View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
O F ST. L O U IS
JUNE 1971

CO N TEN TS
How Fast is Money Growing?......................... 2
The Road to Accelerating Inflation
is Paved with Good Intentions.................... 9
HS

Vol. 53, No. 6




How Fast is Money Growing?
by NORMAN N. BOWSHER

Concern has been expressed about the progress this nation is making in the
struggle against inflation. In recent months money has been rising at a very
rapid pace. Experience has demonstrated that prolonged, rapid increases of
money are follow ed by an excessive rise in spending and an intensification
of inflation.

R e c o v e r y FROM the slowdown of 1969-70 has
continued. Total spending has risen at a 7 per cent
annual rate since the second quarter of 1970, after a
4 per cent rate of increase in the three previous
quarters. The growth rate in real output, adjusted for
strikes and other irregular forces, has steadily in­
creased since the first quarter of 1970. In the second
quarter of this year, it is estimated that total spending
is increasing at about a 10 per cent rate and real out­
put is rising at about a 5 per cent rate.1
Retail sales have risen markedly since last Novem­
ber, following a two-year period of sluggishness, and
housing starts have risen substantially since last fall.
The composite of leading business indicators has risen
at a 15 per cent annual rate since last September.
Industrial production, after rebounding from the au­
tomobile strike, increased gradually in March and
April. By contrast, industrial production declined
about 3 per cent in the year preceding the strike.
Indications of the course of inflation are mixed.
Consumer prices have risen at a 4 per cent annual
rate since June of last year, compared with 6 per cent
from mid-1969 to mid-1970. However, there has been
little, if any, improvement in the wholesale sector.
Average hourly earnings in manufacturing, adjusted
for interindustry shifts and changes in overtime, have
risen at an 8 per cent rate since last August, compared
with a 6.4 per cent increase in the previous year.
Monetary restraint was applied in 1969 to reduce
the inflationary pressures. During 1969, the money
stock rose about 3 per cent, down from the 7.6 per
cent rate of the previous two years. Growth in total
spending slowed about six months later. After a still
longer lag, the rate of advance in some price indica­
tors began receding gradually.
1See the “Quarterly Economic Trends” release of this Bank,
May 26, 1971, p. 6.
Digitized forPage
FRASER
2


Since early 1970, monetary policies have been re­
laxed considerably. During 1970 money increased 5.4
per cent. Spending and production have been stimu­
lated, despite the auto strike and cutbacks in Govern­
ment defense spending. Early this year the growth
rate in money again accelerated. Concern is develop­
ing over whether the rate of monetary expansion has
become too rapid.2
This article discusses the recent rate of money
growth and attempts to place it in some historical
perspective. The accompanying note discusses some
problems in measuring money growth.

Recent Growth of Money
In the four months from January to May, the money
stock rose at a 14 per cent annual rate to a level of
about $224 billion. The rapid rise did not depend on
an unusual jump in any one month. On the contrary,
month-to-month annual rates of increase were 15 per
cent, 12 per cent, 10 per cent, and 18 per cent,
respectively.
Since last November, money has risen at a 10 per
cent annual rate and since September, at an 8 per cent
rate. For the entire fifteen-month period from Feb­
ruary last year, which began a marked and sustained
increase in the rate of growth, to May this year,
money grew at an average 7.6 per cent annual rate.

Comparisons With Previous Rates
The recent rates of money expansion are relatively
rapid compared with other periods since the early
1950’s. The 10 per cent annual rate since November,
and the 7.6 per cent rate since February 1970, com­
pare with a 3 per cent rate from January 1969 to
February 1970, a previous period of a relatively
2See dissents in the “Record of Policy Actions of the Federal
Open Market Committee,” contained in the Federal Reserve
Bulletin for February 1971, pp. 118-19; for April 1971, p.
327; and for May 1971, p. 397.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

uniform growth rate in money. With the 3 per cent
rate, total spending slowed to about a 5 per cent
rate of growth, just slightly faster than the upward
trend of productive capacity and perhaps near an
optimum rate for the longer run. However, because
of previous excesses, prices continued to rise rapidly
at about the same rate as total spending, leaving total
production nearly unchanged.

JU N E 1971

Money grew at a 5.8 per cent average rate from
May 1965 to January 1969. Total spending on goods
and services rose at a rapid 8 per cent annual rate
from 1965 to 1969. Since production was at near
capacity levels, output was limited by growth in labor,
capital, and technology, and prices were bid up at
increasing rates. Overall prices, which had risen 1.5
per cent from 1963 to 1964, rose 1.9 per cent from

Some Problems in Measuring Money Growth

Monetary developments have significant effects on
spending, production, employment, incomes, and prices.
One measure of monetary influence is the growth rate in
the nation’s money stock (private demand deposits and
currency in the hands of the public). Measuring how
fast money is currently rising, and judging the appro­
priateness of that rate, however, are not simple matters.
The appropriateness of a given rate of money growth
depends, in part, on the economic situation. Because the
economy is now sluggish, some analysts believe that
money growth, no matter what the rate, has been too
slow. Others, focusing on inflation, believe that the growth
rate of money has been much too fast. However, most
analysts feel a moderate policy course is more appro­
priate than either of these extremes which focus on a
single objective.
Some recommend a policy of stimulation so long as
gains in current production and employment outweigh
the increases in current prices. However, value judg­
ments differ on the costs of inflation and idle resources,
causing disagreements on the appropriate rate of mone­
tary expansion. Still others emphasize the effect of lags,
and find that a rate of money growth acts with a longer
lag on inflation than on employment. To them, the ap­
parent paradox of unemployment with inflation may
merely be an unavoidable transition from a period of
excessive monetary expansion.
The money supply fluctuates each day by as much as
a billion dollars and more. Short-run fluctuations may be
caused by movements in total bank reserves, Treasury
deposits, time deposits, and excess reserves, as well as
by a number of other factors. Most of these daily move­
ments are offset within a brief period by opposite shortrun fluctuations. Daily fluctuations in money probably
have no significant effect on aggregate spending, produc­
tion, and prices, and daily data are not published regularly.
D ata on money are collected, tabulated, and published
on a daily average basis, both seasonally adjusted and
unadjusted, for weeks and for months. Compounded
annual rates of change for various combinations of be­



