View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE B A N K
O F ST. L O U IS
FEBRUARY 1978




C O N T E N T S

The Mechanics of Intervention in Exchange Markets
ANATOL B. BALBACH

O n January 4, 1978 the Treasury and the Federal
Reserve System, in conjunction with the Exchange
Stabilization Fund, announced that they would inter­
vene in foreign exchange markets to prevent a specu­
lative decline in the international value of the U.S.
dollar.1 This announcement has been happily received
by European and Japanese central banks and has
elicited lively discussion in the news media. The
stated purpose of intervention is to eliminate “specu­
lative” swings in the value of the dollar. But it is
also clear that if such speculation has indeed affected
the value of the dollar, it has been unidirectional
for the past nine months as the international value
of the dollar has been declining steadily and, at times,
precipitously. This has been particularly true with
respect to the Deutsche mark, Swiss franc, British
pound and Japanese yen. Thus intervention in this
article is viewed as the buying of dollars in foreign
exchange markets by U.S. and foreign governments
and central banks.
There have been many assertions with respect to
the issue of intervention. There are those who argue
that U.S. intervention will have contractionary effects
on the U.S. money stock and will not cause expan­
sionary pressures on the money stock of other coun­
tries. It is also argued that U.S. intervention will
produce a different impact on U.S. interest rates than
that produced by foreign intervention. The purpose
of this article is to consider the validity of these
propositions by examining the mechanics of interven­
tion in foreign exchange markets. The issue discussed
here is not whether intervention is desirable or
whether it is, or will be, successful. Nor is the purpose
to evaluate what ultimate impact it will have on
economic activity in the United States and abroad.

The Framework for Analysis
To isolate the impact of foreign exchange interven­
tion on U.S. and foreign money stocks and U.S. in­
terest rates, without getting involved in possible or
probable reactions by fiscal and monetary authorities,
four assumptions are made.
1Federal Reserve Press Release, January 4, 1978.


Page 2


1. T h e U .S. T reasu ry deficit is unaffected by for­
eign exchan ge intervention. Specifically, this implies
th at if foreigners buy m ore T reasu ry securities than
they did prior to intervention, few er G overnm ent
securities will be sold to the dom estic sector. I t is
also assumed th at T reasu ry deposits at F e d e ra l R e­
serve Banks will, on average, rem ain at th e same
level. If intervention increases these deposits, the
increase will be spent or sales of T reasu ry securities
in dom estic m arkets will decline.
2. M onetary authorities here and abroad do not
undertake m onetary actions to offset th e im p act of
intervention. Thus, if intervention causes dom estic
bank reserves to increase, perm itting com m ercial
banks to expand their loans and consequently the
m oney stock, cen tral banks will not start selling
securities in the open m arket to red u ce bank re ­
serves by an equivalent am ount.
3. Fo reig n cen tral banks im m ediately con vert their
dollar holdings (deposits at F ed eral R eserve Banks)
into U .S . T reasu ry securities.

4.

Gold reserves will not be used for intervention.

The first two assumptions are dictated by the scope
of this analysis. The purpose is to isolate the pressures
that result from intervention, not how governments
react to these pressures. The third assumption is
simply consistent with historical evidence — except
for gold, foreign central banks minimize their holdings
of noninterest-bearing assets. And the fourth as­
sumption arises from current practices as evidenced
by swaps of the type just arranged.
Accounting techniques can be used to demonstrate
the impact of intervention itself, without consideration
of further repercussions. To trace the financial flows
that result from intervention, the balance sheets of
the U.S. Treasury, Federal Reserve Banks, and a
representative Foreign Central Bank, along with the
consolidated balance sheets of U.S. commercial banks
and foreign commercial banks, are used.2 In practice,
intervention in foreign exchange markets can be
undertaken by three distinct institutions: foreign cen­
tral banks, the Federal Beserve System, and the Ex-This analysis could be extended to the balance sheets of the
public, but the results of intervention itself would be
identical.

F E D E R A L . R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

FEBRUARY

1978

E x h ib it I

Foreign Central Bank Intervention
U.S. Tre a sury (UST)

Federal Reserve
Banks (FRB)
res.

— 100

res.

— 100

Dep. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

(1 )

Dep. o f
UST a t
FRB + 1 0 0

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

(2 )

D ep. o f
Treas.
UST a t
sec.
<3 > FRB — 1 0 0 o f cb — 100

Dep. o f
fcb
— 100

Dep. o f
FCB — 100

D ep. o f
FCB a t
FRB
+100

res.

+100

res.

+100

D ep. o f
fc b in
US
— 100

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

Dep. o f
UST — 1 0 0

res.
+100
Treas.

res.

sec.
o f cb — 1 0 0

+100

Foreign C om m ercial
Banks (fc b )

Foreign C e n tra l
B ank (FCB)

Dep. o f
FCB a t
FRB — 1 0 0

Dep. o f
UST + 1 0 0

Treas.
see. o f
FCB + 1 0 0
(N e t)

U.S. C om m ercial
Banks (c b )

Dep. o f
Treas.
fc b
— 10 0
sec.
o f cb — 1 0 0

Treas.
sec.
o f cb — 100

change Stabilization Fund. This last institution can in­
tervene by using three types of assets: deposits at
Federal Reserve Banks, Treasury Securities, or Special
Drawing Rights ( SD R ) at the International Monetary
Fund. Thus there are five separate cases to analyze,
three of which are initiated by the Exchange Stabili­
zation Fund.

Intervention by Foreign Central Banks

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

res.

+100

res.

+100

Dep. o f
fcb in
US
— 100

be affected if the sellers of dollars were the U.S. or
foreign public. Thus intervention in the foreign ex­
change market means that the Foreign Central Bank
buys dollar deposits of foreign commercial banks at
U.S. commercial banks and pays for them by crediting
foreign commercial bank reserves. The Foreign Cen­
tral Bank deposits its dollar proceeds at Federal Re­
serve Banks. When this dollar draft is cleared, U.S.
commercial banks lose reserves.

Foreign central banks can support the value of the
dollar (keep their own currency from appreciating)
by simply creating their own currency denominated
deposits and using them to buy dollars in the foreign
exchange market. Such action increases the demand
for dollars on the foreign exchange market and raises
the price of the dollar in terms of this foreign cur­
rency. This type of intervention was widely practiced
during 1977, as foreign central banks accumulated
upward of $30 billion in dollar denominated assets.

Transaction (2) shows the conversion of Foreign
Central Bank deposits at Federal Beserve Banks into
Treasury securities. It is assumed here that the For­
eign Central Bank buys these securities directly from
the Treasury. If it were to buy them in the open
market, the final impact on reserves and interest rates
would be identical.3 Thus the security holdings of the
Foreign Central Bank increase, its deposits at Federal
Reserve Banks decrease, and Treasury deposits at
Federal Reserve Banks increase.

For the sake of balance sheet brevity, the following
abbreviations will be used: U.S. Treasury (UST),
Federal Reserve Banks (F R B ), Foreign Central Bank
(F C B ), Exchange Stabilization Fund (E S F ), foreign
commercial banks (fcb), U.S. commercial banks (cb),
and commercial bank reserves (res).

Since we have assumed that the Treasury will not
increase the level of its deposits at Federal Reserve
Banks, in transaction (3) this increase in deposits is
used to buy Treasury securities from U.S. commercial
banks, or more likely, the Treasury will simply sell
fewer securities in domestic markets. The results of
such reduced sales are equivalent to transaction (3).

In Exhibit I, transaction (1) is the process of inter­
vention — the purchase of dollar deposits by the
Foreign Central Bank. We shall assume throughout all
following transactions that sellers of dollars are foreign
commercial banks. This assumption is made for the
sake of simplicity only, and final results would not



:iThe purchase of Treasury securities in the open market would
increase U.S. commercial bank reserves. An increase in the
demand for Treasury securities by the Foreign Central Bank
would produce effects on interest rates identical to transac­
tion ( 2 ) where the supply of securities was reduced.
Page 3

FEBRUARY

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

1978

In Exhibit II, transaction (1) depicts the acquisition
by the Federal Beserve System of foreign denomi­
nated deposits at the Foreign Central Bank. The
Foreign Central Bank credits the Federal Beserve
account and in return receives Treasury securities
which are paid for by the Federal Beserve System in
the form of a credit to the Treasury’s account at the
Federal Beserve. This transaction does not affect bank
reserves in either country. In transaction (2) the
Federal Beserve System buys dollar denominated
deposits of foreign commercial banks at U.S. commer­
cial banks and pays for them with its foreign currency
deposits at the Foreign Central Bank. When the Fed­
eral Beserve payment is cleared, foreign commercial
banks experience an increase in reserves. Meanwhile,
when the foreign commercial bank draft on dollar
deposits is cleared, U.S. commercial bank reserves
decline. In transaction (3) the Treasury disposes of its
increased balance at Federal Beserve Banks by buying
Treasury securities from U.S. commercial banks (as in
the previous case, this transaction is in lieu of a de­
crease in Treasury borrowings in private markets).
This raises U.S. commercial bank reserves.

