View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Farm Price Supports at Cost of Production
CLIFTON B. LUTTRELL

I V I a NY people are concerned that the costs of pro­
duction in a number of key industries, such as agricul­
ture, will exceed the price of the product, thus
destroying entire sectors of the nations economy. This
concern has been the basis for numerous public policy
actions, including tariffs and import quotas to protect
domestic producers from foreign competition and
Government guaranteed minimum prices to producers
of farm commodities.
Arguments for maintaining the prices for farm com­
modities at levels sufficient to cover production costs
have been found among those who have had influence
on farm legislation since the early 1920s. Such pro­
ponents include various Secretaries of Agriculture,
major farm organizations, and a number of profes­
sional economists.1
1In 1922, Secretary of Agriculture, Henry C. Wallace, wrote,
“ There is overproduction, so far as the producer is con­
cerned, whenever the quantity produced cannot be marketed
at a price which will cover the production costs . .
He
contended that such overproduction will drive the less effi­
cient producers out of business, and that both farmers and
consumers would benefit from more stable farm prices. See
U.S. Department of Agriculture, Yearbook 1922, p. 4. In
1934, his son, Secretary of Agriculture, Henry A. Wallace,
stated, “ Agriculture must be maintained; and to maintain it
the prices paid for farm products must cover the costs.” Like
his father, he also argued that both producers and consumers
would gain in the long run from such supports. See U.S.
Department of Agriculture, Yearbook 1935, p. 4. In the
1920s, a bill was introduced in the Senate to create a Federal
export corporation which was designed to keep farm com­
modity prices at least up to cost of production levels. See
Dan F. Hadwiger, Federal W heat Commodity Programs
(Am es: The Iowa State University Press, 1970), p. 100.
Additional arguments for supporting farm prices at or near
costs of production are found in: Orville Merton Kile, The
Farm Bureau Through Three Decades (Baltimore: The
Waverly Press, 1948), p. 199; J. A. Baker, “ Supply Control:
Farmers Union View,” Journal of Farm Economics (D ecem ­
ber I9 6 0 ), p. 1180; Geoffrey Shepherd, “ What Should Go
Into the Parity Price Formula,” Journal of Farm Economics
(M ay 1953), p. 171; and Rainer Schickele, Agricultural Policy
(N ew York: McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc., 1954),
p. 298. Numerous proponents of price supports contend that
they are necessary in order to maintain a viable industry.
Such arguments imply that the level of price supports should
be determined by some measure of cost of production. See,
for example, John C. White, Deputy Secretary of Agriculture,
“ A Gamble That Has to Be Encouraged,” New York Times,
September 13, 1977. He stated: “ . . . If we continue all out
production of commodities in large world oversupply, the
odds are against success and survival for U.S. farmers . . . .”
Page 2



The voice of proponents of such price supports has
not gone unheeded. The parity price concept estab­
lished in the 1933 Agricultural Adjustment Act was in
itself an attempt to relate the Government guaranteed
support prices on farm commodities to average costs.
It provided for a higher support base if farm produc­
tion costs, including interest, taxes on real estate, and
commodities bought by farmers, rose. The Act, as
amended in 1949, included wages paid to farm labor
in the parity index for agricultural price supports.
The artificially high prices resulting from these pro­
grams led to major surplus accumulation, which in
turn created demands for new legislation to control
production, enhance food consumption, and provide
for surplus disposal through export (subsidy) schemes.
Despite major efforts to reduce surpluses through in­
ternational and domestic surplus disposal programs,
and the massive efforts to prevent stock accumulations
through production restrictions, the value of Govern­
ment owned surplus commodities exceeded $6 billion
or about 20 percent of total farm product sales in the
late 1950’s. Furthermore, total carryover stocks, largely
under CCC loan or owned outright by the CCC, of
cotton, wheat and sorghum grain often exceed annual
production. In the early 1970s the price for farm
products rose sharply, but the support prices were not
increased much. Consequently, Government stocks of
farm commodities were largely liquidated and most
farm production controls were removed.
More recently, however, the argument for farm
price supports based on cost of production has been
revised. The Food and Agriculture Act of 1977 pro­
vided for a support price ( target price) for feed grains
for the years 1979 through 1981 at the 1978 level of
supports, adjusted for changes in costs of production.
Costs of production for this purpose were defined as
variable costs, machinery costs, and general overhead
costs allotted to the crops involved on the basis of
their proportion of the total value of production.2
2Food and Agricultural Act of 1977, Conference Report, 95th
Congress, 1st Session, Report No. 95-418, p. 19.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

Which Cost of Production?
Those who advocate a Government guaranteed
farm commodity price support program based on costs
of production are first faced with the problem of
determining a cost of production measure that has
meaning for any specific farm or commodity. There
are a number of different concepts of costs: total,
average, marginal, fixed, variable, short-run, long-run,
and various combinations.
While none of the proposals for basing support price
levels on costs of production state the specific concept
to be used, average cost would apparentiy be applied,
given the objective of raising farm income through
price supports. The difference between the price per
unit sold and the average cost measures the current
profit (or loss) per unit of output for the farm. Profit
(or loss) per unit multiplied by the number of units
sold yields the total annual profit (or loss) for the
farmer. Thus, price supports based on average cost
could be related to the objectives of the policymakers
of increasing current farm incomes. Nevertheless,
Government guaranteed prices based on any cost of
production concept lead to major problems in the
longer run if guaranteed prices are maintained above
free market prices.

W hose Cost of Production?
A second problem encountered in basing support
prices on costs of production is the question of whose
cost o f production is appropriate. In 1976 there were
about 2.8 million farms in the United States, each
having a different cost structure. While income and
cost data are not available for individual farms, aver­
age realized net income to farm operators in the
various sales classes indicates the diversity of produc­
tion cost. For example, in the largest size category,
with sales of commodities of $100,000 and over per
farm, realized net income averaged $55,700 per farm
operator. But, for those farms having sales of $2,500 to
$4,999, average realized net income per farm operator
was only $1,725.3 It is apparent that many farms in
the latter category realize little or no net income once
opportunity costs (highest valued alternative use for
resources) are deducted for the operator’s labor and
use of capital.4 However, many farms in the larger
size group apparently yield sizable returns to all re­
3U.S. Department of Agriculture, Farm Income Statistics,
Statistical Bulletin No. 576, July 1977, p. 54.
4The U.S. Department of Agriculture net income data repre­
sent returns to the operator’s labor and equity capital. Hence,
the value of these resources in alternative uses must be
deducted in order to determine the profitability of the farm.




DECEM BER

1977

sources. Hence, cost of production per unit of output
on larger farms is well below that of most farms in the
smaller size group.
The short-run average cost of production on farms
will no doubt decline as the size of farms in the
smaller farm size groups increase. However, as the
size of farms in the larger size groups increase, man­
agement is spread over wider areas, and the costs
per unit of output will tend to level off and may even
begin to increase.
The variation in the short-run average cost of pro­
duction for farms results from a number of factors
such as quantity and quality of various inputs, includ­
ing land, labor, operating capital items, and the qual­
ity of management. For example, the quantity of land
and/or equipment will vary among farms, and if there
are major returns to scale, as is often the case in
agriculture, the larger farm will have lower average
costs than will the smaller farm.

Some Prices Profitable for Some Farms and
Not Profitable for Others
Given the fact that some farms are more efficient
than other farms and that the more efficient farms
have lower average production costs than the less
efficient, Government price supports sufficient to
cover such costs on the more efficient farms might be
set at relatively low levels. For example, some of the
more efficient farms may be able to produce com
profitably at a price as low as $1.25 per bushel,
whereas other less efficient farms may require a price
of $2.50 or more to produce com profitably. At these
cost of production levels, price supports set at $1.25
will be sufficient to guarantee the profitability of com
production only on the most efficient farms.
Alternatively, price supports which guarantee a
profit for the marginal producers (no farm failures)
will guarantee above normal profits for the more effi­
cient producers. For example, assume that the market
price for com is $1.75 per bushel and the support
price is set at $2.50 per bushel, a level sufficient to
cover production cost on the least efficient farm.
Those farms which can produce corn profitably at
$1.25 per bushel will realize profits relative to free
market levels (about $1.25 per bushel), at the expense
of the taxpayers and consumers. Production on these
efficient farms will also tend to rise, since they now
have an incentive to increase output until marginal
cost rises to the new price level. Their marginal cost
will increase as a result of their increased use of vari­
Page 3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

able productive factors such as fertilizer. It will pay
these farmers to increase the use of such resources
until marginal cost (cost of producing an additional
bushel) rises to the support price level of $2.50 per
bushel. Nevertheless, despite the increase in marginal
costs, these farms will realize a major gain in total
profits. The Government, in turn, would be faced with
disposing of an even larger “surplus.”

