View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF ST. LOUIS
JULY 1976

'

CONTENTS

CONTENTS
Bank Financing of the Recovery ....
An Explanation of Movements in
Short-Term Interest R a te s.........

Vol. 58, No. 7




2
10

Bank Financing of the Recovery
R. ALTON GILBERT

t t h i l e recovery periods display many common
characteristics, each such period has its own unique
features which distinguish it from other recoveries.
A unique feature of the current recovery period is
the lack of growth of bank loans. In previous re­
coveries, total loans of commercial banks have in­
creased soon after recession troughs; in the current
recovery period, total loans have remained essentially
unchanged since the March 1975 trough in economic
activity.

Even more uncharacteristic of previous recovery
periods is the pattern of business loans at commercial
banks. In contrast to the increases posted in previous
recoveries, commercial bank business loans have de­
clined in the current recovery. Since March of last
year, business loans at commercial banks have de­
clined at a 5 percent annual rate, compared to a 5.5
percent rate of increase for comparable phases of
previous recoveries. In addition, the rate of decline
in business lending by the larger commercial banks
has been more rapid than for the rest of the banking
system; since March of last year commercial and in­
dustrial loans of weekly reporting banks have declined
at a 9.5 percent annual rate.
This pattern of bank lending raises some important
questions for public policy. Have banks become more
conservative in their lending practices than in the
past? Is the relative lack of bank financing likely to
hamper continued economic recovery? Have busi­
nesses developed alternative sources of credit? How
have these developments influenced the ability of the
U.S. Treasury to finance large deficits without causing
substantial upward pressure on short-term interest
rates?

Page 2


Total Loans by A ll Com m ercial B an ks
T ro « g h s= 1 0 0
130

______________ S e a s o n a l l y A d j u s t e d ______________

T ro u g h s= 1 0 0
130

Average

-4

0

4

8

12

M O N TH S TO A N D FR O M TR O U G H S
N o t e : D a t e o n e a c h lin e in d ic a t e s t ro u g h m on th.
’ A v e r a g e o f 3 p r e v i o u s r e c e s s i o n / r e c o v e r y p e r io d s w ith t r o u g h s in O c t o b e r 1 9 4 9 ,
M a y 1 9 5 4 , a n d A p r il 1958.
C h a r t II

Business Loans b y A ll Com m ercial B an k s

-1 6

-12

-8

-4

0

4

8

12

M O N T H S TO A N D FR O M TR O U G H S
N o t e : D a t e o n e a c h lin e in d ic a t e s t ro u g h m on th.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

HAVE BANKS BECOME
MOBE CONSEBVATTVE?
Several events of the past two
years would tend to make banks
more conservative. Banks have
sustained unusually large losses
in the past two years, particu­
larly on loans (see Table I for
some historical comparisons).
The Securities and Exchange
Commission and the Federal
bank regulatory agencies have
been requiring banks to disclose
more information on the risks
they assume, and the press has
published lists of “problem
banks.” In addition, bank regu­
lators have been trying during
recent years to get banks to in­
crease their capital ratios, par­
ticularly the ratio of capital to
riskier bank assets.1

JULY

1976

Table 1

LOSS RATIOS OF ALL COMMERCIAL BANKS
(thousands of dollars)
Net
Total Losses1
1948
1949
1950
1951
1952
1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1966
1967
1968
1969
1970
1971
1972
1973
1974
1975

$

46,450
56,837
36,985
51,620
54,342
91,822
61,798
113,617
172,985
138,996
67,773
250,001
225,595
188,208
165,553
237,676
275,558
327,031
458,770
455,948
440,941
499,212
983,259
1,088,661
885,416
1,162,566
1,958,400
3,244,828

Percent of
Total Assets2
.0304
.0374
.0238
.0309
.0306
.0492
.0323
.0566
.0827
.0643
.0306
.1053
.0927
.0734
.0597
.0803
.0884
.0948
.1222
.1132
.0978
.0988
.1853
.1889
.1384
.1576
.2352
.3556

Net
Loan Losses3
$

35,643
53,333
34,226
36,258
33,099
55,574
49,111
48,623
80,812
67,113
58,442
48,525
196,173
175,656
153,962
226,578
236,390
305,428
401,788
432,514
410,592
488,750
981,638
1,087,200
887,326
1,159,187
1,956,931
3,242,830

Percent of
Total Assets2
.0233
.0350
.0220
.0217
.0187
.0298
.0257
.0242
.0386
.0310
.0264
.0204
.0806
.0685
.0555
.0766
.0758
.0885
.1070
.1073
.0911
.0967
.1850
.1886
.1387
.1571
.2350
.3554

The “banks have become more
conservative” explanation of re­
cent bank lending behavior is
supported by several empirical
observations. For one, banks 1Losses on loans and securities less recoveries on loans and securities.
assets for each year measured as of the end o f the prior year. Assets in December 1968 and
have not reduced their loans to 2Total
prior years include "other loans and discounts" at gross (before deduction of valuation reserves)
value, as reported in 1969 and 1970. ‘ 'Other loans and discounts” iil 1948-1968 exclude Federal funds
businesses because of a lack of
sold, now reported separately. Source: FDIC Annual Reports.
available reserves. Bank loans 3Losses on loans less recoveries on loans.
plus investments have risen at
rate for larger firms. Since March of last year the dif­
a 5.1 percent annual rate since March of last year,
ferential between the prime rate and the commercial
but almost all of this increase in earning assets has
gone to investments, especially Federal Government
paper rate has averaged 1.4 percentage points,
debt. Investments as a percentage of the interest-earn­
whereas that differential averaged 0.5 percentage
point during 1971-74. Chart III compares the pattern
ing assets of banks rose from 27 percent in the last
quarter of 1974 (the low point for this ratio in recent
of the differential between the prime rate and the
years) to 32 percent in June of this year. This ratio
commercial paper rate in the current recovery to the
rose to 34 percent in mid-1971 and declined steadily
average differential and the range of that differential
in comparable phases of four previous recoveries.2
thereafter until early 1975.
Since last fall, the interest rate differential has been
As another possible indication of conservative be­
above the average differential for comparable periods
havior, banks have kept their announced prime lend­
of prior recoveries. In addition, for most of the period
ing rates high relative to the four- to six-month prime
since early this year the interest rate differential has
commercial paper rate — an* alternative borrowing
been greater than that posted for comparable periods
of each of the five prior recoveries. The relatively
!O ne of the major methods bank regulators have been using to
induce banks to reduce their exposure to risk of failure is to
deny applications by the most highly leveraged and poorly
managed banking organizations to engage in new activities.
For examples of such actions by the Federal Reserve Board,
see discussions of cases in the following issues of the Fed­
eral Reserve Bulletin: June 1974, pp. 458-59; October 1974,
pp. 731-32; November 1974, pp. 791-93; December 1974,
pp. 864-65.




2This interest rate differential tends to have a cyclical pattern
which, therefore, must be compared to its value in previous
recession/recovery periods to determine whether it has been
unusually large during recent months. See Richard T. Selden,
Trends and Cycles in the Commercial Paper Market (N ew
York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1963), pp.
72-82.
Page 3

FEDERAL. RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

C h a r t III

D iffe re n tia l B e tw e e n the
Com m ercial B a n k Prime Lending Rate a n d the
4 - to 6 - M o n t h Prime C o m m e rc ia l P a p e r R ate
in C urre n t a n d P ast C ycles
P e rc e n ta ge
3

Perc e n tage

P o in t s

P o in t s
3

1976

ducted early this year indicates that the loans which
banks expect to declare as losses this year are pri­
marily real estate loans.4 Also, loss ratios tend to be
higher on consumer lending than on lending to
business. Therefore, these increases in real estate and
consumer loans indicate that risk reduction has not
become a dominant objective of commercial bank
lending policies.

Decline In Demand for Business Credit

0

4

>

12

16

20

24

M O N T H S TO A N D F R O M T R O U G H S

high prime rate is an apparent indication of reluc­
tance by banks to expand their lending to businesses.

WEAKNESSES OF THE CONSERVATIVEBANKER EXPLANATION
Some Categories of Loans Increase
An indication that banks have not been unusually
conservative in their lending practices in recent
months is that, while business loans have declined,
banks have increased their real estate and consumer
loans. Mortgage debt held by all commercial banks
rose 4.2 percent from the first quarter of 1975 to the
first quarter of 1976. Consumer installment loans of
all commercial banks began to increase after May of
last year, rising at a 4 percent annual rate from May
1975 to April 1976.3 The patterns of change in real
estate loans and consumer installment loans have been
somewhat different at the larger commercial banks.
Real estate loans of weekly reporting large commer­
cial banks remained essentially unchanged during the
year ending in March of this year, but have increased
at a 9.8 percent annual rate in the last three months.
Their consumer installment loans began rising after
June of last year, increasing 7.9 percent from June
of last year to June of this year.
A large share of bank loan losses in the past two
years has been in real estate loans. A survey con-

Even though the commercial bank prime rate has
been unusually high in relation to the commercial
paper rate during the current recovery, there has not
been a large-scale shift in credit demand by business
firms from commercial banks to the commercial paper
market. Commercial paper volume moved in its typi­
cal counter-cyclical pattern during the recent reces­
sion/recovery period, rising during the recession and
declining for several months after the recession
trough.5 From March 1975 to May 1976, the volume
of commercial paper declined at a 2 percent annual
rate. '
Since borrowing from commercial banks and bor­
rowing in the commercial paper market are primary
sources of short-term credit for many large businesses,
the sum of these two sources can be used as a measure
of the demand for short-term business credit. If the
decline in business loans by banks during the current
recovery was just due to banks keeping their interest
rates on loans uncompetitive with the commercial
paper rate, the sum of business loans plus commercial
paper volume would have tended to follow the usual
recovery pattern. During previous recovery periods
the sum of commercial bank loans to business plus
commercial paper volume has risen a few months
after recession troughs, whereas in the current recov­
ery this measure of credit demand has declined (see
Chart IV).