When U.S. commercial banks clear the check from
the U.S. Treasury, their reserves rise.
The net effects of Foreign Central Bank intervention
are that the Treasury has financed some of its expendi­
tures through a sale of its securities to a Foreign
Central Bank, foreign commercial bank dollar holdings
have decreased, the U.S. commercial bank portfolio
of Treasury securities has decreased, and foreign com­
mercial banks have exchanged their dollar assets for
domestic reserves.
Since foreign commercial bank reserves have in­
creased, there is pressure to increase the rate of
growth of the foreign money stock. U.S. commercial
bank reserves have not changed, but since the Treas­
ury has sold some of its securities directly to a Foreign
Central Bank, it doesn’t have to sell them in the do­
mestic credit market. Interest rates on U.S. Govern­
ment securities can therefore be expected to be
lower than they would have been in the absence of
intervention.

Intervention by the Federal Reserve System

The net result of this type of intervention is identi­
cal to the one produced by Foreign Central Bank
intervention: foreign commercial bank reserves ex­
pand, U.S. commercial bank reserves do not change,
and there is downward pressure on the interest rates
of U.S. Treasury securities.

Since intervention to prevent the dollar from de­
clining requires foreign currencies with which to buy
dollars, the swap network must be activated. Swap
arrangements permit the U.S. Treasury or the Federal
Beserve to borrow foreign currencies while (in effect)
giving dollar denominated deposits at the Federal
Beserve Banks as collateral. In practice, these deposits
are usually converted into Treasury Securities, pri­
marily of the nonnegotiable type. The acquired foreign
currencies are then used to buy dollars in the foreign
exchange market.

Intervention by the Exchange Stabilization
Fund
The Exchange Stabilization Fund was created in
1934 specifically for the purpose of intervening in

E x h ib it II

Federal Reserve Intervention
U.S. Tre a sury (UST)
(1 )

D ep. o f
UST at
FRB + 1 0 0

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

Dep. o f
FRB a t
FCB + 1 0 0

Treas.
D ep. o f
UST a t
sec.
FRB — 100 o f cb — 100

U.S. C om m ercial
Banks (c b )

— 100

Treas.
sec.
o f cb — 1 0 0


Page 4


— 100

D ep. o f

res.

UST

— 100

tre a s .

res.

+100

sec.
o f cb — 1 0 0

Dep. o f
fc b
— 100

■" i

l

l

Dep. o f
FRB a t
FCB + 1 0 0
D ep. o f

res.

FRB a t
FCB — 1 0 0

D ep. o f
fc b in

+100

res.

+100

US

— 100

res.

+100

res.

+100

+100

D ep. o f
Treas.
fc b
— 100
sec.
o f cb — 100

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0
(N e t)

res.

F oreign C om m ercial
Banks ( fc b )

Foreign C e n tra l
B ank (FCB)
Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

D ep. o f
UST + 1 0 0

D ep. o f
res.
FRB a t
FCB — 1 0 0

(2 )

(3 )

Federal Reserve
Banks (FRB)

"

: ■

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

Dep. o f
fc b in
US
— 100

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

FEBRUARY

1978

E x h ib it IN

Exchange S tab ilizatio n
Federal Reserve
Banks (FRB)

U.S. Tre a sury (UST)
SDR
cert.

(1)

+ 1 00

U.S. C om m ercial
Banks (c b )

Foreign C e n tra l
B ank (FCB)

Foreign C om m ercial
Banks (fc b )

Dep. o f
ESF a t
FRB + 1 0 0
Dep. o f
ESF a t
FRB — 100

(2 )

Dep. o f
FCB at
FRB + 1 0 0

Dep. o f
ESF a t
FCB + 1 0 0

Dep. o f
FCB a t
FRB + 1 0 0
res.

— 100

res.

— 100

Dep. o f
ESF a t
FRB + 1 0 0

(3 )

Dep. o f
UST a t
FRB + 1 0 0

Treas.
sec. o f
ESF + 1 0 0

Dep. o f
fc b in
US
— 1 00

Dep. o f
ESF a t
FCB — 1 0 0

res.

+100

res.

+100

Dep. o f
fc b in
US
— 100

res.

+ 1 00

res.

D ep. o f
ESF a t
FRB — 100

(4 )

D ep. o f
UST a t
FRB + 1 0 0
D ep. o f
UST a t
FRB + 1 0 0

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

(5 )

Dep. o f
UST at
FRB — 2 0 0

Treas.
sec. o f
cb
— 200
Treas.
sec. o f
ESF + 1 0 0

(N e t)

Fund Intervention by Using FRB Deposits

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

Dep. o f
FCB a t
FRB — 1 0 0

Dep. o f
FCB a t
FRB — 1 0 0

Dep. o f
UST a t
FRB + 1 0 0

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

res.

+200

Dep. o f
UST a t
FRB — 2 0 0
SDR
cert.

res.
+100

+100

Treas.
sec- o f
cb
— 200
res.
+200
res.

+100

Treas.
sec. o f
cb
— 200

Dep. o f
fc b in
US
— 100

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

+100

D ep. o f
fc b in
US
— 100

Treas.
sec. o f
cb
— 200

exchange markets during the fixed exchange rate
regime. While the Fund is owned by the U.S. Treas­
ury, it is a separate entity with its own financial re­
sources and with its own account at Federal Reserve
Banks. The bulk of its assets consists of Special Draw­
ing Rights and nonnegotiable Treasury securities. The
impact of its intervention depends upon the type of
assets that it uses. If it uses Treasury securities or its
deposits at Federal Reserve Banks, then it must ac­
quire foreign currencies in a manner similar to the
Federal Reserve. If it uses SDR, which are accepted
by central banks, it can sell them outright to the For­
eign Central Bank for foreign currency denominated
deposits. Consequently, Exchange Stabilization Fund
intervention will be discussed in three parts: using
deposits at Federal Reserve Banks, using Treasury
securities, and using SDR. In these transactions one
additional assumption must be made: the Exchange
Stabilization Fund also minimizes its noninterest bear­
ing assets and holds minimal balances at the FRB.



Using FRB D eposits — Since the Exchange Stabili­
zation Fund has minimal deposits at the FRB, it can
acquire them by selling SDR certificates to the Fed­
eral Reserve and receiving deposits in return (Exhibit
III, transaction (1 )). In transaction (2) the Exchange
Stabilization Fund writes a check on its account at the
Federal Reserve Bank and acquires foreign currency
denominated deposits at the Foreign Central Bank. It
then uses tliis account (transaction (3 )) to buy dollar
denominated deposits of foreign commercial banks at
U.S. banks and deposits these proceeds at Federal
Reserve Banks. This transaction increases foreign
commercial bank reserves and reduces the reserves of
U.S. commercial banks. Since the Exchange Stabiliza­
tion Fund now has an increase in its balances at the
Federal Reserve, it will use these balances to buy
securities from the Treasury (transaction ( 4 ) ) . In
transaction (2) the Foreign Central Bank accumu­
lated additional deposits at Federal Reserve Banks
and uses these deposits to buy securities from the
Page 5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

FEBRUARY

Treasury (transaction (5 )). Transactions (4) and (5)
increase Treasury deposits at Federal Reserve Banks,
and the Treasury uses these deposits to buy Treasury
securities from U.S. commercial banks (this transac­
tion is again in lieu of selling fewer securities in the
future).
The net effect of this intervention is an increase in
foreign commercial bank reserves and an increase in
the reserves of U.S. commercial banks. Since the de­
mand for Treasury securities (by the Exchange Sta­
bilization Fund) increases and the supply decreases,
these transactions produce a downward pressure on
Treasury security yields.
Using Treasury Securities — This set of transactions
assumes that the Exchange Stabilization Fund sells its
Treasury securities directly to the Foreign Central
Bank. If the Fund were to sell these securities in the
open market or to the Federal Reserve System, and if
Foreign Central Banks were subsequently to buy
these securities, the results would be the same.
In transaction (1) of Exhibit IV, the Exchange
Stabilization Fund sells its Treasury securities to the
Foreign Central Bank and acquires a foreign deposit.
In transaction (2) it uses its foreign currency denomi­
nated deposit to buy dollars from foreign commercial
banks and deposits these dollars at its account at the
Federal Reserve Bank, which causes reserves of U.S.
commercial banks to contract. Intervention-induced
transactions could stop here, and the net effect would
be an increase in foreign commercial bank reserves