High Price Supports Lead to Greater
Production, But Less Sales Than
Market Prices
In addition to the fact that support prices based on
cost of production can guarantee large profits to some
farmers while others may still incur losses, the level of
the support price has a major impact on the volume
of farm production. Continuing adjustments in re­
sources and production are made by farmers in re­
sponse to price changes.
In the short run, the way in which such adjustments
are made can be explained by the law of diminishing
returns. This economic law states that as more units
of a variable factor of production (fertilizer, for
example) are applied to a fixed amount of other re­
sources (for example, land), the additional production
per unit of fertilizer added will eventually decline.
This decline in the additional production for each
additional unit of fertilizer means that the cost per
additional unit of crop produced (i.e., marginal cost)
rises.
The marginal cost and the expected price of a
product determine the most profitable rate of produc­
tion. For example, if the expected market price of
com is $1.75 per bushel and a farmer can produce an
additional bushel of com by adding $1.50 worth of
fertilizer, he will add the additional fertilizer. He will
continue to add fertilizer as long as he can increase his
profit by doing so, i.e. until the cost of the fertilizer
added equals the value of the additional com pro­
duced. On the other hand, no additional fertilizer will
be added once the point is reached where $1.75 worth
of additional fertilizer is required to produce an addi­
tional bushel of com. The farm’s most profitable shortrun production occurs at that rate of output where the
marginal cost of production equals the price received
for the commodity. This maximizes the farmer’s total
profit, since before that point is reached any additional
unit produced adds to profits, and after that point any
additional output is produced at a loss. Consequently,
when prices are increased as a result of price support
Page 4



DECEM BER

1977

programs, marginal revenue rises above marginal cost
and farmers always find it profitable to increase
production.
In addition to the effect of increasing production,
support prices set above current market prices tend
to reduce the quantity of products demanded from
farmers. In general, the result is an increase in
the amount of farm products supplied to the market
and a decrease in the amount demanded. This differ­
ence will emerge as a “surplus” of current farm prod­
ucts, which the Government must absorb and store or
dispose of.
But of greater consideration is the longer-run im­
pact of support prices on exports. Higher prices faced
by agricultural producers in those nations which im­
port from the United States, and by such producers in
other nations, provide incentive for increased produc­
tion and decreased importation of farm products from
the United States.5 Hence, stocks of farm commodi­
ties, unwanted at the support price, will tend to build
up. The United States Government can alleviate this
situation by “dumping” farm products in the world
market; that is, the Government can sell farm prod­
ucts in foreign markets at below domestic costs of
production and prohibit the importing of these com­
modities through import quotas or tariff barriers. Some
foreign governments allegedly follow such practices
with respect to some nonfarm products. Several com­
modities, such as steel and textiles, are allegedly
“dumped” on the United States market.
The market price is the only price which equates
production and sales of all goods and services. While
domestic production restraints, such as acreage con­
trols, may tend to reduce the commodity accumula­
tions which result from price supports, such controls
have in the past had only limited effectiveness. Fur­
thermore, in those cases where controls are relatively
effective (for example, tobacco production), the in­
centive to produce larger quantities leads to overall
inefficiencies in national resource use.

Higher Prices Increase Size of
Farm Sector . . .
Prices which are artificially set above market prices
have an important impact on national resource use.
5The new farm bill contains an escape clause, similar to those
in most tariff laws, which authorizes the Secretary of Agricul­
ture to lower the loan rates when United States farm products
are being priced out of world markets. However, any price
support level which is above the equilibrium market price will
reduce exports, to some extent, and the higher the support
price is maintained, the greater will be the reduction.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

Average returns to all resources used for farm produc­
tion will rise as farmers bid for additional resources.
More of the variable cost items will be brought into
agriculture. For example, it will be profitable for
farmers ( in the short run at least) to increase the use
of chemical fertilizer, pest and weed control agents,
and improved seeds, and intensify crop cultivation.
In the longer run, farmers make continuous adjust­
ments of all resources in response to higher prices.
There is neither a unique size of farm, a unique
amount of labor or machinery on farms, nor a specific
number of farms, nor a specific total acreage in farms.
In other words, over a longer time period all resources
are variable. If com is selling below production cost
for some farmers, they will make greater adjustments
in the long run of five years than in the short run of a
year or less. A fanner who is producing at a loss in the
long run will attempt to sell his farm and go into
another occupation, or he may develop his farm into
a profitable one by purchasing land from another rela­
tively inefficient farmer. Hence, without price sup­
ports, long-term adjustments in response to growth in
farm technology result in fewer (but more efficient)
farms, a smaller farm labor force, and lower food costs.
In contrast, the artificially high prices resulting from
farm price supports in the longer run will lead to a
portion of the nation’s scarce resources being em­
ployed, inefficiently, in agriculture. Higher prices,
resulting from price supports, will tend to increase the
farm labor force and other resources. Likewise, the
number of farm consolidations will be slower among
marginal farmers as such fanners will tend to remain
in agriculture for a longer period rather than selling
out. The more efficient farmers, however, will have
the incentive to bid labor and other resources away
from nonfarm uses and increase farm production
capacity. Excessive resources will thus remain in
agriculture. Acreage controls may be used to reduce
the land allocated to crop production but they do not
reduce the incentive for using land or other resources
in the industry. The free market price is the only price
which assures that no waste occurs in the use of scarce
resources.

But Returns to Farm Workers Unchanged
Since labor and capital can move from one sector of
the economy to another, higher returns to farm labor
through price support programs cannot be maintained
indefinitely. If price supports are set sufficiently high
to cover labor cost (opportunity cost for farm labor)
on the less efficient farms, the more efficient farms



DECEM BER

1977

will find returns from hiring extra labor increased and
will employ additional workers until the value of the
output produced by the last worker hired equals the
cost of hiring the worker. However, once complete,
this process insures that costs of farm labor ( wages)
will remain about the same as the cost of labor
(wages) of the same quality employed elsewhere in
the economy. Otherwise, further shifts in labor be­
tween the farm and nonfarm sectors would occur as
workers search for those jobs which are expected to
maximize their own income. Also new entries into the
labor force will tend to select those occupations where
their own well being is maximized, thereby tending to
equalize returns to labor of equivalent quality in all
sectors. Consequently, in a community where workers
can move freely among the various occupations, there
can be no permanent disparity in returns to workers
having similar abilities.
Only by limiting employment can labor income in
agriculture be maintained for a long period of time at
above equilibrium levels. However, such rigid con­
trols lead to major inefficiencies in overall resource
use throughout the economy and, in addition, are a
massive infringement on freedom of choice in the
selection of a vocation.

The Only Long-Run Gainers Are
Current Landowners
As indicated earlier, over a longer-run period of
perhaps five years or more, all resources in agriculture
are variable. They can be increased or decreased de­
pending on the expected rate of return in agriculture
versus other industries. Labor can readily shift to or
from farming. Capital invested in farm machinery,
livestock, and other capital items can likewise shift
between farm and nonfarm uses as the capital items
are depreciated or marketed. Land, however, repre­
sents a somewhat different type of investment, being
more of a fixed investment than either farm buildings,
machinery, or livestock. Also, the quantity of land
relative to other forms of capital in agriculture is
greater than in most other industries. Returns to much
of the nation’s land-( opportunity cost) is, thus, largely
determined by its rental value for agricultural pur­
poses. While the effective supply of land for agricul­
tural purposes can be augmented somewhat through
the use of fertilizer, irrigation, and limited changes in
its use for other purposes, the quantity available for
farming is still relatively inelastic (quantity changes
only a small amount with relatively large changes in
Page 5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA NK OF ST. LO U IS

land prices) even in the long run.8 Hence, increases
in land prices which result from permanently higher
farm profits tend to be more permanent than the
higher returns on other farm resources.7 The higher
returns to land as a result of price supports thus tend
to remain permanent, whereas returns to other factors
of production tend toward their previous levels, about
equivalent to returns on similar resources used in the
nonfarm sector of the economy.8