ginning and ending periods are published by this Bank in
order to facilitate comparisons.1
Selecting a proper period for analysis is an important
step in interpreting money movements. One-week or onemonth changes are quite irregular and seldom have been
found to have a measurable effect on spending, produc­
tion, or prices. The minimum period for meaningful
analysis is usually about three months. Yet, arbitrarily
picking a three-month or one-year period may be quite
misleading.
Experience indicates that selecting “good” base and
ending periods for comparison is essential. Ideally, these
points should mark the terminal points of a relatively
uniform trend, or at least be on such a trend. The points
selected should be free of significant bulges or dips, and
if the ending period is the most recent data available, as
is frequently the case, then allowances should be made
for possible revisions and for known influences that are
likely to be temporary. This is especially true where the
period to be studied is relatively short, since a given
deviation affects rates of change more over a short pe­
riod than when spread over a longer time span. On the
other hand, if the period reviewed is unduly long, mean­
ingful shorter run trends may be lost.
Other considerations in selecting appropriate periods
for measuring money growth may include policy inten­
tions, movements in related monetary aggregates, and
movements in spending, production, and prices. Then,
too, periods selected may differ, depending on the use
to be made of the data. For example, if the object is to
evaluate the effectiveness of the Federal Reserve System
in controlling money, the period should be relatively
short, say, about three months. If the object is to measure
the im pact of a given change in a money trend on a
change in the rate of real production, a longer period
would probably be desirable for the new trend, say about
five months to a year. If the object is to relate the
growth of money to the upward trend of prices, the ap­
propriate period may be a trend over several years.
xSee the statistical release H.6, “Money Stock Measures,” and
the Federal Reserve Bulletin published by the Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Also see the “U.S.
Financial Data” and “Monetary Trends” releases of this
Bank.
Page 3

JU N E 1971

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

M o n e y Stock

Percentages ore onnuoi rates o f change for periods indicated

1964 to 1965, and 2.7 per cent, 3.2 per cent, 4.0 per
cent, 4.7 per cent, and 5.3 per cent, respectively, in
successive years.
The trend growth in money was 2.3 per cent per
year from 1951 to 1965. This trend was sufficient to
accommodate the growth in business and financial
transactions caused by the expansion of real output.

Comparisons With Other Recovery Periods
The economy is now in the process of recovering
from a mild recession. Some stimulation might be ap­
propriate during a recession, but the 10 per cent rate
of growth of money since last November is more rapid
than during other recovery periods.
Recessions occurred in 1949, 1954, 1958, and 1960,
and there was a marked slowing of activity in 1966-67.
During the recession of 1949, money growth acceler­
ated, and from November 1949 to April 1953 money
grew at a 4.3 per cent annual rate. From April 1954
to May 1955 and from January 1958 to June 1959,
money again grew at the accelerated rate of 4.3
per cent. In each of these recessions, monetary
actions were considered to be aggressively stimu­
lative at the time; in each case the acceleration of
money growth was followed within a few months by
an upturn in the growth rate of spending and produc­
tion. Also, inflation generally became stronger about a
year later, and the rate of monetary expansion ap­
peared, in retrospect, to have been too rapid.

http://fraser.stlouisfed.org/
Page 4
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

Money growth accelerated again during the reces­
sion of 1960. The rate of money growth, beginning in
1960, was more moderate than those during the three
earlier recovery periods, and was continued longer.
Money, after declining from mid-1959 to mid-1960,
rose at a 3 per cent average rate for about 5 years,
from June 1960 to May 1965. The economic recovery
after 1960 was less pronounced than after the three
previous recessions, but the expansion occurred with­
out great imbalances or an intensification of infla­
tionary pressures. By late 1964 and early 1965, pro­
duction was approaching the limits of capacity and
expanding at near the maximum sustainable pace.
The economy was then given an upward jolt by a
sharp increase in Federal spending and the accom­
panying large monetary injections of 1965, 1967, and
1968.
During the slowdown in spending and production
of late 1966 and early 1967, money growth accelerated
to a 7.6 per cent annual rate, and this rate was main­
tained through 1968. Total spending spurted after
about a six-month lag, and inflationary pressures in­
tensified more quickly and to a greater extent than
after any of the previous recessions.

Percentile Comparisons
Comparison of monetary increases in some recent
periods —the last three months, the last six, the last
nine, and the last twelve — with all earlier periods
of similar length may provide additional insight into
how rapid recent monetary growth has been. In the
last three months, money has risen at a 13 per cent
annual rate. This is in the 100th percentile of all con­
secutive three-month periods since January 1950. In
fact, money rose faster in both the January-to-April
and the February-to-May 1971 periods than in any of
the other 255 three-month periods.
In the last six months, money has risen at a 10 per
cent annual rate. This also is in the 100th percentile of
all consecutive six-month periods since January 1950.
The 8 per cent rise in money over the last nine months
places it in the 99th percentile of all nine-month
periods. The 7 per cent growth of money in the last
twelve months is in the 95th percentile.
Sizable monetary injections might be appropriate
under extremely depressed economic conditions for
brief periods. At the present time, excess capacity in
the nation is moderate, and price increases continue
at near peak rates. Unemployment, which averaged
5.7 per cent in the last twelve months, was in the 79th
percentile of all twelve-month periods since January

JU N E 1971

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

1950. Overall prices rose 5 per cent in the last four
quarters, which is in the 90th percentile of all fourquarter changes.

Quantity of Money Demanded
The supply of money should be just sufficient to
accommodate increasing public desires to hold money
as an asset when spending rises at a rate consistent
with potential output. If money rises more rapidly
than the amount demanded (given current interest
rates, incomes, wealth, and other pertinent condi­
tions ), the public will tend to increase current expen­
ditures in an attempt to reduce the excess cash
balances. Conversely, if the money supply rises
less rapidly than does the amount the public wishes
to hold, they will decrease current expenditures in
an attempt to build up cash balances.
The aggregate amount of money demanded cannot
be measured precisely. Relating past changes in the
money stock with the accompanying and lagged
changes in spending is, in effect, a method for esti­
mating the past growth in the demand for money to
hold. Such studies indicate that the growth in money
demanded in the United States has been relatively
steady at about a 3 per cent annual rate since the late
1940’s. Whenever the money stock rose at a 2 per cent
rate or slower for an extended period, economic acti­
vity tended to slow. On the other hand, whenever
money rose at a 4 per cent rate or faster for an ex­

