to change the direction of its
policy by moving cautiously toward a less restrictive
policy. As the year 1970 progressed, real GNP de­
clined slightly, unemployment rose considerably, and
price increases tended to slow.2 Because of this slug­
gish performance of the economy, the Committee
pursued a more expansionary policy through the year.
The method of implementing the Committee’s pol­
icy decisions also was modified in 1970, compared to
the approach taken in the previous two decades. At
the January meeting, the Committee stated its desire
to have increased emphasis placed on achieving spe­
cific growth rates of certain monetary aggregates. The
amount of emphasis given to achieving growth targets
of the aggregates, however, varied considerably dur­
ing the year.

which is released to the public about 90 days after
each meeting.3 The records include the directive to
the New York Federal Reserve Bank, a summary of
information reviewed by the Committee members,
discussion of prevailing and prospective economic
conditions, and a summary of the discussion on policy
matters by the members.

PO LICY O BJECTIV ES AND T H EIR
IM PLEM ENTATION IN 1970
The Committee’s basic concern in the long run is
the performance of the economy in terms of produc­
tion, employment, prices, and the balance of pay­
ments. The variable over which the Committee has
direct control, the buying and selling of Government
securities, does not affect these ultimate objectives
direcdy. Open market operations, however, affect var­
ious monetary and financial variables, including the
money stock, bank credit, and market interest rates.
These variables, in turn, affect the spending decisions
of consumers and businesses, and ultimately influence
production, employment, prices, and the balance of
payments.

Interest Rates and Monetary Aggregates
In general, there are at least two broad views con­
cerning the manner in which Federal Reserve policy
actions are transmitted to the economy. Each view has
associated with it an indicator which measures the
thrust of monetary actions on the ultimate policy
goals.4 The first view emphasizes interest rates, and
the second emphasizes the money supply.

This article examines and summarizes the monetary
policy decisions of the Committee in 1970. The main
source of information is the “Record of Policy
Actions of the Federal Open Market Committee,”

The interest rate approach uses market interest
rates as the indicator of the effect of policy actions on

1The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) henceforth
will be referred to as the“Committee” in this article.
2See Norman N. Bowsher, “1970 —Economy in Transition,”
this Review (December 1970), pp. 2-13 for a review of eco­
nomic developments in 1970.

3A11 quotes in this paper are from these records unless speci­
fied otherwise.
4See Albert E. Burger, “The Implementation Problem of
Monetary Policy,” this Review (March 1971), pp. 20-30, for
a detailed discussion of the indicator problem.


Page 14


F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

ultimate objectives. In general, followers of this ap­
proach believe that Federal Reserve actions dominate
movements in interest rates, and that policy actions
are transmitted through interest rates to investment
and consumption expenditures, and thus the ultimate
policy objectives.
The Federal Reserve does not control interest rates
rigidly. Day-to-day open market operations are deter­
mined by looking at money market conditions, which
include such measures as free reserves, member bank
borrowings, the Federal funds rate, Treasury bill rates,
and the attitudes of major market participants. Using
these measures as “gauges,” the Federal Reserve can
affect the amount of “pressure” or “ease” in the mar­
ket, thereby influencing interest rates in the desired
direction.

MAY 1971

An alternative approach to economic stabilization
uses the money supply as the main indicator of the
thrust of policy actions on economic activity. Accord­
ing to this view, changes in the nation’s money stock
have a substantial influence on the growth of total
spending in the economy over a year or more. It is
contended that policy actions should be directed
towards maintaining relatively stable growth of the
money stock in order to achieve a long-run growth of
total spending which is consistent with full employ­
ment and stable prices.
Supporters of this view believe that changes in the
public’s demand for credit dominate movements in
market interest rates, and that the present demand
for credit is outside the direct control of the Federal
Reserve. It is held that current actions of the Federal

Federal Open Market Committee in 1970
The Federal Open Market Committee consists of the
seven members of the Federal Reserve Board of Gover­
nors, and five of the twelve Federal Reserve District
Bank Presidents. The Chairman of the Board of Gover­
nors is also, by tradition, Chairman of the Committee.
The President of the New York Federal Reserve Bank is
a permanent voting member of the Committee and is
its Vice-Chairman. All other Federal Reserve Bank Presi­
dents attend the meetings and present their views, but
votes may be cast by only four of these Presidents, who
serve as voting members for one-year terms on a rotation
basis.
At the first two meetings of 1970, the Committee in­
cluded the Governors and five Presidents: Mr. Hayes
(New York), Mr. Bopp (Philadelphia), Mr. Scanlon
(Chicago), Mr. Clay (Kansas City), Mr. Coldwell (Dal­
las). At the February meeting, Arthur F. Burns was
elected the new Chairman of -the Committee. Mr. Burns
had been appointed by President Nixon to the Board of
Governors to succeed Mr. Martin, effective February 1,
1970. At the March meeting, the four rotating positions
of the Committee were filled by new members who were
to serve one-year terms. The new members were the late
Mr. Hickman (Cleveland), Mr. Heflin (Richmond), Mr.
Francis (St. Louis), and Mr. Swan (San Francisco).
The Committee meets about every four weeks to dis­
cuss economic trends and to decide on open market opera­
tions. At these meetings they may discuss other possible
policy actions for subsequent weeks and months. During
1970, the Committee met thirteen times. At each of these
meetings, a directive was issued which stated the ultimate
goals of the Committee and provided general guidelines
"The Manager of the System Open Market Account may be
referred to as the “Account Manager” or “the Desk,” mean­
ing the Trading Desk of the New York Federal Reserve Bank.




as to how the Manager of the System Open Market Ac­
count” at the New York Federal Reserve Bank should
conduct open market operations to achieve these goals
(see Exhibit I). The first paragraph of each directive gave
a short review of economic data considered, and the
general economic goals sought by the Committee. The
second paragraph gave operating instructions to the Ac­
count Manager. These instructions were stated in terms of
money and short-term credit market conditions, growth
rates of monetary aggregates, and any special factors to be
taken into account, such as Treasury financing operations.
In previous years, the directive was stated in general
terms which provided an outline by which the Desk
should operate. In 1970, the Committee tended to specify
more precisely what the directive meant in quantitative
terms of variables such as monetary aggregates and
money market conditions. That is, the directive with
accompanying interpretations became more specific as
to the short-term guidelines the Account Manager was to
follow and targets he was to achieve.
The decisions on the timing and amount of daily buy­
ing and selling operations of securities in fulfilling the
Committee’s directive are the responsibility of the Account
Manager. Each morning, he and his staff decide on a
program for open market operations to be undertaken
that day. In developing this program, money and credit
market conditions and aggregate targets desired by the
Committee are considered as well as other factors which
may be of concern at that time. Each morning, the Ac­
count Manager places a conference call to staff members
of the Board of Governors and one voting President, to
give information about the present market conditions
and the market operations which he proposes to execute
that day. Other members of the Committee are informed
of the daily program by wire summary.

Page 15

Page 16

EXHIBIT I

FEDERAL OPEN MARKET COMMITTEE E C O N O M IC POLICY DIRECTIVES
D ate o f
FO M C
M e e tin g

Policy Consensus

Operating Instructions

Proviso Clause of Directive

J a n u a ry 15

In lig h t o f th e fo re g o in g d e ve lo p m e n ts, it
is th e p o lic y o f th e F e d e ra l O p e n M a rk e t C om ­
m itte e to fo s te r fin a n c ia l c o n d itio n s conducive
to th e o rd e rly re d u c tio n o f in fla tio n a ry pres­
sures, w ith a v ie w to e n c o u ra g in g s u s ta in a b le
econ o m ic
g ro w th
and
a tta in in g
re a so n a b le
e q u ilib riu m
in
th e
c o u n try 's
b a la n ce
of
p a ym e n ts.
D issents:
N on e

To im p le m e n t th is p o lic y , w h ile ta k in g accou n t o f
th e fo rth c o m in g T re a sury re fu n d in g , p o s s ib le b a n k re g ­
u la to ry changes a n d th e C o m m itte e ’s d e sire to see a
m odest g ro w th in m o ne y a n d b a n k c re d it, System o pen
m a rket o p e ra tio n s u n til th e n e x t m e e tin g o f th e C om m ittee
s h all be c o n d u cte d w ith a v ie w to m a in ta in in g firm co n ­
d itio n s in th e m one y m a rk e t;

p ro v id e d , h o w e v e r, th a t o p e ra tio n s s h a ll be m o d ifie d
i f m o ne y a n d b a n k c re d it a p p e a r to be d e v ia tin g
s ig n ific a n tly fro m c u rre n t p ro je c tio n s .