Price Supports Not Necessary to Prevent
Massive Farm Failures
The observed adjustments to market forces made
over the years by agriculture are not consistent with
the view that all fanners will suddenly go bankrupt
and domestic food production will cease unless costs
of production are guaranteed by the Government on
all existing farms. If there were only a few farmers
with the same average cost of production, and farm­
ing in the nation was at a comparative disadvantage
with that in the rest of the world, it would be possible
for them to all fail at the same time. Then the nation
would be forced to rely exclusively on imports for
food. However, in this case, well-being would still be
enhanced by importing food and exporting those
goods in which the nation has a comparative advan­
tage. Neither condition, however, is applicable to the
United States. This nation has more than 2.7 million
farms, each of which has a unique cost of production,
and, as a whole, it has a comparative advantage over
other nations in the production of farm commodities.
6See John E. Floyd, “ The Effects of Farm Price Supports on
the Returns to Land and Labor in Agriculture,” Journal of
Political Economy ( February-December 1965), pp. 152-55.
7A reduction in crop acreage resulting from Government acre­
age control programs will have a similar impact on returns to
land since any reduction in acreage cropped will result in
higher returns to the remaining acres.
8For a detailed discussion of this subject, see D. Gale Johnson,
Farm Commodity Programs: An Opportunity for Change
(Washington, D .C .: American Enterprise Institute for Public
Policy Research, 1973), pp. 51-63. Johnson reports, “ Since a
very large fraction, if not all, of the net benefits from com ­
modity programs go to land, the percentage of farm real
estate that is owned by farm operators is of some interest . . .
perhaps as much as 40 percent of net benefits accruing to
land goes to landowners who do not farm the land they own.”
Floyd found “ that most of the benefits (from the price
support and acreage control programs) will take the form of a
windfall gain, either an increase in the value of land or the
receipt of marketing certificates issued by the government
and having a commercial value, and that the gain is once
and for all.” Floyd,p. 158.
Similar results were found in a study by Earl O. Heady,
Edwin O. Haroldsen, Leo V. Mayer, and Luther G. Tweeten,
in Roots of the Farm Problem (Ames, Iowa: The Iowa
State University Press, 1965), p. 66.


Page 6


DECEM BER

1977

Its relative advantage is indioated by the fact that
about 30 percent of the nation’s farm production is
exported.
Since average cost of production per unit varies
widely among the numerous farms in the nation, some
farmers will be making profits in a free market setting,
while others will take losses at all likely prices for farm
products. Only the marginal (least profitable) ones
will cease production in any year, however, and find
other uses for their resources. As marginal producers
leave the industry, the supply of farm products will
tend to decline. The decline in supply will tend to
increase the price and the profit level to the remaining
producers. Consequently, the larger the number of
failures in any given year the greater will be the
profits in succeeding years for those producers remain­
ing in agriculture. Hence, the system is self-adjusting
if left alone. Consumers thus have no need to fear
from the possibility of massive failure in farm produc­
tion resulting from free market forces.

Some Failures
Economy

—

Expected in Growing

Much of the support for Government farm pro­
grams no doubt reflects the benevolent concern of the
American public for the relatively large number of
low-income farm families. Failure in agriculture by
such families is often envisioned as a catastrophe. No
farm nor business failure is desirable for its own sake
since it is associated with personal costs and losses.
But, there is little that the commodity supply-control
and price-support programs can do to prevent failures
by the low-income farm group. They own little land
and it is the existing landowners who receive the
major benefits from farm price-support programs.
Hence, the economic status of the low-income farm
families is little improved.
Furthermore, there is a social cost in preventing
failure that should be weighed against the losses from
failure. As indicated earlier, farms, like other busi­
nesses, can misuse labor, land, capital, and other fac­
tor inputs. Unless some failures are permitted, such
misuse will continue, and the resources will not be
available to other sectors of the economy, where they
could be used more efficiently.
The various sectors of the economy grow at differ­
ent rates — some at a high rate, some more slowly
and some not at all. If no failure is permitted by assur­
ing market returns to all resources, growth in the
faster growing sectors of the economy will be retarded
because of lack of resources. Thus, programs which

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

tend to support farm prices at production cost and
freeze the resources in farming at their current levels
are not compatible with maximum economic growth
or well-being. Hence, the cost to society of preventing
failure may be much greater than the hardships of the
relatively small number of failures which result from
price competition in the market place; and if we wish
to ameliorate the hardships, it can be done by more
efficient means than by subsidies to all farms. Exam­
ples are Government grants and loans for retraining
and relocation of farmers and farm workers.

SUMMARY
Arguments have been made for Government farm
price supports based on cost of production. Some of
the arguments are based on the alleged possibility of
massive failure and loss of production in the industry.
The arguments fail to specify which cost or whose cost
of production should determine the level of supports.
There are several different concepts of cost of pro­
duction. Possibly the most widely understood concept
is average cost. But there are more than two million
farms in the nation, each with a different average cost.
Hence, any likely level of price support selected for a
farm commodity will be above average cost for some
farms and below average cost for all others.
Consequently, any farm price-support level which
may be selected contains all the handicaps of all other




DECEM BER

1977

price-support schemes. Any level of price supports
which is above market levels for a commodity will tend
to increase output and raise marginal costs of produc­
tion. Hence, the price supports themselves, if effective
in raising prices, stimulate the production of “surplus”
commodities, and result in higher food costs, reduced
farm commodity exports, and higher taxes to cover
the higher Government outlays.
In addition, the supports cause inefficiencies in both
the farm and the nonfarm sectors of the economy and
fail to achieve the objectives of the program. They
lead to excessive resources in agriculture which re­
duces the quantity of resources available to the non­
farm sector of the economy. Consequently, there is
less production of nonfarm goods. But of greater im­
portance, the higher prices are of little benefit to farm
labor and low-income farm families, major objectives
of the program. Most of the gains accrue to existing
landowners.
Furthermore, the supports are not necessary to pre­
vent massive failures. The system of market prices is
self-correcting, as failures tend to reduce the overall
supply, increase the price of farm products, and im­
prove the profitability of the remaining farms. Some
failures and some temporarily high profits are to be
expected in a competitive economy. They indicate
that resources are moving toward their most efficient
uses.

Page 7

Do Foreigners Control the U.S. Money Supply?
GEOFFREY E. W O O D and DOUGLAS R. M UDD

1 HERE have recently appeared claims that de­
velopments in the Eurodollar market have contributed
substantially to the current expansion of the U.S.
money supply ( M , )
These claims imply that the
Eurodollar system is a source of monetary disturb­
ances which the Federal Reserve System cannot offset.
On the basis of these claims, it is sometimes then
asserted that the recent weakness of the dollar in
foreign exchange markets has been due to an expan­
sion of M i caused by transactions in the Eurodollar
market.
In fact, the extent to which transactions in the
Eurodollar market can affect M ,, and thereby make
more difficult the Federal Reserve’s task of monetary
control, is at most very small. Further, any effect on
M i from Eurodollar transactions can be fully offset
by Federal Reserve actions. Therefore, if Eurodollar
transactions do affect M h it must be with the concur­
rence of the Federal Reserve System.

claims are owned not only by foreign citizens and
corporations but also by U.S. citizens and corpora­
tions, international organizations, and by national
governments.
Funds can be transferred from a U.S. bank to a
Eurodollar account for a variety of reasons. It may be
that a U.S. citizen sees that a higher rate of interest
can be earned at a Eurobank (any bank outside the
U.S. which has dollar-denominated assets and liabili­
ties), or that a foreign corporation receives a check
from a U.S. corporation in payment for goods, and
decides to keep those funds in dollars, although at a
bank outside the U.S.
In any event, the Eurobank now owns a demand
deposit at a U.S. bank. The effect on the U.S. banking
system of establishing the Eurodollar deposit has been
to transfer ownership of a demand deposit from a U.S.
resident to a Eurobank. Thus, the “creation” of the
Eurodollar deposit has no effect on the money stock
of the U.S.

Can Eurodollar Transactions Increase
the U.S. M oney Supply?
Eurodollar deposits are dollar-denominated deposit
liabilities of banks, including branches of U.S. banks,
located outside the U.S.- These dollar-denominated
1See, for example, “ Economic Diary: Solving the Riddle of
Monetary Growth,” Business W eek, November 7, 1977, p. 14
and “A Reader Writes: Euromarket Has Gained Control of
U.S. Money Supply,” The Money Manager, October 17, 1977,
p. 8. M i is defined as demand deposits plus currency and in­
cludes holdings of these by foreign governments, financial
institutions, and individuals, as well as those of U.S. residents.
^Eurodollar deposits are therefore not U.S. dollars owned ex­
clusively by foreigners. It should also be noted that EuroPage 8




The Eurobank receiving the deposit can subse­
quently extend dollar loans based on the demand
deposit which it holds at a U.S. bank, maintaining
some portion of the demand deposit at the U.S. bank
as “precautionary reserves.”3
dollars are dollar-denominated claims on banks outside the
U.S., not bundles of U.S. currency. (Just as the bulk of the
U.S. money stock comprises claims on banks in the U.S., and
not actual currency in circulation.)
:1There is no reason in principle why the loan should be a dol­
lar loan; it could be in some other currency. W e have dealt
only with a dollar loan so as to focus on the particular point
at issue.