tended period, spending tended to rise more rapidly
and, in time, price increases accelerated.
It is possible that the amount of money demanded
has changed recently, so that earlier relationships no
longer hold. Economic studies indicate that the
amount of money demanded as an asset depends on a
number of factors, particularly interest rates, real in­
come and wealth, and prices, as well as the technology
of minimizing cash balances.
Interest rates are currently at relatively high levels
historically. Since an increase in interest rates raises
the opportunity cost of holding money, the amount of
money demanded has probably declined. A reversal
occurred last fall and winter with the decline of
interest rates from their peak levels, but most rates
have risen again since March.
Real income has changed little since mid-1969. By
comparison, the upward trend of real income was 4
per cent per year from 1957 to 1969. With the slower
growth of income (and wealth), other things equal,
it might be expected that the growth in the amount
of money demanded also has slowed.
Inflation has been strong in recent years, and infla­
tion and inflationary expectations have several effects
on the amount of money demanded. Since inflation
Prices
Ratio S ca le
1 9 67= 100
130

R atio S ca le
1 9 67= 100
130

Interest Rates
R atio S c a le
o f Y ie ld s
11

R atio S c a le
o f Y ie ld s

M onthly A v e ra g e s of Dot

----,11

10
Consumer

9

8
7
Corporate

Wholesale Industrial

1963

1964

1965

19 6 6

Latest d a ta plotted: M ay




1967

1968

19 6 9

19 7 0

1971

1 96 3

196 4

1965

19 6 6

19 6 7

1968

196 9

1970

1971

Source-. U .S. Department of Labor
Percentages are a nnu al rates of change for perio ds indicated.
L atest data plotted: C onsum er-April; W ho lesale-M ay

Page 5

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

reduces the real value of money, the amount desired
as a store of value declines. On the other hand, as
prices for goods and services increase, the amount of
money demanded by individuals and businesses for
transactions probably rises. However, supplying
money in response to an inflation-induced increase in
the amount of money demanded tends to accommo­
date the inflation malady. The rate of inflation may
have been gradually receding for about a year, slow­
ing the increase in the amount of money demanded
for transactions because of rising prices.

JU N E 1971

Grow th in Total Spending1
St. Louis M od el Simulation Assuming
9 Per Cent Grow th in M oney S to ck 1^
Per C ent
12

Per Cent

10

8

This review of recent developments in the forces
thought to be most influential in determining the
quantity of money demanded suggests that only litde
change has occurred in the trend of money demanded
in the last year. If this is true, past relationships be­
tween the quantity of money supplied and the sub­
sequent growth in spending can be expected to con­
tinue with little change. To the extent that there have
been any changes in the past year, some acceleration
in the growth in the amount of money demanded
probably occurred in 1970 with the decline in market
rates. More recentiy, most forces seem to be slowing
the growth rate in the amount of money demanded,
indicating that the growth rate of total spending will
be faster in the near future relative to growth in the
quantity of money supplied.

6

4

0

1968

1969

1970

1971

1972

[^ F ig u re s p lotted a re co m p o u n d e d a n n u a l rates of c h a n g e , a d ju s te d to
rem ove irre g u la r flu ctu a tio n s in both a c t u a l a n d p rojecte d d a ta .
B e g in n in g in 11/1971, p ro je c tio n s assu m e 9 p e r c e n t gro w th in m o n e y
stock a n d high-em ploym ent F e d e r a l e x p e n d itu re s b a s e d on the
fiscal 1972 b u d g e t through 11/1972; th e re a fte r, e x p e n d itu re s are
assu m ed to g ro w a t a n 8 p e r cent rate.
[2 S e e " A M o n e ta r is t M o d e l for E c o n o m ic S t a b iliz a t io n ," this R e v ie w
(A p ril 1970), pp. 7-25.

Model Projections
Evaluation of whether a rate of money growth is
too rapid depends on the likely economic impact.
Assuming a 9 per cent annual rate of money growth,
which is slightly less than that experienced since last
November, a very rapid economic expansion is likely
in the near future. At this rate of monetary injection,
this Bank’s model indicates that growth in total spend­
ing for goods and services would accelerate from the
recent 7 per cent annual rate to about a 10 or 11 per
cent rate in the latter part of 1972.3 Deviations of
spending from the model projections seem more likely
to occur on the high side than on the'low. Typically,
when money has risen very rapidly for an extended
period, the growth in velocity of money also has risen
after a two or three quarter lag .4 The model has not
captured fully the increases of velocity in previous
recovery periods.
3For details on the model, see “A Monetarist Model for Eco­
nomic Stabilization,” April 1970 Review of this Bank, pp.
7-25. For current projections of this model, see the “Quar­
terly Economic Trends” release of this Bank.
4See “Changes in the Velocity of Money,” Reprint No. 4 of this
Bank.

Page 6


Growth in real product with a 9 per cent rate of
increase of money would accelerate from the recent
1 per cent annual rate of increase to about a 6 per cent
rate late next year, according to this Bank’s model.
This would be above a sustainable rate, given the
trend growth of productive capacity, estimated to be
about 4 per cent per year.
By utilizing idle resources, a greater-than-sustainable rate of production growth could be accommo­
dated for a short period with the current rate of
inflation changing little. The model indicates litde or
no increase in the rate of price advance for the next
year and a half, even with the 9 per cent money
growth. However, the model indicates that inflation
would intensify markedly after 1972 under such a
stimulative policy. Resisting inflation at a later time,
then, would lead to greater costs in reduced output
growth than presentiy.

Interest Rate Considerations
Although money has expanded sharply, most inter­
est rates have risen in recent months. Interest rates on
highest-grade corporate bonds rose from 7.1 per cent

JU N E 1971

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Yields on Selected Securities

Interest rates perform a function in our economic
system similar to that of prices of goods and services.
They allocate scarce resources among competing users,
but have little bearing on the level of total resource
utilization. As such, high market interest rates should
be viewed as having about the same implications for
economic stabilization as higher market prices on
commodities or services.