1978

and a decrease in reserves of U.S. commercial banks.
There would be no effect on Treasury security yields
since no securities were traded in the market.
However, the asset mix of the Exchange Stabiliza­
tion Fund has changed; they have less Treasury secu­
rities and higher deposits at Federal Reserve Banks.
If the Fund desires to maintain the same asset mix
and the same income as prior to intervention, it would
activate transaction (3) in which it would buy Treas­
ury securities in the market thereby increasing U.S.
commercial bank reserves.4 Under these circumstances
the net effect of intervention would again be an in­
crease in foreign commercial bank reserves, no change
in U.S. commercial bank reserves, and downward
pressure on Treasury security yields.
Using SDR — In transaction (1 ) of Exhibit V, the
Exchange Stabilization Fund sells SDR to the Foreign
Central Bank and receives a foreign currency denomi­
nated deposit. In transaction (2) it spends this deposit
to buy dollar deposits from a foreign commercial bank
and transfers these deposits to Federal Reserve Banks.
Again, since the Exchange Stabilization Fund keeps
its dollar assets mainly in the form of Treasury securi­
ties, it will buy such securities (transaction (3 )) and
4If the Exchange Stabilization Fund were to buy securities
directly from the U.S. Treasury, it would have increased
Treasury balances at Federal Reserve Banks. This would
have caused the Treasury to buy its securities in the market
or reduce its sales of new securities. These transactions would
have produced changes in commercial bank reserves and in­
terest rates identical to transaction ( 3 ) .

E x h ib it IV

Exchange S tab ilizatio n Fund Intervention Using Treasury Securities
U.S. Tre a sury (UST)

Federal Reserve
Banks ( FRB)

U.S. C om m ercial
Banks (c b )

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0
(1 )

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

— 100

res.

— 100

D ep. o f
ESF a t
FRB + 1 0 0

(2 )

Treas.
sec.
o f cb — 100

D ep. o f
ESF a t
FRB — 1 0 0

Treas
sec.
o f c b — 100

Treas.
sec. o f
ESF + 1 0 0

res.

res.

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0
( N e t)

F oreign C om m ercial
Banks (fc b )

D ep. o f
ESF a t
FCB + 1 0 0

Treas.
sec. o f
ESF — 1 00
res.

(3 )

F o re ig n C e n tra l
B ank (FCB)

Treas.
sec.
o f cb — 1 0 0

Page 6



+100

Dep. o f
fc b in
US
— 100

D ep. o f

res.

ESF a t
FCB — 1 0 0

Dep. o f
fc b in

+100

res.

+100

US

— 100

res.

+100

res.

+100

+100

Treas.
sec.
o f cb — 100

D ep. o f
fc b in
US
— 100

Treas.
sec. o f
FCB + 1 0 0

Dep. o f
fc b in
in US — 1 0 0

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

FEBRUARY

1978

E x h ib it V

Exchange Stabilization
U .S. Trea su ry (UST)

Federal Reserve
Banks (FRB)

Fund Intervention by Using SDR
U.S. C om m ercial
Banks (c b )

F oreign C e n tra l
Bank (FCB)
SDR

+100

(1 )
res.
(2 )

Dep. o f
UST a t
FRB + 1 0 0

Treas.
sec. o f
ESF + 1 0 0

(3 )

(4 )

res.

— 100

Dep. o f
fc b in
US
— 100

Dep. o f
E SFat
FCB + 1 0 0
Dep. o f
ESF a t
FCB — 1 0 0

res.
+100
D ep . o f
, c b in

res.

+100

US

— 100

res.

+100

res.

+100

Dep. o f
ESFat
FRB — 100
Dep. o f
UST a t
FRB + 1 0 0

Treas.
Dep. o f
sec.
UST a t
FRB — 100 o f cb — 1 00

Dep. o f
UST a t
FRB — 1 0 0
res.

Treas.
sec. o f
ESF + 1 0 0
( N e t)

— 100

Dep. o f
ESF at
FRB + 1 0 0

F oreign C om m ercial
Banks (fc b )

+100

res.
+100
Treas.
sec.
o f cb — 1 0 0
Treas.
Dep. o f
fc b in
sec.
o f cb — 100 US
— 100

Treas.
sec.
o f cb — 100

the U.S. Treasury will use these additional deposits to
buy securities from U.S. commercial banks (transac­
tion (4 )). The net result of this type of intervention
produces an increase in foreign commercial bank re­
serves and no change in U.S. commercial bank re­
serves. Furthermore, it lowers yields on Treasury
securities.

Summary and Conclusions
The techniques described above exhaust the most
frequently used methods of buying dollars in foreign
exchange markets. Except for the case in which the
Exchange Stabilization Fund is willing to issue addi­
tional SDR certificates, there are several results of
intervention which are common to all the remaining
methods:
1. In the absence of domestic fiscal and monetary
policy actions to offset the impact of intervention, all
intervention to support the dollar will lead to an
expansion in foreign commercial bank reserves, pres­
sure to expand the money stock and presumably
upward pressure on the rate of inflation in affected
countries.
2. Under the same conditions the reserves of U.S.
commercial banks will not be affected and will not




SDR

+100

D ep. o f
fcb in
US
— 100

produce expansionary or contractive effects on the
U.S. economy through monetary channels.
3. In all of these cases, and assuming no change in
Treasury expenditures and receipts, there would be
a decline in Treasury securities sold in the domestic
market or an increase in the demand for such securi­
ties. This would exert downward pressure on U.S.
Treasury security yields.
4. From the standpoint of economic repercussions
caused purely by the acts of intervention, there is
absolutely no difference in whether the intervention
is undertaken by foreign central banks or by U.S.
authorities.
5. In general, intervention in foreign exchange
markets to support the value of the U.S. dollar is
possible only through the cooperation of foreign
central banks and their willingness to accept upward
pressures on their commercial bank reserves. At the
same time, as long as foreign central banks keep
their dollar holdings in the form of U.S. Treasury
securities, intervention will produce no impact on
U.S. commercial bank reserves.
The exception is the case where the Exchange
Stabilization Fund issues SDR certificates to the Fed­
eral Reserve and uses acquired deposits to intervene
in foreign exchange markets. This method produces
an increase in both foreign and U.S. commercial bank
reserves.

Page 7

A Tax-Based Incomes Policy (T IP ):
What’s It All About?
NANCY AMMON JIANAKOPLOS

S u b j e c t corporations to higher corporate in­
come tax rates if they give pay raises which are too
large. This is the essence of a plan devised by Gov­
ernor Henry C. Wallich of the Federal Reserve Board
and Sidney Weintraub of the University of Pennsyl­
vania.1 Their proposal to use the tax system to curb
inflation is called “TIP,” an acronym for tax-based in­
comes policy. As inflation continues to plague the
economy, many economists feel that the traditional
tools of monetary and fiscal policy are inadequate to
handle the situation and have recommended direct
measures to stop wage and price increases.2 The Wallich-Weintraub plan has received considerable atten­
tion as a policy measure which might be capable of
dealing with the problem of inflation.3
Before adopting a program such as TIP, it is im­
portant to understand clearly how the proposal would
operate and, more importantly, whether it would
achieve the desired results. The first part of this
article describes the functioning of TIP and the
rationale for such a program as envisioned by Wallich
'W allich and Weintraub first collaborated on this idea in
Henry C. Wallich and Sidney Weintraub, “A Tax-Based In­
comes Policy,” Journal of Economic Issues (June 1 9 7 1 ), pp.
1-19.
2See, for example, “Another Weapon Against Inflation: Tax
Policy,” Business W eek, October 3, 1977, pp. 94-96; “Debate:
How to Stop Inflation,” Fortune (April 1 9 7 7 ), pp. 116-20;
Lindley H. Clark, Jr., “Uneasy Seers: More Analysts Predict
New Inflation Spiral or Recession in 1978,” Wall Street
Journal, December 2, 1977.
3See, for example, U. S. Congress, Congressional Budget Office,
Recovery With Inflation, July 1977, p. 40; U. S. Congress,
Joint Economic Committee, T he 1977 Midyear Review of the
Economy, 95th Cong., 1st sess., September 26, 1977, p. 76;
“Well-Cut Taxes Should Be Tailored,” New York Times, De­
cember 21, 1977.


Page 8


and Weintraub. The rest of the article is devoted to
an assessment of whether TIP would accomplish its
stated objectives.

