View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
O F ST. L O U IS
MARCH 1971

Capital Markets and Interest Rates in 1970

2

The 1971 National Economic Plan ............. 11
The Implementation Problem
of Monetary P olicy.......................................... 20

Vol. 5 3 , No. 3




Capital Markets and Interest Rates in 1970

JL H E M OST SP E C T A C U L A R fluctuations in m ar­
ketable securities prices in the era since W orld W a r II
have been encountered since early 1970. The markets
for both common stocks and bonds staged large rallies
between June 1970 and February 1971, after declin­
ing in the spring of last year. At their zenith in June,
high-grade bond yields reached levels never before
recorded in U. S. financial annals. Stock prices
slumped to six-year lows in May. Capital market pes­
simism reached great extremes; some ( though not a ll)
observers foresaw a dearth of funds available for in­
vestment extending far into the decade. Low er inter­
est rates and higher stock prices have doubtless
caused revision of such views, although the pace of
the market changes makes reappraisal of long-run
financing prospects difficult. Beyond that, the 1970
experience raises questions about the causes of such
gyrations and their effects on the economy.

Cyclical Variations in
Interest Rates and Stock Prices
Among the unusual features of financial markets in
1970 was the delayed response of long-term interest
rates to the business downturn. W hereas in previous
postwar business slowdowns, peaks in bond yields o c­
curred promptly after business peaks or even pre­
ceded them, three quarters elapsed after the business
downturn in 1969 before long-term Treasury and cor­
porate bond yields reached their peaks. Since then,
the reductions in yields have been the greatest in
amount of any comparable period since W orld W ar
II. Seasoned corporate Aaa bonds, for example, de­
clined from a peak of 8.6 per cent in the week ending
June 26, 1970 to 7.1 per cent in the week ending
M arch 5, 1971. Long-term U. S. government securities
fell from a yield of 6.8 per cent to 5.9 per cent in the
same span of time. In a recent reversal, yields, esPage
2



Yields on Seasoned
A a a Corporate Bonds
Per C ent

Per C ent

1 9 6 9 -7 2
.

19 59 -6 2
P

-------------------- —

"

_______________ P

_________

1 9 5 6 -5 9

P"— —

19 53 -5 6
1 9 4 8 -5 1
4 T H Q TR. 49
3RD Q TR/54
ow n r t p
1ST Q T R '61
4T H Q T R . 7 0

_______ I--------___________________________________________ 1_______________ i_______________ 1

•6

-5

-4

-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
Q U A R T ER S TO A N D FRO M T R O U G H

4

5

6

S o u rc e -. M o o d y 's In v e s to r S e r v ic e
P d e n o t e s th e p e a k q u a r t e r of th e b u s in e s s c y c le .
L a t e s t d a t a p lo t t e d : 1st q u a r t e r 1971 e s tim a te d

pecially on corporate new issues, have risen and other
long-term interest rates have stopped declining.
Short-term interest rates displayed more typical
cyclical behavior, reaching highs at the beginning of
1970, a quarter after the downturn in business activity,
then falling rapidly with only one tem porary reversal
throughout the year. The four- to six-month com m er­
cial paper rate, which was 9.08 per cent in the second
week of January 1970, plumm eted to 4.25 per cent
by early M arch 1971. Three-m onth U. S. Treasury bill
yields fell from 7.91 per cent to 3.35 per cent in the
same period.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

MARCH

In terest R a te s on Four- to S ix -M o n th
C o m m e rcia l P a p e r

-6

-5

-4

-3
-2
-1
0
1
2
3
Q U A R T E R S TO A N D FRO M T R O U G H

4

5

6

P d e n o te s the p e a k q u a r t e r o f th e b u s in e s s c y c le .
Late st d a ta p lo tte d : 1st q u a rte r 1971 estim ated

1971

months, both their average level and the term struc­
ture of interest rates are affected. It is typical for
short-term rates to fall much more rapidly than long­
term yields. F o r example, rates on U. S. Government
obligations maturing in less than one year, which
entered 1970 one percentage point above twenty-year
U. S. bonds, were m ore than two percentage points
below long-term bond yields by February 19, 1971.
This is consistent with the assumption that the long­
term bond yield is an average of a sequence of ex­
pected short-term yields. A decline in current short­
term market rates would generally have only a small
immediate effect in changing this long-term average.
As mentioned previously, short-term rates peaked
several months before long-term rates. If the bond
market had anticipated the general decline in inter­
est rates, the decline should have been reflected ini­
tially (although mildly) in medium-term or longerterm interest rates. A related development was the
whiplash action of the yield curve between January
2, 1970 and May 28, 1970 when yields fell in the
shortest maturity ranges, while rising in the mediumand long-maturity segments. Usually, all segments of
the yield curve move in the same direction simultane­
ously, with the short-term end moving more than the
long-term end. This pattern did indeed quickly reas­
sert itself by July 1970.

Stock prices underwent a broad retreat throughout
1969 and early 1970. In Spring 1970, retreat threat­
ened to turn into rout for a brief interval, as stock
prices fell by 23 per cent between April 1 and M ay
26. By the end of May, however, the market began
to regain composure, and since then, stock prices
have rebounded. The Standard and Poor’s Index of
500 Stocks (1941-43 = 1 0 ), which reached a low of
69.29 on May 26, 1970, climbed to 97.56 by early
M arch 1971.

Term Structure of Interest Rates
The accompanying chart depicts three “yield
curves” (relationships between maturities of fixed in­
terest-bearing obligations and their market yields)
for U. S. obligations with maturities running from less
than one year out to thirty years. The curves were
observed at three different dates: January 2, 1970,
M ay 28, 1970, and February 19, 1971. They are based
on actual yields on these dates, but each curve has
been smoothed to fill in gaps in maturity where no
actual obligations are available.
In general, when interest rates undergo a rapid
downward readjustment, as in the past fourteen



Page 3

FEDERAL RESERVE

B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

Inflation Expectations and Interest Rates
The expectations interpretation of the yield curve
helps explain how some of the recent change in in­
terest rates was transmitted through the maturity
spectrum. Other considerations would explain how the
general level of interest rates is determined. A factor
which may have contributed greatly to the high levels
of interest rates up to the 1970 peaks is anticipated
inflation. Interest rates on new loans were adjusted
upward to reflect the expected depreciation of the
purchasing power of the dollar during the period of
each loan. Since borrowers expect to repay loans in
depreciated dollars, they were willing to offer higher
interest rates. Lenders, on the other hand, were will­
ing to accept such terms only because high interest
rates include an inflation premium that compensates
for the exp ected reduction in the value of the dollar.
In other words, what borrowers and lenders agree
upon is a nominal or market interest rate ( R n ) which,
when the premium for the expected percentage rate
of inflation (A P e) is subtracted, leaves a net interest
rate (R r ) that represents both an acceptable rate of
return to the lender and cost to the borrower. This
net return, after allowing for anticipated inflation, is
what some economists have labelled the “real” rate of
interest.1 That is, the real rate, Rr, equals Rn — A Pe.
This interpretation of interest rate movements has
been incorporated in the interest rate equations of
the St. Louis model.2 It has also been employed in a
related study of stock price determination.3 These
studies find that other factors influence real rates of
interest, notably growth in the money stock (currency
plus demand deposits) which exercises a short-lived
negative effect (positive on stock p rices), and growth
in real output, which affects the real rate of interest
positively with a lag over a longer time span (n e g a ­
tive effect on stock p rices). Corporate after-tax profits
also have a positive impact, with a lag, on stock prices.
Anticipated inflation, in the sense already described,
has a powerful influence in these equations, tending
to drive average stock prices down and interest rates
up.4
^‘Interest Rates and Price Level Changes, 1952-69,” this
Review (December 1969), pp. 18-38.
2“A Monetarist Model for Economic Stabilization,” this Review
(April 1970), pp. 7-25.
•^“Expectations, Money and the Stock Market,” this Review
(January 1971), pp. 16-31.
4The effect of anticipated inflation on stock prices runs
counter to some interpretations of stocks as “hedges” against
inflation. The findings suggest that expected corporate earn­
ings do not fully adjust to anticipated price advances. In­
vestors apparently regard common stocks typically as mixtures

Page
4


MARCH

1971

Most of the rise in bond yields from 1965 until
early 1970 can be attributed to the escalation in the
inflation premium. It appears, however, that inflation
anticipations ( based on past price experience) cannot
fully account for the high levels of interest rates ( and
low levels of stock prices) in the second and third
quarters of 1970. Correspondingly, in the first quarter
of 1971, the interest rate equations forecast only a
mild decline in rates, by comparison with the declines
which have already occurred. Stock price forecasts
are below the current market average, although the
direction of change is being correcdy predicted.
Either inflation fears are now subsiding more rapidly
than these equations recognize, or some other factors
are at work pulling interest rates down.

Other Possible Explanations for Recent
Interest Rate and Stock Price Movements
Apart from anticipated inflation, other factors might
have exercised an influence on nominal interest rates
by altering die real rate of interest. Such factors in­
clude special disturbances affecting either the supply
of money relative to the demand for money, or the
flow of intended saving relative to intended invest­
ment. In addition, there might have been sudden or
unusual shifts among sectors in their borrowing or
lending patterns, causing tem porary adjustment prob­
lems that could have been reflected in interest rates.
Recent developments will be surveyed from each of
these points of view.

Factors Affecting Demand for and
Supply of Money and Near Monies
Rapid growth in monetary aggregates relative to
growth in demand for them should exert downward
pressure on interest rates — in the short run. The op­
posite short-run effect on rates occurs when the sup­
ply of monetary aggregates is growing less rapidly
than their demand.
Monetary rates of change, both including and ex­
cluding net time deposits, reached lows in the latter
half of 1969, and thereafter reversed the downtrends
that began in 1968.5 Business activity began to recede
in the third or fourth quarter of 1969. This represents
of fixed nominal income streams, like bonds, and earnings
streams that escalate with inflation. For this reason, the
average price of all common stocks cannot be viewed simply
as the market valuation of real capital.
"'Net time deposits are total time deposits less large denomina­
tion CD’s. A similar statement could be made describing
the rate of growth in money plus total time deposits, or even
broader liquidity aggregates including savings and loan
shares and mutual savings bank deposits.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

MARCH

1971

a prominent feature of growth in monetary aggre­
gates. Negotiable C D ’s grew from $13.2 billion in
June 1970 to $27 billion in February 1971. Money
supply plus all comm ercial bank time deposits in­
creased at a 17.4 per cent annual rate in the same
period. Upward interest adjustments on C D ’s (follow­
ing suspension in June of Regulation Q interest ceil­
ings on large C D ’s of less than 90 days m aturity),
combined with a declining trend of interest rates on
competitive assets such as commercial paper, E u ro­
dollars, and Treasury bills, made C D ’s more attractive
for businesses to hold.
There has also been a very substantial increase in
net time deposits at commercial banks and savings
institutions. Between June 1970 and February 1971,
these liquid assets grew by $43.1 billion. Over the
same time span, money supply, defined as currency
plus demand deposits, rose at a 5.7 per cent annual
rate. In comparison with the turnarounds in previous
periods of monetary expansion, the increased growth
in the money stock relative to its low point in 1969
has been m oderate, but the recovery in growth of
money stock plus net time deposits has been rapid.
Some of this growth can be ascribed to “reinterm e­
diation” which occurs when interest rates decline on
competing liquid assets. In addition, the decline in
these interest rates, especially in recent months, has
received a significant stimulus from expansionary
monetary policy. F o r example, reserves of member
banks have increased at an annual rate of 14.3 per
cent since last June. The recent high rates of growth
in the broader aggregate of money plus net time de­
posits reflect both the rapid expansion in bank re­
serves and the sharp decline in interest rates on
marketable securities.
a relatively early turnaround in comparison with
monetary rates of change near previous postwar busi­
ness cycle peaks.11 Frequently the lowest rates of
monetary growth have come several months after the
business peak. Hence, the continued high level of
interest rates in early 1970 cannot be attributed to
sluggish increases in the monetary aggregates in the
face of the business slowdown.
During the last half of 1970, when interest rates fell
sharply, the large increase in negotiable C D ’s was
•’Centered rates of change of moving averages give somewhat
different results than “step” rates of change. Both are shown
in chart above. The “step” method is generally used in this
Bank’s reports. Changes in “steps” tend to be preceded by
peaks and troughs in centered moving average rates of
change.



A useful, though crude, measure of the demand for
money balances in relation to income is the “income
velocity of money” — the ratio of income to money
balances. This ratio is an indicator of the turnover
rate of money balances in exchange for goods and
services. The following chart shows the ratio of
GNP to money plus “net time deposits” (com ­
mercial bank time deposits excluding large denomi­
nation C D ’s) in postwar business recessions. The
amount of money balances demanded increases either
more or less than proportionately with income or GNP.
D uring much of the postwar period, the chart shows
velocity to have risen with each successive business
cycle, indicating a tendency for holders of money and
net time deposits to increase their spending on goods
and services faster than the growth in their liquid
Page 5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

MARCH

V elo city of M o n ey Stock
Plus Time Deposits*
2.6

2.6

19 59-62

1 9 5 6 -5 9
_______

1 9 5 3 -5 6

/

/
/
/

/

^ ------- 1948-51
/
4TH
T R .4 9
3RD Q T R .5 4
1ST QTR. 61
4TH QTR. 70
~
------ 1
------- 1------- j------- 1
------- 1
------- 1-------1---------------1
------- i-------------4

-3
-2
- 1 0
1
2
3
4
5
6
Q U A R T E R S TO A N D FR O M T R O U G H
Source-. U .S. D e p artm en t o f Com m erce
g ro ss n a tio n a l p ro d u c t
m o n e y s to c k + n e t tim e d e p o s its
* N e t time d ep o sits e q u a ls a ll tim e d e p o s its le s s c e rtific a te s of
d e p o s it in d e n o m in a tio n s e x c e e d in g $1 00,00 0.
P d e n o te s the p e a k q u a rt e r of the b u s in e s s c y c le .
L a te s t d a ta p lo tte d : 4th q u a rte r 1970

balances.7 However, during business slowdowns, velo­
city falls — monetary assets increase relative to GNP.
This happened in each of the recessions of 1949, 1954,
1958, and 1961, and in 1970.
The decline in velocity during business slowdowns
is typically associated with reductions in interest
rates.8 After the business trough is reached, interest
rates rise and velocity tends to recover. If the contracyclical rise in long-term interest rates in early 1970
had been the result of a sudden rise in the demand
for money plus net time deposits, we should be able
to detect it in an abnormally sharp drop in velocity.9
Similarly, the rapid decline in interest rates would be
associated with an abnormally sharp rise in velocity
— signifying a reduction in the demand for money
plus net time deposits. The decrease in velocity dur7The rise in velocity of money stock as conventionally defined
has been greater than the rise in the velocity of money plus
“net time deposits,” especially in the last decade.
sThe rise in velocity between successive post World War II
business cycles is associated with (and may, in part, be due
to) successive higher levels of interest rates.
^Assuming that unintended variations in velocity are of negli­
gible importance.