Trends of Money Growth

Source: Board ol Governors ot the Federol Reserve System ond Moody s Investor! Service
11 Weekly averoges ol doily figures
|2 Thursday figures

in February to 7.7 per cent in early June. Concern
has been expressed that a rise in interest rates, par­
ticularly long-term rates, might choke off the economic
recovery.5
Market interest rates are the prices at which the
quantity of credit supplied and the quantity de­
manded are equated. Monetary actions affect both
the demand for and supply of credit. An increase in
the stock of money and bank credit adds directly to
the supply of loanable funds, tending to cause interest
rates in the short run to be lower than they otherwise
would be.
A rise in the money stock also has expansionary
effects on the total demand for goods and services.
When dollar balances and credit are increased rap­
idly, given existing assets, incomes, prices, and inter­
est rates, the public attempts to exchange some of the
“excess money” for goods and services. This tends, in
time, to cause an increase in total spending, produc­
tion, and prices. With expectations of greater sales
and a higher rate of inflation, demands for credit may
be expanded at a faster rate than the supply of credit
created, and net upward pressure on interest rates
results. The rise in rates in recent months is probably
a reflection of a very rapid monetary stimulation of
demands for credit rather than evidence of any mone­
tary restraint.6
5See Wall Street Journal, “Interest Rates Reverse Downward
Trend; Stir Fears for the Economy,” May 25, 1971, p. 1; and
Ben Weberman, “Fed Baffled as to How to Get Rates
Down,” American Banker, May 24, 1971, p. 1.
6For additional analysis of the interaction of monetary actions,
inflation, and interest rates, see “The Road to Accelerating
Inflation is Paved with Good Intentions,” in this Review,
pp. 9-15.



Additional perspective on the recent rate of money
growth can be obtained by comparing trends over
longer periods, covering several monetary cycles.
From early 1952 to mid-1964, the money stock grew
at an average 1.9 per cent average annual rate.
Within this twelve and a half year period, several
cyclical upswings in money growth occurred, and
spending, production, and employment increased rap­
idly. At other times, the money stock drifted down
relative to the trend, and, with a brief lag, spending
and production slowed and unemployment rose. Over­
all prices in this period rose at a relatively slow 1.8
per cent annual rate.
Since mid-1964, money has risen at a faster 5.3 per
cent average annual rate. Early in the period, as
money accelerated to the new trend, and later, as
money moved up relative to the trend, spending,
production, and employment received a temporary
stimulus. But as money moved down relative to the
trend, sluggishness and slack reappeared. The rate of
overall price increase has accelerated from the 1.8
per cent rate of the Fifties and early Sixties to a 5.3
per cent rate since mid-1969.
Unemployment experience was about the same
whether the trend growth of money was 1.9 per cent
(1952-64) or 5.3 per cent (1964-71). Both trend pe­
riods contained some relatively high and some rela­
tively low unemployment rates. The trend growth of
money apparently had its chief impact on the trend of
spending growth and the rate of price advance. It
has been the shorter-run movements around the
trends which have apparently had the greatest im­
pact on cyclical changes in spending, production, and
employment.

Conclusions
Recent growth rates of money have been very
rapid, as measured in a number of ways. Experience
has demonstrated that large, prolonged injections of
money will be followed by an excessive rise in spend­
ing and an intensification of inflationary pressures.
Largest increases of money have usually occurred
Page 7

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JU N E 1971

during periods of economic slack for the purpose of
stimulating spending, but from 1960 to early 1965 a
balanced recovery and expansion occurred while
money rose moderately. Experience also indicates
that when money growth accelerates for a prolonged
period and then ceases to accelerate, as it must if the
economic system is to survive, growth in production
slows and unemployment increases at higher rates of
inflation.
Two lessons seem to emerge from the money ex­
perience of the past two decades. First, if the upward
thrust of inflation is to be halted, the trend growth of
money must be reduced to a moderate rate. The pre­
cise rate depends on the growth of money demanded

under conditions of anticipated price stability (per­
haps about a 3 or 4 per cent annual rate). However,
money has risen rapidly in the last six months, rais­
ing slightly the growth trend of money for the past
several years and indicating likely intensification of
inflation in the near future if continued much longer.
Second, changes in the trend growth of money
should be gradual, and short-run movements around
the trend should be slight, because marked move­
ments away from a previous trend have usually been
followed by destabilizing changes in spending. The
sharp money growth in recent months has deviated
significandy upward from the previous trend, indicat­
ing a faster-than-sustainable rate of increase in pro­
duction in the near future.

Reprint Series
0 VER THE YEARS certain articles appearing in the R e v i e w have proved to he helpful to
banks, educational institutions, business organizations, and others. To satisfy the demand for these
articles, our reprint series has been made available on request. The following articles have
been added to the series in the past year. Please indicate the title and number o f article in your
request to: Research Department, Federal Reserve Rank o f St. Louis, P.O. Rox 442, St. Louis,
Mo. 63166.
NUM BER

TITLE O F ARTICLE

ISSU E

57. Federal O pen M arket Committee Decisions in 1969 —
Y e a r of M o n etary Restraint

Ju n e

58. M etropolitan A re a G row th: A Test of Export Base Concepts

Ju ly

59. Selecting a M onetary In d ic a to r— Evidence from the
United States and O ther D eveloped Countries

Septem ber 1970

60. The “ C row ding O u t” of Private Expenditures
by Fiscal Policy Actions

O ctober 1970

61. A g g reg a te Price Changes and Price Expectations

N ovem ber 1970

62. The Revised M o n ey Stock: Explanation and Illustrations

Ja n u a ry

1971

63. Expectations, M o n ey and the Stock M arket

Ja n u a ry

1971

64. Population, The Labor Force, and Potential Output:
Implications for the St. Louis M odel

February 1971

65. O bservations on Stabilization M anagem ent

December 1970

66. The Im plem entation Problem of M o n etary Policy

M arch

67. Controlling M on ey in an O pen Econom y: The Germ an Case

A pril

68. The Y e a r 1970: A "M o d e s t" Beginning for
M o n e ta ry A ggregates

M ay


Page 8


1970
1970

1971
1971

1971

The Road to Accelerating Inflation
Is Paved with Good Intentions
First Annual Monetary Policy Lecture, delivered by DARRYL R. FRANCIS, President,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, to the School of Banking of the South,
Louisiana State University, Baton Rouge, Louisiana, June 1, 1971