HOW WOULD TIP OPERATE?
According to the plan presented by Wallich and
Weintraub, TIP would be centered on a single wage
guidepost established by the Government.4 The ac­
ceptable percentage wage increase could be set some­
where between the average increase in productivity
throughout the economy (asserted to be around 3 per­
cent) and some larger figure which incorporates all or
part of the current rate of inflation. The ultimate aim
of the guidepost is to bring wage increases in line
with nationwide productivity increases.
The TIP guidepost is directed at wages only, al­
though the tax is levied on corporate profits. The
basic assumption behind TIP is that monetary and
fiscal policies have been ineffective because they have
not been able to prevent labor from obtaining wage
increases in excess of productivity gains, even when
there is significant unemployment in the economy.
Furthermore, Wallich and Weintraub contend that
empirical evidence supports the view that price in4Unless otherwise noted, all descriptions of TIP in this article
are based on Wallich and Weintraub, “A Tax-Based Incomes
Policy”; Henry C. Wallich, “Alternative Strategies for Price
and W age Controls,” Journal of Economic Issues (December
1 9 7 2 ), pp. 89-104; Henry C. Wallich, “A Plan for Dealing
W ith Inflation in the U.S.,” Washington Post, August 21,
1977; Sidney Weintraub, “An Incomes Policy to Stop Infla­
tion,” Lloyds Bank Review (January 1 9 7 1 ), pp. 1-12; and
Sidney Weintraub, “Incomes Policy: Completing the Stabili­
zation Triangle,” Journal of Economic Issues (December
1 9 7 2 ), pp. 105-22.

F E D E R A L . R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

creases have been a constant markup over unit wage
increases. Therefore, if wage increases can be kept
down, price increases will also be held down.
The corporate income tax system would be em­
ployed to enforce the TIP guidepost. Corporations
which grant wage increases in excess of the guidepost
would be subject to higher corporate income tax rates
based on the amount that wage increases exceed
the guidepost.
In order to understand how TIP would operate,
consider the following example. Suppose the guidepost for wage increases is set at, say, 5 percent for a
particular year. In the base year, Corporation A had
a total wage bill of $100,000 and in the following year
granted increases which brought its total wage bill to
$108,000 — an 8 percent increase. Assuming no change
in either the number or composition of the employees,
this 8 percent increase is 3 percentage points above
the guidepost. This excess would then be multiplied
by a penalty number. If, for instance, the penalty was
set at 2, the corporate tax rate of Corporation A
would be increased by 6 percentage points ( 3 per­
centage point excess times penalty number of 2).
Thus, instead of paying 48 percent of its profits in
taxes, the existing corporate tax rate, Corporation A
would have to pay 54 percent of its profits, as a pen­
alty for acceding to “excessive” wage demands.
Wallich and Weintraub argue that because of com­
petitive forces this additional tax could not be shifted
forward to prices.5 They, therefore, believe that such
a tax penalty would cause corporations to deal more
firmly with labor. In their view the penalty would
ultimately restrain the rate of wage increases and,
hence, reduce the rate of inflation.6 Since wage in­
creases would be curbed, corporations would not
have higher costs to pass through in the form of price
increases, thereby eliminating a major “cost-push” ele­
ment of inflation. Furthermore, since the increases in
incomes of workers would more closely approximate
increases in productivity, there would be smaller in­
5See Richard A. Musgrave and Peggy B. Musgrave, Public
Finance In Theory and Practice (N ew York: McGraw-Hill
Book Company, 1 9 7 3 ), Chapter 18, pp. 415-29, who con­
tend that empirical evidence is inconclusive in determining
whether the corporate income tax is shifted.
6Studies by Yehuda Kotowitz and Bichard Portes, “The ‘Tax
on W age Increases’ : A Theoretical Analysis,” Journal of
Public Economics (M ay 1 9 7 4 ), pp. 113-32, and Peter Isard,
“The Effectiveness of Using the Tax System to Curb Infla­
tionary Collective Bargains: An Analysis of the WallichWeintraub Plan,” Journal of Political Economy (M ay-June
1 9 7 3 ), pp. 729-40, analyze the effect of TIP on an individ­
ual firm and conclude that theoretically TIP should lead to
lower wage settlements for an individual firm.




FEBRUARY

1978

creases in spending, reducing the “demand-pull” as­
pect of inflation.
Wallich and Weintraub acknowledge certain diffi­
culties in computing the corporation’s wage bill. One
method which they believe would overcome many of
these difficulties would be to construct arr index of
wages, rather than using the gross dollar figure. Using
this method, wages, fringe benefits, and other related
payments would be computed for each job classifica­
tion and skill level and divided by the hours worked
at each level. These wage figures would then be com­
bined into an index weighted by the proportion of
each of these classifications in the entire corporation.
Changes in this index would then be compared to the
guidepost in order to assess whether the corporation
would be penalized.
Administrative problems are not neglected by W al­
lich and Weintraub. They recognize that the tax laws
must be specific and “airtight” in order to avoid loop­
holes. However, it is argued that TIP would not in­
volve establishing a new bureaucracy. Most of the
data necessary to administer TIP are already collected
for corporate income tax and employee payroll tax
purposes.
One of the principal merits of TIP, in the view of
Wallich and Weintraub, is that it would not interfere
with the functioning of the market system. They argue
that there would be no direct controls or distortions
to the pricing mechanism. Firms would still be free to
grant large wage demands, but would face the pen­
alty of a higher corporate tax rate.
Rather than a short-term plan to curb inflation, TIP
is envisioned to be a long-term means of reducing
the rate of price increase. However, TIP is not in­
tended to function by itself. Both Wallich and Wein­
traub see it as a supplement to “appropriate” mone­
tary and fiscal policies. In addition, if labor contends
that TIP would hold down wages while allowing
profits to increase, Wallich proposes the implementa­
tion of an excess profits tax. This could be accom­
plished by increasing the basic corporate tax rate to
keep the share of profits in national income constant.7

WOULD TIP WORK?
The TIP proposal has two principal objectives:
(1 )

to curb inflation, and

7Other adjuncts proposed for TIP include a payroll tax credit
designed to entice workers to accept lower wages. See Law ­
rence S. Seidman, “A Payroll Tax-Credit to Bestrain Inflation,”
National Tax Journal (Decem ber 1 9 7 6 ), pp. 398-412.
Page 9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

(2 )

to avoid interfering with the functioning of the
m arket.

Given these aims of TIP, one can analyze whether
TIP will, in fact, be able to accomplish its goals. Other
issues raised by TIP, such as the costs of implementa­
tion and the ability of firms to avoid the tax penalty
of TIP, will not be discussed here.8

Would TIP Curb Inflation?
TIP is based on the assumption that most of the
inflation in the economy is of a “cost-push” nature.
Inflation occurs, according to this framework, because
labor is able to attain wage increases in excess of
increases in productivity. Business is not capable of
resisting, or finds it does not pay to resist, labor’s
demands. Faced with higher costs, businesses pass
these costs through in the form of higher product
prices. As prices rise, further wage increases are
granted, forming the basis of a wage-price spiral.
TIP is proposed as a measure which will intervene
in this process and bring inflation to a halt.
As the Congressional Budget Office stated in a re­
cent study, the assumption that inflation is the result
of “cost-push” is “a conjectural notion at best.”9 A
major challenge to the concept of “cost-push” rests
on empirical evidence supporting an alternative the­
ory of the cause of inflation. According to this other
view, ongoing increases in the general price level
(inflation) are primarily the result of excessive in­
c re a s e s in th e r a t e of m o n e ta r y e x p a n s io n .10 L a g s
exist between the time when the money stock is in­
creased and when prices rise. In this framework, the
observed relationship between the rate of wage in­
crease and the rate of price increase is explained as
part of the adjustment process through which prices
increase in response to increases in the money stock.
This view does not deny the “cost-push” phenomenon,
8Fo r a discussion of implementation problems, see Gardner
Ackley, “Okun’s New Tax-Based Incomes-Policy Proposal,”
Survey Research Center, Institute for Social Research, The
University of Michigan, Economic Outlook USA (W inter
1 9 7 8 ), pp. 8-9. Although Ackley deals with the anti-inflation
proposal put forward by Arthur Okun, he notes that the
critique also applies to the Wallich-Weintraub proposal.
Congressional Budget Office, “Recovery W ith Inflation,” p. 41.
10Empirical support of this view for the period 1955 to 1971
is presented by Leonall C. Andersen and Denis S. Karnosky,
“The Appropriate Time Fram e for Controlling Monetary Ag­
gregates: The St. Louis Evidence,” Controlling Monetary
Aggregates II: The Implementation, Federal Reserve Bank of
Boston, Conference Series No. 9, September 1972, pp. 14777. Additional evidence for the period 1971 to 1976 is found
in Denis S. Karnosky, “The Link Between Money and Prices
— 1971-76,” this Review (June 1 9 7 6 ), pp. 17-23.