Page 6


1971

ing the 1970 business contraction was not unusual by
comparison with postwar recessions. Nor has there
been any evidence of an unusually sharp rise in veloc­
ity in recent months. E xcep t for possibly the fourth
quarter, one may rule out sudden changes in the
demand for money plus net time deposits as a con­
tributing factor to the abnormal behavior of interest
rates since Januar) 1970.10
The velocity of money plus net time deposits is
perhaps too broad a measure, especially since it tends
to consist very largely of liquid assets held by house­
holds, which exhibited none of the symptoms of a
liquidity crisis in 1970. Some observers found such
symptoms among business firms reacting to unfavor­
able financial developments in 1970. The failure of
Penn Central Company sent liabilities of business fail­
ures upward in midyear. Corporate profits sagged for
four quarters in a row beginning with third quarter
1969. Liquidity positions of nonfinancial corporations,
by a variety of yardsticks, were stretched thinner in
m id-1970 than in any previous postwar year. There
is little evidence, however, that in 1970 a significant
number of otherwise financially viable firms were
forced to close for liquidity reasons alone.
Velocity of nonfinancial corporate cash balances
tends to decline during business contractions. The
1970 decline was delayed until three quarters after
the fourth quarter 1969 turning point in business ac­
tivity, but it is not clear whether this was a cause or a
result of high interest rates. To be a cause of high
interest rates, one must assume the rise in corporate
velocity after the business peak was unintended, so
that corporations were attempting to improve their
liquidity positions. Much of what appears to be a
decline during 1969 and early 1970 in corporate liq­
uidity (rise in velocity) merely represents switching
from negotiable C D ’s to comm ercial paper and gov­
ernment securities. Such shifts were a result of high
interest rates ( and regulatory interest ceilings on
C D ’s ) , not a cause of high interest rates.
10The General Motors strike of September-November, 1970
may have temporarily depressed the amount 'of money de­
manded in the fourth quarter of 1970 by reducing output
and income below what it would have otherwise been.
This response would not be fully reflected in velocity, if
both income and demand for money declined and money
stock were also reduced or permitted to grow less rapidly.
Interest rates, therefore, could have been forced downward
in the fourth quarter because of the effect of the strike. In
the three months since the strike was settled, output growth
has recovered from its strike-induced low, but interest rates
have continued to fall. Other factors are evidently at work
in reducing interest rates currently.

FEDERAL RESERVE

B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

MARCH

Personal saving, measured in the national income
accounts as disposable income minus consumption
expenditures, excludes accumulation of consumer dur­
ables. It represents mainly liquid asset accumulation,
net of additions to consumer debt. During the cur­
rent business slump, this category of saving grew as a
percentage of personal disposable income from 5.3
per cent in the second quarter of 1969 to a peak of
7.6 per cent in the third quarter of 1970, and declined
slightly to 7.3 per cent in the fourth quarter. Taken
by itself, the rise in personal saving has exerted a
downward influence on interest rates since 1969.

Velocity of
Corporate Cash Balances*
11

10
9

8
7

6
5
4
3

0
- 6 - 5 - 4 - 3
- 2 - 1 0
1
2
3
Q U A R T E R S TO A N D FRO M T R O U G H

4

1971

5

6

S o u rc e s -. S e c u r it ie s a n d E x c h a n g e C o m m is s io n a n d
U .S . D e p a rtm e n t of C o m m e rc e
* R a tio fo r n o n fin a n c ia l co rp o ra tio n s of g ross c o rp o ra te p ro d u c t to
c a sh on h a n d a n d in b a n k s.

In previous postwar recessions, the personal saving
rate has shown no clear cyclical pattern; it has some­
times risen, sometimes declined. The cyclical varia­
tion in measured personal income around its expected
growth path does not seem to exercise a substantial
influence on the saving rate. Part of its behavior may
reflect monetary growth itself, since high rates of
liquid saving relative to income are likely to take the
form of rapid accumulation of cash balances. A rise
in price levels will reduce the purchasing power of
liquid assets and might induce households to attempt
to restore that purchasing power by increased liquid

P d e n o t e s th e p e a k q u a r t e r o f th e b u s in e s s c y c le .
L a t e s t d a t a p lo t t e d : 3 r d q u a r t e r 1 9 7 0

More recently, the velocity of corporate cash bal­
ances has declined, partly because of the reversal of
previous movements out of C D ’s. Even so, corporate
liquidity is not at present exceptionally high, nor has
it improved rapidly by comparison with experience
in previous business slowdowns. Hence, current down­
ward pressures on interest rates do not appear to have
their origin in greater liquidity of corporations.

Saving and Investment in
a Business Slowdown
An excess of intended saving over intended invest­
ment tends to reduce interest rates, and conversely.
There are practical difficulties, of course, in distin­
guishing intended from actual saving and investment.
One technique for attempting this involves a decom ­
position of saving by sector and investment by cate­
gory of expenditure, within the national income
accounting framework. Saving is composed of three
volatile components — personal saving, corporate
undistributed profits (adjusted to remove inventory
revaluation), and the net surplus of Federal and
state and local governments. Investment consists of
residential construction plus business expenditures on
durable equipment, and structures, and inventory a c­
cumulation, shown in the accompanying chart.



Page 7

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

saving. Sustained inflation, on the other hand, builds
up anticipation of future price advances, which tends
to discourage liquid saving. Higher interest rates on
liquid assets, however, could compensate for antici­
pated inflation, and may have done so to some extent
in recent years.
The rise in the personal saving rate that began in
the third quarter of 1969 appears to coincide with
more rapid monetary growth. Looking ahead, a sub­
stantial decline in personal saving rates could occur
as a result of lower interest rates, slower monetary
growth or reduced inflation, especially if anticipated
inflation remains high.
Investment in dwellings is generally regarded as
highly responsive to interest rate movements, rather
than as a factor operating to exert strong pressure on
interest rates, especially pressure of a procyclical na­
ture. High and rising mortgage interest costs in 1969
and early 1970 were reflected in declining residential
construction expenditures. Federal government sup­
port of housing programs may have moderated the
decline. Since the second quarter, homebuilding ex­
penditures have rebounded to an annual rate of $32
billion, less than $2 billion below their 1969 peak.
Prospects for a continuation of this resurgence have
been bolstered by the recent declines in long-term
interest rates. These have enabled the Federal gov­
ernment to reduce FH A and VA ceiling mortgage
loan rates to 7 per cent from the 8V2 per cent level of
D ecem ber 1969.
Capital expenditure plans in the business sector
were exceedingly bullish in the early stages of the
economic slowdown. Initial anticipations called for
plant and equipment outlays in 1970 to increase by
more than 10 per cent over the previous year. Actual
1970 business capital spending was only 6.6 per cent
greater than in 1969. As the chart (p. 7 ) shows, busi­
ness spending on equipment and nonresidential struc­
tures turned down after the third quarter of 1970.
Nevertheless, the early plant and equipment surveys
for 1970 mirrored the upward thrust of fixed invest­
m ent intentions at the outset of the 1969-70 slowdown.
Coupled with declining profits, which reduced the
ability of corporations to finance capital spending
through retained earnings, the net pressure on inter­
est rates of the corporate sector’s intended saving
and fixed investment was undoubtedly upward in
early 1970.11 Capital spending plans were revised
n A $9.7 billion decline in inventory accumulation from the
third quarter of 1969 to the first quarter of 1970 helped
offset this pressure. In the second quarter, inventory change
reversed direction, and by the fourth quarter was increas­
ing at a $3.6 billion annual rate.
Digitized for Page
FRASER
8


MARCH

1971

downward later in the year and corporate profits im­
proved, so that this pressure on interest rates was
eased.1- In the latest survey conducted by the D e­
partm ent of Com m erce and SEC in January and
February, business planned to increase its 1971 spend­
ing on plant and equipment by 4.3 per cent over the
1970 level.
An important sector affecting capital markets
through flows of expenditures relative to receipts is
the Federal Government. The Federal budget, on a
national income accounts (N IA ) basis, moved from
a surplus at a $13.4 billion annual rate in the second
quarter of 1969 to a $14.2 billion rate of deficit in the
second quarter of 1970. An increase in the Federal
net deficit usually occurs during business slowdowns
due to reduced growth in tax revenues relative to
expenditures. Expiration of the surtax, retroactive
Federal pay increases, and increased social security
benefits also contributed to the decrease in the net
surplus in early 1970.
The strong swing by the Federal Government from
a net “saver” to a net “dissaver” position, primarily
between the fourth quarter of 1969 and the second
quarter of 1970, coincides with the abnormally long
lag in response of bond yields to a downturn in
business activity. A continuing large government defi­
cit may not elevate interest rates, but a rapid increase
in the deficit, or decrease in the surplus, may exert
tem porary upward pressure on interest rates. The de­
cline in long-term interest rates since midyear may
therefore represent a return to their typical cyclical
response as the Federal deficit passed its period of
most rapid increase.13
The Federal deficit (national income accounts
basis) increased somewhat in the fourth quarter of
,2It is conceivable that some or even most of the strength in
early capital expenditure plans for 1970 reflected inflation
anticipations. Expected productivity of additional plant and
equipment might even have declined throughout 1970. Low
and falling levels of capacity utilization suggest that the
marginal productivity of new facilities may be decreasing;
so also does the deceleration of growth in total real output
in the economy, which began in early 1968. It can be
argued that the rate of growth in total output is an approxi­
mation to the expected return on physical investment.
13The immediate impact of a sharp rise in the government
deficit need not be concentrated in the maturity ranges in
which new government debt is being issued. The effects
might register most heavily in another sector, if simultane­
ously with heavy government borrowing in one maturity
region, the private sector is retiring debt in that range and
increasing its borrowing in some other maturity region. As
discussed below, in 1970 corporations were retiring their
short-term debt while increasing their long-term debt. At
the same time the Federal government was borrowing
heavily in the short-term end of the maturity range.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

1970 to an estimated $15.3 billion annual rate. From
this point, the NIA deficit is likely to decrease gradu­
ally as the economic recovery picks up momentum.
The Administration projects a $15 billion NIA deficit
in fiscal 1971, which would imply deficits averaging
more than a $13 billion annual rate in the first two
quarters in 1971. In fiscal 1972, which begins July 1,
1971, the NIA deficit is projected to decline to a $4.2
billion annual rate. Taking the national income a c­
counts budget as an indicator, and assuming the a c­
curacy of the Administration’s projections, the Federal
sectors’ upward pressure on interest rates would seem
to be easing.14

Disturbances in the Capital Markets
Sudden changes in asset and liability positions in
various sectors, especially when they are related to
alterations in the maturity structure of outstanding
credit obligations, sometimes provide clues about the
net direction of pressures on interest rates. It is not
always easy to distinguish between autonomous and
accom m odating financial transactions, but when the
changes are of extremely large magnitude, as some
w ere in 1970, there may be less difficulty in discern­
ing the sources of disturbances in credit markets.
Tw o features of 1970 capital markets are deserving
of special mention. The first is the exceptionally sharp
increase in long-term borrowing by nonfinancial cor­
porations. Much of this reflected refinancing of shortrun debt (bank loans primarily) carried over from
1969 and earlier, and did not represent a marked
change in the rate of growth in total corporate debt.
Lengthening of the maturity of corporate debt in
1970 may have eased the pressure of net government
borrowing in short-term credit markets, while adding
to weakness in long-term credit markets early in the
year.
The dollar volume of new corporate securities is­
sued (gross proceeds) continued at an unslackened
rate throughout 1970, totaling more than $38 billion,
only $8.6 billion of which were new stock issues. New
issues in the first two months of 1971 were in excess
of the corresponding months of 1970, and there are
as yet no definite signs of a letup in long-term financ­
ing demands. The calendar of new corporate issues
for M arch is extremely heavy. Since corporations have
been reducing their short-term borrowing, particularly
from banks, while adding to their short-term assets,
14For an evaluation of the Administration’s fiscal 1972 budget
and 1971 economic plan, see “The 1971 National Economic
Plan” in this Review, pp. 11-19.