J t is good to be here this evening, and it is an
exciting experience for me to deliver the “First Annual
Monetary Policy Lecture” to the School of Banking
of the South. I have felt for a long time that people
engaged in banking should become more familiar with
the influence of monetary policy actions on the econ­
omy. Increased public awareness of the ways policy
decisions are made, and the ways stabilization actions
work, may help to move us towards better policies in
the future. I wish you a long and successful lecture
series.
As we approach the mid-point of 1971, I wish I
could say to you that it is my belief that the battle
against inflation is nearing successful completion and
that we can now turn our primary attention to moving
the economy quickly back towards its noninflationary,
high-employment growth potential. Unfortunately,
this is not the case. I must report diat I am just as con­
cerned now about the long-run inflationary trend of
the U. S. economy as I was last year and the year
before.
Tonight I will trace the economic developments
from the mid-1960’s to the present which, in my
opinion, created the present inflationary environment
and cause me great concern regarding the prospects
for achieving price stability in the near future.
It is important to make clear at the outset that I do
not believe anyone desires a continuation of the



inflationary trend in this country. However, I do be­
lieve that there is a danger of focusing too much
attention on other immediate objectives, and that the
consequences of resulting actions could lead to a re­
acceleration of the rate of inflation, contrary to our
desires. I will elaborate more fully on this view after
looking back to the events which led to our present
situation.

Approach to Analysis
Throughout my remarks I will be drawing heavily
on research of the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.
In recent years our economists have been exploring
new approaches to empirical measurement of the re­
sponse of total spending, real product, prices, the
unemployment rate, and market interest rates to vari­
ous monetary and fiscal actions. This research has
shown that changes in the nation’s money stock — that
is, demand deposits at commercial banks and cur­
rency in the hands of the public —provide a reliable
indicator of the influence of monetary policy actions
on total spending in the economy.
Furthermore, evidence has been provided and be­
come widely accepted that the levels of, or changes
in, market interest rates do not give a reliable indica­
tion of the “tightness” or “ease” of stabilization policy
actions. On the contrary, it has been shown that mar­
ket interest rates are significantly influenced by the
Page 9

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

past rate of inflation and people’s expectations with
regard to the future rate of inflation.
Finally, the ongoing work by our research staff is
attempting to quantify the immediate and delayed
responses of real product and prices to a pronounced
change in the rate of increase of total spending. We
have been able to make fairly reliable predictions of
the rate at which total spending will accelerate or
decelerate in response to substantial accelerations or
decelerations in the growth of the money stock. There
is less certainty, however, about the breakdown of the
changes in total spending into the real product and
price component parts. The range of estimates on this
breakdown is especially large at a time when there
appears to be substantial slack in the economy, in the
form of unused plant and equipment capacity and
relatively high unemployment, while there continues
to be a fairly high rate of inflation as a result of
previous excesses. I believe that a careful study of
events from the mid-1960 s to the present sheds con­
siderable light on the risks that would be incurred
by underestimating the speed at which substantial
inflationary pressures would be rekindled if prolonged
monetary stimulus resulted from efforts to achieve
other short-term objectives.

Background to the Current Situation
I turn now to consideration of past developments
which seem to provide clues to assessing our future
course.1 In this review I will emphasize the fact that
avoidance of increased inflationary pressures was at
all times a fundamental desire of stabilization au­
thorities. For the most part, however, the actions
actually taken were with a view to achieving other
near-term objectives. It is my opinion that this suc­
cession of actions taken to deal with goals other than
achieving price stability has added up to an uninten­
tional long-run acceleration in the rate of inflation.
The review begins with 1964, the last year of a sixyear period of relative price stability. Growth of both
total spending and real product strengthened through­
out that year as a result of the continuing monetary
■Federal Open Market Committee policy actions for each year
have been discussed in detail in the following articles published
in this Review: “Implementation of Federal Reserve Open
Market Policy in 1964,” (June 1965); “Federal Reserve Open
Market Operations in 1965: Objectives, Actions, and Accom­
plishments,” (June 1966); “1966 — A Year of Challenge for
Monetary Management,” (April 1967); “1 9 6 7 — A Year of
Constraints on Monetary Management,” (May 1968); “Fed­
eral Open Market Committee Decisions in 1968 — A Year of
Watchful Waiting,” (May 1969); “Federal Open Market
Committee Decisions in 1969 — Year of Monetary Restraint,”
(June 1970); and “The Year 1970; A ‘Modest’ Beginning for
Monetary Aggregates,” (May 1971).



JU N E 1971

stimulus initiated in 1963 and the tax-cut of March
1964. The published record of Federal Reserve policy
actions2 shows that for the first eight months of 1964,
policy was conducted with a view to maintaining
prevailing conditions in the money markets. In the
final four months, System actions were directed to
move towards slightly firmer conditions in the money
markets. However, the rate of growth in total spend­
ing was increasing, and the public was demanding
a growing amount of credit to finance increased spend­
ing. Consequently, System holdings of Government
securities rose fairly rapidly, as the tendency for mar­
ket interest rates to rise was resisted by open market
purchases of securities. The result was progressively
more rapid rates of growth in the nation’s money
stock. On balance for 1964, money rose 4.5 per cent,
over twice as fast as the average growth rate during
the previous decade.
As a direct consequence of the growing monetary
stimulus in 1964, 1965 became the first of many years
of mounting inflationary pressures. Reflecting back on
1965, I find it to be a year of great paradox. At each
of the sixteen meetings of the Federal Open Market
Committee in that year, the ultimate policy objective
was to avoid emergence of inflationary pressures, yet
monetary actions were more stimulative than at any
time since the Korean War. Throughout the year the
operating instructions for policy were to maintain the
same or slightly firmer conditions in the money mar­
kets. In view of the increasing demands for credit,
this meant, in effect, that open market operations
were to be conducted so as to keep interest rates
from rising significantly. Yet interest rates did rise a
significant amount in 1965, in spite of record pur­
chases of securities in the open market by the Federal
Reserve.
This is where the paradox comes in. Restrictive
policy was desired in order to combat inflation, and
many observers contended that the rising interest rates
were an indication that restraint was achieved. But I
think a closer look indicates that the rising interest
rates were not at all restrictive, while the actions to
resist the upward trend of interest rates were very
stimulative.
During ten of the sixteen policy periods in 1965,
open market transactions were directed to take ac­
count of the U. S. Treasury financing activity. As I
see it, the problem was that the public demand for
2AU quotes and references to policy instructions in this speech
are from the Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the
Federal Reserve System unless specified otherwise.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

