View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF ST. LOUIS
DECEMBER 1969




1969 —

Battle A gainst Inflation ...............

2

Selective Credit — N o Substitute for
M onetary Restraint................................. 13
Interest Rates and Price Level Changes,
1952-69

18

Federal Reserve System Actions
During 1969 ........................................ 39
Review Index —

1969 ............................... 40

1969—Battle Against Inflation
by NORMAN N. BOWSHER

] \ INETEEN SIXTY-NINE has been the fifth year
of intensifying inflation. Overall prices, after remain­
ing fairly stable in the early Sixties, rose 1.7 per cent
during 1965, 3.5 per cent a year in 1966 and 1967,
4.0 per cent during 1968, and an estimated 5 per cent
in 1969. Not since W orld War II has the American
economy experienced such a sustained price upsurge.
General Price Index *

R a tio S c a le

R a tio S c a le

1958=100
130

1958=100
130

of experts are neither complacent about inflation, nor
so pessimistic about its cure. Although stopping infla­
tion is generally believed to involve hardships, it is
felt that the necessary transition costs of following
proper public policies would not be great compared
with the inequities and inefficiencies resulting from
continued reductions in the purchasing power of the
dollar.
This article traces the course of the inflation of
the past five years. It sets forth some of the chief
causes and effects, reviews the actions taken to resist
inflation, presents an analysis of economic develop­
ments during 1969, and provides some observations
on the outlook.

Balanced Economic Expansion
1961 through 1964

1961

1962

1963

1964

1965

1966

1967

1968

1969

• A * used in No tio nal Income Accounts
Source: U.S. Deportm ent of Commerce
Percentages are a n nu a l rates of chan ge between periods indicated. They are presented to a id in
com paring most recent developm ents with pa st "tren d s.”
late st d ata plotted: 3rd quarter

Inflation has been the nation’s most serious domestic
economic problem in recent years. The extent of con­
cern over this problem has been evident from the
numerous tough decisions the public authorities have
made in an attempt to moderate it. Tax rates were
raised, growth in Government spending was reduced,
and monetary growth was restrained. Despite these
actions there is as yet no firm evidence that the rise
in prices has decelerated, or that inflationary expecta­
tions have moderated.
Some believe that inflation has now become inevi­
table, and that the country should learn to live with
it. They feel that inflation has some desirable features,
and that even if undesirable on balance, the nation
apparently cannot stop it, or the costs of doing so are
likely to exceed the benefits. At the other extreme,
some feel that inflation is intolerable, and that it must
be stopped even though the necessary cost is likely
to be a severe and prolonged recession. The majority
Page 2



—

Following the recession of 1960, the country ex­
perienced four years of pronounced economic expan­
sion with little inflationary pressure. Real output of
goods and services increased at a 5.4 per cent annual
rate from early 1961 to late 1964. Except for a pause
in late 1962, this was a period of steady economic
expansion.
In the early Sixties real growth was faster than the
estimated 4 per cent rate of growth in productive
potential. As a result, unemployment was reduced
from about 7 per cent of the labor force in early 1961
to less than 5 per cent in late 1964, and manufactur­
ing plant utilization rose from 75 per cent to 86 per
cent of normal capacity. These gains were accom­
plished in an orderly fashion without great frictions,
shortages, or imbalances, while average prices re­
mained relatively steady. Overall prices, measured
by the GNP deflator, rose at a 1.3 per cent annual
rate. However, because of the difficulty of fully taking
account of changes in discounts granted and quality
improvements, the index probably overstated the
actual price increase.
The economy demonstrated a great resiliency and
ability to expand in the 1961 to 1964 period.
Fiscal and monetary management caused no great
shocks to the economy, and the free enterprise system
responded admirably. The nation’s money stock grew
at a 2.7 per cent annual rate from mid-1960 to mid-

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUI S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

Excessive Spending and Inflation
1965 through 1969

—

Since 1964 total spending for goods and services
has risen much faster than the country’s potential to
supply them. Total outlays rose at an average 8 per
cent annual rate from late 1964 to late 1969. With
little excess capacity, increases in real output were
constrained by the growth in the nation’s capacity to
produce. The rise in spending was roughly double
the estimated rate of expansion in potential output,
given the growth in the labor force, capital equip­
ment and technology.

1964, faster than the average 2 per cent rate of the
previous decade, but slower than the estimated 4
per cent rate of growth in productive capacity. Dur­
ing the early Sixties policymakers faced two major
economic problems which apparently called for op­
posite courses, probably accounting for a compromise
between moderate and relatively steady growth in
money. Unused resources were a signal for monetary
expansion while an adverse balance of payments and
gold outflows called for restraint. Since the demand
for money to hold was probably increasing less rap­
idly than either real production or productive poten­
tial, it was appropriate that money expand less rapidly
than either of these magnitudes in order to avoid
inordinate inflation.
The influence of the Federal budget on total spend­
ing, as commonly measured, was moderate from 1960
to early 1964. The growth rate of Government
spending and the net surplus or deficit of both the
high employment and the national income accounts
budgets remained in fairly narrow ranges. Despite the
strong and balanced economic expansion without ex­
cesses during the early Sixties, some policy advisers
held theories which indicated that the state of the
budget was highly depressing to total spending, pro­
duction, and employment. After a substantial delay,
taxes were cut in early 1964, with the objective of
keeping the country moving by eliminating the al­
leged actual or potential “fiscal drag.”



Most sectors of the economy have participated in
the rapid increase in spending which began in late
1964. Government purchases of military goods have
expanded at an 11 per cent annual rate since 1964,
compared with a trend rate of 2 per cent from 1957
to 1964. Other Federal Government expenditures
have also increased at an 11 per cent rate since late
1964. Business investment has risen at an 8 per cent
rate since late 1964, after increasing at a 5 per cent
rate from 1957 to 1964. Personal consumption expendi­
tures have increased at a 7.6 per cent rate since late
1964, following a 5 per cent rate of increase from
1957 to 1964.
With spending on goods and services rising faster
than their production, prices were bid up. The rate of
inflation appeared mild at first, reflecting inflexibility
of some prices in the short run, the moderate amount

Demand and Production
R a tio S c a le

Q u arterly Totals at A n n u al Rates

R atio S c a le

Q G N P in current dollars.
Source: U.S. Department of Comm erce
[2 G N P in 1958 dollars
Percentages are annual rates of change between periods indicated. They are presented to aid in
comparing most recent developments with past "trends.”
Latest d ata plotted: 3rd quarter

Page 3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

of excessive demand, and fuller use of resources.
Overall prices went up 1.7 per cent from late 1964 to
late 1965. About one-sixth of the rise in total spend­
ing was reflected in higher prices while five-sixths
went for additional goods and services.
As time passed, demand-pull intensified, and price
increases accelerated. During both 1966 and 1967
prices rose 3.5 per cent, and in 1968 they rose 4 per
cent. Only about half the total growth in spending
during the 1966 through 1968 period went for addi­
tional real output; the other half was taken in higher
prices. Effective prices may have risen even more than
these figures indicate, for when demand becomes ex­
cessive, discounts and rebates are eliminated, sur­
charges abound, and there is a tendency to reduce
quality standards. In the preparation of price indexes,
some of these developments may have been missed,
since producers are not likely to disclose their com­
plete discount policies or a deterioration in product
quality.
The inflation has been even more severe during
1969. The continued rise in total spending in excess
of production, prompted in part by deterioration of
the illusion that money has a relatively constant value,
has contributed to the greater price increases. Overall
prices have gone up about 5 per cent in the past year,
even though there has been a little moderation of
growth in total spending. As a result, nearly threefourths of the rise in outlays has been used to pay
higher prices. Growth in real production declined to
about 2 per cent in 1969, or to about half the trend
rate. In recent months the rise in prices probably has
been at about the same pace as the rise in spending,
with little net change in total real output.

Causes of Excessive Spending and Inflation
In our free enterprise system each spending unit —
household, business firm, or governmental unit — de­
termines whether to spend or save the funds available
to it. Hence, one might conclude that the excessive
total spending resulted from an unfortunate bunching
of expansive individual decisions. Such a conclusion
is only a half-truth, providing little insight into the
basic forces determining total spending.
Consumer spending is closely related to income, and
business outlays are generally related to expected
profits. Although these sectors account for a major
portion of total spending, and changes in them do
have considerable affects on total spending, they alone
have seldom been the prime motivating forces in
bringing about cyclical movements in total spending
Page 4



DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

Two forces in the economy which are under the
control of public policy and which are believed to
have a great influence on private spending decisions
are fiscal policy and monetary management. Most
studies of economic stabilization have focused on
them.
Fiscal Actions — The results of decisions by the Fed­
eral Government which change its spending and tax­
ing programs are fiscal actions. It has commonly been
believed that such changes expand or contract total
public and private spending by some multiple. H ow­
ever, the aggregate influence of the Government on
total spending is greatly diminished if the resulting
deficits or surpluses are financed by the public out of
planned saving rather than accompanied by changes
in the money stock.1 Changes in Government activi­
ties tend to be offset by opposite movements in pri­
vate spending when the Government finances its
deficits with debt paid for by the public out of cur­
rent planned saving.
Among the commonly used measures of Govern­
ment fiscal actions are the national income accounts
budget, the expenditure component of this budget,
and the high-employment variation of it. The national
income accounts budget summarizes the receipts and
expenditures of the Federal Government sector as an
integral part of the national income accounts. The
high-employment budget is an estimate of the ex­
penditures and revenues in the Federal sector of the
national income accounts at an assumed constant rate
of growth of real economic activity (conventionally
about 4 per cent unemployment). It attempts to ab­
stract from the impact of actual economic activity on
the realized surplus or deficit.
It is widely believed that the inflation since 1964
has been caused by Government fiscal mismanage­
ment. Forthcoming defense spending was greatly un­
derestimated, there was lack of restraint on non-de­
fense outlays, and there was delay in raising taxes.
As a result, from 1963 to mid-1968 the Government
cut tax rates and increased growth rates in both de­
fense and nondefense outlays. The high-employment
budget, which was at a $13 billion surplus in 1963,
declined to about a $14 billion annual rate of deficit
in the first half of 1968. The national income accounts
budget shifted from a small surplus in 1963 to a $9
billion deficit in the first half of 1968. From 1963 to
1Leonall Andersen and Jerry Jordan, “Monetary and Fiscal
Actions: A Test of Their Relative Importance in Economic
Stabilization,” this Review, November 1968, pp. 11-24; and
Michael Keran, “Monetary and Fiscal Influences on Eco­
nomic Activity — The Historical Evidence,” this Review,
November 1969, pp. 5-24.

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

rose at a 7.3 per cent rate until January 1969. The
course of money reflected roughly parallel courses
of Federal Reserve credit, the monetary base and
member bank reserves.

Effects of Inflation
Inflation is a rise in the general level of prices
or, otherwise stated, a decline in the purchasing power
of the dollar, and tends to cause a redistribution of
wealth and income.2 It affects holders of money
adversely, reduces the relative value of bonds, savings
accounts, and other dollar-denominated assets, and
gives a windfall to debtors. For a savings account
drawing 5 per cent per year interest, while prices
increase at a 6 per cent annual rate, the saver re­
ceives a net yield before taxes of minus one per cent,
since when the saver receives his principal plus in­
terest, the funds will buy less than his principal alone
would have bought at the time the deposit was made.
After-tax income is a yet greater net loss.
early 1968 national income accounts expenditures rose
at a 10 per cent annual rate, after increasing at a 6
per cent rate from 1957 to 1963.
Monetary Actions — Another force under the con­
trol of public policymakers, which is believed to have
a vital influence on private spending decisions, is
monetary actions. The Federal Reserve, by determin­
ing the volume of Federal Reserve credit outstanding
and thereby the amount of the monetary base and
the reserves of the member banks, can manage the
supply of money (demand deposits and currency)
in the economy. By supplying more money than the
public desires to hold, given current levels of income,
wealth, and interest rates, the public’s demand for
other financial assets and for real goods and services
is stimulated. Businesses and households undertake
to exchange excess money balances for assets which
will provide more satisfaction. Conversely, by pro­
viding less money than the public wishes to hold, the
central bank can place downward pressure on the
rate of spending, since businesses and individuals will
reduce outlays in an attempt to build up cash balances
in relation to other assets.
Monetary actions share responsibility for the over­
heating of the economy. From the end of 1964 to the
end of 1968 the stock of money rose at an average 5
per cent annual rate. By comparison, money grew at
about a 2 per cent rate from 1957 to 1964. By sub­
periods, from late 1964 to the spring of 1966 money
rose at a rapid 6 per cent rate, remained on a plateau
during the summer, fall and winter of 1966, and then



Inflation has different effects on various individuals
and businesses, depending on types of assets and
liabilities held and sources of income, which, in turn,
may have been affected by the extent to which infla­
tion has been anticipated. When inflation can be an­
ticipated and provided for, types of asset and liability
holdings may be adjusted and the rate of price in­
crease built into contracts by cost-of-living or other
escalators. If both borrower and lender expect a 5 per
cent inflation, and funds are worth a real 4 per cent,
the interest rate stated in the contract would be 9
per cent. Then, with the 5 per cent rate of inflation,
neither party gains nor loses.3 Hence, with greater
inflationary expectations market interest rates are
driven up to progressively higher levels.
Since there is much uncertainty about the future
course of prices and all people are not capable of
making contracts against contingencies, inflation
causes a redistribution of wealth and income. Money
is noninterest bearing, and so adjustments cannot be
made for reduced purchasing power of money hold­
ings. Many mortgages, pensions, bonds, and other
long-term contracts cannot be changed until they ma­
ture. Persons with small savings have been especially
disadvantaged by inflation.
2See Albert E. Burger, “The Effects of Inflation (1960-68),”
this Review, November 1969, pp. 25-36.
3Income tax considerations would make the stated rate even
higher, since the borrower is able to deduct from his income
the amount of interest paid, and the lender must include
as income the greater amount of interest received.
Page 5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

Inflation has a tendency to cause inefficiencies and
reduce output. For example, many find it advanta­
geous to devote more effort to holding cash balances
to a minimum. Because some prices are not com­
pletely flexible, shortages develop, causing inefficien­
cies in production. Uncertainties regarding the rate
of inflation tend to encourage speculation.