FEDERAL. R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

The loan might take the form of a dollar loan to a
European corporation, executed by transferring some
portion of the deposit which the Eurobank holds in
the U.S. to a demand deposit account held by the
borrowing corporation at the same or another U.S.
bank. The net effect on the U.S. banking system of
this Eurodollar loan again would be a transfer of
ownership of demand deposit accounts without chang­
ing the level of total U.S. demand deposits.
The foreign-based corporation receiving the Euro­
dollar loan in this example could use the demand
deposit account which it now owns in the U.S. to make
final payment for goods and services purchased in the
U.S. Alternatively, it could decide to deposit part or
all of the Eurodollar loan in another Eurobank. In this
case, the Eurobank could extend further Eurodollar
loans, pending the use of the funds by the corporation.
The “creation” of Eurodollar deposits is thus a
process identical to the “creation” of bank deposits in
the U.S. banking system. Eurobanks are, insofar as
they deal in dollars, part of the U.S. banking system,
just as Missouri banks are, in that all require U.S.
dollar deposits before they can grant U.S. dollar
loans.4
In the case of the Eurodollar market, the expansion
of Eurodollar deposits is based, in effect, on the
transfer of ownership of demand deposits held by
Eurobanks at U.S. banks.5 The total level of demand
deposit liabilities held by the U.S. banking system,
however, is not changed by the multiple expansion of
Eurodollar deposits.6 The process is identical to that
which would follow if a deposit is withdrawn from one
bank in the U.S. and transferred to another. The first
bank would lose reserves and have to reduce its earn­
ing assets, for example its loans, while the second
4This was first pointed out by Milton Friedman, “ The EuroDollar Market: Some First Principles,” this Review (July
1971), pp. 16-24, and later re-emphasized by John William­
son, “ Review of The Economics of the Euro-Currency Sys­
tem by George W. McKenzie,” The Manchester School
(March 1977), pp. 86-88, and by Michael J. Hamburger and
Geoffrey E. W ood, “ Interest Rates and Monetary Policy
in Open Economies” (paper presented to Federal Reserve
Committee on Financial Analysis, November 16-18, 1977).
5Only to the extent that Eurobanks hold “ precautionary re­
serves” in the form of time deposits, rather than demand de­
posits, at U.S. banks will U.S. M i change. This change in
M i could, however, be entirely offset by Federal Reserve open
market operations, as described later in this paper.
BThis abstracts, for expository simplicity, from the existence of
different reserve requirements at different banks. For a discus­
sion of the consequence of this, see Albert E. Burger and
Robert H. Rasche, “ Revision of the Monetary Base,” this
Review (July 1977), pp. 13-23.




DECEM BER

1977

bank would acquire reserves and thus be able to
expand loans. In the absence of a change in the
monetary base on which the loans are pyramided, the
total of loans which could be extended will not change.
In summary, the reason why movements between
M, and Eurodollars do not affect M , is that one
acquires a Eurodollar asset by supplying U.S. dollars.
This transfers the ownership of some U.S. dollars, but
does not affect the total.
One qualification is in order. A U.S. bank may
have the ability to affect demand deposits, and hence
M 1; by changing the composition of its liabilities be­
tween demand deposits and funds borrowed from the
Eurodollar market. An example of this would be when
a large bank in the U.S., which was holding a demand
deposit due to a bank in London, has that deposit
converted to a loan from that bank. The immediate
effect of this is a fall in M 1; but it does release re­
serves, since the reserve requirement on Eurodollar
borrowings is 4 percent, while that on demand de­
posits is 16.25 percent at the largest banks. If the
entire amount of reserves which have been freed is
used to make loans which subsequently become de­
mand deposits at banks with a smaller marginal
reserve requirement, and these banks then extend
loans which remain as demand deposits at banks with
the same reserve requirement as themselves, an ex­
pansion of M j is possible.7 However, as Eurodollar
transactions tend to be concentrated in the larger
banks, such an effect is not likely. But even should
such an effect occur, as is shown below it can be
fully offset by Federal Reserve action.
So far we have examined the effect of an owner
of a part of M x moving his deposit to a Eurobank. It
is also necessary to consider a movement from an
interest earning asset, such as a time deposit, to a
Eurodollar deposit. In this case, the dollars held as
time deposits would initially be shifted into demand
deposits, and subsequently transferred to a Eurodollar
deposit. The initial shift from a time to a demand
deposit would increase M j, just as would a shift from
a time deposit to a demand deposit made for any
7Currently, reserve requirements on net demand deposits
which apply to member banks are: 7% for banks having less
than $2 million in demand deposits, 9.5% for $2-$ 10 million
in demand deposits, 11.75% for $10-100 million in demand
deposits, 12.75% for $100-400 million in demand deposits,
and 16.25% for banks having demand deposit liabilities in
excess of $400 million. It can be seen that for the effect on
M i of a deposit moving from one bank to another to be non­
trivial, the deposit would have to move from a bank with
deposits in excess of $400 million to one with deposits of
less than $10 million.
Page 9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

other reason. However, this increase in M] could also
be fully offset by Federal Reserve open market
operations, that is, by the purchase or sale of U.S.
Government securities by the Federal Reserve.

How the Fed Can Control the M oney Supply
It is useful to set out the sequence of events
through which Eurodollar transactions are viewed as
affecting M ,. Once that has been done, it can be seen
how the Federal Reserve, should it choose to do so,
can counteract these effects. The sequence of events
through which Eurodollar market transactions are
supposed to result in increases in the U.S. money sup­
ply can be set out as follows. The continued decline
in the foreign exchange value of the U.S. dollar has,
the argument inns, encouraged Eurodollar holders to
convert their Eurodollars into Deutsche marks, Swiss
francs, French francs, etc. Thus, as the value of the
dollar in terms of most European currencies declines,
foreigners holding dollar-denominated deposits in
European banks “ . . . have been selling dollars to buy
German marks and the like. . . ”8
European central banks, it is further asserted, take
part in these transactions by selling their domestic
currencies for U.S. dollars. Some portion of the in­
creased dollar balances held by European central
banks is then used to purchase U.S. Treasury securi­
ties from U.S. residents. These U.S. residents subse­
quently deposit the proceeds from these sales in their
checking accounts. As a result U.S. demand deposits,
and consequently M ,, have been increased.
Now, as was shown above, that analysis is incom­
plete. It neglects that the Eurodollars had as their
base deposits within the U.S. banking system. When
holders of Eurodollar deposits instruct the banks at
which these deposits are held to convert the deposit
from dollars to some other currency, the effect may
indeed be to transfer the ownership of a U.S. demand
deposit from the Eurobank to a foreign central bank.
If it so desires the foreign central bank may then use
this U.S. demand deposit to purchase U.S. Govern­
ment securities. This transaction would transfer own­
ership of the U.S. demand deposit from the foreign
central bank to the U.S. residents from which the
securities were purchased.
Thus, Eurodollar deposit holders can convert these
deposits into foreign currencies, ultimately resulting
in foreign central bank purchases of U.S. Government
8Business W eek, p. 14.

Digitized for Page
FRASER
10


DECEM BER

1977

securities, with no substantial change in the level of
U.S. demand deposits occurring. Insofar as it affects
M i, the process in the end result is exactly like that
of one U.S. resident buying U.S. Government securi­
ties from another; no matter how many intermediate
steps there are, there is ultimately no effect on M ,, ex­
cept in the case where reserves are released by the
transactions, and that effect is, as shown above, minor.
Even should that minor effect occur, the Federal
Reserve can offset it in two ways.9
First, when the Eurodollar holders sell their dollars,
they do not go along and offer them to foreign central
banks; rather, they sell them on the foreign exchange
market to whomever will buy them. There is nothing
to stop the Federal Reserve System from using its for­
eign exchange reserves to buy the dollars at that point,
thus bringing the process to a quick end, for there
would be no increase in foreign central banks’ holdings
of dollars. Alternatively, the “reappearance” of Euro­
dollar deposits as U.S. demand deposits could be off­
set domestically. Changes in the U.S. money supply
can be offset by Federal Reserve open market opera­
tions. In this present case, the Federal Reserve System
would sell some of its holdings of Government secu­
rities. This action would reduce both bank reserves
and M j.
Thus, any increase in the U.S. money supply which
might conceivably result from investors converting
Eurodollar deposits into foreign currency holdings can
readily be offset by the U.S. monetary authorities.
They can offset the increase in M-, by operating either
in the foreign exchange market or in the market for
U.S. Government debt, or both. Far from being un­
able to offset this monetary impulse, the Federal
Reserve actually has two instruments by which it
can do so.