MARCH

1971

especially C D ’s, it is evident that many corporations
are striving to strengthen their liquidity positions.
The second notable feature was the extremely large
rise in commercial banks’ net lending, particularly in
the third quarter. A major portion of this, of course,
arose out of the retirement of commercial paper by
banks’ parent holding companies and its replacement
by C D ’s. Bank credit expansion was $25.8 billion
greater (annual rate) in the Summer quarter than in
the Spring, after allowing for this. Almost $15.2 billion
of this increase in bank credit was accounted for by
loans to security dealers and brokers to finance a c­
quisition of U. S. Government and other securities.
An increase in the rate of acquisition by banks of
U. S. Government securities accounted for another
$8.2 billion (annual ra te ) of the bank credit increase.
Commercial bank lending to business slowed in the
third quarter and declined in the fourth. In the fourth
quarter, banks becam e heavy net purchasers of muni­
cipal and Federal agency securities.
Long-term bond yields, which had generally de­
clined in January, February, and M arch 1970, con­
forming to their cyclical pattern, rose again in April,
May, and June. It appears that the sharp declines in
the Spring, and the subsequent Summer rallies in
bond and stock markets, gained strength from a mas­
sive shift in investment policy among securities deal­
ers and brokers, from net liquidation of their positions
in the second quarter to aggressive rebuilding in the
third quarter. The reasons for this behavior may be
traceable to special circumstances — the Cambodian
incursion, the campus riots, and a series of failures,
forced mergers and recapitalizations among broker­
age firms. These events took their toll on the stock
and bond markets in the Spring. Then the failure of
Penn Central sent tremors through the bond and
commercial paper markets in June. After the severe
buffeting subsided, securities dealers regained confi­
dence. The much discussed liquidity crisis of the
Spring and early Summer of 1970 centered very
largely in the fortunes of brokerage firms. It may
account for a large part of the unusual cyclical re­
sponse of bond yields. The effect on interest rates
and stock prices, while possibly significant at that
time, was short-lived.

Summary and Conclusions
Interest rates, particularly bond yields, remained
near peak levels for an abnormally lengthy period
in 1970 after the downturn in business activity. Sev­
eral factors could have contributed to this long lag in
response. These include ( 1 ) the persistence of infla­
Page 9

FEDERAL RESERVE

B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

tionary anticipations; (2 ) the sharp rise in the Federal
deficit during fiscal 1970; (3 ) heavy long-term borrow ­
ing by corporations, coupled with exuberant capital
expenditure programs early in the year; (4 ) the very
gradual decline in real output growth, compared with
previous postwar recessions; (5 ) the financial prob­
lems of securities dealers, which were reflected in net
liquidation of their securities inventory positions in
the Spring; and (6 ) special circumstances, such as
the Cambodian incursion and campus rioting. The
Penn Central crisis temporarily lifted interest rates in
June.
After the mid-year turnaround in bond yields, all
interest rates except yields on lower grade bonds went
into a decline, which accelerated in the fourth quar­
ter. In part, the fall in rates represented a return to
their typical behavior during cyclical downswings in
economic activity. The drop in long-term and short­
term rates continued, however, in the first two months
of 1971, following the low point of the business slow­
down that was reached in the fourth quarter of 1969.
In February, three-month Treasury bills yielded less

Digitized forPage
FRASER
10


MARCH

1971

than 4 per cent for the first time since 1967, and Aaa
corporate bonds yielded less than 7 per cent for the
first time since 1968.
Inasmuch as the high interest rates of the last few
years may well have been largely a reflection of infla­
tion anticipations, it is possible that we are now wit­
nessing a dram atic de-escalation of these anticipations.
A broader interpretation accepts such de-escalation as
part of the story. It would, however, emphasize other
forces exerting downward pressure on interest rates
and upward pressure on common stock priccs in re­
cent months. These include ( 1 ) an improved financial
outlook among securities firms; (2 ) the automobile
strike in the fourth quarter; and (3 ) reduced business
optimism regarding rates of return on physical invest­
ment (reflected in conservative 1971 plant and equip­
ment spending plans and sluggish short-term business
borrow ing). An expansive monetary policy, especially
as displayed in the broader m onetary aggregates, also
may have played a major role in the recent bond and
stock market rallies.

The 1971 National Economic Plan
by K E IT H M. CARLSON

X H E F E D E R A L B U D G E T , the E conom ic Report
of the President, and the Annual R eport of the C o u n ­
cil of Econom ic Advisers were presented recently
to Congress and the public.1 These three documents
represent the Administration’s national econom ic plan
for the eighteen-month period ending June 30, 1972.
Targets for total spending (G N P ), output, prices, and
unemployment are presented along with a proposed
Federal budget program presumably consistent with
these goals. Underlying the statement of targets and
the Fed eral budget plan is an assumption regarding
the course of monetary actions by the Federal R e­
serve System.
Specific targets for the U. S. economy are set forth
by the Council of Econom ic Advisers (C E A ) in their
A nnual Report.2 These goals, stated with reference
to second quarter 1972, consist of a reduction in the
unemployment rate to near 4.5 per cent of the labor
force and a reduction of the inflation rate, as measured
by the GNP deflator, to near a 3 per cent annual
rate. An 11 to 12 per cent annual rate of increase of
total spending (nominal G N P) from fourth quarter
1970 to second quarter 1972 is proposed as a means
of achieving these targets. To realize this advance
of total spending, the C E A recommends an 8 per cent
annual rate of increase in Federal expenditures and
a continuation of the 5 to 6 per cent rate of monetary
expansion which prevailed in 1970.
This article evaluates the Administration’s national
economic plan with the aid of a methodology de­
veloped at this Bank. The 1970 economic plan is
compared with actual developments for purposes of
obtaining some perspective on stabilization plans and
realizations. Then, the 1971 economic plan is ex­
amined in terms of feasibility and internal consistency.
The St. Louis model is used to evaluate the Admin­
istration’s plan, thus any conclusions necessarily reflect
the particular characteristics of that methodology.
1T he B udget o f the United States Government, Fiscal Year
Ending June 30, 1972 (Government Printing Office, 1971),
and Econom ic Report o f the President, together with The
Annual Report o f the Council o f Econom ic Advisers (Gov­
ernment Printing Office, 1971).
21971 CEA Report, p. 78.



Stabilization Actions and Economic
Developments in 1970
The recent E conom ic R eport of the President
described 1970 as a year of transition, when the U. S.
economy paid for the excesses of 1966 through 1968.
The general level of prices rose 5.3 per cent
from fourth quarter 1969 to fourth quarter 1970,
G ene ral Price Index*
Ratio Scale
1958=100
150

1964

Ratio Scale
1958=100
150

1965

1966

1967

1968

1969

1970

1971

1972

*As used in N otional Income Accounts
Source: U.S . Department of Commerce
P e rce n tag e s a re o nn u al rates of change fo r periods in dicated.
Latest data plotted: 4th quarter 1970; dashed line in dicates h a lf-y e a r estim ates by this Bank based on
the fis c a l 1972 Fe d e ral Budget and the 1971 A nnual Report o f the C ou ncil of
Economic Advisers.

com pared with a 5 per cent advance in the previous
year, and unemployment rose from 3.6 per cent of
the labor force in fourth quarter 1969 to 5.9 per cent
a year later. Total spending increased at a m oderate
4 per cent rate in the first half of the year, then
stepped up to a 7 per cent rate in the second half
(after allowance for the depressing influence of the
auto strike in the fourth q u arter).3 The faster advance
of total spending in the second half of the year was
fostered by more rapid monetary expansion and
increased growth of Federal spending beginning in
early 1970.
3The CEA estimated the impact of the fourth quarter strike
to be approximately $14 billion, or that total spending (GNP)
would have risen at about a 7 per cent annual rate from
third to fourth quarter in the absence of the auto strike. See
the 1971 CEA Report, pp. 34-36.
Page 11

MARCH

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

Fiscal Actions
Federal budget actions w ere moderately stimula­
tive in 1970, as Federal expenditures rose somewhat
faster than during the previous year. Accelerated
growth of Federal expenditures, along with expiration
of the 10 per cent tax surcharge, resulted in a slight
net fiscal stimulus during 1970.
E xpend itures — Federal spending in 1970 was dom­
inated by developments in the second quarter. Effec­
tive in April, but retroactive to January 1, social
security benefits w ere increased at a $4.3 billion an­
nual rate, and Federal employee compensation was
raised at a $2.5 billion annual rate. The 7.1 per cent
increase in Federal spending during the year ending
fourth quarter 1970 compared with a 4.6 per cent rise
during the previous year and a 13.4 per cent average
annual rate of increase from 1965 to 1968.
The advance of Federal spending from late 1969
to late 1970 reflected a 5.3 per cent decline in
defense spending and a 16 per cent rise in non­
defense spending. Defense spending had changed
litde in 1969, after increasing at a 15 per cent average
annual rate from 1965 to 1968. Nondefense spending


Page 12


1971

had advanced 8.4 per cent in 1969 following a 12.4
per cent average rate of increase from 1965 to 1968.
R eceipts — The major actions affecting budget rev­
enues were the two-step elimination of the 10 per
cent tax surcharge originally imposed July 1, 1968,
and some net tax relief as a result of the T ax Reform
Act of 1969. Expiration of the surcharge decreased
Federal receipts by an estimated $8.3 billion. This
action, along with sluggish growth in econom ic activ­
ity, resulted in a $9 billion dollar decline in Federal
receipts from fourth quarter 1969 to fourth quarter
1970.
S urp lu s/deficit position — The combination of a c­
celerated Federal spending, lower effective tax rates
for personal and corporate income, and a reduced
rate of advance of total spending in the economy,
resulted in a shift of the national income accounts
(N IA ) budget from a $7.2 billion annual rate of
surplus in the second half of 1969 to a $14 billion
rate of deficit in the second half of 1970.
The $21 billion shift of budget position, as measured
by the NIA budget, tends to overstate the extent of
stimulus provided by the Federal budget. A substan­
tial portion of the 1969 to 1970 shift from surplus to a
deficit reflects the slowdown of the economy and is
thereby misleading as a measure of discretionary fiscal
action. Standardizing the estimates of expenditures
and receipts on a high-employment basis provides a
method of more accurately measuring the extent to
which discretionary Federal budget actions were
taken. On a high-employment basis, as estimated by
this Bank, the NIA budget moved from a $10 billion
annual rate of surplus in the second half of 1969 to
a $7 billion rate in the second half of 1970.4 By com ­
parison, this measure of the Federal budget averaged
a $7.2 billion rate of deficit from 1966 to 1968.

Monetary Actions
M onetary actions in 1970 were quite expansive com­
pared with the previous year, but according to most
measures were less stimulative than in 1967 and
1968. The money stock increased 5.1 per cent during
the year ending fourth quarter 1970, com pared with
3.8 per cent in the previous year and a 7 per cent
average rate of increase in 1967 and 1968.
4Estimates of the high-employment budget are prepared by
this Bank and are published in our quarterly release, “Fed­
eral Budget Trends.” These estimates differ slightly from
those published in the 1971 CEA Report, pp. 24 and 73. For
further discussion of the high-employment budget concept,
see the 1971 CEA Report, pp. 70-74.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

MARCH

Table I

M o n e y Stock
Ratio Sc a le

Q u a rte rly A v e ra g e s of M onthly Fig ures

1971

Ratio Sc a le

Projected a n d A c t u a l C h a n g e s in
T o ta l S p e n d in g ( G N P )
a n d C o m p o n e n t s — 1 9 6 9 to 1 9 7 0
(B illio n s of D ollars)
CEA
Projection
Personal consumption
Business fixed investment

$ 4 0 .0

Actual

Error

$ 3 9 .2

$0 .8
4 .6
4.1

7.9

3 .3

Business inventories

- 0 .9

- 5 .0

Residential construction

- 2 .2

- 2 .3

0.1

Federal purchases

- 4 .5

— 1.6

- 2 .9

11.5
0 .9

10.1

1.4

1.7

- 0 .8

State and local purchases
Net exports
Total spending (G N P )

5 2 .7

45.1
( 4 8 .6 ) *

7.6
( 4 .1 ) *

* Excluding effect of auto strike, CEA estimate.

was underestimation of the growth of Federal pur­
chases of goods and services.

Evaluation of Last Years National
Economic Plan
The C E A R eport of a year ago projected a 5.7 per
cent increase in total spending (G N P ) for calendar
1970 over 1969.5 The subsequent actual increase was
4.8 per cent, or, after adjusting for the effects of the
auto strike in the fourth quarter, 5.2 per cent. The
C E A anticipated a slow advance of total spending in
the first half followed by a quickened pace in the
second half. Apparently this pattern was realized,
though an accurate assessment is clouded by the
strike developments late in the year.
The C E A error of $7.6 billion in projecting the
growth of GNP from 1969 to 1970 was not large,
considering that about $3.5 billion was attributable to
the auto strike. A comparison of the actual changes
in the components of GNP with the C E A projections
(Table I) indicates the primary source of error was
overestimation of business fixed investment and of in­
ventory accumulation. This type of forecasting error
is common when the pace of econom ic activity is slow­
ing; business investment plans typically are scaled
back at such times. The other source of error, which
partly offset the error in the investment projection,
•’1970 CEA Report, Chapter 2.



Added relevance for stabilization policy is provided
by the C E A projections of real product, prices and
unemployment. Table II shows that the C E A pro­
jected an increase in real product from 1969 to 1970
of 1.2 per cent, a 4.4 per cent rise in the price level,
and a rise in the unemployment rate of .8 per cent.
Despite considerable success in projecting the growth
in total spending, the C E A failed to anticipate the
continued strength of inflation and the extent of
sluggish growth in real product and employment.
Table II

Proje cted a n d A c t u a l C h a n g e s in S p e n d in g ,
O u t p u t , Prices a n d U n e m p l o y m e n t —
1 9 6 9 to 1 9 7 0
(P er Cent)
CEA
Projection

Actual

Real product

5 .7 %
1.2

4 .8 %
- 0 .4

Prices

4.4

5.3

— 0 .9

Unemployment rate

0.8

1.4

- 0 .6

Total spending (G N P )

Error
0 .9 %
1.6

Stabilization plans vs. realizations — To evaluate the
1970 C E A projections and determine underlying
sources of error, it is useful to compare monetary and
fiscal plans with realizations. Table III gives planned
and actual changes in the NIA budget from 1969 to
1970 on both an actual and a high-employment basis.
From the standpoint of fiscal plans, the high-employ­
ment budget is more relevant. On this basis, expendi­
tures increased $4.5 billion more in 1970 than planned.
Combined with a quite accurate projection of highemployment receipts, the change in net position
Page 13

MARCH

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

Table III

P la n n e d a n d A c t u a l C h a n g e s in F ed e ra l Budgets —
1 9 6 9 to 1 9 7 0
(B illio n s of D ollars)
Budget Plan
N IA receipts
N IA expenditures
N IA surplus or deficit
High-employment receipts
High-employment expenditures
High-employment surplus
or deficit

Error

Actual
$

4.8

$ - 0 .6

$ — 5.4

9 .6

15.0

— 5.4

- 1 0 .2

— 20.4

10.2

1 1.0

10.4

0 .6

8 .7

13.2

- 4 .5

2.3

- 2 .8

5.1

N ote: Federal budget plans for 1970 were tfiven in the quarterly
release. “ Federal Budget Trends,” prepared by this Bank,- Feb­
ruary 20, 1970.

turned out to be a slight stimulus compared with
plans for slight restraint. This error in fiscal planning
is not large, however, compared with some in the past.
The C E A assumption about monetary actions in
1970 was not specific in terms of a growth rate of the
money stock, though a rate about mid-way between
the 1967-68 rate and the rate in the second half of
1969, or about 4.5 per cent, was implied.(i Money
actually grew 5.1 per cent from fourth quarter 1969
to fourth quarter 1970. Consequently the C EA pro­
jection of monetary growth was quite accurate.

