View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

The R e v i e w is published 10 times per year by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis. Single-copy subscriptions are available to the public free of charge. Mail requests
for subscriptions, back issues, or address changes to: Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis, P.O. Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166.
Articles herein may be reprinted provided the source is credited. Please provide the Bank’s Re­
search Department with a copy of reprinted material.


2


The New Bank-Thrift Competition:
Will It Affect Bank Acquisition
and Merger Analysis?
MICHAEL E. TREBING

JLHE Depository Institutions Deregulation and
Monetary Control Act (MCA) enacted by Congress
in March 1980 will significantly affect the competitive
environment in which financial institutions operate.
This act broadens both the asset and liability powers
of savings and loan associations (S&Ls), mutual sav­
ings banks and credit unions, opening opportunities for
these institutions that traditionally have been limited
to banks. In light of these new powers and the in­
creasing erosion of both legal and economic differ­
ences between thrift institutions and banking organi­
zations, thrifts have become important competitors in
markets for banking services — especially for trans­
action or checking accounts.1 Logically, the presence
of thrift institutions should carry greater weight in
analysis of mergers between commercial banks and
acquisitions of banks by bank holding companies
(BHCs).
The following discussion reviews several provisions
of the MCA that permit more intense bank-thrift com­
petition, describes the current approach used by bank­
ing regulatory agencies to review applications for
approval of bank mergers and BHC acquisitions,
and discusses its validity in light of the new legisla­
tion. Finally, the article discusses some alternative
approaches to the analysis of competition in local
markets.

THE MCA PROVISIONS
The distinctions between thrifts and banks have be­
come less rigid because of a long list of recent finan1The term “thrift institutions” in this article is defined as sav­
ings and loan associations, credit unions and mutual savings
banks.




cial innovations and the geographic expansion of socalled “non-banking” institutions.2 The MCA, in re­
sponse to these developments, reduces even further
the actual differences between banks and thrifts. Regu­
lations that have attempted to control or constrain
pricing and portfolio decisions of financial institutions
are being liberalized. In essence, the act provides for
a greater reliance on market forces to determine both
the flow of deposits to financial institutions and the
flow of credit from these institutions to borrowers. The
major elements of the MCA that will affect bankthrift competition are listed in table l.3
An important change is the authorization of interestearning “transaction” accounts at both banks and
thrifts. This is achieved through the nationwide legali­
zation of negotiable order of withdrawal (NOW)
accounts, automatic transfer service (ATS) accounts
and credit union share drafts.4 In some areas of the
country (especially New England), depository in2See Jean M. Lovati, “The Growing Similarity Among Financial
Institutions,” this Review (October 1 9 7 7 ), pp. 2-11, and
Harold C. Nathan, “Nonbank Organizations and the M cFadden A ct,” Journal of Bank Research (Summer 1 9 8 0 ), pp.
80-86.
3For a more detailed discussion of the elements of the MCA
see “The Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary
Control Act of 1980,” Federal Reserve Bulletin (June 1 9 8 0 ),
pp. 444-53.
4ATS and NOW accounts represent a type of individual “check­
ing” account. By providing for the automatic transfer of funds
from a savings account to cover checks drawn against a zerobalance ATS account, individuals can earn interest on “check­
ing” balances. NOW accounts are interest-earning savings
accounts against which customers can write “negotiable
drafts.” Similarly, credit union share drafts permit payable
drafts drawn on a credit union member’s interest-earning
share account. Share drafts, which resemble checks, are proc­
essed through the credit union’s account at a commercial
bank.

3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

F E B R U A R Y 1981

Table 1
Selected Provisions from the Depository
Institutions Deregulation and Monetary
Control Act of 1980
1.

T h e p h a s e - o u t of interest rate c eilin g s on d e pos its ov er
a s i x - y e a r per io d

2.

T h e autho ri za tio n to offer N O W ( n e g o t i a b le o r d e r of
w it h d r a w a l ) a c c o u n t s (f u n d a m e n ta ll y , interest-e arnin g
c h e c k in g a c c o u n t s ) at all federally insu re d de p o sito r y
institutions b e g in n i n g D e c e m b e r 31, 1980 to indiv id ua ls
a n d no n-pr ofit o rganiza ti o ns

3.

T h e authoriz at io n of s har e drafts at federally insur ed
cre dit un io ns (e ffective M a r c h 31, 198 0)

4.

T h e au th o riza tio n for mutual s a v in g s ba nk s
d e m a n d de posits to bu s ine ss c u s to m e r s

5.

In cr e a s e d inves tm e nt optio ns for thrift institutions

to offer

F o r fe d e ra l- c h a rt e re d s a v in g s a n d loans:
a.

c o n s u m e r le nd in g, c o m m e r c i a l pa per , an d
d e b t secu rit y inv es tm ent of up to 20 p e r ­
ce n t of assets

b.

i s su ance of credit c a r d s

c.

trus t-fiduciary p o w e r s

F o r fed erally insur ed credit un io ns:
a.

real estate loans

F o r federa l m ut ua l s a v in gs bank s:
a.

c o m m e r c i a l , co r p o r a te a n d bu s in e ss loans,
( u p to 5 pe r c e n t of as s ets)

stitutions had already offered interest-earning trans­
action accounts since the early 1970s. Accompanying
these powers is the provision for the gradual phase­
out of deposit interest rate ceilings.
In addition to these significant changes, the MCA
allows S&Ls to engage in consumer lending, trust
activities and credit card operations. The MCA au­
thorizes thrifts to invest in, sell, or hold commercial
paper and corporate debt securities (up to 20 percent
of assets). Limited business and commercial loan
powers have also been granted to federally chartered
mutual savings banks.
The basic findings of the act are that the existing
institutional structure has discouraged persons from
saving, created inequities for depositors, impeded the
ability of depository institutions to compete for funds
and failed to achieve an even flow of funds among
institutions. The act also states that all depositors are
entitled to receive a market rate of return on their
savings.

4


Credit market activity of thrifts over the past
decade has developed by piecemeal expansion; these
institutions evolved originally as special-purpose in­
stitutions whose asset-liability powers have been ex­
tended only by gaining legislative approval.5 Legisla­
tion in the 1970s has increasingly widened their
powers and scope of business. The new powers legal­
ized in the MCA will affect further the traditional
lines of business that have separated these institutions;
banks and thrifts will now com pete more directly for
many lines o f business.

CURRENT METHOD OF ANALYZING
COMPETITION
The Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 requires
the Federal Reserve to consider the likely effects of
proposed holding company formations and acquisitions
on competition, the convenience and needs of the
communities involved, and the financial and mana­
gerial resources and future prospects of the institu­
tions involved.6 If the Board of Governors finds that
a transaction will substantially lessen competition (or
tend to create a monopoly or be in restraint of trade),
the Board must deny the application unless the anti­
competitive effects are judged to be clearly outweighed
by “the convenience and needs of the community.”

Legal Doctrine
The critical problem in antitrust law is selecting
the specific industry and industry output (or “line of
commerce”) to use in analyzing competition between
firms. In analyzing cases under the Bank Holding
Company Act, the Federal Reserve has generally
chosen “commercial banking” to be the relevant line
of commerce. This definition is based on the Supreme
Court’s controversial Philadelphia National Bank de­
cision in 1963.7
In this case, the Court concluded that commercial
banks have an advantage over other financial institu­
tions in attracting funds for loans and other services
5See Leonard Lapidus, “Commercial Banks and Thrift Institu­
tions: The Differing Portfolio Powers,” Banking Law Journal
(M ay 1 9 7 5 ), pp. 450-93, and Jean M. Lovati, “The Chang­
ing Competition Between Commercial Banks and Thrift Insti­
tutions for Deposits,” this Review (July 1 9 7 5 ), pp. 2-8.
Com petitive analysis is also done with respect to applications
filed under the Change in Bank Control A ct of 1978 and
mergers filed under the Bank Merger Act of 1960.
7United States v. Philadelphia National Bank, 374 U.S. 321
(1 9 6 3 ) . Subsequent Supreme Court cases have upheld this
decision. See United States v. Phillipsburg National Bank and
Trust Co., 399 U.S. 350 (1 9 7 0 ); and United States v. Con­
necticut National Bank, 418 U.S. 655 (1 9 7 4 ).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

since only they can legally accept demand deposits.
In addition, banks were said to enjoy “settled con­
sumer preferences” for full-service banking. Thus, the
“general store” nature of the banking business made
it a distinct line of commerce, distinguishing banks
from other financial institutions.
Banking agencies have relied on simple market
share tests to judge the likely effects of mergers or
BHC acquisitions on competition, using “concentra­
tion ratios” as a form of prima facie evidence of these
effects on competition. A concentration ratio is a sum­
mary measure intended to represent the degree of
market power that larger firms possess.8 This ratio is
defined as the percentage of total industry activity
(measured by output, employment, assets, etc.) ac­
counted for by the larger firms. A four-firm concen­
tration ratio (using total deposits as a proxy for
output) for all the commercial banks in a local bank­
ing market, for example, may be 75 percent; that is,
the four largest banks hold 75 percent of the total
bank deposits in this market.9
Although other factors are analyzed in evaluating
the competitive effects of mergers and acquisitions,
concentration ratios continue to be the main factors in
such analysis.10 The important issue is that the calcu­
lation of concentration ratios using commercial bank
organization deposit data alone accepts the Court’s
8Fo r a discussion of concentration measures used in analysis
of banking markets, see “Measures of Banking Structure and
Competition,” Federal Reserve Bulletin (September 1 9 6 5 ),
pp. 1212-22.
9See the appendix for a discussion of how the relevant geo­
graphic market is defined.
10This point is highlighted by the merger guidelines published
by the Justice Department in 1968 which are frequently
cited in bank merger and acquisition analysis. These guide­
lines indicate that the department will challenge a hori­
zontal merger between firms in a concentrated industry (i.e.,
one with a four-firm concentration ratio greater than 75% )
when the following market shares are involved:
Acquiring
Acquired
Firm
Firm
4%

10 %
15%

4% or more
2% or more
1% or more

In nonconcentrated markets (i.e. ones with four-firm concen­
tration ratios less than 75% ) the Justice Department chal­
lenges mergers with the following shares:
Acquiring
Acquired
Firm
Firm
5%

15%

5%
4%
3%

20%

2%

25%

1%

10%

See M erger Guidelines, U.S. Department of Justice, May 30,
1968.