credit to finance an accelerating rate of total expendi­
tures was growing very rapidly, and at the same time
the Government was incurring very large deficits as
expenditures rose rapidly to finance the Vietnam War
buildup along with mounting nondefense outlays.
Since Federal Reserve policy actions were conducted
with an immediate objective of maintaining stable or
only slightly rising interest rates, System actions pro­
vided increased bank reserves at a very rapid rate.
This, in turn, resulted in “a record expansion of bank
credit and deposits” to finance the faster rate of spend­
ing of the public and government.
Early in 1966 policy objectives shifted to “moderat­
ing the growth in the reserve base, bank credit, and
the money supply” in order to resist inflationary pres­
sures. However, through April of 1966 policy actions
were constrained by continued Treasury financing. As
a result, the money stock rose at a very rapid 6 per
cent rate from May 1965 to April 1966.
Here I must emphasize that the 6 per cent rate of
money growth in 1965 and early 1966 was sufficiently
rapid to stimulate substantial inflationary pressure,
even though real product was growing very rapidly
as prior unused capacity declined. The rate of price
advance as measured by the GNP deflator moved up
from about 1% per cent in early 1965 to over 3% per
cent by mid-1966. The acceleration of consumer price
increases was even greater.
The last nine months of 1966 marked a period of
effective restrictive action to combat inflation. The
growth of the money stock dropped to zero, as interest
rates were allowed to rise in response to market de­
mand. Policy instructions explicitly called for a reduc­
tion in bank reserves, as fighting inflation finally be­
came a more important objective than maintaining
relatively low interest rates, or stable money markets,
or accommodating Treasury financing.
You may recall that the economy survived a “credit
crunch” in the early fall of 1966, as the continued
strong demands for credit in the face of restrictive
monetary actions resulted in a temporary upward
spurt in market interest rates. In comparison with
recent interest rates, those of the 1966 credit crunch
period look rather low. The yields on neither shortnor long-term market securities rose above six per
cent at their peak levels.
There is an especially important lesson here. Dur­
ing 1964 and 1965, policy actions were directed to­
wards maintaining relatively low interest rates, but
the efforts were in vain, since the resulting rapid
growth in money generated inflation and rising inter­



JU N E 1971

est rates. On the other hand, following the nine-month
period in 1966, when the immediate attention of pol­
icy actions was turned to controlling the growth of
monetary aggregates in order to combat inflation,
lower interest rates accompanied the slower growth
of total spending and easing demands for credit.
The restrictive monetary actions of 1966 were fol­
lowed by a sharply slower rate of growth of total
spending and real product in late 1966 and the first
half of 1967. This was the period of the so-called
mini-recession. As the growth of total spending in the
economy slowed, the immediate objective of policy
turned to other near-term goals such as stimulating
renewed real economic growth, maintaining the lower
interest rates that had resulted from previous restric­
tions, and facilitating continued large Treasury financ­
ing activities. During most of the first half of 1967,
there was a definite desire to move policy in the
direction of ease. Since the growth of total demand
continued to slow in delayed response to the restraint
of 1966, demands for credit continued to be moderate
and market interest rates continued to fall. Even with
falling interest rates making money market conditions
easier, System open market purchases of securities
increased, resulting in a rapid resumption in the
growth of the money stock.
The very clear intention of policymakers was to
be only as expansionary as necessary to promote
growth of real production, but not so stimulative as
to refuel the inflationary forces. During the spring,
however, policy ceased seeking still easier conditions
in the money market, and sought only to maintain
the easier conditions that had developed. Although
concern was being expressed about the possibility of
re-emergence of inflationary pressures, other immedi­
ate considerations received more weight.
By June the economy was strengthening rapidly,
and a definite tendency developed for all market in­
terest rates to rise. Once again, as in 1964 and 1965,
open market policy actions turned towards a direct
attempt to prevent market interest rates from rising
further in response to growing public demands
for credit and extremely heavy Treasury financing
requirements.
The published public policy record shows that
through the summer and well into the fall of 1967,
a dominant reason for attempting to slow the uptrend
in interest rates was the view that higher interest
rates might reduce the flow of funds into mortgages
and slow the recovery of residential construction activ­
ity. Also, some argued that higher interest rates might
Page 11

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST

LOUIS

have adverse effects on the flow of funds into financial
intermediaries such as savings and loan associations.
Inasmuch as the U. S. Treasury borrowed over $23
billion in the fiscal year beginning in July 1967, money
and capital markets were under great pressure. Consequendy, many contended that open market opera­
tions by the Federal Reserve should hold interest
rates down in order to avoid these many undesired
effects. In response, the System expanded bank re­
serves and the money stock at very rapid rates in this
period.
Furthermore, in the fall of 1967, some felt that pol­
icy actions should be constrained from becoming re­
strictive, because of the possible adverse effects such
actions might have on the position of the British
pound sterling in the foreign exchange markets. The
prevailing view was that if System actions became
less expansionary through reduced purchases of securi­
ties in the open market, and market interest rates
rose as a consequence, relatively more international
capital might flow out of Britain and into the United
States. Such events might, in turn, force the British
to devalue the pound. Thus, the international situation
was a more immediate concern of policymakers than
was the avoidance of renewed inflationary pressures.
As you may recall, the British devalued the pound in
late November 1967 in spite of the good intentions of
United States policy.
By the end of 1967, it finally became clear that
inflationary pressures were building up rapidly and
some restraint would have to be exercised in order
to avoid greatly overheating the economy. However,
policy actions were constrained to allowing only
slightly firmer conditions to develop in the money
market, because of the continuing concern about the
possible adverse effects of higher interest rates on
financial intermediaries.
This is a puzzling period to assess. The experience
of 1964 and 1965 had shown that direct policy actions
attempting to maintain low interest rates would be
frustrated, since the rapid growth of the money stock
which resulted from the low interest rate policy caused
acceleration of inflation and sharply rising interest
rates. The more recent experience of 1966 had shown
that an anti-inflationary policy of holding down the
growth of the money stock would produce lower in­
terest rates once the upward thrust of inflationary
expectations was broken. Yet, policy actions in 1967
returned to direct attempts to maintain low interest
rates. Once again the result was accelerating inflation.
If policy decisions were misdirected in 1967, it was
even more true in 1968. In the first half of 1968 there