1971

but this was not the primary source of error, according
to St. Louis methodology. In fact, the projections based
on policv assumptions w ere closer to the actual than
w ere the projections based on perfect knowledge about
the course of these policy actions. Realized monetary
and fiscal actions implied that the projections should
have been low rather than high. As a result, based on
the St. Louis methodology, the C E A error in project­
ing total spending reflected factors other than errors in
projecting the course of monetary and fiscal actions.
Though the C E A error in projecting total spending
was not large, there were larger errors in projecting
the division of total spending growth betw een prices
and real product. Table IV shows prices, real product,
and unemployment as projected and realized. Real
product growth from calendar 1969 to 1970 was over­
estimated by the C E A , a projection of a 1.2 per cent
increase, com pared with no change in actual output
(excluding the effect of the fourth quarter strike).
Unemployment was forecast to rise to a 4.3 per cent
average for the year, but turned out to be 4.9 per
cent. The rate of inflation, on the other hand, was
underestimated. The C E A in early 1970 expected a
substantial improvement in price inflation over 1969,
projecting a 4.4 per cent increase. Prices actually rose
5.3 per cent from calendar 1969 to 1970.

Table IV shows that the projections for prices,
Analysis based on St. Louis m odel — To better un­
output, and unemployment based on St. Louis m e­
derstand the significance of the difference between
thodology were more accurate than the C E A ’s projecprojected and actual changes in key econom ic varia­
bles from 1969 to 1970, some alterna­
Table IV
tive simulations with the St. Louis
Projected C h a n g e s in S p e n d in g , O u t p u t , Prices
methodology are examined.7 Fou r cases
a n d U n e m p l o y m e n t — 1 9 6 9 to 1 9 7 0
are considered: estimates based on (1 )
changes in money and expenditures as
Unem ploy­
Real
ment Rate
Total Spending
Product
Prices
assumed by the C EA in February 1970;
Billions of
(2 ) perfect anticipation of changes in
Per Cent
Per Cent
Per Cent Per Cent
Dollars
Federal expenditures, but not money;
1. 2 %
4 .4 %
0.8%
CEA Projection ( 2 / 2 / 7 0 )
$ 5 2 .7
5 .7 %
(3 ) perfect anticipation of changes in
1 .4*
5 .2 *
4 8 .6 *
5 .2 *
0.0 *
Actual *
St. Louis Model Projections
money, but not Federal expenditures;
1 ) with changes in money
and (4 ) perfect anticipation of both
and Governm ent spend­
money and expenditures.
ing based on CEA
Examination of Table IV suggests
that the C E A was quite accurate in
their total spending projection, mainly
because they assumed an acceleration
in the rate of monetary expansion in
1970. Federal expenditures advanced
somewhat more rapidly than planned,
«1970 CEA Report, p. 60.
7“A Monetarist Model for Economic Stabili­
zation,” this Review (April 1970), pp. 7-25.

Page 14


assumptions

52 .5

5.6

0.6

5 .0

1.3

2)

with changes in
Government spending
perfectly perceived but
not changes in money

5 6 .0

6.0

1.0

5 .0

1.2

3)

with changes in money
perfectly perceived but
not changes in G o v­
ernment spending

53.1

5 .7

0 .7

5 .0

1.3

4)

with both changes in
money and Government
spending perfectly
perceived

5 6 .6

6.1

1.0

5 .0

1.2

* Excluding effect of auto strike, CEA estimate.

FEDERAL RESERVE

B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

tions. Again, the St. Louis projections were more
accurate when based on policy plans than when
calculated with policy realizations. Nevertheless, de­
spite the error in projecting total spending, the St.
Louis methodology forecast prices to rise 5 per cent
from 1969 to 1970, or only slightly less than realized.
Due to the slow short-run response of prices to mone­
tary and fiscal actions in the St. Louis model, these
price projections were relatively insensitive to the dif­
ference between policy plans and realizations.

MARCH

Federal Budget Program for Calendar 1971
The budget plan for calendar 1971 calls for a sur­
plus in the high-employment (N IA ) budget of $6.5
billion, as estimated by this Bank.8 A surplus of this
magnitude would be about the same as in 1970. W hen
compared with calendar 1969, the budget plan ap­
pears slightly more expansionary, but compared with
the 1966 to 1968 period, when the high-employment
budget was substantially in deficit, the budget for
calendar 1971 appears much less expansionary.

St. Louis model projections of real product growth
were in error by about the same amount as the CEA .
By past projection experience, neither of the projec­
tions for real product, by the C EA or by the St. Louis
methodology, were in substantial error. The differ­
ences between the projections by the C E A and St.
Louis of real product translated into larger discrepan­
cies in the projection of unemployment. The C EA
correctly foresaw the rise in unemployment but under­
estimated its magnitude. The St. Louis model forecast
the rise with considerable accuracy, even with a pro­
jection of real product growth similar to that by the
C EA .
Sum mary — The C E A projected quite closely the
growth of total spending, even though they under­
estimated the rise in Federal purchases from 1969 to
1970 by $3 billion. Their errors were significant, how­
ever, with respect to projections of inflation and
unemployment. The magnitude of these errors was
typical of most forecasts, including those of large
econom etric models. As indicated in the 1971 C EA
A nnual Report, the inflation proved to be much more
stubborn than anticipated. As a result, all of the ad­
vance in total spending manifested itself in price in­
creases, and output did not grow at all, resulting in a
much sharper rise in unemployment than anticipated.
The St. Louis model, which has built into it a very
slow price response, also underestimated the rate of
inflation. F o r this one year, however, it cam e closer
than the C E A in its projection of inflation and un­
employment, despite the fact that the St. Louis model
did not do as well in projecting the change in total
spending.

Economic Goals and Policy Plans for 1971
The Administration has set targets of 4.5 per cent
unemployment and a 3 per cent rate of inflation by
second quarter 1972. To achieve these goals, a 9 per
cent advance of total spending from calendar 1970 to
1971 has been projected. This section summarizes the
Federal Budget program for calendar 1971, and then
evaluates the Administration’s plan with the aid of the
St. Louis methodology.



1971

H ig h - E m p lo y m e n t B u dg e t Surplus or Deficit
as a Per Cent of H ig h - E m p lo y m e n t G N P *

jA----

( V

1964

1965

1966

1967

1968

1969

1970

.

/A

1971

,

1972

So u rce s: U .S . D epartm ent o f C om m erce, C ou ncil of Econom ic A d vise rs , a nd Fe d e ra l R eserve Bank
of St. Louis
*H ig h .E m p lo y m e n t G N P is P o te n tia l G N P in c u rre n t d o lla rs .
la te s t d a ta p lo tted : 4th q u a rte r 1970; d o sh e d lin e in d ic a te s h a lf- y e a r e stim ates b y this Bank ba se d
on the fis c a l 1972 F e d e r a l B udget and the 1971 A n n u a l R e p o rt o f the C o u n c il of
Econom ic A d vise rs.

E xpend itures — The budget plan projects an 8.4 per
cent increase in Federal expenditures from calendar
1970 to calendar 1971. This increase would be up
slightly from the 6.6 per cent rise in 1969 and 1970,
but much less than the 14 per cent average rate of
advance in Federal spending from 1965 to 1968. The
1971 increase in Federal expenditures translates into
about a 1 per cent advance in real terms, compared
with a 1.3 per cent decrease in real terms in 1970.
Defense spending is projected to decline about
5 per cent in calendar 1971, compared with a 3 per
cent decline in 1970 and a 1 per cent increase in
1969. The average annual rate of advance from 1965
to 1968 was a very rapid 16 per cent. Estim ates for
1971 apparently reflect declines in Vietnam spending,
8The Administration’s budget program is discussed as it relates
to calendar 1971 rather than fiscal 1972, with estimates for
calendar 1971 prepared by this Bank. Furthermore, to be
consistent with the GNP accounts, which represent the frame­
work in which the CEA projections are made, the Federal
sector of the national income accounts (NIA budget), rather
than the unified budget, is used to summarize Federal budget
plans. For a summary of the budget program on a fiscal year
basis, along with rate-of-change triangles, see the quarterly
release of this Bank, “Federal Budget Trends,” February 1971.
Page 15

FEDERAL

R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

MARCH

though no figures are given in the budget as to their
magnitude.
Federal spending on civilian programs, that is, non­
defense spending, is planned to rise 16.5 per cent
from calendar 1970 to 1971. This increase would
follow increases of 15 per cent in 1970 and 9 per cent
in 1969. From 1965 to 1968, nondefense spending rose
at a 12 per cent average annual rate. 1971 expendi­
tures for nondefense purposes reflect proposed in­
creases in social security benefits and a pay raise for
Federal employees, both effective January 1, and an
increase in grants-in-aid to state and local govern­
ments (general revenue-sharing), effective O ctober 1.
R eceipts — Federal receipts on a national income
accounts basis are projected to rise $18 billion from
calendar 1970 to 1971, or by 9 per cent. This projec­
tion is closely associated with the assumption about
the growth of total spending (G N P).

1971

Fiscal M e a s u r e s
(+) S u rp lu s ; (-} D e fic it
Q u a rte rly To ta ls a t A n n u a I R a te s

B illio n s of D o lla rs

B illio n s o f D o lla rs

20

20

1964

1965

1966

1967

1968

1969

1970

1971

1972

Sources: U .S. Department of Com m erce, Council of Econom ic A d vise rs, a n d Fe d e ral Reserve Bank
of St. Louis
L ate st d a ta p lo tted : 4th q u a rte r 1970; d a sh e d lines indicate ha lf-ye a r estim ates by this Bank ba se d
on the fisca l 1972 Federal B udget and the 1971 A n n u a l Report of the Council of
Econom ic A d v is e rs .

Table V

P la n n e d C h a n g e s in F e d e ra l Receipts— 1 9 7 0 to 1971
N a t i o n a l Inco m e Accounts B u dg e t
(B illio n s of D ollars)
Change in total receipts .............................................................. -..................

$ 1 7 .8

Change due to growth ................................................. .......................

19.6

Change due to tax rate changes .... -..................................... — 1.8
Personal tax and nontax receipts ........... .......................

— 5 .3

Corporate profits tax accruals ................. ..........................

— 2.6

Indirect business tax and nontax accruals ............

0 .2

Contributions of social insurance ................. ................

5 .9

Table V shows the sources of increased receipts for
1971. Changes in tax policy include (1 ) the sched­
uled increase in social security taxes, which was effec­
tive January 1, (2 ) a proposed expansion of the base
for social security taxes, from $7,800 to $9,000, (3 )
continuing the effects of the T ax Reform A ct of 1969,
and (4 ) the effect of liberalized depreciation allow­
ances, tending to reduce receipts. The combined effect
of these tax changes is expected to decrease receipts
by $1.8 billion in 1971. All of the expected increase in
receipts reflects the rapid expansion of economic
activity projected by the Administration.
Surp lu s/deficit position — The NIA budget is pro­
jected to be in deficit by $10.6 billion in calendar
1971, com pared with a deficit of $11.1 billion in 1970.
Since the NIA budget is influenced to a considerable
extent by the p ace of econom ic activity, it is useful to
estimate receipts and expenditures on a high-employment basis. By eliminating the effects of deviations
in real economic activity from high-employment,
budget plans can be assessed more accurately in terms
of their econom ic impact.
Digitized for Page
FRASER
16


On a high-employment basis, the planned NIA
budget indicates a $6.5 billion surplus for calendar
1971. This estimate is about the same as for 1970,
indicating no change in the degree of fiscal stimulus
from 1970 to 1971.
The Federal budget program for calendar 1971 ap­
pears to contain about the same amount of stimulus
as did the program in 1970. W hether the im pact of
such a program will turn out to be essentially un­
changed from 1970 depends largely upon Congres­
sional action as well as the lag structure of economic
reaction. Developments in Southeast Asia and domes­
tic demands for Government: programs are of vital
importance in determining the actual course of F e d ­
eral spending.