F E B R U A R Y 1981

line of commerce definition and assumes that the ag­
gregate of the many products and services supplied
by banks represents a meaningful product line for
analysis of market competition.11

Economic Analysis of Line of Commerce
Definition
The definition adopted by the Court in 1963 was
based on a particular view of the market for bank
services: namely, that many bank products are de­
manded jointly. In other words, it is possible to
identify “clusters” or “bundles” of services demanded
by customers for which banks compete.12 Such de­
mand may result because of transportation costs and
transaction costs (including the cost of obtaining in­
formation) which makes it costly or impractical for
customers to deal with more than one institution.
Banks, however, compete in many different product
markets and in different geographic market areas.
Commercial banks participate principally in markets
for financial assets. Banks demand customer deposits
which they invest in a variety of earning assets. Cus­
tomers using demand accounts are, in turn, supplied
a transaction service. Customers holding time deposits
are provided an intermediation service — funds are
invested in interest-earning assets. Banks also supply
various types of credit, trust services, safe deposit
services, correspondent services, etc. Each of these
activities can be identified as an individual “output”
of a bank. One can argue that each “output” is sold in
1:1The use of such concentration ratios is not necessarily ad hoc.
Their use has both theoretical and empirical support in the
literature. Nevertheless, it is reasonable to conclude that the
use of such ratios, essentially a result of data scarcity, has
unfortunately guided research efforts as well. For a summary
of the empirical evidence for banking, see Stephen A.
Rhoades, Structure and Performance Studies in Banking: A
Summary and Evaluation, Staff Economic Studies 92 (Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1 9 77) and
George J. Benston, “The Optimal Banking Structure: Theory
and Evidence,” Journal of Bank Research (W inter 1 9 7 3 ),
pp. 220-37. Fo r a criticism of such “conduct/structure/performance” studies, see Yale Brozen, “Concentration and
Profits: Does Concentration Matter?” T he Antitrust Bulletin
(Summer 1 9 7 4 ), pp. 381-99. See also Harold Demsetz, “In­
dustry Structure, Market Rivalry, and Public Policy,” Journal
of Law and Economics (April 1 9 7 3 ), pp. 1-9.
12An alternative argument holds that banks have offered
diverse services in the past because they have been prohib­
ited from paying interest on demand deposits since 1933.
Customers holding large demand deposit balances receive
“implicit interest” in the form of other services offered below
cost to depositors. In other words, competition resulted in
institutions, faced with prohibition on direct payment of
interest, offering implicit interest in the form of services,
such as low or zero service charges, drive-in facilities,
branches, and occasionally gifts (porcelain china, silverware
and calculators, for example).

5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

a distinct market defined in terms of specific groups of
buyers (for example, by location of customer, or ma­
turity and denomination of the particular loan). There­
fore, choosing the appropriate measure of bank “out­
put” is a difficult task.13
The above reasoning suggests that the usefulness of
the line of commerce definition adopted in the Phila­
delphia case should be determined on empirical
grounds. Although the “department store” or “cluster
of service” approach may be valid in some instances,
the concept is completely irrelevant for many readily
identifiable bank “products.” For example, an indi­
vidual seeking a mortgage loan will choose an institu­
tion primarily on the basis of the price of the loan
(the interest rate); the package of other services
offered by competing institutions is not pertinent in
this decision.
Measuring the extent of competition between differ­
ent types of institutions in a product line must be
based upon the degree of substitution between prod­
ucts of these institutions. In economic terms, the
important issue is the magnitude of the “cross-elas­
ticity” of demand between individual products offered
by financial institutions.14 The higher the cross-elasticity between the products of banks and thrifts, the
greater the substitution and the stronger the argu­
ment for including the outputs of these institutions
in the same industry or the same product line. The
cluster approach used by the Supreme Court assumes
that the degree of substitution between lines of com­
merce (thrift output and bank output) is “small.”
For example, if institution A (say, a thrift) increases
the (explicit or implicit) interest rate on savings de­
posits while institution B (a bank) keeps its rates
unchanged, the volume of business transferred by
local customers from bank B to thrift A rises with the
magnitude of the cross-elasticity of supply. The other
13Researchers’ views have varied considerably in their theoret­
ical definitions of the appropriate banking output measure.
See Stuart I. Greenbaum, “Competition and Efficiency in the
Banking System — Empirical Research and Its Policy Impli­
cations, ’ The Journal of Political Economy ( Supplement:
August 1 9 6 7 ), pp. 461-79, and Michael A. Klein, “A Theory
of The Banking Firm ,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Bank­
ing (M ay 1 9 7 1 ), pp. 205-18.
14The “cross-elasticity” of demand is defined as a measure of
the relationship between the demand for one firm’s output
when the price of another firm’s output changes (when all
other things remain the sam e). The cross-elasticity between
goods 1 and 2 is given by the equation
__% change in quantity of good 1 demanded
% change in price of good 2
If e is less than zero, the outputs are normally considered
“complements.” If e is greater than zero they are considered
substitutes. The degree of substitution can be gauged by the
magnitude of this coefficient: higher positive cross-elasticity
coefficients correspond to greater degrees of substitution.




F E B R U A R Y 1981

services offered by bank B (for example, checking
services), however, may preclude a significant transfer
of business between institutions. Since both thrifts
and banks can now offer transaction accounts, the
degree of substitution between their respective out­
puts will increase.15
Bank regulatory agencies have emphasized the
“locally limited” customer in analysis of bank mergers
and acquisitions. As such, regulators have tended to
stress the services provided to individuals and small
business customers. Since most large commercial and
industrial customers have access to national and
regional markets, competition for these accounts is
intense. Empirical estimates of the relevant cross­
elasticities for retail and small business customers in
local banking markets, however, are difficult to obtain.
Begulatory ceilings on interest rates interfere with
obtaining good estimates of these magnitudes. As pre­
viously mentioned, competitive forces have resulted
in institutions competing by means other than the
payment of explicit rates of interest. Institutions
located in different market environments offer differ­
entiated clusters of outputs. Differing degrees of
branching restrictions across governmental jurisdic­
tions, for example, may affect the form of implicit
interest paid to consumers.
Even before the MCA, other structural changes
since the last Supreme Court ruling on a merger case
(1974) had cast doubt on the validity of the banking
regulatory agencies’ approach to competition. The
asset and deposit liability growth of thrifts has out­
paced that of banks over most of the periods from
1960-79 (tables 2 and 3). It is unlikely that the pre­
vious degree of substitution between the outputs of
banks and thrifts has remained constant since the
Philadelphia definition in 1963. Retail customers in
local banking markets have reacted to significant fi­
nancial developments in the 1970s. Inflation, interest
rate ceilings, and new instruments such as money
market certificates, money market funds, ATS ac­
counts and telephone transfer accounts, have all con­
tributed to an increased degree of substitution be­
tween seivices offered by banks and non-bank
institutions. The nationwide legalization of thrift
transaction accounts further weakens the argument
that banks have a clear advantage in attracting
customers.
15Accumulated evidence prior to the MCA supports the view
that customers already treat time and savings accounts of
banks and thrifts as substitutes. Fo r a review of the empirical
evidence before 1970, see Gary G. Gilbert and Neil B.
Murphy, “Competition Between Thrift Institutions and Com­
mercial Banks: An Examination of the Evidence,” Journal
of Bank Research (Summer 1 9 7 1 ), pp. 8-18.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

F E B R U A R Y 1981

Table 2
Distribution of Assets — Com m ercial Banks and Thrifts (billions of dollars)
E n d of Period