The Changing Role of the Prime Rate
Several recent news stories mention that banks have
been offering loans below the stated prime rate to a
greater extent during recent months than in the past.
In addition, banks have been relaxing other terms of
lending, such as compensating balance requirements.6
These stories about more bank loans at rates below
*Wall Street Journal, May 14, 1976, p. 10.

3Consumer installment loans outstanding tend to begin rising
about two months after the rate of economic activity begins
to rise. See Philip A. Klein, The Cyclical Timing of Consumer
Credit, 1920-67, Occasional Paper 113, National Bureau of
Economic Research, 1971, p. 28.


Page 4


5Selden, Trends and Cycles in the Commercial Paper Market,
pp. 72-74.
8American Banker, May 5, 1976, p. 1; Business W eek, May 24,
1976, pp. 33-34.

FEDERAL. RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

risks of engaging in liability management during pe­
riods of widely fluctuating interest rates.

C h a r t IV

Bu sin ess Loans by A ll C om m ercial B an k s
Plus Com m ercial Paper Volu m e
T r O U f l h s ^ l O Q _______________________S e c o n d l y A d j u s t e d _______________________ T r C » | t » = I O O

F e b r u a t f 61^ ^ ^

iT O

M a r c iT T T

.....................

■16

-12

i t 1 i i i 1 i i

............................

-8

-4

X

0

4

8

i

_

1 I

12

i i

1 i i

16

i 1 i i

20

i

24

M O N T H S TO A N D FROM TRO U G H S
N o t e : D a t e o n e a c h lin e in d ic a t e s t r o u g h m o n th.

the prime rate are confirmed by surveys of interest
rates on short-term business loans at a sample of large
commercial banks. Table II presents the percentage
of loans made at and below the prime rate for selected
survey periods.7 The percentage of loans at interest
rates below the prime rate increased in February and
May of this year, although there was no marked rise
in the percentage of loans made “at and below” the
prime rate. The rise in the percentage of loans made
at rates below prime was confined to loans of $1 mil­
lion and over. These observations raise doubts about
the reliability of the difference between the com­
mercial bank prime lending rate and the commercial
paper rate as an indicator of conservative lending
policies by banks.
Incentives for maintaining the stated prime rate
high relative to alternative interest rates and making
loans at less than the prime rate, as in the current
recovery period, may be the result of banks having
made business loans at interest rates that float with
the prime rate. This policy has become widespread
throughout the banking industry in recent years.8 By
making loans with floating rates, banks have forgone
the windfall gains they formerly received during pe­
riods of interest rate declines, but have reduced the
7In the sample, banks report the dollar amount and interest rate
of each business loan S1,000 and over made during the first
seven business days of February, May, August and November
of each year. The date each loan was made is not reported.
The prime rate has changed during several of these survey
periods in recent years, creating difficulty in determining
which loans were made at the prevailing prime rate. Obser­
vations in Table II are from surveys conducted during periods
when the prime rate did not change.
^Richard B. Miller, “Everybody’s Floating the Loan Rate,” The
Bankers Magazine (Spring 1975), pp. 42-45.




1976

If interest rates on a bank’s outstanding loans are
not affected by prime rate changes, the bank’s interest
income on such loans will not be affected when the
prime rate is adjusted. However, if banks make float­
ing rate loans, a change in the prime rate does affect
the interest income on outstanding loans as well as
the volume of new loans attracted.
During the recent period of declining business de­
mand for short-term credit, banks with floating in­
terest rates on their outstanding loans have had in­
centives to keep their stated prime rates high and
earn relatively high income on outstanding business
loans until they are paid off. However, given the rela­
tively large differential between the stated prime
rate and other short-term interest rates, banks have
had strong incentives to offer credit at less than the
prime rate to firms which can also borrow in the
commercial paper market, disregarding the conven­
tional banking practice of using the prime rate as
the minimum loan rate.9 As noted above the increase
in loans at interest rates below the prime rate since last
year has been primarily loans of $1 million or more,
which would be largely to firms that could also bor­
row in the commercial paper market.

EXPLANATIONS OF THE DECLINE
IN BUSINESS LOANS
Discarding the argument that banks have be­
come more conservative, two reasons appear to explain
the lack of bank financing in the current recovery:
(a) Businesses continued to reduce their inven­
tories by large amounts and for an unusually long
period of time into the current recovery.
(b ) The volume of funds that business firms gen­
erate internally has increased even more rapidly dur­
ing recent quarters than during previous recovery
periods, reducing the external financing requirements
of businesses. Banks have responded to the decline in
business credit demand by significantly expanding
their holdings of investments and increasing their
loans in sectors of the economy in which demand for
bank financing has been rising (including real estate
and consumer loans) with the pace of economic
activity.
9For an analysis of the role of the prime rate before floating
rates became so common, see Donald Hodgman, Commercial
Bank Loan and Investment Policy (Champaign, Illinois: Uni­
versity of Illinois, 1963).
Page 5

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

1976

Table II

PERCENTAGE OF BUSINESS LOANS AT A N D BELOW THE PRIME RATE
Percentage Distribution of Dollar Amount by Size of Loan and Interest Rate
(thousands of dollars)

$ 1,000
Month of
Survey

Prime
Rate

All
Sizes

May

1976

6.7 5 %

below 6.75
at and
below 6.75

Feb.

1976

6.75

below 6.75
at and
below 6.75

Aug.

1975

7.50

below 7.50
at and
below 7.50

May

1975

7.50

below 7.50
at and
below 7.50

Aug.

1974

12.00

below 12.00
at and
below 12.00

$1 - $10

$10 - $100

$100 $500

$500 $1,000

and
over

0 .9 %

1 .5 %

2 .4 %

1 8 .7 %

13 . 9 %

2 .2 %

46.8

3.7

5.7

20.2

36.2

56.6

8.7

1.8

0.5

1.1

1.8

12.0

38.0

3.1

5.0

18.4

29.8

46.4

4.3

3.4

1.3

3.1

3.4

4.9

39.3

5.5

6.7

21.9

32.1

46.7

6.8

3.9

1.3

2.3

4.6

8.4

46.1

5.4

6.4

22.0

35.9

55.6

5.2

49.4

30.0

11.8

5.9

2.6

63.1

55.8

42.7

38.9

49.8

70.1

Reduction in Inventories
Changes in business inventories during the first
four postwar business cycles were similar in amount
and timing; the average changes in inventories dur­
ing those recession/recovery periods are shown in
Chart V. The 1970 recession was rather mild com­

C h ort V

C h a n g e in Business Inventories

pared to other postwar recessions; firms were not in­
duced to reduce inventories, but merely to reduce the
rate of accumulation for one quarter. In contrast,
inventory reductions beginning in late 1974 were un­
usually large and have continued for an unusually
long period of time into the current recovery. Busi­
nesses finally began to increase their inventories in
the first quarter of this year.
The unusually rapid accumulation of inventories
during 1973 and much of 1974 was partially a reac­
tion to shortages of various materials and products
caused by wage and price controls and the real and
expected effects of the reduction in the supply of
energy. Also rapid price increases in late 1973 through
the first three quarters of 1974 induced speculation on
the prospects of inventory profits. The depth of the
recession in 1974-75 reduced the prospects of inven­
tory profits and gave businesses incentives for the
rapid liquidation of inventories beginning late that
year as inventories became excessive in relation to
sales.
Statistical studies of the determinants of bank loans
indicate that changes in business inventories have
been primary determinants of changes in bank loans
to businesses.10 Therefore, the large inventory reduc­

QU ARTERS TO A N D FROM TRO UG HS
S o u rc e : U.S. D e p a r t m e n t o f C o m m e rc e
• A v e r a g e o f 4 p r e v i o u s r e c e s s io n / r e c o v e r y p e r io d s w ith t r o u g h s in IV / 4 9 , 11/54,
11/58, a n d 1/61.