Has the Eurodollar Market Made the
Dollar W eak?
It is sometimes claimed that the dollar’s recent
weakness has been due to self-fulfilling expectations
9It is useful to note that even if the Federal Reserve does not
try to offset these effects on M i, they may be only transitory.
Suppose the Federal Reserve is controlling an interest rate,
such as the Federal funds rate. Suppose further that there is
an increased desire to borrow dollars and sell them for some
other currency. This increased demand for credit raises interest
rates. In attempting to offset this rise the Federal Reserve
increases bank reserves by buying Treasury bills. The money
supply thereby expands. Suppose that those who sell foreign
currency to dollar holders wish to buy U.S. Treasury bills.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

operating in the Eurodollar market. The argument for
this position is that the dollar has been weak only
because M, has been growing unduly rapidly, and
that M j has been growing because of Eurodollar
transactions undertaken in the expectation of further
weakness of the dollar.
Even if the argument that Eurodollar transactions
could substantially affect M, were correct, it is easy to
see that the Federal Reserve can offset such influ­
ences on the U.S. money stock. Eurodollar transac­
tions cannot be blamed for the slide in the U.S.
dollar’s foreign exchange value.
This increased demand for Treasury bills lowers interest rates.
The Federal Reserve now sees interest rates falling, and reacts
by supplying Treasury bills, thus offsetting its original action.




DECEM BER

1977

Summary and Conclusions
The net effect of transactions in the Euromarket on
the U.S. money supply is virtually negligible. Trans­
actions in the Eurodollar market cannot have con­
tributed significantly to the recent growth in M j.
Further, the arguments in the second section of this
paper show that the U.S. monetary authorities have the
ability to offset whatever effects on Mj Eurodollar
transactions may have. The existence of that market
has not reduced the ability of the Federal Reserve
System to control the U.S. money stock. It therefore
also follows that any claim that the foreign exchange
value of the U.S. dollar is declining because of selffulfilling expectations operating through the Euro­
dollar market is totally false.

Page 11

The Tax Penalty on Married Workers
NANCY AMMON JIANAKOPLOS

J

OHN Doe and Jane Smith each earned $15,000
in 1976 and each paid $2,403 in Federal personal
income taxes.1 The Internal Revenue Service col­
lected $4,806 from John and Jane. If John and Jane
had been married during 1976, however, they would
have jointly paid $6,092 in Federal income taxes.
Getting married would have cost John and Jane $1,286
in additional 1976 Federal income taxes. This example
points out one of the peculiarities of the present
Federal income tax structure; under certain circum­
stances two working people would pay more taxes if
they are married than if they are single.
Dealing equitably with households of different sizes,
marital status, and number of working family mem­
bers has been a problem for tax law writers. Even
without referring to the economic theory of taxation,
however, it is possible to examine the factors which
contribute to a possible tax penalty on married
workers. The consequences and possible remedies for
this apparently inequitable treatment of households
can also be considered.

FACTORS CONTRIBUTING TO THE
TAX ON MARRIED WORKERS
The task of specifying all possible household situa­
tions where a marriage penalty (or benefit) occurs is
v e r y d ifficu lt, a n d is n o t a v e r y r e w a r d in g ex ercise.

However, the fundamental characteristics of the situa­
tion remain if a few simplifying assumptions are
made:
1 ) the standard dedu ction is used b y all taxpayers;
2)

all in com e is derived from w ages a n d /o r salaries;

3 ) all married couples file joint returns;
4 ) household adjusted gross incom es are $30,000 or
less; and

5) household m em bers h ave no children.
While these assumptions are limiting, all except the
last assumption are fairly widespread. Even the exclu­
sion of children from the example is not that unusual.
In March 1976, 15 percent of all husband-wife house­
holds were childless and both spouses were em­
ployed.2 With regard to the other assumptions, analy-

sis of 1973 tax returns indicates that 65 percent of all
returns utilized the standard deduction.3 Wages and
salaries represented 83 percent of adjusted gross in­
comes in 1973 and 95 percent of all married couples
filed joint returns. The Internal Revenue Service re­
ported that 96 percent of all taxpayers in 1976 had
adjusted gross incomes below $30,000.4
The basis for calculations of the tax penalty on
married workers is the comparison of tax liabilities of
a man and woman, holding constant everything except
their marital status. This is not a frivolous exercise
when consideration is given to the employment sta­
tistics dealing with married couples. According to
March 1976 data, there were 47.3 million husbandwife families.5 In 22.3 million (47 percent) of these
households both husband and wife worked outside
the home. Full-time working wives contributed 39
percent of family income in 1976. Furthermore, the
alternative of a man and woman living together with­
out being legally married has been increasingly
adopted. The number of households where unrelated
adults of the opposite sex shared living quarters
doubled between 1970 and 1976, although constituting
only 1 percent of all households in 1976.6
The marital status of two hypothetical people, John
and Jane, for the entire tax year of 1976 is based on
their marital status on December 31, 1976. There is
one technicality involved with this. The Internal Rev­
enue Service states:
If you obtain a foreign d ivorce for the sole pur­
pose o f enabling you and your spouse to qu alify as
unm arried individuals eligible to file separate re­
turns, and if you then remarry each other early in
the next tax year, you and your spouse must file as
married individuals.7
“ The Tax Structure and Discrimination Against Working
Wives,” National Tax Journal (June 1972), pp. 183-191.
31973 is the most recent year for which detailed analysis are
published. Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income —
1973, Individual Income Tax Returns (Washington, D.C.:
Government Printing Office, 1976), p. 41.
4Information obtained from the Internal Revenue Service in
Washington, D.C.
5“ ‘Typical’ Family Not So Typical.”

'This assumes that they used the standard deduction, claimed
no dependents, and all income was derived from wages or
salaries.

8U.S. Bureau of the Census, “ Marital Status and Living Ar­
rangements: March 1976” Current Population Reports, Series
P-20, No. 306 (Washington, D .C.: Government Printing
Office, 1977), pp. 4-5.

‘Typical’ Family Not So Typical,” St. Louis Post-Dispatch,
March 14, 1977. For a discussion of the effects of children on
the tax penalty on married workers, see Joyce M. Nussbaum,

"Internal Revenue Service, Publication 17, Your Federal In ­
come Tax — 1977 Edition (Washington, D .C.: Government
Printing Office, 1977), p. 13.


Page 12


F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

D ECEM BER

1977

ECONOMIC CONCEPTS OF TAXATION
A m ong the characteristics o f taxes, w hich are g en ­
erally considered desirable, are tw o features o f par­
ticular im portance in evaluating the effect o f taxes on
households. Taxes should be equ ita b le or fair am ong
households and neutral towards m ost econ om ic d e ci­
sions.1 D efining these terms, h ow ever, is no easy
matter. In econ om ic theory tw o types o f equity are
usually defined — vertical equity and horizontal
equity. Vertical equity is defined to m ean that taxpaying units, such as individuals or households, with
greater incom es should pay m ore taxes than units with
less incom e. By horizontal equity w e mean, units o f
equal incom e should pay equal taxes.
These simple recipes, on ce again, contain terms
w hich are not easily defined. W h at is the appropriate
taxpaying unit? Is it the legal recipient o f the incom e
or the w hole household w hich is supported b y the
incom e?
F or
exam ple,
consider
three
possible
households:
Household
Mr. A
Mrs. A
Total Household A

Income
$ 3 0 ,0 0 0
0
$ 3 0 ,0 0 0

Mr. B

$ 1 5 ,0 0 0

Mrs. B

$ 15,0 0 0

Total Household B

$ 3 0 ,0 0 0

Mr. C

$ 3 0 ,0 0 0

Total Household C

$ 3 0 ,0 0 0

In household A, Mr. A makes $30,000 a year, w hile
Mrs. A stays at h om e (a n d m aybe raises a fa m ily ). In
household B, Mr. B earns $15,000 as does Mrs. B. In
household C, there is only Mr. C , w h o earns $30,000.
H ow m uch tax should each h ousehold pay?
If the appropriate taxing unit is the individual in­
com e earner, Mr. A and Mr. C should pay the same
’ For a more complete discussion of the desirable aspects of
taxes and actual characteristics of taxes, see Richard and
Peggy Musgrave, Public Finance in Theory and Practice

Even the Internal Revenue Service apparently recog­
nizes the possible benefits of filing as single taxpayers.