A n n u a l G r o w t h Rates

1960

1965

1970

1975

1979

196 01965

19651970

19701975

197 51979

C O M M E R C I A L B A N K S (i n s u r e d
o n ly )
$ 43.1

$ 71.2

$112.2

$174.3

$256.0

1 0.6%

9 .5 %

M o rtg a g e s

28.7

49.4

73.1

134.6

243.2

11.5

8.1

13.0

15.9

C o n s u m e r loans

26.4

45.5

66.0

106.0

186.4

11.6

7.7

9.9

15.1

U.S. Tre a su ry and agency
sec ur itie s

60.4

59.2

61.6

117.6

136.8

-0 .4

0.8

13.8

3.9

State a n d local securities

17.3

38.5

69.4

101.8

131.9

17.3

12.5

8.0

6.7

11.7

9.8

9.2

9.0

10.4

10.2

6 .4 %

13.1%

14.3%

B u s in e s s loans

80.4

111.6

194.1

310.4

441.2

6.8

256 .3

375.4

576 .4

944.7

1,395.4

7.9

$ 60.1

$110.3

$150.3

$278.6

O t h e r assets
TOTAL

9 .2 %

10 .1 %

S A V IN G S & LO AN A S S O C IA TIO N S
M o rtg a g e s

$

475 .8

12 .9 %

I nves tm en t securities

4. 6

7.4

13.0

30.9

46.5

10.0

11.9

18.8

10.8

O t h e r assets

6.8

11.9

12.8

28.8

57.0

11.7

1.6

17.5

18.6

71.5

129.6

176.2

338.3

579.3

12.6

6.3

13.9

14.4

$ 26.7

$ 44.4

$ 57.8

$ 77.2

6.2

5.5

3.2

4.7

7.6

-2 .6

-1 0 .5

8.5

12.6

.7

.3

.2

1.5

2.9

-1 3 .8

-9 .2

51.0

17.3

C o r p o r a te a n d ot he r securities

5.1

5.2

12.9

28.0

37.1

0.4

20.0

16.8

7.3

O t h e r assets

1.9

2.8

5.0

9.6

16.8

8.5

12.1

13.9

15.1

40.6

58.2

79.0

121.1

163.4

7.5

6.3

8.9

7.8

1 1.7%

14.8%

17.2%

TOTAL
M U TU A L S A V IN G S B AN K S
M o rtg a g e s
U . S . g o v e r n m e n t secur itie s
State an d local secur itie s

TO TAL

$

98.9

10.7%

5 .4 %

6.0%

6.4%

C R E D IT U N IO N S
Lo a n s out sta nd in g
O t h e r assets
TOTAL

$

4.4

8.1

$ 14.1

$ 28.2

53.1

1 3.0%

1.3

$

2.5

3.8

9.9

12.7

14.3

9.4

20.8

6.6

5.7

10.6

18.0

38.0

65.9

13.3

11.2

16.2

14.7

$

SOURCES: Banking and Monetary Statistics, 1941-1970; Annual Statistical Digests, 1971-1975 and 1974-1978; Federal Re­
serve Bulletin, March 1980 and October 1980.

The presumed “settled consumer preference” for
banks over competing institutions has become less
and less evident.18 First, S&Ls have unique advantages
over banks. They enjoy statewide branching privileges,
16The “settled consumer preference” notion adopted by the
Court conflicts with economic theory. Microeconomic theory
explains that a consumer’s choice between the outputs of
many banks is based on the relative prices of those out­
puts. All preferences are “settled,” or stable, in that they are
considered to be independent of price. Such stable prefer­
ences, however, do not preclude changes in response to
changing relative prices.




for example, in some states that limit branching for
banks. Second, new technology continues to alter the
traditional methods of marketing financial services.
Electronic banking is the most obvious example of
the declining importance of locational convenience in
banking — i.e., one-stop banking. Automated teller
machines, automatic payroll check deposit, banking
by mail and point-of-sale terminals expand the geo­
graphic scope of competition among depository insti­
tutions for what was once considered the locally
limited customer.
7

F E D E R A L . R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

F E B R U A R Y 1981

Table 3
Com position of Deposits (billions of dollars)
E n d of Period

A n n u a l G r o w t h Rates
19601965

19 6 51970

19 701975

19 7 51979

1960

1965

1970

1975

1979

$155.7

$183.8

$247.2

$319.8

$429.5

73.3

147.7

235.3

455.5

656.5

15.0

9.8

14.1

9.6

229 .0

331 .5

482.5

775 .2

1,086.0

7.7

7.8

9.9

.8.8

$ 62.1

$110.4

$146.4

$2 85.7

$470.2

12 .2 %

5 .8 %

14.3%

13.3%

$ 36.1

$ 52.1

$ 71.2

$109.3

$144.1

7 .6 %

6.4%

9 .0 %

7 .2 %

C O M M ER C IA L B AN K S
Demand
T i m e a n d s a v in gs
TOTAL

3 .4 %

6 .1 %

5 .3 %

7 .7 %

S AVIN G S A N D LO A N
A S S O C IA TIO N S
S a v i n g s capital
M U T U A L S A V IN G S B A N K S
T i m e a n d s a v in g s

.3

TOTAL

.3

.4

.6

1.9

5.4

4.8

6.6

35.1

36.3

Other

52.4

71.6

109.9

146.0

7.6

6.4

8.9

7.4

9.2

$ 15.5

$ 33.0

$ 56.2

13.1%

10.9%

1 6.3 %

14 .2 %

C R E D IT U N IO N S
M e m b e r savings

$

5.0

$

SOURCES: Banking and Monetary Statistics, 1941-1970; Annual Statistical Digests, 1971-1975 and 1974-1978; Federal R e­
serve Bulletin, March 1980 and October 1980; and National Fact Book of Mutual Savings Banking, 1976 and
1980.

Legal Issues
The Supreme Court case that most recently ad­
dressed the relevance of thrifts in competitive analy­
sis was the Connecticut National Bank case in 1974.17
A lower court had found that savings banks were
“fierce competitors” of banks in certain markets. The
Supreme Court, however, reaffirmed the line of com­
merce definition adopted in the Philadelphia case,
maintaining that commercial banks offer a unique
cluster of services that distinguish them from other
institutions. The Court in particular emphasized that
there was a lack of significant competition between
banks and mutual savings banks for commercial
accounts.
There was, however, an indication that the Court
realized that the Philadelphia definition’s usefulness
was declining. For example, in the Connecticut case
the Court stated:
A t som e stage in th e developm ent of savings banks
it will b e unrealistic to distinguish them from co m ­
m ercial banks for purposes of th e Clayton A ct. In
17United States v. Connecticut National Bank, 4 1 8 U.S. 656
(1 9 7 4 ).

8



C o n n ecticu t, th at p oint m ay w ell be reach ed w hen
and if savings banks b eco m e significant particip an ts
in the m arketing of bank services to com m ercial
enterprises. B u t, in ad herence to th e tests set forth
in our earlier bank m erg er cases, . . . such a point
has not y et been re a ch e d .18

The Court’s emphasis on competition for commer­
cial business has led some analysts to speculate that,
even with the passage of the MCA, thrifts will still
be excluded from the Federal Reserve’s competitive
analysis of mergers and acquisitions. Indeed, the quan­
titative impact of the new law is greater with respect
to the array of services offered to retail customers. All
depository institutions in the nation may offer NOW
accounts, but not to commercial and business enter­
prises.19 Mutual savings banks are now permitted to
18Ibid.
19NOW accounts are to be made available only to an individual
or to an organization that is “primarily for religious, philan­
thropic, charitable, educational, or other similar purposes and
which is not for profit.” These depositors have been defined
by the Federal Reserve Board to include individuals, sole
proprietors, husbands and wives operating unincorporated
businesses, local housing authorities, residential tenant se­
curity deposits, independent school districts and redevelop­
ment authorities.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

extend business loans ( up to 5 percent of total assets)
to firms within 75 miles of their main office, but since
most mutual savings banks are located in the East,
their competitive impact will be limited to eastern
markets. Likewise, the commercial lending authority
granted to mutual savings banks applies only to sav­
ings banks with federal charters. In addition, ex­
panded services to corporations would remain gener­
ally unavailable from S&Ls. The MCA, however, per­
mits Federal S&Ls to invest in commercial paper and
corporate debt securities ( up to 20 percent of assets).
Whether these specific changes will be sufficient to
alter the line of commerce definition in court cases is
an unsettled issue. Although the competitive impact
of the MCA on competition for commercial customers
may not be viewed as substantial in quantitative terms,
any marginal increases must be considered significant
since these new powers allow additional entrants into
markets for these services.