Page 6


10Stephen M. Goldfeld, Commercial Bank Behavior and Eco­
nomic Activity (Amsterdam: North Holland Publishing Co.,
1966), pp. 82-86, 162; and Patric H. Hendershott, “ Recent
Development of the Financial Sector of Econometric Models,”
Journal of Finance (M arch 1968), pp. 57-58, 62-65.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

1976

Table III

SELECTED SERIES FROM THE FLOW OF FUNDS ACCOUNTS FOR NO N FINAN CIAL CORPORATE BUSINESS
(billions of dollars; seasonally adjusted annual rates)
1973
1

II

1974
III

IV

1

II

1975
III

IV

1

19761

II

III

IV

1

Profits Before Tax

94.2

98.1

94.9

93.5

100.8

109.6

126.8

100.2

72.7

86.4

108.1

108.9

114.2

Gross Internal Funds

83.7

83.6

84.8

86.3

85.3

80.5

75.3

84.8

85.9

103.0

113.7

112.8

120.0

104.1

107.6

110.9

112.0

112.3

118.0

116.3

113.3

110.6

107.8

110.9

115.8

119.7
32.3

Fixed Investment
Net Funds Raised In
Financial Markets

73.9

70.7

66.1

57.9

75.4

91.6

72.8

68.7

30.9

36.4

31.5

44.7

Net New Equity Issues

7.0

8.7

5.1

8.9

6.2

5.0

0

5.2

7.7

12.9

6.9

12.2

7.2

Corporate Bonds

9.2

11.9

12.5

10.3

18.8

20.7

18.0

27.9

41.9

33.7

17.0

26.7

19.7

15.1

18.4

17.7

13.3

12.6

17.4

7.3

6.3

6.6

9.2

11.1

13.6

12.0

Corporate Mortgages

JData for 1/76 are incomplete and preliminary.

tions during the current recovery period can be con­
sidered a major cause of the declines in bank loans
to businesses.

Increase in Internally Generated Funds
Table III presents several series from the flow-offunds accounts for the nonfinancial corporate sector
in recent years. The series “Gross Internal Funds”
measures retained earnings of nonfinancial corpora­
tions plus their capital consumption allowances, with
some adjustments for foreign profits and changes in
the value of inventories. The larger the increase in
gross internal funds, the smaller the external financing
requirements of firms tend to be, other things equal.
Gross internal funds increased 40 percent from the
first quarter of 1975 to the first quarter of this year.
This was a more rapid rate of increase than in the
first year of each of the four previous recoveries. This
relatively rapid expansion was due to a sharp accel­
eration in pre-tax corporate profits, which rose 57
percent from the first quarter of 1975 to the first
quarter of 1976.

Lengthening the Maturities of Business
Liabilites
From the fourth quarter of 1974 to the first quarter
of 1976, net funds raised in financial markets by non­
financial corporations increased $41.6 billion. Funds
raised from long-term sources ( issuing equities, bonds,
and mortgages) increased $57.1 billion, and short­
term liabilities that had been incurred in financial
markets were reduced by $15.5 billion.11 Since fixed
11These data were calculated by accumulating seasonally un­
adjusted quarterly changes in funds raised. Note that data
in Table III are at seasonally adjusted annual rates.




investment by corporations during the current re­
covery has been about equal to their internally
generated funds (see Table III), the increase in funds
from long-term sources has not been used to finance
increases in long-term assets; instead, such funds have
been used to replace short-term debt in corporate
balance sheets. This shift to long-term financing is
largely a response to regular cyclical forces and the
unusually large changes in business inventories dis­
cussed above.
As indicated in Chart VI the ratio of long-term
funds raised by nonfinancial corporations to net total
funds raised has increased during recession periods
and remained relatively high for a few quarters after
recession troughs. This pattern can be attributed to
both a cyclical response in the allocation of business
investment between inventories and fixed investment
and to cyclical movements in the demand for financial
credit and demand for equities.
Business firms tend to finance inventories from
short-term borrowing and fixed investment from long­
term borrowing, thereby attempting to match the
length of time over which assets are held with the
maturities of funds raised. Corporate fixed investment
and inventory investment move pro-cyclically, with
inventory investment more sensitive to reductions in
aggregate demand. As discussed above, business firms
do not begin rapid inventory accumulation until a
few quarters after recession troughs. These cyclical
patterns of fixed investment and inventory investment
help explain the cyclical pattern of financing illus­
trated in Chart VI.
Total demand for credit in the economy tends to
decline during recessions and rise as economic ac­
tivity increases. Total net funds raised by nonfinancial
corporations also move procyclically, but funds raised
Page 7

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

1976

C h ort V I

R a t io o f F u n d s R a is e d from L o n g -T e rm S o u rc e s
to T o ta l N e t F u n d s R a i s e d *

- 3 1---------- ---------- --------------------- ---------- ---------- ---------- ---------- '---------- ---------- '---------- '---------- 1---------- 1---------- 1---------- 1---------- 1---------- '---------- ---------- 1---------- 1---------- 1-------------------- --------------------1952
1 95 3 1 95 4
1955 1956
1957
1958
1 95 9 1 9 6 0
1961
1 96 2
1963
1964
1965
1 9 6 6 1 96 7
196!
196 9
1970
1971
197 2
1 9 7 3 197 4
1975
1976

.3

The first four sh a d e d are a s represent p e rio d s of b u sin e ss recessions a s defined by the N a tio n a l Bu re au of Economic Research. The fifth sh a d e d a re a is tentative, a n d h as been defined b y the Fe de ral Reserve
B an k of St. Louis.
'L o n g -te rm so u rc e s of fun d s are equ ity iss u e s, b o n d s, a n d m o rtga ge s.
L atest d a t a plotted: 1st q u a rte r

by nonfinancial corporations from issuing bonds and
equity securities have different cyclical patterns.
The procyclical pattern of total credit demand tends
to cause interest rates to move procyclically, including
interest rates on long-term debt instruments. Business
requirements for funds from long-term sources rise
when economic activity is expanding and businesses
are increasing their capital investments. Therefore,
given the tendency for long-term interest rates to be
lower during recessions than during the following
periods of economic recovery, there is some incentive
for businesses to do their long-term financing during
recessions in anticipation of future increases in capital
investment.
Changes in corporate debt over business cycles re­
flect such a financing strategy. Corporate bonds out­
standing have increased more rapidly during the past
five recessions than in periods just prior to those re­
cessions, even though total net funds raised by non­
financial corporations declined during those recession

Page 8


periods.12 Although long-term credit demanded by
corporations increases during recession periods, the
net effect of corporate credit demand, reduction in
demand for credit by other sectors, and possible shifts
in supply of credit due to reduced inflationary antici­
pations create a tendency for long-term interest rates
to decline during recessions. One study traces this
cyclical pattern of corporate financing back to 1900.13
Typically, stock prices begin to rise a few months
before recession troughs, as investors anticipate
coming recoveries and corresponding rises in business
profits. Rising stock prices, in turn, increase the
12These past five recessions include the most recent one ending
around March 1975. The phase of the recent recession that
was due to a decline in aggregate demand began in the fall
of 1974, and that period is used as the cycle peak for pur­
poses of examining the influences of declining aggregate de­
mand on long-term interest rates and long-term borrowings by
corporations. For an analysis of causes for the most recent re­
cession, see Norman N. Bowsher, “ Tw o Stages of the Current
Recession,” this Review (June 1975), pp. 2-8.
13W . Braddock Hickman, The Volume of Corporate Bond Fi­
nancing Since 1900 ( New York: National Bureau of E co­
nomic Research, 1953), pp. 132-179.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

attractiveness to businesses of raising funds by is­
suing equity securities. During postwar business cy­
cles equity issues by nonfinancial corporations have
increased substantially during trough quarters and
the first few quarters of recovery.
Corporate financing patterns during the recent re­
cession and current recovery appear to reflect the
usual cyclical influences plus that of the unusually
large swings in inventory investment and liquidation.
There may have been a more permanent shift in
business preferences for more long-term financing, but
not enough time has elapsed since the recent reces­
sion to distinguish such an influence from the cyclical
tendencies in corporate finance.

IMPLICATIONS FOR FINANCING
FEDERAL BUDGET DEFICITS
Commercial banks increased their holdings of
Federal Government debt at a 57 percent annual rate
from January 1975 to March 1976, largely in re­




JULY

1976

sponse to the decline in demand for bank loans by
business firms. This reduction in demand for short­
term credit by businesses is one development which
has made it possible for the Treasury to finance large
budget deficits in 1975 and into 1976 without having
put substantial upward pressure on short-term
interest rates.
Business demand for short-term credit is likely
to increase in the near future, as the incentives for
inventory investment increase along with the gen­
eral economic expansion. Corporate cash flow is
likely to increase less rapidly in the future since cor­
porate profits tend to rise less rapidly after the first
year of an economic recovery. The shift in corporate
financing to long-term sources during the recent re­
cession and current recovery appears to be largely a
cyclical phenomenon. As business demand for short­
term credit increases, the Federal Government will
not be able to continue financing large budget deficits
without putting some upward pressures on short-term
rates.

