View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

F E D E R A L R ES ER V E B A N K
OF ST. LOUIS
DECEMBER 1979




Vol. 61, No. 12

The R e v i e w is published monthly by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve Rank of
St. Louis. Single-copy subscriptions are available to the public free of charge. Mail requests for
subscriptions, back issues, or address changes to: Research Department, Federal Reserve Rank of
St. Louis, P.O. Rox 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166.
Articles herein may be reprinted provided the source is credited. Please provide the Rank’s Re­
search Department with a copy of reprinted material.




Evidence on the Temporal Stability of the Demand
for Money Relationship in the United States
R. W. HAFER AND SCOTT E. HEIN

fjC O N O M IS T S and policymakers are extremely
interested in the temporal stability of the money
demand relationship. Most economists use macroeconomic models which assume that money demand
is consistently related to a number of predetermined
variables. As such, evidence of instability in the re­
lationship casts doubt on the validity of such models.
Evidence of temporal instability is likewise discon­
certing to monetary policymakers. When the relation­
ship between money demand and the variables that
determine it breaks down, policymakers by definition
are unsure of future money demand. Thus, project­
ing the linkage between the money stock and eco­
nomic variables such as output, prices, and interest
rates becomes even more difficult and tenuous than
before.

In 1976, however, two separate studies found evi­
dence which suggests that the money demand rela­
tionship had broken down around 1973. Both Enzler,
Johnson, and Paulus (EJP), and Goldfeld found that
the traditional transaction money demand relationship
significantly overpredicted post-1972 real money bal­
ances.8 Being unsuccessful in attempting to explain
the decline statistically, both studies concluded that
there had indeed been a downward shift in the re­
lationship over this period.

With regard to narrowly defined money (M l), the
evidence on the stability of the demand relationship
has recently taken a drastic turn. Prior to the mid1970s, the evidence supporting a stable money de­
mand relationship in the United States was “over­
whelming,” to borrow Laidler’s description.1 Along
the same line, Laumas and Mehra provided statistical
evidence that the relationship was stable under a
broad range of alternative specifications.2

This conclusion recently has come under attack in
a number of studies which resurrect concern about
the appropriate money demand specification. These
studies argue that other specifications of the money
demand relationship do not indicate any recent break­
down. This article provides a critical review of the
existing evidence on the issue of the temporal stability
of the money demand relationship. Various money
demand specifications are examined in terms of their
dynamic out-of-sample predictive ability over the post1972 period and more formally through the use of the
Brown-Durbin-Evans ( BDE) cusum-squares tests.4
The forecasting ability of these alternatives is com­
pared using a common sample period, data base, and
means of generating post-sample predictions.

xDavid E. W. Laidler, “ The Influence of Money on Economic
Activity: A Survey of Some Current Problems,’ in G. Clayton,
J. C. Gilbert, and R. Sedgwick, eds., Monetary Theory and
Policy in the 1970’s, (London: Oxford University Press,
1971).

3Jared Enzler, Lewis Johnson, and John Paulus, “ Some Prob­
lems of Money Demand,” Brookings Papers on Economic Ac­
tivity (1: 1976) pp. 261-79; Stephen M. Goldfeld, “The Case
of the Missing Money,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activ­
ity (3: 1976), pp. 683-730.

2G. S. Laumas and Y. P. Mehra, “The Stability of the Demand
for Money Function: The Evidence from Quarterly Data,”
The Review of Economics and Statistics (November 1976),
pp. 463-68.

4R. L. Brown, J. Durbin, and J. M. Evans, “Techniques for
Testing the Constancy of Regression Relationships Over Time,”
Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Ser. B, Vol. 37, ( No. 2,
1975), pp. 149-92.




Page 3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

RECENT EVIDENCE ON THE
STABILITY OF THE MONEY
DEMAND RELATIONSHIP
The basic Goldfeld equation, which posits a real
adjustment lag, provides the standard of comparison
for alternative money demand specifications.5 The real
adjustment version of the Goldfeld specification is
(1 )

In ( y 1) = a„ + a, In y, + a 3 In CPR, +
a 3 In RTD, + a, In

where

+ v,,

M = nominal M l balances,
P = the general price level (the implicit
GNP deflator),
y = real income (real GNP),
CPR = the commercial paper rate,
RTD = the rate on time deposits,
v = an error term.6

The first row of table 1 reports the coefficient esti­
mates and summary statistics for this money demand
specification. All estimates shown are for the sample
period II/1955-IV/1972 and are based on the Cochrane-Orcutt (CORC) estimation technique. In addi­
tion, table 1 reports the root-mean-squared error
(RMSE) of the dynamic post-sample simulations
(I/1973-I/1977).7

DECEM BER

Although the sample period is slightly different,
the results for this equation are similar to Goldfeld’s.
The estimated coefficients all have the anticipated sign
and are significantly different from zero. These esti­
mates reveal that more than one-third of the desired
change in the money stock is completed within one
quarter and that the long-run income elasticity is
0.54. The resulting large RMSE for the dynamic sim­
ulation demonstrates a marked deterioration in the
relationship after 1972. A comparable simulation over
the period IV/1968-IV/1972 yielded an RMSE of only
2.33 — merely one-tenth of that found for the post1972 period.
One of the earliest rebuttals to the instability claim
came from Hamburger, who contended that EJP and
Goldfeld were too restrictive in their choice of asset
yields hypothesized to affect money demand.8 He
argued that the exclusion of long-term asset yields
from the specification was both theoretically and em­
pirically unjustified.
To support his argument, Hamburger incorporated
long-term government bond yields and the common
stock dividend-price ratio in estimating an altered
version of the MPS (MIT-Pennsylvania-Social Science
Research Council) money demand equation. The
adapted specification used by Hamburger was
(2)

5The equation hypothesizes that the real money stock only par­
tially adjusts to the desired level in the current quarter (the
desired level being determined by real income and the two
contemporaneous interest rates). Another popular version of
the partial adjustment process hypothesizes that the nominal
money stock partially adjusts to the desired level within one
quarter. This version is similar to equation 1 in all respects
except that the lagged money stock variable is divided by the
contemporaneous price level. It should be noted that Goldfeld
found the nominal adjustment mechanism slightly preferable
in terms of out-of-sample forecasting ability. We use his real
version, however, since it has become the standard reference
equation in most studies considered here.
•'Since Goldfeld estimates equation 1 by the Cochrane-Orcutt
(CORC) estimation procedure, he implicitly assumes vt =
p vt i -r £t, where p is a constant and e is an error term
with classical properties. In theory, the coexistence of a lagged
dependent variable and serially correlated error terms casts
doubt about the consistency and efficiency of CORC esti­
mates. However, the work of Laumas-Spencer suggests that
the gains from more elaborate estimation procedures are small.
See G. S. Laumas and David E. Spencer, “The Stability of
the Demand for Money: Evidence from the Post-1973 Period,”
unpublished manuscript, 1979.
•Two important points about the post-sample simulations need
to be noted. In the first place, the simulations are based on the
transformed equation, in which the autocorrelation in the error
terms is explicitly recognized. In other words, the forecasts
are based on the equation
In

= So (1 - p) - f a , ( lny, - p lny, ,) +

a 2 (In CPR, - 0 In CPR,-,) + a > (ln RTD, - p In R TD ,.,) +

* ■ "($ ? )

where p is the estimated serial correlation coefficient and oti

Page 4


1979

In ( jT“ ~ ) = P° + P- ln R TD ‘ + P’ ln DPR‘ +
ln RGL, + P. ln ( | y )

+ e„

where DPR is the dividend-price ratio on common
stock, RGL is the yield on long-term government
bonds, e is an error term, and other variables are as
previously defined.
Estimation results for this equation are reported in
the second row of table 1.® These results, similar to
(i = 0, . .
4) is the estimated regression coefficient. It is
unclear from the cited studies whether such a procedure is
commonly followed. Second, the RMSE for each equation is
determined by comparing the actual money stock with the
nominal level simulated by each equation. Many previous
studies use the real money stock and projected real balances
as the source of comparison.
The endpoint of our sample period (1/1977) was chosen
to enhance the comparability between our findings and others
considered here. Also, the series for net wealth used in this
study was available only through 1/1977.
8Michael J. Hamburger, “ Behavior of the Money Stock: Is
There a Puzzle?” Journal of Monetary Economics, ( No. 3,
1977), pp. 265-288.
9This equation is based on the nominal adjustment mechanism
discussed in footnote 5. We also estimated the equation assum­
ing a real adjustment mechanism in which the lagged money
stock is deflated by the term (P,_, y ,). Except for the coeffi­
cient on the commercial bank passbook rate, which was insig­
nificantly different from zero, the coefficient estimates were
similar to those reported in table 1. However, the RMSE in­
creased dramatically to 14.59 when the real adjustment ver­
sion was employed.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

DECEM BER

1979

Table 1

Alternative Money Demand Equation
Regression Results: 11/19 5 5 - IV / l972
__________________________________________________ C oefficient*__________________________________________________

Equation

Constant

Income

(1 ) G oldfeld

-.8 6 1
(5 .1 8 )

.177
(5 .0 4 )

(2 ) Hamburger

- .4 5 8
(3 .2 5 )

(3 ) B. Friedm an

- .6 1 3
(3 .4 9 )

(4 )

Laumas-Spencer

(5 ) G arcia-P ak

Net
W ealth

Time
Deposits
- .0 4 0
(3 .5 1 )

.100
(2 .3 8 )

.065
(2 .6 3 )

- .0 4 0
(3 .7 1 )

.056
(4 .8 5 )
.174
(5 .0 3 )

- .0 3 8
(3 .4 2 )

Dividend
Price
Ratio

Money
la g g e d b

Summ ary Statistics

R2

D .W .