SOME ALTERNATIVES
Many analysts believe that a different approach to
the analysis of competition among depository institu­
tions is called for.20 To a limited degree, banking au­
thorities have already begun to introduce the influence
of thrifts into their analysis.21 The question still re­
mains, however, how the impact of increasing thrift
competition should be weighted in the analysis. In
other words, how would the line of commerce be
“unbundled?” Should commercial banks, mutual sav­
ings banks and S&Ls together encompass a line of
commerce, or should individual product markets of
these institutions be analyzed? Several options are
available.
20See, for example, Henry C. Wallich and W alter A. Varvel,
“Evolution in Banking Competition,” The Bankers Magazine
(November/December 1 9 8 0 ), pp. 26-34, and Commercial
Banking as a Line of C om m erce: An Examination of Its
Economic and Market Validity in Commercial Bank Anti­
trust Law, prepared by Golembe Associates Inc. for the
Association of Bank Holding Companies (Decem ber 1 9 8 0 ).
21For recent Federal Reserve actions see (1 ) approval for the
merger of The Bank of New York with Empire National
Bank, Federal Reserve Bulletin (September 1 9 8 0 ), pp. 80709; ( 2 ) denial for Republic of Texas Corporation to acquire
Citizens National Bank of W aco, Federal Reserve Bulletin
(September 1 9 8 0 ), pp. 787-89; ( 3 ) approval for Key Banks,
Inc., to acquire the National Bank or Northern New York,
Federal Reserve Bulletin (September 1 9 8 0 ), pp. 781-82; ( 4 )
denial for Texas Commerce Bancshares, Inc. to acquire The
First National Bank of Port Neches, Federal Reserve Bulletin
(July 1 9 8 0 ), pp. 584-85; ( 5 ) denial for Republic of Texas
Corporation to merge with Fort Sam Houston Bankshares,
Inc., Federal Reserve Bulletin (July 1 9 8 0 ), pp. 580-82; ( 6 )
approval for Fidelity Union Bancorporation to acquire Gar­
den State National Bank, Federal Reserve Bulletin (July
1 9 8 0 ), pp. 576-79; ( 7 ) denial for United Bank Corporation
of New York to acquire The Schenectady Trust Company,
Federal Reserve Bulletin (January 1 9 8 0 ), pp. 61-64.




F E B R U A R Y 1981

Add Thrifts to Line of Commerce
Framework
One alternative is simply to include thrift institu­
tions as direct competitors of banks; in other words,
treat thrifts as commercial banks for purposes of a line
of commerce definition. Concentration ratios would
continue to be the most likely candidates as the key
proxies for measuring competition under such an ap­
proach. Including thrifts into the analysis would liber­
alize merger and acquisition policy to some degree.
Since concentration ratios would be diluted by de­
posits or assets of thrifts, the number of possible bank
mergers meeting the Justice Department’s current
merger and acquisition “standards” would be
increased.22
Unfortunately, this approach suffers from the same
flaws that exist with the general use of “commercial
banking” as a line of commerce definition. Because
significant differences exist in the asset and liability
powers between banks and thrifts, competition varies
across relevant product lines. Likewise, the varying
forms of financial structure observed among geo­
graphic areas of the country (location of mutual sav­
ings banks in the East and different thrift and bank
branching laws across states, for instance) make such
concentration ratios difficult to apply consistently.
Maintaining the line of commerce framework by
including thrifts but continuing to rely on aggregated
market share statistics also suffers from major eco­
nomic flaws. As argued above, the relevant cross­
elasticities among products of banks and thrifts have
been altered by changes in technology and a great
number of financial innovations in recent years. Like­
wise, as regulations on interest rate ceilings are re­
moved over the next six years, financial institutions
will undoubtedly “unbundle” their own services. Com­
petition among institutions will result in independently
priced services and these prices will more closely
approximate the marginal costs of their provision.

Maintain Current Approach With “Subjective”
Addition of Thrifts
Another alternative is to maintain the current ap­
proach of including only banks in concentration analy­
sis, except in cases where thrifts are seen as “signifi­
cant competitors.” In such cases, thrifts would be used
22For an evaluation of the impact of including thrift deposits
in market concentration ratio calculations for banking mar­
kets in New York and New Jersey, see Roger E . Alcaly and
Richard W . Nelson, “Will Including Thrifts in the Banking
Market Affect Mergers,” T he Banking Law Journal (April
1 9 8 0 ), pp. 346-51.

9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

F E B R U A R Y 1981

in calculating market share data. In essence, this is
the approach that the banking regulatory authorities
are now using and, given the uncertainties of the
MCA’s impact, is the likely route they will follow dur­
ing a transition period. This methodology provides
enough flexibility to accommodate regional differences
in market structure, but is not likely to be legally
satisfying given its subjective framework. In addition,
it suffers from the same problems as the current line
of commerce definition of lumping together the many
outputs of banks and thrifts into one aggregate
measure.

uct lines. Each product line might correspond to a
different geographic market. Correspondent banking
services, for example, would have to be analyzed in
terms of larger geographic regions (e.g., a state),
whereas small business loans would be analyzed
within a more localized market. One would have to
identify both customers of such product lines and the
financial institutions offering close substitutes for this
approach. Practical data problems would therefore
limit the degree of disaggregation possible.

Unbundle Financial Institution Products

Although Supreme Court cases to date have con­
sistently upheld “commercial banking” as a distinct
line of commerce definition in bank merger cases, the
foundation of the Court’s reasoning has eroded since
1963. Significant market changes since the last Su­
preme Court case (1974) cast doubt on the practice
of evaluating mergers and acquisitions as narrowly as
the traditional analysis requires.

A third alternative, more consistent with economic
theory, is to disaggregate the traditional line of com­
merce (defined as commercial banking) into spe­
cific subcategories. Though this strategy would more
accurately reflect the actual competitive situation, it
would increase the difficulty of assessing the impact
on “overall” competition. Regulators would first be
faced with the problem of assigning weights to the
competitive effects of a merger or acquisition across
product lines. Since institutions are multi-product
producers, it is possible that competition among firms
may be lessened for some outputs but not for others.
For example, two local banks proposing to merge
might produce a monopoly on local trust services but
still generate vigorous competition with many other
financial institutions for checking and savings deposits.
Depending on the relative weights assigned to the
competitive effects across product lines (which would
continue to be measured by concentration ratios),
the disaggregated product approach might result in
a more restrictive stance against mergers and
acquisitions.
A second limitation to the disaggregation approach
is the lack of detailed statistics measuring some prod­

10



CONCLUSION

With the passage of the Monetary Control Act,
there is greater reason to depart from the established
tradition of treating commercial banking as an exclu­
sive line of commerce in antitrust analysis. A more
broadly defined line of commerce would increase the
number of mergers and acquisition proposals meeting
antitrust standards. On the other hand, a disaggre­
gated approach to analyzing the product lines of banks
and thrifts would more accurately scrutinize proposals
for actual anticompetitive effects. Such changes in
product and geographic market definitions will have
important implications for the future structure and
competitive performance of the financial industry.
Although the proper analytic approach is still evolv­
ing, increased thrift competition will certainly play
a more significant role in the evaluation of future
bank mergers and BHC acquisition proposals.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

F E B R U A R Y 1981

Appendix
Defining Banking Markets
The most crucial element of competitive analysis in
many bank merger and acquisition cases is the definition
of the relevant local banking market. In many proposals
analyzed by the Federal Reserve, the only dispute (over
which approval or denial of an application depends) is
over the appropriate market definition. Given the tendency
of the courts in recent years to rely on simple market share
tests, it is important to understand the logic and reasoning
behind the delineation of banking markets.
There are both conceptual and empirical problems in
defining banking markets. The conceptual problems deal
with describing the relationship between “sellers” and
“buyers,” so that an area can be defined as a market.
The most basic and widely accepted concept for analyz­
ing markets is “cross-elasticity of demand.” The crossprice-elasticity is a measure which summarizes the rela­
tionship between the change in price of any one firm’s
output and the amount of business done by others (see
footnote 14 in text). If an increase (decrease) in the price
of one firm’s service results in a significant increase (de­
crease) in the sales of another, the two may be considered
to be subject to the same market forces — and are in the
same market. Economic theory does not tell us, however,
what magnitude of the cross-elasticity should be used for
such determinations. It does tell us that if competition
exists, output prices of these firms tend to equalize to prices
equivalent to the marginal cost of providing these services.
Implementing this conceptual framework in actual case­
work is not easily achieved. Since price data to measure
cross-elasticities are difficult to obtain, a number of other
proxies are used in defining a market. Most of these indi­
rect measures of cross-elasticity center around judgments
about the “reasonable interchangeability” of the products
of firms. The “products,” of course, have been defined as
the general category of banking services (total deposits
being used as a proxy for such output) to conform to the
line of commerce definition adopted by the courts.
Although there is no uniformly accepted method of
defining banking markets, the following items are impor­
tant factors in the process of defining markets.
A. Structural information — the size and location of
competing institutions and branches, other statutes
which restrict actual or potential entry (restric­
tive chartering practices and branching laws, for
example).
B. Distance factors and commuting patterns — the
distance between relevant competing institutions,
traffic flows, the quality of roads and other nat­
ural boundaries which affect access to competing
institutions.
C. Political boundaries — county and state boundaries
(banking laws which restrict branching within




such boundaries adds some weight to using these
definitions).
D. •
Geographic distribution of advertising — radio,
television and newspapers.
A useful proxy for interaction of suppliers of banking
services and customers is primary service area (PSA) data.
The PSA is normally defined as that geographic area con­
tiguous to an office from which 80 percent of the dollar
amount of that office’s deposits is derived. Applicants are
frequently requested to submit comparable data for
other services (e.g., demand deposits, savings deposits,
loans, etc.).
Confusion reigns among bankers about the difference
between PSAs and markets as economists define them. The
lack of overlapping service areas between banks does not
necessarily mean that banks are located in distinct market
areas. The two are not equivalent concepts. All of the fac­
tors mentioned above may make the market substantially
larger than a bank’s PSA. In other words, two banks,
competing in the same market, need not have common
customers or overlapping PSAs.
For those wishing to review the literature on the ana­
lytics of defining banking markets, the following sources
are suggested:
David D. Whitehead, “Relevant Geographic Banking
Markets: How Should They Be Defined?” Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review (January/
February 1980), pp. 20-28.
Paul R. Schweitzer, “Definition of Banking Markets,”
Banking Law Journal (September 1973), pp. 745-62.
Ira Horowitz, “On Defining the Geographic Markets in
Section 7 Cases,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Proceedings of a Conference on Bank Structure and
Competition (1977), pp. 169-82.
Charles D. Salley, “Uniform Price and Banking Mar­
ket Delineation,” Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta
Monthly Review (June 1975), pp. 86-93.
Douglas V. Austin, “The Line of Commerce and the
Relevant Geographic Market in Banking: What
Fifteen Years of Trials and Tribulations Has Taught
Us and Not Taught Us About The Measure of Bank­
ing Structure,” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Pro­
ceedings of a Conference on Bank Structure and
Competition (1977), pp. 185-209.
Steven A. Mathis, Duane G. Harris and Michael Boehlje,
“An Approach to the Delineation of Rural Banking
Markets,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics
(November 1978), pp. 601-08.