Page 9

An Explanation of Movements
In Short-Term Interest Rates
ALBERT E. BURGER

^ IRTUALLY all central banks are concerned about
movements in interest rates since, rightly or wrongly,
the public usually regards the central bank as being
responsible for such movements. An influential body
of economic analysis also assigns considerable import­
ance to the effects of movements in interest rates
on economic activity. In addition, central banks have
traditionally been concerned with the stability or
viability of financial markets, where such stability
and viability is usually viewed as being endangered
by substantial fluctuations of interest rates. Conse­
quently, in their policy deliberations the monetary
authorities tend to give considerable weight to the
possible impacts of their policy actions on interest
rates.
It is important, therefore, to investigate the process
by which interest rates are determined. This article
is a modest step in that direction as it illustrates the
manner in which a proposed explanation (hypothesis)
of the movements in the short-term interest rate can
be designed and tested. The purpose is not to develop
a forecasting equation for the short-term interest
rate, but to understand the process whereby interest
rates are generated. The influence of key policy-deter­
mined variables, such as the growth rate of the mone­
tary base and the money supply, are incorporated into
the hypothesis.
A basic tenet of scientific investigation is that it is
never proven that an hypothesis describes the one and
only true world. Every hypothesis, if it is of any
scientific value, must be formulated in such a manner
that it can be falsified by some set of observations.
The more easily it can be falsified, the better the
design of the hypothesis. Therefore, the result of any
such process should be considered only tentative
and subject to further testing. If the logical conse­
quences of an hypothesis are not in agreement with
the data, then it is back to the drawing board. Such
a situation could result for any number of reasons,
all of which must be carefully studied. If the hypoth­
esis is not rejected, we have not found the truth, but
instead have taken just a very tentative step in our

Page 10


understanding of some economic process. Given this
caveat emptor, we now proceed with the formal
derivation and testing of an hypothesis designed to
explain the month-.to-month movements in the short­
term interest rate.
The first step in the design and testing of the
hypothesis is to present a model of the market for
short-term credit with specified constraints on the
parameters of the model. The next step is to specify
the observable data used to represent such general
terms as “the state of economic activity,” the “growth
rate of money,” “growth of prices,” etc. The conjunc­
tion of the model, the constraints, and the specifica­
tion of the empirical counterpart of the terms appear­
ing in the model represent the hypothesis.
A reduced-form expression for the short-term inter­
est rate is constructed and, using the restrictions on
the structural parameters, test statements are derived.
These test statements are then confronted with em­
pirical observations to determine whether they are in
“good agreement” with historical observations. After
testing the hypothesis, a dynamic simulation of the
short-term interest rate is performed using the re­
duced-form model for the interest rate.

THE MODEL AND ITS EMPIRICAL
SPECIFICATIONS
An algebraic formulation of the hypothesis is pre­
sented in Exhibit I. In the short-term credit market
model, the demand for and supply of credit are
divided into two parts — the private sector ( equations
1 and 2) and the Government sector (equations 5
and 6 ). The private sector demand ( D p) and supply
(SD) of credit are influenced by such factors as the
prevailing interest rate (i), the expected interest
rate (ie), the expected rate of change of prices (Pe),
and the growth rate of the monetary base (B). The
expected rate of change of prices is postulated to de­
pend upon the prevailing long-run growth rate of
money (M) , recent changes in prices (P), and the

JULY

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Exhibit I

ALGEBRAIC FORMULATION OF THE
HYPOTHESIS
Market for Short-Term Credit
(1 ) private sector demand for credit:
DP = ao + ai i + a 2 ie + a3 Pe
(2 ) private sector supply of credit:
Sp = bo + b i i + b 2 ie + b3 Pe + b 4 B
(3 ) formation of interest rate expectations:
ie = co + c i it-i + C2 it-2
(4 ) formation of price expectations:
Pe = d i P + d 2 M + d3 U + vt
(5 ) Government demand for credit: D ° = eo + ei U
(6 ) Government supply of credit: SG = fo + fi U
(7 ) total demand for credit: D = DP + D G
(8 ) total supply of credit: S = Sp + S°
(9 ) equilibrium condition: D = S

where:
i = short-term interest rate
ie = expected short-term interest rate
B = short-run rate of growth of the monetary base
Pe = expected rate of change of prices
P = lagged actual rate of change of prices
U = state of economic activity
M = lagged long-run growth rate of money
vt = random variable
Constraints
(1 0 ) ai < 0

(2 1 ) d2 > 0

(1 1 ) a2 > 0

(2 2 ) d3 < 0

(1 2 ) a3 > 0

(2 3 ) ei > 0

(1 3 ) b i > 0

(2 4 ) ft < 0

(1 4 ) b 2 < 0

(2 5 ) |a3d3| > |fi - ei|

(1 5 ) b3 < 0

(2 6 ) d2 > di

(16)b4 > 0

(2 7 ) |di| > |d3|

(1 7 ) c i > 0

(2 8 ) |d2| > |dsl

(1 8 ) c i + C2 > 0

(2 9 ) 1 — c i — C2 > 0

(1 9 ) c i > C2

(3 0 ) 1 + C2 > 0

(2 0 ) di > 0

(3 1 ) 1 + c i — c 2 > 0
Reduced Form for Interest Rate

(3 2 ) it = Ao_+ A i it-i + A 2 it-2 + A 3 P +
A4 M
As U + A6 B + £t
Test Statements for the Hypothesis
(3 3 ) A i > 0

(3 8 ) As < 0

(3 4 ) A i + A2 > 0

(3 9 ) A6 < 0

(3 5 ) A i -

(4 0 ) A4 — A3 > 0

A2 > 0

(3 6 ) As > 0

(4 1 ) As + As > 0

(3 7 ) A* > 0

(4 2 ) A 4 + As > 0




1976

current state of economic activity (U). Equation (4)
essentially states that expectations about future move­
ments in prices depend not only upon the past rate
of change of prices, but also upon information about
the long-run growth rate of money and the current
state of economic activity. Price expectations are also
hypothesized to depend upon certain random shocks
that are represented by the term vt which appears
in equation (4).
The expected interest rate (ie) is stated to depend
upon past values of the interest rate (equation 3).
Current-month decisions to supply or demand credit
are hypothesized to depend, among other things,
upon the level of the short-term interest rate in the
two previous months. The supply of credit is also
stated to depend upon the growth of a liquidity
variable, in this model represented by the growth
of the monetary base.
The Government sector’s demand for and supply
of credit are specified as dependent upon the state of
economic activity. Observation of the behavior of the
Government sector suggests that its demand for credit
also depends upon such things as its commitment to
financing social programs, military developments in
the world, and changes in tax laws. The hypothesis
presented in this paper does not explicitly take these
factors into account, but allows them to affect the
intercept term that appears in the equation for the
Government sector’s demand for credit. Further de­
velopment of the hypothesis might explicitly include
these factors. However, primarily due to the diffi­
culty of finding empirical counterparts to these con­
cepts on a monthly basis, they were not explicitly
taken into account.

Constraints on the Variables
The lower portion of Exhibit I presents a listing
of the hypothesized constraints on the structural
parameters of the model used to represent the short­
term credit market. These constraints state that the
private sector’s demand for credit ( Dp) depends
positively upon the expected short-term interest rate
(ie) and the expected rate of change of prices (Pe),
and negatively upon the current short-term interest
rate (i). The private sector’s supply of credit (SB)
depends positively on the rate of growth of the
monetary base (B ) and the current interest rate, and
negatively on the expected rate of change of prices
and the expected interest rate. The expected interest
rate is postulated to depend positively upon past
values of the interest rate. A series of past increases
in the interest rate is hypothesized to generate expec­
Page 11

FEDERAL. RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

tations of still further upward movements in interest
rates, thereby decreasing the amount of credit sup­
plied at the current interest rate and increasing the
quantity demanded at the current interest rate.
Price expectations are hypothesized to depend posi­
tively on recent changes in prices and the long-run
growth rate of money, and negatively on the state
of economic activity. For example, if prices have been
rising rapidly in the current period, but the long-run
trend growth of money has fallen and unemployment
has risen, then the hypothesis implies that investors
will not fully extrapolate into the future the current
rapid growth of prices, but will modify their price
expectations based on these latter two factors.
The Government sector’s demand for credit is spec­
ified to depend positively, and the Government sec­
tor’s supply of credit to depend negatively, upon the
state of economic activity. For example, as the state
of economic activity deteriorates, the expenditures of
Government trust funds rise faster than their receipts
and, hence, they reduce their purchases of Govern­
ment securities.
As a further restriction upon the parameters of
the model it is assumed that:
(2 5 ) |a3ds| >

|fi — ei|

This assumption essentially states that the response
of private demands for credit to changes in the state
of economic activity are larger than the net Govern­
ment reaction.
Furthermore, it is hypothesized that a one per­
centage point change in the long-run growth rate of
money has a greater impact on the expected rate of
inflation (Pe) than does a one percentage point in­
crease in the rate of change of prices (P):
(2 6 ) d2 >

di

It is also hypothesized that a one percentage point
change in the rate of change of prices has more of an
effect on price expectations than does a one percentage
point change in the state of economic activity (U) :
(2 7 ) |di| >

|ds|

In addition, it is hypothesized that a one percentage
point change in the long-run growth rate of money
has more of an influence on the expected rate of infla­
tion than does a one percentage point change in the
state of economic activity:
(2 8 ) |d2| >

|d3|

The specification of the signs and relative size of
the coefficients on the structural parameters of the
model is part of the hypothesis to be tested.