Household Characteristics
Table I shows the tax penalties and benefits of
marriage in 1976 for John and Jane, given the simpli­
fying assumptions. To use this table, select any com­
bination of the two adjusted gross incomes which
equals $30,000 or less. Follow the horizontal line rep­
resenting Jane’s income to the right until it intersects
with the vertical column corresponding to John’s in­
come. If the number at the intersection is negative,
John and Jane must pay that amount in additional



taxes. Mr. and Mrs. B should each pay less tax, w hich
together m ight not equal the taxes paid b y Mr. A or
Mr. C . If the appropriate taxing unit is the household,
then it can be argued that all three households should
pay the same am ount o f taxes. U nder 1976 tax laws
Mr. C pays the m ost taxes, Mr. and Mrs. B pay less
taxes, and Mr. and Mrs. A pay the least taxes, assuming
all other circum stances are equal.
T h e other term w hich presents difficulty in deter­
m ining equitable tax treatment is the definition o f
incom e. T h e con cep t o f in com e is frequently dealt
with in terms o f “ ability to pa y.” Thus, households
with the same dollar incom e, but o f different sizes and
different expenses incurred in earning the incom e,
have different abilities to pay. Currently, households
are allow ed a certain am ount o f incom e exem pt from
taxation for each m em ber o f the household (personal
exem ption s), w hich can be justified as a measure o f
the differing abilities to pay o f different sized house­
holds. Furthermore, the cost o f earning incom e can
vary from h ousehold to household. F or exam ple, the
expenses incurred if only one m em ber o f the house­
h old is em p loyed outside the h om e w ill usually b e less
than if tw o m em bers o f the same h ousehold work. F or
this reason the dedu ction o f child care expenses can
b e rationalized as a m easure o f differing expenses
incurred in earning in com e and, hence, differing
abilities to pay am ong households.
T h e term neutrality, applied to the con cep t o f taxes,
means that tax provisions should b e chosen to m ini­
m ize interference in market decisions, such as whether
to w ork or h ow to spend incom e. H ow ever, there are
tax provisions w h ich exp licid y prom ote certain b e ­
havior. Tax preferences reduce incom e subject to taxa­
tion, for exam ple, if the household contributes to
charity, buys a house, or invests in new business
equipm ent. Apparently, these are activities w hich
society finds beneficial and prom otes through tax
preferences ( d ed u ction s).
(N ew York: McGraw-Hill Company, 1973).

Federal taxes if they are married, rather than single.
If the number is positive, John and Jane would bene­
fit from a tax saving of that amount if they are mar­
ried, rather than single. For example, if Jane makes
$10,000 and John makes $12,000, they pay $483 more
taxes if they are married than if they are single. In
contrast, if Jane makes $15,000 and John makes $1,000,
they save $339 in taxes by getting married.8
The outlined area of the table indicates those com­
binations of incomes which are associated with a tax
8This neglects the loss of any welfare payments or earned
income tax credits John would lose by marrying Jane.
Page 13

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

DECEM BER

1977

DECEM BER

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO UIS

1977

Table I

TAX PENALTIES A N D

BENEFITS FOR M A RR IED W O R KER S

Jan e 's
Adjusted
Gross
Income
(Dollars)
3 0 .0 0 0

1,701

2 9 .0 0 0

1,618

28,0 0 0

1,566

1,218

27,0 0 0

1,486

1,166

818

49 9

26,000

1,406

1,086

76 6

45 9

254

25,000

1,329

1,009

689

410

217

24,000

1,264

949

629

1 85

2

-1 9 0

23,000

1,158

878

56 3

350
284

119

-3 6

-2 1 6

-3 9 6

22,000

1,078

79 8

5 18

244

79

-7 6

-2 2 8

-396

21,000

1,002

722

442

203

43

-1 1 2

-2 6 4

-4 0 4

-5 6 2

-7 1 6

20,000

93 2

662

3 82

143

18

-1 3 2

-284

-4 2 4

-5 5 4

-6 9 6

-8 3 6

19,000

84 7

597

327

88

-3 7

-1 5 2

-2 9 9

-4 3 9

-5 6 9

-6 8 3

-8 1 1

-957

18,000

787

537

28 7

58

-1 8 2

-2 9 4

-4 2 9

-5 5 9

-6 7 3

-7 7 3

-907

-1 ,0 6 5

17,000

705

480

23 0

21

-6 7
-94

-2 0 9

-3 2 1

-4 2 1

-5 4 6

-6 6 0

-760

-8 6 6

-1 ,0 1 2

-1 ,1 5 6

16,000

62 5

41 5

190

-1 9

-1 1 4

-2 1 9

-331

-4 3 1

-521

-6 3 0

-7 3 0

-836

-9 5 4

-1 ,0 8 6

-1 ,2 1 '

15,000

526

339

1 29

-5 5

-1 5 0

-2 3 5

-3 3 7

-4 3 7

-5 2 7

-6 0 1

-6 9 6

-8 0 2

-9 2 0

-1 ,0 2 4

-1 ,1 4

-1 ,2 8 6

14,000

310

123

-4 6

-1 1 6

-2 0 1

-2 8 3

-3 7 3

-4 6 8

-5 3 7

-597

-6 9 8

-8 1 6

-9 2 0

-1 ,0 1

-1 ,1 4 2

-1 ,2 1 6

13,000

486
454

25 6

80

-6 6

-1 2 1

-1 8 1

-2 6 3

-3 3 3

-4 1 3

-487

-5 4 7

-6 1 3

-726

-830

-9 2

-1 ,0 2 4

-1 ,0 8 6

-1 ,1 5 6

12,000

44 6

238

40

-9 5

-127

-1 7 2

-2 2 9

-2 9 9

-3 5 9

-4 2 3

-483

-5 4 9

-627

-726

-8 1

-9 2 0

-9 5 4

-1 ,0 1 2

11,000

426

244

36

-1 2 1

-1 4 2

-1 6 4

-2 0 6

-2 5 1

-31 1

-3 5 5

-4 0 5

-549

-6 1 3

-6 9

-8 0 2

-8 3 6

-8 6 6

—9 0 7

10,000

38 2

212

30

-137

-180

-1 9 1

-2 1 0

-240

-2 7 5

-3 1 9

-3 4 9

-4 7 1
-4 0 5

-4 8 3

-5 4 7

-5 9

-696

-7 3 0

-7 6 0

-7 7 3

-8 1 1

9,0 0 0

332

162

-8

-1 4 9

-2 0 2

-2 3 5

-243

-2 5 0

-2 7 0

-2 8 9

-319

-3 5 5

-4 2 3

-487

-5 3

-6 0 1

-6 3 0

-660

-6 7 3

-6 8 3

-6 9 6

-716

8,000

2 96

126

-4 4

-1 7 3

-200

-2 4 3

-273

-2 6 9

-2 6 6

-2 7 0

-2 7 5

-311

-3 5 9

-4 1 3

-4 6

-527

-5 2 1

-5 4 6

-5 5 9

-5 6 9

-5 5 4

-5 6 2

-566

7,000

265

106

-6 4

-1 9 3

-2 0 8

-2 2 5

-265

-2 8 3

-2 6 9

-250

-2 4 0

-2 5 1

-2 9 9

-3 3 3

-3 7

-4 3 7

-4 3 1

-4 2 1

-4 2 9

-4 3 9

-4 2 4

-4 0 4

-3 9 6

-3 9 6

6,0 0 0

24 7

85

-74

-2 0 3

-2 1 8

-2 2 3

-2 3 7

-2 6 5

-2 7 3

-2 4 3

-2 1 0

-229

-2 6 3

-2 8

-3 3 7

-3 3 1

-3 2 1

-2 9 4

-2 9 9

-2 8 4

-2 6 4

-2 2 8

-216

5,0 0 0

233

79

-8 3

-2 0 1

-2 2 1

-2 2 3

-2 2 5

-2 4 3

-2 3 5

-1 9 1

-1 7 2

-1 8 1

-2 0

-2 3 5

-2 1 9

-2 0 9

- 1 82

-1 5 2

-1 3 2

-1 1 2

-7 6

-3 6

4,000

196

68

-8 6

-207

-216
-2 1 1

-206
-1 6 4

-216

-218

-2 0 8

-2 0 0

-2 0 2

-180

-1 4 2

-127

-1 2 1

-1 5 0

-1 1 4

-9 4

-3 7

43

79

119

185

217

25 4

41

41

-8 7

-200

-2 0 7

-2 0 1

-1 9 3

-1 7 3

-1 4 9

-137

-1 2 1

-9 5

-6 6

-5 5

-19

58

88

284

350

410

459

0
0

0
0

0
0

-8 7

-8 3
79

-6 4

30
212

36
24 4

40
238

129

190

28 7

327

382

518

56 3

629

68 9

76 6

106

-8
162

12"

85

-4 4
126

80

41

-8 6
68

203
442

244

2,000
1,000

-2 0 3
-7 4

123210

-6 7

3,000

-1 1
-4

0

0

0

0

41

196

233

24 7

265

296

3 32

38 2

426

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,0 0 0

6,0 0 0

7,000

8,000

9,0 0 0

10,000

11,000

1,258
858

22
(Positive figures indicate tax savings John and Jane receive if they are
married rather than single. Negative figures indicate extra taxes John and
Jane pay if they are married rather than single.)