F e b ru a ry 10

N o C ha n g e
D issents:
M r. H ayes
M r. B rim m er
M r. C o ld w e ll

. . . w h ile ta k in g accou n t o f th e c u rre n t T re a sury re fu n d in g .
p ossible b a n k re g u la to ry ch an g e s a n d th e C o m m itte e ’s
desire to see m o d e ra te g ro w th in m o ne y a n d b a n k c re d it
o v e r th e m onths a h e a d . System o p e n m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s
u n til th e n e x t m e e tin g o f th e C o m m ittee sh a ll be c o n ­
ducted w ith a v ie w to m o vin g g r a d u a lly to w a rd s o m ew h a t
less firm c o n d itio n s in th e m one y m a rk e t;

p ro v id e d , h o w e v e r, th a t o p e ra tio n s s h a ll be m o d ifie d
p ro m p tly to re sist a n y te n d e n c y fo r m o ne y a n d b a n k
c re d it to d e v ia te s ig n ific a n tly fro m a m o d e ra te g ro w th
p a tte rn .

M a rc h

In lig h t o f th e fo re g o in g d e ve lo p m e n ts, it
is th e p o lic y o f th e F e d e ra l O p e n M a rk e t C om ­
m itte e to fo s te r fin a n c ia l c o n d itio n s co nd u cive to
o rd e rly re d u c tio n in th e ra te o f in fla tio n , w h ile
e n c o u ra g in g th e re s u m p tio n o f s u s ta in a b le eco­
n om ic g ro w th a n d th e a tta in m e n t o f re aso n a ble
e q u ilib riu m
in
th e
c o u n try 's
b a la n ce
of
p a ym e n ts.
D issents:
N one

. . . th e C om m ittee desires to see m o d e ra te g ro w th in
m oney a n d b a n k c re d it o v e r th e m onths a h e a d . System
open m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til th e n e x t m e e tin g o f th e
C om m ittee s h a ll be co nd u cte d w ith a v ie w to m a in ta in in g
m oney m a rk e t c o n d itio n s c o n s is te n t w ith th a t o b je c tiv e .

no p ro v is o clause

A p r il 7

N o C ha n g e
D issents:
N one

. . . th e C om m ittee desires to see m o d e ra te g ro w th in
m oney a n d b a n k c re d it o v e r th e m onths a h e a d . System
open m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til th e n e x t m e e tin g o f th e
C om m ittee s h a ll be co nd u cte d w ith a v ie w to m a in ta in in g
m oney m a rk e t c o n d itio n s c o n siste n t w ith th a t o b je c tiv e ,
ta k in g accou n t o f th e fo rth c o m in g T re a sury fin a n c in g .

no p ro v is o clause

M ay 5

N o C hange
D issents:
M r. Francis

. . . th e C o m m ittee desires to see m o d e ra te g ro w th in
m oney a n d b a n k c re d it o v e r th e m onths a h e a d . System
o pen m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til th e n e x t m e e tin g o f th e
C om m ittee s h a ll be c o n d u cte d w ith a v ie w to m a in ta in in g
b a n k reserves a n d m o ne y m a rk e t c o n d itio n s co nsiste n t
w ith th a t o b je c tiv e , ta k in g accou n t o f th e c u rre n t Tre a sury
fin a n c in g ;

p ro v id e d , h o w e v e r, th a t o p e ra tio n s s h a ll be m o d ifie d
as nee d e d to m o d e ra te excessive pressures in fin a n c ia l
m a rk e ts , s h o u ld th e y d e v e lo p .

M ay

N o C hange
D issents:
N on e

. . . in v ie w o f c u rre n t m a rk e t u n c e rta in tie s a n d liq u id ity
s tra in s , o p e n m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til th e n e x t m e e tin g o f
th e C om m ittee s h a ll be co nd u cte d w ith a v ie w to m o d e ra t­
in g pressures on fin a n c ia l m a rk e ts , w h ile , to th e e x te n t
co m p a tib le th e re w ith , m a in ta in in g
b a n k reserves a n d
m oney m a rk e t c o n d itio n s co n s is te n t w ith th e C om m ittee 's
lo n g e r-ru n o b je c tiv e s o f m o d e ra te g ro w th in m one y a n d
ban k c re d it.

no p ro v is o clause

10

26




June

23

Page 17

N o C hange
D issents:
N one

. . . in v ie w o f p e rs is tin g m a rk e t u n c e rta in tie s a n d liq u id ity
s tra in s , o pe n m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til th e n e x t m e etin g o f
th e C om m ittee s h a ll c o n tin u e to be co nd u cte d w ith a v ie w
to m o d e ra tin g pressures o n fin a n c ia l m a rkets. To th e e x ­
te n t c o m p a tib le th e re w ith , th e b a n k reserves a n d m o ne y
m a rk e t c o n d itio n s m a in ta in e d s h a ll be c o nsiste n t w ith
th e C o m m itte e ’s lo n g e r-ru n o b je c tiv e o f m o d e ra te g ro w th
in m o ne y a n d b a n k c re d it, ta k in g a ccou n t o f th e B o a rd 's
re g u la to ry a c tio n e ffe c tiv e Ju ne 24 a n d some p ossib le
co n s e q u e n t s h iftin g o f c re d it flo w s fro m m a rk e t to b a n k in g
ch an n e ls.

no p ro v is o clause

J u ly 21

N o C hange
D issents:
N one

. . . w h ile ta k in g a cco u n t o f p e rs is tin g m a rk e t u n c e rta in tie s ,
liq u id ity s tra in s , a n d th e fo rth c o m in g T re a s u ry fin a n c in g ,
th e C o m m ittee seeks to p ro m o te m o d e ra te g ro w th in
m one y a n d b a n k c re d it o v e r th e m onths a h e a d , a llo w in g
fo r a p o s s ib le c o n tin u e d s h ift o f c re d it flo w s fro m m a rk e t
to b a n k in g ch an n e ls. System o pen m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til
th e n e x t m e e tin g o f th e C om m ittee s h a ll be co nducted
w ith a v ie w to m a in ta in in g b a n k reserves a n d m o ne y
m a rk e t c o n d itio n s c o n siste n t w ith th a t o b je c tiv e ;

p ro v id e d , h o w e v e r, th a t o p e ra tio n s sh a ll be m o difie d
as n e e d e d to c o u n te r excessive pressures in fin a n c ia l
m a rkets sh o u ld th e y d e v e lo p .

August 1 8

N o C hange
D issents:
M r. H ayes
M r. Brim m er
M r. Francis

. . . th e C om m ittee seeks to p ro m o te some e a s in g o f
c o n d itio n s in c re d it m arkets a n d s o m e w h a t g re a te r g ro w th
in m o ne y o v e r th e m onths a h e a d th a n occurred in th e
second q u a rte r, w h ile ta k in g account o f p o s s ib le liq u id ity
p ro b le m s a n d a llo w in g b a n k c re d it g ro w th to re flect a n y
c o n tin u e d s h ift o f c re d it flo w s fro m m a rk e t to b a n k in g
c h a n n e ls . System o pe n m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til th e n e xt
m e e tin g o f th e C om m ittee s h a ll be c o n d u cte d w ith a v ie w
to m a in ta in in g b a n k reserves a n d m o ne y m a rk e t c o n d itio n s
c o n s is te n t w ith th a t o b je c tiv e , ta k in g accou n t o f th e effects
o f o th e r m o n e ta ry p o lic y action s.

no p ro v is o clause

S e p te m b e r 15

N o Change
D issents:
M r. H ayes

. . . th e C o m m ittee seeks to p rom o te some e asin g o f c o n ­
d itio n s in c re d it m arkets a n d m o d e ra te g ro w th in m one y
a n d a tte n d a n t b a n k c re d it e x p a n s io n o v e r th e m onths
a h e a d . System o pe n m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til th e n e xt
m e e tin g o f th e C o m m itte e s h a ll be c o n d u cte d w ith a v ie w
to m a in ta in in g b a n k reserves a n d m o ne y m a rk e t co n ­
d itio n s c o nsiste n t w ith th a t o b je c tiv e .