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

Federal Government Expenditures
N a t i o n a l In c o m e A c c o u n t s B u d g e t
R a tio S c a le

500
400

400

300

300
+3 9 %

200

Actions Taken to Resist Inflation
Because inflation is such a serious problem, the
Government has regretted the policy errors which
produced it, and taken a number of actions designed
to resist or eliminate it. Unfortunately, many of these
actions have been based on poor economic analysis,
and they have proven to be largely ineffective, at
least until very recently. Chief actions presumed and
intended to be anti-inflationary have been raising tax
rates, reducing the rate of increase of planned Gov­
ernment spending, regulating credit, permitting high
interest rates, using moral suasion, and slowing the
growth in money. Some have suggested that since
these measures as yet have been largely ineffective in
stopping price acceleration, the country should resort
to a broad set of wage and price controls in order to
govern prices.
Fiscal Actions — Because the rapid increase in the
demand for goods and services and the resulting ac­
celeration of price increases were thought to stem
from expansionary fiscal actions, a serious step in re­
sisting inflation was to reverse these actions. In fact,
it was widely felt that the best, and perhaps only,
way to reduce inflation was to raise taxes and reduce
Government spending.
After long deliberations filled with assurances of
potency of fiscal actions, the Revenue and Expendi­
ture Control Act was passed and signed into law on
June 28, 1968. The Act represented a significant move
in fiscal policy for the express purpose of moderating
Digitized for Page
FRASER
6


+14.5

To al
-

The presumed benefits of inflation are dependent
upon its continued acceleration and upon the losses
of some to the benefit of others. Only if the rate of
inflation were stabilized, with all the public fully an­
ticipating it and acting upon the anticipations intelli­
gently and costlessly, would the rate of inflation be
immaterial. But, under present conditions of uncer­
tainty, nonuniform expectations, and lack of flexibility,
inflation is unjust, inefficient, and undesirable, and it
is the stated policy of the Government to eliminate it.

R a tio S c a le
illio n s o f D o ll a r s

Quarterly Data at An n ual Rates

B illio n s o f D o ll a r s

__

— '—

—

_

793.6

100

100

80

+20 9%

' 80.3

+1.1%
/V

. ---

60
----------

40

20

200

+4.6%

^

lslqlr.

2nd qtr

2nd qtr.

t

...

1961

80
60

1962

1963

1964

1

1965

1966

t

1967

2nd qtr.

t
1968

3rd qtr.

t
1969

Source: U.S. Department of Comm erce
Percentages are an nu a l rates of change between periods indicated. They are presented to aid in
com paring most recent developm ents with past "trends."
Latest d ata plotted: 3rd quarter

growth of total demand, and thereby reducing infla­
tion. The major features of the Act were reductions
in some proposed spending and a 10 per cent sur­
charge on corporate and individual income taxes.
Reflecting the provisions of the Act and a few sub­
sequent decisions made in the same spirit, growth in
total Federal expenditures slowed sharply. In the
last half of 1968 outlays in the national income ac­
counts budget rose at an 8 per cent annual rate, and
in the first three quarters of 1969 at only a 4 per cent
rate, compared with a rapid 13 per cent per year
pace from late 1964 to mid-1968.
The larger tax receipts, flowing from the surtax and
the higher levels of the public’s income, and the
slower growth in Government spending led to an
abrupt reversal in the Federal budgets. The national
income accounts budget went from a $9 billion annual
rate deficit in the first half of 1968 to a $10 billion
rate surplus in the first three quarters of 1969. On a
high-employment budget basis, the shift was from a
rate of $14 billion deficit to an $8 billion surplus.
Despite the predominant feeling that a tax increase
and some expenditure controls were necessary, many
analysts in the late summer and fall of 1968 felt that
the steps actually taken were too vigorous, and ex­
pressed a fear of overkill. Most econometric models
of the economy indicated a quick and drastic slow­
down in spending and inflation as a result of the fiscal
actions. Arthur Okun, then the Chairman of the Coun­
cil of Economic Advisers, summed up this opinion by
stating, “I know of no one who would say now that our
worries are still those of expanding too fast. If any­

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

thing, the balance has shifted a bit in the other
direction.”4
Responding to the marked shift in sentiment and
expectations after the tax increase and the cut of
planned Government spending, monetary policy was
ostensibly relaxed. The directive to the System’s op­
erating manager on July 16, 1968, stated in part, “The
new fiscal restraint measures are expected to contri­
bute to a considerable moderation of the rate of ad­
vance in aggregate demands,” and he was instructed
to accommodate “ . . . the tendency toward somewhat
less firm conditions in the money market . . ”6
Not all early evaluations of the impact of the fiscal
action agreed that the inflation would be stemmed by
this action alone. For example, this bank’s study of
the effects of the fiscal program published in the
August 1968 issue of this Review (pp. 3-6) concluded:
Fiscal authorities have adopted a program
of Federal budget restraint in an effort to com ­
bat excessive total demand. It is hoped that
this action will moderate inflationary pressures
while only slightly affecting output and em­
ployment. However, an inflationary psychology
has becom e entrenched in the economy, as
evidenced by large wage settlements and the
rising costs of credit. If the Administration and
Congress have finally assigned high priority to
the task of reducing inflationary pressures,
monetary actions to complement the fiscal pro­
gram are needed.

The tax increase and the controls placed on Fed­
eral spending did not produce the results expected
by their sponsors. Excessive growth in total demand
continued at only a slightly reduced rate. Slower
growth in spending by the Federal Government was
largely offset by greater outlays by those who were
able to attract the funds formerly flowing to the Gov­
ernment to finance its deficits. To some, fiscal action
as a tool of economic stabilization became largely
discredited by this experience, while the more de­
voted followers of this approach believe that the in­
flation would have been much worse without the
higher tax rates and spending cuts, that the actions
were not large relative to the size of either the econ­
omy or the inflation, and yet total spending growth
stopped accelerating and slowed moderately after the
action.
Interest Rates — Market interest rates have risen
greatly since the early 1960’s, but the increasing rates,
4“What’s Ahead for Business,” U. S. News and World Report,
August 5, 1968, pp. 52-55.
5Federal Reserve Bulletin, October 1968, p. 866.



excessive total spending and resulting inflation. Yields
on highest grade seasoned corporate bonds, which
averaged less than 4% per cent in the first half of the
1960’s, rose to 5.13 per cent in 1966, 5.51 per cent in
1967, 6.18 per cent in 1968 and over 7.30 per cent in
the fall of 1969. Interest rates on other marketable
securities also increased sharply.
Greater costs of credit, it was argued, should mod­
erate inflation since higher rates make expansion of
spending more difiicult and are a stimulus to increased
saving. The high interest rates have made it more
costly for businessmen to purchase plant, equipment,
and inventories. Higher rates have made it more
expensive for consumers to buy homes, purchase
automobiles, and obtain other durable goods. Yet, the
excessive growth in aggregate spending has continued,
placing more and more upward pressure on prices.
The higher interest rates have not stopped the in­
flation, but rather the inflation itself has been largely
responsible for the rise in rates. Interest rates are a
price for the use of funds, and as a price, they are
affected by inflation. Price expectations, as indicated
by recent actual price behavior, have been a major
factor in the rise of market interest rates.6 With
expected inflation, saving is discouraged unless inter6“ lnterest Rates and Price Level Changes, 1952-1969,” by
William P. Yohe and Denis S. Karnosky on pp. 18-38 of
this Review.
Page 7

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

est rates paid are high enough so that expected future
real purchasing power of funds is protected, while
boiTowers offer higher rates since they expect that
the prices of investment goods will increase.

annual rate from 1957 to 1968 to a 4.9 per cent rate
in the first half of 1969 and to a 1.8 per cent rate of
decline from June to November. With fewer funds
flowing to them, banks have had less to lend or invest.

The higher market rates in 1969 may have had no
more stimulative effect on savers or restraining in­
fluence on investors than the lower market rates did
in the early 1960’s. In fact, recent rates paid on sav­
ings accounts have not even equalled the attrition in
the purchasing power of the dollar, and many bor­
rowers have anticipated that equipment and building
costs would rise faster than the interest rate charged
to finance purchases. Income tax considerations have
also dulled the effectiveness of interest rates, since
lenders must pay taxes on interest “earnings” and
borrowers receive deductions for interest “expense.”

Regulation Q limitations, however, have had no
demonstrable effect on the total amount of credit ex­
tended in the economy. Funds have failed to flow
through commercial banks because they have been
attracted to users through other channels, such as di­
rect loans, commercial paper, and the Eurodollar
market. By diverting loan funds through a second
best route, the financial system has become less effi­
cient. Other financial intermediaries subject to similar
regulations have also been severely affected. Interest
rate limitations have made it more difficult for home
buyers and smaller businesses who must rely on local
institutions to obtain credit. Larger businesses which
can obtain funds in the central money markets have
probably obtained funds cheaper and more readily
than in the absence of disintermediation. Small savers
have been penalized by the low rates received, while
larger lenders who have more alternatives have re­
ceived higher returns. Despite these inequities and
disruptions to the financial system, it appears that
growth in total credit granted (bank plus nonbank)
was largely unaffected by the limitations placed on
interest rates paid by financial intermediaries.

Controlling Bank Credit — During 1969, the rate of
growth of commercial bank loans and investments
has been sharply reduced. In the first six months of
the year outstanding bank credit rose at a 3.5 per cent
annual rate, and since June has declined at about a
2 per cent rate. By comparison, this credit increased
at an average 7 per cent rate from 1959 to 1966, and
at an 11 per cent rate in 1967 and 1968. The reduc­
tion in the growth of bank credit has been brought
about largely by regulating the maximum interest
rate banks are allowed to pay on savings and other
time deposits (Regulation Q ). The marked slowing
in time deposits and corresponding bank credit
growth seems unlikely to have exercised any restraint
on excessive total spending and inflation.
Regulation Q was instituted following bank failures
of the early Thirties, primarily as a device to keep
maverick banks from establishing rates clearly out of
line with market conditions. However, in recent years
as market rates have risen above Regulation Q ceil­
ings, and most banks have found it increasingly diffi­
cult to compete for time deposit funds. Regulation Q
apparently has been considered a tool for influencing
total spending, on the grounds that a lower growth
in time deposits causes a reduced growth in bank
credit.
Largely because of limitations on interest rates
they can pay on time deposits, banks have been
drained of a substantial amount of time funds and
have been unable to attract a normal flow. Large
certificate of deposit obligations of commercial banks
have fallen by more than half in the past year, from
about $24 billion to about $11 billion. Growth in other
time and savings deposits slowed from an 11 per cent
Page 8



Moral Suasion — Another popular suggestion for re­
sisting inflation, which is usually considered to be
largely ineffective, is to ask the public to forego rais­
ing wages and prices. A set of guideposts was pro­
posed by the President’s Council of Economic Ad­
visers in mid-January 1969: wages were to be raised
no faster than average productivity growth ( estimated
at about 3 per cent a year), and prices were to be
established so as not to raise profit margins.
However, the guideposts and other appeals to the
public to use restraint in setting prices and wages
have never been effective. Workers and businessmen
cannot be expected to forego returns which are avail­
able to them. If they did, the economy would become
less efficient; incentives would be dulled; shortages
would quickly develop; and resources would not be
attracted into areas of greatest demand.
Some have suggested that prices and wages should
be rigidly controlled by law, with severe penalties for
violations. Yet, attempts to control prices in the past
indicate that such controls have been largely ineffec­
tive, because blackmarkets develop, quality deterio­
rates, and in other ways effective prices are raised.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

Money Stock
Ratio Scale
Billions o f D o lla rs

Ratio S cale
Billions o f D ollars

M onthly A v e ra g e s of D a ily Figures
S e a so n a lly Adjusted

210

210

205

205

+4.0%

200

200

from 1957 to 1964 when total spending was restrained.
Most of the recent slowing of the money supply oc­
curred in the demand deposit component. The cur­
rency component, which responds more to trends in
spending than to current changes in member bank
reserves, continued to rise rapidly in 1969.

199 r

195

195

190

190

185

185

180

180

175

175

170

170

|
-0.3%

165

165
160

160
155

N
•o

s

O'
o
S

4-

150

11 Iti 1 1 11 l . u l t i 1 1.1-I..I..

1966

1967

O'
;0
c
-3

Q
O>
o
Z

1 1 1 1 1 1 l 1 1 l I It; I 1 I itl I I 1 ltl

196 8

155
150

1969

Percentages are ann ual rates of c h an ge between periods indicated. They are presented

The reduced rate of money stock growth during
1969 reflected a marked reduction in the rate of ex­
pansion in other monetary aggregates. Federal Re­
serve credit outstanding, which had risen at a 10 per
cent rate during 1967 and 1968, slowed to about 5.5
per cent rate in the first five months of 1969 and to a
4.7 per cent rate after May. The monetary base
after rising 6.5 per cent in both 1967 and 1968, in­
creased at a 5.3 per cent rate in the first five months
of this year, and has slowed to a 1.5 per cent rate
since then. The deceleration in total member bank
reserves growth was even sharper.

to aid in com paring m ost recent developm ents with p ast "trend s."
Latest d ata plotted: N o v e m b e r prelim inary

Controls are costly to administer, impinge on freedom,
create shortages, and misallocate resources.7 Controls
interfere with the continuous price adjustments which'
are essential for equating supply and demand in the
myriad sectors of the economy and attracting re­
sources to the uses where they are most needed. In­
flation may be “bad,” but an inflation temporarily
repressed by a broad set of arbitrary wage and price
controls is worse. Unless controls are accompanied
by policies which will reduce the excessive demand
for goods and services, they provide no solution to
inflation. If total spending is restrained, the controls
are unnecessary.