SEE

rho

RMSEC

.665
(8 .3 6 )

.994

1.76

.0040

.440

2 1 .8 8
(7 .6 5 )

.908
(3 4 .7 7 )

.999

1 .70

.00 4 0

.566

4 .5 4
(1 .5 9 )

- .0 1 4
(4 .0 5 )

.728
(9 .5 6 )

.995

1.81

.003 8

.372

21 .7 2
(7 .5 9 )

- .0 1 7
(4 .4 5 )

.924
(2 1 .8 8 )

.993

1.88

.004 4

.377

28 .9 4
(1 0 .1 2 )

-.0 2 1
(6 .1 0 )

.760
(1 2 .2 4 )

.993

2 .0 2

.005 5

.021

9 .9 5
(3 .4 8 )

- .0 1 6
(4 .5 7 )

-.0 2 1
(2 .2 4 )

- .2 8 6
(5 .6 0 )
- .9 0 8
(5 .2 2 )

Permanent
Income

GovernCom­
ment
m ercial
Bond
Paper
Y ield

- 0 .0 2 0
(1 .9 1 )

- .0 2 4
(3 .0 3 )

"All variables enter logarithmically and all equations are estimated using the Cochrane-Orcutt iterative technique. The numbers
in parentheses are absolute values of t-ratios.
'The Goldfeld, Friedman, and Laumus-Spencer equations contain a lagged money variable of the form (M t-i/Pt-i). The
Hamburger specification includes a lagged money variable of the form (M t-i/Ptyt). The lagged money term in the GarciaPak equation is of the form (M ,-i/P t-i), where M = M l + IAF.
‘ The RMSE is the root-mean-squared error for dynamic extrapolation over the I/1973-I/1977 period. The error is in billions
of current dollars, and the percentage error — the RMSE relative to the mean level of M l balances over the post-sample
period — is listed in parentheses.

Hamburger’s, indicate that “long-term” yields have a
significant effect on money demand. Furthermore, the
equation performs quite well relative to Goldfeld’s
equation in post-sample simulations.
Important differences between the Goldfeld and
Hamburger estimation results should be noted, how­
ever. First, Hamburger’s specification implies that less
than 10 percent of the change in the desired money
stock occurs within one quarter, much slower than
the 34 percent adjustment suggested by Goldfeld.10
In addition, Hamburger’s specification, by excluding
real income as a separate independent variable, has
constrained the long-run income elasticity to be
unity.11 This, again, is quite different from the 0.54
10It is interesting to note that the relatively slow speed of ad­
justment found for this specification is not wholly attributable
to the use of a nominal adjustment specification as has been
found in other cases. When Hamburger’s equation is reesti­
mated using a real adjustment mechanism, the estimated
speed of adjustment declines to 7 percent per quarter.
u This may be shown formally by considering the nominal ad­
justment mechanism used by Hamburger:
M, _ [ M? 1 X
Mt ,
IM .-J
or
Mt
r _M?_ I X
Pty< __ I P.yt I
Mt-i
I Mm I
Ptyt
I Ptyt *
which, after taking the logarithm and rearranging, yields

“ ( k t ) = Xh ( e 7:)

(p!yf)-

Returning to equation 2 in the text, we see that Hamburger’s
specification implies,



estimate yielded by Goldfeld’s equation. Finally, while
Goldfeld was criticized for excluding long-term yields
from the relationship, Hambiyger equally can be
criticized for excluding short-term rates other than the
passbook rate. This exclusion creates problems when
Regulation Q prevents the commercial passbook rate
from moving in step with other short-term yields.
Thus, Hamburger has no good proxy in the equation
to pick up movements in freely fluctuating short-term
yields.
Friedman has criticized Hamburger’s conclusion that
long-term asset yields provide the key to understand­
ing the recent money demand problem.12 Friedman’s
analysis considered aggregate wealth as a separate
determinant of money demand. Arguing that Ham­
burger’s dividend-priee ratio variable is simply a proxy
for aggregate wealth, Friedman replaced the equity
yield in Hamburger’s specification with aggregate
household financial asset holdings and obtained a net
improvement in post-sample predictive ability. Based
X l n ^ P - = P„ + P, In RTDt + P, In DPR. + p3 In RGL, + e,
x tyt
and B, =

1 - X. From this it is clear that f-;ln
- 1,
f) In yt
so that Hamburger’s equation constrains the long-run income
elasticity to be unity. Hamburger’s specification can be criti­
cized further on the grounds that he includes a real rate of
return when a nominal rate is appropriate.
12Benjamin Friedman, “Crowding Out or Crowding In: Eco­
nomic Consequences of Financing Government Deficits,”
Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (3: 1978), pp. 593641.
Page 5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

on this finding, he conjectured that . . Hamburger’s
proposed solution for the mystery of the missing
money is simply a disguised story about the role of
wealth in the money-demand function, and that the
solution works better without the disguise.”13
Were this true, however, one would also expect the
inclusion of a wealth measure in a conventional equa­
tion (such as Goldfeld’s) to yield more reliable post­
sample forecasts. The estimated results for such a
specification are reported in the third row of table 1.
Although the wealth variable (measured here by
household net worth) does have a significant effect
on money demand, it does little to improve post­
sample predictions.
These results do not support Friedman’s interpre­
tation of Hamburger’s finding.14 According to this
interpretation, the inclusion of a wealth variable in
any specification should improve the equation’s pre­
dictive ability. When incorporated in Goldfeld’s equa­
tion, it did not. This suggests that the inclusion of a
proxy for real wealth is not the crucial feature of
Hamburger’s specification.
Laumas and Spencer examined the applicability of
permanent income — measured as an exponentially
weighted average of past values of real GNP — as the
scale variable in the money demand relationship.18
The relevance of such a variable is explored in the
fourth row of table l.16 The estimation results of this
equation are similar to Laumas and Spencer’s. They
imply a slow speed of adjustment (8 percent per
quarter), similar to that of Hamburger’s specification.
On the other hand, the coefficient estimates yield a
long-run permanent income elasticity that is less than
unity (0.74). This specification, however, performs
worse than the original Goldfeld equation over the
post-sample period which suggests that permanent
income, at least measured adaptively, is not a solu­
tion to the puzzle. Our findings (not detailed here)
further indicate that this conclusion is insensitive to
the measurement of interest rates.
Finally, Garcia and Pak have suggested that the
recent problem stems from the use of an improperly
18Ibid., p. 629.
14Interestingly enough, Friedman also finds that the inclusion
of a wealth variable in Goldfeld’s specification yields an un­
stable relationship, at least based on a “ Chow test.” This
finding should have cautioned him against viewing Ham­
burger’s solution as based on finding a proxy for wealth,
since wealth itself does not appear to make the relationship
stable.
15Laumas-Spencer, “The Stability of the Demand for Money.”
16We used the same real permanent income series as Laumas
and Spencer. It was kindly provided to us by David Spencer.

Page 6


DECEM BER

1979

measured money stock.17 They argue that the recent
widespread use of repurchase agreements has led to
an important underestimation of “true” M l balances.
The final equation of table 1 investigates this argu­
ment by including immediately available funds (IAF)
data in the measurement of the money stock.18 In all
other respects, this equation is analogous to Goldfeld’s.
The coefficient estimates are similar to the estimates
obtained for Goldfeld’s specification. The standard
error of the equation, however, is larger, which sug­
gests a poorer sample period fit. While this equation
predicts post-1972 M l balances better than the Gold­
feld equation, it is unclear whether this alone jus­
tifies the conclusion that the relationship is stable.
An examination of the forecasting ability of these
alternative money demand equations indicates that
the inclusion of neither permanent income nor wealth
in the conventional equation significantly improves
post-sample forecasts. Also, while the addition of re­
purchase agreements to M l improves the post-sample
predictions, the significance of the improvement re­
mains unclear. Although Hamburger’s specification
does a superior job in forecasting money balances,
the source of the improvement is puzzling.

A CLOSER LOOK AT
HAMBURGER S FINDINGS
As noted in the previous section, Hamburger’s speci­
fication performs quite well in predicting post-1972
money balances. His specification, however, differs
from the conventional equation not only in its incor­
poration of long-term asset yields, but also in its treat­
ment of the long-run income elasticity and its exclusion
of short-term interest rates.
Consider, first, the issue of the long-run income
elasticity. Hamburger’s specification constrains the
long-run income elasticity to be unity while the others
suggest that the long-run income elasticity is signifi17Gillian Garcia and Simon Pak, “ Some Clues in the Case of
the Missing Money,” American Econom ic Review, Papers and
Proceedings (May 1979), pp. 330-34.
18The IAF data used in the present study is taken from Gillian
Garcia and Simon Pak, “ The Ratio of Currency to Demand
Deposits in the United States,” T he Journal of Finance (June
1979), pp. 703-15. It has been argued that the Garcia-Pak
equation is misspecified because of the exclusion of the ap­
propriate own interest rate on the repurchase agreements.
Using federal funds rate as a proxy for such a rate, Porter,
Simpson, and Mauskopf report that out-of-sample forecast
errors ( III/1974-I/1979) are higher than those based on
the equation examined in the text. See Richard D. Porter,
Thomas D. Simpson, and Eileen Mauskopf, “Financial In­
novation and the Monetary Aggregates,” Brookings Papers
on Economic Activity (1 : 1979), pp. 213-29.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

DECEM BER

1979

Table 2

Variations on Hamburger's Specification
II/1 9 5 5 -IV /1 9 7 2
____________________________

Equation

Constant

(1 )

Hamburger

- .4 5 8
(3 .2 5 )

(2 )

Unconstrained
Hamburger

- .7 7 4
(4 .2 5 )

(3 )

Ham burger

(4 )

Unconstrained Ham ­ - .7 3 8
burger -|- CPR
( 4 .3 8 )

CPR

Income

- .1 5 8
(2 .8 0 )

- .5 2 5
( 4 .3 2 )
- .0 9 4
(1 .8 2 )

Coefficient"

Summ ary Statistics

Time
Deposits

Dividend
Price
Ratio

Government
Bond
Yield

- .021
( 2 .2 4 )

- .0 2 4
( 3 .0 3 )

- .0 2 0
( 1 .9 1 )

- .0 3 7
( 3 .1 9 )

- .0 2 5
( 3 .0 2 )

- .0 1 8
(1 5 7 )

- .0 2 6
( 3 .2 4 )

- .0 1 5
(2 .0 7 )

.0 0 3
( 0 .3 2 )

- .0 3 8
(3 .6 1 )

- .0 1 6
(2 .1 0 )

.0 0 2
( 0 .1 8 )

Corn­
mercial
Paper

Money
Laggedb

R2

D .W .