no p ro v is o clause

O c to b e r 2 0

N o C hange
D issents:
M r. H ayes

. . . th e C om m ittee seeks to p ro m o te some e a s in g o f
c o n d itio n s in c re d it m arkets a n d m o d e ra te g ro w th in
m o ne y a n d a tte n d a n t b a n k c re d it e x p a n s io n o v e r th e
m onths a h e a d . System o pe n m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til th e
n e x t m e e tin g o f th e C o m m ittee s h a ll be co nducted w ith a
v ie w to m a in ta in in g b a n k reserves a n d m one y m a rk e t
c o n d itio n s c o nsiste n t w ith those o b je c tiv e s , ta k in g accou n t
o f th e fo rth c o m in g T re a sury fin a n c in g s .

no p ro v is o clause

N o v e m b e r 17

N o C hange
D issents:
M r. M a is e l

. . . th e C om m ittee seeks to p ro m o te some e a s in g o f
c o n d itio n s in c re d it m arkets a n d m o d e ra te g ro w th in
m o n e y a n d a tte n d a n t b a n k c re d it e x p a n s io n o v e r th e
m onths a h e a d , w ith a llo w a n c e fo r te m p o ra ry s h ifts in
m o ne y a n d c re d it d e m a n d s re la te d to th e a u to s trik e .
System o pe n m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s u n til th e n e x t m e etin g o f
th e C o m m ittee s h a ll b e co nd u cte d w ith a v ie w to m a in ­
ta in in g b a n k reserves a n d m one y m a rk e t c o n d itio n s c o n ­
s is te n t w ith th o se o b je c tiv e s .

no p ro v is o clause

N o C hange
D isse n ts:
M r. Francis

. . . System o pe n m a rk e t o p e ra tio n s s h a ll be co nd u cte d
w ith a v ie w to m a in ta in in g th e re c e n tly a tta in e d m o n e y
m a rk e t c o n d itio n s u n til th e n e x t m e e tin g o f th e C o m m itte e ,

p ro v id e d th a t th e e xp e c te d rates o f g ro w th in m oney
a n d b a n k c re d it w ill a t le a s t be a chieved.

SOURCE: “ Record o f Policy Actions o f the Federal
Open Market C o m m itte eC u rr e n t
Economic Policy Directive




MAY 1971

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

Reserve influence the public’s future demand for
credit through its delayed influence on total spend­
ing. Such lagged effects of previous policy actions
result in current interest rates giving misleading infor­
mation about the effects of monetary actions on total
spending.
For instance, when an economic recovery is occur­
ring, rising interest rates reflect a growing demand for
credit, as business firms seek to expand productive
capacity and build inventories. If policymakers view
the rising interest rates as being restrictive, they may
attempt to direct open market operations to resist the
tightening of credit conditions, in order to stabilize or
slow the rise in interest rates. To accomplish this, re­
serves would have to be supplied at rapid rates, re­
sulting in an accelerating growth rate of the money
stock. After some time lag, the rapid growth in money
would induce further acceleration in growth of total
spending, resulting in inflation and even higher inter­
est rates as an inflation premium becomes built into
market interest rates.
Before 1970, the Committee followed more closely
the money market conditions approach of implement­
ing its policy decisions. In 1970, more emphasis was
placed on monetary aggregates. However, according
to an article in the February 1971 Federal Reserve
Bulletin, the increased emphasis on aggregates since
early 1970 “is consistent with a variety of economic
theories, and does not necessarily imply any particular
judgment as to the importance for the economy of
monetary flows relative to interest rates and credit
conditions or relative to other influences such as fiscal
policy and technological innovation.”5
In 1970, a hybrid approach was employed of con­
trolling money market conditions on a day-to-day
basis with a view to controlling monetary aggregates
over the longer term. According to this approach, the
growth of the demand deposit component of the
money stock can be influenced by appropriate adjust­
ment of money market pressures. The central idea is
that the demand for money is influenced by interest
rates as well as so-called transactions needs of the
public, and that money market pressures can be con­
trolled in such a way to achieve a desired growth of
deposits.
At the January 1970 meeting, the Committee ex­
plicitly stated its desire to have more importance
placed on achieving growth rates of monetary aggre­
gates when conducting open market operations. A
B“Monetary Aggregates and Money Market Conditions in Open
Market Policy,” Federal Reserve Bulletin (February 1971),
p. 86.

Page 18


principal change in the implementation of policy,
which accompanied the greater attention on mone­
tary aggregates, was that the Committee adopted a
somewhat longer horizon in specifying the desired
changes in policy variables. Specifically, quarterly
goals for money6 were set at the meeting preceding
each quarter and reviewed as the quarter progressed.
This longer time horizon allowed greater flexibility in
attaining the money and bank credit targets, while
avoiding excessive short-run fluctuations in interest
rates.

Modifying Objectives
Although the Committee put more emphasis on
achieving desired growth rates of monetary aggre­
gates, other short-run objectives were specified in
most directives, as was done in the past. In addition
to policy goals regarding production, prices, employ­
ment and the balance of payments, the Federal Re­
serve has generally assumed responsibility for main­
taining orderly and smoothly functioning money
markets. This responsibility is assumed, partly be­
cause orderly market conditions are considered desir­
able by some in order to successfully achieve the
objectives of the Committee. According to the Fed­
eral Reserve Bulletin, “the nation’s central bank has
a unique responsibility for maintenance of orderly
conditions”7 in the money market. One interpretation
of this objective is that disorderly markets might
develop in absence of the Federal Reserve’s efforts.
In accord with this self-imposed objective, empha­
sis on aggregates received secondary importance when
conflicts arose. For instance, at the late May meeting
and the June meeting, the Committee was largely
concerned with excessive pressures in credit markets,
and directed that open market operations be con­
ducted so as to moderate such conditions. Many
followers of the money supply approach, however,
believe that the Federal Reserve System can make its
greatest contribution toward avoiding disorderly mar­
ket conditions by keeping the growth of money in a
moderate range.
Most directives in 1970 also called for other items
to be taken into account as open market operations
were carried out. Five directives called for specific
consideration of either regulatory changes (Regula­
tions D and Q) or the shifts in funds from market to
banking channels caused by changing relationships be­
tween Regulation Q ceilings and market interest rates.
6Targets for bank credit were also given at some meetings,
but, in general, money was the dominant aggregate target.
7“Monetary Aggregates and Money Market Conditions in
Open Market Policy,” p. 94.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

During 1970, six directives called for the Account
Manager to consider “forthcoming” or “current” Treas­
ury financings. Historically, the Federal Reserve has
assumed some responsibility in keeping market con­
ditions conducive to the success of Treasury financings,
often referred to as “even-keel” operations. The objec­
tive of “even-keel” operations is to stabilize money
market conditions during the period between the
Treasury’s announcement of a security offering and
their sale, and thus to maintain an orderly and recep­
tive market for these securities. In effect, the Federal
Reserve may buy securities in the market while the
Treasury is selling. Particular emphasis was placed
on even-keel operations in late April and in May of
1970, “when it appeared that the Treasury’s cash
financing might be in jeopardy.”

MAY 1971

M o n ey Stock
R atio Scale
B illio n s o f D o lla rs
2 40
2 30

8Ibid., p. 94, for a rationale for continuing the use of money
market conditions. Also see Paul Meek and Rudolf Thunberg,
“Monetary Aggregates and Federal Reserve Open Market
Operations,” Monthly Review, Federal Reserve Bank of New
York (April 1971), pp. 80-89.
nFor a detailed explanation of the revision, see Albert E.
Burger and Jerry L. Jordan, “The Revised Money Stock:
Explanation and Illustrations,” this Review (January 1971),
pp. 6-15.
10Because of the revision, three money series are used in this
paper: old, revised, and roughly adjusted. Unless otherwise
specified, references to money will be the old series.



+12.)%/l
f i 221.2

220

+55% /

210

210

+3.0%^

6.0

Revised SeriesM

200

200
Old Series

+7
190

oj
190

>/ /
S'

180

Achieving Targets for Monetary Aggregates

Uncertainties surrounding a revision of the money
stock series caused difficulties for policymakers in
1970. In the latter half of 1970, it became known that
a measurement error arising from certain international
transactions was contained in the money series.9 The
revised series was available to the Committee in com­
pleted form at the November meeting, but at the
preceding two or three meetings, the Committee had
only a rough idea of the magnitude of the underesti­
mation of money growth indicated by the old money
series.10

230

220

170

In carrying out day-to-day open market operations
in 1970, the Desk relied mainly on money market con­
ditions.8 On a daily basis, the Desk concentrated
principally on the Federal funds rate, which was
thought to be consistent with the desired target
growth rates for the monetary aggregates. Ry main­
taining the Federal funds rate in a prespecified
range, an attempt was made to obtain the desired
growth of aggregates. This approach implies that the
quantity of securities purchased by the Desk is not as
important in influencing the near-term growth of
money as the effect of these actions on money market
conditions.