JULY

1976

Stability Conditions
The equation for the expected interest rate may
be rewritten as
ie —■c i it-i — C2 it-2 = co,

a second order difference equation. Hence, the
necessary and sufficient conditions for the stability
of the equilibrium value of i and the condition ie — i
requires further restrictions on admissable values
for cx and C2:1
(2 9 ) 1 — c i — C2 > 0
(3 0 ) 1 + C2 >
(3 1 ) 1 +

0

ci — c2 > 0

Reduced Form for the Short-Term
Interest Rate
Using the equilibrium condition that total demand
for credit equals total supply (D = S) and substitut­
ing equations (3 ) and (4) into ( 1 ) and ( 2 ), the fol­
lowing reduced-form expression for the short-term
interest rate is derived:
(32) it = A0 + A i it-i + A2 it-2 + A3 P + A4 M + A5U
4- AgB + £t
where: A<> =

C„(b2 - a2) + (bo - a„) + (f„ - e„)

ai - bi
ci (b2 - a2)
ai - b i
c 2 (b2 - a2)
ai - bi
di (b3 - a3)
ai - b i
d 2 (b3 - a3)
ai - b i
d 3 (b3 - a3)
ai - b i

ai - bi

b4

ai - b i

Specification of Test Statements
The constraints (10) - (31) that were placed on the
parameters of the credit market model logically
imply signs and ordering relationships for the co­
!For a discussion of necessary and sufficient conditions for
stability of a second order difference equation, see Samuel
Goldberg, Introduction to Difference Equations (N ew York:
John W iley & Sons, Inc., 1958), pp. 169-72.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

efficients of the reduced-form equation for the short­
term interest rate. From the statement of the reduced
form in equation (32) and from the set of conditions
(10) - (31), the test statements numbered (33) - (42)
are derived (Exhibit I). These test statements are
used to test the hypothesis. The derivation of these
test statements is shown in the Appendix to this
article.

ESTIMATION OF THE REDUCEDFORM EQUATION: 1963-72
The reduced-form equation (32) was estimated
by ordinary least squares using monthly data. All
data are seasonally adjusted, except the interest
rate. The data that were used were those available
at the end of May 1976.
The yield on prime four-to-six-month commercial
paper is used as the measure of the short-term in­
terest rate (i). It should be emphasized, however,
that the purpose of this paper is not to build a model
of the commercial paper market. The four-to-sixmonth commercial paper rate is taken as a proxy
for the movement of all short-term interest rates.
The unemployment rate is used as a proxy for the
state of economic activity (U). The money stock
is represented by the amount of demand deposits
and currency. The long-run growth rate of money
(M ) is represented by the annual rate of growth
of money over the last 36 months. Prices are
measured by the consumer price index. The rate of
growth of prices (P ) is measured as the annual rate
of growth of the consumer price index over the
previous six months. The monetary base is repre­
sented by the series published by the Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis. The variable B is measured as the
annual rate of change of the monetary base over the
prior three months.2
The growth rates of the consumer price index and
the money stock are lagged one period, based on the
presumption that these are the data that credit market
participants would have available in each period.
Since the unemployment rate is taken as a general
P = — ---------- — (2) (100) = annual rate of change of conP t_7
sumer price index over the pre­
vious six months.
M = ——-------- — (100)
M |_37

t

3 = annual rate of change of money
over the previous 36 months.

• Rt - Bt 3
B = ------------- (4)(100)= annual rate of change of the monetary
Bt_3
base over the previous three months.




JULY

1976

proxy for the state of economic activity, it is not
lagged.
Equation (32) was first estimated over the 120
monthly observations from January 1963 through De­
cember 1972. The results are as follows, where the
numbers in parentheses are t-statistics:
(4 3 ) it = .781 -f 1.348 it-i - .500 it-2 + .060 P + .064 M
(4.60 ) (16.90)
(-6 .9 4 )
(2.03 )
(2.28)
- .0 6 6 U - .029 B
(-2 .9 6 )
(-2 .4 8 )
R2 = .98

SE = .186

D W = 1.99

The estimated values of the coefficients of the
reduced-form equation are in agreement with the
test statements (33) - (40) that are shown in
Exhibit I.
Ai = 1.348 > 0
A i + A 2 = .848 > 0
Ai — A 2 = 1.348 + .500 > 0
As = .060 > 0
A4 =

.064 > 0

A 5 = - .0 6 6 < 0
Ae =

- .0 2 9 < 0

A4 — A 3 = .064 -

.060 > 0

ESTIMATION OF THE REDUCEDFORM EQUATION OVER
ALTERNATIVE PERIODS
To investigate whether the hypothesis remains in
good agreement with observed data when the sample
period is altered, the reduced-form equation for the
short-term interest rate was estimated over mov­
ing ten-year periods beginning with 1961 and ending
in 1975 (six, ten-year periods). This procedure gives
an indication as to whether the results reported so far
are peculiar to the sample period 1/63 -12/72.
The results of estimating the reduced-form equa­
tion over alternative sample periods are given in
Table I. Most of the results are in good agreement
with the test statements (33) - (40). However, there
are two cases where the test statements do not appear
to be in agreement with the data. The coefficient on
the growth of the base in the period 1/66 -12/75
appears to violate test statement (39), where Ae < 0.
Even though the sign on the coefficient is negative,
the t-statistic is very small, indicating that only at a
very low level of probability can the hypothesis that
A 6 = 0 be rejected. In the period 1/61 -12/70 the
estimated coefficient on prices exceeds that on money,
hence, A 4-A 3<0. This result suggests that the con­
jecture that the response of price expectations to the
long-run growth of money exceeds the response to
Page 13

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

1976

Table I

ESTIMATED VALUES OF THE COEFFICIENTS
OF THE REDUCED-FORM EQUATION*
Estimated Coefficients
Independent
Variable

1/61-12/70

1/62-12/71

1/63-12/72

1/64-12/73

1/65-12/74

P

0.068
(2.74)

0.056
(2.20)

0.060
(2.03)

0.062
(1.65)

0.125
(4.09)

0.089
(2.82)

M

0.047
(1 4 6 )

0.064
(2.42)

0.064
(2.28)

0.126
(3.19)

0.134
(3.12)

0.170
(3.13)

U

-0 .0 6 7
(-2 .8 3 )

-0 .0 5 9
(-2 .8 2 )

-0 .0 6 6
(-2 .9 6 )

-0 .0 8 3
(-2 .6 8 )

-0 .1 0 6
(-2 .6 8 )

— 0.122
(-3 .8 9 )

B

-0 .0 2 5
(-2 .6 2 )

— 0.029
(-2 .7 1 )

-0 .0 2 9
(-2 .4 8 )

-0 .0 3 2
(-2 .1 1 )

-0 .0 3 5
(-1 .8 6 )

-0 .0 1 4
(-0 .7 5 )

it-l

1.235
(13.74)

1.375
(17.60)

1.348
(16.90)

1.302
(15.98)

1.261
(15.79)

1.262
(15.24)

it-2

-0 .3 7 8
(-4 .5 9 )

-0 .5 2 0
(-7 .3 1 )

-.5 0 0
(-6 .9 4 )

-0 .4 8 4
(-6 .6 1 )

-0 .5 0 9
(-6 .8 8 )

-0 .4 7 9
(-6 .1 1 )

0.780
(4.44)

0.734
(4.69)

0.781
(4.60)

0.733
(3.39)

0.929
(3.58)

0.648
(2.09)

Constant

1/66-1 2/7

R2

0.992

0.989

0.984

0.976

0.973

0.958

SE

0.157

0.169

0.186

0.246

0.314

0.365

DW

1.965

1.956

1.994

1.843

1.875

1.897

•Numbers in parentheses are t-statistics.

the past rates of change of prices is not correct in
the earlier periods.
Test statements (41), where A 3-f-A5>0, and (42),
where A 4-f-A5>0, involve comparing the relative size
of the coefficient on the unemployment rate ( A5)
with the coefficient on prices ( A3) and the long-run
growth rate of money ( A4). The unit of measurement
of the unemployment rate differs from the units of
measurement of prices and money, which are meas­
ured as annual rates of change. Therefore, beta co­
efficients are computed for A3, A4, and A5, and are
used to assess the test statements (41) and (42).3
The beta coefficients for each of the independent
variables in the six sample periods are presented
in Table II. For each of the sample periods, the
beta coefficient for prices exceeds the beta co­
efficient for the unemployment rate. Hence, assump­
tion (27), where |di|>|d3[ (a one percentage point
change in the past rate of change of prices has more
effect on price expectations than does a one percent­
age point change in the unemployment rate), is
judged to be in good agreement with the data.
3The beta coefficient for an independent variable is defined as
the coefficient for that variable multiplied by the standard
deviation of the variable divided by the standard deviation of
the dependent variable. See Arthur S. Goldberger, Econometric
Theory (N ew York: John W iley & Sons, Inc., 1964), pp.
197-98; and Dick A. Leabo, Basic Statistics, 4th ed. ( Home­
wood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1972), pp. 473-74.


Page 14


Table II

BETA COEFFICIENTS AND STANDARD DEVIATIONS
OF THE INDEPENDENT VARIABLES
Beta Coefficients
Sample Periods

P

M

U

1/61 - 1 2/70

.073

.044

— .041

— .027

1/62 - 12/71

.062

.063

— .035

— .036

1/63 - 12/72

.067

.058

-.0 4 2

— .040

1/64 - 12/73

.074

.102

-.0 4 5

-.0 4 1

1/65 - 12/74

.180

.083

-.0 5 2

-.0 4 0

1/66 - 12/75

.136

.095

-.1 0 2

-.0 1 7

U

B

B

Standard Deviations
Sample Periods

P

M

1/61 - 12/70

1 .8 2 4 %

1 .6 0 6 %

1/62 - 12/71

1.750

1.565

1 .0 5 4 %

1/63 - 12/72

1.632

1.317

.930

2.010

1/64 - 12/73

1.912

1.295

.872

2.057

1/65 - 12/74

2.735

1.180

.937

2.156

1/66 - 12/75

2.743

.996

1.490

2.204

.925

1 .8 5 9 %
1.925

The beta coefficient for the long-run growth rate
of money exceeds the beta coefficient for the un­
employment rate in every period except the last
sample period 1/66-12/75. Hence, assumption (28),
where |d2|>[d3| (a one percentage point change in
the long-run growth rate of money has a greater ef-

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

feet on price expectations than does a one percentage
point change in the unemployment rate), is in
agreement with the data in all sample periods except
the one that extends into 1975. The results in this
last period raise serious questions about the accept­
ance of proposition (28). However, this latter period
appears to have special characteristics that were
not associated with the majority of the years
in the earlier sample periods. For example, as
shown in Table II, the standard deviation of the
unemployment rate rises to 1.490 in the 1966-75 pe­
riod, compared to a standard deviation of between
0.872 and 0.937 in the four prior sample periods.
These results indicate a need for careful further in­
vestigation of the difference between specific initial
conditions in this latter period and the earlier periods.