Evaluation of 1971 National
Economic Plan
Using the St. Louis methodology, two questions are
considered in the evaluation of the 1971 economic
plan of the Administration: ( 1 ) whether the price
and unemployment goals are consistent with the pro­
jected increase in total spending; and (2 ) w hether the
projected increase in total spending is consistent with
proposed stabilization policies.
Feasibility of total spending goal — Table VI shows
the results for the St. Louis model for four different
combinations of policies:
(1 ) an increase of Federal spending as proposed
in the budget and an expansion of the money
stock at a 6 per cent annual rate;

FEDERAL RESERVE

MARCH

B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

Table VI

Projected C h a n g e s in T o ta l S p e n d in g ( G N P ) —
1970 to 1971
Billions of
Per Cent
Dollars
Increase
CEA Projection

(2 / 2 / 7 1 )

$ 8 8 .2

1 9 7 0 to 1 9 7 2
1971 to 1972
Billions of
Per Cent
Dollars
Increase

9 .0 %

$ 1 2 0 .9

11.4%

St. Louis Model Projections
1 ) with 6 per cent money growth
and Government spending
based on fiscal 1972 budget
(C EA policy assum ptions)

6 7 .6

6 .9

2)

with 8 per cent money growth
and Government spending
based on fiscal 1972 budget

7 4 .4

7 .6

3)

with 6 per cent money
growth and accelerated
Governm ent spending

7 1 .4

7 .3

4)

with 8 per cent money
growth and accelerated
Government spending

7 8 .2

8 .0

(2 ) an increase of Federal spending as proposed
and a faster 8 per cent rate of expansion of the
money stock;
(3 ) a faster increase of Federal spending than pro­
posed and a 6 per cent rate of expansion of the
money stock; and
(4 ) both a faster increase of Federal spending than
proposed and an 8 per cent rate of expansion
of the money stock.
According to the St. Louis methodology (T able V I),
the planned policies would not yield a growth in total
spending of 9 per cent in 1971. Since the model is
subject to error, the question arises whether this dis­
crepancy is within the range of possible error. F o r this
purpose, the model was used to forecast one year
ahead, quarter by quarter from 1966 through 1970.
The largest error in prediction of total spending was
$8 billion, or substantially less than the $20 billion
discrepancy between the C E A projection and the St.
Louis model projection based on their policy assump­
tions.” The possibility of error in the St. Louis model
cannot be ruled out, but it seems most likely that
continuation of monetary and fiscal stimulus in 1971
of roughly the same magnitude as we had in 1970
will not foster a sharp acceleration in growth of total
spending in 1971. Because the monetary and fiscal
restraint of 1968 and 1969 is fading into the past,
total spending is projected to advance more rapidly
in 1971 than in 1970, but not markedly so.
!lThese forecasts were based on estimation of the total spend­
ing equation for a sample period through 1966, then 1967,
etc., and using actual money and expenditures to generate
the forecasts outside of the sample period. Perhaps more
relevant for the current situation is the performance of the
model around business cycle turning points. Within the sam­
ple period of 1953 to 1970, the average error for the fourquarter period following business cycle troughs was $5.3
billion, or 1 per cent of GNP in the four-quarter period
ending with the trough quarter.



7 7 .9

7.5

1971

To determine if some other combina­
tion of policies might not yield the
targeted growth of total spending, the
im pact of alternative policy assump­
tions was examined with the St. Louis
methodology. Table VI suggests that
the combination of more expansionary
monetary and fiscal actions yields a
total spending projection closer to the
C E A ’s, but it still falls short by a sub­
stantial amount.

Implications of C E A total spending
goal — The 1970 economic plan was in
error primarily with respect to its dis­
8 1 .9
7.8
tribution of total spending change be­
tween prices and real product. To
10 3 .5
9.8
assess the implications of the St. Louis
methodology for real product, prices, and unemploy­
ment, the C E A projections of total spending were
assumed for the St. Louis model. W ithout concern
for how the total spending is going to be achieved,
Table V II shows the implied paths for real product,
prices, and unemployment.10
9 9 .5

9.5

According to these estimates based on the St. Louis
model, real product would rise about 4 per cent from
calendar 1970 to calendar 1971, com pared with the
C E A projection of 4.6 per cent. As a result, the St.
Louis model suggests unemployment would average
5.5 per cent in calendar 1971, or slightly above the
C E A projection of 5.3 per cent. Furthermore, the St.
Louis model indicates that the C E A projection of total
spending would lead to a 4.9 per cent advance of
prices in 1971, com pared with the C E A estimate of
4.2 per cent.
The difference between the C E A projections and
those based on the St. Louis methodology becomes
more evident when examined with reference to 1972.
The C E A projections imply that real product would
continue its strong advance in 1972, rising 7.7 per cent
above 1971, and push the unemployment rate down to
a 4.4 per cent average for the year. The St. Louis
model also indicates a rapid increase of real product,
but at a slower 6 p er cent rate of advance. Unemploy­
m ent would be reduced for 1972 to 5.1 per cent of the
labor force. In sharp contrast with the C E A projection
of a 3.4 per cent increase in prices in 1972, the St.
Louis model shows a 5.2 per cent increase.
10Given the proposed Federal budget program, the St. Louis
model indicates that a 12 per cent rate of increase in
money beginning in first quarter 1971 would be required
to achieve the CEA projection of a 9 per cent increase in
GNP in calendar 1971.
Page 17

Table VII

Projected C h a n g e s i a Spe nding , O u t p u t , Prices a n d U n e m p l o y m e n t —

1 9 7 0 to 1 9 7 2

(Per C e n t*)
1971
1

1972

II

III

IV

Year

1

ii

III

IV

Year

1 3 .0 %
9 .4
3.2
5 .7

1 1.5%
6.8
4 .4
5 .5

1 1.8°/!
7 .7
3.8
5 .2

11.3%
7.3
3 .7
4.9

9 .0 %
4 .6
4.2
5.3

11 .7 %
8 .0
3.4
4 .7

11.2%
7.8
3.1
4.5

1 1.0%
7.7
3.1
4.2

10.5%
7.5
2.8
4 .0

1 1.4%
7 .7
3 .4
4.4

with CEA total spending
assumption
Total Spending
Real Product
Prices
Unemployment Rate

13.0
8.5
4.1
5 .6

1 1.5
6.1
5.1
5 .6

11.8
6.3
5.2
5.5

11.3
5.9
5 .2
5 .4

9 .0
3 .9
4.9
5.5

1 1.7
6.2
5.2
5.3

11.2
5 .9
5.1
5.1

1 1.0
5.8
5.0
5 .0

10.5
5 .5
4 .9
4 .9

1 1.4
6 .0
5.2
5.1

with 6 per cent money growth
and Government spending based
on fiscal 1972 budget
(C E A policy assum ptions)
Total Spending
Real Product
Prices
Unemployment Rate

11.1
7.6
3.2
5 .6

6.4
2.0
4.3
5.8

9.1
4 .7
4.2
5.9

7.2
3.0
4.1
5 .9

6.9
2.5
4.3
5.8

6 .9
2.9
3 .9
6 .0

8.1
4 .4
3 .7
6.1

7.3
3 .7
3.4
6.1

7.0
3 .7
3.2
6.1

7.5
3.5
3.8
6.1

CEA Projection (2 / 2 / 7 1 ) * *
Total Spending
Real Product
Prices
Unemployment Rate
St. Louis Model Projections
1)

2)

*P e r cent changes for total spending, output and prices are at compounded annual rates : unemployment rates are levels.
♦♦Quarterly pattern estimated by this Bank based on the 1971 Annual R ep o rt o f the Council o f Econom ic A dvisers and amplifying statements
by the CEA.

Summary

A c t u a l a n d Potential Real Product
Ratio S c a le
B illio n s of D o lla rs
900

Ratio S c a le
B illio n s o f D o lla rs
900

Q u a r te r ly T o ta ls a t A n n u a l R ates
S e a s o n a lly A d ju s te d

The Administration has forecast that the U. S. eco­
nomy in 1971 will attain reductions of unemployment
and inflation simultaneously. To achieve these goals,
a rapid expansion of total spending has been proposed.
According to methodology developed at this Bank,
the projected increase in total spending is not consist­
ent with the policy actions proposed by die Admin­
istration. A much slower increase is more likely.
Furtherm ore, when the targeted increase of total
spending is accepted (which is only possible in the
St. Louis model with a very rapid acceleration of
monetary an d /o r fiscal stimidus), the goals for un­
employment and prices also appear too optimistic.
Our model suggests that such a policy of rapid spend­
ing growth would lower unemployment, but inflation
would continue unabated.

1954

1956

1958

1960

1962

1964

1966

1968

1970

1972

S o u rc e s : U .S . D e p a rtm e n t of C o m m e rc e , C o u n c il o f Econom ic A d v is e r s , a n d F e d e r a l
R e se rv e B a n k of Sf. Louis
[^ P o ten tia l G N P in 1958 d o lla r s , o s o r ig in a lly fo rm u la te d b y the C ou n cil of Eco n om ic
A d v is e r s . B a s e p e rio d is m id-1955. R ate of gro w th from IV /1 9 5 3 to IV /196 2 is 3 .5 % ,
IV /1 962 to IV / J 9 6 5
IV /1 9 7 0 to IV /1971
(2 A c tu a l G N P in 1958
Latest d a ta p lo tte d :

is 3 .7 5 % , iV /1 9 6 5 to IV /19 6 9 is 4 % , IV /1 9 6 9 to IV /1 9 7 0 is 4 .3 % ,
is 4 .4 % .
d o lla rs .
P o te n tia l G N P p r o je c te d th ro u g h 4th q u a rte r 1971
A c tu a l G N P , 4th q u a rte r 1970; d a s h e d lin e in d ic a te s h a lf- y e a r e stim a te s
b y this B a n k b a s e d on the fis c a l 1972 F e d e r a l B u d g e t a n d the 1971
A n n u a l R e p o rt o f the C o u n c il o f Eco n om ic A d v is e rs .

In summary, introducing the C E A projection of
total spending into the St. Louis model leads to the
conclusion that such a policy of rapid spending growth
would provide slight gains in reducing unemploy­
ment. However, such gains would be at the cost of no
gains in the battle against inflation.
Digitized forPage
FRASER
18


The nation is faced with a serious dilemma, but a
search for quick and easy solutions may be selfdefeating. The current inflation developed persistently
over a substantial period of time. F o r this reason the
current problem defies a fast and smooth adjustment
to high employment with price stability. M onetary
actions consisting of a 5 to 6 per cent annual rate of
growth in money, and fiscal actions consisting of an 8
per cent annual rate of advance in Federal expendi­
tures, appear to be consistent with an orderly, but
slow, return to a viable high-employment path. The
post W orld W ar II economic experience does not indi­
cate that the present unemployment-inflation dilemma
can be solved as quickly as the C E A has suggested.
An A ppendix to this article is on the next page.

A P P E N D IX

ALTERNATIVE BUDGET CONCEPTS

All references to the Federal budget in the preceding
article are in terms of the national income accounts
budget. This appendix discusses three budget concepts
to provide the reader with an understanding of their
interrelations.

Unified Budget
The unified budget was adopted as the Government’s
basic planning document in January 1968, replacing both
the administrative and consolidated cash budgets. E x ­
penditures and receipts are recorded on a cash basis (when
the checks are issued or the payment received). This
budget will be presented on an accrual basis after ac­
counting procedures are revised. N et transactions of
trust funds are included in this budget. All lending ac­
tivities of the Government as well as certain Governmentsponsored agencies are described in the unified budget,
but only certain direct loans are included in the figures
for total outlays (expenditures plus net lending). (F o r a
com plete discussion of Federal lending activities see
“Special Analysis E ” in S p ecia l A n alyses: B u d g et o f th e
U. S. G overn m en t, F isca l Y ear 1972).
The unified budget is presented to Congress for ap­
proval by the President in January or February of every
year, for the fiscal year ending June 30, eighteen months
hence. Also included are revised figures for the current
fiscal year ending approximately six months later. The
Office of Management and Budget normally revises the
budget figures for the coming fiscal years in the spring
and fall of every year. T he current data are published
by the Treasury D epartm ent on a monthly basis.

National Income Accounts Budget
The national income accounts (N IA ) budget presents
the receipts and expenditures of the Federal Govern­
ment as an integrated part of the economy, as represented
by the national income and product accounts. The major
differences betw een the NIA budget and the unified
budget are: ( 1 ) the NIA budget excludes all lending
transactions; ( 2 ) tax receipts in the NIA budget are, in
general, recorded on an accrual basis (corporate income



taxes are accrued when the income is earned rather than
when the Government receives payment, and personal
income taxes, most of which are withheld from earnings
or paid on a quarterly basis, are recorded when the
taxpayer makes paym ent); (3 ) on the expenditure side,
defense purchases are recorded when the items are re­
ceived by the Government rather than when they are
produced or paid for.
The NIA budget is developed in conjunction with the
rest of the national income accounts by the D epartment
of Commerce. It is published on a quarterly basis, sea­
sonally adjusted at annual rates. ( “Special Analysis A” in
the fiscal 1972 budget contains a more detailed descrip­
tion of the reconciliation of the unified budget with the
NIA budget.)

High-Employment Budget
The high-employment budget is based on the NIA
budget; however, it is adjusted to remove the effects of
the level of econom ic activity on the NIA budget. For
example, during a recession NIA receipts will tend to
fall in response to lower levels of income, and NIA ex­
penditures for unemployment benefits will rise. T he re­
sulting move toward deficit in the NIA budget, however,
implies expansionary policies when, in fact, the opposite
might be occurring.
T h e high-employment budget reflects primarily dis­
cretionary changes in fiscal policy, such as a change in
the tax rate structure or a change in the pattern of ex­
penditures. The high-employment budget estimates pub­
lished by this Bank are based on potential gross national
product as defined by the Council of Econom ic Advisers.
In their 1970 A nnual R ep ort, the C E A defined potential
GNP as the output of the economy at a 3.8 per cent
unemployment rate. Incom e shares and tax rates, esti­
mated at high-employment levels, are applied to poten­
tial GN P in current dollars to arrive at the high-employment budget data. Such data are not published regularly
by any Government agency. Estim ates prepared by this
Bank are published in the quarterly release, “Federal
Budget Trends.”
Page 19

The Implementation Problem of Monetary Policy
by A L B E R T E . B U R G E R
D u ring the last two decades, there has b e en considerable controversy regarding the appro­
priate m ethod of im plem enting monetary policy. O ne approach em phasizes market interest rates;
the other, monetary aggregates. This article sets forth the basic issues underlying this controversy.
It demonstrates the m anner in w hich the m arket interest rate approach can lead to perverse
monetary actions; w hereas the monetary aggrega te approach redu ces the likelihood of such a
result.