R atio Scale
B illion s o f D o lla rs
240

M o n th ly A v e ra g e s o f D a ily F ig u res

160

180

-o
<> -0.5%
Q.
<
t
1966

170

S.
0
c
0

0

1

.*
1967

1968

S fs
R k
♦
1969

160
1970

1971

jjjS e rie s p u b lis h e d p rio r to N o v e m b e r 19 70 .
b jT h e re vis ed series re flects a n n u a l revisions o f s e a s o n a l (ac to rs a n d b e n c h m ark
ad ju s tm en ts, as w e ll as m a jo r ad ju s tm en ts fo r a n u n d e re s tim a tio n o f th e o ld series
a ris in g fro m in te rn a tio n a l tran s ac tio n s .
P e rc e n ta g e s a r e a n n u a l rates of c h a n g e fo r p e rio d s in d ic a te d .
L atest d a t o p lo tte d : A p ril

Initially, it appeared that in the first three quarters
of 1970, money growth had been in the range desired
by the Committee, but the revised series indicated
that money had grown more rapidly than desired. For
instance, the old money series grew at a 4.4 per cent
annual rate dining the first three quarters of 1970,
compared with a 6.1 per cent rate for the revised
series. At the September meeting, some members ex­
pressed the view that “it would be desirable to place
less emphasis on a specific growth rate for the money
stock.”
The experience in 1970 suggests that some improve­
ment in technique may be needed in controlling ag­
gregates. The following bar chart shows actual growth
rates of money as measured by the old and revised
series, compared to that desired by the Committee in
the four quarters of 1970. Better control over mone­
tary aggregates might have been achieved by a more
direct method, such as by concentration on bank re­
serves or the monetary base, rather than the state of
money market conditions.

F E D ER A L OPEN MARKET
CO M M ITTEE DECISIONS IN 1970
This section presents a summary of the 1970 policy
decisions of the Committee. The discussion outlines
the economic data and forecasts available to the Com­
mittee at the time of each meeting and the policy de­
cisions at each meeting. The policy directives of the
Page 19

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

MAY 1971

F O M C ’s M oney Stock Targets
and Actual Rates Achieved
Per C e n t
1 0 1-----------

P er C e n t

A n n u a l R ates o f C h a n g e *

--------- 10

[ g g g j TARGET

9

9

j l H O L D M O N E Y SERIES (4th q tr. N .A .)
^ R E V I S E D M O N E Y SERIES

8

8
7

7
05

6

6

D

<

(C)

9-

5

Z

O

4

■

5
4
3

3
<

2

1 ----------- IV .V .V

1st q u a r te r

—-

TTdTq u a r te r

q u a r te r

m

q u a r te r

2
1

1970

N .A . — N o t a v a ila b le .
* Rates o f ch a n g e a re c a lc u la te d u sing th e le v e l in th e la s t m o n th o f a q u a rte r co m p a re d to th a t in th e la s t m o n th o f th e p re ce d in g
q u a rte r.
N o te : The “ Record o f P o lic y A c tio n s o f th e F e de ra l O p e n M a rk e t C o m m itte e ” fo r th e J a n u a ry m e e tin g d id n o t s p e c ify a m o n ey ta r g e t.
(A )

The e x a c t m o n ey ta rg e t w a s n o t s p e c ific a lly sta te d in th e “ R e c o r d ." H o w e v e r, p ro je c tio n s p re se n te d a t th is m e e tin g in d ic a te d a
g ro w th ra te o f 3 to 4 p e r ce nt “ i f p re v a ilin g m o n ey m a rk e t c o n d itio n s w e re m a in ta in e d ” a n d 4 to 5 p e r cent “ i f m o n ey m a r­
ke t c o n d itio n s w e re eased s o m e w h a t.” Since th e F e b ru a ry d ir e c tiv e a sked f o r e a s in g , p re s u m a b ly a b o u t a 4 p e r cent ta r g e t w as
d e s ire d b y th e C o m m itte e .

(B )

A t th is m e e tin g , p ro je c tio n s in d ic a te d

(C )

The C o m m itte e

(D )

The C o m m itte e w as w illin g

sta te d

th a t

it
to

o n ly a 2 p e r ce n t g ro w th ra te o f m oney in th e fir s t q u a rte r.

p re fe rre d
a ccep t 4

d e v ia tio n s

fro m

th is

p e r cent b ecause o f

ta r g e t to

Committee for 1970 can be divided into four periods.
January through April entailed the important decisions
to move toward more emphasis on monetary aggre­
gates in implementing monetary policy and to pursue
a more expansionary monetary policy than was sought
during 1969. May through July was characterized by
pressures in financial markets and subsequent subor­
dination of monetary aggregates in an effort to main­
tain money market conditions conducive to some eas­
ing of strained market conditions. From August
through November, the Committee reinstated target
growth ranges of monetary aggregates and, in addi­
tion, specifically called for some easing in money and
credit markets. In December, the Committee moved

Page 20


be on th e u p s id e .

w e a k c re d it d e m a n d s a t th e tim e , a ttrib u te d

to th e a u to

s trik e .

towards less emphasis on monetary aggregates and
more emphasis on money market conditions.

January through April:
Emphasis on Monetary Aggregates
The Committee gradually moved toward a more ex­
pansionary policy in this period. Many members were
concerned about a possible renewal of inflationary
expectations if easing came too fast or was too pro­
nounced. In addition to changing the direction of
monetary policy action, the Committee also stated its
desire to have more emphasis placed on monetary
aggregates in the formulation and implementation of
policy.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

MAY 1971

Economic Outlook and Policy Decisions
of the Committee
January 15 M eeting —Available data showed that
real GNP had not grown in the fourth quarter of 1969,
industrial production had fallen for five consecutive
months, and prices were still rising rapidly. Board of
Governors staff projections noted that prospects were
for “little change in real economic activity in early
1970.” The staff also projected that prices would con­
tinue to rise rapidly, with perhaps some moderation
as the year progressed. Some expansionary elements
were noted, including plans by businesses to increase
expenditures on new plant and equipment in 1970,
reduction of the income tax surcharge from 10 to 5
per cent on January 1 and its elimination on July 1,
and the 15 per cent increase in social security benefits
as of January 1.
Although the Committee was aware of the reduced
level of economic activity, it was “agreed that any
marked relaxation of monetary restraint would be pre­
mature at present in light of the persistence of infla­
tionary pressures and expectations.” The main con­
cerns of Committee members continued to be
inflation, and the need to show the public a willing­
ness to persist in its restrictive policies until there was
evidence that real progress against inflation was being
attained.
Staff projections suggested that there would be little
change in money and some decline in bank credit if
prevailing money market conditions and Regulation
Q ceilings were maintained. Members expressed con­
siderable concern over these prospects and disagreed
D e m a n d a n d Pro duction
R a tio S cale
T rillio n s o f D o lla rs

Quarterly Total* at Annual Rotes
Seasonally Adjusted

R a tio S e a l*
T rillio n s o f D o lla rs

1.1

1.0
.9

.8

.7

over the course of action that should be taken. Some
members wanted money market conditions to remain
“sufficiently firm to be consistent with a posture of
monetary restraint,” but “likely to be conducive to
modest growth in bank credit and the money stock
over the first quarter.” Other members wanted the
main emphasis put on a relaxation of Regulation Q,
and some favored “maintaining the prevailing condi­
tions in the money market.”
The final decision of the Committee was to place
increased emphasis on “the objective of achieving
modest growth in monetary aggregates” giving “about
equal weight” to bank credit and the money stock.
The Committee continued in a way similar to the
past, by directing that open market operations should
be conducted “with a view to maintaining firm condi­
tions in the money market.”11 The Committee also
added a proviso clause in the January directive, stat­
ing “that operations shall be modified if money and
bank credit appear to be deviating significantly from
current projections.” In view of the Committee’s de­
sire to pay more attention to aggregates, presumably
the proviso clause was to be invoked sooner and more
vigorously than in the past.
It was noted that the Board of Governors planned
to consider raising Regulation Q interest rate ceilings

IX G N P in current dollars.
(2 GNP in 1958 dollars.
Percentages are annual rotes of change for periods indicated.
Latest d a ta plotted: I st q u arter




Source: U.S Department of Commerce

11Presumably, firm conditions did not mean prevailing con­
ditions, but some slight easing, since the staff had projected
no growth in money and a decline in bank credit if prevail­
ing money market conditions were maintained. But most
members were apparently unwilling to specify an actual
easing of market conditions in the directive at this time
because of the continued rapid rise in prices.
Page 21