EXAMINATION OF SELECTED
PROPERTIES OF THE MODEL
In this section certain specific properties of the reduced-form model of interest rate determination are
examined. The testing of the hypothesis of interest
rate determination that was presented in the first
section of this paper is, of course, prior to the ex­
amination of the specific properties of the reducedform model.
First, the importance of the growth rates of prices,
money, and base, and the level of the unemployment
rate on the short-term interest rate is examined. The
equilibrium short-term interest rate for each sample
period is determined and then is decomposed to show
the influence of each component.
Second, the dynamic properties of the model are
examined. The model, as estimated over the period
1/63 -12/72, is simulated over the period 1/63 - 5/76.
In the simulation, the actual values of P, M, B, and U
are used, and the model generates lagged values of
the interest rate.
Dynamic simulation of the reduced-form model,
which is derived from the hypothesis about interest
rate determination, provides another chance to con­
front the hypothesis with the actual behavior of the
interest rate. If such a dynamic simulation fails to
replicate the general pattern of movements in the
short-term interest rate, this does not in itself falsify
the hypothesis. However, such a result would tend to
raise questions about the specification of the model
and, hence, influence most economists’ willingness to
tentatively accept the hypothesis from which the
reduced-form model has been derived.



JULY

1976

The reduced-form model of interest rate deter­
mination is specified such that random shocks to price
expectations influence the behavior of the short-term
interest rate. It will be recalled that the reducedform model for the interest rate (32) has a disturb­
ance term ( £ t)- In the first dynamic simulation this
term is set equal to zero. In the next simulation,
shocks are introduced in specific months to illus­
trate the effects of such shocks on the dynamic be­
havior of the model. This procedure does not prove
that shocks took place in the months in which they
are introduced. It only shows that an observed pat­
tern of sharp fluctuations in the short-term interest
rate, that appears to be unrelated to the basic under­
lying movements of money, prices, base, and eco­
nomic activity, is consistent with the hypothesis.

Equilibrium Interest Rate
The reduced-form equation, as estimated over the
sample period 1/63 -12/72, may be written as follows:
it — 1.348 it—
i “h .500 it—2 = ^

Therefore, the equilibrium solution for the interest
rate, i*, is given by:

j--------------- ®______
1 — 1 -

1.348 + .500

As shown in the Appendix, the solution for this sec­
ond order difference equation satisfies the condi­
tions for a stable equilibrium value of the interest
rate.4
To solve for the equilibrium value of the interest
rate (i°), the values of P, M, B, and U were set at
their mean values for each sample period. As an
example of the computation of the equilibrium in­
terest rates, the following method was used for the
1/63-12/72 period. The numbers in parentheses are
the estimated coefficients for that period, as shown
in Table I, and these coefficients are multiplied by
mean growth rates for the respective independent
variables, as shown in Table III.
3.303 (.0 6 0 )
4.756 (.0 6 4 )
4.653 ( - . 0 6 6 )
5.458 ( - . 0 2 9 )
Constant

=
=
=
=

.198
.304
- .3 0 7
-.1 5 8
.781
.818

5 = .818
4A stable equilibrium is defined as one for which any displace­
ment from equilibrium is followed by a sequence of values of
the interest rate which again converge to an equilibrium. See
Samuel Goldberg, Introduction to Difference Equations, pp.
169-70.
Page 15

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

Table III

EQUILIBRIUM INTEREST RATES
Sample Periods

r .... .
Equilibrium
Interest Rate

.
P

Mean Values
. ----------------- M
U

1/61 - 12/70

5 .07 %

2 .8 0 5 %

3 .9 0 6 %

4 .7 2 3 %

B
4 .56 1%

1/62 - 12/71

5.27

3.108

4.295

4.649

4.999

1/63 - 12/72

5.38

3.303

4.756

4.653

5.458

1/64 - 12/73

5.90

3.865

5.274

4.573

5.740

1/65 - 12/74

6.45

4.877

5.683

4.619

1/66 - 12/75

6.68*

5.530

5.927

5.017

♦Assuming tbe coefficient on the growth rate o f the monetary base is not
the coefficient on the base is set equal to zero, then i* = 7.08%.

.818

.818

1 - 1.348 + .500

.152

= 5.38%

This procedure was repeated using the estimated
coefficients for each sample period and setting the
values of P, M, B, and U at their mean values. These
results are shown in Table III.
The mean values of the independent variables
were chosen so as to approximate a consistent set
of values for these variables. For example, using past
relationships, it would seem inappropriate to assume
that an equilibrium growth rate of prices of, say, 9
percent would be consistent with a 2 percent equilib­
rium growth rate of money, or that an 8 percent
equilibrium growth rate of base would be consistent
with 2 percent money growth.

Relative Importance of P, M , B, U on
Interest Rates
Each of the estimated coefficients of the reduced-form equation was multiplied by the respective
mean growth rate of that variable to which the co­
efficient is attached. For example, A 3 (the estimated
coefficient of the growth rate of prices) was multi­
plied by the mean growth rate of prices.
If we let 6 i =
S2 =
63 =
64 =
6„ =

A 3 • (mean growth rate of prices)
A 4 • (mean growth rate of money)
A 5 • (mean unemployment rate)
A 6 • (mean growth rate of base)
A0

then the equilibrium interest rate ( i ° )
expressed as:
i° =

5°

+

1 — Ai — A 2

5l

+

1 — Aj — A 2

52
1 — Ai — A 2

83

84

1 — Ai — A 2

1 — Ai — A 2

+ --------------- + --------------Digitized for Page
FRASER
16


can be

1976

The relative contribution of each fac­
tor to the equilibrium interest rate in
each sample period is given in Table
IV. For comparison purposes, the re­
sults in Table IV should be read from
left to right across the Table. Each row
in the Table shows the changing influ­
ence of each factor as all factors are
assumed to vary in a consistent manner.

6.049

The results of this procedure indicate
that the major factors accounting for
equal to zero. If
the rise in the equilibrium interest rate
from 5.07 percent in 1/61 - 12/70 to
6.68 percent in 1 /66-12/75 were the accelerations
in the mean growth rates of prices and the long-run
growth rate of money. The mean value of the longrun growth rate of money rose from 3.9 percent in
1/61 -12/70 to 5.9 percent in the last sample period.
Associated with this increase in the mean growth
rate of money was an increase in the mean growth
rate of prices from 2.8 percent to 5.5 percent. Since
in this model P and M are the major factors influ­
encing the expected rate of change of prices, these
results indicate that a rise in the expected rate of
inflation is a major influence operating to raise the
equilibrium interest rate.
6.210

These results also indicate that the liquidity effect
of a rise in the growth rate of the monetary base
has a small effect relative to the effects of the as­
sociated changes in other factors. As the average
growth rate of the monetary base increased across
the sample periods, the average growth rate of money
also increased, and consequently, the average growth
rate of prices increased. The combined effect of the
accelerated growth rates of money and prices
swamped the corresponding liquidity effect of the
faster growth rate of the base on the short-term
interest rate.

Dynamic Simulations
In this section the results of two dynamic simula­
tions are reported. The simulations were performed
using the reduced-form equation for the short-term
interest rate as estimated over the period 1/63 -12/72.
Then, using these estimated coefficients and the ac­
tual values of P, M, U, and B, and setting et = 0, the
monthly pattern of the short-term interest rate was
simulated for the period 1/63 - 5/76. The period
1/63 -12/72 was an in-sample simulation, and the
period 1/73 - 5/76 was an out-of-sample simulation.
Values of P, M, U, and B vary over the period and

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

1976

Table IV

INDIVIDUAL CONTRIBUTIONS OF MAJOR
FACTORS TO EQUILIBRIUM INTEREST RATE
1/61-12/70

1/62-12/71

1/63-12/72

1/64-12/73

1/65-12/74

1/66-12/75

P

1 .3 4 %

1 .2 0 %

1 .3 0 %

1 .3 2 %

2 .4 6 %

2 .2 7 %

M

1.29

1.90

2.00

3.65

3.07

4.65

U

— 2.21

— 1.89

-2 .0 2

— 2.09

-1 .9 8

— 2.82

B

-.8 0

-1 .0 0

-1 .0 4

— 1.01

— .86

-.4 0

Constant

5.46

5.06

5.14

4.03

3.75

2.99

Total*

5.08

5.27

5.38

5.90

6.44

6.69

♦Total figures may differ slightly from rates reported in Table III due to rounding.

lagged values of the interest rate are those generated
by the model. The results of this simulation are shown
in Chart I.

performance of the simulation show a marked rise
in the errors. As shown in Table V, the mean error
for the period 1973-75 rises to 68 basis points, and
the root mean squared error rises to 145 basis points.