Continued growth in spending at an excessive rate
during most of 1969 was consistent with the monetary
actions of the past two years. Growth of the money
stock was very rapid until early 1969, and the expan­
sionary effects of such growth have usually been

M onetary Base and Federal Reserve Credit

Monetary Actions — Growth in the nation’s money
stock has slowed markedly in the past year. This ac­
tion has already limited total spending, and studies
of past lags of the effect of monetary restraint indicate
that this action will be effective in further reducing
demand for goods and services. Reducing the stock
of money relative to the demand for it causes con­
sumers and business to spend less than their incomes
in an attempt to build up actual cash balances to
desired levels.
During 1967 and 1968, the money stock rose at a
very rapid 7 per cent annual rate. In the first half
of 1969, growth in money slowed to a 4 per cent rate,
and since June money has risen only slightly. By
comparison, money rose at a 2 per cent trend rate

[H J s e s of the m onetary b a se a re m em b e r b a n k rese rve s a n d currency held b y the p u b lic
a n d n o n m e m b e r ban ks. A djustm ents a re m a d e for rese rve requ ire m e n t c h a n g e s a n d
shifts in d e p o sits a m o n g c la s se s of b an ks. D a t a a re com puted by this b an k.
[2 Total F e d e ra l R e se rve credit o u tsta n d in g inclu d e s h o ld in g s o f securities, loans, float,
a n d "o t h e r " a ssets. Adjustm ents a re m o d e for rese rve requirem ent c h a n g e s a n d
shifts in d e p o sits a m o n g c la s se s o f b an ks. D a t a a re com puted b y this bank.
Percentages a re a n n u a l rates of c h a n g e betw een p eriod s indicated. They a re p resented

7See “Controlling Inflation,” a speech by Darryl R. Francis,
President, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, printed in the
September 1969 issue of this Review, pp. 8-12.



to a id in c om paring m ost recent d e ve lo p m e n ts with p a s t "tre n d s ."
Latest d a t a plotted: N o v e m b e r p re lim in a ry

Page 9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

Reserves of M ember Banks *

SELECTED M O N ET A R Y AG G REG ATES
(Annual Rates of Change)

R a tio S c a le
Bill o n s o f D o lla r s

Dec. 6 7 to
Dec. 68

Dec. 6 8 to
June 69

Ju n e 6 9 to
N o v . 6 9 p.

Stock

7 .2

4.4

0 .8

D e m a n d D e p o sits

7.1

3 .7

— 0 .5

C urren cy

7 .4

6 .6

5 .4

9 .4

0.1

-4 .0

10.2

5 .9

4 .2

M o n e t a r y Base

6.5

4 .0

2.3

25

Total

7.8

0 .7

— 5 .9

24

M oney

M o n e y Plus Tim e D ep osits

Reserves

R a tio S c a le
B illio n s o f D o ll a r s

29

29

28

28
I V

2 7.4

27

27
y

26
Federal Reserve C redit

M o n t h ly A v e r a g e s of D a ily F igures

26

/J

25

(

24

p — P r e lim in a r y

strongest after a lag of about two quarters. Hence,
spending in the first half of 1969 was being affected
primarily by earlier expansionary monetary develop­
ments. Then in the first half of 1969, money expan­
sion, although dampened, continued at a rate in ex­
cess of the trend since 1957. As a result, one might
have expected only a gradual moderation in the
growth rate of spending during the summer and early
fall. Since mid-year monetary restraint has intensified,
and the initial major effects of this action would nor­
mally be expected to occur in late 1969 or early 1970.

Economic Developments in 1969
Despite the many actions taken in the battle against
inflation, price increases accelerated in 1969. The
greater inflation has been caused by both a continued
strong demand-pull effect from excessive spending
and a cost-push effect from previous excessive de­
mands for goods and services. As the year progressed,
however, there were increasing signs that the de­
mand excesses were waning.
First Half — In the first half of 1969, growth in total
spending continued to be excessive and moderated
only slightly from a year earlier. Total spending on
goods and services rose at a 7.4 per cent annual rate,
down from the 9 per cent rate in the previous six
quarters, but only a slightly less than the average 8
per cent rate that had prevailed since late 1964. Final
sales (that is, total sales less changes in business in­
ventories) rose at an 8.3 per cent rate in the first half
of 1969, virtually the same as in the previous year and
a half, and in the entire period since late 1964.
Growth in production, however, slowed in early
1969. Real output of goods and services rose at a 2.3
Page 10



23

23

22

22

21

20

£

s

fc

*

*

I

a*

■*?

5

z

. i . t -------

1966

C O

— t ------------------------------ .

1967

i i 1 i i 1 i i 1 i i tl 1 1 i f

1968

21

0

1 1 1 !■ itl

20

1969

‘ D a t a before M a y 1969 h av e been a d justed fo r estim ated effect o f reserve requirem ent
c h a n g e s . C u rre n t d a ta exclud e in cre a se in re q u ire d re se rv e s d u e to c h a n g e s in
R e g u la t io n s M a n d D, effective O c to b e r 16,1969.
P e rc e n ta g e s a re a n n u a l rates of c h a n g e betw een p e rio d s in d ica te d . T he y a re
p re se n te d to a id in c o m p a rin g m ost re c e n t d e v e lo p m e n t s w ith p a st "tre n d s ."
L atest d a t a plotted: N o v e m b e r prelim inary

per cent annual rate during the first six months of
1969, about half the rate of the period from late 1964
to late 1968. Despite cutbacks in total output, both
industrial production and employment continued to
rise at rapid rates, and the level of unemployment
remained unusually low. The upward trend in total
production was probably restrained as the economy
approached capacity and could not physically main­
tain the earlier growth pace. Growth of productivity
slowed reflecting inefficiencies resulting from the
inflation.
With spending continuing to rise rapidly and with
production expanding at slower rate, the pace of in­
flation accelerated in early 1969. Overall prices went
up at a 5 per cent annual rate in the first half of the
year after rising 4 per cent in 1968 and 3.5 per cent
in 1967. Consumer prices rose at a 6.4 per cent rate
in the first half of 1969 compared with 4.7 per cent
in 1968 and 3.1 per cent in 1967. Wholesale prices
increased at a 6.3 per cent rate in the first half of
1969 following a 2.8 per cent rise in 1968 and a 0.8
per cent increase in 1967.
Second Half — Evidence of some real progress in
combatting the economic ebullience was provided by
a number of sensitive data series during the third
quarter of 1969. Although the overall measure of

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUI S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

Prices
Ratio S c a le

Ratio Sc a le

1957-59=100
135

1957-59=100
135

Aug 66

1961

1962

1963

1964

1965

1966

Aug.67

♦

1967

1968

1969

Source: U.S. Department of Labor
Percentages are a n nu a l rates of chan ge between periods indicated. They are presented to aid in
comparing most recent developm ents with past "trends."
Latest data plotted: Consum er - O ctober;
W h o le sa le - Novem ber

total spending expanded slightly faster than in the
first half, analysis of spending by major categories
indicated much less strength. Spending was supported
by an unusually large catch-up Government pay raise
in July. Nevertheless, final sales rose at only a 6.3 per
cent annual rate, down from the 8.3 per cent rate in
the first half. Total sales were bolstered by a sub­
stantial, probably largely unintended, buildup in in­
ventories, as final sales apparently did not measure up
to earlier expectations. An unplanned rise in business
inventories while sales fall below expectations is fre­
quently a sign of developing weakness in total
demand.
Real output of goods and services grew at a 2.2
per cent annual rate from the second to third quarter
of 1969, about the same as in the first half. Other
measures of performance, however, indicated weak­
ness. Real final sales were about unchanged from the
second to the third quarter after rising at a 3.3 per
cent annual rate in the first quarter. Industrial pro­
duction declined at a 5 per cent rate from July to
November after rising at a 6 per cent annual rate from
last December to July. Payroll employment rose at a
1.1 per cent annual rate from June to November, fol­
lowing a 4.2 per cent increase in the first half. Total
civilian employment rose at a 1.6 per cent annual
rate from August to November, after increasing at a
2.8 per cent rate in the first eight months of the year.
Private nonfarm housing starts were at a 1.4 million
rate from July to October, down from a 1.6 million
rate in the first half.



Prices have risen since June at about the same pace
as during the first half. The overall measure increased
at a 5.4 per cent annual rate from the second to third
quarter, up from a 5.1 per cent rate earlier in the
year. Consumer prices rose at a 5.1 per cent annual
rate from July to October, compared with a 5.9 per
cent rate in the first seven months of the year. W hole­
sale prices increased at a slower pace from June to
November, but the improvement provided little en­
couragement to those seeking to control inflation since
it reflected a decline in farm prices resulting primarily
from a jump in supplies.
Personal income grew at a 4.5 per cent annual rate
from August to October after growing at an 8.8 per
cent rate in the first eight months of the year. Rusiness spending may have been moderated by rising
inventories, declining corporate profits, and less op­
timistic expectations. Consumers found personal in­
come rising at a slower rate after mid-summer, a
development which, according to surveys, was ac­
companied by deterioration of consumer confidence.
State and local governments have reduced the growth
rate of their outlays in response to higher interest
rates, in some cases to levels above ceilings permitted,
and to public discontent with ever rising tax burdens.

Summary and Outlook
The past year has been the worst of five successive
years of inflation. Overall prices have risen about 5

Industrial Production

Ratio S c a le

R atio Scale

1957-59=100
200

1961

1957-59=100

Se ason a lly Adjusted

1962

1963

1964

1965

1966

200

1967

1968

1969

Percentages ore an nu al rates of chan ge between periods indicated. They are presented to aid in
comparing most recent developm ents with post trends."
Latest data plotted:October preliminary

Page 11

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

per cent while consumer prices have increased 5.6
per cent. The inflation has caused a substantial re­
distribution of real wealth and income and has created
inefficiencies.
The inflation has resulted from an unduly large
demand for goods and services which was nurtured
by expansive monetary developments in 1967 and
1968. In addition, prices have been forced up in­
creasingly by cost-push forces resulting from the de­
layed effects of previous excesses. The rapid increases
in spending and inflation have continued despite
higher tax rates, cuts in Government spending pro­
grams, higher interest rates, a reduction in the growth
of bank credit and exhortations by public officials for
business and labor to use restraint in raising prices
and wages.
The end of inflation is not clearly in sight. The re­
cent record of economic advice and business forecast­
ing has not been distinguished for its accuracy. A
slowdown in activity and inflation widely predicted
for the last half of 1968 and then for the first half of
1969 as a result of the restrictive policies adopted
failed to materialize. This unimpressive record should
engender caution, if not humility, for those who ven­
ture judgments as to current economic prospects.
Monetary actions continued very expansive through
1968, and projections based on these developments
have not been misleading, except when based on
short-run movements in preliminary data which were
later revised. Monetary expansion was moderate in
the first half of 1969, and since midyear the money
stock has been virtually unchanged. Experience indi­
cates that spending usually slows in about two quar­
ters after a marked reduction in the growth rate of
money.
After mid-1969, evidence began accumulating that
the economic environment was changing, that the ex­
pansionary forces were weakening, and that a slack­
ening in the quarter-to-quarter growth rate of spend­
ing was in prospect. It now (early December) ap­
pears that further reductions in the growth of total
spending and production appear to be in prospect
for early 1970 as a result of the monetary restraint in
the summer and fall of 1969.
Even if growth of total spending continues to slow
and is moderate in 1970, inflationary forces will prob­
ably remain serious throughout the year and perhaps
for some time afterward. Expectations of rising prices
are strong. Price increases usually continue for an ex­
12
Digitized for Page
FRASER


DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

tended period after growth in overall demand for
goods and services moderates, reflecting cost-push
forces generated by the earlier excessive spending.
It took about seven years of restrained growth of
spending in the 1950’s to eliminate the inflationary
pressures created during the Korean conflict. Some
prices, such as negotiated wages and those set in
other contracts, which have been relatively inflexible
during recent periods of rapid price increase, will
probably be adjusted upward later at time of rene­
gotiation. Other prices have been held back by a
money illusion, lack of knowledge of costs, public
opinion, and inertia. As these wages and prices ad­
vance toward equilibrium levels, the increase in pro­
duction costs will place upward pressure on other
prices.
Nevertheless, the campaign against inflation seems
to be yielding results in the last half of 1969, as infla­
tionary pressures probably passed their peak in in­
tensity. The results of great economic imbalances
are likely to be felt more keenly in 1970 than they
were in the late 1960’s when they were generated.
Assessment of economic prospects suggests that the
country faces a very difficult period. Spending is
likely to be sluggish, with corollaries of reduced pro­
duction, rising unemployment, and a squeeze on busi­
ness profits. At the same time significant deceleration
of price increases may be dishearteningly slow. Suc­
cess will require great perseveranoe which is more
likely to be achieved if extreme erratic stabilization
actions can be avoided.
The crucial consideration for stabilization policy­
makers in the coming year will be the determination
of how rapidly the excessive growth of total spending
can and should be reduced. Because of past errors,
the choice now is to determine the lesser of evils.
If monetary and fiscal actions are followed which will
slow the rise in total demand for goods and services
abruptly, inflationary pressures may be extinguished
sooner than otherwise. However, the costs in terms
of lower production, employment and incomes would
be great, and the temptation would be strong to restimulate the economy before the task is completed
as was the case in 1967. On the other hand, if de­
mand grows so rapidly as to permit growth in produc­
tion, employment and income to continue at near their
long-run maximum trends, moderation of inflationary
pressures may not be achieved and we are likely to
have a continuation of the inefficiencies and inequi­
ties caused by a continuous erosion of the value of
the dollar. A middle course is advisable.