SEE

rho

RM SE'

.9 0 8
( 3 4 .7 7 )

.9 9 9

1 .7 0

.0 0 4 0

.5 6 6

4 .5 4
(1 5 9 )

.6 7 3
( 7 .8 2 )

.9 9 9

1.63

.0 0 3 9

.6 6 0

12.55
( 4 .3 9 )

- .0 1 6
(3 .8 1 )

.8 9 9
(4 0 .1 0 )

.9 9 9

1.81

.0 0 3 7

.5 0 9

1 1.29
(3 .9 5 )

- .0 1 4
( 3 .2 2 )

.7 5 5
( 9 .2 6 )

.9 9 9

1.74

.0 0 3 6

.561

2 5 .7 3
( 9 .0 0 )

e l l variables enter logarithmically and all equations are estimated using the Cochrane-Orcutt iterative technique. The numbers
in parentheses are absolute values of t-ratios.
T h e lagged term in all equations is given by M t-i/P ty t.
'The RMSE is the root-mean-squared error for dynamic extrapolation over the I/1973-I/1977 period. The error is in billions
of current dollars, and the percentage error — the RMSE relative to the mean level of M l balances over the post-sample
period — is listed in parentheses.

cantly less than one. Hamburger’s constraint can be
tested easily by adding the natural log of real income
as a separate independent variable to his original
specification. This allows the long-run income elas­
ticity to be freely estimated.19
These estimation results are reported in the second
row of table 2. The estimated coefficient on real in­
come is negative and significantly different from zero,
which suggests that the long-run income elasticity is
less than unity. In fact, the estimation results indicate
that this parameter is 0.52 — not much different from
Goldfeld’s equation. Incorporation of real income into
the specification yields a larger estimate of both the
speed of adjustment and the short-run interest elas­
ticity on the time deposit variable. Also, the standard
error of the equation is reduced slightly upon the
relaxation of the income elasticity constraint. Thus,
on empirical grounds, there is no apparent justifica­
19If real income is included in the specification as a separate
variable, we have, following footnote 11,
X In ( ^

)

= P» + Pi In RTDt + P* In DPR, +

Pa In RGLt + p5 In yi,
(where P< ( = 1 - X ) is the coefficient on the lagged variable)
or,
hi

= (P ./X ) + (P ./X ) In RTDt + (P ,/X ) In DPR, +

( P,/X) In RGL, + ( p5/X + 1) In y „
This implies that the long-run income elasticity,
/ <9In (M ?/P t)\

.

.....................

-- / ’ 18 (PsA) + 1' where
p5 is the coefficient on the real income variable and X is the
speed of adjustment. ( Note again that Hamburger’s specifica­



tion for Hamburger’s restriction that the income elas­
ticity be unity.
Finally, note that the forecasting accuracy of this
general specification (in terms of the RMSE) declines
markedly relative to Hamburger’s original specifica­
tion. This suggests that an important characteristic of
Hamburger’s specification — as far as predictive abil­
ity is concerned — is the imposed income elasticity
constraint.20
Unlike most other specifications, which ignore long­
term asset yields, Hamburger’s equation excludes both
short-term interest rates and ( since nominal rates
should incorporate expected inflation) short-term in­
flationary expectations as well. Row three of table 2
enumerates the results of adding the commercial paper
rate to Hamburger’s specification. As far as sample
period estimation is concerned, this short-term rate
has a significant negative impact on money demand.
However, the estimated coefficient on the long-term
government bond yield now becomes insignificantly
different from zero.
As observed when the real income variable was
added, the inclusion of the commercial paper rate
tion constrains p5 to be zero, implying a long-run income
elasticity of unity).
-°As far as static predictive ability is concerned, Hamburger's
specification can be further improved by constraining the
income elasticity to values in excess of unity. See Scott E.
Hein, “Empirical Evidence on the Macroeconomic Demand
for Money Relationship in the United States,” ( Ph.D. disser­
tation, Purdue University, 1979). Hein argues that these fore­
casts are accurate because the specification is essentially an
autoregressive process.
Page 7

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

improves the sample period fit, but only at the ex­
pense of post-sample predictive ability. Exclusion of
short-term interest rates from the specification, al­
though empirically unjustified, is partially responsible
for Hamburger’s superior forecasting results.
The addition of both real income and the commer­
cial paper rate to the basic Hamburger specification
has a significant impact on both sample period and
post-sample period findings, as shown in row four of
table 2. The coefficients on both variables have the
anticipated signs and are statistically significant. The
estimated coefficient on the lagged money term is
smaller than that of the original specification, which
suggests a quicker speed of adjustment. Also consist­
ent with the Goldfeld equation results, the long-run
income elasticity is estimated to be 0.62. Once again,
the addition of these variables produces both a de­
cline in the sample-period standard error of the equa­
tion and a deterioration in the equation’s post-sample
predictive ability. In this specification, though, the de­
terioration is so marked that the RMSE is larger than
that of the original Goldfeld equation.
The preceding results suggest that crucial to Ham­
burger’s forecasting accuracy are (1) his treatment of
the long-run income elasticity and (2) his exclusion of
short-term interest rates, not the incorporation of long­
term asset yields as he argues.21 This also explains
why the substitution of a wealth variable in Ham­
burger’s specification yields accurate post-sample pre­
dictions, while its inclusion in the Goldfeld equation
does not.

AN ALTERNATIVE TEST OF
TEMPORAL STARILITY
In the course of reviewing evidence on the tem­
poral stability of the money demand relationship, this
discussion like most recent literature has emphasized
the relative post-1972 forecasting ability of alterna­
tive money demand specifications. This basis of com­
parison, however, assumes that the equation which
performs best in terms of yielding the smallest post­
sample RMSE is the most stable relationship.
The inappropriateness of such an assumption should
be obvious. If one is concerned with the temporal sta­
bility of a given relationship, one should be concerned
- 1All versions of the original Hamburger specification consid­
ered in table 2 were also estimated assuming a real rather
than a nominal adjustment mechanism. The results, available
from the authors upon request, were similar in most respects
to those reported above.

Page 8


DECEM BER

1979

with the predictive ability of that specification at dif­
ferent points in time, not its predictive ability rela­
tive to other specifications. Evidence that a given
equation’s predictions over a certain time interval are
inferior to its predictions at earlier time periods
( especially when such predictions are consistently
to one side of the actual values) is highly suggestive
of a breakdown in that relationship. A comparison of
the predictive ability of any two equations over a
given time period, however, will not allow one to de­
duce anything about the temporal stability of either
equation.
In order to redirect attention to the basic issue of
temporal stability, an alternative criterion to that of
examining the relative forecasting ability of alterna­
tive specifications is now applied. This alternative test
procedure will be used to examine the temporal sta­
bility of each specification discussed earlier.
The test used here is formulated and described in
Brown, Durbin, and Evans.2- To test the hypothesis
of coefficient stability statistically, the BDE test re­
quires the calculation of the one-period-ahead forecast
error of each specification. This prediction error is
based on a regression over the time period 1 to r,
where r = k -(- 1, . . T (k is the number of regres­
sors, including the constant, and T is the sample size).
In other words, if k is equal to, say, five, then the
first one-period-ahead prediction error would be based
on a regression estimated over the sample 1 to 6. The
second prediction error is based on the regression
estimated over the sample 1 to 7 and so on until the
end of the sample (T ) is reached.
The BDE statistic used, called the cusum-squares
statistic, may be written as
Z

w?

t«= k+ l

(3 )

S , = -----------T

Z

r = k + l,...,T

wr

t-k + 1

where w[ represents the squared one-period-ahead
prediction errors. The cusum-squares statistic is es­
sentially the ratio of the squared one-period-ahead
prediction errors based on the sample period k + 1
to r, to the squared one-period-ahead prediction errors
based on a regression estimated over the sample pe--Brown, Durbin and Evans, “Testing the Constancy of Regres­
sion Relationships.” Recently, Heller and Khan have applied
this technique to a short-run money demand specification
which includes an approximation of the interest rate term
structure. See H. Robert Heller and Mohsin S. Kahn, “ The
Demand for Money and the Term Structure of Interest
Rates,” Journal of Political Economy (February 1979), pp.
109-29.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

DECEM BER

1979

Tab le 3

Alternative Money Demand Equation
Regression Results: 11/1955-1/1977
Coefficient*

Equation

Constant

Income

Goldfeld

- .6 8 4
( 3 .2 9 )

.1 5 4
(4 .3 0 )

Ham burger

.3 4 7
(3 .6 9 )

Unconstrained
Hamburger

- .3 6 6
(3 .7 0 )

Hamburger + CPR

- .3 1 2
(3 -2 7 )

Unconstrained
Hamburger + CPR

Perm a­
nent
Net
Income W ealth

- .0 5 0
( 2 .7 1 )

- .0 2 0
(.6 6 8 )

- .2 5 5
( 2 .8 7 )

.041
( 1 .3 2 )

B. Friedman

.111
(1 .1 7 )

- .0 6 4
( 2 .4 2 )

Laumas-Spencer

- .1 3 7
( 2 .6 7 )

G arcia-P ak

- .9 5 2
(5 .1 5 )

Time
Deposits

.1 0 0
(3 .5 0 )

Com­
mercial
Paper

G overn­
ment
Bond
Yield

Dividend
Price
Ratio

- .0 1 3
( 2 .9 0 )

Money
Laggedb

R2

D .W .

SEE

rho

.6 4 2
( 7 .5 5 )

.9 9 2

2 .0 4

.0 0 5 0

.9 2 2

- .0 1 4
(1 .9 5 )

- .0 1 5
(1 .6 8 )

- .0 2 0
( 3 .6 8 )

.9 3 0
(5 1 .0 6 )

.9 9 9

1.82

.0 0 4 2

.4 7 8

- .0 1 6
(2 .0 2 )

- .0 1 4
(1 .4 7 )

- .0 2 2
(3 .5 8 )

.9 0 3
(2 2 .4 5 )

.9 9 9

1 .8 4

.0 0 4 2

.5 1 2

- .0 1 4
(1 .8 6 )

- .0 0 8
(2 .2 7 )

- .0 0 2
(0 .1 2 )

- .0 1 9
(3 .4 2 )

.9 3 8
(5 0 .4 3 )

.9 9 9

1 .90

.0041

.4 9 3

- .0 0 9
(1 .3 4 )

- .0 1 0
(2 .5 9 )

.0 0 2
( 0 .1 7 )

- .0 1 5
(2 .5 9 )

.9 9 5
(2 3 .1 4 )

.9 9 9

1 .89

.0041

.4 0 5

- .0 0 3
( 0 .4 0 )

- .0 1 5
(3 .8 2 )

1.02
(2 6 .5 1 )

.9 9 2

2 .0 0

.0 0 4 9

.3 7 0

- .0 1 8
(4 .0 5 )

.9 9 2
(2 1 .1 5 )

.991

2 .0 7

.0 0 5 2

.5 6 3

- .0 1 4
(2 .7 2 )

.7 4 2
(1 2 .5 0 )

.9 9 3

2.2 8

.0 0 4 2

.3 9 2

.0 2 5
(2 .3 6 )
.1 8 2
(5 .1 4 )

Summary Statistics

- .0 4 4
(3 .3 3 )

"All variables enter logarithmically and all equations are estimated using the Cochrane-Orcutt iterative technique. The numbers
in parentheses are absolute values of t-ratios.
T h e Goldfeld, Friedman, and Laumas-Spencer equations contain a lagged money variable of the form (M t-i/Pt-i). Ham­
burger and its variations used a lagged money variable of the form (M t-i/P tyt). The lagged money term in the Garcia-Pak
equation is of the form (M t-i/Pt-i), where M = M l + IAF.

riod k + 1 to T.23 The Sr statistic is compared to a
critical value and, if the estimated relationship is
stable, the value of Sr will be less than the prede­
termined critical value.24 This test may be illustrated
graphically by plotting Sr against time, along with
parallel sets of significance lines which provide the
statistical “boundaries” used to indicate a break point
at that given level of statistical significance.