As can be seen from the chart, the simulated pat­
tern of the commercial paper rate follows the general
contours of the actual pattern of the commercial
paper rate. This relation is quite close in the period
1963-72. During this period the mean error be­
tween the actual interest rate and the simulated
interest rate was about 4 basis points, and the root
mean squared error was about 45 basis points. These
and other statistics for comparing the performance
of the simulation are given in Table V.

Two points should be made about the simulation
results from the 1973 through mid-1976 period. First,
as the simulation is carried on from the start of 1973
through May 1976, the simulated values of the short­
term interest rate continue to reproduce the general
pattern of the short-term interest rate. The simulated
rate rises sharply from early 1973 through late 1974
and then falls sharply into 1975. However, in con­
trast to the smooth pattern of the simulated interest
rate, the actual interest rate displayed a series of
very sharp fluctuations in this period. For example,

As the simulation is carried on from early 1973
through mid-1976, the statistics used to evaluate the
C h a rt I

Short-Term Interest Rate
D y n a m ic S im u la t io n R e s u lt s
P e rc e n t

P e rc e n t

LL 4 - to 6 - m o n t h p rim e c o m m e rc ia l p a p e r ra te.
12 S i m u l a t e d in te re st ra te u s i n g c o e ffic ie n t s e stim a te d o v e r 1 / 6 3 - 1 2 / 7 2 , in it ia l v a l u e s se t a t a c tu a l in te re st rate fo r 1 1 / 6 2 a n d 1 2 / 6 2 .
L a te st d a t a plotted-. M a y




Page 17

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

C h a r t II

Table V

Short-Term Interest Rate

DIFFERENCE BETWEEN THE ACTUAL A N D
SIMULATED SHORT-TERM INTEREST
RATE: SUMMARY STATISTICS

D y n a m ic S im u la t io n

Mean

.0 3 7 %
.355

1.217

Mean Squared Error

.199

2.109

Root Mean Squared Error

.446

1.452

P ercent

/T \A c tu a l i
7

1973-1975

Absolute Mean

R e s u lts

P ercent

Simulated (C|

id ) L2

/

i

.6 7 9 %

M

J /

Second, the actual interest rate does not continue
to diverge from the simulated value of the interest
rate. For short periods the actual value moves sharply
above the simulated rate, but then it rapidly con­
verges back to the pattern of the simulated rate. By
the end of 1975 and into 1976, the actual and simu­
lated rates are again moving closely together.
Therefore, the question arises as to what accounts
for these sharp short-run deviations of the actual in­
terest rate from the simulated path of the interest
rate. To begin, first note that in the initial simulation
£t was set equal to zero. In other words, no random
shocks to price expectations were introduced into the
simulation. Given the dynamic characteristics of the
reduced-form equation for the interest rate, adding
shocks (setting s t =^=0 ) will affect the simulated pat­
tern of the interest rate. For example, if £t is set at
a value greater than zero in one period and then al­
lowed to return to zero in every following period, the
effect on the simulated interest rate will appear, not
only in the first period, but also in following periods.
Eventually the simulated interest rate will converge
back to the level determined by the growth rates of
money, prices, base, and the level of the unemploy­
ment rate. However, in the interim, the simulated
rate will have deviated sharply from that generated
by setting et = 0.
Consequently, a second simulation was performed
to illustrate the behavior of the simulated interest
rate when periodic shocks are introduced. The sim­
ulation was begun in 1/73 and the initial values for
the interest rate were set at their actual values for
November and December 1972. Then, shocks were
introduced in selected months, and the system was

//

/

,J s

/I
/

the actual interest rate (commercial paper rate) rose
from about 6 percent in early 1973 to above 10 per­
cent in September 1973, fell to about 8 percent
in early 1974, then rose to about 12 percent in July
1974, and fell to about 6 percent in March 1975.

\

i
■
i
i
i
«

1963-1972

Digitized forPage
FRASER
18


1976

\

i
\
\
\
\
\

/ *
Simulateid (6f=0)

\

\

S
-

V '

W

\

\

\

v . ^
' /--K
V
v
- A

1973

1974

°

~
1975

LL 4 - to 6 - m o n t h p r im e c o m m e rc ia l p a p e r ra te .
12 S i m u l a t e d in t e r e s t ra t e u s i n g c o e f fic ie n t s e st im a t e d o v e r 1 / 6 3 - 1 2 / 7 2 , in it ia l
v a l u e s se t a t a c tu a l in te re st ra t e f o r 1 1 / 7 2 a n d 1 2 / 7 2 .
L a t e s t d a t a p lo t t e d : D e c e m b e r

allowed to adjust to the shocks. In many months £t
was set equal to zero. Then periodically £t was set
at a value greater or less than zero. The results of
this simulation, one in which periodic shocks were
introduced in selected months along with the chang­
ing growth rates of prices, money, base, and the
unemployment rate, are shown in Chart II and Table
VI. Chart II shows that by selectively introducing
periodic shocks, a simulated pattern of the short­
term interest rate can be generated that closely ap­
proximates the actual behavior of the short-term in­
terest rate.
The exact causes of such shocks are not well under­
stood and have not been the subject of much empiri­
cal investigation. One example of such a shock to
price expectations would be the announcement of
the oil embargo that occurred in 1973. This develop­
ment quite likely affected price expectations, but
was not incorporated in information about the past
rate of change of prices, money, or the state of
economic activity. This development probably had
recurring effects on price expectations each time
OPEC met to set the price of oil and each time the
U.S. Government announced a new program to
combat the “energy crisis.”
As another example of how such shocks might
originate, consider the case where the Federal Gov­
ernment announces that it expects to run a deficit
over the next few years that, by past standards, is

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

conceivably lead to a substantial shock to price ex­
pectations. In other words, the future rate of inflation
would now be expected to be greater than what in­
dividuals had expected given the past rate of change
of prices and the long-run growth of money.

Table VI

COM PARISON OF ACTUAL A N D SIMULATED
INTEREST RATES: E t # 0

Date

Actual
Interest
Rate

Simulated
Interest Rate
Et 7^ 0

Shocks
Et

1/73

5 .78 %

5.6 5 %

0

2/73

6.22

5.83

0

3/73

6.85

6.51

.50

4/73

7.14

6.91

0
0

5/73

7.27

7.17

6/73

7.99

7.88

.50

7/73

9.18

9.00

.75

8/73

10.21

9.90

9/73

10.23

10.19

10/73

8.92

9.58

11/73

8.94

9.10

.50
0
—

.50
0

12/73

9.08

8.76

0

1/74

8.66

8.55

0
0

2/74

7.83

8.49

3/74

8.42

8.48

0

4/74

9.79

9.53

1.00

5/74

10.62

10.95

1.00

6/74

10.96

11.31

0

7/74

11.72

11.65

.50

8/74

11.65

11.38

0
0

9/74

11.23

10.81

10/74

9.36

9.19

11/74

8.81

8.76

.50

12/74

8.98

8.42

0

-1 .0 0

1/75

7.30

7.24

-1 .0 0

2/75

6.33

6.27

-

3/75

6.06

5.91

0
0

.50

4/75

6.15

5.73

5/75

5.82

5.69

0

6/75

5.79

5.54

0

7/75

6.44

6.42

1.00

8/75

6.70

6.65

0

9/75

6.86

6.66

0

10/75

6.48

6.51

0

11/75

5.91

6.25

0

12/75

5.97

6.01

0

very large. Consequently, there is a great amount of
discussion in the financial press and among economic
forecasters concerning the implications of this pattern
of projected large deficits. Suppose further that the
consensus opinion is that these deficits imply that the
central bank will respond by sharply increasing its
purchases of Government securities; hence, the
growth of money will be much more rapid than
was previously observed. This chain of events could



1976

Suppose that after a period of time, even though
there are large deficits, the money supply does not
accelerate, and the Federal Reserve firmly announces
that it does not intend to allow an acceleration in
money growth. Consequently, this may result in a
revision of price expectations in the downward direc­
tion ( s t < 0 ) and, hence, a substantial fall in interest
rates may occur.
These results contain the interesting implication
that the basic mechanism generating interest rates may
not have changed radically during the period 197375. Rather, a series of shocks occurred during this
latter period which resulted in much greater variation
in interest rates than can be accounted for by the
changing growth rates of money, base, prices, and
the level of the unemployment rate.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
An hypothesis designed to explain the movements
in the short-term interest rate has been presented
in this article. The hypothesis was given explicit form
in the mathematical representation of the short-term
credit market presented in equations (1) - (9). Signs
and relative sizes were attached to the parameters
of the structural equations. From the structural equa­
tions a reduced-form expression for the interest rate
was derived. Empirical counterparts to the terms ap­
pearing in the reduced-form equation were specified.
All of these steps are integral parts of the hypothesis.
Other economists might favor a different specifica­
tion of the short-term credit market. Also, they might
contend that “the short-term interest rate” should be
mapped into the empirical counterpart of the Treasury
bill rate instead of the commercial paper rate, or
that “prices” should be represented by the wholesale
price index rather than the consumer price index, or
that the “state of economic activity” is not well repre­
sented by the unemployment rate. These assertions
can only be evaluated when they are given definite
form by respecifying the hypothesis and deriving new
test statements that can be confronted with empirical
evidence.
No attempt was made to justify a -priori the
specification of the model, the assignment of signs to
the parameters of the model, or the use of specific
Page 19