Page 12


JU N E 1971

was a clear consensus that a restrictive anti-inflation­
ary policy was appropriate. Yet, short horizons and
other immediate considerations forestalled restrictive
actions. There was the almost ever-present Treasury
financing to consider, and in March the crisis in the
London gold market militated against restrictive
actions.
The public policy record for early April 1968 delin­
eates the considerations which dominated this period.
Although the desirability of fighting inflation was com­
monly agreed upon, some argued that any firming
actions should proceed with caution for several rea­
sons. First, restrictive monetary policy was believed
to be inappropriate in view of the prospects for fiscal
restraint. Second, some thought the sharply rising in­
terest rates indicated “a considerable degree of mone­
tary restraint had already been achieved”, and also
there was the persistent concern that restrictive actions
“might have large adverse effects on flows of funds to
financial intermediaries”, and such would be undesir­
able. Finally, there was uncertainty about the eco­
nomic effects of the Vietnam War.
The second half of 1968 was a regrettable period
for United States stabilization policy. In June, Con­
gress passed the Revenue and Expenditure Control
Act which raised corporate and personal income taxes
and slowed the growth of Government spending. A
view became very widely held in the summer and
fall that this fiscal package was too restrictive and
would cause too sharp a slowdown in the economy.
As a result, there was an overt move towards easier
monetary policy to counter this presumably very re­
strictive fiscal impact.
By December 1968, however, it became widely rec­
ognized that the fiscal package had little, if any,
restrictive impact, and that the monetary ease had
further fanned the flames of inflation. Monetary ac­
tions moved strongly towards restraint, as the growth
of the money stock was curtailed in spite of continuing
strong demands for credit and rising interest rates.
This marked the end, for the time being, of a twoyear period of the most stimulative monetary actions
since the Korean War. The direct efforts to thwart the
tendency for interest rates to rise had been a total
failure, since the expanding inflationary pressures had
resulted in sharply higher short- and long-term inter­
est rates.
To recapitulate so far, the rapid 6 per cent rate of
growth of the money stock in 1965 and early 1966
resulted in an overall inflation rate of about 3% per
cent, and interest rates of 5% to 6 per cent before the

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

restrictive actions of 1966 took effect. The still more
rapid 7% per cent growth in money throughout 1967
and 1968 ultimately resulted in the overall rate of
inflation accelerating to over 5% per cent and most
interest rates peaking between 8 and 9 per cent.
Finally in 1969, policy actions brought about significandy slower growth rates of money. In turn, after
a lag, the slower growth of money brought the growth
in total demand down to more sustainable long-run
rates. As in the credit crunch of 1966, restriction of
the growth of money in 1969 temporarily resulted in
sharply higher interest rates, as the inflation-fed growth
in demands for credit continued very strong for a
while after the supply of new funds to the market
was curtailed. But, as before, once the upward thrust
of expectations concerning continued inflation was
broken, growth in the demand for credit slowed and
interest rates began to move quickly downward.
After two major episodes of stop-and-go actions,
policymakers in 1970 were in a position to benefit
significantly from their recent past experience. Last
year monetary policy actions moved to a moderately
expansionary stance, and I have no disagreement with
the growth of the money stock that resulted on bal­
ance in 1970. By year’s end the quantity of money
outstanding was somewhat over 5 per cent greater
than a year earlier, and I think that was about right
in view of the lack of real output growth and the
rising unemployment we were experiencing.
However, I believe that over a longer period of time
and especially under conditions of a stronger pace of
real economic growth and a higher level of employ­
ment, a 5 to 6 per cent rate of growth of the money
stock would prove excessive in terms of the average
rate of inflation. It is my view that the longer-run noninflationary growth rate of money most likely would
be on the order of 3 to 4 per cent. As the economy
strengthens, I believe that the rate of growth of money
should be lowered to this more sustainable range. I
would like to elaborate on this view within the con­
text of the overall experience during the post-Korean
War period.

Trend Velocity of Money
During the decade ending in late 1962, money grew
at about a 1% per cent average annual rate. Both the
velocity of money and the economy’s productive po­
tential increased at about a 3% per cent average rate
during this period. As a result, the overall rate of
price increase was a relatively slow 1% per cent aver­
age annual rate. Then, from 1962 to the end of 1966,
which includes the period of restrictive monetary ac­



JU N E 1971

tions in 1966, the growth of money was at an acceler­
ated 3% per cent average annual rate. With velocity
continuing to rise at its earlier pace, and potential
real output growing somewhat faster, this rate of mon­
etary expansion resulted in a quarterly rate of inflation
of 4 per cent in the latter part of that period.
Following the credit crunch of 1966, the growth of
money accelerated to very rapid rates, as emphasized
previously. By looking across the second period of
monetary restraint in 1969, the resumption of mod­
erately rapid growth of money in 1970, and the period
of very rapid monetary growth thus far in 1971, I see
that the growth of the money stock has risen at about
a 6V2 per cent average annual trend rate since January
1967. In this period there was a marked fall in the
rate of increase of velocity, and the rate of potential
output growth rose slightly. Consequently, the very
rapid growth of money since early 1967 has resulted
in about a 4% per cent average annual rate of infla­
tion as measured by the implicit price deflator, and a
peak rate of inflation of over 7 per cent as measured
by the consumer price index.
Even if the trend growth of velocity should continue
in the future to be at the recent slower rate, which,
in my estimation, would be a highly optimistic out­
look, a continuation of the 6% per cent trend growth
of money since early 1967 would imply a sustained
4 per cent rate of inflation. If, on the other hand, the
trend growth of velocity in the future were some­
where between the low IV2 per cent rate of the past
four years, and the 3 V2 per cent rate of the previous
fifteen years, then the recent trend of monetary growth
could imply as much as a sustained 6 per cent trend
rate of inflation.
If I get somewhat ahead of myself by noting that
the money stock has risen at a 9V2 per cent rate
in the past six months, I am sure that you can see
why my reading of the events of the past seven or
eight years gives me cause for concern. The trend
growth of money from 1962 to 1966 was over twice
the average rate of the previous decade. I am fairly
certain that after the credit crunch of 1966, there
were few who would have viewed another doubling
of the growth of money to be desirable. But that is
what happened in 1967 and 1968. After the high
interest rate, highly inflationary developments of 1969,
and the liquidity crisis of 1970, I suggest that further
acceleration of the longer-term trend growth of money
should be avoided at all cost. Thus, the excessively
rapid growth of money in recent months gives me a
feeling of “butterflies” where butterflies ought not to
be.
Page 13

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Recent Monetary Growth
Additional insight into how rapid monetary growth
has been recently can be obtained by comparing the
increases in some recent periods with all earlier pe­
riods of similar length. In the last three months money
rose at a 12 V2 per cent annual rate, which is faster
than all other three-month periods since World War
II. In the last six months, money rose at about a 9V2
per cent annual rate, which is also faster than all
other consecutive six-month periods in the last twentyfive years. Similarly, in the fifteen months since Feb­
ruary 1970, the approximate time when more rapid
monetary growth was resumed following the restraint
initiated in early 1969, money has risen at about a
7V2 per cent annual rate. This is faster than all but one
per cent of similar length periods. This is telling
evidence that recent monetary growth has indeed
been very rapid, whether viewed in terms of absolute
rates of growth or relative to historical experience.