FEDERAL

Page 22

RESERVE

EXHIBIT II

M A JO R FEDERAL RESERVE ACTIO NS OTHER THAN OPEN MARKET OPERATIONS IN 1970

BANK
OF

Nature of Action

Effect of Action

J a n u a ry 2 0

The B o a rd o f G o ve rn o rs ra is e d m axim um in te re s t ra te s p a y a b le on

This a c tio n a llo w e d s a v in g fu n d s to re -e n te r b a n k in g c h a n n e ls , thus

(E ffe c tiv e J a n u a ry 21 )

tim e a n d savings d ep o sits

e n c o u ra g in g

Date of Announcement

ST.

g ro w th

o f m ore

b ro a d ly

d e fin e d

a g g re g a te s

such

as

L O U IS

(R e g u la tio n Q ) .

b a n k c re d it a n d m o ne y stock plus tim e d e p o sits.
J u n e 23

The B o a rd o f G o ve rn o rs suspended R e g u la tio n Q c e ilin g s on la rg e

(E ffe c tiv e J u n e 2 4 )

ce rtific a te s o f d e p o s it a n d o th e r s in g le -m a tu rity tim e d e p o s its o f 3 0 -

This a c tio n w as ta k e n b y th e B oard in a n e ffo rt to a llo w b an ks to be
in a p o s itio n to accom m o d a te business custom ers u n a b le to o b ta in

to 8 9 - d a y m a tu ritie s .

fu n d s in th e co m m ercia l p a p e r m a rk e t, w hich a t th e tim e w as und e r
stress. The e ffe c t w as to e n c o u ra g e g ro w th o f la rg e CD ’s.

A u g u s t 17

The B o a rd o f G o ve rn ors p la ce d reserve re q u ire m e n ts (R e g u la tio n D)

By these a c tio n s , la rg e c e rtific a te s o f d e p o s it a n d fu n d s o b ta in e d

(E ffe c tiv e in th e reserve c o m p u ta ­

on fu n d s o b ta in e d b y m em ber b an ks th ro u g h th e issuance o f co m ­

b y b a n k s th ro u g h issuance o f co m m ercia l p a p e r b y th e ir a ffilia te s

tio n

m e rcia l p a p e r b y th e ir a ffilia te s .

w ere p la c e d o n e q u a l term s. S u b s e q u e n tly , b a n k -re la te d com m ercial

p e rio d b e g in n in g O c to b e r 1)

The B oa rd a ls o re du ce d

reserve

re q u ire m e n ts fro m 6 to 5 p e r cent on tim e d e p o s tis in excess o f $ 5

p a p e r d e c lin e d r a p id ly .

m illio n .
N o v e m b e r 10

The B o a rd o f G o ve rn o rs a p p ro v e d a re d u c tio n in th e d is c o u n t ra te

This

(E ffe c tiv e a t a ll Reserve Banks b y

b y Reserve Banks fro m 6 to 5 % per cent.

m a rk e t rates w h ic h h a d fa lle n s u b s ta n tia lly .

N ovem ber 30

The B o a rd o f G o ve rn o rs a p p ro v e d a n o th e r re d u c tio n in th e d is c o u n t

This

(E ffe c tiv e a t a ll Reserve Banks b y

ra te b y Reserve Banks fro m 5 %

to 5 %

r a p id ly fa llin g s h o rt-te rm in te re s t rates.

The B o a rd

reserve re q u ire m e n ts fro m

a c tio n

b ro u g h t th e

d is c o u n t

ra te

in to

c lose r a lig n m e n t w ith

N ovem ber 16)

p e r cent.

a c tio n

a ls o b r o u g h t th e

d is c o u n t ra te

m ore

in

lin e

w ith

the

D ecem ber 1 1)

N ovem ber 30
(E ffe c tiv e

in

th e

4 -w e e k

reserve

c o m p u ta tio n p e rio d e n d in g D ecem ­

ce n t

to

20

o f G o ve rn o rs ra ise d
per

cent

“ re s e rv e -fre e ” base.

on

E u ro d o lla r

b o rro w in g s

th a t

10

per

exceed

the

The a c tio n w as in te n d e d to h e lp th e b a la n c e o f p a y m e n ts b y d is ­
c o u ra g in g

b an ks fro m

re d u c in g

th e ir

E u ro d o lla r b o rro w in g s

b e lo w

th e ir re s e rv e -fre e base.

ber 2 3)

MAY
1971




F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

MAY 1971

soon. Effective January 21, 1970, the Board raised
ceilings on time and savings deposits. The effect of
this change was to encourage growth in bank credit
and other broadly defined aggregates (see Exhibit
I I). In 1969, disintermediation of time deposits from
banks as well as other financial intermediaries had
occurred as market interest rates rose above Regula­
tion Q ceilings. Most of these funds were simply
channeled to other market instruments, such as com­
mercial paper, and to that extent did not affect total
credit in the economy. The increase in Regulation Q
ceiling rates encouraged a rechanneling of funds back
into banks. This outflow and inflow of time deposits
during 1969 and 1970, however, distorted the growth
rates of broadly defined aggregates such as money
stock plus net time deposits, making interpretation of
these series less meaningful as indicators of monetary
influences.
February 10 M eeting — Evidence of further weak­
ening in the economy was presented, although it was
expected that some real growth would occur in the
second half of the year. Weakness in the labor market
was becoming evident, as unemployment rose from
3.5 per cent in December 1969 to 3.9 per cent in
January 1970.
The Committee agreed that “it was appropriate to
move gradually toward somewhat less restraint at this
time.” The directive issued to the Desk called for both
“moderate growth in money and bank credit over the

months ahead” and “somewhat less firm conditions in
the money market.” The word “moderate” meant a
faster rate of growth for aggregates than the “modest”
growth called for at the January meeting.
Three members of the Committee, Mr. Hayes, Mr.
Brimmer, and Mr. Coldwell, dissented from the Feb­
ruary directive. They believed that “any overt move
toward less firm money market conditions was pre­
mature at this time and could strengthen market ex­
pectations of substantial easing.” They stressed the
continuing inflationary pressures, business plans for
large volume capital spending, and the prospectively
large balance-of-payments deficit. Although they
agreed that some growth in money and credit was de­
sirable, they preferred a directive similar to Janu­
ary’s which called for “firm” money market conditions
along with some growth in aggregates.
M arch 10 and April 7 M eetings — At these meet­
ings, important changes in the wording of the direc­
tive were made, clarifying the meaning of the new
attention to aggregates. Although the earlier directives
of 1970 gave increased importance to the money
stock and bank credit, they continued to be stated in
terms of money market conditions, with an appended
proviso clause regarding the aggregates. In the March
and April meetings, an objective with respect to
money market conditions was not specified in the
directives. Rather, the wording of these directives in­
dicated a willingness on the part of the Committee to

E m p lo y m e n t a n d U n e m p lo y m e n t

Latest doto plotted: A pril




Sources: U.S. Deportment of Labor and U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census

Page 23

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

MAY 1971

Selected Short-Term Interest Rates
P er C e n t

Per C e n t

S o u rc e : B o a rd o f G o v e r n o r s o f th e F e d e ra l R es e rv e S y s te m
[ ^ W e e k ly a v e ra g e s o f d a ily fig u re s .
L a te s t d a t a p lo tt e d : M a y 14

allow money market conditions to fluctuate if neces­
sary, in order to attain desired money and bank
credit growth targets. The March directive stated:
. . . the Committee desires to see moderate growth
in money and bank credit over the months ahead.
System open market operations until the next meet­
ing of the Committee shall be conducted with a view
to maintaining money market conditions consistent
with that objective.

Page 24


The growth targets for the money stock at the
March meeting called for a 2 per cent annual growth
rate in the first quarter (December 1969 to March),
and a 3 per cent rate in the second quarter ( March to
June). At the April meeting, a 3 per cent growth tar­
get for the money stock was reaffirmed as the appro­
priate rate for the second quarter.