Page 10


FEBRUARY

1978

but contends that it is consistent with the view that
inflation is ultimately caused by money growth.11
When the stock of money is increased faster than
the rate of increase in production, people find them­
selves with larger cash balances than they desire to
hold. In order to bring their cash balances down to
desired levels, they will spend the money, thereby
bidding up prices on goods and services, and the
general price level will rise. As long as the stock of
money increases faster than the demand for money,
inflation will persist, even if TIP manages to hold
down wages temporarily.
Conversely, just as inflation is caused by excessive
growth of the money stock, the only way to stop
inflation is to reduce the growth of the money stock.
As the rate of monetary expansion is reduced, people
will have cash balances below their desired levels.
They will reduce their rate of spending in order to
build up these balances. As spending (demand) falls,
the rate of inflation will decrease. Prices are “sticky,”
and just as it took several years to build up the cur­
rent rate of inflation, it will take several years for
inflation to wind down. One of the by-products of
reducing inflation is a temporary idling of resources,
since prices do not tend to be flexible in the short
run. This is a cost of reducing inflation which must
be borne, just as there are costs imposed on society
as inflation mounts.
The idea that there are certain “key” wages in
society, such as union wages, to which other wages
and prices adjust, confuses the motivation for increas­
ing the money stock with the cause of inflation.12 If
certain unions are able to attain large wage increases,
even in the face of falling demand, the prices of the
products produced by this labor will increase. As
prices increase, less of this product will be demanded
and the use of the resources (labor and capital) which
produce this product will be decreased. Unemploy­
ment will rise as resources are freed to work in the
production of other products whose prices are lower.
The relative prices of products will change, but the
average price level will be unchanged.
11See Leonall C. Andersen and Denis S. Karnosky, “A Mone­
tary Interpretation of Inflation” in Joel Popkin, ed., Analysis
of Inflation: 1965-1974, Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol.
42, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. ( Cam­
bridge, Massachusetts: Ballinger Publishing Company, 1977),
pp. 11-26.
12This argument draws on Armen A. Alchian and William R.
Allen, University Economics: Elements of Inquiry (Belmont,
California: Wadsworth Publishing Company, Inc., 19 7 2 ),
pp. 684-85.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

However, if the Federal Reserve policymakers keep
a close watch on these “key” industries and see an in­
crease in idle resources (unemployment) in these
industries, they may take actions to alleviate the un­
employment by increasing the money stock. The in­
creases in spending resulting from monetary expan­
sion will bid up average prices and return relative
prices to a position similar to that prior to the grant­
ing of the wage demands. It was as a consequence of
the excessive wage demands that policy actions were
m otivated, but it was monetary expansion which
caused the subsequent inflation.
Some proponents of TIP base their support on the
belief that TIP will reduce expectations of inflation.
Lower expectations of inflation in the future, accord­
ing to this view, will lead to lower demands for wage
increases and eventually lower prices. However, ex­
pectations of inflation do not cause inflation.13 It is
ongoing inflationary forces in the economy, excessive
rates of monetary expansion, which lead to expecta­
tions of future inflation. Curbing inflationary expecta­
tions requires curbing the underlying forces which
cause them.
Wallich and Weintraub agree that TIP is a supple­
ment to, not a substitute for, “appropriate” monetary
and fiscal policy. However, the character of their
“appropriate” monetary policy is questionable. In the
basic article which outlined TIP, Wallich and Wein­
traub stated, “. . . the proposal is conceived as a sup­
plement to the familiar monetary-fiscal policies so that
the economy might operate closer to full employment
without the inflationary danger of excess demand and
‘overheating.’ ”14 Indeed, in a later article Weintraub
is more specific: “Given a suitable incomes policy to
align wages (and salaries) to productivity, monetary
policy would be released to make its contribution to
full employment. . . Full employment requires ample
money supplies for its sustenance.”15 Thus, it appears
that “appropriate” monetary policy, in the view of
Wallich and Weintraub, is expansionary; however, a
restrictive monetary policy is necessary to curb
inflation.
This disparity in determining the appropriate char­
acter of monetary policy points out another problem
with TIP. Given the lag time involved in the func­
13Weintraub supports this contention in Weintraub, “Incomes
Policy: Completing the Stabilization Triangle,” p. 116.
14Wallich and Weintraub, “A Tax-Based Incomes Policy,” p. 1.
15Weintraub, “Incomes Policy: Completing the Stabilization
Triangle,” p. 110.




FEBRUARY

1978

tioning of monetary policy, it might appear in the
short run that TIP is, at least temporarily, holding
down prices. If, at the same time, the Federal Reserve
increases the rate of monetary expansion, inflationary
pressures will actually be augmented. An incomes
policy, such as TIP, gives policymakers the illusion of
taking corrective measures against inflation when, in
fact, reducing the rate of monetary expansion is the
only way to accomplish that goal. In summary, it
appears that TIP would not be effective in reducing
inflation and could make matters worse by fostering
inappropriate monetary policy.

Would TIP Interfere With the Market?
Wallich and Weintraub argue that TIP would not
interfere with market pricing because no ceilings are
placed on any wages or prices. TIP operates through
the tax system, yet it is based on a single guidepost
for every firm and industry. They contend that a
single guidepost is appropriate because in competi­
tion all comparable workers would earn the same
wage. TIP, therefore, is only imposing what competi­
tion would achieve.
The problem with this argument is that it is only
true if all industries are in equilibrium and remain
there. In a growing, changing economy, equilib­
rium prices and wage rates are changing. Prices and
wages are constantly moving toward new equilibria;
hence, there is no reason to believe that each sector
in the economy would be at equilibrium when TIP
was imposed or would remain there afterward. In the
U. S. economy, demands and tastes of consumers are
constandy shifting and the technology and products
offered by business are also changing. As a conse­
quence, the equilibrium prices of some goods are ris­
ing (houses, for example) while others are fall­
ing (electronic calculators). In addition, some firms
are growing, making large profits, and seeking addi­
tional labor, while others are declining, earning very
little profit, and contracting their labor forces.
Imposing a single wage guidepost would distort the
price system. It does not matter whether the guidepost
is imposed through the tax system or by direct fines
and penalties. Those firms which are growing or are
adapting to changing consumer tastes have an incen­
tive to hire scarce resources (capital and labor) away
from other firms, but they would be penalized either
through a lower rate of return, if they grant “excess”
wage demands, or by a barrier to growth if they
adhere to the guidepost. Consequently, in some in­
stances labor would not be compensated in accord
Page 11

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

with the demand for its services. In other cases, firms
would not be able to attract all the labor they de­
sired. Relative prices would, therefore, be distorted
by the establishment of a single guidepost for all
firms and industries.
The TIP proposal would lead to a misallocation of
resources. Prices, when allowed to operate freely, offer
signals of where demand is increasing and where de­
mand is falling. Resources move to those industries
or firms where they will receive the highest compen­
sation. The TIP proposal would obscure these price
signals and, hence, resources would not move to
where they would be used most efficiently. The econ­
omy would suffer since production would be lower
than it would be otherwise.
The distortions in the economy caused by TIP
could have a very long lasting effect. Capital (plant
and equipment) is allocated by the market to those
firms which have the highest rate of return. The TIP
proposal would reduce the rates of return of those
firms which are growing, and capital would not be
adequately allocated to them. Capital generally tends
to have a relatively long life. Once it is misallocated,
as a result of TIP, it would not be easy to reallocate
it to a more efficient use. Thus, TIP could have serious
long-term consequences, as a result of the distortions
it would cause in the price system.


Page 12


FEBRUARY

1978

CONCLUSION
TIP is an incomes policy designed to reduce infla­
tion without interfering with the market system. The
essence of the proposal is to subject corporations to
higher corporate income tax rates if they granted pay
increases in excess of a single Government-mandated
guidepost.
TIP would not be successful in reducing the rate of
inflation because it is based on the premise that infla­
tion is largely a “cost-push” phenomenon — higher
wages leading to higher prices, which lead to still
higher wages. Inflation, however, is caused primarily
by excessive growth of the money stock. The TIP
proposal, therefore, deals only with the symptoms of
inflation, rather than attacking inflation at its root.
TIP would distort the market pricing system be­
cause the imposition of a single wage guidepost
would not allow relative prices to adjust fully to
change. This would lead to inefliciencies and a lower
level of production than would be otherwise
attainable.
Inflation is a serious problem, and there are no magic
solutions. There may be a temporary reduction in the
apparent rate of inflation with TIP, but eventually
leaks will develop in the system and prices will rise
anyway. The only way to stop inflation is to reduce
the rate of monetary expansion.