Implications for the Future
In closing, I would like to review with you some
factors which may have an important influence on
the growth rate of money in the near future. For
obvious reasons, I cannot divulge recent policy deci­
sions, and I could not disclose the growth rate of
money that is likely to result from policy actions, even
if I knew. However, I can discuss some factors which
might be considered in the formulation and especially
in the implementation of policy, as these have been
made public elsewhere.
I will indicate my judgment as to the direction of
influence of some factors which seem likely to lead to
excessive monetary growth if we do not profit from
the experiences of the past. These factors are: Treas­
ury financing requirements in fiscal 1972; concern over
the general level and trend of market interest rates;
and desires to rapidly expand growth of real product
and to achieve a lower rate of unemployment as soon
as possible. Obviously there is some overlap among
these factors.
First, I think the direction of influence of Treasury
financing requirements in the past is clear; that is,
periods of large Government deficits have tended to
be accompanied by rapid monetary growth. President
Nixon’s budget message in January this year indicated
a deficit of $11% billion in the fiscal year beginning
July 1, 1971. However, as widely discussed at the
time, the deficit will be larger than otherwise to the
extent that national income falls short of the assump­
tions made by the President’s advisers. Also, the deficit
will be larger if there is any tendency for Congress to
Digitized for Page
FRASER
14


JU N E 1971

spend more than the President requested. According
to assessments reported in the press earlier this year,
the planned deficit is probably the minimum that will
occur. The experiences of two previous periods, 1965
through early 1966 and 1967 through early 1968, in­
dicate that monetary actions may result in a more
rapid growth of the money stock than otherwise under
conditions of substantial Treasury financing.
The second factor which must be guarded against
in order to avoid continued excessively rapid growth
of money, and this ties in with the Treasury financing
constraint, is concern for the level and trend of inter­
est rates. As the growth of real output in the economy
accelerates during the balance of this year and in
1972, or as anticipation of inflation increases, the de­
mand for credit to finance production, consumption,
and investment will increase. Such increases in de­
mand for credit put upward pressure on market inter­
est rates.
There are at least two ways such a tendency for
market interest rates to rise would indicate conditions
which might induce excessively rapid growth of
money, unless we carefully guard against them. First,
interest rates have traditionally played an important
role in the implementation of policy decisions, as I
have illustrated previously. High or rising interest
rates have frequently been identified with more re­
strictive monetary policy, and I doubt there is a pre­
dominant desire of policymakers to achieve a very
restrictive policy stance at this time. Decisions to
maintain relatively easy conditions in the money and
short-term credit markets might lead to substantial
purchases of securities on the open market. Such ac­
tions could very well foster too rapid growth of bank
reserves and deposits, and thereby too rapid a rate of
money creation, if we are not careful to avoid such a
development.
The other way that a tendency for interest rates to
rise might suggest rapid growth of money is the view
that low interest rates, especially on longer-term se­
curities, are essential for a recovery of real economic
growth. This view holds that the market level of long­
term interest rates is an important factor in business
investment plans. It is argued that a rise in interest
rates might “choke-off” recovery in business capital
expenditures before the economy has returned to a
balanced level of high-employment real growth. I am
suggesting that one approach to stabilization analysis
views low interest rates as being necessary for real
recovery, and that stabilization actions should be di­
rected towards achieving and maintaining low inter­
est rates. Again, policymakers cannot accept this line

JU N E 1971

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

of reasoning without running the risk of excessive
growth in money.
The third factor which, if given considerable weight,
would tend to indicate continued rapid monetary
growth is the desire for rapid reattainment of high
growth in real output and a low rate of unemploy­
ment. Aside from the influence of interest rates, there
are some who argue that rapid growth of money is
necessary and desirable in order to reduce quickly the
rate of unemployment by two or more percentage
points, and to avoid the lasses in output inherent in
continuing to produce below capacity.
While I agree that these are very desirable objec­
tives, I feel that achieving continued reduction in the
rate of inflation is also a worthy cause. It seems that
some balance between the actions necessary to achieve
a quick end to the inflation and those necessary to
achieve a quick return to full employment is best.
Especially at the present time, those who argue for
very stimulative policies should make a realistic assess­
ment of the implications for future inflation, and
indicate their willingness to accept such consequences.
Given the very long lags we have observed in the
past between the initiation of restrictive actions and
progress towards smaller price rises, it is not sufficient
to say we can fight that battle when the time comes.




Present actions must be made with full recognition
of their eventual consequences. In the period we have
reviewed tonight, policy actions were frequently di­
rected towards the attainment of short- or intermedi­
ate-term objectives, such as holding interest rates down
to help the housing industry or to encourage business
investment. Recently, actions also have been directed
towards achieving an early reduction in the average
rate of unemployment, and a prompt return to growth
of real output at long-run potential. However, a careful
analysis of the events of this period show that actions
taken to deal with an immediate concern can later
have adverse effects on longer-run aspects of eco­
nomic activity. Thus, it frequently appears that pres­
ent actions are simply dealing with problems created
by past actions. While I do not view the situation as
hopeless, it is obvious that there is ample room for
improvement.
In conclusion, my remarks tonight may not appear
to be very optimistic. Possibly our future policy ac­
tions will be better than in the past. We have ample
experience from which we can learn. If we do, then
an adage regarding our ability to learn from past
experience would not be valid, at least with regard
to the conduct of stabilization policy. The adage is:
W hat men learn from history,
is that men do not learn from history.

Page 15

SUBSCRIPTIONS to this bank’s

R

e v ie w

are available to the public without

charge, including bulk mailings to banks, business organizations, educational
institutions, and others. For information write: Research Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis, P. O. Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166.