Selective Credit —No Substitute for
Monetary Restraint
A speech given by DARRYL R. FRANCIS, President, Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis, at the 23rd Annual Conference of Bank Correspondents,
First National Bank of St. Louis, November 13, 1969

I HE USE of selective credit controls for economic
stabilization is not of recent origin. The eligible paper
provisions of the Federal Reserve Act passed in 1913
are a form of selective credit control. They provide
for easier Federal Reserve Bank credit terms to bor­
rowing member banks who offer short-term commer­
cial paper as collateral. This provision implies that, if
bank credit is limited to short-term commercial loans,
monetary conditions will approach an optimum.
Selective credit controls were given a major boost
in 1934 with the passage of the Securities Exchange
Act, which delegated authority to the Board of Gov­
ernors to control margin requirements (Regulations
G, T and U ) on securities traded on the major ex­
changes.1 This control was provided for the purpose
of preventing the “excessive” use of credit for pur­
chasing or carrying securities. It was generally be­
lieved that a large volume of bank credit led to a
major increase in stock prices and the ultimate col­
lapse of the stock market in the late 1920’s and early
1930’s.2 It was assumed that the expansion and con­
traction of stock market credit was; a major factor
contributing to the Great Depression of the 1930’s.
'Securities Exchange Act, 1934, Federal Reserve Act as
amended through Oct. 1, 1961, p. 222.
2See John T. Abele, “Black Tuesday, ’29: Forgotten Lesson?”
New York Times, Oct. 26, 1969 for a discussion of this
view.



Another boost to selective credit controls was pro­
vided by the passage in 1933 and 1935 of interest
rate restrictions on demand and time deposits. Under
authority granted by this legislation both member
and nonmember banks were prohibited from paying
interest on demand deposits. This legislation also au­
thorized the Federal Reserve Board and the F.D.I.C.
to limit the rates that banks could pay on time and
savings deposits. At that time it was contended that
these restrictions would tend to reduce the rates
charged to bank customers, slow the movement of
funds from smaller to larger communities where it
was believed that they were used for “speculative”
purposes, and prevent the excessive bidding up of
rates, thereby reducing bank failures. More recently,
time and savings deposit rate controls have been in­
tended to reduce competition between banks and
savings and loan associations, and thereby to speed
the flow of funds into the housing market. This move
away from free competition implies that it is better
for the nation to have larger credit flowsi to the
housing industry than to bank creditors, who may
use the funds for plant and equipment expenditures
and other purposes judged to be less worthy.
In 1941 the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System was authorized by an Executive
Order of the President to restrict the use of credit for
Page 13

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUI S

consumer purchases (Regulation W ). This was done
by requiring a minimum down payment and a maxi­
mum time to maturity for such credits. The immedi­
ate reason for the restriction was to reduce the infla­
tionary danger during the war by restricting the de­
mand for consumer goods.3 Actually, however, the
legislation was associated with the thought that ex­
cessive consumer credit in the 1920’s had contributed
to the 1929-33 depression.
Restrictions on real estate credit were imposed in
1950 as part of a program to check inflation after
the start of Korean fighting (Regulation X ). These
restrictions followed the general pattern of consumer
credit controls by requiring minimum down-payments
and maximum maturities on new one- and two-family
houses. Credit restrictions were later extended to
other real estate.
As an indication of the wide interest in the use of
selective credit for controlling inflation, Time maga­
zine, in discussing the reluctance of the Administra­
tion to impose price controls, reported that “ credit
controls, which were last imposed on the U. S. during
the Korean War, might work more selectively to re­
strain lending, and in turn, demand for some kinds
of goods” .4 In recent testimony before a Senate sub­
committee, the President of the National Association
of Home Builders stated that “we are now convinced
that some type of credit controls must be undertaken”.5

Selective Credit Controls — Pros and Cons
The argument for selective credit controls rests
primarily on the assumptions that restrictive mone­
tary actions cause high interest rates, and that high
interest rates have an unduly harsh impact on some
sectors of the economy such as residential construc­
tion. Proponents of selective credit controls believe
that the “undesirable” impact of aggregate monetary
controls can be eliminated by controlling the volume
of credit used for specific purposes.
The view that credit controls in a specific sector
will have an impact on total credit outstanding and
total demand for goods and services may be looked
upon as a variant of the Income-Expenditure ap­
proach to economic activity. For example, if one
3Charles R. Whittlesey, Arthur M. Freedman and Edward
S. Herman, Money and, Banking: Analysis and Policy (New
York: Macmillan Co., 1963), p. 256.
*Time, Oct. 10, 1969, p. 87.
5U.S., Congress, Senate, Subcommittee on Financial Institu­
tions of the Committee on Banking and Currency, Hearings
on S-2499 and S-2577, 91st Congress, 1st session, September
9, 1969, p. 17.
Digitized forPage
FRASER
14


DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

viewed total economic activity as resulting from au­
tonomous expenditures in each of the separate sectors
of the economy, a variation of expenditures in any
one sector would have an impact on total expendi­
tures and total income. This is consistent with the
fiscal view of economic stabilization, which asserts
that an increase in Government spending on goods
and services results in an increase in total expendi­
tures and total income. However, I do not mean to
imply that all proponents of fiscal stabilization would
recommend the use of selective credit controls for
stabilization purposes.
In contrast to the Income-Expenditure approach
to economic activity, I hold to the view that the stock
of money is a major influence on total demand and
the course of spending. Preferences for specific goods
and services determine amounts that consumers will
spend in each sector. If specific credit controls or
other nonmarket controls are applied in any one sec­
tor, I believe that any reductions achieved will be
offset by higher expenditures for other goods and
services.
Despite the merits attributed to selective credit
controls, I believe that they are socially undesirable
for the following reasons: they are useless in con­
trolling inflation; most of the hardships attributed to
general monetary restraint are actually caused by
selective controls or self-imposed rigidities; they are
difficult to enforce; they are biased in favor of the
wealthier groups; to the extent that they reduce de­
mand for particular goods and services, they also
reduce national welfare; and they are a restriction on
individual freedom.

Selective Credit Controls —
for Quantitative Controls

No Substitute

The argument that selective credit controls will
restrain inflation is not consistent with the functioning
of our monetary mechanism and the factors which
determine total demand. With our fractional reserve
system of banking, the volume of bank credit is
strongly influenced by total reserves and the reserve
ratio requirements. Within limits, total credit is de­
termined by the Federal Reserve System simultane­
ously with the determination of bank reserves and
the stock of money. With fixed reserve ratios, other
monetary multipliers, and a given level of bank re­
serves, credit restrictions on some purchases are fully
offset by credit expansion for other purchases. Thus
the total stock of money or credit remains unchanged
after application of the restrictions. Money created

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

by one type of credit expansion is equal in quality to
money created by another type of credit, and total
demand is unchanged.
Even if one subscribes to the idea that monetary
management exercises its influence primarily through
the credit market rather than through the money
stock, selective credit controls are not a solution to
the problem of excess demand. Credit restrictions on
some purchases will cause rising demand for uncon­
trolled goods and services. Prices for uncontrolled
goods will rise faster and resources will, in turn, flow
from the production of controlled to uncontrolled
goods. Output will be enhanced in the uncontrolled
sectors and reduced in the controlled sectors, but
prices for all goods will continue up, assuming ex­
cessive credit and monetary expansion has been
permitted.
The argument that quantitative controls are per­
verse and create undue hardships in some sectors
implies that the judgment of the controller is superior
to market decisions. To the extent that the controls
work, the controller is essentially transferring to others
his own values as to what the nation should produce
and sell. I contend that the market place can de­
termine with least welfare loss which goods and serv­
ices should be produced at slower or accelerated rates
as a result of stabilization actions. Consumer pur­
chases of goods and services under aggregate mone­
tary controls are determined by utility at the margin,
thus providing greater welfare than purchases arbi­
trarily determined for specific products through
selective credit restrictions. Furthermore, appropri­
ate monetary policies will reduce the wide swings
in demand of recent years. A reduced amplitude of
demand fluctuations would eliminate the unevenness
of the effect of controls on total money and credit.
Credit used for purchasing and carrying common
stocks has been given major attention because of the
widespread belief that stock market credit and stock
prices tend to trigger major swings in economic activ­
ity. Proponents of this view contend that speculators,
when borrowing to make stock purchases, bid up stock
prices to excessive levels and the following sharp
declines tend to produce recessions.
I believe that both the impact of credit on stock
prices and the impact of stock prices on economic
activity have been greatly overestimated. Much of the
fluctuation in the stock prices can be traced to the
unevenness of aggregate monetary controls. Stock
prices may be influenced temporarily by the volume
of credit extended for security purchases. Reverse



DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

causation, however, is more likely the case. In other
words, movements in stock market credit are influ­
enced by changes in stock prices. Statistical analysis
tends to demonstrate this reverse causation.6
Causation likewise runs from economic activity to
stock prices. Rather than being an important factor
contributing to the Great Depression as some contend,
the sharp decline in the stock market in the late
Twenties and early Thirties was mainly the result of
a decline in earnings and in earnings expectations.
This outlook for earnings can be traced to a decline in
demand for goods and services, which, in turn, can
be traced to a sharp reduction in the stock of money.
Carrying the securities market analysis a step fur­
ther, we can assume that business capital will expand
according to profit incentives and the cost of capital
to entrepreneurs. If margin restrictions restrain the
opportunity for raising capital through security sales,
business will likely resort to borrowing directly from
financial institutions to meet capital demands. I can
see little difference between making loans to corpora­
tions and making them on securities which represent
ownership of corporations. Furthermore, like other
credit restrictions, if margin requirements alter credit
or monetary flows, they also reduce national welfare
as indicated by individual expenditure preferences.

The Apparent Need for Selective Credit
Controls — A Result of Other
Restrictions
Most of the hardships attributed to general mone­
tary restrictions by advocates of selective credit con­
trols would disappear if other useless impediments to
credit flows were eliminated. Quite often the alleged
victims of financial market imperfections are actually
the victims of other controls. First, let us look at the
argument that restrictive monetary actions discrimin­
ate against residential construction. Recent studies
indicate that relatively slow rates of monetary growth
'’'Statistical analysis of the Standard and Poors 425 Industrials
and of the 500 Stocks gives better results for the hypothesis
that changes in stock values cause changes in credit for
stock purchases than the reverse-causation hypothesis. The
hypotheses were tested by regressing first differences of
monthly data (stock price indices and credit extended to
margin customers by banks plus customers’ net debit
balances at member firms of the New York Stock Exchange)
on current and three lagged periods. The time period
used was February 1953 to July 1969. The response of
credit to changes in stock values was positive and significant
for the current plus the first and second lagged month for
each index. In contrast, the hypothesis that stock market
credit causes stock prices to rise gave positive and significant
results only in the current period. The coefficients were nega­
tive in the first and second lagged month for both indices.
Page 15

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LO U I S

do not cause excessive cutbacks in spending on homes.
Conversely, all marked and sustained declines in hous­
ing starts began in periods of rapid monetary expan­
sion after excessive demands for goods and services
had driven up prices and interest rates. The sharp
rises in costs and interest rates were the major factors
in reducing housing demand, and the reduced flows
of funds into housing during these periods of high
interest rates can be traced in part to such market
impediments as usury laws, interest rate ceilings, and
other regulations on financial intermediaries. When
market rates reached these imposed ceilings, funds
were diverted to other uses where rates could move
to market-determined levels.
An additional side effect of this diversion of credit
from its normal flows through intermediaries is its
bias against small savers and borrowers. Small savers
are relatively unable to place their savings in funds
and securities and are relatively limited to controlled
rates. These rates are lower than market-determined
rates and small savers are the losers. Similarly, small
borrowers are limited to the use of financial agencies
for credit, and when this credit dries up because of
rate regulations, small borrowers are, for all practical
purposes, banned from the credit market. In contrast,
large borrowers can participate in the capital mar­
kets through either new common stock offerings or
other securities.
Self-imposed rate restrictions by state and local
governments and rate restrictions on public utilities
likewise reduce their expenditures during periods of
high market rates. Rather than serving to reduce in­
terest costs, the restrictions simply serve to postpone
the expenditures until supply and demand conditions
for credit cause market rates to return to levels that
these spending units are willing to pay.