Does the St. Louis Equation Now
Believe in Fiscal Policy?
KEITH M. CARLSON

HE “St. Louis equation” was developed in 1968
in an article in this Review by Leonall Andersen and
Jerry Jordan.1 The St. Louis equation is an estimated
relationship (using the Almon procedure) between
changes in total spending ( G N P ) and changes in the
money supply and high-employment Federal expen­
ditures. The focus of the Andersen-Jordan article was
on the relative impact of monetary and fiscal actions.
They rejected the propositions that the response of
economic activity to fiscal actions relative to mone­
tary actions was (1) larger, (2) more predictable, and
(3) faster. In fact, their results suggested that the
overall effect of fiscal actions was relatively small and
not statistically significant. It was this result that gen­
erated considerable controversy among members of
the economics profession.2 The conventional wisdom
of the time was that fiscal actions (whether in the
form of a maintained increase in expenditures or a
tax cut) did have an impact on economic activity,
'Leonall C. Andersen and Jerry L. Jordan, “Monetary and
Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their Relative Importance in
Economic Stabilization,” this Review (November 1 9 6 8 ),
pp. 11-24.
2No attempt is made here to give a complete bibliography on
the St. Louis equation. Among the earlier articles, see Frank
de Leeuw and John Kalchbrenner, “Monetary and Fiscal Ac­
tions: A Test of Their Relative Importance in Economic
Stabilization — Comment,” this Review (April 1 9 6 9 ), pp.
6-11; Richard G. Davis, “How Much Does Money Matter? A
Look at Some Recent Evidence,” Federal Reserve Bank of
New York Monthly Review (June 1 9 6 9 ), pp. 119-31; E . Ger­
ald Corrigan, “The Measurement and Importance of Fiscal
Policy Changes,” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Monthly
Review (June 1 9 7 0 ), pp. 133-45; and Edward M. Gramlich,
“The Usefulness of Monetary and Fiscal Policy as Discretion­
ary Stabilization Tools,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Bank­
ing (M ay 1 9 7 1 ), pp. 506-32.




with a multiplier usually estimated at about 1.5 or
greater.3
In a recent article, Benjamin Friedman published
updated estimates of the St. Louis equation.4 Accord­
ing to Friedman, the St. Louis equation now “be­
lieves in” fiscal policy. He presented results showing
that the St. Louis equation yields a significant gov­
ernment spending multiplier of about 1.5 when esti­
mated with data through second quarter 1976. This
result conforms with neo-Keynesian thinking. At the
same time, Friedman duly noted that with these up­
dated estimates the relatively strong impact of mone­
tary actions continues to hold.
The Friedman results are indeed interesting, and
deserve closer examination. Those who accept the
3See, for example, Frank de Leeuw and Edward M. Gramlich,
“The Federal Reserve-MIT Econometric Model,” Federal R e­
serve Bulletin (January 1 9 6 8 ), pp. 11-40; James S. Duesenberry, Gary Fromm, Lawrence R. Klein, and Edwin Kuh,
eds., The Brookings Quarterly Econometric Model of the
United States (Chicago: Rand McNally, 1 9 6 5 ); Michael K.
Evans and Lawrence R. Klein, The Wharton Econometric
Forecasting Model, 2nd Enlarged Edition (Philadelphia: Uni­
versity of Pennsylvania, 1 9 6 8 ); Maurice Liebenberg, Albert
A. Hirsch, and Joel Popkin, “A Quarterly Econometric Model
of the United States: A Progress Report,” Survey of Current
Business (M ay 1 9 6 6 ), pp. 425-56; and Daniel M. Suits, The
Economic Outlook for 1969, Papers Presented to the Six­
teenth Annual Conference on the Economic Outlook at the
University of Michigan (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan,
1 9 6 9 ), pp. 1-26.
4Benjamin M. Friedman, “Even the St. Louis Model Now
Believes in Fiscal Policy,” Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, (M ay 1 9 7 7 ), pp. 365-67. Also see William G. Dewald and Maurice N. Marchon, “A Modified Federal Reserve
of St. Louis Spending Equation for Canada, France, Germany,
Italy, the United Kingdom, and the United States,” forth­
coming in Kredit und Kapital.
Page 13

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

original St. Louis evidence regarding the relative
strength of monetary and fiscal actions do not ques­
tion the importance of fiscal actions; such actions do
have economic impact over a certain period. How­
ever, the size of the steady-state multiplier is in
dispute. In particular, past estimates of the St. Louis
equation showed that there was a short-run impact
for fiscal actions, but this impact washed out over
time. If the fiscal action were accompanied by a
change in the rate of monetary expansion, there
would be an effect, but this would be attributable to
the monetary action.
To deal with Friedman’s results, the St. Louis equa­
tion is examined for the original sample period from
1953 through 1969, and then compared with updated
estimates through 1976. On the basis of this exami­
nation, it is found that in light of developments since
1969, the form in which the original St. Louis equa­
tion was specified is no longer statistically appropri­
ate. The St. Louis equation was originally estimated
in arithmetic first difference form (with a constant),
that is, all variables were defined as first differ­
ences in dollar amounts. Examination of the statisti­
cal properties of this specification indicates that at
least one of the assumptions of least squares estima­
tion appears to be violated when the experience from
1969 to 1976 is added to the data set. An alternative
specification estimated with data through 1976 is
offered which appears to satisfy the assumptions of
least squares estimation, and in the process the orig­
inal conclusions about the impact of fiscal actions are
found to hold.

UPDATING THE ORIGINAL
ST. LOUIS EQUATION
The original St. Louis equation, as published in
November 1968, was estimated with data from 1/1952
through 11/1968. A later version, published in April
1970, used 1/1953 through IV/1969 as the sample
period.5 This second version served as the fundamen­
tal relation in the “St. Louis model.” This model was
an extension of the original St. Louis equation — ex­
tended to include determination of prices, output,
unemployment, and interest rates.
There are several possible explanations of Fried­
man’s results, including the effect of data revisions.
Since the original presentation of the St. Louis equa­
tion, many data revisions have occurred. The net

FEBRUARY

effect of these data revisions on the estimated coeffi­
cients is summarized in Table I. An update of the
equation using revised data through 1976 is presented
in Table II as a prelude to an examination of the
factors contributing to the “appearance” of a signifi­
cant fiscal multiplier.

The Estimates
In Table I, consider first a comparison of the St.
Louis equation as published in April 1970 with a
recent version estimated over the same original sam­
ple period. All constraints and the number of lags
are maintained. At issue here is whether all the re­
visions of the National Income Accounts (NIA) and
the money supply have altered the conclusions re­
garding the relative impact of monetary and fiscal
actions drawn from the original St. Louis equation.
Table I

EFFECT OF DATA REVISIONS ON
ST. LOUIS EQUATION
Based on Data Available in
April 1970 and Feb. 1978
(Sample Period: 1/1953— IV/1969)
4

Page 14



4

AY,=constant + 1 m ^M , (+ 1 e! AE,
i= o
April 1970 Estimate*

i= o
Feb. 1978 Estimate*

m0

1.22

(2.73)

1.37

(2.96)

m,

1.80

(7.34)

1.92

(7.62)

m2

1.62

(4.25)

1.58

(3.96)

m3

.87

(3.65)

.63

(2.59)

m4

.06

-.2 4

(-.5 2 )

5.57

( 12)
(8.06)

5.26

(8.01)

eo

.56

(2.57)

.48

(2.32)

el

.45

(3.43)

.52

(4.07)

“ m,

e2

.01

( 08)

.15

( .81)

e3

-.4 3

(-3 .1 8 )

-.4 0

(-3 .0 7 )

e4

-.5 4

- ei
Constant
R2

(-2 .4 7 )

-.6 7

(-3 .2 2 )

.05

( 17)

.07

( .21)

2.67

(3.46)

2.32

(2.82)

.66

.69

S.E.

3.84

3.97

D.W.

1.75

1.93

t s t a t is t ic sh ow n in p a re n th e s e s
S y m b o ls a r e defin ed a s fo llo w s:
A Y : d o lla r c h a n g e in G N P
AM: c h a n g e in m o ney sto ck ( M l)
A E: c h a n g e in h ig h -e m p lo y m e n t e x p e n d itu re
R 2: co e fficie n t o f m u ltip le d e te rm in a tio n
S .E .: sta n d a rd e rr o r o f th e reg re s sio n

BLeonall C. Andersen and Keith M. Carlson, “A Monetarist
Model for Economic Stabilization,” this Review (April 1970),
pp. 7-25.