11

Selecting a Monetary Indicator:
A Test of the New Monetary Aggregates
R. W. HAFER

T he Federal Reserve System changed its approach
to implementing monetary policy on October 6, 1979.
Prior to that date, it attempted to reduce fluctuations
in short-run interest rates as a means of achieving,
along with interest rate stability, a degree of control
over movements in the monetary aggregates. On Oc­
tober 6, however, the Federal Reserve shifted its
focus from movements in short-run interest rates to
movements in reserves held by the banking system.
Shortly thereafter, in early 1980, the Federal Re­
serve announced major redefinitions of the monetary
aggregates.
The shift in operating procedures and the change
in the monetary definitions points up the need to
investigate which of the new monetary aggregates
is the best indicator of monetary actions. Selecting
the appropriate aggregate as an indicator requires
that several issues be addressed. The first issue con­
cerns the controllability of a given monetary aggre­
gate. In other words, given a change in monetary
actions, which aggregate will respond to that change
in a predictable manner? A second issue concerns the
predictability of the movements in the indicator and
economic activity, i.e., how well the monetary aggre­
gate explains movements in a measure of economic
activity such as nominal GNP. Finally, there is the
important question of the proposed indicator s exo­
geneity with respect to the economic variable that
policymakers are attempting to influence. This article
will examine the last issue, that of exogeneity, using
the new monetary aggregates.

EXOGENEITY TESTS
A monetary indicator is a variable that signals the
current direction of monetary policy. Thus, move­
ments in the indicator must not be influenced unduly
by, or result from changes in, some non-policy action;
that is, the indicator must be exogenous to (not
Digitized for12
FRASER


caused by) non-policy actions.1 If monetary policy­
makers attempt to control nominal GNP, for example,
changes in GNP should be a direct result of changes
in monetary actions as evidenced by changes in the
monetary indicator; the monetary indicator must not
be directly influenced by changes in GNP. In this
sense, a monetary aggregate can be used as an indi­
cator only if movements in GNP do not result in
movements in the monetary aggregate.
Previous investigations into the selection of an ap­
propriate monetary indicator have focused primarily
on the predictability of the relationship between the
hypothesized indicator and nominal income. Friedman
and Meiselman, for example, regressed nominal GNP
on various measures of money, concluding that M2
(currency, demand and time deposits) was the pref­
erable definition.2 Along these same lines, Schadrack
examined the relationship between GNP and six dif­
ferent monetary measures, also concluding that M2
was statistically superior.3 Levin provided another
'An unresolved debate exists concerning the appropriateness
of the term indicator. In some instances, the characteristics
used here to denote an indicator have also been used to char­
acterize targets of policy actions. In this article the term
indicator describes a variable that points to the current direc­
tion of monetary policy. To appreciate the complexity of the
issues surrounding discussions of “targets” and “indicators”
of monetary policy, see Karl Brunner and Allan Meltzer, “The
Meaning of Monetary Indicators,” Monetary Economics: Read­
ings on Current Issues, ed. William E . Gibson and George C.
Kaufman (N ew York: McGraw-Hill, 1 9 7 1 ), pp. 403-15; Karl
Brunner, ed., Targets and Indicators of Monetary Policy (San
Francisco: Chandler Publishing Co., 1 9 6 9 ); Benjamin A.
Friedman, “Targets, Instruments, and Indicators of Monetary
Policy,” Journal of Monetary Economics (October 1 9 7 5 ), pp.
443-73.
-Milton Friedman and David Meiselman, “The Relative Stabil­
ity of Monetary Velocity and the Investment Multiplier in the
United States, 1897-1958,” in Commission on Money and
Credit, Stabilization Policies (Englewood Cliffs: PrenticeHall, 1 9 6 3 ), pp. 165-268.
3Frederick C. Schadrack, “An Empirical Approach to the Defi­
nition of Money,” Monetary Aggregates and Monetary Policy
(Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 1 9 7 4 ), pp. 28-34.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

test procedure in which changes in GNP are regressed
on current and lagged changes of various money and
credit aggregates using the Almon lag technique.4 In
addition to regressing GNP on the different monetary
measures, he estimated the relationships using fiscal
variables and strike dummies as additional explana­
tory variables. Based on in- and out-of-sample results,
Levin concluded that bank credit should be used as
a monetary indicator.
In contrast, Hamburger explicitly tested for the
exogeneity of several monetary variables.5 He did this
by regressing the different monetary variables on cur­
rent and lagged values of GNP and the Treasury bill
rate. Based on these tests, Hamburger concluded that
nonborrowed reserves is a better indicator of policy
actions than the other monetary variables studied.
Recently, Carlson and Hein also have addressed the
issue of selecting a monetary indicator.6 Their tests,
using the new MIA, M1B and M2 definitions of
money, provide a useful examination of the predictive
relationship between these money measures and GNP.
Their study also provides evidence about the statisti­
cal exogeneity of these measures with respect to GNP
using tests designed to detect simultaneous equation
bias in the estimated regressions.
The focus of this article is to test directly for the
exogeneity of the new monetary aggregates with re­
spect to GNP. Nominal GNP is the measure of eco­
nomic activity traditionally used in studies of this kind.
Moreover, there is evidence to suggest that the influ­
ence of monetary actions is channeled directly to the
economy via nominal GNP. The tests utilized in this
article are based on the works of Granger and Sims.7
4Fred J. Levin, “The Selection of a Monetary Indicator: Some
Further Empirical Evidence,” Monetary Aggregates and
Monetary Policy (Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 1 9 7 4 ),
pp. 35-39.
5Michael J. Hamburger, "Indicators of Monetary Policy: The
Arguments and the Evidence,” American Econom ic Review,
Papers and Proceedings (M ay 1 9 7 0 ), pp. 32-39. The mone­
tary measures used by Hamburger include effective nonbor­
rowed reserves, total reserves, old M l, old M2 and bank
credit.
eKeith M. Carlson and Scott E . Hein, “Monetary Aggregates
as Monetary Indicators,” this Review (November 1 9 8 0 ), pp.

12 21
-

.

7See C.W .J. Granger, “Investigating Causal Relations by Econ­
ometric Models and Cross-Spectral Methods,” Econometrica
(July 1 9 6 9 ), pp. 424-38; C.W .J. Granger and Paul Newbold,
“The Time Series Approach to Econometric Model Building,”
N ew Methods in Business Cycle Research: Proceedings from
a C onference (Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, 1 9 7 7 ),
pp. 7-21; Christopher A. Sims, “Money, Income, and Caus­
ality,” American Economic Review (September 1 9 7 2 ), pp.
540-52 and “Exogeneity and Causal Ordering in Macroeco­
nomic Models,” in N ew Methods, pp. 23-43.