-5 6 6

|

-1 ,0 6 5
-9 5 7
-8 3 6

1 14318

-190
1

2

22
499
818

858

31

339

41 5

480

537

597

6 62

722

79 8

878

94 9

1,009

1,086

1,166

1,218

1,258

446

25 6
45 4

48

526

62 5

70 5

787

847

93 2

1,002

1,078

1,158

1,264

1,329

1,406

1,486

1,566

1,618

1,701

1 2,000

13,000

14,00

15,000

16,000

1 7,000

18,000

19,000

2 0 ,000

21,000

22,0 0 0

23,0 0 0

24,0 0 0

25,000

26,0 0 0

2 7 ,000

28,000

29,0 0 0

3 0 ,0 0 0

Jo h n’s Adjusted G ross Income
( Dollars)
N O T E : The figures represent the tax liability o f the com bined incom e o f two single w orkers minus the tax liability o f tw o m arried workers with the sam
jo in t incom e. Calculations assume tw o workers with no dependents. All incom e is derived from wages or salaries. T axpayers claim the standar
deduction and 1976 individual tax credit.

penalty on marriage, under the assumptions used here.
As the numbers indicate, the penalty is a function of
the size of combined income and the degree of equal­
ity between the two incomes. This means that the
closer Jane’s income is to John’s income and/or the
more John and Jane earn, the larger is the tax penalty
on marriage. Since the tax penalty increases with the
size of combined income, increases in income which
merely represent increases due to inflation increase
the tax penalty on married workers."
<JNancy Jianakoplos, “ Paying More Taxes and Affording It
Less,” this Review (July 1975), pp. 9-13.
Page 14



S O U R C E : Computed from 1976 Federal incom e tax schedules.

Tax Provisions
Aware of the family characteristics which contribute
to the marriage penalty, one can examine the specific
provisions of the tax structure which produce this
result. Table II compares and contrasts how John’s
and Jane’s taxes are calculated when each is single
and when they are married. In both cases, their ad­
justed gross incomes (A G I) are $15,000 each. If they
are married, their joint income equals $30,000. A first
step in tax computation is to deduct their personal
exemption allowances. As single taxpayers, John and
Jane are each entitled to a $750 personal exemption.

This reduces each of their AGI’s to $14,250, for a
combined total of $28,500. As married taxpayers, they
can also deduct $750 apiece as personal exemptions,
leaving a household AGI of $28,500. Thus, the per­
sonal exemption has not contributed directly to either
a tax benefit or penalty on marriage.
Next, each single taxpayer can subtract the stand­
ard deduction equal to 16 percent of AGI, but not less
than $1,700 or greater than $2,400. As a single tax­
payer, 16 percent of John’s AGI is $2,400, the maxi­
mum allowable standard deduction. Jane can also

deduct $2,400 as a single taxpayer. If single, John and
Jane each take standard deductions which total
$4,800, leaving taxable incomes of $11,850 each
($23,700 combined). In contrast, as married taxpayers,
their maximum allowable standard deduction is $2,800
leaving taxable income of $25,700. Thus, the standard
deduction benefits the two taxpayers more when they
are single than when they are married.
Next, the tax rates are applied to taxable income in
order to determine the tax liability. It is important to
note that there are four different tax rate schedules.
Page 15

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

Single taxpayers with dependents use the “head of
household” tax schedule. Single people who do not
qualify as a head of household must use the tax rates
for single taxpayers. Married taxpayers may either
file a joint or separate return. The tax schedule for
married taxpayers filing separately differs from the
rates applied to single taxpayers. The “married sepa­
rate” schedule applies “married joint” rates to half the
income that would be taxed at each level on the
“married joint” schedule. Consequently, the tax rate
progression is much steeper on the “married separate”
schedule. Unless one spouse has a large amount of tax
preferred income, such as capital gains or medical
expenses, a married couple usually minimizes their tax
liability by filing a joint return.
John and Jane, as single taxpayers must pay taxes
on $11,850 of income each. This puts them in the 27
percent marginal bracket of the tax rate schedule for
single taxpayers. Consequently, John and Jane each
have tax liabilities of $2,583 for a total of $5,166.10 As
married taxpayers, John and Jane have $25,700 of joint
taxable income, which puts them in the 36 percent
marginal tax bracket for married taxpayers filing joint
returns. Their joint tax liability is $6,272 or $1,106
more than their combined tax liabilities as single tax­
payers. Thus, tax rates benefit two single taxpayers
more than two married taxpayers.11
Finally, as single taxpayers John and Jane can each
claim an individual tax credit equal to the greater of
$35 each or 2 percent of taxable income ($11,850
apiece) limited to $180. Thus, John and Jane are each
entitled to reduce their tax liabilities by $180, for a
final tax of $2,403 each or $4,806 total. If John and
Jane are married, their joint tax credit is limited to
$180, as opposed to $180 each when single. Their final
joint tax liability is $6,092, which is $1,286 greater than
the combination of their single tax liabilities.
In summary, given the simplifying assumptions
made above, the standard deduction, the tax rate
schedules, and 1976 tax credits contribute to the ad­
ditional Federal income taxes paid by married work­
ing taxpayers simply because of their marital status.
10These figures are taken from the 1976 Tax Table, which the
IRS prepares. Since 1976 taxes are calculated over $50
income intervals for incomes less than $20,000, the liability
is slightly lower, than if calculated from the tax rate
schedules.
n The fact that single taxpayers have less taxable income as a
result of larger combined standard deductions does bias
downward the applicable tax bracket. However, because the
tax rate schedules differ between married and single tax­
payers, tax rates still contribute to the generally lower tax
liability for two single taxpayers, whose combined incomes
equal a married couple’s joint income.
16
Digitized for Page
FRASER


DECEM BER

1977

Table II

C O M P A R IS O N O F 1976 TAX C A L C U LA T IO N S
BETWEEN SIN G LE A N D M A RRIED STATUS*
S ingle

Adjusted Gross
Income
Personal
Exemption

Standard
Deduction
Taxable Income

Jane

Combined

Joint

$ 1 5 ,0 0 0

$ 1 5 ,0 0 0

$ 3 0 ,0 0 0

$ 3 0 ,0 0 0

75 0

75 0

1,500

1,500

$ 1 4 ,2 5 0

$ 1 4 ,2 5 0

$ 2 8 ,5 0 0

$ 2 8 ,5 0 0

2,400

2,400

4,8 0 0

2,800

$1 1,850

$1 1,850

$ 2 3 ,7 0 0

$ 2 5 ,7 0 0

$ 2,583

$ 5,1 6 6

$ 6,272

180

$ 2,583
1 80

36 0

180

$ 2,403

$ 2,403

$ 4,8 0 6

$ 6,092

M a rgin a l
Tax Bracket
Tax Liability
Tax Credit
Tax

Married

John

27%

36%

•Assumes no dependents and all incom e is from wages or salaries.