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

1976

empirical counterparts to the theoretical terms that
appear in the model. Instead, the hypothesis was
formulated in such a manner that statements could
be derived from the hypothesis that were capable of
being falsified by observed data. The potential falsi­
fiers of the hypothesis were the test statements (33)(42). These test statements are derivable conse­
quences of the hypothesis. Conceivably, some or all
of the test statements (33) - (42) could have turned
out to be not in agreement with the data. This could
have resulted from any of the steps involved in con­
structing the hypothesis. Such results provide evi­
dence against the hypothesis, hence, requiring care­
ful analysis of the cause of the falsification and pos­
sible reformulation of one or more parts of the
hypothesis.

rate. The results of these simulations indicated the
possibility of recurring shocks in the 1973-75 period.
Consequently, an alternative simulation was per­
formed where shocks were introduced in selected
months. It was shown that such a procedure resulted
in a pattern of the simulated interest rate which
closely approximated the pattern of the actual interest
rate. These results led to the conjecture that the under­
lying mechanism generating interest rates was un­
changed in the last few years. In other words, the
evolution of the short-term interest rate continued to
depend upon the same basic factors — the influence
of the growth rate of money, prices, the state of eco­
nomic activity, and the growth of the base. Sharp
divergences from this path were accounted for by
periodic shocks.

The test statements were generally in good agree­
ment with the observed data. These results were not
specific only to the initial sample period that was
chosen, but also held as the sample period was varied
over fifteen years. This does not mean the hy­
pothesis is a “true” representation of the determinants
of the short-term interest rate. It only means that,
subject to a continuation of more rigorous testing of
the hypothesis, it might be tentatively considered as
a representation of the process whereby the short­
term interest rate is determined.

At the start of this paper it was stated that it was
not the purpose of this article to develop a pure fore­
casting model for the short-term interest rate. The
simulation results reported in the paper, however,
have some interesting implications for forecasting
interest rates. They indicate that even if an indi­
vidual were lucky enough to correctly predict the
future growth rates of prices, money, monetary base,
and the unemployment rate, this might only permit
a forecast of the general contour of the future path
of interest rates. In periods such as the last few years,
periodic shocks may occur which, according to the
model developed in this paper, would result in sharp
upward or downward movements in interest rates.
Without knowledge of the timing and magnitude of
these shocks, which are usually assumed to be ran­
domly distributed over a sufficiently long period, it
would not be possible to closely forecast for an ex­
tended period the actual path of the short-term
interest rate.

As was pointed out in the discussion of the test
results, there were a few cases where some of the
test statements did not agree with the data. These are
important results and cast doubt on parts of the
hypothesis. Hence, they require careful further in­
vestigation. Two of these results were peculiar to
the sample period 1966-75. It was mentioned that
the latter years of this period had special char­
acteristics that were “different” from the earlier years
of the sample period. This assertion was developed
in more detail in latter sections of the paper.
After testing the hypothesis, the reduced-form
model for the interest rate was used to examine cer­
tain selected properties of the proposed explanation
of the movements in the interest rate. An equilibrium
interest rate was derived for each of the sample pe­
riods. These results indicated a fairly substantial rise
in the equilibrium interest rate as the sample period
was changed. This rise was attributed primarily to
the increased average long-run growth rate of money
and the faster average growth of prices operating
through their effects on price expectations.
Dynamic simulations of the interest rate were per­
formed using the reduced-form model for the interest

Page 20


These results also point out difficulties that can
result for a central bank if it tries to tightly con­
trol short-run movements in interest rates. Suppose
there is a shock that raises price expectations and,
consequently, interest rates. The dynamic proper­
ties of the reduced-form interest rate model de­
rived from the hypothesis presented in this paper
show that such shocks result in a sharp rise in the
interest rate. However, in the absence of future
shocks, the interest rate will not continue to rise
indefinitely, but after a time will begin to fall and
converge back toward the level determined by the
growth rates of prices, money, base, and the state of
economic activity. If, however, the central bank takes
aggressive action to halt the rise in rates, then inter­

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

est rates will not converge back to the level deter­
mined by the previous growth rates of prices, money,
and base, but will converge to a new higher level.

1976

Also, such a process raises the possibility of further
positive shocks to price expectations and substantial
further upward pressures on interest rates.

APPENDIX I
DERIVATION OF TEST STATEMENTS

(33) A, > 0

(36) A3 > 0

Ci (b2 - a2)
A, = -------------------ai - bi

At

di (b3 - a3)
—

ai - bi

(17) Cl > 0

(20) di > 0

(14) b 2 < 0

( 12) a3 > 0

(11) a2 > 0

(15)

Therefore: c i (b2 — a2) < 0

b3 < 0

Therefore: dt (b3 - a3) < 0

(10) a, < 0

Since: ai —bi < 0

(13)

Therefore: A3 > 0

bi > 0

Therefore: (ai — b j) < 0
Therefore: Ai > 0

(37) A, > 0

(34) A! + A2 > 0
b 2 — a2
Ai + A2 = (ci + c 2) (------------- )

ai - bi

d2 (b3 - a3)
a4 =

(21)

7

ai - bi
d2 > 0

Since: (ai — b i) < 0

Therefore: d 2 (b3 —a3) < 0

Since: (b2 — a2) < 0

Since: ai —bi < 0

b 2 — a2
T h e re fo re :------------- > 0

Therefore: A4 > 0

ai - bi
(18) ci + c 2 > 0
Therefore: Ai + A2 > 0

(35) Aj - A2 > 0
b 2 — a2
A, - A2 = ( d - c2) (------------- )
ai - b[

(19) ci > c 2
Therefore: ci - c 2 > 0
b 2 — a2

Since: (------------- ) > 0

(38) A5 < 0
d3 (b3 - a3) + (fi - ei)
a 5 ------------------------------------ai - bi
(22) d3 < 0
(25)

I a3 d3 I > I f4 - e, I

Therefore: - a3 d3 + (fi - ei) > 0
Since: d3 b3 > 0
Therefore: d3 (b3 —a3) + (fi —ei) > 0

ai - b ,

Since: ai —bi < 0

Therefore: Ai - A 2 > 0

Therefore: A5 < 0




Page 21

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

(39)

A6

JULY

(41) A 3 + A s > 0

As < 0

b4

—

1976

b3 “ 33

fi —ei

ai —bi

ai —bi

A 3 + A 5 = (d , + da) (------------- ) + (------------- )

ai - b!
(16) b 4 > 0

(27)

I d( I > I d 3 I

Therefore: di + d 3 > 0

Since: ai — bi < 0
T herefore: A 6 < 0

b3 —a3

Since: (-

-) > 0

ai - bi
fi —ei

(40) A, - A3 > 0

Since: (■

-) > 0

ai - bi

,b3 — a3
Aj —A3 — (d2 — di) (ai - bi

Therefore: A 3 + A 5 > 0

(20) di > 0

(21)

d2

(26)

>0

(42) A4 + As > 0

d 2 > di

b3 - a3
A 4 + A 5 = (d 2 + d3) ( ---------- - ) +

Therefore: (d 2 — d i) > 0

b3 — a3
Since: (-

-)

ai - bi

fi —ei
(-

ai - bi

>0

ai - bi

(28) I d 2 I > I d 3 I
Therefore: (d 2 + d a )> 0
Therefore: A4 + A5 > 0

Therefore: A 4 — A 3 > 0

APPENDIX II
STABILITY CONDITIONS FOR EQUILIBRIUM INTEREST RATE

G iven a difference equation o f the form :

it + zi i, 1 + z 2 it - 2 - 5

yk+2 + Z i yk+ 1 + Z2 y k = 6

where,

5 = constant
the necessary and sufficient conditions
equilibrium are given by:

for a stable

1 + zi + z 2 > 0
1 - z2 > 0
1 - zi + z 2 > 0

Rewriting the equation for the interest rate as:

Page 22



zi = - A,
z2 = - A2
the stability conditions for 1/62 - 12/73 are given as:
1 + (-1 .3 4 8 ) + .500 > 0
1 - .500 > 0
1 - (-1 .3 4 8 ) + .500 > 0

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

JULY

1976

Publications of This Bank Include:
Weekly

U. S. FINANCIAL DATA

Monthly

REVIEW
MONETARY TRENDS
NATIONAL ECONOMIC TRENDS

Quarterly

SELECTED ECONOMIC INDICATORS - CENTRAL
MISSISSIPPI VALLEY
FEDERAL BUDGET TRENDS
U. S. INTERNATIONAL TRANSACTIONS
AND CURRENCY REVIEW

Annually

ANNUAL U. S. ECONOMIC DATA
RATES OF CHANGE IN ECONOMIC DATA
FOR TEN INDUSTRIAL COUNTRIES
(QUARTERLY SUPPLEMENT)

Single copies of these publications are available to the public without charge.
For information write: Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,
P. O. Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166.




Page 23