F E B R U A R Y 1981

Granger Test
Granger’s test procedure is based on the following
premise: if forecasts of some variable Y (say, GNP)
obtained using both past values of Y and past values
of another variable X (say, money) are better than
forecasts obtained using past values of Y alone,
then X is said to “cause” Y.8 This causal ordering
between two variables is analogous to the order­
ing between economic activity and certain leading
indicators.9
Although Granger’s test is founded on the notion
of causation, it is nevertheless well adapted to deter­
mine exogeneity. Suppose, for example, it is shown
that changes in GNP “cause” changes in money in
Granger’s sense. The consequence of this obviates the
use of money as an indicator of monetary actions
since the policymaker can not differentiate between
movements in money due to current changes in policy
from those due to changes in GNP. Based on the
criteria for selecting a monetary indicator set forth
above, the discovery that GNP “causes” money indi­
cates that money is not exogenous to GNP. Conse­
quently, it is not a viable indicator of monetary
actions.
To test for Granger causality, it is assumed that the
information relevant to the prediction of the respec­
tive variables is contained solely in the data series
Y and X (e.g., GNP and money).10 Granger’s test
8More formally, Granger causality may be defined in the fol­
lowing manner. L et P (t)(Y | U ) be the optimal, unbiased
prediction of the variable Y given that all relevant informa­
tion U accumulated since period t -1 is known. Using this pre­
diction, the relevant error series £ ( t ) is defined as £ (t)(Y | U )
= Y ( t ) - P (t)(Y | U ). The variance of the error series is
represented by o 2 (Y|U ). To say that some variable X
“causes” Y in Granger’s sense requires that the variance of
the error terms — the forecast error variance based on all
relevant information — is less than the forecast error variance
with an information set that does not include X. In other
words, if ( U - X ) is the information set excluding the data
embodied in X , then Granger causality may be defined in
the following manner:
If a 2 (Y|U) < o 2(Y | U -X ),
then X is said to cause Y.
It should be noted, however, that satisfying the above cri­
terion is a necessary but not sufficient condition to conclude
that unidirectional causation running from X to Y exists.
“Bidirectional causation” or feedback from one variable to
another may also exist. Feedback occurs if the conditions
o2 (Y|U) < o 2 (Y IU -X ) and o 2 (X|U) < o 2(X | U -Y ) occur
simultaneously. W nen this result emerges, causation is said to
run both from X to Y and from Y to X.
9Paul A. Pautler and Richard J. Rivard, “Choosing a Monetary
Aggregate: Causal Relationship as a Criterion,’ Review of
Business and Economic Research (F all 1 9 7 9 ), pp. 1-18.
10It is further assumed that the time series X and Y are sta­
tionary, i.e., the stochastic processes generating the observed
Xs and Ys have respective means and variances that are in­
variant with respect to time.

13

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

F E B R U A R Y 1981

then consists of estimating the equations
(1 ) X (t) = Z a , X (t-j) +
j

Z Pj Y ( t - j ) +

=i

e ,

i= i

and
(2 ) Y ( t ) = Z y , X ( t - j ) +
i=i

Z 8, Y ( t - j ) +
1=1

n*.

It is assumed that in estimating these two equations
the error series s (t) and q (t) are uncorrelated.11 On
the basis of estimating equations 1 and 2, unidirec­
tional causation from variable X to Y is implied if the
estimated coefficients on the lagged X variable in equa­
tion 2 are statistically different from zero as a group
and the set of estimated coefficients on the lagged
Y variable in equation 1 is not statistically different
from zero. Conversely, unidirectional causation from
Y to X exists if the coefficients on lagged Y in equa­
tion 1 are statistically non-zero as a group and the
set of the lagged X’s coefficients is zero in equation
2. Feedback (bidirectional causation) from Y to X
exists when the set of the coefficients on lagged Y in
equation 1 and on lagged X in equation 2 are statis­
tically different from zero.

Sims Test
The causality/exogeneity test procedures proposed
by Sims also are used to examine the relationship
between GNP and the new monetary aggregates.
Basically, the notions of Granger causality and sta­
tistical exogeneity are equivalent if all of the esti­
mated “future” coefficients 6ct (i = -m, . . . , ~1) are
jointly zero in the equation
(3 ) Y (t) = Z a , X (t-i) + n (t),
i= -m

where p (t) is a white noise residual.12 If ctj = 0
for all i (i = -m, . . . , -1 ), then “Y does not cause
X” and “X is exogenous to Y” are equivalent.
The test procedure proposed by Sims involves re­
gressing current values of the variable Y on past, cur­
rent and future values of X and testing the signifi­
cance of the coefficients on the future Xs. If the coeffi­
cients on the future values of X are not statistically
significant as a group, then X is exogenous to Y. Thus,
11 More specifically, it is assumed that E [ e ( t ) , e ( s )] =
E [r| (t), r)( s )] = 0 and E [ s ( t ) , r|( s )] = 0, for all t

0,
s.

12Equation 3 is based on the assumption that the Y and X
time series are jointly covariance-stationary. In other words,
the covariance of Y and X are invariant with respect to
time. See C.W .J. Granger and Paul Newbold, Forecasting
Economic Time Series (New York: Academic Press, 1 9 7 7 ).

Digitized for 14
FRASER


regressing current values of the various monetary ag­
gregates on past, current and future values of GNP
provides additional evidence about the exogeneity be­
tween GNP and each of the new monetary aggregates.
Moreover, regressing current values of GNP on cur­
rent, past and future values of the different mone­
tary measures allows us to test for the possibility of
bidirectional causation.13

Empirical Results
Quarterly observations of the logarithms of nominal
GNP and the monetary aggregates MIA, M1B, M2,
M3 and L are used to test for exogeneity.14 Because
the monetary measures are available only since 1959
and because lagged variables must be used in con­
ducting the tests, the empirical results reported are
based on the sample period III/1961-II/1980. Even
though seasonally adjusted data are used, seasonal
dummy variables are included in all regressions as a
precaution against residual seasonality.
The Granger-test regressions are reported in table
1. Each regression includes four lagged observations
of the dependent variable and eight lags on the inde­
pendent variable. The Granger test requires the data
to exhibit stationary characteristics, a requirement
satisfied by entering a linear trend variable in the

13The implementation and interpretation of the Granger and
Sims tests are subject to several caveats. For example, in
establishing causality, the use of a specific set of variables ne­
cessitates that causality statements be made only with refer­
ence to the relative information set. In other words, if the
information set consists solely of the variables X and Y,
causality is defined only relative to this information. This
problem has been explored more fully by Jacobs, et al., who
argue that tests of the type proposed by Sims are really tests
of “informativeness,” not econometric exogeneity.
Another problem that may influence the outcome of these
tests is the observation period over which the data are re­
ported. For example, while test results using annual data
may imply unidirectional causation from X to Y, feedback
between the two variables may result when data for shorter
time periods are used.
Finally, it should be stressed that the information provided
by these tests is necessary for exogeneity between two vari­
ables. If the test results indicate that future coefficients of
the independent variable in equation 3 are significantly
different from zero, or that the coefficients on the “independ­
ent” variables in equations 1 and 2 fulfill the required condi­
tions, then exogeneity is possible. See Rodney L . Jacobs,
Edward E. Learner, and Michael P. W ard, “Difficulties with
Testing for Causation,” Economic Inquiry (July 1 9 7 9 ), pp.
401-13.
14For a description of the new monetary aggregates and how
they compare to the old measures, see R. W . Hafer, “The
New Monetary Aggregates,” this Review (February 1 9 8 0 ),
pp. 25-32.
15This approach also is employed by Thomas Sargent, “A
Classical Macroeconomic Model for the United States,” Jour­
nal of Political Economy (April 1 9 7 6 ), pp. 207-37.

Table 1
Regression Results for the Granger Test
R eg res sion T e s t e d :

Y (t)

=

i

oc (j) Y ( t - j )

+

i

p (j) X (t-j)

+

£t

S a m p l e P e rio d : 111/1961-11/1980

Y

X

GNP

M1A

0 (1 )

0 (2 )

o (3 )

o (4 )

[5 (1 )

P (2 )

P (3 )

P (4 )

P (5 )

P (6)

P (7 )

P (8 )

GNP

0.916

-0.0 8 9

0.078

0.056

0.609

-0 .3 5 7

0.202

-0 .8 0 2

0.781

-0.4 3 7

-0 . 1 8 1

0.280

(6 . 3 3 )

(0.46 )

(0 . 4 1 )

(0 . 4 0 )

(2 .7 5 )

(0.96 )

(0.5 1 )

(2.06 )

(2 .0 1 )

(1.05 )

(0 . 4 5 )

(1 . 3 3 )

0.933

-0.0 9 2

0.061

0.026

0.551

-0 .2 7 7

0.141

-0.8 5 3

0.778

-0.3 6 8

-0 .1 5 5

0.268

(6.45 )
GNP

M1B

(0.48 )

(0.32 )

(0 . 1 9 )

(2.3 9 )

(0 .7 0 )

(0.32 )

(2.03 )

(1 .8 5 )

(0.84 )

(0 . 3 8 )
0.136
(0 . 3 0 )

0.847

-0 .1 1 1

0.044

-0.052

0.521

-0 .4 9 3

0.482

-0 .8 9 1

0.903

-0.3 9 9

(0.61 )

(0.25 )

(0 . 4 2 )

(2.66 )

(1.1 5 )

(0.96 )

(1 . 7 4 )

(1 . 7 4 )

(0 . 7 6 )

1.161
(2 .4 2 )

-1 .3 3 3

0.762

-0 .1 5 3

(2.67 )

(1 .7 0 )

1.023

-0.194

0.070

-0.018

0.364

-0.212

-0.0 6 2

-0 .4 1 5

(1.02 )

(0 . 3 8 )

(0 . 1 4 )

(1 . 8 6 )

(0.5 0 )

(0.13 )

(0 . 8 7 )

0.907

-0.1 6 8

0.016

-0.00 1

0.508

-0.0 4 0

-0 .2 6 1

-0.8 8 4

1.736

-1.291

0.216

0.204

(0 . 9 2 )

(0.09 )

(0 . 0 0 )

(2 .0 2 )

(0.0 8 )

(0 . 4 7 )

(1 . 5 8 )