CONSEQUENCES
There are several important consequences of the tax
penalty imposed on two married workers. One readily
apparent effect of this differential tax treatment is
that 1976 tax laws made it more expensive for two
married people to work. The disincentive to work
provided by tax laws affects the money standard of
living which a household will achieve. If the tax laws
make it more expensive to work, other things held
constant, households will achieve a lower money in­
come than would be otherwise possible.
The work disincentive of the tax laws is of particular
importance in the decision of married women to enter
the labor force. Since it is traditionally (but not always
correctly) assumed that the husband is the primary
breadwinner, the wife is typically considered to have
greater latitude in deciding to enter the labor force.
In making a rational decision to go to work, a wife
would balance (either explicitly or implicitly) the
added costs of going back to work, such as child care
expenses, transportation costs, appropriate clothes,
etc., against the additional income she will earn. The
additional income will be her salary after taxes and
other deductions. The tax penalty on married workers
reduces her salary more than if she were single.
For example, if her husband makes $10,000, the last
dollar of his income is taxed at 19 percent.12 When
1-This figure assumes that the standard deduction is used, all
income is derived from wages or salaries, and the married
couple has no dependents and files a joint return.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO U IS

the wife goes to work, since her husband is already
working and paying taxes, the first dollar of her in­
come is taxed at 19 percent. That is, her income does
not benefit from exemptions, deductions, or lower
marginal tax rates applicable on initial amounts of
income. Consequently, the tax structure has a nega­
tive influence on the labor force participation of
married women. Of course, other factors can and have
offset this influence, as evident from the increase in
the labor force participation rate of married women
in recent years.
Another effect of the disparity between the tax
treatment of workers who are married and those who
are single is an increase in Government revenue. The
Government collects more taxes, under the circum­
stances outlined above, when two workers marry
rather than remain single. In addition, when mar­
ried workers receive cost-of-living adjustments, the
Government also benefits, as mentioned earlier, since
the extra tax liability on married workers increases as
their incomes increase. Thus, the tax penalty on mar­
ried workers makes the Government’s deficit less than
it would be otherwise.
A final consideration is that the differentiation of
tax liability based only on marital status tends to
undermine the equity which many people expect to
find in the tax system. The less “just” a tax, the more
incentive there is to find ways to avoid paying the tax,
and this in turn reduces tax revenues or increases the
cost of enforcing tax laws.

DECEM BER

1977

ture in 1948 to make this benefit available to all mar­
ried taxpayers. This was done by doubling the income
ranges for married taxpayers associated with each tax
rate. For example, if the first $500 of income were
taxed at 14 percent for a single person, the first $1,000
of income for married couples would be taxed at
14 percent.
While the income-splitting provision extended tax
benefits to married couples in all of the states, single
taxpayers were now subject to much higher marginal
tax rates than a married person making the same in­
come, but able to benefit from the income-splitting
provision. Perceiving the harsher tax treatment of
single people, lawmakers lowered the tax rates for
singles in 1971. As Table III shows, prior to 1971,
single taxpayers with the same taxable income (in­
come after subtracting personal exemptions and de­
ductions ) as married taxpayers filing jointly could pay
as much as 42 percent more taxes than a married
couple. The 1971 rate changes for single taxpayers
reduced this differential to 20 percent. In reducing
rates for single taxpayers, however, a tax penalty for
households in which both spouses are employed
resulted.
Measures already enacted to change 1977 tax laws
alter the standard deductions allowed single and mar­
ried taxpayers, thereby partially reducing the tax
penalty on married workers. In 1976 the maximum
Table III

SIN G LE TAXPAYER LIABILITIES A S A PERCENTAGE
OF M A RR IED TAXPAYER LIABILITIES’

POSSIBLE REMEDIES
Considering the traditionally high value placed on
marriage, family, and work in American society, it is
likely that steps will eventually be taken to reduce
the tax penalty imposed on married workers. The
existence of this penalty is itself the result of previous
Congressional actions which attempted to correct ap­
parent inequities in the tax structure. Prior to 1948,
husbands and wives in community property states
could each claim half of their household income for
tax purposes, even if only one of the spouses actually
earned all of the income. For example, if one spouse
earned $20,000 and the other was not employed out­
side the home, each claimed $10,000 of income. Given
the progressively higher marginal tax rates, two in­
comes of $10,000 were taxed less than one $20,000
income. In noncommunity property states, this benefit
was not available. A provision referred to as incomesplitting was added to the Federal income tax struc­



Taxable
Income2
;

1,000

197 0

1976

3 .6 %

5,0 0 0

12.3

3 .6 %
11.2

10,000
15,000

20.3
30.9

16.9

20,0 0 0

38.6

19.4

14.8

22,0 0 0

40.0

19.3

24,0 0 0

41.9

26,0 0 0
28,0 0 0

41.5
42.1

20.0
19.0

3 0 ,0 0 0

41.5

19.2

4 0 ,0 0 0

37.3

18.5

6 0 ,0 0 0

29.1

18.3

8 0 ,000

25.3

18.1

1 0 0 ,0 0 0

22.8

17.5

1,000,00 0

2.2

1.8

19.6

1M axim um tax on earned incom e, 1970 tax surcharge, and 1976 tax
credit are ignored. Assumes m arried couple files jo in t return.
2Taxable incom e is that incom e, a fter exem ptions and deductions, on
which tax liability is com puted.
S ou rce: Calculated from statutory tax rates.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E BA N K OF ST. LO UIS

standard deduction was $2,800 for a married couple
and $4,800 for two single workers, a $2,000 difference.
The 1977 law provides a $3,200 standard deduction
for joint returns and $2,200 ($4,400 combined) for
singles. This reduces the difference to $1,200.13
Recent proposals by the Treasury Department call
for a special tax deduction to be granted to families
where both spouses work outside the home, to deal
explicitly with the tax penalty on married workers.14
Under this proposal, the spouse with the lower income
would be allowed to deduct 10 percent of the first
$6,000 of earnings. This proposal would benefit lower
income couples relatively more than couples with
higher incomes.
An alternative method, not included in the Treasury
proposals, would completely eliminate the tax penalty
on married workers. Married individuals who both
work could be given the option of using the single tax
rate schedule. Couples could compute their taxes
using the “married joint,” “married separate,” and
“single” schedules and use the status which minimizes
their joint tax liability, with the provision that both
spouses must use the same schedule.
13Handbook for Tax Reduction and Simplification Act of 1977,
Federal Taxes, Report Bulletin 25, Section 2 (Englewood
Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall, 1977), p. 5.
14David E. Rosenblum, “ Most Families W ould Pay Less Under
Tax Plan,” New York Times, September 30, 1977.

Page 18



DECEM BER

1977

CONCLUSION
Two individuals, who both work, can be taxed more
if they are married than if they are single. The more
equal their incomes and the larger their incomes, the
greater the tax penalty on married workers. The
standard deduction, tax rate schedule, and individual
tax credit provisions contributed to the greater tax
liability for married couples in 1976. The tax penalty
can be viewed as either a disincentive for working,
single people to marry, or as a disincentive for mar­
ried people to work. While Congressional intent has
never shown an active interest in influencing such
decisions, the tax structure imposes a tax penalty or
benefit on households depending on the marital and
employment status of the household members.
In a broader context, the tax penalty on married
workers is illustrative of the complex and sometimes
unintended consequences of tax provisions. Tax
credits and reductions have been prescribed from
time to time to “stimulate” the economy, reduce
•energy consumption, promote capital formation, and
aid various other social and economic causes. While
the intended objectives of these tax provisions may be
worthwhile and laudable, the unintended conse­
quences may be unacceptable and contrary to social
values. The tax penalty on married workers illustrates
the necessity of careful consideration of all of the
possible consequences of tax proposals.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K OF ST. LO U IS

DECEM BER

1977

REVIEW INDEX - 1977
Issue

Title

Issue

Title

Jan.

Are You Protected From Inflation?
The 1975-76 Federal Deficits and the Credit
Market

July

The Nature and Origins of the U.S. Energy
Crisis
Revision of the Monetary Base

Feb.

A Guide to Capital Outlays in the Current
Recovery
Operations of the Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis — 1976
Outlook for Farm Income in 1977

Aug.

Mar.

The FOMC in 1976: Progress Against Inflation
Free Trade: A Major Factor in U.S. Farm
Income

Utilization of Federal Reserve Bank Services by
Member Banks: Implications for the Costs
and Benefits of Membership
Estimates of the High-Employment Budget and
Changes in Potential Output
Income and Expenses of Eighth District Mem­
ber Banks

Sept.

Some Considerations in the Use of Monetary
Aggregates for the Implementation of
Monetary Policy
Debt-Management Policy and the Own Price
Elasticity of Demand for U.S. Government
Notes and Bonds

Oct.

The Growing Similarities Among Financial
Institutions
The Early 1960s: A Guide to the Late 1970s

Nov.

Economic Goals for 1981: A Monetary Analysis
Effects of Interest on Demand Deposits: Impli­
cations of Compensating Balances

Dec.

Farm Price Supports at Cost of Production
Do Foreigners Control the U.S. Money Supply?
The Tax Penalty on Married Workers

Apr.

Inventory Investment in the Recent Recession
and Recovery
The Effects of Changes in Inflationary
Expectations
Food: Outlook Favorable for Consumers

May

The Effects of the New Energy Regime on Eco­
nomic Capacity, Production, and Prices
The Growing Link Between the Federal Gov­
ernment and State and Local Government
Financing
So What, It’s Only a Five Percent Inflation

June

The Treasury Bill Futures Market and Market
Expectations of Interest Rates
Energy Resources and Potential GNP




Page 19