1978

D .W .: D u rb in -W a tso n s t a t is t ic

F E D E R A L . R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

FEBRUARY

Table I indicates that the effect of all data revisions
since April 1970 has been slight. The sum effect of
monetary actions (Zm j) is slightly smaller, but the
pattern of time distribution among these coefficients
continues to hold. Similarly, for fiscal actions, the
effect of data revisions is very small. The sum effects
on total spending of the independent variables con­
tinue to be dominated by the money variable. The
summary statistics indicate a slightly larger R-, an
improved Durbin-Watson statistic, but a larger stan­
dard error of the regression. In general, there is
nothing to indicate that data revisions have changed
the fundamental conclusions drawn from the original
St. Louis equation.
The equation was then estimated through 1976,
with 1953 maintained as the beginning of the sample
period.6 These estimates are shown in Table II. The
total effect of monetary actions continues to be im­
portant when the equation is estimated through 1976.
The sum effect of monetary actions is somewhat
smaller — 4.48 for the period through 1976, compared
with 5.26 for the earlier period. Probably the most
Table II

EFFECT OF UPDATING ST. LOUIS EQUATION
4
4
=constant + S m AM i 4 “ n e.AEt .
i= 0
i= 0
Sample Period:
1/1953— IV/1969

Sample Period:
1/1953— IV/1976

m0
m.

1.37

(2.96)

2.24

1.92

(7.62)

1.55

(4.04)
(4.39)

m2

1.58

(3.96)

43

( .88)

m3

.63

(2.59)

.07

( .21)

m4

-.2 4

(-5 2 )

40

( .70)

- m,

5.26

(8.01)

4.48

(5.98)

.48

(2.32)

.34

(1.83)
(1.80)

eo
e,
e2

.52

(4.07)

.25

.15

( .81)

.21

(1.34)

e3

-.4 0

(-3.07 )

.36

(2.65)

e4

-.6 7

(-3.22 )

.48

(2.47)

.07

( .21)

1.64

(4.50)

2.32

(2.82)

.45

( 35)

- e,
Constant

.69

.70

S.E.

R2

3.97

7.55

D.W.

1.93

1.77

A ll sy m b o ls and a b b re v ia tio n s a r e d efin ed in T a b le I.

°Friedman also gave estimates for the sample period beginning
in 1/1960. This was also done as a part of this study. How­
ever, none of the conclusions reached here was affected by
this change in sample period.




1978

interesting feature of these updated estimates is that
even though the sum effect of monetary actions did
not appear to change much, the pattern of the lag
distribution changed substantially. Originally the ef­
fect peaked for the change in money lagged one
quarter (AM,_,), but for the sample period extended
through 1976, the peak came on AM,, and only AM,
and AM m are significant.
Examination of the coefficients for the change in
high-employment Federal expenditures (A E) indi­
cates a much greater change for the updated version
of the equation. The sum effect of fiscal actions
climbed from .07 with data through 1969 to 1.64 with
data through 1976. Furthermore, the t statistic for
the sum effect of fiscal actions is statistically signifi­
cant in the 1953-76 regression. It is this result that
Friedman emphasized.

A Critique of These Updated Estimates
To better understand what underlies these
changed results, the error pattern of the St. Louis
equation is examined in greater detail. This error
pattern is shown in Chart I for the equation as esti­
mated for the original sample period through
IV/1969, and for the updated version through
IV/1976.
The IV/1969 version shows extreme errors only for
those periods associated with major strikes. Such is
not the case, however, for the updated version. There
are three periods that stand out — 1/1975, III/1975,
and 1/1976. The equation performs poorly in these
periods, yet these quarters were not associated with
major strikes.
A crucial assumption in linear regression is that the
variance of the error term is constant. Examination
of the errors for the period 1/1975 through 1/1976
suggests that this assumption might be violated. If
this is so, in the absence of collateral information
about the relationship between the nonconstant error
variances, the power of the standard t and F tests
becomes indeterminate.7 If, for example, these errors
are positively correlated with the size of the devia­
tion of the independent variables about their means,
there is increased probability of incorrectly rejecting
the null hypothesis of no significance.8 That is, a
particular coefficient would be incorrectly judged to
be significant.
7For further discussion, see Jan Kmenta, Elements of Econo­
metrics (New York: Macmillan, 1 9 7 1 ), pp. 249-69.
sIbid., p. 256.
Page 15

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

FEBRUARY

1978

C h a rt I

Error Pattern of St. Louis Equation
First D if fe re n c e ( A Y ) S p e c ific a t io n
Error

Error
(Billio n s

of

D o lla rs

(Billions

Sample Period: 1/1953 - IV/1969

20

of

D olla rs)

20

10

10

-10

-10

-20

-20

Sample Period: 1/1953 - 1V/1976

30

30

20

20

10

10

0

0

-10

-10

-20

-20
-3 0

-3 0
1 953

1955

1957

1959

1961

1963

1965

1967

1969

1971

1 973

1975

N o te : E rr o r e q u a ls a c tu a l ( q u a r te r - to - q u a r t e r firs t d iffe r e n c e in G N P ) m in u s fitt e d v a lu e (see e q u a tio n s in T a b le II) fo r s a m p le p e r io d
in d ic a te d . D a sh e d h o r iz o n ta l lin e s

in d ic a te p lu s -m in u s th e s ta n d a r d e r r o r o f th e r e g re s s io n (3.97 fo r I / 1 9 5 3 -IV /1 9 6 9 a n d 7 .5 5

fo r I/1 9 5 3 - IV /1 9 7 6 ) .

To determine if the assumption of constant vari­
ance in the error term is being violated, a statistical
test was conducted for the sample period ending in
IV/1969 and the one ending in IV/1976. These re­
sults are shown in Table III using the GoldfeldQuandt test for homoscedasticity.9 The assumption of
homoscedasticity (constancy of error variances across
all observations) is not rejected with this specification
of the equation for the sample period ending
IV/1969, but is rejected for the period ending
IV/1976. In general, the St. Louis equation, as esti­
mated in its original first difference form, but up­
dated through 1976, does not now appear to satisfy
the requirement of least squares estimation that the
variance of the error term be constant. Given the
evidence of nonconstancy of the error variances and
the absence of reliable information about the relation­
ship among the error variances, confidence in the
significance of the estimated coefficients is reduced.
One way around this problem is to seek an alterna­
9S. M. Goldfeld and R. E . Quandt, “Some Tests for Homo­
scedasticity,” Journal of the American Statistical Association
(June 1 9 6 5 ), pp. 539-547.


Page 16


tive specification which satisfies this assumption of
least squares.10

AN ALTERNATIVE SPECIFICATION
Updating the original St. Louis equation suggests
the emergence of statistical problems — problems
which were not present when the equation was first
estimated in 1968 and 1969. Rather than cling to that
specification, an alternative is examined in an effort
10To determine the direction of the bias in the estimates of the
standard error of the regression coefficients, the results from
the 1976 regression were ranked according to the size of
the independent variables and then grouped to compute
error variances. Correlation of these error variances with the
squared deviations of the group means from the overall
mean yielded the following:
Correlation Coefficient

AE
AM

8 Groups of
12 Observations
_____ Each_____

12 Groups of
8 Observations
Each

.90
.83

.55
.67

These results, although not conclusive, suggest that the esti­
mates of the standard errors are biased downward, that is,
the associated t statistics are biased upward. See Kmenta,
p. 256.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

FEBRUARY

1978

Table

RESULTS OF THE GOLDFELD-QUANDT TEST FOR HETEROSCEDASTICITY
(AY Version of Equation)
Sample
Subgroups
1/53— IV/76
A: 111/67— IV/76
B: 1/53— 11/62
A 1/65— IV/76
B: 1/53— IV/64
1/53— IV/69
A: 11/63— IV/69
B: 1/53— 111/59
A 111/61— IV/69
B: I/5 3 — 11/61

Null
Hypothesis

Alternative
Hypothesis

Critical
F

Calculated
F

Test
Result

H0: V(e,)A=V(c,)B

Ha V(et)A > V(e,)B

F
=2 24
r (0 1 .35.35)

F=3.57

H0 rejected

H0: V (tt)A=V(e,)B

H . V(t ,)A > V(«,)B

F(.01:45.45) =2 02

F=5.30

H0 rejected

H0: V(€,)A=V(€t)B

H,:V(*t)A>V(«,)B

F( 01 24.24)“ 2.66

F = .89

H0 not rejected

H0; V(e,)A=V(e,)B

Ha: V(*,)a > V(*,)B

F = .46

H0 not rejected

01:31,31)

^-3 5

S y m b o ls
V ic .): v a r ia n c e o f re s id u a ls
A. B : su b g ro u p s w h ere A is su sp ected o f h a v in g la r g e r r esid u a l v a r ia n c e th a n B
F:

S n e d e co r's F . te s t s t a t is t ic fo r ind ep en d en ce o f tw o c h i-sq u a re d is trib u te d rand om v a r ia b le s . S u b sc rip ts in p a r e n th e s e s r e f e r to le v e l o f sig n ific a n c e and d e g re e s of
freed om in n u m e ra to r an d d e n o m in ato r.

to avoid these specification problems.11 The alterna­
tive chosen here is to express all variables in the
equation in rates-of-change form.12
In their original article, Andersen and Jordan sug­
gested that a rate-of-change specification might be
preferable.13 At that time both specifications gave
essentially the same results with regard to the rela­
tive impact of monetary and fiscal actions. They opted
for the first difference form because it gave direct
estimates of multipliers which, at the time, were more
commonly used than elasticities in summarizing the
economic impact of changes in policy variables.
^There are various methods of avoiding the statistical prob­
lems discussed here, so it cannot be said with certainty that
the alternative specification chosen here is “the correct one.”
However, if an alternative is found to satisfy the assumption
of homoscedasticity, along with the other assumptions of
least squares, more confidence can be placed on the esti­
mated regression coefficients from that specification than in
the original one.
12Since the primary problem with the arithmetic first difference
(including a constant) specification seems to be one of
heteroscedasticity when the sample period is extended through
1976, an attempt was made to identify the source of the
problem. To see whether a specification error may be the
source of the problem, the Brown-Durbin-Evans test for con­
stancy of the regression coefficients over time was applied to
the first difference specification. The hypothesis of constancy
of the coefficients was not rejected for the original sample
period, but rejected for the extended period. However, for
the rate-of-change specification, the hypothesis of constancy
of the coefficients was accepted for both the original and
extended sample periods. See R. L. Brown, J. Durbin, and
J. M. Evans, “Techniques for Testing the Constancy of Re­
gression Relationships Over Time, with Comments,” Journal
of the Royal Statistical Society, Ser. B ( 1 9 7 5 ) , pp. 149-92.
13Andersen and Jordan, “Monetary and Fiscal Actions,” fn. 10,
p. 16.




The Estimates
Estimates of the St. Louis equation in rate-ofchange form for the two sample periods are shown in
Table IV. The pattern of estimated coefficients as the
Table IV

ALTERNATIVE SPECIFICATION OF
ST. LOUIS EQUATION
•
4
*
4
*
Y, = constant 4 i rt^M, ■i+ - e, Eti= o
i= o
Sample Period:
1/1953 —-IV/1969

Sample Perioc
1/1953 —- IV /19^

m0
m,

.30

(2.06)

.40

(2.96)

.47

(5.90)

.41

(5.26)

m2

.38

(3.01)

.25

(2.14)

m3
m4

09

(1.19)

.06

( 71)

- .1 6

( —1.10)

-.0 5

(-3 7 )

“ mi

1.08

(4.95)

1.06

(5.59)

e0
e,
e2

.07

(1.77)

.08

(2.26)

.09

(3.63)

.06

(2.52)

.03

( -75)

.00

( 02)

e3

-.0 9

( -3.68 )

-.0 6

( -2.20)

e4

-.1 6

( -4 .0 7 )

-.0 7

( -1.83)

- e,

-.0 6

(-.8 8 )

.03

( .40)

Constant

3.22

(4.04)

2.69

(3.23)

R2

.53

.40

S.E.

3.25

3.75

D.W.

1.85

1.78

A ll sy m b o ls and a b b re v ia tio n s a r e defin ed in T a b le 1. e x cep t th e dot o ver a
v a r ia b le sig n ifie s com pounded a n n u a l r a te o f ch a n g e

Page 17

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

FEBRUARY

1978

C h a rt II

Error Pattern of St. Louis Equation
R a t e of C h a n g e ( ? ) S p e c if ic a t io n
Error

E rror

Sample Period: 1/1953 - IV/1969

(Percent)

10

(Percent)

10

-5

-5

-10

-10

Sample Period: 1/1953 - IV/1976
15

15

10

10

5

5

0

0

-5

-5

-10

-10

-15

-15
1 953

1955

1957

1959

1961

1963

1965

1967

1969

1971

1 973

1975

N o te : E r ro r e q u a ls a c tu a l (q u a rte r-to -q u a rte r a n n u a l r a te o f c h a n g e in G N P ) m in u s fitte d v a lu e (see e q u a tio n s in T a b le IV) fo r s a m p le
p e rio d in d ic a te d . D a s h e d h o r iz o n ta l lin e s in d ic a te p lu s -m in u s th e s ta n d a r d e r r o r o f th e re g re s s io n (3 .2 5 fo r I/ 1 9 5 3 - IV /1 9 6 9
a n d 3 .7 5 fo r 1/1953-1V / 1976).

equation is updated differs substantially from those
presented for the first difference form in Table II.
The sum effect of both monetary and fiscal actions
changes little. Although there is some bunching of
the coefficients towards t = 0, the coefficient on $(_!
is still the peak quarter of effect.
Examination of the estimates of the fiscal effect
indicates that the sum effect changes from negative
to positive as this specification is updated. However,
the total of the fiscal effect is not significantly different
from zero for either the original or extended sample
periods. The distribution of the lag coefficients is
little changed as the equation is updated through
1976, in contrast to the first difference specifications
in Table II.

Analysis of the Error Pattern
The results of updating the St. Louis equation in
rate-of-change form differ substantially from those in
first difference form (Chart II). Using rates of change
instead of first differences appears to satisfy the as­
sumption of constant error variances. The results of the
Goldfeld-Quandt test are shown in Table V. For each

Page 18


of the test periods, the null hypothesis of constancy
in the error variances is not rejected. By reason of this
argument, there is no reason to suspect bias in the
estimated standard errors for this specification. The
sum effect for the monetary variable is significant,
but for the fiscal variable it is not.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION
Benjamin Friedman has published results showing
that the St. Louis equation now “believes in” fiscal
policy. This conclusion was based on updated esti­
mates of the equation in its originally published first
difference form. Friedman’s conclusion is shown to be
suspect on statistical grounds. Estimation of that equa­
tion in arithmetic first difference form no longer ap­
pears to be acceptable because there is evidence of
nonconstant error variance. Hence, it is difficult to
assess the statistical reliability of any conclusions
about the impact of monetary and fiscal actions based
on estimates with that form of the equation.
To correct these statistical problems, the St. Louis
equation was reestimated in rate-of-change form. All
other properties of the specification were maintained,

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

FEBRUARY

1978

Table V

RESULTS OF THE GOLDFELD-QUANDT TEST FOR HETEROSCEDASTICITY
(Y Version of Equation)
Sample
Subgroups
1/53--IV /76
A: 111/67 — IV/76
B: 1/53— 11/62
A: 1/65— IV/76
B 1/53— IV/64
1/53--IV/69
A: 11/63— IV/69
B: 1/53— 111/59
A: 111/61— IV/69
B: I/53— 11/61

Null
Hypothesis

Alternative
Hypothesis

Critical
F

Calculated
F

Test
Result

H0: V(et)A= V (*t)B

Ha : V(e,)A > V(e,)B

^(.01 35 . 35) — 2 .2 4

F=.78

H0 not rejected

H0 : V(et)A=V (*,)B

Ha V(tt)A>V(tt)B

^(01 45.45) —2.02

F=.97

H0 not rejected

H0: V(€t)A=V(€t)B

Ha : V (tt)A > V(€,) b

F( 01:24.24)-2 .6 6

F = .34

H0 not rejected

H0: V(€t)A=V(*,)B

Ha V (t,)A > V(et)B

^(.01:31.31) - 2 .3 5

F=.21

H0 not rejected

Symbols

A. B: su b g ro u p s w h ere A is su sp ected o f h a v in g la r g e r r esid u a l v a r ia n c e th a n B
F

S n e d e co r’s F. te st s t a t is t ic fo r ind ep en d en ce o f tw o c h i-sq u a re d is trib u te d ran d om v a r ia b le s S u b sc rip ts in p a r e n th e s e s r e f e r to le v e l o f sig n ific a n c e and d e g re e s of
freed om in n u m e ra to r an d d e n o m in a to r.

that is, the number of lags, the constraints and degree
of polynomial, and the definitions of the variables.
This alternative specification satisfied the least
squares assumptions concerning constancy in the
error variance. With this rate-of-change alternative




preferred on statistical grounds, the original empirical
conclusion regarding the steady-state effect of fiscal
actions was not altered. The evidence does not sup­
port the contention that the St. Louis equation now
“believes in” fiscal policy.

Page 19