In general, short-run income elasticity declines sig­
nificantly as the sample period is extended. For ex­
ample, when the income elasticity is freely estimated
using the Hamburger specification (inclusive or exclu­
sive of the commercial paper rate), the estimated
coefficient on the income term becomes statistically
insignificant and, in the latter equation, even takes
on the “wrong” sign.

Before applying the cusum-squares test, it was nec­
essary to estimate each of the alternative specifications
over the entire sample period (II/1955-I/1977). These
regression results are presented in table 3. In compar­
ing the whole period regression results with those of
the II/1955-IV/1972 period shown in table 1, several
changes are noticeable. In many cases, the full sample
estimation results, in and of themselves, indicate a
breakdown in the money demand relationship.

Another common feature of the full sample period
results is the increase in the magnitude of the coeffi­
cient on the lagged dependent variable. This phe­
nomenon, which has been found in previous studies,
indicates a slower speed of adjustment.25 In the Fried­
man specification, which incorporates the wealth vari­
able, the lagged term coefficient becomes greater than
unity, defying any meaningful interpretation within
the stock-adjustment framework.

23For a critical evaluation of the power of these tests, see K.
Garbade, “Two Methods for Examining the Stability of Re­
gression Coefficients,” Journal of the American Statistical
Association (March 1977), pp. 54-63 and John U. Farley,
Melvin Hinich, and Timothy W. McGuire, “ Some Compari­
sons of Tests for a Shift in the Slopes of a Multivariate
Linear Time Series Model," Journal of Econometrics (Vol.
3, No. 3, 1975) pp. 297-318.
24John M. Evans, “ User Guide to TIMVAR,” Working Paper,
Central Statistical Office (London, 1973).



In general, many of the interest rate coefficients
appear to be unstable. Although the coefficient on the
commercial paper rate variable maintains its magni­
tude, the estimated coefficient on the commercial bank
25Garcia and Pak, “ Some Clues in the Case of the Missing
Money;” Heller and Kahn, “The Demand for Money and the
Term Structure of Interest Rates;” and B. Friedman, “ Crowd­
ing Out.”
Page 9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST LOUIS

DECEM BER

Table 4

Stability Tests for Alternative Money Demand
Specifications: 11/1 955-1/1 977
Critical Values*
Equation

Cusu m-squares

1%

5%

10%

G oldfeld

.1 6 8

.2 3 3

.1 9 2

.1 7 2

Hamburger

.1 0 8

.2 3 3

.192

.172

.161

.2 3 5

.1 9 4

.1 7 3

.1 7 5

.2 3 5

.1 9 4

.1 7 3

Unconstrained
Hamburger
Hamburger +

CPR

1979

be significant, it is clearly smaller than that observed
for the other specifications.
In order to carry out the cusum-squares test, it was
assumed that the autocorrelation coefficient for each
specification ( given in table 3) was constant over the
entire sample period. This assumption allows the trans­
formation of the dependent and all independent vari­
ables to correct for serial correlation in the errors.
This transformation was accomplished by subtracting
the product of the estimated rho coefficient and the
variable’s previous value from the current value of
the variable.26 Specifically, this procedure is given by
the relationship

Unconstrained
Ham burger + CPR

.2 0 6

.2 3 6

.19 5

.1 7 4

B. Friedman

.3 1 7

.2 3 5

.1 9 4

.1 7 3

G arcia-P ak

.3 9 7

.2 3 3

.1 9 2

.1 7 2

(4 )

Laumas-Spencer

.2 1 8

.232

.1 9 2

.171

where Xt represents the transformation of the variable
xt and p is the estimated autocorrelation coefficient.

“The critical values for the cusum-squares test are taken from John
M. Evans, “ User Guide to TIM V AR,” W orking Paper. Central
Statistical Office (London, 1973).

passbook rate shows a marked decline in a majority
of the estimations, sometimes being insignificantly
different from zero. In addition, the coefficient on the
long-term government bond yield in all variations of
the basic Hamburger specification fails to attain sta­
tistical significance over the longer sample period.
In contrast to the other money demand specifica­
tions, the Garcia-Pak and Goldfeld coefficient estimates
are similar over both sample periods. The magnitudes
of Garcia-Pak’s lagged term, income, and time deposit
rate coefficients all appear to change little when the
I/1973-I/1977 observations are included. The largest
change occurs for the coefficient on the commercial
paper rate which declines by 30 percent when com­
paring the II/1955-IV/1972 results with those for
II/1955-I/1977. Given certain reservations about this
specification (see footnote 18), however, these results
should be interpreted cautiously.
The coefficient estimates for Goldfeld’s specification
appear to be as stable as Garcia-Pak’s. For instance,
the estimated speed of adjustment for the full sample
period regression is .358 compared with .335 for the
II/1955-IV/1972 period. Given the relative stability
of the other estimated coefficients, it is clear that the
long-run elasticities for the interest rate variables do
not vary dramatically between the two sample pe­
riods. For the commercial paper rate, the long-run
elasticities are .036 and .048 for the II/1955-I/1977
and II/1955-IV/1972 periods, respectively. The same
measures for the time deposits variable are .140 and
.119. The change in the estimate of the long-run in­
come elasticity is slightly larger. For the early sample
period this parameter was .528, compared with .430
over the full sample period. While this change may
Page 10



X t = x, - p x,-,

The statistical results for the cusum-squares tests
are presented in table 4. These tests indicate that
several specifications are unstable over the full sample
period: Hamburger with CPR (at a significance level
of 10 percent), Unconstrained Hamburger with CPR
(5 percent), Friedman (1 percent), Garcia-Pak (1
percent), and Laumus-Spencer (5 percent). Perhaps
the most interesting finding is that the Goldfeld speci­
fication demonstrates no structural instability using
this test. Indeed, the null hypothesis of stability can­
not be rejected even at the 10 percent level of
significance.27
While the statistical tests reported in table 4 indi­
cate which equations demonstrate structural insta­
bility in the regression relationships over the entire
sample period, they do not locate the probable point
of departure from constancy. Such information is pro­
vided by charts 1-5. In each chart, the sample cusumsquares statistic (Sr) is plotted against time for each
specification in which the hypothesis of stability was
rejected by the cusum-squares test. In addition to the
-''Such a transformation was required since the BDE tests as­
sume that the errors are serially independent. If the serial
coefficient is constant throughout the period, this transforma­
tion yields serially independent error terms. This transfor­
mation, along with the presence of a lagged dependent vari­
able, introduces nonstochastic independent variables, violating
one assumption of the BDE test. However, we know of no
other stability test that adequately deals with such problems.
It should be further noted that the BDE test is derived
on the assumption that the variance of the errors are equal.
In the case of money demand, the general increase in the
standard error of the equation when the sample period is ex­
tended casts cursory doubt on this assumption.
- TAs regards the BDE tests for the Goldfeld equation, one
should recall the above transformation required by the seri­
ally dependent error terms. In performing this transformation
we took the rho value from table 3 (0.922). This serial
coefficient was much larger than that found for the earlier
sample period (0.440). When the latter estimate is used, the
cusum-squares test rejects the null hypothesis at the 1 per­
cent level.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

DECEM BER

1979

C h a rt 1

Brow n-D urbin-Evans Test of
H am burger + CPR
C is im Sq uares
1.0

C isu m Sq u are s

.8

.6

.4

.2

T he d a s h e d lin e re p r e s e n ts th e 10 p e r c e n t le v e l of s ig n ific a n c e , th e g re e n lin e r e p r e s e n ts the 5 p e rc e n t le v e l.
L a te s t d a ta p lo tte d : 1st q u a rte r

C h a rt 2

Brow n-D urbin-Evans Test of
Unconstrained H am burger + CPR

1956 57

58

59

60

61

62

63

64

65

66

67

68

69

70

71

72

73

74

75

76 1977

The d a s h e d lin e re p r e s e n ts th e 5 p e r c e n t le v e l of s ig n ific a n c e , th e g re e n lin e re p re s e n ts th e 1 p e r c e n t le v e l.
L a te s t d a ta p lo tte d : 1st q u a rte r




Page 11

DECEM BER

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

C h a rt 3

Brow n-D urbin-Evans Test of
B. Friedm an

1956 57

58

59

60

61

62

63

64

65

66

67

6S

69

70

71

72

73

74

75

76 1977

The d a s h e d lin e re p r e s e n ts th e 5 p e r c e n t le v e l of s ig n ific a n c e , th e g re en lin e re p r e s e n ts th e 1 p e r c e n t le v e l.
L a te s t d a ta p lo tte d : 1st q u a rt e r

C h a rt 4

Brow n-D urbin-Evans Test of
G a rcia -P a k

1956 57

58

59

60

61

62

63

64

65

66

67

68

69

70

71

72

73

74

75

76 1977

The d a s h e d lin e re p r e s e n ts th e 5 p e r c e n t le v e l of s ig n ific a n c e , th e g re e n lin e re p r e s e n ts the 1 p e rc e n t le v e l.
L a te s t d a ta p lo tte d : 1st q u a rt e r