D
e C ID IN G UPON an ultimate objective for mon­
etary policy, such as a more rapid increase in employ­
ment or a reduction in inflation, is only one part of
monetary policy. The policymakers must also imple­
ment such a policy decision. A considerable amount
of study has been devoted to this problem, resulting
in numerous technical papers, several conferences,
and some rather sharp differences of opinion among
economists about the best way to implement policy
decisions. This article explains this problem in a
simplified form and highlights some of the areas of
disagreement.
First, the implementation problem is outlined. The
use of indicators and operational targets as an aid in
implementing policy is then discussed. Next, two
hypotheses about the way in which the Federal R e­
serve’s policy actions are transmitted through the
econom ic system are presented. Finally, this frame­
work is used to illustrate how alternative policy pre­
scriptions can develop.

The Implementation Problem
The monetary policy process consists of two broad
phases. The policymakers must first decide upon the
movements they desire to achieve in their ultimate
policy objectives such as prices, output, and employ­

Page
20



ment. Second, they must decide how to manipulate
policy instruments such as open market operations,
reserve requirements, and the discount rate to achieve
these desired effects on their ultimate objectives.
This is the implementation phase of policy.
To analyze the implementation problem w e shall
use the physical analogy of heating a room with a
steam furnace. First, let us set up the heating system,
as shown in Exhibit 1. Our policymaker is Mr. Home­
owner. His policy problem is to maintain the tem pera­
ture in his house at a comfortable level. H e uses his
room thermometer to give him a m easurement of
whether the room tem perature is moving in the direc­
tion he desires (th e room is getting hotter or cold er).
The means by which he implements a decision to
change the room tem perature is to adjust the fuel
control lever. If, for example, he wants the room
tem perature to rise, he adjusts the fuel control level
to increase the flow of fuel to the furnace. He then
judges w hether he has correctly adjusted the fuel
lever by watching the room thermometer. H e knows
there is a lag between the time he adjusts the
fuel control lever and when the room temperature
begins to rise. Taking this lag into account, if the
reading on the room thermometer does not rise suf­
ficiently, he would again adjust the fuel control lever.

E x h ib it I

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

It is worth emphasizing that the goal of Mr. H om e­
owner is a comfortable room temperature, not some
reading on the thermometer. The thermometer is
only a device that helps him to monitor the heating
process.
However, let us assume that Mr. Homeowner has
an old furnace, and he is not confident that it works
exactly the way the manufacturer claims it should.
He installs two intermediate gauges to help him in his
control process; a fuel flow gauge to monitor the
flow of fuel between the fuel supply and the furnace,
and a steam pressure gauge on the furnace to monitor
the operation of the furnace. For example, the fuel
flow gauge helps the homeowner check for leaks in
the fuel line. If this gauge registers a leak, then the
homeowner knows that the fuel flow must be increased
to maintain the same heat from the furnace.

Monetary Policy
Now let us convert this discussion into an analogy
with the implementation problem of monetary policy.
The fuel control lever becomes the policy instru­
ments of the Federal Reserve; open market opera­
tions, reserve requirements, and the discount rate.
The furnace becomes the financial system, and the
room becomes the real sector of the economy. Mr.
Homeowner becomes the Federal Open Market Com ­
mittee, and the policy objective becomes something
such as employment, prices, and real output, instead
of room temperature. The room thermometer becomes
a measuring instrument such as the unemployment
rate, consumer price index, and GNP in constant
prices.
M onetary policy implementation would be much
easier if there were complete information about the
way in which policy instruments, financial variables,
and real variables are interrelated. It would only
involve manipulating the policy instruments in a way
that would have a known and desired effect on the
levels and rates of change of the ultimate objectives
of monetary policy. Just as our homeowner, with
complete information about how his furnace operates,
would know where to set the fuel control lever to
get the desired room temperature, the policymakers
would know how close, by manipulating the policy
instruments, they could come to achieving their de­
sired ultimate policy objectives. There would be no
possibility of a “slip twixt cup and lip.” The policy
instruments could simply be set at definite values,
and the desired goals of policy would be achieved
subject to any constraints.



MARCH

1971

Indicators and Operational Targets
The indicator-opcrational target approach is a
pragm atic method of improving the implementation
of monetary policy. It starts with the fact that no one
has perfect information about the way policy actions
filter through the economy, are modified by other
factors, and ultimately influence real output, prices,
and employment. Econom ic research, however, has
provided some theoretical and empirical informa­
tion about these linkages. The indicator-operational
target approach attempts to employ this information
to guide the process by which policy is implemented.
Policymakers are concerned with two major ques­
tions when implementing policy. First, what effects
are monetary influences exerting on the ultimate pol­
icy objectives? Are monetary influences exerting a
more, a less, or an unchanged expansionary influence
on the future rates of change of prices and employ­
ment? An indicator provides information about this
question. Second, policymakers want to know how
they should manipulate their policy instruments to
insure that monetary influences are modified to con­
tinue exerting the effect desired by the policymakers.
An operational target provides a method for answer­
ing this second question.

Indicators
A monetary policy indicator is an econom ic variable
that provides information about the current thrust of
the financial sector, including Federal Reserve a c­
tions, on future movements in the ultimate policy
objectives. Em pirical evidence confirms that the ef­
fect of monetary policy actions on the ultimate policy
objectives is distributed over time. Hence, the F e d ­
eral Reserve cannot accurately judge the degree of
“ease” or “restraint” its current policy actions are
exerting on the ultimate objectives of policy by look­
ing directly at measuring instruments such as the
consumer price index and the unemployment rate.
Current changes in the ultimate objectives primarily
reflect the effects of policy actions taken in previous
periods.
A further point must be clarified. Policymakers do
not need an indicator to tell them their current
intent of policy. They know w hat they intend to
accomplish with their policy actions.1 Policymakers
'Since the intent of current policy is not made public until
about 90 days after the FOMC Meeting in the “Record of
Policy Actions of the FOMC” appearing in the Federal Re­
serve Bulletin, a measure of policy intent may be of interest
to market participants. However, this is a different problem
from the one with which this article is concerned.
Page 21

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

want information about the influence their past policy
actions are exerting on the future course of the
economy.
The choice of an indicator involves choosing some
financial variable that consistently provides reliable
information about the current influence of the finan­
cial sector, including Federal Reserve actions, on
future economic activity. In general terms, this re­
quires that the following relationship holds between
the indicator and the ultimate policy objectives:
A change in the magnitude of the indicator is fol­
lowed by a predictable change in the magnitude of
the ultimate objectives of monetary policy.

An economic variable that meets the above crite­
rion can serve as a “scale” that permits policy advisers
to make meaningful statements about the relative
effects of different policy actions on the ultimate
policy objectives. It provides a means of relative
comparision of different sets of policy actions; not
necessarily an absolute means of comparison.
The usefulness of an indicator hinges on whether
or not it consistently supplies reliable information to
the policymakers. If at times the ultimate policy
objectives move in a direction opposite to the direc­
tion predicted using a given indicator, then in such
instances the indicator provides false information to
the policymakers about the thrust of their policy
actions on the ultimate objectives of monetary policy.

Operational Targets
An operational target for monetary policy is an
economic variable the Federal Reserve attempts to
control directly in its day-to-day money market oper­
ations. Following each Federal Open Market Com ­
mittee (F O M C ) meeting, the Committee issues a
directive to the New York Federal Reserve Bank. The
day-to-dav implementation of open market opera­
tions is carried out by the Trading Desk at the New
York Bank. In general, these directives have tradi­
tionally been worded in broad terms such as:
. . . maintain the prevailing firm conditions in the
money and short-term credit markets.

Although the directive may appear to be worded
in somewhat ambiguous terms, the Trading Desk
does not randomly buy and sell securities. It chooses
some financial variable or variables to control and
aims its day-to-day operations in the money market
at controlling this operational target. The operational

Page 22


MARCH

1971

target, to be of greatest usefulness, should satisfy
three basic criteria as follows:
(1 ) T he Federal Reserve should be able to accur­
ately measure the magnitude of the operational
target over very short periods of time.
(2 ) T he Federal Reserve should be able to control
the operational target by manipulating policy
instruments. In a very short period of time,
the Federal Reserve should be able to offset
any other factors acting to change the magnitude
of the operational target.
(3 ) Changes in the magnitude of the operational
target over an intermediate period of time
should dominate changes in tire magnitude of
the economic variable chosen as an indicator.

The question may arise as to why the concept of
an operational target has to be introduced once an
indicator is chosen. W hy cannot the Federal Reserve
aim day-to-day operations directly at the indicator?
The necessity for the introduction of operational
targets, like indicators, arises basically from the lack
of perfect information. At a minimum, the Trading
Desk must have some means of evaluating whether
its day-to-day operations in the money market are in
accord with the intent expressed by the Federal Open
Market Committee. To maximize the effectiveness of
its daily operations in the money market, the Federal
Reserve needs accurate information regarding the in­
fluence of these actions. In the short-run many other
factors usually influence the movement of intermedi­
ate variables such as the money stock and interest
rates. If these intermediate variables are used as
operational targets, then the short-run influence of
other factors frequently causes these variables to
transmit misleading information to the policymakers
about the effect their day-to-day policy actions are
exerting on the intermediate-term movements of the
indicator variables.
In our furnace analogy, the operational target be­
comes the fuel supply. An indicator is a gauge set
in the process by which monetary policy actions are
transmitted to the real sector of the economy. Usually
the indicator is “attached” to the financial sector. It
gives the Federal Reserve a reading on how m uch of
the fuel they are supplying (through open market
operations, reserve requirements and the discount
rate) is being converted into energy to drive the
economy.

Two Hypotheses
The lack of complete information about the way
policy actions are transmitted to ultimate objectives

FEDERAL RESERVE

B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

MARCH

requires the formulation of proposed explanations
(hypotheses) about the process. A person’s choice of
an indicator and an operational target usually de­
pends upon his hypothesis about the way policy
actions are transmitted through the financial sector
into the real sector. D isagreem ent among economists
as to the appropriate choice of an indicator and op­
erational target is basically a disagreement as to the
correct representation of the m onetary policy trans­
mission mechanism.2
Two frequently used hypotheses about the trans­
mission process of monetary policy, the Market In ­
terest Rate Hypothesis and the Money Supply H y­
pothesis, are compared in Exhibit II. The policy in­
struments and ultimate objectives available to policy­
makers are the same regardless of whedier they use
one of these hypotheses or any other hypothesis about
the transmission process. There may be differences
between advocates of the two hypotheses, however,
concerning the relative importance of different policy
instruments and ultimate objectives.3
In the Market Interest Rate Hypothesis, the in­
dicator is market interest rates. An econom ic variable
such as free reserves (referred to as net borrowed
reserves when borrowings exceed excess reserves) is
generally chosen as the operational target. In a
broader context, free reserves can be viewed as a
substitute for a number of short-term money market
factors, such as the Federal funds rate, “tone and
feel of the market,” and the Treasury bill rate. In the
Money Supply Hypothesis, the indicator is the growth
rate of the money stock ( currency plus demand
deposits of the nonbank public). The operational
target is the net source base, total source base, or
monetary base, as computed by the St. Louis Federal
Reserve Bank.4

1971

Exh ibit

POLICY INST RUMENTS
O pe n M ark e t O p e ra tio n s
R e s e rv e R e q u ire m e n t s

i

*

D iscou nt Rate
R e g u l a ti o n Q

Free

Base

R e s erv es

M oney

*

p g E lB E ffS T E

k

2In some cases, individuals may accept an economic variable,
such as money, as an indicator based solely on empirical evi­
dence, and still not accept a hypothesis in which money
plays a key role in determining economic activity.
3For example, many supporters of the Money Supply Hy­
pothesis have traditionally placed more reliance on open mar­
ket operations and advocated very limited use of the other
policy instruments, particularly Regulation Q.
increases in Federal Reserve credit (holdings of securities,
discounts and advances, and float), the gold stock, and
Treasury currency outstanding increase the stock of source
base. Increases in Treasury deposits at the Federal Reserve,
Treasury cash holdings, and other deposits and other Federal
Reserve accounts decrease the stock of source base.
The net source base is total source base net of member
bank borrowings. The monetary base is total source base ad­
justed for reserve requirement changes. See Leonall C.
Andersen and Jerry L. Jordan, “The Monetary Base — Ex­
planations and Analytical Use,” this Review (August 1968),
pp. 7-14.



Exhibit III illustrates the analogy between the heat­
ing system and the monetary policy mechanism.
The Federal Reserve looks at a wide range of data,
including the unemployment rate, consumer and
wholesale price indexes, and real GNP to evaluate
w hat is happening to employment, prices, and real
output. The Federal Reserve then adjusts open m arket
operations, reserve requirements, or the discount rate
to achieve its objectives with respect to employment,
Page 23

MARCH

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

1971

E x h i b i t III

(Room Thermometer)

(Steam Pressure G a u g e )

) U nem ploym ent

I n d ic a to r
M e a s u r e d in units

Rate

of

I (2) Price Ind exes
---- -

1
%

(Fuel C o n tro l Lever)

(F u rn a c e )

(Fuel S up ply)

—

O pe ra tio na l Target

(Room)
—

F in a nc ia l System

-►
R e a l Sector

(1) O p e n M a r k e t
O p e ra tio n s
(2) Reserve
Require m ents

(Fuel Flow G a u g e )
(1) M o n e y M u l t i p l i e r
(2) T r e a s u r y Bill Rate

(3) D is c o u n t Rate

(Room Tem perature)
(1) E m p l o y m e n t
(2) P r ic e s
(3) R e a l O u t p u t

prices, and real output. By altering the policy instru­
ments, the Federal Reserve changes the flow of fuel
to the economy. The fuel supply is measured in units
of base money or units of free reserves. To analyze
the future effect of these actions on the real economy,
the Federal Reserve then would look at its gauge on
the financial sector, either the growth of the money
stock or the level of m arket interest rates. To further
monitor the process, the Federal Reserve may use
another gauge, equivalent to the fuel flow gauge, such
as the Treasury bill rate for the M arket Interest Rate
Hypothesis or the money multiplier for the Money
Supply Hypothesis.5 This type of gauge signals leak­
ages in the flow of fuel to the financial system.
Examining Exhibit II and Exhibit III, we can see
.where some differences of opinion might arise about
the influence of Federal Reserve actions. F o r one
thing, the two hypotheses in Exhibit II measure the
fuel supply by different means. One viewpoint meas­
ures the flow of fuel in terms of base, the other in
terms of free reserves. Under the Money Supply
Hypothesis, the Federal Reserve is supplying more
3The money multiplier summarizes the influence on the money
supply process of all those factors other than changes in the
base. By monitoring the movements of the components of the
multiplier, the Federal Reserve could determine the effects
of any given growth of base on the growth of the money
stock. For example, an increase in the public’s desired hold­
ings of currency relative to demand deposits would decrease
the growth of money associated with any given growth of
base. This would be a “leakage” between the fuel supply
and the furnace. By increasing the flow of base, the Federal
Reserve could offset this influence on the money supply
process.