FEDERAL. R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

MAY 1971

Yields on Selected Securities
P er C e n t

Per C en t

S o u rce : B o a rd o f G o v e rn o rs o f th e F e d e ra l R eserve S ystem a n d M o o d y 's In v e s to rs S e rv ic e
t l W e e k l y a v e ra g e s o f d a ily fig u re s .
[2 T h u r s d a y fig u re s .
L a te st d a ta p lo tte d : S ta te a n d L o c a l - M a y 7 ; O th e r s - M a y 14

Although as a whole the Committee showed in­
creased willingness to let money market conditions
fluctuate in achieving aggregate targets, some mem­
bers at the April meeting expressed concern about the
possibility of wide fluctuations in money market con­
ditions. It was noted that “precise achievement” of
targets for growth of monetary aggregates “could not
be expected, in part because of the desirability of
avoiding excessive fluctuations in money market con­
ditions and in part because of uncertainties regarding
future relationships among financial variables.” This
view is in keeping with the February 1971 Bulletin
article:

Money market conditions, measured by movements in
short-term interest rates, eased on balance from January
through April, as some growth in monetary aggregates
was sought. The monetary base, the main determinant
of the growth trend of the money stock, grew at a 6.7
per cent annual rate from December 1969 to April

. . . whatever longer-run path for the aggregates may
be included as guidance for open market operations,

12“Monetary Aggregates and Money Market Conditions in
Open Market Policy,” p. 80.




short-run, self-correcting variations in money and
credit demands need to be accommodated in order
to avoid inducing unnecessary, and possibly desta­
bilizing, fluctuations in money market conditions.12

Money Market Developments
and Monetary Aggregates

Page 25

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

1970. The money stock grew slowly in the first part
of this period, but grew very rapidly in late March
and in April. On balance in the period, money grew
at a 5.7 per cent annual rate from December 1969 to
April 1970.
Analysis given at the March meeting indicated that
further easing actions would be necessary to achieve
even a 2 per cent rate of growth of money in the first
quarter and a desired 3 per cent rate in the second
quarter. Money market conditions eased further af­
ter the March meeting, and staff projections showed
that growth rates of aggregates were falling short of
the Committee’s desired rates. Later in the month,
estimates of money growth were revised upwards,
and the Committee no longer sought easing of money
market conditions to promote growth of money. The
money stock jumped sharply upward in the last week
of March, due to technical factors involving a four-day
Easter holiday abroad. With this bulge, money grew
at a 3.9 per cent rate in the first quarter (December
to March), almost double the expected 2 per cent
rate at the time of the March meeting and higher
than the 3 per cent rate desired by the Committee for
the second quarter.
The Committee thus showed considerable concern
for the achievement of the growth targets for mone­
tary aggregates in early 1970, especially the money
stock. This commitment was principally characteristic
of the March and April meetings, when directives
stated that money market conditions were to be con­
sistent with the growth targets for aggregates.
Whether individual members of the Committee pre­
ferred a given money target because they agreed
with the underlying money market condition associ­
ated with the target, or vice versa, is difficult to assess.
The Committee was willing, however, to accept firmer
conditions in late March and April in order to hold
down the growth of money when projections indicated
money was growing rapidly. As noted earlier, how­
ever, the Committee evidently was not willing to
pursue a given quarterly target independent of the
money market conditions that might be implied by
the actions required to achieve the aggregate target.

May through July: Emphasis on
Moderating Pressure in Money
and Credit Markets
During this period, there was considerable concern
by members of the Committee about pressures in the
money markets and a possible liquidity crisis. Follow­
ing the late May and June meetings, open market

Page 26


MAY 1971

operations were aimed primarily at dealing with the
unsettled atmosphere in the money and credit mar­
kets, and less emphasis was placed on achieving
targets for monetary aggregates.

Economic Outlook and Policy Decisions
May 5 M eeting — Preliminary Commerce Depart­
ment estimates indicated a decline in real GNP for
the first quarter. Projections suggested little real
economic growth in the second quarter, but some
renewed growth in the second half of 1970. It was
noted at this meeting that prices continued to rise,
although there were some moderating tendencies.
The unemployment rate continued upward, reaching
4.8 per cent in April.
The unsettled condition of financial markets was
also noted at this meeting. Most interest rates had
risen from the April to May 5 meeting, counter to the
general expectation of many market participants.
Also, common stock market prices fell sharply in
April and continued to fall in May.
Apparentiy, many factors contributed to the interest
rate increases. Factors cited at the May 5 meeting
included concern by market participants about the
prospects for success of the Government’s anti-infla­
tionary program, the Cambodian military operations,
and the unusually heavy demand for funds in the
capital market. Rising interest rates appeared to be
particularly unsettling due to the general expectation
that continued declines in interest rates would ac­
company the slowdown in economic activity.
In light of these various developments, and in view
of the fact that money was growing more rapidly
than previously projected and that attempts to main­
tain the 3 per cent growth target for money might
have undesired consequences, the Committee in­
creased its second quarter growth target for money to
4 per cent. The staff analysis indicated that this rate
could be achieved “with money market conditions
similar to or slightly firmer than those currently pre­
vailing.” The Committee felt that the “demand for
money” was greater than was thought earlier.13 Ac­
cording to a recent Federal Reserve report, “while
anxieties in financial circles that a general liquidity
squeeze was emerging proved to be clearly exagger­
ated, it is true nonetheless that their net effect
was to cause a sharp increase in over-all demand for
liquidity.”14
i:iIn this context, demand for credit is implied, rather than
demand for money. The ambiguity is widely discussed in
economic literature.
l4Federal Reserve Board of Governors, The U.S. Economy in
Transition — A Prelude to the Annual Report for 1970, p. 18.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

The operating clause of the early May directive
was quite similar to that of the previous month, ex­
cept a proviso clause was added which stated:
. . . that operations shall be modified as needed to
moderate excessive pressures in financial markets,
should they develop.

Mr. Francis dissented from the decision to accept
the faster target rate of growth in money. He argued
that a 4 per cent annual rate in the second quarter
would imply a 6 per cent rate from February to June,
and he considered such a rate excessive.
May 26 M eeting — It was observed that revised
Commerce Department figures for real GNP showed
a decline at a 3 per cent annual rate in the first quar­
ter of 1970. Real GNP was still expected to rise in the
second half of 1970, although not as much as previ­
ously expected, with projections indicating no growth
in the second quarter.
Uncertainties and strains surrounding the “liquidity
crisis” continued to be primary concerns of the Com­
mittee at the late May meeting. The Committee
stated a desire to see moderate growth in money and
bank credit, but priority was to be given to the objec­
tive of moderating pressures in financial markets. The
Committee acknowledged that this might bring a
higher growth rate of money than the 4 per cent con­
sidered appropriate as the long-run objective. Projec­
tions indicated a 7 per cent rate of growth of money
was likely in the second quarter, compared with an
earlier target of 3 per cent, and indicated firmer
money market conditions would develop if an effort
were made to hit the 4 per cent target of the
Committee.
June 23 M eeting — Financial markets were reported
to have “calmed considerably” immediately following
the May 26 meeting, and interest rates on many
short-term instruments were tending to move down­
ward. Long-term rates, however, continued to move
upward, many reaching their 1970 peaks in June.
New uncertainties were introduced into financial mar­
kets by the insolvency of the Penn Central Railroad,
which caused the commercial paper market to be
particularly sensitive. Yields on commercial paper
tended to rise, as investors became more selective and
aware of the risks involved in such paper.
In view of the uncertainties and strains in financial
markets, the Committee again directed that open mar­
ket operations be carried out with the objective of
moderating these pressures. Analysis indicated growth



MAY 1971

of money at about a 5 per cent annual rate from June
to September, assuming prevailing money market con­
ditions were maintained. The Committee directed
that to the extent possible this growth rate should be
achieved while at the same time moderating market
pressures. Thus, the target growth rate of money was
increased from the 3 and 4 per cent rates targeted
earlier in the year.
In addition to the actions taken by the Committee,
two other actions were taken by the Federal Reserve.
On the same day as the June Committee meeting, the
Board of Governors suspended Regulation Q ceilings
on 30- to 89-day maturity CD’s and other single-maturity time deposits of $100,000 or more. Also, in late
June the administration of the discount window was
temporarily relaxed, in order to accommodate banks
which were lending to firms having difficulty in ob­
taining financing in the commercial paper market.
July 21 M eeting — Preliminary Commerce Depart­
ment figures indicated that real GNP had increased
only slightly in the second quarter, but projections
continued to suggest that real GNP would pick up in
the second half of 1970. Data for June showed that
industrial production had declined further, but retail
sales and housing starts had risen. The unemploy­
ment rate had declined to 4.7 per cent in June, from
5 per cent in May.
In view of the declining market interest rates, the
Committee decided to place less emphasis on mod­
erating market pressures and more emphasis on
achieving the targets for monetary aggregates. The
Committee agreed that a 5 per cent rate of growth in
money remained the appropriate target for the third
quarter (from June to September), but stated that if
deviations from this target rate developed, they should
be on the upside. The wording of the operating clause
of the July directive was similar to the May 5 direc­
tive, calling for open market operations to be carried
out to achieve growth targets for aggregates, but
added a proviso clause that open market operations
should be modified if financial pressures developed.