Enforcement of Selective Credit
Controls is Difficult
Selective credit controls are extremely difficult to
enforce uniformly among all groups. Enforcement of­
ficials can apply restrictions on a basis of the collat­
eral offered as security, on the borrower’s declaration
of intended use of proceeds, and on the indicated
use of proceeds. None provides a sure test of the use
of loan proceeds. If proceeds from loans are com­
mingled with other income such as salaries, wages,
commodity sales, or other funds, one cannot deter­
mine which funds were used for the various expendi­
tures. For example, if an individual wants to use his
salary, wages, or other sources of income to purchase

Page 16


DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

securities, he may borrow funds to make home pay­
ments or provide for other living expenses. The bor­
rowed funds are similar to the other funds and the
destination of the respective funds is difficult to trace.
The collateral offered is likewise a poor indicator
of how loan funds are used. Proceeds from loans on
common stocks or real estate may be used for medical
payments, to purchase automobiles, or for numerous
other purposes having no connection with stocks or
real estate.
Trade-ins are also a means of by-passing down­
payment requirements of selective credit controls.
With anything that can be considered a trade-in item,
the prospective buyer and seller can get together and
make a mutually satisfactory deal by setting up a
fictitious down-payment which meets both legal and
personal requirements.

Selective Credit Controls Biased
in Favor of the Wealthy
Selective credit controls are biased in favor of
wealthy groups and against those with limited assets.
Real and financial assets can always be used as col­
lateral for loans. From such proceeds down-payments
on purchases of controlled items can be made unless
each dollar can be traced to its ultimate use. Further­
more, those with assets for collateral can avoid instal­
ment credit restrictions altogether by obtaining com­
mercial credit and purchasing consumer items with
the proceeds. In addition, those with wealth are also
likely to have sufficient cash flows to mingle with
borrowed funds to make fund-tracing almost impos­
sible. Control officials cannot determine whether the
borrowed money was used for down-payments on
controlled items or whether other cash flows were
used for such purchases.
On the other hand, those without assets are forced
to use purchased items as collateral. Thus, to the ex­
tent that selective credit controls serve to retard de­
mand in a particular sector of the economy, they are
a boon to persons with assets, providing them with
products at lower prices, while those without assets
for collateral are frozen out of such markets until the
necessary down-payments can be accumulated.

Selective Credit Controls Distort
Resource Use and Reduce Welfare
Fortunately, most selective credit controls are not
readily enforceable. To the extent that they reduce
demand and production of goods and services in any

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

sector, they tend to reduce welfare. The welfare of
an individual is maximized, other things being equal,
when he can spend both proceeds from loans and
funds from other sources without restrictions or im­
pediments. Each expenditure then provides him with
maximum satisfaction at the margin. On the other
hand, the capricious use of restrictions to alter in­
dividual spending, either in the form of higher down­
payments or shorter terms, requires consumers to make
less desirable choices. Fewer goods and services are
purchased in terms of their usefulness for the same
level of expenditures. An economy operating under
selective credit restrictions fails to produce an opti­
mum amount of some goods and overproduces other
goods, with a consequent loss in total welfare.

Selective Credit Controls Reduce Freedom
Equally as important as the economic considera­
tions is the useless infringement of selective credit
controls on freedom. W e can easily moralize as did
the Medieval rulers that the poor should stay out of
debt or that someone should set limits on their loan
terms in order to assure that their credit is used for
“appropriate” purposes. It is my belief, however,
that man is happier when subject to the market forces
rather than to arbitrary decisions of one or a few
individuals. Freedom did not come easily to mankind,
but we tend to take it for granted. Yet, in most of
the periods since man’s early history, he has been
forced to bow in both thought and action to harsh
taskmasters. In my view, we should not take losses
of freedom lightly, despite the fact that controls are
imposed upon us only a fraction at a time.

Summary
The current inflation has brought to the forefront
proposals for using selective credit controls to stabilize
prices and prevent the allegedly perverse effects of
aggregate monetary restraint. Despite the possibility
that selective controls may reduce the volume of
credit used for specific types of purchases, they do
not achieve the announced stabilization goals of the
controllers. They do not restrain total demand for
goods and services. Dollars created by one type of
bank credit have the same purchasing power and the
same impact on demand as dollars created by an­
other type of credit. It is the total amount of credit
and money created that determines average prices
for all goods and services. Actually, to the extent that
selective controls cause misallocation of resources, they
have an inflationary impact.



DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

Selective credit controls are almost impossible to
enforce with equal results among all groups of in­
dividuals and businesses. Their use imposes much
greater credit restraint on the small borrower, who is
without other assets for collateral or large cash flows
which can serve to disguise the actual use made of
borrowed funds.
To the extent that selective credit controls are ef­
fective in changing credit flows, they reduce total
output of goods and services and national welfare.
Furthermore, they are an infringement on freedom
because they impose restraints on how one can utilize
his credit resources.
Last but not least is the fact that selective credit
controls tend to provide their own breeding grounds.
One control must ultimately lead to another as market
forces tend to bypass each new regulation. The pro­
liferation of ceilings on time and savings deposits is
a good example. First, the ceilings were established
uniformly on all accounts. Then there was a “need”
to segregate deposits by size because of major losses
of larger deposits. Smaller depositors could be paid less
under monopolistic pricing because of lack of alterna­
tive investment opportunities. Rates to small savers
were seldom changed. They remain at levels insuf­
ficient to cover the rate of inflation. Permissible rates
on the larger accounts were raised at intervals as
market rates continued up. Observing an opportunity
to capture funds, bank holding companies and bank
affiliates began to issue savings-type instruments which
were not covered by the regulations. Now controls
have been proposed in this leakage area. These at­
tempts to cover all bypasses are like the man who
built a dam to curtail the normal flow of a stream
and discovered a leak. He used his finger to plug the
hole. As water backed up, however, other leaks oc­
curred requiring more fingers. The process of leak
springing and finger plugging continued until the
builder ran out of fingers.
Inflations can be controlled, but not through the use
of specific controls on arbitrarily selected goods or
services. The solution to inflation lies in the adoption
and maintenance of appropriate monetary policies,
which attack the cause of inflation. It requires an
appropriate rate of growth in the stock of money. W e
moved toward a reduced rate of monetary growth
near the end of last year and a still slower rate last
June. I am confident that these actions will soon re­
duce the excess demand which was created by overly
rapid monetary expansion in 1967 and 1968.
Page 17

Interest Rates and Price Level Changes, 1952-69*
by W ILLIAM P. YOHE and DENIS S. KARNOSKY

Our economy has been experiencing an accelerating inflation during the past five years.
At the same time, market interest rates have risen to extremely high levels. The causes of infla­
tion are relatively well-known, but the reasons for high interest rates accompanying inflation are
not. The following article investigates primarily this latter situation.
Inflation develops when, at a high level o f resource utilization, total spending on final
goods and services ( GNP) rises at a rate faster than the rate at which productive potential
grows. Such has been the case in this country since early 1965. Total spending has risen at
an 8 per cent annual rate and real product at a 4.4 per cent rate. As a consequence, the over­
all price level has risen at a 3.6 per cent annual rate.
The major cause of the current inflation has been the stimulus to total spending provided
by an excessive rate of expansion in the money stock. From early 1965 to the end of 1968,
the money stock, on balance, grew at a 5.2 per cent annual rate, compared with a 2 per cent
trend rate in the preceding decade.
Rapid growth in the money stock accompanied by high and rising market interest rates
has appeared a paradox to many observers. According to modern Keynesian economic theory,
an acceleration in the rate of monetary expansion will provide lower market interest rates.
However, this apparent paradox can be explained by the economic theory developed by
Irving Fisher around the turn of the century.
According to Fisher, nominal ( observed) interest rates consist of two components — the
“real” rate of interest, to which real saving and investment respond, and a premium based
on expected changes in the price level. The following study uses this Fisherian analysis to
quantify the effect of inflation on movements in interest rates from 1952 to 1969. The prin­
cipal finding is that past price movements exert a major effect on nominal interest rates, with
the effect largely manifested within two years. Consequently, most of the rise in market inter­
est rates since 1965 can be attributed to the current inflation.
This finding has an important implication for market interest rates as an indicator of
the thrust of monetary actions on economic activity. High market interest rates do not neces­
sarily indicate monetary restraint. Instead, they most likely indicate excessive monetary ease,
( as measured by rapid expansion of the money supply) which results in rapidly expanding
total spending and eventually inflation.

William P. Yohe is currently a visiting scholar with this bank and is also Professor of
Economics and Director of Graduate Studies in Economics at Duke University. H e is the
author of numerous publications, primarily in monetary economics. Denis S. Karnosky is an
economist with the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.


Page 18


F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

X n SUMMARIZING his many years of work on the
subject, Irving Fisher cited four empirical relation­
ships between interest rates and price levels:1

in order to stimulate sufficient investment spending
for the price level to be high, while empirically this
has not been observed.

(1 ) Interest rates tend to be “high” when prices are
rising and “low ” when prices are falling.

The present study is an examination of the second
and third of Fisher’s propositions, making use of
modern data sources and statistical techniques. There
is, at present, a major controversy over (1 ) the ad­
vantages and disadvantages of using monetary ag­
gregates as opposed to using interest rates as indicators
of the effect of monetary policy actions on the econ­
omy, and (2 ) the adjustments, if any, which must be
made to an indicator to “neutralize” it with respect
to changes that are not directly the result of policy
actions.3 Previous studies of the effect of price level
changes on interest rates, some of which will be re­
viewed below, have found the lags to be so long that
recent price behavior could be ignored in evaluating
changes in observed interest rates. In contrast, results
will be presented here based on the 1952-69 period
which indicate that the lags are very short, with
most of the effect of price level changes on both longand short-term interest rates occurring within two
years. Interest rates adjusted to remove the ap­
parent influence of price changes have sometimes
moved contrary to movements in observed rates.
Furthermore, price changes have had a greater effect
on interest rates in the 1960’s than in the 1950’s, and
indeed, price changes in the latter period account for
nearly all of the movement in interest rates.

(2 ) Interest rate movements lag behind price level
changes, which obscures the relationship between
them.
(3 ) There is a marked correlation between interest
rates and a weighted average of past price level
changes, reflecting effects that are distributed
over time.
(4 ) “ High” interest rates accompany “high” prices,
and “low ” interest rates accompany “low ” prices.

The first of these relationships derives from the
fact that, if lenders and borrowers could perfectly
foresee future price level movements, the former
would hedge against changes in the real value of their
loan principal by adding the percentage change in
prices over the life of the loan to the interest charge;
the latter, expecting money income to change in pro­
portion to prices, would readily accept the higher
rate.
Fisher attributed the second and third relationships
to imperfect foresight about future prices and the
resulting inclination to extrapolate past price changes
into the future in order to adjust interest rates for
expected changes in prices. He devised the concept
of the “distributed lag” to explain the way informa­
tion about the past affects expectations of the future.
Fisher thought the fourth relationship, frequently
called the “Gibson paradox,” was an accidental con­
sequence of the other three.2 What is paradoxical is
that the theory prevalent in that period presumably
led to the conclusion that interest rates must be low
“ The authors are grateful to Christopher T. Babb and H. A.
Margolis for advice on the statistical problems of this study,
to Shigeyuki Fukasawa and James B. Greene for making
available the results of their unpublished studies, and espe­
cially to Keith Carlson, Michael Keran, Thomas Havrilesky,
and Edward Kane for helpful suggestions on earlier drafts
of this paper.
1Irving Fisher, The Theory of Interest (New York: Macmillan,
1930), p. 438. Fisher first discussed these relationships in
Appreciation and Interest (New York: Macmillan, 1896),
pp. 75 and 76.
2The term “ Gibson paradox” was coined by J. M. Keynes
in A Treatise on Money, Vol. II (London: Macmillan,
1930), pp. 198-208. A. H. Gibson had studied the high
correlation between levels of interest rates and prices in
England throughout the 19th and early 20th centuries. The
henomenon was earlier called the “ Ricardo-Tooke conunrum,” after the leading antagonists in the Currency SchoolBanking School controversy in England in the first half of
the nineteenth century. For a concise exposition of the
controversy, see Knut Wicksell, Lectures on Political Econ­
omy, Vol. II (London: Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1935),
pp. 168-190.