Page 24


fuel if the growth rate of the base increases. The
Market Interest Rate Hypothesis takes an increase
in the level of free reserves as a measure of an
acceleration in the flow of fuel.
A second area of disagreement can develop about
the manner in which the flow of fuel from the F e d ­
eral Reserve is converted into a flow of total spending.
Supporters of the Money Supply Hypothesis contend
that an increased flow of base money into the finan­
cial sector is converted into an increased growth of
the money stock, which results in an increased flow
of total spending, influencing employment, prices, and
real output. The alternative view is that an increased
level of free reserves is converted in the financial
sector into lower market interest rates, which result
in an increased flow of total spending and hence real
variables are influenced. In our analogy, this question
may be phrased, “how is fuel converted into energy
that drives the econom y?”
Supporters of the two hypotheses are monitoring
the progress of policy by different gauges, where
the gauges are attached to the same part of the
process. Since the growth of the money stock and
market interest rates frequently move in the same
directions, substantial divergences of opinion often
arise regarding the correct policy action to take to
achieve the same ultimate objective.
F o r example, suppose that the supporters of the
Market Interest Rate Hypothesis look at their in­
dicator (th e gauge on the financial system) and

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

observe that market rates are rising. If they desire
no change in the influence of policy, they may
conclude that the flow of fuel to the financial sector
will not be converted into enough energy (low
market rates) to maintain the rate of growth of real
output and employment they desire. Hence, they
would advise that policy instruments be used to raise
the level of free reserves (pum p in more fuel).
However, let us assume that the supporters of the
Money Supply Hypothesis look at their indicator and
observe that the growth rate of money is accelerating.
They conclude that the fuel being supplied by F e d ­
eral Reserve actions would be converted into a prog­
ressively more rapid flow of total spending, and they
advise that the policy instruments should be used to
slow the growth of the base (pum p in fuel at a
slower ra te ).
At this point a substantial divergence of opinion
about the reason for the change in market interest
rates arises between the supporters of the two hy­
potheses. This difference of analysis has important
implications for the conduct of monetary policy. The
supporters of the Market Interest Rate Hypothesis
contend that Federal Reserve policy actions are dom­
inating the movements in interest rates and that
the rise in market rates will result in a slowdown in
the real economic activity. The supporters of the
Money Supply Hypothesis, however, contend that
changes in the public’s demand for credit are domin­
ating movements in market interest rates and that
Federal Reserve actions through their influence on
total spending are influencing the public’s demand
for credit. In terms of our analogy, the Money Supply
Hypothesis asserts that the market interest rate in­
dicator is not insulated from developments in the
real sector. As the real sector heats up (employment,
real output, and prices rise), this influences the read­
ings 011 the market interest rate indicator.
To analyze the importance of this difference of
analysis, we shall first discuss the interdependence
of free reserves and the base. Then the implications
for monetary policy of this interdependence are ex­
amined. I n t h e fo l lo w in g p r e s e n t a t io n , t h e n e t s o u r c e
base

is u s e d , a n d h e r e a f t e r

m o n e y ” o r “b a s e ” a r e

w h en th e

u sed , th ey

te r m s “h a s e

w ill r e f e r to n e t

s o u r c e b a s e . The same results may be derived by

using the monetary base or source base.

MARCH

One of the components of the source base on the
u se s side of the balance sheet is member bank excess
reserves. The net source base is obtained by sub­
tracting member bank borrowings from the source
base. Therefore, the components of the net source
base may be combined so that free reserves is one of
the uses of the net source base." If the Federal
Reserve alters the level of free reserves, and if cur­
rency held by the public and vault cash in nonmember
banks are held constant, the net source base is
changed in the same direction. Free reserves and the
net source base are not independent of each other.
Actions taken by the Federal Reserve to alter or
maintain the existing value of one of these opera­
tional targets exert an influence on the other.
To analyze the importance of this interdependence,
the bank credit market is introduced. Supply and
demand conditions in this market are specified as
follows:
aB z= S = commercial banks’ supply schedule for bank
credit
D = public’s demand schedule for bank credit

The equilibrium condition for the bank credit market
is given as:
S = D

( Amount of credit banks are willing to supply =
amount of bank credit demanded by the public).
In the above expression, ( a ) denotes the bank
credit multiplier, which is the connecting link be­
tween the amount of net source base ( B ) and the
amount of credit banks are willing to extend.7
''In this article, the net source base is denoted by B. Gener­
ally this concept is denoted as B". The superscript has been
removed to avoid any confusion that might arise when the
hank’s credit supply curve is specified later.
The net source base is defined in the following manner:
B

= R"> - A + V + Ci'

where: Rm = member hank reserves = R1 + R1'
V' = vault cash holdings of nonmember banks
A = member bank borrowings from the Federal
Reserve Banks
O' = currency held by the nonhank public
R° = excess reserves of member banks
Rr = required reserves of member banks
Free reserves (K f ) are defined as follows:
Rf = Rc - A
The relationship between the net source base and free
reserves can be expressed as follows:
B = (R e - A) + R''

Interdependence
Free reserves are calculated by subtracting member
bank borrowings from member bank excess reserves.



1971

Q> + V = Rf + R' + C» + V

7The money multiplier and bank credit multiplier summarize
all those factors, other than changes in the net source base,
that affect the money supply process. When the monetary
base is used, the influence of reserve requirement changes
and member bank borrowings are included in movements in
Page 25

FEDERAL

R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

Both the hank credit multiplier, and h en ce the amount
of credit hanks are willing to extend, and the p ublic’s
dem and for bank credit are d ep en d en t upon the bank
credit market interest rate.

MARCH

1971

F ig u re I
B A N K C R E D IT M A R K E T
i

The public’s demand for bank credit and the
bank’s credit supply also depend upon a number of
other factors. F o r example, the public’s demand for
credit depends upon the expected rate of return on
real capital and upon price expectations. The banks’
supply of credit depends upon the amount and rate
of growth of the net source base. In our following
illustrations, these factors would appear as shifts in
the supply and demand schedules.
A rise in market interest rates could result from
either a shift in the credit supply curve, or a shift
in the credit demand curve, or some combination of
the two. The effect of a shift in the credit supply
curve is shown in Figure I. The credit supply curve
shifts from Si to So and, in the resulting adjustment
process, the interest rate rises to i2 and bank credit
outstanding falls to E 2.

F i g u r e II
B A N K C RE DIT M A R K E T
i

Now let us look at an alternative explanation for
the rise in market rates. Suppose that the rise in
rates was due to a shift in the public’s demand for
credit. This appears as a shift to the right of the pub­
lic’s demand curve from D , to D_>, as shown in Figure
II.
At the market interest rate ( i i ), the quantity of
bank credit demanded by the public ( E 4 ) exceeds
the amount of credit the banks are willing to supply
( E x ) , given the stock of base and the value of the
bank credit multiplier. If the Federal Reserve System
does not increase the growth rate of the net source
base in response to the rise in interest rates, but
permits market interest rates to adjust to clear the
credit market, the interest rate rises toward i2. As
the yields on loans and securities rise, the amount of
the base, instead of in the multiplier. The money multiplier
associated with the net source base is:
m1 =

________ I + k_________
(r — b) (l + t + d j + k

k and d, respectively, are the ratios of currency held by the
public and U.S. Government deposits at commercial banks to
the demand deposit component of the money stock,
r, b, and t, respectively, are the ratios of bank reserves,
member bank borrowings, and time deposits to commercial
bank deposit liabilities (excluding interbank deposits).
The reserve ratio, (through the dependence of banks’ de­
rived excess reserves), the borrowing ratio and the time de­
posit ratio are all dependent upon credit market interest rates.
For an illustration of the derivation of a money multiplier,
see Jerry L. Jordan, “Elements of Money Stock Determina­
tion,” this Review (October 1969) pp. 10-19.

Page 26


credit banks are willing to supply rises; banks reduce
their excess reserves, increase borrowings from F e d ­
eral Reserve Banks, and raise the yields they offer
to attract time deposits.8 The new equilibrium quan­
tity of bank credit demanded and supplied is E s.
The policymakers do not observe these supply
and demand curves shifting up and down: all they
observe is the increase in the reading on the market
interest rate indicator. If the policymakers believe
sWhether bank credit increases or decreases depends upon
the relationship between Regulation Q ceiling rates and the
yields banks ofFer on time deposits. If banks are already at
Regulation Q ceilings, then an increase in the public’s de­
mand for credit resulting in a rise in market interest rates
may lead to disintermediation and a decrease in bank credit.

FEDERAL RESERVE

BANK OF ST

LOUIS

the rise in market rates to
represents a leftward
shift (decrease) in the credit supply curve, as in
Figure I, and they desire no change in the influence
of policy, they may now increase their purchases of
securities to raise the level of free reserves. This pol­
icy action, according to the Market Interest Rate
Hypothesis, would shift the credit supply curve to the
right, from SL. back toward Si, and market yields
would decline from i2 back toward ip
If, however, the rise in rates resulted from a right­
ward shift of the public’s demand for credit ( as shown
in Figure II ) , then to prevent market interest rates
rising to iL>, the Federal Reserve must expand the net
source base enough to shift the banks’ credit supply
curve to S;!, as shown in Figure III. At a market inter­

MARCH

1971

Reserve would again have to increase the net source
base to maintain the market yield at i,. Under these
conditions, changes in the base are determined by
shifts in the public’s demand for bank credit via the
reaction of the monetary authorities. This implies
that the Federal Reserve would give up its control
over the money supply process. Total spending would
rise at a progressively more rapid rate and interest
rates would increase.

Implementing Policy Under
Different Economic Conditions
This section illustrates how alternative policy pre­
scriptions can arise in response to changing economic
conditions. Two different sets of conditions are speci­
fied, and the monetary policymakers are assumed to
make a policy decision based upon this information.

Condition 1
State of the economy: T he economy is operating at
full employment. An increasing proportion of
total spending is reflected in rising prices. Com­
mercial banks have raised their offering rates
on time deposits to Regulation Q ceiling rates.
Policy decision: Policymakers shift the focus of their
attention from real output and employment
to achieving stable prices.'1

est rate of i i, banks are now willing to supply a
larger amount ( E 4 ) of credit. Under these conditions,
the operational policy of raising free reserves, which
accelerates the growth of the base, results in a more
rapid expansion of bank credit and monev than would
result in the situations illustrated by Figures I and II.
Supporters of the Money Supply Hypothesis assert
that Federal Reserve actions shifting the credit supply
curve would be self-defeating, if the rise in market
rates reflected a shift in the public’s demand curve.
In a situation such as that illustrated by Figure III,
the money stock expands very rapidly. The Money
Supply Hypothesis predicts that market rates would
only temporarily remain at i , . As the feedback effect
of the rise in the money stock on total spending is
reflected in the public’s demand for credit (shifting
the demand curve further to the righ t), the Federal



Using the Market Interest Rate Hypothesis, policy­
makers reason that interest rates must be pushed
higher to slow total spending and bring aggregate
demand in line with the productive capacity of the
economy. Consequently, they adopt an operating
strategy designed to raise market rates. This involves
using policy instruments to reduce the level of free
reserves. The Trading Desk is instructed to “pursue
open market operations with a view to obtaining
tighter money market conditions.” The result of these
open market actions is to decrease the growth rate of
the base, which results in a slowing in the rate of
expansion of the money stock.
As market interest rates continue to rise, banks can
no longer compete for time deposits and disinter­
mediation begins. Consequently, the amount of earn­
ing assets banks can hold declines. In restructuring
their portfolios, banks attem pt first to reduce their
holdings of lowest-yielding assets. The time sequence
of this process would probably be declines in their
holdings of short-term Government securities first,
'•'This shift in focus of attention does not mean the policy­
makers now ignore the growth rate of real output and em­
ployment. The ability of the policymakers to achieve a price
objective is conditioned by the influence of their policy ac­
tions on real output and employment.
Page 27

F E D E R A L . R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

followed by declines in holdings of municipal securi­
ties. As long as possible, banks try to reduce holdings
of securities in order to continue to acquire business
loans.10
The impact in the credit market is a sharp decline
in the prices of municipal bonds and Government
securities. Cries of a liquidity crisis, or “credit crunch”
may arise in the financial community. Other financial
intermediaries such as savings and loan associations
are also affected by the rapidly rising interest rates.
Added to the outcry from the securities markets may
be the asserted danger of some possible failures
of savings and loan associations. The economists who
use market interest rates and other financial market
conditions as their indicators might warn, in terms
of our furnace analogy, that “there is too much pres­
sure and the furnace is going to blow up!”
The scenario outlined in this stage corresponds, in
rough form, to monetary policy in 1966. In late 1965
and early 1966, monetary policymakers moved to a
more restrictive monetary policy aimed at reducing
the “emergence of inflationary pressures.” During the
summer of 1966 the Federal Reserve pursued a prog­
ressively more restrictive policy. As market interest
rates rose above Regulation Q ceiling rates, the Board
of Governors did not raise Regulation Q ceiling rates.
As funds flowed out of banks and nonbank savings
institutions, these institutions faced a new and costly
period of portfolio adjustment. The result of these
policies culminated in August 1966 in a relatively
short-lived liquidity crisis, called the "Credit Crunch
of 1966.””
Under such conditions, the Federal Reserve policy­
makers face a very difficult decision. Using interest
rates as indicators, the information transmitted to
them is that they are following very restrictive poli­
cies. Slower growth of bank credit, and other informa­
tion transmitted to them directly from financial m ar­
kets and the financial intermediaries, reinforce this
view. The correct operating strategy now appears to
be to reverse quickly open market operations, and
“ease the pressures in the financial markets.
l0The rise in the share of loans in bank assets during periods
when banks must reduce the total volume or growth rate
of bank credit also reflects the long-run profitability of bankcustomer relations. See Edward J. Kane and Burton G.
Malkiel, “Bank Portfolio Allocation, Deposit Variability, and
the Availability Doctrine,” Quarterly Journal of Economics
(February 1965), pp. 113-34.
"S e e Albert E. Burger, “A Historical Analysis of the Credit
Crunch of 1966,” this Review ( September 1969), pp. 13-30.
1-It should also be noted that the Federal Reserve does not
make policy decisions in a vacuum. At such times the Fed­
eral Reserve may be under considerable public or govern­
ment pressure to ease its policy.