Money Market Conditions and
Monetary Aggregates
From April through July, the money stock (old
series) increased at a 2 per cent annual rate, while
the adjusted bank credit proxy increased at an 8 per
cent rate. The latter series was heavily influenced by
the reintermediation of time deposits into banks. The
monetary base grew at a 5.6 per cent rate in this
Page 27

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

M onetary B ase a n d Federal Reserve Credit

MAY 1971

In general, the directives in this period called for a
dual policy objective of both “some easing of condi­
tions in credit markets” and “moderate growth in
money and attendant bank credit expansion.”
Easing in credit markets was sought during this pe­
riod because members of the Committee were con­
cerned about the lack of decline in long-term interest
rates. These members felt that it was desirable to
have long-term rates decline in order to encourage
recovery of residential construction and state and lo­
cal government spending. In general, the instructions
in the directives were as follows:
. . . the Committee seeks to promote some easing of
conditions in credit markets and moderate growth in
money and attendant bank credit expansion over the
months ahead. System open market operations until
the next meeting of the Committee shall be con­
ducted with a view to maintaining bank reserves and
market conditions consistent with those objectives. . .

Q.Uses o f the m o n etary b as e a r e m e m b e r b an k reserves an d currency h eld b y th e p u b lic
a n d n onm em ber banks. A djustm ents a r e m a d e fo r reserve requirem ent changes a n d
shifts in d ep o s its a m o n g classes of banks. D a ta a r e com p u ted b y this bank.
[2 Total Federal R eserve c red it o u ts tan d in g includes holdings o f securities, loans, flo a t, a n d
" o th e r" assets. Adjustm ents a re m a d e fo r reserve re q u ire m e n t ch an g es a n d shifts in
deposits am ong classes o f b an k s. D a ta a re com puted b y this bank.
P e rc e n ta g e s a r e a n n u a l ra te s o f c h a n g e fo r p e rio d s in d ic a te d .
L ates t d a t a p lo tte d : A p ril

period. The substantially slower growth of money
than the base is attributable largely to the rapid
growth of time deposits. This rapid reintermediation
of time deposit funds into banks absorbed reserves
which otherwise could have supported an expansion
in demand deposits. In general, short-term rates rose
in April and May and tended to fall in June and July.
Open market operations were aimed primarily at
moderating pressures in financial markets following
the May 26 and June 23 meetings. Although at the
time of the May 26 meeting a 7 per cent rate of
growth in money was expected in the second quarter,
the old series grew at a 4.2 per cent rate, close to the
4 per cent target desired (the revised data released
in late November indicated the growth of money in
this period was at about a 6 per cent annual rate).

August through November:
Easing in Money and Credit Markets
In the four meetings from August 18 through No­
vember 17, the emphasis on moderating money mar­
ket pressures was reduced, and longer-run objectives
in terms of growth in aggregates were re-established.

Page 28


At times, these dual policy objectives could be in
conflict with one another, but, in practice, they were
not generally in conflict over this period. The de­
mands for credit in the private economy continued
to ease as the pace of economic activity continued
to slow, at least partly in response to restrictive
actions of late 1969.

Economic Outlook and Policy Decisions
August 18 M eeting —Projections for real GNP re­
mained much the same in August as in July; that is,
for some increase in real GNP in the second half of
1970, although below potential. It was noted that
prices were still rising rapidly, but not as fast as
earlier.
The money stock was expected to grow at an an­
nual rate of about 4 per cent over the third quarter,
if prevailing money market conditions were main­
tained, and more easing in money markets was be­
lieved needed to achieve a 5 per cent rate of growth
in money. In the discussion by members of the
Committee, an abatement of expectations of continu­
ing inflation was noted, and it was agreed that policy
should be directed at stimulating real growth of the
economy, while at the same time being careful not to
revive inflationary expectations. To stimulate real
growth, the Committee directed open market opera­
tions to promote some easing in credit markets and to
seek growth in the money stock at about a 5 per cent
annual rate. As in the July directive, the Committee
stated that it preferred deviations from this target to
be on the upside.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

Three members, Mr. Hayes, Mr. Brimmer, and
Mr. Francis, dissented from this directive. They dis­
sented primarily because “they were opposed to the
promotion of ‘some easing of conditions in credit
markets’ as a specific objective of Committee policy
at this time.” They considered this easing unnecessary
to expand economic activity and involving “risk of
rekindling inflationary expectations.”
S eptem ber 15 M eeting —At this meeting the Com­
mittee was informed that the money stock series con­
tained a definite bias. Board of Governors staff
analysis indicated that further easing of money mar­
ket conditions would be necessary in order for the
money stock (roughly adjusted for bias) to grow
at an annual rate of 5 per cent in the fourth quarter.
The Committee decided that a 5 per cent growth in
money and some easing in credit markets remained
appropriate objectives for monetary policy in the
fourth quarter.
Some members felt money should grow somewhat
faster than 5 per cent, while others felt that the money
series should be de-emphasized at this time, in part
due to the uncertainties relating to the forthcoming
revision of the money stock series. Some members
preferred that bank credit be given more weight, be­
lieving that reintermediation was about over. How­
ever, it was decided that for the present, “prepon­
derant weight” should be given to the money stock
“in assaying the implications of the behavior of finan­
cial aggregates for System operating decisions.”
Mr. Hayes dissented from the directive, and ex­
pressed concern about again aiming toward “an easing
of conditions in credit markets.” He noted that inter­
est rates had already fallen and “was not convinced
that further easing would be required to achieve the
objective . . . of moderate growth in money and bank
credit.” He also expressed concern over “the possible
inflationary effects of a policy calling for progressive
easing of credit conditions.”
O ctober 20 M eeting — A rise in real GNP at a 1.4
per cent annual rate for the third quarter was indi­
cated by preliminary Commerce Department figures.
Also in September, there had been a fall in industrial
production which was attributed primarily to the au­
tomobile strike. Unemployment had advanced in
September to 5.5 per cent from 5.1 per cent in Au­
gust. Real GNP was projected to move up slightly in
the fourth quarter, but the auto strike clouded most
statistics at the time.



MAY 1971

Analysis presented indicated that if money market
conditions similar to those recently prevailing were
maintained, the money series (roughly adjusted)
would grow at about a 5 per cent annual rate over
the fourth quarter (from September to December).
The Committee agreed that this remained an appro­
priate target, accompanied by some easing in credit
market conditions. As at the previous meeting, some
members expressed a desire for a faster growth rate
of money, while others wanted less emphasis given to
achieving money growth targets.
Mr. Hayes again dissented for essentially the same
reasons as the previous meeting. He did not disagree
with a 5 per cent growth rate in money, but “he was
concerned about the directive language reading ‘the
Committee seeks to promote some easing of condi­
tions in credit markets,’ because it implied to him
that a persistent push toward lower interest rates was
intended, irrespective of market forces. Such a course,
in his view, would involve undue risks of rekindling
inflationary expectations and of weakening the inter­
national position of the dollar.”
Substantial declines in short-term market interest
rates had occurred so far in 1970, reflecting the weak­
ness in demand for credit relative to supply. In re­
sponse to similar supply and demand forces, the
prime rate, the interest rate charged by banks on
loans to their best business customers, had been re­
duced from 8 per cent to 7% per cent on September
21. On November 11 and succeeding days, the Fed­
eral Reserve Banks reduced their discount rate from
6 per cent to 5% per cent. On November 12, the
prime bank loan rate was reduced to 7% per cent, and
only two weeks later was reduced to 7 per cent.
N ovem ber 17 M eeting — Board of Governors staff
projections reviewed by the Committee indicated that
real GNP would not grow in the fourth quarter, and
data for October showed a decline in retail sales and
industrial production, while the unemployment rose
further. The weaknesses in economic activity were at
least partially caused by the automobile industry
strike. Projections suggested a rebound in economic
activity in the first quarter of 1971, assuming an end
to the strike in the near future.
The money stock rose only slightly (revised series)
in October, and analysis given at the November meet­
ing indicated that further easing of money markets
conditions would be necessary if even a 4 per cent
rate of growth in money was sought in the fourth
Page 29