Page 12


1979

F E D E R A L. R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

DECEM BER

1979

C h a rt 5

Brow n-D urbin-Evans Test of
Laum as-Spencer

1956 57

58

59

60

61

62

63

64

65

66

67

68

69

70

71

72

73

74

75

76 1977

The d a s h e d lin e r e p r e s e n ts th e 5 p e r c e n t le v e l of s ig n ific a n c e , th e g re en lin e re p re s e n ts th e 1 p e r c e n t le v e l.
L a te s t d a t a p lo tte d : 1st q u a rte r

plot of Sr, each chart plots the mean value of Sr [i.e.,
E(Sr) = (r - k ) /( T - k)] and two confidence lines
which, for given levels of significance, are drawn par­
allel to the mean value line. When the plot of S,
crosses one of these boundaries, the hypothesis of sta­
bility can be rejected at the appropriate significance
level.
The charts reveal a varied picture of the timing of
the possible structural shift. Chart 1 — representing
the Sr plot for the Hamburger with CPR specification
— shows that at the 10 percent level the sample plot
first intersects the statistical boundary in 11/1966. At
the 5 percent level the Sr plot stays within the bound­
ary, though nearly touching the 5 percent line in
III/1971.
The Sr plot for the Unconstrained Hamburger with
CPR (chart 2) crosses the 5 percent boundary in
III/1974. Over the period 1966-74, however, the path
of Sr remains close to the 5 percent confidence band.
Chart 3, the Sr plot drawn for the Friedman specifica­
tion, indicates a structural shift ( at the. 5 percent
level) in 1/1966. Similar to chart 3, the Sr plot for the
Garcia-Pak specification (chart 4) indicates that at
the 1 percent level a shift in the underlying struc­
tural relationship occurred as early as IV/1962. Finally,
the path of Sr derived from the Laumus-Spencer



equation (chart 5) crosses the 5 percent confidence
line in 1/1970, and intersects the 1 percent line in
IV/1973.
An interesting feature of these results is that the
equations which indicated structural instability shifted
much earlier than might have been expected. The
finding of break points during the mid-1960s is at
odds with much of the recent literature which sug­
gests structural shifts later in the sample period.28
The results presented here do, however, tend to agree
with those of Slovin and Sushka who, using a money
demand equation in which demand deposits were
used as the definition of money, found evidence of
structural instability during the early 1960s.29 Their
work suggests that this shift was due to changes in
Regulation Q limits during this period.
28Applying the Quandt log-likelihood ratio test to these equa­
tions suggests the following possible points to structural shift
in the regression relationships: Hamburger with CPR, 1/1975;
Unconstrained Hamburger with CPR, III/1974; B. Friedman,
1/1974; Garcia-Pak, IV/1967; and Laumus-Spencer, IV /
1973. While these results are in general agreement with those
found by others ( e.g., Enzler, Johnson, and Paulus, Goldfeld,
Hamburger), the findings suggest that the structural instabil­
ity of these models may have occurred at various times over
the sample period.
29Myron B. Slovin and Marie Elizabeth Sushka, “The Structural
Shift in the Demand for Money,” The Journal of Finance
(June 1975), pp. 721-31.
Page 13

DECEM BER

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

In summary, these results indicate that many of the
money demand specifications which have been offered
as possible explanations of the missing money puzzle
have actually been subject to significant structural
changes over the II/1955-I/1977 sample period. A
most interesting finding is that the regression coeffi­
cients on the Goldfeld specification do not change
markedly when the sample period is extended to in­
clude the post-1973 period. In addition, when the
autocorrelation coefficient was constrained to be 0.92,
the equation did not indicate instability according to
the cusum-squares test.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSIONS
This article has examined the temporal stability of
several alternative money demand relationships. Re­
cent literature on money demand has drifted away
from this concern and has focused too narrowly on
the issue of predicting post-1972 real money balances.
The formal test results presented in this article sug­
gest that such a shift in emphasis has been misleading.
The findings in this paper indicate that, while sev­
eral of the respecifications of the traditional transac­
tion money demand relationship have yielded accu­

1979

rate post-1972 forecasts relative to those found for the
real adjustment version of the Goldfeld specification,
none of the modifications which stood up under criti­
cal review was temporally stable over the entire
II/1955-I/1977 sample period. The modifications con­
sidered here included changing the measurement of
the scale variable, broadening the asset range to in­
clude long-term yields, and redefining money to incor­
porate repurchase agreements.
The test employed in this paper (the BDE cusumsquares test) did not allow us to reject the hypothesis
that the underlying relationship between the prede­
termined variables and real money balances, given by
the conventional Goldfeld specification, was stable.
In fact, the regression coefficients for the sample pe­
riod including the turbulent period I/1973-I/1977 were
markedly similar to those found when the sample pe­
riod was ended in IV/1972. This finding indicates that
the purported breakdown in this specification was
overemphasized as a result of the reliance on the short­
term predictive ability of the equation. In terms of
policy implications, this finding suggests that long­
term monetary policy prescriptions based on the as­
sumption of a stable money demand relationship will
be more reliable than previous analysis has implied.

Appendix: Data Definitions and Sources
Commercial paper rate (C P R ) — 4-6 month prime
commercial paper rate. Prior to III/1 9 7 4 average o f
most representative daily offering. After III/1 9 7 4
average o f midpoint o f range o f daily dealer closing
rates.
Source: Federal Reserve Hank o f New York

Price level (P ) — implicit gross national product price
deflator (1972 = 100)
Source: U.S. Department o f Commerce, Bureau of
Econom ic Analysis
Time deposit rate (R T D )
Source: Stephen M . Goldfeld

Long-term U.S. government bond yields (R G L )
Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin

Dividend price ratio on common stocks (D P R )
Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin

M oney stock ( M l ) — narrowly defined money bal­
ances (in billions o f dollars), seasonally adjusted,
quarterly average o f monthly figures.
Source: Federal Reserve Board

Permanent income — exponentially weighted average
o f past values o f real gross national product.
Source: David E. Spencer
Household net worth (w ealth)

Incom e ( y ) — gross national product in billions o f 1972
dollars at seasonally adjusted annual rates.
Source: U.S. Department o f Commerce, Bureau of
Econom ic Analysis

Digitized forPage
FRASER
14


Source: Federal Reserve Board
Immediately available funds (I A F )
Source: Garcia-Pak, “ The Ratio o f Currency.”

Outlook for Food and Agriculture —1980
CLIFTON B. LUTTRELL and NEIL A. STEVENS
The U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) annually appraises the outlook
for food and agriculture for the year ahead. These appraisals for 1980, sum­
marized below, have been made on the basis of a number of factors which
influence the supply and demand for farm products and food. Such factors in­
clude the size of livestock and poultry inventories, the incentive for feeding,
feedstocks, stocks of other crops available for food processing, and the prospects
for other crops which have not been harvested. The outlook for food and farm
product demand reflects both domestic and foreign demand. Domestic demand
is based largely on prospects for national income, and foreign demand is based
largely on crop supplies, crop conditions, and prospects for income abroad.1
The U.S. government’s embargo of grain shipments to the Soviet Union oc­
curred as this article was being completed for publication. This action obviously
can have a large effect on the food and agricultural outlook for 1980 and, beyond.

I
OOD prices are projected by the USDA to in­
crease by about 8 percent for 1980. This is well be­
low both the 11 percent increase in 1979 and the
overall rate of inflation projected by most analysts
for 1980.
A larger supply of most food products is in pros­
pect for 1980. Large crops in 1979 provide the base
for expanded food processing and livestock feeding.
The large feed crops point to increased production
of livestock foods, especially pork, poultry, and dairy
products. Egg production may also be slightly higher
than in 1979. The supply of canned and frozen vege­
tables is up 6 to 7 percent. The larger oilseed crop
points to increased supplies of fats and oils and feed
by-products.

during the period 1965-70, and to an 8.8 percent
rate during 1970-75 (table 1). They have continued
to increase since 1975 at an average rate of 6.4 per­
cent per year. Most of the increase in the price of
food since the mid-1960s can be traced to rising
demand. Since the consumer price index (CPI) has
accelerated since 1965, it is apparent that the rate of
increase in demand for all consumer goods and serv­
ices has exceeded output growth.
Table 1

Change in Consumer Prices, Food Prices,
and Percent of Farm Products Exported
Rate of Change of
Consumer Prices

Food Prices Since the Mid-1960s
Food prices began to accelerate along with the
rate of inflation in the mid-1960s and have increased
at a relatively high rate throughout most of the 1970s.
From an annual rate of increase of less than 1.5 per­
cent per year during the decade 1955-65, food prices
accelerated to a 4.0 percent annual rate of increase
1Unless otherwise noted, all projections for food and farm
products included in this article are based on reports and
speeches given at the USDA Agricultural Outlook conference
in Washington, D.C., November 5-8, 1979, and other recent
USDA publications.



Percent of Farm
Products Exported*

A ll Items
Less Food

Food

1950-55

2 .3 %

1 .8 %

1 0 .6 %

1 9 55-60

2.2

1.5

13.2
15.2

Years

1960-65

1.3

1.4

1 9 65-70

4 .3

4 .0

14.5

1970-75

6.1

8.8

20.1

1975-78

6.8

6 .4

2 4.8

1 9 50-70

2.5

2,2

13.4

1970-78

6 .4

7 .9

2 1.8

1950-78

3 .6

3 .8

15.8

*Average of 1951-1955, 1956-1960, 1961-1965, etc.
SOURCE: Economic Reports
Indicators.

of

the

President

and

Economic

Page 15

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

DECEM BER

Table 2

Tab le 3

Change in Farm Output, Industrial Production,
and Relative Food Prices
195019 70

19701975

Percent Change
Component

1 .5 7 %

2 .4 5 %

2 .2 9 %

Industrial Production Index
(R ate of change)

4 .4 8

1 .79

7 .1 9

Food Prices minus Prices of
A lt Items less Food
(Rates of change)

- .3 2

- 1 .6 3

2 .08

.6 7

- .2 0

- 2 .4 4

SOURCE: Economic Reports o f the President.