(3 .0 9 )

(2.12 )

(0 . 3 8 )

GNP

1.458

-0 .6 6 1

0.048

0.119

-0 .0 2 5

0.050

-0.0 9 7

0.032

0.192

-0 .0 9 6

(0 . 1 9 )

(0 . 7 6 )

(0 .2 6 )

(0 . 4 0 )

(0 .7 8 )

0.226
(1 . 8 1 )

-0 . 3 2 1

(2 . 6 1 )

(2 . 5 3 )

(0 . 2 5 )

(1.53 )

GNP

1.484

-0.6 3 4

-0.0 3 7

0.125

-0 .018

0.062

-0 .0 5 5

-0 .1 7 6

-0 .2 9 5

0.226

0.226

-0 .1 1 4

(2 . 5 0 )

(0.14 )

(0 . 8 2 )

(0 . 2 0 )

(0 . 5 2 )

(0.46 )

(1.48 )

(2 .4 6 )

(0.21 )

(1.8 8 )

GNP

1.784

-0 . 9 9 3

0.320

-0.105

-0 .1 8 6

0.076

0.030

0.034

-0 .127

0.078

0.024

0.05 6

(3 . 7 1 )

(1.19 )

(0 . 7 4 )

(2.08 )

(0 . 6 6 )

(0.26 )

(0 .3 0 )

(1 .1 1 )

(0.69 )

(0.2 1 )

7.67

1.94

3.84

7.99

1.89

2.96

7.47

2.01

4.44

5.47

1.81

1.54

5.23

1.82

1.36

5.06

1.99

0.12

5.28

1.96

0.35

3.81

1.98

0.67

(0.70 )

GNP

1.917

-1 . 1 3 9

0.169

0.042

-0.0 8 8

0.060

-0.0 1 0

0.003

-0.0 0 7

-0 .0 2 3

-0.0 2 0

0.082

(1 4 .8 1 )

(4 . 0 4 )

(0.59 )

(0 . 2 9 )

(1 .0 0 )

(0 . 5 0 )

(0 .0 8 )

(0 .0 2 )

(0 .0 6 )

(0.20 )

(0 . 1 7 )

(1 .0 4 )

1.796

-0 .8 4 2

0.014

0.030

-0 .0 3 3

0.037

-0 . 0 7 3

0.104

-0.1 2 8

0.026

0.071

-0 .0 0 9

(1 3 .6 2 )

L

2.43

(1 . 4 1 )

(1 3 .6 8 )
M3

1.96

(1 .1 4 )

(9.8 5 )
M2

8.20

(0 .7 4 )

L

(9 .5 3 )
M1B

2.49

(0.7 4 )

M3

0.021

(6 .6 7 )

M1A

1.96

(0.10 )

M2

(7 . 4 6 )
GNP

8.18

(1 .2 5 )

(6 .1 6 )
GNP

F-statistic
on all P ( j )
S E X 1 0 - 3 D.W .
F (8 5 >
U

(3 . 1 6 )

(0.05 )

(0 . 2 0 )

(0.50 )

(0 .4 3 )

(0 .8 4 )

(1 .2 2 )

(1 .4 7 )

(0.30 )

(0.84 )

(0 . 1 6 )

GNP

Notes: All equations included a constant term, linear trend variable and three seasonal dummy variables. Absolute value of t-statistics appear in parentheses. Because
the R2 exceeds 0.99 in every instance, only the standard error of the estimating equation is reported. D.W . is the Durbin-Watson statistic. Critical values for
the F-statistic are F<s.m 2.82 (1 percent) and 2.10 ( 5 percent).
»:




F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

The upper section of table 1 reports the results of
testing the hypothesis that money is exogenous to
(causes) GNP. The Durbin-Watson (D.W .) statis­
tic shows no first-order serial correlation.16 The Fstatistics in the last column of table 1 test the joint
significance of all the lag terms ( |3jS) for the differ­
ent monetary variables, given lagged GNP. These
F-statistics indicate that for the monetary aggregates
MIA and M1B, the hypothesis that money is exo­
genous to GNP cannot be rejected at the 5 percent
significance level. At the 1 percent level of significance,
the hypothesis cannot be rejected for the M2, M3
and L aggregates. These results thus indicate that
money, when defined as MIA, M1B, M2, M3 or L,
is statistically exogenous to GNP at high levels of
significance.
Showing that the lagged money variables are sig­
nificant as a group, however, does not preclude the
possibility of bidirectional causality (GNP also is exo­
genous to money). To test for this, a second set of
regressions is estimated. This group of regressions
employs the different monetary measures as the de­
pendent variables and lagged values of GNP as inde­
pendent variables. These regressions, reported in the
lower section of table 1, are used to test the null
hypothesis that GNP is exogenous to ( causes) money.
The F-statistics reported in the lower-half of table
1 indicate that lagged GNP does not significantly ex­
plain movements in the various money measures,
once lagged money is accounted for. Not only are
they all well below acceptable critical values, but
few of the individual coefficients on lagged GNP
achieve statistical significance. Thus, the results re­
ported in table 1 support the contention that there is
unidirectional causation from money to GNP for the
MIA, M1B, M2, M3 and L monetary measures.
To further investigate the econometric relationship
between GNP and money, the Sims test procedures
are implemented. Regression estimates for the Sims
test are presented in table 2.17 Because future obser­
vations are required for the Sims test, the sample
16The D.W . statistic is not appropriate when the regression
includes a lagged dependent variable. In each regression reorted in table 1, however, the Durbin h-statistic could not
e calculated. As a check, the residuals were calculated from
each regression and used in estimating a second and fourth
order autoregressive process (see footnote 1 7 ). The results
from these tests support the contention in the text that no
significant serial correlation exists.
17The reported k-value in table 2 is the k used to “whiten”
the data. Some comments on the technique used to whiten
the data in order that the Sims test can be used are in
order. Preliminary estimates using the simple filter process

Digitized for 16
FRASER


F E B R U A R Y 1981

period ends in 11/1979. In each regression, four future
and eight past values of the independent variable are
used. The upper half of table 2 reports the results for
the test that money is exogenous to GNP while the
lower section reports those for the test that GNP is
exogenous to money. A comparison of these two sets
of regressions reveals an appreciable difference. The
difference is the general insignificance of the esti­
mated coefficients on future money in contrast to the
relatively large number of statistically significant co­
efficients on future GNP. Indeed, this is precisely the
outcome to be expected if money is exogenous to
(causes) GNP.
Another interesting feature of the regression results
is the pattern of the estimated coefficients on the fu­
ture observations. The general pattern for the a (-4 )
to a (0 ) terms in the upper part of table 2 suggests
an increasing influence of money on GNP over the
first two quarters, followed by a decline in its influ­
ence over the next two quarters. This pattern is con­
sistent with that found in studies examining the lag
structure between GNP and money via reduced-form
equations.18 In contrast, the future coefficients .re­
ported in the lower half of table 2 (the regressions
used to test the hypothesis that GNP is exogenous to
money) show no regular pattern.
The F-statistics pertinent to Sims’ exogeneity test
employed in the Granger tests revealed that the residuals
were highly serially correlated. Because the F-tests used in
the exogeneity tests are inappropriate in the presence of
serial correlation, the following iterative procedure was
used to remove serial correlation. Assuming that the serial
correlation is not of order greater than two, the second-order
filter ( 1 - k L ) 2 (where 0 < k < 1 and X tL ‘ = X t- i ) was
used to prefilter the data. The relevant regression is estimated
with future and past values of the independent variable pres­
ent and some initial value of k. The residuals from this re­
gression are calculated and examined for autoregressive char­
acteristics. This is accomplished by estimating the equations
(A )

Resid ( t ) = a , +

I
t-i bi

Resid ( t - i ) + Vi ( t )

and
(B )

Resid ( t ) = ai +

Z b! Resid ( t - i ) + v2( t ) ,

1=1

where Resid is the estimated residual and V i(t) and v2( t )
are error structures assumed to possess classical properties.
The test for serial correlation, then, involves using the stand­
ard F-statistic to test for the significance of the bi and bi
coefficients. If the calculated F-value exceeds the 5 percent
critical value, another value of k is chosen and the entire
process is repeated. The final value of k used to transform
the data is that value which yields statistically insignificant
F-statistics from both equations A and B. This procedure is
described in Y. P. Mehra, “Is Money Exogenous in MoneyDemand Equations,” Journal of Political Economy (April
1 9 7 8 ), pp. 211-28.
18See, for example, Carlson and Hein, “Monetary Aggregates
as Monetary Indicators.”