Previous Studies of
Price Expectations ( Fisher) Effects
Tests for Fisher effects have generally been based
on two hypothesized relationships:
(1 )

mt

(2)

P* = 2 WiPt—i
t

= PF
t + rrt

i= o

The first equation states that the nominal interest
rate (rn) prevailing at time t for a particular debt
instrument is equal to the annual rate of change in
prices (Pe) expected at time t to occur over the life of
the instrument plus its “real” rate of interest (rr) 4
3See, for example, Leonall Andersen, Michael Keran, and
Emanuel Melichar, “The Influence of Economic Activity on
the Money Stock,” this Review, August 1969, and Patric H.
Hendershott, The Neutralized Money Stock (Homewood,
Illinois: R. D. Irwin, 1968).
4Fisher used “real” rate in the sense of “virtual” or “true”
rate. Technically, he also included a third term, rrtPj, on
the right side of equation (1 ). This is the interest that
would be earned on the price adjustment to the nominal
rate. The term is ordinarily so small that it is customarily
Page 19

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUI S

Equation (2 ) is an application of the theory
o f “ adaptive expectations,” “error-leaming,” or,
alternatively, “extrapolative forecasting.” Faced with
uncertainty about the future, an economic de­
cision-making unit is presumed to base its pre­
dictions about future price m ovem ents on a
weighted average of current and past changes in
prices. Thus, in equation (2 ) the rate of price change
expected at time (P?) for some future period is the
weighted sum of actual past price changes ( P t- i ) ,
where the importance of each past change is re­
flected in the weight xvu and where n indicates how
many periods in the past are relevant in forming
expectations.5 The approach is “adaptive” in the sense
that in each period expectations are adjusted (or
forecasting errors are corrected) for actual price
changes. The approach is “extrapolative” in that past
changes are extended (extrapolated) into the future.
Substituting equation (2 ) into equation (1 ) yields
the form of the equation that is usually estimated:
n
(3 )

2

rnt =

wiPt-i + rrt

i= o

The unmeasurable price expectations are not ex­
plicitly considered, but instead it is assumed they can
be approximated by the observable pattern of past
changes in actual prices (or in some other variable
that may be critical to the formation of expectations
about prices).
Fisher assumed that the weights in equation (3 )
declined arithmetically as one goes backward in time.
His procedure was first to posit a time interval over
which the entire effect of price level changes would
omitted. For the complete derivation of equation (1 ), see
Appreciation and Interest, pp. 8-11, 66 and 67.
Some studies have also been concerned with the effect of
changes in the rate of price change (i.e., price level ac­
celerations) on changes (rather than levels) in interest rates.
To see how this may be done, it is necessary to expand P“:
dPe

pe — __
1

Pt

Substituting this term in equation (1 ), differentiating, and
manipulating the result yields:
/ d 2Pe
d(mt) =

dP° \
-

p rJ

be reflected in a nominal interest rate series, for
example, ten years. Ignoring the current period price
change, he then computed for each year the weighted
average of past price level changes, using a weight
of nine for one year earlier, a weight of eight for
two years back, and so forth. The weighted price
changes divided by the sum of the weights (9 -)- 8 —
|
—
. . . . + 0) yielded the weighted average of past rates
of price change. Fisher then observed which of these
weighted averages best correlated with the nominal
interest rate.6 The “best fit” would be obtained where
the correlation was highest or where further length­
ening of the interval would not add appreciably to
the correlation.7
A useful statistic for comparing the results of many
distributed lag studies is the mean (or average) lag,
that is, the time that elapses until half of the effect
of a change in the independent variable is reflected
in the dependent variable.8 Using annual and quar­
terly data for the United States, Fisher found very
long mean lags for the effect of price changes on
long- and short-term interest rates. For example, the
highest correlation between commercial paper rates
and rates of change in the wholesale price index
from 1915-27 was obtained when the latter was lagged
over 120 quarters (30 years), implying a mean lag
of about 40 quarters (10 years).
6Within the framework of equation (3 ), Fisher calculated
the correlation coefficient corresponding to the following re­
gression equation:
mt =

P

2

i=l

(n—i )

5For a concise survey of the theoretical literature on adaptive
expectations, see Zvi Griliches, “ Distributed Lags: A Survey,”
Econometrica, January 1967, pp. 42-45.

•

—----- -Pt_i -f. rrt +ut
n(n— 1 )/2

where n(n— 1 ) /2 is the sum of n terms ranging from zero
to ( n— 1 ).
7His procedure was directly related to the present-day prac­
tice of choosing an estimated equation with the highest R2
( coefficient of determination or square of the correlation
ratio).
8The mean lag is simply the weighted-average lag, where
the coefficients [wi’s in equations ( 2 ) and (3 )] are used for
the weights. When all of the weights are positive, the for­
mula for the mean lag is as follows (Griliches, p. 31):
n

2

i • wi

2

wi

i=o
n

p T + d (rrt)

The term within the large parentheses represents price ac­
celeration. See, inter alia, Allan H. Meltzer, “The Appro­
priate Indicators of Monetary Policy, Part I,” Savings and
Residential Financing: 1969 Conference Proceedings (Chi­
cago: U.S. Savings and Loan League, 1969) p. 14.

Page 20



DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

i=o

that is, a weighted sum divided by the sum of the weights.
In Fisher’s calculations, the denominator is unity (his weights
necessarily sum to one), so the formula for his mean lags is

2 ( i
i= l\

•

n_i
n(n l )/2 /

which simplifies to (n—1 )/3 . Fisher estimated his mean lags
as n/3.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

In recent years there has been a considerable re­
vival of interest in the study of Fisher effects, osten­
sibly the result of the reappearance of substantial
variability in interest rates and price levels and me­
thodological developments in the estimation of dis­
tributed lags. Two studies have attempted to measure
“real” rates directly and then to relate the spread
between various nominal rates and the estimated
“real” rates to historical time series for price level
changes, with inconclusive results.9
Most of the published studies have regressed nom­
inal rates directly on current and past rates of price
changes (or changes in nominal rates on price ac­
celerations).10 Data intervals have ranged from
quarters (Gibson) to business cycle phases (Fried­
man and Schwartz). The time span has ranged from
as early as 1873 to as late as 1966. Lagged rates of
change in various price level indexes and even nom­
inal income (Gibson) have been tried as indicators
of price expectations. The forms of the distributed
lags estimated have generally been either “uncon­
strained” lags or “geometrically decaying” lags.11
Without exception, the mean lags of interest rates
behind price changes were found to be very long.
For example, Friedman and Schwartz found mean
lags for short-term rates of about ten years and for
9Suraj B. Gupta, “Expected Rate of Change in Prices and
Rates of Interest” (unpublished dissertation, University of
Chicago, 1964), and Phillip Cagan, Determinants and Ef­
fects of Changes in the Stock of Money, 1875-1960 (New
York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1965), pp.
305-309. Gupta’s work is summarized and his empirical
work extended in William E. Gibson, “Effects of Money on
Interest Rates,” Staff Economic Studies, No. 43, Board of
Governors of the Federal Reserve System, March 1968, pp.
45-48 and 88-89. Preliminary work along similar lines was
reported in David Meiselman, “Bond Yields and the Price
Level: The Gibson Paradox Regained,” in Deane Carson
( ed.), Banking and Monetary Studies ( Homewood, Illinois:
R. D. Irwin, 1963), pp. 119-122.

10Meiselman, pp. 112-133; Milton Friedman and Anna Jacob­

son Schwartz, “Trends in Money, Income, and Prices, 18671966” (unpublished manuscript, National Bureau of Ecoconomic Research, November 1966), chapter 2, pp. 110-143;
and Gibson, pp. 44-66 and supplementary tables. In their
multiple regression study, Michael J. Hamburger and Wil­
liam L. Silber ( “An Empirical Study of Interest Rate De­
termination,” Review of Economics and Statistics, August
1969, pp. 369-373) rejected the rate of change in prices
as insignificant.

11Both forms will be discussed later. To estimate uncon­
strained lags, one merely regresses the current value of the
dependent variable on the current and a predetermined
number of lagged values of the independent variable —
there is thus no a priori constraint on the time shape of the
coefficients. Geometrically decaying lags impose a geomet­
rical decay on the coefficients, that is, part of each coeffi­
cient is a constant decay term less than one which, when
raised to higher powers as the lag recedes into the past,
decays (asymptotically approaches zero). See Griliches, pp.
16-49, and Lawrence R. Klein, “The Estimation of Dis­
tributed Lags,” Econometrica, October 1958, pp. 553-565.



DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

long-term rates of 25 to 30 years, which they at­
tributed to the “slow and gradual adjustment of
anticipations of price changes to the actual behavior
of prices.”12

A Search for Fisher Effects
This study is based upon earlier work but departs
from previous studies in ways that appear to have
significant effects on the results, in particular:
(1 ) Monthly, instead o f exclusively quarterly or annual,
data are used for short-term and long-term interest
rates (dependent variables) and for price level
changes and other independent variables. Further,
the interest rate series have been seasonally
adjusted.
(2 ) A variety o f kinds o f distributed lags are estimated,
in order to investigate the effect o f lag form on
the length of the lags.
(3 ) The monthly data are aggregated into quarterly
and annual series to determine the effect of aggre­
gation over time on the lag estimates.
(4 ) The study is purposely confined to the period
following the Treasury-Federal Reserve A ccord of
1951 in order to avoid having to contend with the
constraint on interest rate movements imposed by
the Federal Reserve’s “par pegging” o f Govern­
ment securities prices. Further, the 1952-69 period
is divided into two sub-periods to see whether
there has been any apparent change in the m ech­
anism relating past price changes to the formation
of price expectations and any clues to the reasons
for earlier findings of very long lags.
(5 ) A model will also be tested to see what happens
to the explanatory power o f past price level
changes when variables assumed to affect “real”
rates of interest are added to the regressions.
( 6 ) Experimental “ real” rate series will be generated
and their movements compared with nominal rates
to see whether there have been times when nomi­
nal rate movements might have been misleading
indicators o f changes in “ real” interest costs.

Seasonal Movements in Interest Rates
A number of economists have observed not only
seasonal movements in monthly and quarterly inter­
est rate series, but also the influence on the seasonal
12Friedman and Schwartz, chapter 2, p. 139. Gupta, esti­
mating geometrically distributed lags for the nominal rate
— “real” rate spread behind price changes, found a mean
lag of 16 years for long-term rates. Gibson estimated un­
constrained lags for relatively short lag intervals (ten quar­
ters and four years), so it is not possible to calculate mean
lags for the total effect of price changes on interest rates.
In Meiselman’s study, the geometric decay coefficients came
out very close to one, implying a long mean lag (nearly
twenty years, for example, with a decay coefficient of 0.967,
which he found in regressing bond yields on price changes
over the 1873-1960 period).
Page 21

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUI S

of changes in Federal Reserve operating strategy for
open market purchases and sales.13 Since some of
the data used for independent variables in the regres­
sions were seasonally adjusted, it was advisable to
seasonally adjust the short-term and long-term inter­
est rate series, so that the results could be compared
with those generated using unadjusted series.14 As
expected, stronger seasonals were detected in the
short-term than in the long-term interest rates. The
finding of pronounced seasonals in both for the 1952GO period and the virtual elimination of seasonal move­
ments for the 1961-65 period, probably the conse­
quence of the Federal Reserve strategy to assist
the balance of payments, confirms the conclusions of
earlier studies. The resumption of pronounced sea­
sonals is apparent in the calculations for the 1966 to
mid-1969 period. The explanation may lie in the
insertion of “proviso clauses” in the Federal Open
Market Committee directives over the later period
and the implementation of such directives by the
Trading Desk at the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York.15

Empirical Results — Interest Rates Regressed
on Rates of Price Change
Data for the period 1952-69 were used to test the
hypotheses about the effect of price expectations on
the level of nominal interest rates. Several measures
of both prices and interest rates were used in the
estimation, and various lengths for the total lags were
tested. In addition, several estimation techniques were
employed. The results were very similar across the
many combinations of data, length of the lag dis­
tribution, and estimation procedures, all suggesting
a much shorter time horizon in formation of price
expectations than had previously been found.
The interest rates used in this study are yields
on securities issued by the private sector.16 Short­
13Leonall C. Andersen, “ Seasonal Movements in Financial
Variables — Impact of Federal Reserve and Treasury,”
Business and Government Review, University of Missouri,
July-August 1965, pp. 19-26; “A Closer Look at InterestRate Relationships, The Morgan Guaranty Survey, April
1961, pp. 3-5; Gibson, pp. 30-32 and Tables 3 and 4; and
Hamburger and Silber, pp. 370-371.
14Data have been seasonally adjusted using the X -ll Variant
of the Census Method II Seasonal Adjustment Program,
U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census.
Source: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
Federal Reserve Bulletin.
15Jan Warren Duggar, “The Proviso Clause and Bank Credit
Proxy” (unpublished manuscript, Federal Reserve Bank of
New York, 1969).
16Since there are many factors in addition to price expecta­
tions that affect the level of interest rates, die dependent
variable used in the regressions should be the one least
22
Digitized forPage
FRASER


DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

term interest rates ( rns) were approximately by the
yield on four- to six-month commercial paper. The
yield to maturity on Aaa-,rated corporate bonds was
used as the measure of long-term interest rates ( rnL).
Price expectations were approximated by the rate of
change of the consumer price index for all items,
p c 17

Using monthly data for the period January 1952 to
September 1969, the function
mt = ao -|- ajP't 4- a2Pct_ 1 -f- a3P\—2 + —

+

“ n + lP ° t -n

was estimated first by least squares regression of rnt
on current and lagged values of price changes for
n = 24, 36 and 48 months. The coefficients of the
regressions are presented in Chart I.
These regressions were run with both seasonally
adjusted and nonseasonally adjusted interest rate
series, and in each case the results using seasonally
adjusted data traced quite closely those using un­
adjusted data. The introduction of the seasonal
factor decreased the unexplained variance (increased
the adjusted coefficient of determination, R2) only
slightly. Chart II presents the coefficients of the
regressions:
m s =
t

do

+

m L =
t

a0 +

a i P ct +

a 2P ct _ i +

----- +

“ 2 5 P ct— 24

a i P ° t -)-

a 2P ct_ i +

----- +

a 2 5 P ct— 24

The coefficients using seasonally adjusted interest
rates are quite similar to those using unadjusted data.
influenced by those other factors. Yields on private securi­
ties were selected, instead of rates on Government debt,
because they are more free of the direct influences of debtmanagement and monetary actions. However, Fukasawa
obtained similar results using yields on Government securi­
ties. Greene found that price expectations were somewhat
easier to identify using interest rates on private debt.
17Mortgage costs are included in the consumer price index
and might contribute to some degree of spurious correlation
between interest rates and price movements. Since mort­
gage interest rates tend to move with other nominal rates,
using the consumer price index as the measure of price
movements would tend to result in a positive bias in the
observed relationship between interest rates and price move­
ments. To test for this effect the consumer price index
was purged of mortgage rate effects. Data on the mortgage
component of the CPI were available from the Bureau of
Labor Statistics only for the period 1954-64. Thus, nominal
interest rates were regressed on the rate of change of the
CPI and the adjusted CPI.for this period only. The regres­
sions using this adjusted Pc series were still quite close to
those using the index inclusive of mortgage costs. Gibson’s
procedure of using changes in national income as a proxy
for price expectations was also treated, using however, per­
sonal income, which is available on a monthly basis. The
results, summarized in the appendix, were quite similar to
those using the consumer price index.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LO U I S