It is now generally conceded that excessive de­
mand and inflation in all sectors occur largely as a
result of excessive monetary growth. During the
1950s and early 1960s, the stock of money rose at an
average rate of 1.5 percent per year. It accelerated to
3.8 percent per year from 1962 until late 1966 and
to 5.8 percent per year from late 1966 to early 1970.
Since then, monetary growth has averaged about 6.5
percent per year.
In the long run, monetary growth predominantly
influences the average rate of inflation since all sec­
tors make about the same fundamental adjustments
in response to excessive demand. If resources are
fully utilized and production techniques are un­
changed, rising demand for goods and services
caused by an increase in the stock of money will not
lead to major changes in the relative prices of food
and other consumer goods. Rather, prices of all goods
and all resources will tend to be bid up equally over
the long run.
In M ost Years Food Prices Rose Less
Than Nonfood Prices
Nonmonetary factors can affect the relative prices
of food and other consumer goods. Such factors in­
clude changing consumer tastes and preferences, un­
even rates of technological growth in the various
sectors of the economy, population growth, changing
weather conditions, and changing foreign demand.
Relative prices have changed during most five-year
periods since 1950. As indicated in table 1, food
prices rose at a slower rate than the average price of
other consumer items from 1950 to 1970 and from
1975 to 1978, but at a faster rate from 1970 to 1975.
The rise in food prices relative to other consumer
Digitized forPage
FRASER
16


Changes in Food 1Prices for
1979 and Forecasts for 1980

19751978

Farm Output
(R ate of change)

Farm Product Prices minus Prices
of A ll Industrial Commodities
(Rates of change)

1979

A ll food

Relative
Importance
1 0 0 .0

19781979

19791980

1 1 .0 %

8 .0 %

Food a w a y from home

3 0 .4

11 .3

9 .7

Food at home

6 9 .6

10.8

6 .8

Cereals and bakery
products

8.5

9.8

8.9

Beef and veal

9 .3

2 7 .9

8.2

Pork

5 .6

1.5

- 5 .6

O ther meats

3 .0

1 4 .6

4 .5

Poultry

2 .5

4 .7

- 0 .6

Fish and seafood

2.3

9 .8

9 .2

Eggs

1.4

9 .4

- 1 .3

D airy products

9 .3

11.1

9 .2

Fresh fruits

2.4

14.1

7 .3

Fresh vegetables

2.5

2.9

8 .4

Processed fruits and
vegetables

4.8

9 .0

8.2

Sugar and sweets

2 .4

8.1

8.0

Fats and oils

2.0

8.0

7 .4

Nonalcoholic beverages

7 .8

4 .7

7 .9

O ther prepared foods

5.8

10.2

9 .2

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Agriculture.

prices in 1970-75, however, does not necessarily indi­
cate the beginning of a high food-cost era in the
United States. Despite a possible slowing, the rate of
food production is still expected to exceed the rate of
population growth. U.S. population in the 1980s is
projected to grow at a modest .70-.75 percent rate,
well below the 1.5 percent rate projected for food
output. Hence, a rising quantity of food per capita
is in prospect for U.S. consumers.
One factor contributing to the more rapid increase
in food than nonfood prices during 1970-75 was the
sharp increase in export demand for U.S. farm prod­
ucts. Export demand for farm products rose as a re­
sult of reductions in tariffs and other trade barriers.
Also contributing to rising export demand was the
decline in the foreign exchange value of the dollar
in the early 1970s when the United States abandoned
the gold exchange standard.
As shown in table 1, farm exports rose from an
average of 14.5 percent of farm commodity sales dur­
ing 1966-70 to 20.1 percent of sales during 1971-75,
to 24.8 percent during 1976-78. In contrast, the ratio
of farm exports to sales was relatively stable in the
1950s and 1960s, rising from 10.6 percent in the first

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

DECEM BER

1979

Tab le 4

Percent of Disposable Personal Income
Spent on Selected Groups of Consumer Goods

Total durable goods

1950

1955

1960

1965

1970

1975

1978

1979*

1 5 .0 %

1 4 .1 %

1 2 .3 %

1 3 .3 %

1 2 .4 %

1 2 .2 %

1 3 .7 %

1 3 .3 %

Motor vehicles & parts

6 .7

6 .5

5 .6

6 .3

5.1

4 .9

6 .2

5 .9

Furniture & household equipment

6 .7

5 .9

5.1

5 .2

5 .3

5 .3

5 .3

5 .2

4 7 .8

4 4 .9

4 3 .2

3 9 .9

3 8 .6

3 7 .6

3 6 .4

3 6 .3

2 6 .2

2 4 .6

2 3 .2

2 0 .9

1 9.9

1 9.3

18 .6

1 8 .6

Clothing & shoes

9 .5

8 .4

7 .6

7.1

6 .8

6 .4

6 .2

6.1

G aso line & oil

2 .7

3.1

3 .4

3.1

3.2

3 .6

3 .5

3 .7

3 0 .7

3 3 .7

3 7 .4

3 7 .8

3 9 .2

4 0 .3

4 2 .5

4 2 .7

Total nondurable goods
Food

Services
♦Annual rate for first two quarters.

SOURCE: Economic Reports o f the President and Economic Indicators.

half of the fifties to 14.5 percent in the last half of
the sixties. It has stabilized again in the last three
years, with exports totaling 25.2 percent of sales in
1975 and 24.6 percent in 1978.
The acceleration of foreign demand for U.S. food
and farm products in the early 1970s resulted in sharply
higher farm product prices which in turn led to an
increase in farm output growth. Farm output growth
rose from 1.6 percent per year during the two decades
1950-70 to 2.5 percent per year in 1970-75 (table 2).
While farm output accelerated in response to rising
foreign demand for U.S. farm products, industrial pro­
duction decelerated in response to rising imports of
nonfarm products and higher energy costs, declining
from a 4.5 percent rate of increase in 1950-70 to a
1.8 percent rate in 1970-75.
The increase in farm exports and nonfood imports
was associated with the faster growth in food than
nonfood prices in the early 1970s. Rising farm ex­
ports led to relatively higher farm commodity prices,
and rising imports to relatively lower prices on non­
farm goods. Food prices rose about 2 percentage
points faster than nonfood products and service
prices during 1970-75 (table 2). Since 1975, however,
the growth in farm commodity exports has decel­
erated, and food prices have increased at a somewhat
slower rate than nonfood prices.
Food Price Increases to Moderate in 1980
While food prices and the CPI rose at about the
same rate from 1978 to 1979, food prices are expected
to rise at a somewhat slower pace than other con­
sumer items in 1980 and to average only about 8
percent higher than in 1979 (table 3). This is well
below the 10 percent rate of inflation projected



by the USDA outlook conference participants. The
USDA projects moderate increases in food prices for
the early months of the year reflecting larger prospec­
tive supplies of pork and poultry and a possible
slackening in demand growth. More rapid increases,
however, are projected for the last half of the year
because of a potential decline in meat output and
rising overall demand due to economic recovery.
Most of the increase in food prices projected for
1980 stems from the rising marketing costs of domes­
tic farm products and from higher prices for fish and
imported food products. Assuming no serious weatherrelated problems, the farm price of food is expected
to average only about 1 percent higher in 1980 than
in 1979. Rising marketing costs, reflecting the pace
of inflation, are expected to continue throughout the
year and to account for about 75 percent of all food
price increases.
Major price increases for individual food products,
such as the 28 percent increase for beef and veal in
1979, are not anticipated. Commercial beef produc­
tion is expected to total about the same in 1980 as in
1979. Pork production, however, may be 10 percent
greater, thus holding down the increases in overall red
meat prices. The greatest price increases are projected
for food consumed in restaurants and other eating es­
tablishments. The price of such food, which accounts
for about 30 percent of the average urban family’s
food budget, will probably increase by about 10 per­
cent largely reflecting higher service costs. Dairy prod­
uct prices are expected to rise about 9 percent as a
result of higher government support prices for milk.
Other prices projected to rise rapidly are those with
relatively large processing and marketing costs such as
cereals, bakery products, and other prepared foods.
Lower prices are expected for pork, poultry, and eggs.
Page 17

DECEM BER

F E D E R A L. R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

Food Expenditures and Consumption
Expenditures on food as a percent of disposable
personal income have trended down for most of the
century and, on the basis of current income and food
price projections, are likely to continue down through
1980. As shown in table 4, food expenditures declined
from 26.2 percent of disposable personal income in
1950 to 18.6 percent in 1978. The outlook for an in­
crease in food production and a moderation in food
price increases means that a further decline will likely
occur in 1980.
Total food consumption per capita has been rela­
tively stable for more than a decade. In 1979, per
capita food consumption was estimated at 104.8 per­
cent of the 1967 level, about the same as in the two
previous years but slightly less than in 1976 (table
5). Per capita consumption of poultry and vegetable
oils has trended up while consumption of red meat,
dairy products, cereal, and bakery products has re­
mained about the same, and eggs and animal fats
has declined. With somewhat larger supplies of food
and relatively moderate food price increases in pros­
pect for the year, per capita consumption of all foods
may rise slightly from the 1979 level.

OUTLOOK FOR AGRICULTURE
Following two generally prosperous years for most
farmers, the outlook by USDA analysts for farm in­
come in 1980 is not optimistic. Net income of farm
operators may decline from about $32 billion in 1979
to about $25 billion in 1980.
Table 5

Change in Per Capita Food Consumption1
( 1 9 6 7 = 100)
1976

1977

1978

19792

A ll food

1 0 5.8

1 0 4 .7

1 0 4 .6

104.8

Anim al products

103.5

103.1

102.1

102.1

M eat

1 0 7 .9

1 0 7 .0

1 0 3 .0

100.5

Poultry

1 1 6 .0

1 1 9 .4

12 5 .9

1 3 6 .7

Egg*
D airy

8 5 .5

8 4 .8

8 6 .5

8 7 .7

10 1 .6

1 0 1 .0

101 .5

1 0 2 .0

1 0 8 .4

1 0 6 .4

1 0 7 .4

107.8

Fruits

107.1

1 0 5 .9

106.1

107.1

V egetables

1 0 7 .2

1 0 7 .0

1 0 8 .6

109.2

C ereal and bakery

1 0 4 .0

10 0.8

1 0 1 .4

1 0 1 .4

V egetable oils

1 4 6 .4

1 4 0 .2

1 4 7 .9

142.1

Crop products

individual items combined, using 1967-69 prices.
Prelim inary.
SOURCE: U.S. Department o f Agriculture.