Table 2
Regression Results for the Sim s Test
R egres sion T e s t e d :

Y (t) =

2

a ( i ) X (t-i) +

n(t)

S a m p le P e rio d : 111/1961-11/1979
Y

X

«(-4 )

M1A

GNP

-0 .1 4 3

0.080

0.148

0.214

(2 .0 9 )

(1 . 0 9 )

(2 . 1 4 )

(3.09 )

a (-2 )

a (-1 )

oc (0 )

a (7 )

a (8 )

-0.0 9 8

0.130

-0.098

(1.37 )

(1.7 8 )

(1 .3 2 )

a (4 )

a (5 )

a (6 )

-0.082

0.034

-0 .1 2 8

(1 .1 8 )

(0.47 )

(1.7 2 )

oc(1)

a (2 )

a (3 )

0.171

0.055

-0 .0 07

(2.42 )

(0.7 8 )

(0.11 )

M2

-0.163

0.082

0.165

0.215

0.172

0.076

0.031

-0.0 1 5

0.050

-0.127

-0 .0 8 1

0.159

-0.0 6 8

(2 .5 7 )

M1B

GNP

o c(-3)

(1.22 )

(2 . 5 7 )

(3.35 )

(2.63 )

(1.17 )

(0.49 )

(0.24 )

(0.75 )

(1 . 8 5 )

(1 .2 3 )

(2.3 5 )

GNP

GNP

-0 .0 6 7

0.161

0.232

0.31 3

0.203

0.054

-0.025

(1.98 )

(2 . 9 6 )

(4.11 )

(2 . 6 5 )

(0.7 4 )

(0 .3 5 )

-0.006

0.127

0.231

0.297

0.226

0.073

0.006

(0 . 0 8 )

(1.41 )

(2 . 6 6 )

(3.53 )

(2.67 )

(0 . 9 0 )

(0 .0 8 )

-0 .0 1 5

-0 .1 2 6

-0 .0 6 1

0.018

-0.0 7 9

(0 . 0 4 )

(0.20 )

(1 . 5 9 )

(0.77 )

(0.2 3 )

-0 .0 1 0

-0.0 4 2

-0 .0 7 0

-0 .0 4 0

-0 .073

0.023

(0.13 )

(0 .5 1 )

(0 . 7 9 )

(0 . 4 6 )

(0.8 2 )

GNP

GNP

0.070

0.172

0.231

0.223

0.160

0.138

0.075

0.102

-0.0 0 5

0.013

0.039

0.043

(1.21 )

(3 . 1 0 )

(4.27 )

(4 . 1 1 )

(3 . 0 8 )

(2.75 )

(1.42 )

(1 .8 9 )

(0.0 9 )

(0.23 )

(0.6 9 )

M IA

0.383

-0.4 8 6

0.175

0.061

(2 . 0 1 )

(0 . 7 4 )

(0.26 )

0.632
(2.59 )

-0.0 0 5

0.363

(0 . 0 2 )

(1 .3 6 )

0.467
(1 .8 1 )

-0.0 9 4

-0 .1 53

0.020

0.037

0.131

(0 .3 7 )

(0.6 0 )

(0 .0 7 )

(0.1 5 )

-0.4 0 6

0.037

0.724

-0 .0 2 6

0.256

-0.1 0 8

-0 .1 5 6

-0 .051

0.028

0.138

(1.70 )

(0 . 8 0 )

(0 . 1 6 )

(2.89 )

(0.1 0 )

(1.00 )

(1.62 )

(0 .4 4 )

(0.6 4 )

(0.21 )

(0.12 )

-0 .0 9 9

-0.0 1 5

-0.014

0.205

0.363

-0 . 0 8 1

0.412

-0 .3 7 8

0.14 6

0.042

0.178

0.164

(0.32 )

(0 . 0 5 )

(0.04 )

(0 . 6 2 )

(1 . 0 9 )

(0.24 )

(1.19 )

(1.13 )

(0.4 5 )

(0.13 )

(0.55 )

-0 .1 0 5

0.213

-0 .0 6 3

-0.110

0.225

0.208

0.17 8

0.092

-0 .3 94

0.685

-0 .4 36

0.234

0.087

(0.72 )

(0.21 )

(0.37 )

(0.76 )

(0.7 2 )

(0.61 )

(0.31 )

(1 .3 4 )

(2.3 0 )

(1.46 )

(0 .7 9 )

GNP

M3

L

0.024

-0.2 2 6

0.194

0.006

0.404

0. 16 5

0.249

-0.2 6 5

-0.041

0.197

(0 . 5 8 )

(0 . 5 0 )

(0 . 0 2 )

(1.02 )

(0 .4 2 )

(0.62 )

(0.63 )

(0 .1 0 )

(0 . 7 4 )

0.400

0.130
(0.3 3 )

-0 .7 1 1
(1.74 )

0.622
(1.50 )

1.70

1.55
0.8

3.29

1.89
0.8

8.24

1.92
0.6

(0.4 2 )

(0 .2 4 )
GNP

5.14

(0.76 )

0.04 9

0.186

1.64

0.8

(0.64 )

(0.0 9 )

M2

0.547

(0 .4 9 )

GNP

4.64

(0.58 )

(2 .5 7 )

M1B

1.52

0.6

(0.82 )

(1 .8 0 )
GNP

4.33

(0 .2 8 )

-0.050

D.W ./k

0.6

(1 .0 7 )

0.003

(0 .9 7 )

L

4.41

(0 .9 9 )

(0 .9 3 )
M3

S E X 10-*

7.76

2.20
0.6

7.83

1.74
0.4

8.44

1.58
0.5

7.83

1.61
0.4

Notes: All equations included a constant term, linear trend variable and three seasonal dummy variables. SE is the standard error of the estimated equation, D.W.
is the Durbin-Watson statistic, and k is the value used to construct the second-order linear filter ( 1 - k L ) 2 where 0 < k < 1. The reported k-value yielded
residuals that do not exhibit serial correlation up to order four. Absolute values of the t-statistic are in parentheses.




F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F S T . L O U IS

F E B R U A R Y 1981

CONCLUSION
Table 3
Sim s Test Results
Dependent
v aria ble

In d e p e n d e n t
v ar ia ble

F-statistic
4.33

M1A

GNP

M1B

GNP

5.58

M2

GNP

5.72

M3

GNP

3.70

L

GNP

5.69

GNP

M1A

1.65

GNP

M1B

2.28

GNP

M2

0.09

GNP

M3

0.15

L

0.14

GNP

Notes: The calculated F-statistic is pertinent to testing the
joint significance of the future values in the regres­
sions reported in table 2. Critical F-values (4 ,5 4 )
are: 2.54 ( 5 percent) and 3.68 (1 percent).

are reported in table 3. To reiterate, these tests in­
vestigate the joint significance of the future coeffi­
cients. If the set of future coefficients is significantly
different from zero, then the Y variable (the depend­
ent variable) is exogenous to the X variable (the
independent variable). Based on standard levels of
statistical significance, the results in table 3 suggest
that every monetary aggregate is exogenous to nomi­
nal GNP; the hypothesis that money is exogenous to
GNP cannot be rejected at the 5 percent significance
level. In contrast, the notion that GNP is exogenous
to money is not supported by the results of the Sims
test; the calculated F-statistics are below the 5 percent
level of significance. Thus, the Sims and Granger test
results agree: the new monetary aggregates are exo­
genous with respect to nominal GNP.19
19The tests used in this article are useful in detecting statistical
exogeneity, not empirical correlations between GNP and
the different monetary aggregates, per se. Because of the
relatively nondefinitive nature of the results in selecting a


18


Increased emphasis has been placed on the growth
of the monetary aggregates in the formulation and
implementation of monetary policy. In February
1980, the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System announced major redefinitions of existing
monetary aggregates. Crucial to selecting an appro­
priate monetary measure to be used in policymak­
ing is its exogeneity with respect to the goal vari­
able. This article has empirically investigated the
relationship between the new monetary aggregates
and nominal GNP by using the exogeneity tests pro­
posed by Granger and Sims. Based on quarterly
observations for the period III/1961-II/1980, the re­
sults reported here indicate that each of the new
monetary aggregates is statistically exogenous to
GNP. This supports the belief that control of the
money stock is important in influencing movements
in GNP.
Although the evidence in this article does not per­
mit the selection of one of the new monetary aggre­
gates as the “best” indicator of monetary actions, it
does form a foundation upon which a selection can be
made. In this regard, further study into the issues of
controllability and predictability of monetary aggre­
gates is warranted.
“best” indicator, it was felt that a useful exercise would be
to briefly examine the issue of predictability. This was done
by regressing the compounded annual rate of growth of
GNP ( Y ) on the compounded annual growth rates of money
( M ) in its different definitions and high-employment govern­
ment expenditures ( E ) . The form of the regression equa­
tion is

*

K

•

Y t = c + Z mi M t i + 2 ei E i-i + £t,
1=0

1=0

where the lag lengths f and g are each equal to four and
£ t is a random error term. Following Carlson and Hein, this
relationship is estimated using ordinary least squares. The
sample period was III/1 9 6 1 -II/1 9 8 0 .
Comparing the adjusted R2s obtained by using the M IA,
M1B, M2, M3 and L monetary aggregates indicates that
M1B explains movements in the growth rates of GNP better
than the other aggregates. For comparison’s sake, the mone­
tary aggregates and their corresponding R2s are: M IA
( 0 .3 6 ) ; M IB ( 0 .3 9 ) ; M 2 (0 .2 3 ); M 3 (0 .2 1 ); and L ( 0 .3 3 ) .
Given the results from the exogeneity tests, this evidence
further supports the choice of M1B as the most likely mone­
tary indicator from the aggregates examined.