0

t-4

t-8

t-12

t-16

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

t-20

t-24
t-28
Months

Since this close relationship was observed in all of
the tests, only the results using unadjusted data will
be explicitly considered.
The regressions show that price movements ac­
counted for about 50 per cent of the variance in
interest rates between 1952 and late 1969. The pat­
tern of coefficients is consistent with the adaptive
expectations hypothesis, that is, they are generally
declining. The presence of small negative coefficients
in the “tails” of the distributions could be explained
theoretically by the eventual domination of positive
“extrapolative effects” by negative “regressive effects”
(see page 32 below ). Although the t-test is suspect
in dealing with a distributed lag regression,18 the
coefficients tend to be small beyond t-24 months and
generally insignificant. Increasing the length of the
18Multicollinearity ( correlation between independent variables)
is a possible source of difficulty in estimation of this type of
distributed-lag relationship. In the presence of multicollinearity, the ordinary least squares regression technique is
unable to identify the exact parameter associated with each
independent variable. See J. Johnston, Econometric Methods
(New York: McGraw-Hill, 1963), pp. 201-207.



t-32

t-36

t-40

t-44

t-48

t-52

lag from 24 to 48 months had little effect on the
distribution of coefficients. The sum of the coefficients
increased as the lag was extended, however, sug­
gesting that, although great weight in the formation
of price expectations comes from quite recent ex­
perience, the total adjustment procedure is probably
somewhat longer, with only relatively small weight
given to price movements in the distant past. In
other words, the “true” distribution probably has a
“tail” of small declining coefficients. These results sug­
gest a much shorter time horizon information of price
expectations than had been found in the investiga­
tions cited earlier.
Due to multicollinearity, direct estimation of an
unconstrained distributed-lag function tends to re­
sult in wildly fluctuating coefficients. In order to re­
duce this fluctuation, the relationships were estimated
using the Almon lag technique.19 This procedure re­
sults in a much smoother distribution, which is more
19Shirley Almon, “The Distributed Lag Between Capital
Appropriations and Expenditures,” Econometrica, January
1965, pp. 178-196.
Page 23

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

C hart II

Regression Results Using Se a so n ally Adjusted
a n d Not S e a so n a lly Adjusted Interest Rates
Coefficients

consistent with the adaptive-expectations hypothesis,
that is, expectations are a continuous function of past
price movements.
The Almon lag estimates are presented in Chart
Iip o 'The distribution of the Almon coefficients fol­
lows the least squares estimate quite closely. For
lags from 24 to 48 months, most of the effect on
interest rates come from price movements over the
previous year. The tails of coefficients beyond these
points sum to nearly zero.
The regression using 48 lags suggests that, if the
annual rate of change of the consumer price index
increased by one per cent in a given month (for
20The regressions presented here were generated using a
sixth-degree polynomial. Other degree polynomials were
tested and gave similar distributions. The sixth-degree was
chosen because it best approximated the unconstrained
estimates, in that it minimized the sum of the squares of
the difference between the unconstrained and Almon es­
timates. The only constraint on the selection of the degree
of the polynomial is that it must be less than or equal to
the number of lagged coefficients. The sixth-degree poly­
nomial was the maximum which could be used in the pro­
gram available to the authors.
Digitized forPage
FRASER
24


Coefficients

example, from a 3 per cent annual rate of increase to
a 4 per cent annual rate) and prices continued to
rise at that rate, the yields on four- to six-month com­
mercial paper would rise 72 basis points ( for example,
from 4 per cent to 4.72 per cent) during the first year,
if all other factors affecting interest rates were un­
changed. After 48 months, short-term interest rates
would have risen by 69 basis points.21
n In the long run, the nominal rate of interest does not rise
by the full amount of the change in price expectations.
An increase in price expectations will increase the difference
between the nominal and Wicksellian market rates. How­
ever, the change in price expectations will tend to lower
the market rate. Assuming an equilibrium position with ex­
pected price changes equal to zero, then rnt=rmt. If
price expectations increase by one per cent per year, after
4 years the nominal interest rate will rise by 69 basis
points, thus
(1 )
(2 )

mt+48 — rmt+48 = 1.00
mt+48 — rnt = 0.69

Since mt = rmt, equations (1 ) and (2 ) reduce to
(3 ) rmt+48 — rmt = — 0.31
Thus the market interest rate falls by 31 basis points fol­
lowing the increase in price expectations. This result is
consistent with findings of other investigators; for example,
see Keith M. Carlson and Denis S. Karnosky, The Influence

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUI S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

C h a rt III

S u m m a r y o f R e g r e s s io n R e su lts
( A lm
o........
n L
ag)
__*
.
-......nSIT..—

Coefficients
.12

/
.10

U -

Short-Term Interest Rate
(1952-1969)

\

\ 48 Lags

.08
Sum

.06

.04

Constant

R2

24 Lags

.670

2.471

.607

36 Logs

.771

2.277

.618

48 Lags

.760

2.294

.617

.02

A '
-.02

' '

-.04
Coe ficients
.08

36 Lags

Long-Term Interest Rate
(1952-1969)

X 48 Lags
\

Sum

Constant

R2

24 Lags

.457

3.403

.514

36 Lags

.537

3.249

.531

48 Lags

.549

3.222

.526

-.02
-.04
t-4

t-8

t-12

t-16

t-20

t-24
t-28
M onths

of Fiscal and Monetary Actions on Aggregate Demand: A
Quantitative Appraisal, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis,
Working Paper No. 4, March 1969. In the aggregate de­
mand model developed there, an increase in expected prices
ceteris paribus generates a Government budget surplus



t-32

t-36

t-40

t-44

t-48

t-52

Fisher hypothesized that the time horizon in form­
ing price expectations was related to the term to
which results in a decrease in the stock df wealth and re­
duces the “real” interest rate. The net result is an increase
in nominal rates less than the increase in expected prices.
Page 25

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUI S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

C h a rt IV

Quarters

maturity of the instrument. Potential buyers and sell­
ers of long-term debt would be interested in how
prices move over an extended period and would tend
to look further into the past than would those people
who were dealing in short-term instruments. Partici­
pants in the market for short-term securities are less
likely to be concerned with long-term price move­
ments and might need less information in forming
their expectations. The results in the present study
are consistent with this idea.
The long-term interest rate is relatively less re­
sponsive to changes in price expectations. Twelve
months after the one per cent increase in prices,
long-term rates would be 59 basis points higher than
they were originally, as opposed to 72 basis points
for short-term rates. The effect on long-term rates
would be a total increase of 56 basis points after
48 months.

Why Such Long Lags In Earlier
Studies? — Three Hypotheses
The present study has found mean lags for the
effect of price level changes on both long-term and
short-term interest rates of less than a year. In con­
trast, earlier studies yielded mean lags of anywhere

Page 26


from seven to thirty years. It is important to try to
explain this discrepancy and to defend the results
presented here.
The authors have explored three hypotheses that
might reconcile the differences:
(1) The “true” lags of interest rates behind price
changes are short, so that biases arise in aggregat­
ing the interest rate and price change series over
longer observation periods, which lead to system­
atic overestimates of the length of the lags.22
(2) The forms of the lags estimated in other studies,
in contrast to the more flexible class of lags esti­
mated in this study, are biased toward yielding
longer average lags.
(3) Institutional changes have occurred over time in
financial and real markets, with the result that
price level changes have come to have prompter
22Griliches, pp. 45-46; Yair Mundlak, “ Aggregation Over
Time in Distributed Lag Models,” International Economic
Review, May 1961, pp. 154-163; and William R. Bryan,
“ Bank Adjustments to Monetary Policy: Alternative Esti­
mates of the Lag,” American Economic Review, September
1967, pp. 855-864. Griliches summarizes the issue as fol­
lows: “ aggregation over time (e.g., from quarterly to annual
data) will in general result in a misspecification of the
model. It will also . . . cause us to overestimate the implied
average lags.”

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

C h a rt V

Years
and larger effects on interest rates.23 T o put it
differently, there has been considerable thinning
o f the “molasses (long-lag) world,” particularly in
the past decade.

Aggregation of Data
To test the first hypothesis, the monthly data for
all of the interest rate series and the rate of change
in the consumer price index were aggregated to quar­
terly and annual averages of monthly data for the
1952-69 period. Almon distributed lags over 16 quar­
ters with sixth-degree polynominals were estimated
for the quarterly series. The results (see Chart IV)
were virtually identical to the original monthly re­
gressions with 48 month lags and the same degree
polynomials.24
23The post-war increase in the degree of financial “market
perfection” and its consequent effect on interest rate flexi­
bility is the subject of James S. Duesenberry’s essay, “The
Effect of Policy Instruments on Thrift Institutions,” in
Savings and Residential Financing: 1969 Conference Pro­
ceedings, pp. 135-143.
24Fukasawa has run unconstrained lags extending back six
quarters with quarterly data from IV/1951-IV/1968 for
Treasury bill and bond rates regressed on the rate of
change in the GNP deflator. His results are similar to those
reported here.



The quarterly regressions suggest that if the annual
rate of change of prices increases by one per cent in
any quarter and remains at the higher level the short­
term rate would rise by 84 basis points after 4 years.
The long-term rate would rise by 66 basis points over
the same period. Using the results of the monthly
estimates, an increase by one per cent in the annual
rate of change in prices, would yield an increase of
69 basis points in short-term rates and 56 basis points
in long-term rates after four years.
There were too few observations, given the length
of the lags and the degree of the polynomials, to fit
Almon lags to the annual observations, so only un­
constrained lags were estimated, ranging from one to
five years (see Chart V ). For the unadjusted com­
mercial paper rate, the R2 was highest (0.709) with
only the current rate of change in prices in the regres­
sion; in all cases, only the coefficient for the current
price changes was significant. As might be expected,
the R2 for the unadjusted corporate Aaa yield was
highest (0.552) when the current and one year lagged
price change term were included, although in every
Page 27

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

case only the coefficient on the current term was
significant. The regressions using annual data gave
somewhat larger total effects. If the rate of change
of prices rises by one per cent per year, short-term
rates would be 137 basis points higher after four years.
Long-term rates would rise by 134 basis points.
The discrepancy between this and earlier studies
apparently cannot be explained on grounds of an
aggregation bias in the latter, and the first hypothesis
cannot be accepted. The reason probably lies in the
fact that the adjustment of interest rates to price level
changes is not so rapid that aggregation of monthly
into quarterly and annual data leads to systematic
overestimates of the underlying lags.

Estimation Procedure
The second hypothesis pertains to the nature of
the lag distributions estimated in other studies. Since
several of the studies have estimated geometrically
decaying (K oyck) lags, the monthly data used in the
earlier part of the present study were used to estimate
such lags. The following regression was run for each
of the yield series, using for Pt both the simple
monthly rate of change and compounded annual rates
of change:25
mt = Xmt-i + /3Pt + constant

The decay coefficient X, presumably somewhere be­
tween zero and one, indicates the rate at which the
weight of the past rates of price change declines
backward in time ( that is, X = 1 means that the lagged
terms never decay at all, while X = 0 means that only
the current price change term has any effect).
All of the initial regressions yielded decay coeffi­
cients slightly greater than one, which, taken at face
value suggests that the lagged terms do not decay.
ms = 1.012 ms
t

mL = 1.007 mL
t

+

.057 P't — .024

R2 = .980

+

.053 K

R2 = .994

t— l

— .020

t— 1

A danger in such estimates of the decay coefficients
and the (3 parameter is that they are inconsistent, and
25This is the convenient form in which such lags are usually
estimated. This equation may be expanded into the
following:
mt = X0/SPt + XijSPui + X2/3Pt-2 + . . . + Xoo/SPt-33
+ constant
or, more simply,

OO

•

mt = /32 X‘P t_i + constant.

Page 28


i= o

the estimate of X is probably biased upward.26 Fol­
lowing procedures outlined by Griliches and by Goldberger, the decay coefficients were re-estimated, which
reduced them by only a very small amount:
ms = 1.005 ms

+

mL = 1.003 mL

+ .054 K

t

t

t—i
t—i

.071 Pct — .024
— .020

Decay coefficients greater than one are clearly in­
consistent with the adaptive expectations hypothesis.
It would not be unreasonable to expect decay co­
efficients only slightly less than one to result from
tests using different sample periods or data defini­
tions than were used here.
The monthly data were divided into two sub­
periods, 1952-60 and 1961-69, and separate estimates
of the decay coefficients obtained. For the earlier
period, the coefficients dropped below one, ranging
(unadjusted for consistency) from 0.977 for commer­
cial paper rates to 0.996 for corporate Aaa yields.
These results imply long mean lags for both interest
rates, with longer lags for the long-term rates. The
coefficients on the current rate of price change in the
commercial paper rate regressions strangely became
negative for the 1952-60 period.27 For 1961-69, the
decay coefficients were nearly the same as for the
entire 1952-69 period, that is, slightly greater than
one, for which it is difficult to find any theoretical
rationalization.
To see what would happen to the decay coeffi­
cients, the monthly data were aggregated into quar­
terly data and the decay coefficients re-estimated for
the 1952-69 period and for the subperiods mentioned
above. All of the decay coefficients for the entire
period declined, which would be expected if a monthly
decay process were to be converted into an equivalent
quarterly process, but the decay coefficients for short­
term rates fell to below one (0.968 for commercial
paper rates, with a mean lag of 20 quarters or five
years). For 1952-60 alone, all the coefficients were
less than one, but the decay process was again nega­
tive for short-term rates. For 1961-69 the results
were all plausible, and the decay coefficients were
26See Griliches, p. 41, and Arthur S. Goldberger, Econo­
metric Theory (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1964), pp.
276-278, and Kenneth F. Wallis, “ Some Recent Develop­
ments in Applied Econometrics: Dynamic Models and Sim­
ultaneous Equation Systems,” Journal of Economic Litera­
ture, September 1969, pp. 774-775.
27This implies that the lagged price change effects are op­
posite in sign from those hypothesized; they could be inter­
preted as evidence for Sargent’s “regressive effects” of price
changes on short-term rates (see p. 32 below).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LO U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

all lower than corresponding coefficients for 1952-60.
The effect of price level changes on commercial paper
rates for the latter period decayed with a X of 0.834
(mean lag of about three quarters), while the decay
factor was 0.919 (mean lag of seven quarters) for
corporate Aaa yields.28

As was the case with the entire period, there was
little difference in the total price expectations effect
between different degree polynomials. The length of
the lag distribution was crucial, however. The total
effect on short-term interest rates tended to decline
as the lag was extended beyond 24 months, and this
was quite pronounced in the 1961-69 period. The
effect on long-term rates, however, increased as the
lag was extended up to 36 months. Beyond 36
months, the sum of the coefficients remained almost
constant. None of the coefficients beyond 48 months
were significant. These results suggest that the time
horizon in forming price expectations increases as the
term to maturity of the security increases.