Page 28


MARCH

1971

If the money stock is being used as an indicator,
the reduced growth rate of money resulting from the
slowing in the rate of increase of the base also signals
that the policymakers have begun to exert a less
expansionary influence on the ultimate policy objec­
tives. However, the supporters of the Money Supply
Hypothesis would argue that the sharp rise in credit
market interest rates and the “above average liquidity
pressures in the financial market” do not necessarily
signal the desirability of a significant reversal of
operating strategy. The key elements of a less expan­
sionary monetary policy are a reduced expansion of
demand deposits and bank credit. This is the neces­
sary preliminary to the desired policy objectives of
reduced aggregate demand and hence a reduced
rate of increase of prices.
An analysis based on the Money Supply Hypothesis
agrees that a continued operational policy of restrict­
ing the growth rate of the base would, in the short-run,
lead to higher levels of market interest rates. Over
the intermediate-term, however, the resulting slower
growth of the money stock would exert a dampening
influence on total spending. The slowdown in total
spending would exercise a dampening influence on
the upward pressures on prices and also lead to a
reduction in the demand for credit. H ence, pursuing
such an operational target would, according to this
hypothesis, lead to lower market interest rates and
the desired ultimate policy objective of lower prices.

Condition 2
L et us now assume that the policymakers have en­
gaged in a set of policy actions that resulted in a
slowing of economic activity. This permits an analysis
of the implications of different methods of implement­
ing policy in a cyclical downturn.
State of the economy: T he growth rate of real out­
put has been reduced well below its long-run
potential. T he level of unemployment has risen
above 5 per cent.
Policy decision: Pursue a monetary policy that re­
sults in an increased growth rate of real output
and hence a decreased level of unemployment.

In an economic downturn, if the Federal Reserve
uses market interest rates as its indicator, it might
conclude that the falling market rates signal monetary
policy has become “easier” than previously. This in­
terpretation depends upon the condition that the de­
crease in interest rates is resulting from a shift in
the credit supply curve. If the decrease in interest
rates reflects a decrease in the dem and for credit,

FEDERAL RESERVE

BANK OF ST

LOUIS

then Federal Reserve policy may be “tighter” than
previously. The fall in interest rates raises the banks’
desired excess reserve ratio which operates to reduce
the money multiplier. Also, if the downturn has been
preceded by a “crunch” in the financial markets, this
may also operate to raise banks’ desired excess re­
serve ratio. If during the “crunch” the Federal Re­
serve exercised relatively strict administration of die
discount window, this factor would lower the banks’
desired ratio of borrowings to deposits. Therefore, the
decline in the growth rate of money, resulting from
a slower growth of the base, is reinforced by the fall
in market interest rates.1'1 Hence, the monetary ag­
gregates transmit the opposite information, that policy
actions are having more of a restrictive effect 011 the
future movements of real output, employment and
prices.
A rise in the member banks’ desired holdings of
excess reserves, and a decrease in their borrowings
from Federal Reserve banks, result in a rise in the
level of free reserves. Under these conditions, to re­
duce the operational target of free reserves below
its previous level, the Federal Reserve must engage in
an even more aggressive policy of open market sales.
The result is an even more rapid decrease in the net
source base, and hence a further downward impetus
on the money supply process.
This stage might be labeled the “L et us turn it
around” stage. As our previous discussion implies, the
choice of an indicator and an operational target have
important implications for the ability of the Federal
Reserve to turn the economy around to a renewed
period of expansion in the time period desired by
the policymakers. To briefly outline the problems that
might arise, let us assume that the policymakers
decide that to achieve their ultimate objectives the
money stock should increase at a more rapid rate.
However, although policymakers accept the growth
rate of the money stock as their indicator, let us
assume that policy is still implemented using the
operational target of the Market Interest Rate H y­
pothesis. W hen judging the im pact of day-to-day open
market operations on the growth rate of money, the
Trading Desk uses free reserves or, with equivalent
results, the Federal funds rate. The growth rate of
money is used to gauge the extent to which Federal
Reserve actions are being converted into energy that
will drive the economy upward. However, the flow of
fuel is measured in free reserve units instead of in
units of base.
1:1The reader may refer to footnote 7, page 25, to see how
these factors would lower the money multiplier.



MARCH

1971

Under the economic conditions set forth for this
stage, the equilibrium level of free reserves would be
expected to rise and the Federal funds rate would
fall. If the m onetary authorities are guided in their
open market operations by either of these operational
targets, they may be reluctant to pursue an ag­
gressive policy of open market purchases. Therefore,
the growth of the base may be slower than what is
required to achieve the desired growth rate of the
money stock.
The policymaker’s failure to achieve some publicly
announced growth rate of money does not mean that
the Federal Reserve cannot control money. The fail­
ure to reach the desired monetary growth path may
result from using an inappropriate operational target.
As shown earlier, if the Federal Reserve tries to re­
sist market-determined movements of interest rates,
without taking adequate account of the influence of
of these actions on the growth rate of the base,
policymakers may not be able to achieve the growth
of money they desire. The Federal Reserve can
continue to use- open market operations to smooth
short-run pressures in the financial markets arising
from situations such as Treasury financings or a Cam ­
bodian Crisis. However, to control the growth rate of
the money stock, it must consider the effect of these
actions on the growth of the base, which dominates
the intermediate-term growth rate of the money
stock.14 Empirical evidence has been presented that,
by combining information about the past move­
ments of money multiplier with a base operational
target, the Federal Reserve can exercise reasonably
close control over the intermediate-term growth rate
of the money stock.1 r‘

Summary
This paper has presented a simplified explanation
of the implementation problem of monetary policy.
The actual implementation process is somewhat more
complicated. F or example, we assumed that the F e d ­
eral Reserve had only one ultimate objective. In an
actual situation its ability to achieve stable prices
will be constrained by the effect that its policy
actions have 011 employment. In our furnace analogy,
this would be a case where the homeowner is con­
cerned not only with the room temperature, but also
with the relative humidity in the room. The speed
with which the homeowner can increase the room
' •For a further discussion of this point, see Allan Meltzer,
“Controlling Money,” this Review (May 1969) pp. 16-24.
'•"’Lionel Kalish, “A Study of Money Stock Control,” Journal
o f Finance (September 1970), pp. 761-776.
Page 29

FEDERAL

RESERVE

BANK OF ST

tem perature to a comfortable level and still maintain
a tolerable level of humidity is dependent upon a
number of conditions under which the process is
carried out (initial conditions), such as the outside
tem perature. Likewise, the ability of the Federal
Reserve to influence prices while maintaining a "tol­
erable” level of employment will depend upon initial
conditions, such as price expectations, the price and
employment response of producers to a decrease in
total spending, and the structure of the labor market.
M onetary policy at present and in the foreseeable
future must be implemented under conditions of less
than perfect information about the structural relation­
ships linking the economy together. The indicatoroperational target method uses existing knowledge to
achieve efficient implementation of policy. This article
has shown that the correct choice of an indicator,
and an operating strategy for controlling that indica­
tor, are important problems. If the Federal Reserve
follows an indicator that is providing false informa­
tion, then this can have severe consequences for
prices and employment.
Movements of market interest rates and the growth
rate of the money stock frequently give conflicting
information about the thrust of monetary policy. The
possibility of conflict between proponents of these two
indicators is greatest at times when it is most impor­
tant that the Federal Reserve accurately assess the
thrust 6f monetary policy actions. The operational
strategy used to influence the level of market inter­
est rates affects the relative expansionary or con trac­
tionary influences the Federal Reserve is exerting on
the money supply process. If the Federal Reserve
a tte m p ts to offset changes in levels of market interest
rates that result from shifts in the public’s demand
for credit, then the growth rate of the base becomes
endogenously determined. Under these conditions, the
growth of the money stock reinforces expansions or
contractions in total spending and hence movements
in prices and employment.

T h is a r t ic le is a v a il a b le a s R e p r in t N o . 66.


Page 30


MARCH

LOUIS

1971

Bibliography
This bibliography is not intended to be a comprehen­
sive listing of the literature 011 the implementation of
monetary policy. In addition to the articles cited in the
footnotes of this article, these references were chosen to
provide the reader with a variety of opinions among
economists concerning this subject.
E. An E x p lan ation o f th e M on ey S upply
P rocess. Belmont, Calif.: Wadsworth, Forthcoming,
Septem ber 1971.
Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. C on trollin g M onetary
Aggregate's. Septem ber 1969.
F a n d , D a v id I. “Some Issues in Monetary Econom ics.”
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis R ev iew . (January
1 9 7 0 ), pp. 10-2.3,
F r a z e r , W i l l i a m J. and Y o h e , W i l l i a m P. T h e A n aly­
tics a n d Institutions o f M on ey a n d B an kin g. New
York: D. Van Nostrand and Co., 1966, Chapters
24-26.
B urg er, A l be r t

H a m b u r g e r , M ic h a e l J .

H o l b r o o k , R o b e r t . S c h a p ir o ,

Papers Presented at the
Session 011 “Money W ithin the General Econom ic
Framework of the Econom ic System .” A m erican E c o ­
n om ic R ev iew . (M ay 1 9 7 0 ), pp. 32-58.
H a n s e n , B e n t . T h e T h eo ry o f E co n o m ic P olicy an d
P lanning: L ectu res in E co n o m ic T h eo ry : Part T w o.
Lund, Sweden: Student Litteratur, 1967.
K e r a n , M i c h a e l W . “Selecting a Monetary Indicator —
Evidence from the United States and O ther D evel­
oped Countries.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
R ev iew . (Septem ber 1 9 7 0 ), pp. 8-19.
H a r o l d . Z e g h e r , R ic h a r d .

M e ltz e r ,

A lla n

H . H o rw ic h ,

G eo rg e.

H e n d e rs h o tt,

“T he Appropriate Indicators of Monetary
Policy.” Savings a n d R esid en tia l F in an cin g 1969 C o n ­
fe r e n c e an d P roceed in g s. Chicago: Sponsored by
the United States Savings and Loan League, 1969,

P a tr ic

H.

pp. 11-67.
W i l l i a m . “Optimal Choice of Monetary Policy
Instruments in a Simple Stochastic Macro M odel,”
Q u arterly Jou rn a l o f E co n o m ics. (M ay 1 9 7 0 ), pp.
197-216.'
S a v i n g , T h o m a s R. “Monetary Policy Targets and Indi­
cators.” Jou rn a l o f P olitical E co n o m y . (August 1 9 6 7 ),
pp. 446-456.
T arg ets a n d In d icators o f M on etary P olicy. E d . K a r l
B r u n n e r . San Francisco: Chandler, 1969.
T i n b e r g e n , J a n . E co n o m ic P olicy: P rin ciples an d D esign.
Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1966.
W i l l m s , M a n f r e d . “An Evaluation of Monetary Indica­
tors in Germany.” P ro ceed in g s o f th e F irst E u ro p ea n
C o n fer en c e o f M on etary P olicy at K on stan z. Edited
by Karl Brunner. Goettinger, W est Germany: Vandenhoeck and Rupreeht, Forthcom ing 1971.
P o o le ,

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

MARCH

1971

Publications of This Bank Include:
W eekly

U. S. FIN A N C IA L DATA

Monthly

R E V IE W
M O N ETA RY TR EN D S
N ATIO N AL EC O N O M IC TR EN D S
S E L E C T E D E C O N O M IC IN D ICA TO RS - C E N T R A L
M ISSISSIPPI V A L L E Y

Quarterly

Q U A R T E R L Y EC O N O M IC TR EN D S
F E D E R A L B U D G E T TR EN D S
U. S. BA LA N C E O F PAYM EN TS TR EN D S

Annually

AN N U AL U. S EC O N O M IC DATA
R A TES O F CH A N G E IN EC O N O M IC DATA
F O R T E N IN D U ST R IA L C O U N T R IES
(Q U A R T E R L Y S U P P L E M E N T )

C opies of these publications are available to the p ublic without charge, including
bulk mailings to banks, business organizations, educational institutions, and others.
F o r information w rite: R esearch D epartm ent, F ed era l R eserve Bank of St. Louis,
P. 0 . Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166.




Page 31

S U B S C R IP T IO N S to this bank’s

R e v ie w

are available to the p ublic without

charge, including bulk mailings to banks, business organizations, educational
institutions, and others.

F o r information w rite: R esearch D epartm ent, F ed era l

R eserve Bank of St. Louis, P. O. Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166.