Page 18



1979

USDA analysts did not anticipate the gain in net
farm income of about $4 billion in 1979 at last year’s
outlook conference. Although they expected some in­
crease in net income due to rising livestock receipts,
the large increase in crop receipts came as a surprise.
This increase resulted primarily from a rise in export
demand, in part due to a crop shortfall in the Soviet
Union. When the final tally is made, 1979 crop re­
ceipts will be about $63 billion, up $11 billion from
1978, while livestock receipts will be about $67 bil­
lion, up $8 billion. These cash receipt estimates total
$130 billion, 17 percent above the 1978 amount. Gross
farm income (which includes cash receipts, inventory
value changes, government payments, and nonmoney
income) is expected to total $146 billion, up from
$126 billion in 1978 (table 6).
Production expenses also rose sharply in 1979 total­
ing about $114 billion, up about 16 percent from 1978.
Most of this increase was due to higher prices for
feed, livestock, and fuel, and to higher interest pay­
ments. Fuel expenditures, for example, increased
about 40 percent over the 1978 level and accounted
for about 6 percent of total farm production costs.
Assuming normal weather and crop yields, total
farm cash receipts in 1980 are expected to rise only
2 or 3 percent. Most of the increase will be from crop
sales where prices are expected to average somewhat
higher. Cash receipts will likely be up for most crops
except oilseeds. Livestock cash receipts may total
about the same as last year. Receipts from dairy
products and cattle may rise, but it is likely that this
will be offset by declines in hog and poultry sales.
Production expenses in 1980 are expected to rise
faster than gross income, resulting in a lower net in­
come. Most of this increase reflects higher prices re­
sulting from inflation. Among those inputs that are
expected to show rapid price increases are fuel and
fertilizer. Fuel prices may increase 33 percent or more.
Feed, pesticides, and other farm chemicals may also
rise, but less rapidly than the rate of inflation.
The outlook for farm income in 1980 is subject to
considerable uncertainty, particularly in the second
half of the year. Crop receipts will depend substan­
tially on domestic and foreign weather developments.
Unfavorable weather conditions and lower crop yields
would result in a greater increase in cash receipts
than currently anticipated. On the other hand, unusu­
ally favorable weather could result in no gain or even
a small decline in crop receipts. Because of govern­
ment price support and reserve programs, however,
cash receipts will not decline drastically. Returns to
livestock producers will depend not only on 1980 crop

DECEM BER

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

1979

Aggregate farm income measures also
fail
to reflect the sizable differences in
Farm Income
income among individual farmers and
(B illio n s of D ollars)
types of farming operations. The returns
1979
1978
197 7
197 5
197 6
on resources from various farming oper­
$ 1 4 6 .0
$ 1 2 6 .0
$ 1 0 8 .5
$ 1 0 1 .8
$ 1 0 0 .3
Gross Income
ations over the long run must tend to­
1 3 0 .0
111.1
9 4 .8
9 5 .6
88 .2
M arketing Receipts
ward equality since resources will be
16 .0
1 2 .9
14.9
12.1
7 .0
O ther Income1
switched from lower return to higher re­
1 1 4 .0
8 8.8
98.1
7 5 .9
83.1
Production Expenses
turn uses. In the short run, however, ag­
gregate income measures may not reflect
3 2 .0
2 7 .9
19.8
2 4 .5
1 8 .7
Net Farm Income
(current d o llars)
the financial status of individual fanners
whose income depends on such factors
1 4 .7
1 0 .9
14.3
15.2
1 1 .0
Net Farm Income
(1 9 6 7 d o llars)
as the particular commodity produced,
farm size, and local weather patterns. In
includes inventory value changes, direct government payments, and nonmoney and other
income items.
1980,
for example, returns to pork
SOURCE: U.S. Department o f Agriculture.
poultry producers are likely to remain
relatively low whereas returns to grain and feeder
production and prices, but also on how quickly pro­
cattle producers may be relatively high.
ducers of pork and poultry respond to current market
signals to moderate production increases. For ex­
ample, if hog producers cut back plans for farrowing
Crop Outlook
this winter so that pork supplies rise more slowly in
the second half of next year, livestock and poultry
Major factors that contributed to the rise in crop
prices and cash receipts will be higher than now
prices and the income of producers in 1979 were the
anticipated.
favorable growing and harvesting conditions in the
United States and the shortfall in Soviet Union har­
In addition to these supply factors, overall demand
vests. The Soviets experienced a 20 percent decline
for farm products is quite uncertain for 1980. Global
in coarse grain and a 29 percent decline in wheat
demand for food is expected to rise, but at a reduced
production. Wheat production was also down in sev­
pace from the past two years. Recent OPEC oil price
eral major exporting nations, including Canada, Aus­
increases plus more restrictive monetary policies in a
tralia, and Argentina. This decline increased foreign
number of countries suggest that overall economic
demand for U.S. food and feed grains, thus placing
growth is likely to slow further in 1980. It is assumed,
upward pressure on grain prices. With relatively high
however, that a recession will not be as severe as in
yields and record grain crops, U.S. producers bene­
1974-75. Should a severe recession develop, however,
food demand will slow more than currently antici­
fited from these rising prices (table 7).
pated, and farm prices and farm income will be lower
than currently forecast.
Table 7
While measures of farm income are useful in judg­
Yields of Major U.S. Crops
ing the general financial position of farmers, they can
(p er harvested acre)
also be misleading. The concept of farm income
1979
1978
1977
1976
measures only the annual income flows to the farm
3 4 .0
3 1 .6
3 0 .6
30 .3
sector from farming operations. This measure does not
W h e a t(b u )
take into account capital gains or losses, which affect
4 ,5 6 8
4 ,4 9 3
4 ,4 1 2
4 ,6 6 3
Rice (lb s )
the wealth of farmers.
Table 6

In the past decade the nominal value of all pro­
ductive assets used in agriculture has tripled; in
1979 the value of farm assets is estimated to have in­
creased 16 percent over 1978. Real estate holdings
comprise about three-fourths of farm assets and have
been the leading source of capital gains in farming.
Farmland vahies in 1979 rose about 16 percent. Such
capital gains are a source of increased wealth to
farmers not measured in the cash flow from farming
operations.



Feed G rain
(m etric tons)

_

1.88

2.08

2 .2 4

Corn (b u )

8 7 .9

9 0 .7

101.2

1 0 6 .4

Sorghum (b u )

4 8 .9

5 6 .3

55.1

6 3 .7
53.1

O ats (b u )

4 5 .7

5 5 .8

5 2 .2

Barley (b u )

4 4 .9

4 3 .9

4 8 .4

4 8 .9

Soybeans (b u)

26.1

3 0 .6

2 9 .5

3 1 .5

4 65

520

421

528

Cotton (lb s)

SOURCE: U.S. Department o f Agriculture.

Page 19

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

The upward price pressure from the reduced crops
abroad, however, was moderated by the generally
large grain inventories carried over from previous
years. For example, world grain stocks at the beginning
of the current marketing year totaled 227 million tons,
about 16 percent of annual use.2 Despite reduced pro­
duction, world grain consumption in the 1979-80 mar­
keting year is expected to rise slightly. This contrasts
with some other years when declines in output had
more severe consequences. For example, production
in 1974-75 declined less than 4 percent, but due to
smaller grain inventories, world consumption declined
2% percent.
World grain stocks will be reduced during the cur­
rent marketing year so that carryover inventories are
projected at 195 million tons, or 13.7 percent of
use. This ratio of stocks to use is below the 15 per­
cent and 14 percent levels held at the end of 1976-77
and 1977-78, respectively, but larger than the 11 per­
cent at the end of 1975-76. Grain stocks in the United
States have been replenished in recent years after
being drawn down earlier in the 1970s.
Food Grains — W heat and Rice
U.S. wheat and rice production increased substan­
tially in 1979, while foreign production of these crops
declined sharply. U.S. wheat production totaled 57.5
million tons, up 17 percent from 1978. There was an
8 percent increase in acres planted and a favorable
growing season, which resulted in higher yields per
harvested acre and a larger percent of the acres
planted being harvested.
Export demand for wheat has been very strong
largely because of the 29 percent reduction in the
Soviet Union’s wheat crop. Exports for the 1979-80
season are projected at 1.4 billion bushels, up 17 per­
cent from last year. Total usage of U.S.-produced
wheat is forecast at about 2.2 billion bushels, up 7
percent from last year and slightly above the 2.1 bil­
lion bushels produced. Stocks at the end of the 197980 marketing year are estimated to decline about 8
percent to around 850 million bushels.
Strong export demand has led to higher wheat
prices over the past several months despite the large
U.S. crop. Prices in the 1979-80 marketing year are
expected to average about $3.75 per bushel, up from
$2.94 last year. With higher prices in prospect for
1980 and no set-aside acreage restrictions (for pro­
ducers to be eligible for target-price protection, loans,
and the farmer-owned reserve), wheat acreage is ex-

DECEM BER

1979

pected to increase about 10 percent. Production, how­
ever, is not likely to rise by 10 percent as yields will
likely decline from the unusually high yields of
1978-79.
U.S. rice production was estimated at a record
139.6 million cwt., an increase of 4 percent over 1978.
The combined domestic and export use of rice is
expected to increase somewhat in 1979-80, though
still remaining below production levels. Rice stocks
at the end of the 1979-80 marketing year are likely
to rise to around 42 million cwt., or a stock-to-use
ratio of 32 percent. However, farm prices for rice are
expected to average about $9.75 per cwt., up from $8
in 1978-79.
World rice production is forecast at 369 million
tons in 1979-80 (rough basis), down 4 percent from
1978-79. World utilization of rice is expected to be
near 1978-79 levels, and world stocks are expected
to be reduced somewhat. The stock-to-use ratio is
expected to remain at about 9.5 percent, well above
the 5 percent for the 1972-74 period.
Feed Grains — Corn, Sorghum, Oats,
Barley, and Rye
U.S. feed grain production increased about 5.5 per­
cent in 1979. With the help of large beginning stocks,
the total supply for the 1979-80 marketing year is up
6.4 percent. Com production was up nearly 7.6 mil­
lion bushels, or 7 percent, and sorghum production
was up 10.3 percent. These increases more than offset
the declines in barley, oats, and rye.
Domestic use of feed grains is expected to rise only
slightly in 1979-80 since livestock feeding is not ex­
pected to increase substantially. Exports of feed grains,
however, are expected to increase sharply (about 17
percent), again a reflection of the sharp drop in
Soviet production. Under the five-year US/USSR bi­
lateral grains agreement, the Soviet Union can pur­
chase up to 25 million tons of United States wheat
and corn in the October 1979 to September 1980 pe­
riod without further consultation. Consequently, ex­
ports to the Soviet Union and elsewhere are expected
to increase about 12 percent in 1979-80, and the
United States share of world feed grain exports is
expected to increase from 64 percent to 70 percent.3
With the increase in export demand and a slight
increase in domestic demand, U.S. feed grain stocks
will be up only slightly by the end of the 1979-80
marketing year despite the large crops last fall. Prices
are expected to average higher than in 1978-79. For

2
A marketing year begins with the beginning of the harvesting
season for most crops. Thus, the marketing year varies for
3These export estimates represent the outlook prior to the
embargo.
different crops.
Page 20