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

quarter.15 This shortfall below the 5 per cent target
growth of money desired by the Committee was at­
tributed to weakness in the demand for money and
credit, mostly associated with the auto strike. Again,
the view prevailed that the dem and for money, or the
“transactions needs” of the nonbank public, determines
the growth of the money stock. This view appears to
attribute relatively little significance to growth of
bank reserves or the monetary base in the determina­
tion of the growth of money, even over a period of
three or four months.
The Committee agreed that some further easing
of credit and moderate growth in money remained
appropriate targets, but felt that the actions that
might be necessary in order to achieve a 5 per cent
growth in money in both the fourth quarter of 1970
and the first quarter of 1971 could result in unde­
sirable fluctuations in money and credit market condi­
tions. The consensus of the Committee members was
that a “4 per cent growth rate in the fourth quarter
would be acceptable if the results of operating experi­
ence over coming weeks bore out the indication of
the staff analysis that attainment of a 5 per cent rate
would require a sharp easing of money market condi­
tions.” This decision was made with the expectation
that money would grow faster in the first quarter of
1971.
Mr. Maisel dissented from this directive because he
favored growth of money in the fourth quarter “at
least as high as the rate that had prevailed on the
average in the first three quarters of the year.” Thus,
he favored growth in money at about a 6 per cent
annual rate, whereas the Committee was willing to ac­
cept a 4 per cent rate of growth in the fourth quarter.

Money Market Conditions and
Monetary Aggregates
The money stock (revised series) grew at a 4.6 per
cent annual rate from July to November, and the
monetary base increased at a 4.2 per cent annual
rate. Both short-term and long-term interest rates de­
clined considerably during these months. For exam­
ple, three-month Treasury bills fell from about 6.45
per cent in July to about 5.3 per cent in November,
and yields on corporate Aaa bonds declined from 8.44
per cent to 8.05 per cent.
Following the August and September meetings, open
market operations were aimed at easing credit mar­
kets and achieving moderate growth in money. Short­
term interest rates fell somewhat during this period,
15Revision of the money series had been completed and was
available to members at the November meeting.

Page 30


MAY 1971

but yields on corporate and municipal bonds declined
only slightly. At the mid-September meeting, a 4.5
per cent growth rate of money (old series) was ex­
pected for the third quarter (June to September),16
but a 5.2 per cent rate was obtained, close to the 5 per
cent target desired. The revised money series grew at
a 6.2 per cent rate in the third quarter.
Growth of the money stock fell short of expecta­
tions in October and November. Projections had indi­
cated an increase at a 4.5 per cent rate in October
(roughly adjusted series), while the actual rate was
about 1 per cent ( revised series). The shortfall was
attributed to the weakness in credit demand associ­
ated with the automobile strike and slow business
activity.
The Federal funds rate dropped sharply in this
period; however, by observing the monetary base it
is evident that the slow growth in money is attribu­
table to the small increase in the monetary base in
October and November. The base grew at only a 2 per
cent annual rate in these two months.
Following the November meeting, easier money
market conditions were sought in order to promote
easing in credit markets and growth of money. Part
of open market purchases were made in intermediateand long-term securities, which tend to lower longerterm interest rates. Both short-term and long-term
interest rates fell substantially between the November
and December meetings.
16About 1 percentage point less was expected for the roughly
adjusted series, that is, 3.5 per cent.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

December: Less Emphasis on Aggregates
Less emphasis on aggregates prevailed during the
December 15 meeting. The summary of discussion
said, “the outlook for the monetary aggregates was
particularly uncertain at this time, both because of
the difficulties of assessing the precise impact on fi­
nancial markets of the surge in activity expected in
the aftermath of the automobile strike and because of
the churning in those markets that is typical of the
period around the year-end.” In view of these uncer­
tainties, a number of Committee members suggested
that less weight be given to aggregates and more to
money market conditions.
The status of monetary aggregates as indicators of
monetary policy actions was somewhat unclear at this
juncture. Some members favored less emphasis only
on a temporary basis, while others were for less em­
phasis on “more general grounds.” Some members
brought attention to more broadly defined monetary

MAY 1971

the first quarter of 1971. Money was expected to grow
faster than 5 per cent in the first quarter of 1971, and
members concluded that movements in this series in
the immediate future should appear consistent with
the faster anticipated average rate. The Committee
agreed that “money market conditions should be eased
if it appeared that shortfalls from those growth paths
were developing, but that otherwise operations should
be directed at maintaining the conditions most re­
cently attained.” The operating clause of the Decem­
ber directive read:
System open market operations shall be conducted
with a view to maintaining the recently attained
money market conditions until the next meeting of
the Committee, provided that the expected rates of
growth in money and bank credit will at least be
achieved.

Mr. Francis dissented from this directive, because
he favored both maintaining a target 5 per cent an­
nual rate of monetary growth and increasing the em­
phasis on money rather than reducing it. He expressed
concern that a rate of growth in money at a rate faster
than 5 per cent could possibly prolong inflation and
even intensify it, while holding the growth in money
to a 5 per cent rate “was likely to assure steady prog­
ress toward moderating price increases, along with a
gradually increasing pace of expansion in real output.”
At the December meeting, it was still expected that
a 5 per cent growth of money would occur in the
fourth quarter, even though the growth of money in
October and November had been substantially below
this target. However, growth of money was substan­
tially less than expected in late December; for the
fourth quarter, money grew at a 3.4 per cent rate.
Immediately after the December meeting, open mar­
ket operations were aimed at maintaining the pre­
vailing money conditions. Since the demands for
credit were continuing to ease substantially, market
conditions remained easy. Nevertheless, Desk opera­
tions did not result in enough additional reserves to
achieve the desired growth in money.

CONCLUSION
aggregates. For instance, money plus net time de­
posits grew at a rapid 10 per cent rate from February
to December, partly reflecting the rapid reintermedia­
tion of time deposits into banks.17
There was some disagreement as to the appropriate
targets for money in the fourth quarter of 1970 and
17Net time deposits are defined as total time deposits at com­
mercial banks less large negotiable certificates of deposit.



The year 1970 marked a “modest” beginning for the
use of monetary aggregates in the formulation and
implementation of monetary policy decisions. The
emphasis on aggregates, however, varied during the
year.
After the initial statement by the Committee at the
January meeting, its position on monetary aggregates
evolved; at the March and April meetings the objec­
tive of the directive was stated totally in terms of
Page 31

MAY 1971

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

monetary aggregates. Beginning in May and continuing
through the July meeting, the emphasis on aggregates
was greatly reduced, and replaced by other short-term
objectives such as moderating pressures in financial
markets. However, targets for aggregates still were to
be sought to the extent that they were consistent with
these other objectives. The Committee raised the
targets for money in several stages from a 3 per cent
rate for the second quarter (March meeting) to a 5
per cent target for the third quarter at the July
meeting.18 The emphasis on aggregates was some­
what reinstated at the August meeting and continued
through the November meeting. However, the objec­
tive of achieving “some easing of conditions in credit
markets” also was stated explicitly.
The December meeting left the future status of
monetary aggregates somewhat in doubt. The direc­
tive was again stated in terms of money market con­
ditions; some Committee members expressed reserva­
tions about the use of monetary aggregates, and some
desired more use of money market conditions. Part of
the return to primary emphasis on money market con­
ditions at the end of the year may have been due to
the data problems involving the revision of money
stock series. As was noted earlier, according to the old
series money growth had been fairly close to that
18The Committee desired to have deviations from the 5 per
cent target on the upside.




sought by the Committee, but with the revision,
money had grown faster in the first three quarters of
the year than desired.
Although growth of the money stock (old series)
was quite close to the quarterly targets desired by
the Committee, by looking more closely one could
argue that this was partly an accident. For example,
at the May 26 meeting a 7 per cent growth rate of
money was expected for the second quarter. An un­
expected shortfall in money occurred in June, and a
4.2 per cent rate was achieved in the second quarter,
quite close to the earlier 4 per cent target. Growth of
aggregates for the fourth quarter of 1970 was consid­
erably under-achieved. Growth of money in October
and November fell short of expectations, even though
money market conditions eased as was called for in
the directive. Despite these shortfalls, at the De­
cember 15 meeting, a 5 per cent rate of money growth
was expected for the period September to December,
but only a 3.4 per cent rate (revised series) was
achieved.
These developments give the impression that con­
trol methods for money have yet to be perfected.
Part of the problem may lie with the “money market
conditions” approach. A more direct approach such as
controlling bank reserves or the monetary base may
be a more reliable method for controlling the money
stock.

This article is available as Reprint No. 68.