F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

example, com prices are expected to average about
$2.40 a bushel, compared with $2.20 a bushel last
season.
With the projected decline in world feed grain
stocks, the USDA has not established a set-aside pro­
gram for feed grains in 1980. All producers, however,
will be eligible for target price protection, loans, and
the farmer-owned reserve program. Current price re­
lationships indicate that acreage planted to com in
1980 will increase and acreage planted to soybeans
will decline.
Oilseeds
In contrast to the expected decline in world food
and feed grain crops, oilseed production in 1979-80
is forecast to be up about 13 percent. In the Southern
Hemisphere, these crops won’t be harvested until
spring (their fall), but a sizable increase in this pro­
duction is expected. U.S. oilseed production in 197980 was up 23 percent from a year earlier. Soybean
production was up nearly 20 percent accounting for
about three-fourths of this gain. Sunflower seed pro­
duction doubled, and cottonseed production rose
about 35 percent.
Growth in world demand for oilseed products in
1979-80 is expected to slow somewhat because of
slower economic growth and smaller increases in live­
stock production. Consequently, an increase in world
stocks of oilseeds is likely by the end of the market­
ing year. With world oilseed supplies at record levels,
prices have been subject to downward pressure. Soy­
bean prices are expected to average about $6.15 per
bushel in the 1979-80 season, below last year’s $6.75
per bushel. Demand for soybeans is expected to ex­
pand in 1979-80, but quantities available for con­
sumption are about 66 million tons, up 19 percent
from a year ago. Total soybean use is expected to
expand about 8 percent, but carryover inventories
next September will be up about 11 million tons,
double that of September 1979. The prospect of lower
soybean prices and relatively high prices of some
competing crops will probably lead to a decline in
acreage planted to soybeans this spring.
Cotton and Tobacco
World cotton fiber production in 1979-80 is esti­
mated to be 7 percent above 1978-79, with most of
the increase occurring in the United States. U.S. cot­
ton production in 1979-80 was estimated to be 14.5
million bales, 34 percent above a year earlier and
about the same as in 1977-78.



DECEM BER

1979

Demand for U.S. cotton is expected to increase this
year largely because of increased foreign demand.
Domestic mill use may fall slightly, but exports are
likely to total 7.0 million bales, up from 6.2 million
a year ago. Since production exceeded expected usage,
stocks will rise to about 5.3 million bales at the end
of the current marketing year, up from 4.0 million
bales last year and about the same as the year before.
Prices at the farm level may average below the gov­
ernment target price, making producers eligible for
deficiency payments.
Tobacco production was down about 22 percent in
1979. This decline reflects both reduced acreage
(down about 11 percent) and reduced yields. Be­
cause of a substantial carryover, however, total to­
bacco supplies are down only about 7 percent. Fluecured tobacco prices increased only about 4 percent
in 1979 whereas burley tobacco prices rose to an alltime high, exceeding the previous record of $1.31 per
pound in 1978.
Production of tobacco is heavily influenced by gov­
ernment price support programs. Under current legis­
lation, price supports for eligible tobaccos must rise
about 9 percent in 1980. The national marketing
quota for flue-cured tobacco, 1,095 million pounds in
1979, will increase somewhat in 1980. On the other
hand, the burley tobacco quota is expected to re­
main at the 1979 level of about 614 million pounds.
Livestock Outlook
The livestock outlook continues to be influenced by
the supply and demand fluctuations of the early 1970s.
The sharp increase in export demand for feed grain
in the early seventies as well as the U.S. crop failure
in 1974 have contributed to a sharp increase in domes­
tic feed prices, low returns to feedlot operations, and
the prolonged liquidation of beef herds. Beef cattle
production responds to changing supply and demand
factors only after a considerable time lag. For ex­
ample, when livestock feeding became generally
profitable following the large grain harvests of 1977
and 1978, sharp increases in pork and poultry pro­
duction soon occurred. Beef herds, however, were
still being reduced, increasing the supply of beef and
depressing prices. Since 1975 pork and broiler pro­
duction have increased 31 and 38 percent, respec­
tively. Meanwhile, beef production continued down,
dropping 4 percent in 1978 and 12 percent in 1979
when beef herd liquidation ended. With more young
female cattle being added to herds for reproduction,
beef production will remain relatively low for another
year or two.
Page 21

DECEM BER

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

Beef Cattle
Prospects in 1980 for cattle producers, especially
cow-calf operators, are more favorable than for pork
and poultry producers. Cattle herds have been re­
duced about 16 percent since 1975. In the initial
phase of the reduction, beef supplies were increased
and prices depressed by the increased slaughter of
breeding herds and calves. As herds were reduced
and the calf crop fell, beef output declined. As a re­
sult, cattle prices have been rising since the beginning
of 1978. In 1979 cattle producers began to rebuild
herds by holding back part of the calf crop for breed­
ing purposes and reducing the number of animals for
slaughter.
In 1980 cattle and calf slaughter is expected to be
near the reduced 1979 level. Total meat supplies,
however, will increase to record levels because of the
expected increases in pork and poultry production in
the first half of the year. Choice steer prices may
average near $70 per hundred pounds during the
first half of 1980. Prices, however, may increase in
the second half of the year if pork and poultry pro­
ducers slow production in response to unfavorable
profit margins.

Hogs
Hog production in 1979 increased 15 percent over
the previous year as producers responded to higher
profit margins. These gains, however, were offset by a
13 percent decline in beef and veal so that total red
meat production increased only a small amount.
The decline in pork prices and the sharp increase
in feed costs in the second half of 1979 greatly re­
duced profitability for hog producers and will affect
future production decisions. Production in the first
half of 1980, however, will be heavily influenced by
decisions already made. For example, hog slaughter
in the first half of 1980 will come largely from the
September pig inventory and the September-November pig crop. The number of pigs weighing less than
60 lbs. on September 1 was up 16 percent, and far­
rowing intentions for the September-November period
were up 13 percent from a year earlier. Hence, pork
production will be up about 17 percent during the
first half of 1980.
Production will be increased even more if hog pro­
ducers reduce their breeding herds. Large supplies
are likely to keep hog prices relatively low (at least
through mid-1980), with the price of barrows and
gilts averaging in the mid $30s per hundredweight.
Many hog producers may experience losses in the
Digitized for Page
FRASER
22


1979

first half, but an improvement could occur by yearend if farrowings in the March-May period are near
year-earlier levels. In this case, pork production at the
end of 1980 would be only slightly above earlier lev­
els, and hog prices could average in the upper $30s
per hundredweight in the second half of the year.
Poultry
Poultry producers also face less favorable price and
income prospects in 1980. Broiler production gener­
ally has been profitable over the past four years, but
profit margins turned down last fall as a result of ris­
ing feed costs and falling broiler prices. Production
costs are expected to continue to rise while broiler
prices are expected to remain considerably below
year-ago levels. Returns to most producers, therefore,
may not cover all expenses (including fixed costs).
These prospects have already begun to slow produc­
tion, and a further slowing will occur if current con­
ditions persist or worsen. Thus, output may be near
year-ago levels by spring.
Broiler prices were generally favorable until mid1979 when large increases in pork and broiler produc­
tion led to depressed prices. Increased pork produc­
tion early this year is expected to keep broiler prices
well below year-ago levels during the first half of the
year. Should pork production decline to the year-ago
levels after mid-year, broiler prices may rise above
the 1979 level, but with substantially higher costs in
prospect, profit margins will be well below a year
earlier.
Dairying
Producers of dairy products experienced a relatively
profitable year in 1979 and the milk-feed price ratio
is expected to remain at a generally profitable level
this year. Milk prices rose an average of 14 percent
in 1979. This increase largely reflected market forces
as government purchases of milk under the price sup­
port program were relatively small. Beginning in June,
milk production began to increase and for the year
was about IV* percent higher than in 1978.
Farm prices for milk in 1980 are expected to rise
about 10 percent with most of the gain occurring in the
second half. A year-to-year increase in prices is ex­
pected because higher government support prices
have already been announced and the adjustment of
production support prices is due to occur again in
April. Should milk production increase as expected
and demand growth subside, government purchases
of milk would be much higher in 1980 than the rela­
tively small purchases of 1979. Nonetheless, higher

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUIS

prices for milk are likely to be offset by rising prices
of inputs, particularly higher feed prices. The milkfeed price ratio, however, is expected to remain gen­
erally favorable for producers. Consequently, milk
production in 1980 will probably be up about 1
percent.

SUMMARY
According to the USDA analysts, food prices are
likely to increase only about 8 percent in 1980, less
than the expected rate of inflation. Most of the in­
crease will result from rising processing and market­
ing costs rather than prices at the farm level. Indeed,

DECEM BER

1979

farm commodity prices are expected to average only
about 1 percent higher than a year ago.
Net farm incomes are expected to decline in 1980
from the 1979 level. Cash farm receipts are expected
to increase 2 or 3 percent, but production expenses
will likely continue up at about the same rate as
general inflation. Consequently, net farm income may
be down to about $25 billion, $7 billion less than in
1979. Net incomes will be above average for producers
of most crops except soybeans and for dairy and cowcalf operators. Net incomes for producers of poultry,
eggs, hogs, and fat cattle, however, are likely to be
down from year-earlier levels.

Review Index -1 9 7 9
Jan.

The "Danger” From Foreign Ownership of U.S.
Farmland

June

Do Rising U.S. Interest Rates Imply a Stronger
Dollar?

Disintermediation: An Old Disorder With A
New Remedy
Operations of the Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis — 1978
Feb.

July

Aug.

The FOMC in 1978: Clarifying the Role of the
Aggregates
Benefits of Borrowing from the Federal Reserve
When the Discount Rate is Below Market
Interest Rates

Apr.

Did Discount Rate Changes Affect the Foreign
Exchange Value of the Dollar During
1978?
May

Sept. The Productivity Problem
Repurchase Agreements
Oct.

Formulating Economic Policy for 1979 and Be­
yond: Old Problems and New Constraints
Do Floating Ceilings Solve the Usury Rate
Problem?

Energy Prices and Capital Formation: 19721977
Monetary Targets — Their Contribution to Pol­
icy Formation




Inflation and Personal Saving: An Update
Does Eurodollar Borrowing Improve the Dol­
lar’s Exchange Value?

1979 Food and Agricultural Outlook
Mar.

Rising Farm Exports and International Trade
Policies
Government Debt Financing — Its Effects in
View of Tax Discounting

Automatic Transfers and the Money Supply
Process
Economic Developments in 1978

Alternative Measures of the Monetary Base

TTL Note Accounts and the Money Supply
Process
Explaining the Economic Slowdown of 1979:
A Supply and Demand Approach

Nov. Money Stock Control Under Alternative Defini­
tions of Money
Federal Agency Debt: Another Side of Federal
Borrowing
Dec.

Evidence on the Temporal Stability of the
Demand for Money Relationship in the
United States
Outlook For Food And Agriculture — 1980

Page 23