The preceding experiments with simple geometri­
cally declining lag structures suggest that such lags,
requiring an exponential decay, may not be the most
appropriate ones to impose on the interest rate and
price level data for the period of this study in the
attempt to capture the “true” underlying lag dis­
tribution. In every case the average lags obtained
with this procedure were considerably longer than
with either unconstrained or Almon lags, which pro­
vides some explanation for the differences between
this and previous studies.29

The total price expectations effect is much larger
in the 1961-69 period than in the earlier period. In
the latter period the total effect on short-term rates
is about 90 per cent of the annual rate of change in
prices. The effect on long-term rates is about 80 per
cent of the rate of price change. In the 1952-60 pe­
riod the sum of the coefficients range between 5 and
35 per cent of the price change for a lag of 36 months.
Chart VI contains the lag coefficients for short-term
rates ( second-degree polynomial and 24 lags for
1961-69, and sixth-degree with 36 lags for 1952-60)
for the relationship between the commercial paper
rate and the rate of change in the consumer price

Institutional Changes
The third hypothesis asserts that price level changes
have come to have larger and prompter effects on
interest rates because of institutional changes in the
economy. As a preliminary test of this hypothesis, the
1952-69 period was again divided into two subperiods,
1952-60 and 1961-69, and various Almon lag struc­
tures estimated separately for each.30 Table I con­
tains the sum of the lag coefficients for 12 to 48 lags
and second- to sixth-degree polynomials.

28James B. Greene, using quarterly
data for 1961-68, obtained a decay
coefficient of 0.824 for the commer­
cial paper rate regressed on the
rate of change in the consumer
price index, which implies a mean
lag of about 2% quarters; for the
corporate Aaa yield his decay co­
efficient was 0.919 implying a mean
lag of about seven quarters.
29Experiments were also conducted for
the whole period and the subperiods
with simple second-order lags (in
the regressions the dependent vari­
able was lagged one and two pe­
riods ). The results were not appreci­
ably different from those for the
first-order lags.
30The “Chow test” was conducted to
see whether there was a fundamen­
tal shift in behavior patterns within
the 1952-1969 period. For both
commercial paper rates and corpo­
rate Aaa yields the “F” statistics were
significant at the one per cent level,
which indicates a substantial differ­
ence in the anticipations forming
mechanism in the two subperiods.
For an explanation of the test, see
Gregory C. Chow, “Tests of Equality
between Sets of Coefficients in Two
Linear Regressions,” Econometrica,
July 1960, pp. 591-605.



T ab le I

SU M OF THE REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS*
(monthly data)
Short-term interest rates
Length of Lag
1 9 5 2 -6 0

1 9 6 1 -6 9

D e g re e of
P olyno m ial

12

24

36

2

.2 8 2 5

.2 2 6 5

.0 8 9 9

48
— .0 4 8 2

12

24

36

48

.921 1

.9 5 1 8

.8 0 3 9

.5 7 2 6

3

.2 7 6 0

.2 2 5 4

.3 0 5 5

.1 8 5 6

.9 1 0 5

.9 0 3 5

.7 2 3 5

.5 3 4 4

4

.2 8 3 7

.2 4 0 2

.341 8

.1 3 4 9

.91 18

.9 2 3 1

.7 3 7 3

.4 7 5 0

5

.2 8 3 6

.2 4 0 6

.3 3 7 8

.0 5 3 9

.9 1 3 4

.9 2 1 0

.7 1 2 4

.4 6 6 8

6

.2 8 3 4

.2 4 3 9

.3 3 4 0

.0 9 6 0

.9 1 3 1

.9 1 7 2

.7 1 8 0

.4 7 5 9

Long-term interest rates
Length of Lag
1 9 5 2 -6 0

1 9 6 1 -6 9

D e gre e of
P o lyn o m ia l

12

24

36

48

12

24

36

48

2

.1 4 3 2

.1 1 5 4

.0 5 3 7

.0 0 8 1

.5 8 5 4

.7 0 8 6

.8 4 0 6

.8 3 2 1 ”

3

.1 4 1 7

.1 1 2 2

.1 6 3 9

.1 5 8 0

.5 8 8 1

.7 4 0 5

.8 6 1 8

.7 9 4 5

4

.1 4 4 5

.1 1 4 0

.2 0 7 8

.1 3 7 4

.5 8 8 6

.7 5 3 1

.8 5 4 0

.8 2 1 0

5

.1 4 4 5

.1 1 9 3

.2 0 6 2

.0 7 9 8

.5 8 8 9

.7 5 3 3

.8 4 7 4

.8 2 2 7

6

.1 4 4 4

.1 2 0 0

.2 0 2 3

.0 7 5 6

.5 8 8 6

.7 5 2 4

.8 5 2 6

.8 3 0 3

♦ A ll c o e ffic ie n ts in th e ta b le f o r th e 1961-69 p e r io d a r e s ig n ific a n t a t th e o n e p e r c e n t le v e l. T h o se
f o r th e 1952-60 p e r io d w e re in s ig n ific a n t f o r 48 la gs.

Page 29

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

Chart Vt

Sum m ary of Regression Results
Coefficients

Months

index. The sum of the coefficients for the earlier pe­
riod was .344 and the mean lag, 1 to 2 months. For
the latter period, the sum was .952, and the mean
lag 4 to 5 months. While it is true that the smaller
effect in the earlier period was exhausted more quickly
(the mean lag was shorter), the peak in total effect
for the earlier period was reached after eleven months,
while the same level of effect was attained in the

Page 30


latter period in only 2 to
jumps from 0.255 to 0.901,
rate of change in prices
cent of the variation in

3 months. Further, the R2
so for the latter period the
accounts for over 90 per
commercial paper rates.31

31The highest R 2 (0.938) for the commercial paper rate was
obtained for 1961-69 using sixth-degree polynomials and
48 month lags.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

These results are thus consistent with the hypothesis
of the effect of institutional changes.3Similar results were obtained for the corporate Aaa
yield (Chart V I), and the jump in R- for the latter
period is even more pronounced, from 0.164 to 0.973.
The coefficients of the long-term rate were generated
using a second-degree polynomial and 48 lags for
1961-69 and sixth-degree with 36 lags for 1952-60.
All of the coefficients estimated for the 1961-69 period
are significant at the one per cent level. A mean lag
of 16 months is implied by this result, meaning more
than half of the adjustments in interest rates to price
changes in the period were attained in less than a
year and a half. A summary of the 1961-69 regressions
appears in the appendix.
What factors might cause a shift in the framework
for transmitting past price level changes, via price
expectations, to nominal interest rates? A listing of
plausible explanations might include the following:
(1 ) According to Friedman and Schwartz, “ the period
used in forming anticipations should depend on
the characteristics o f price behavior,” particularly
the “variability in the behavior of the general
level of prices .”33 Thus, one could argue that
prices have been more variable, at least in an up­
ward direction, in the 1950’s and 1960’s than over
long, earlier historical periods. Further, the greater
publicity given to price level movements, as well
as the more rapid processing of data, could convey
greater awareness of recent price level behavior
and affect price level expectations and interest
rates more substantially than once was the case.
(2 ) Nominal rates may have come to reflect past price
level changes more fully both because of a de­
crease in “money illusion” and because of de­
creased effects of price changes on real wealth
over time .34 The former could be explained by
the increased importance of large institutional in­
vestors in markets such as that for corporate bonds.
For the latter to be a contributory factor, real
wealth would have to be affected relatively less
than before by price changes (because assets not
32Fukasawa has estimated unconstrained lags with quarterly
data for five subperiods from 1951-68 and has obtained
similar results.
33Friedman and Schwartz, p. 143.
34“ Money illusion” means that behavior is based on and di­
rected toward nominal magnitudes rather than “real” mag­
nitudes, for example, investment outlay in money terms
would be related to money income and nominal interest
rates.
If real wealth influences the decisions of savers, the
saving function would not shift upward by the expected
rate of increase in prices because of expected decreases in
the real value of assets fixed in nominal terms ( for ex­
ample, money), which dampen the effect of price expecta­
tions on nominal rates (see Robert Mundell, “ Inflation and
Real Interest,” Journal of Political Economy, June 1963,
pp. 280-283).



DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

fixed in nominal terms may have becom e rela­
tively more im portant), thus reducing the “ drag”
on upward shifts in the saving function by the
amount of expected price level changes.
(3 ) Interest rates are more flexible than in many past
periods. According to Duesenberry,
“ Restrictive monetary policy has in the past
operated to a large extent through [nonprice]
rationing . . . . Market forces and public policy have
been working toward perfecting capital markets,
and thereby reducing the effectiveness of ration­
ing . . . [and resulting in] a world requiring
wide swings in interest rates for stabilization
purposes . . ,”35
Thus, one would expect to find larger coefficients
linking price changes to interest rates than in the
past.
(4 ) The frame o f reference for forming expectations
may well have changed, particularly in the 1960’s.
The relative absence of cycles in prices except for
the very distant past deprives individuals of a suc­
cession of comparable reference points from which
to extrapolate into the future and forces the use
of heavier weights on the more recent past.

Price Expectations In An Expanded Model
A recent study by Thomas J. Sargent3" differs
from earlier studies of the effect of price expectations
on interest rates in two important respects. Besides
relating past price changes to nominal interest rates,
he sought also to decompose the “real” rate into
components representing the equilibrium “real” rate
and the deviation of current “real” market rates from
the equilibrium rate. In addition, the shapes of the
distributed lags he estimated were more general,
that is, capable of fitting the data into a greater
variety of geometrical configurations.
Sargent devised a useful identity:37
(a)
(b )
mt = ret
+
(rmt — ret)
V
----------------- V-----------------'
“Real” rate ( rmt = m )

+

(c )
(mt — rmt)
v------------ y------------ '
Fisher effect ( )

where r e t is the rate of interest at which real saving
and investment would be in long-run equilibrium and
rm t is the current market level of the “real” rate, that
is, rm t is the same as rrt in equation ( 1 ) above.
Movements in the nominal rate may then be attrib­
uted to changes in the equilibrium rate (a), to a
deviation between the equilibrium rate and the “real”
market rate ( b ) , and to a Fisher effect ( c ) .
35Duesenberry, pp. 136 and 140.
3eThomas J. Sargent, “Commodity Price Expectations and
the Interest Rate,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Feb­
ruary 1969, pp. 127-140.
37Sargent, p. 130. It is an identity, since it simplifies
to mt = mt.
Page 31

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

Earlier studies (including that which we have re­
ported above) regarded either ( b ) or ( a + b ) as a
residual and regressed nominal interest rates on past
price changes only, but Sargent attempted to estimate
each of the components of the level of nominal rates.
The relationships among the components of the nom­
inal rate and how he sought to identify them statis­
tically are shown in Figure I. Assume that real
investment (I/P) and real saving ( S / P ) are func­
tions of real income and “real” market rates of
interest and that real income is given (so shifts in
the saving and investment schedules do not have to
be accounted for). The equilibrium “real” interest
rate (re) is the rate at which real saving and invest­
ment would be in equilibrium. The market rate (rm)
below the equilibrium rate indicates that some por­
tion ( A B ) of current investment is being financed from
sources other than intended saving, for example, by
newly created money from the banking system or
through the drawing down of previously accumulated
money balances. This is sometimes called the “Wicksell effect” on interest rates.38
Assuming savers and investors form the same price
expectations and that neither are subject to “money
illusion” (an important Fisherian concept39), both
functions would be shifted upward by the expected
rate of change in prices, P\ = rnt — rmt.
Since the equilibrium rate cannot be directly ob­
served, Sargent used a reduced form proxy for it. He
solved his real saving and investment functions simul­
taneously, so that the one market rate consistent with
equilibrium (equality of intended savings and in­
vestment) is a function of the other determinants of
real saving and investment, namely real income and
(from an investment accelerator) the change in real
38Knut Wicksell, Lectures on Political Economy, pp. 190-198,
and Interest and Prices (London: Macmillan, 1936). Wick­
sell assumed that savers and investors expected current
prices to continue into the future, so he did not need to
account for price expectations effects on interest rates. As
Sargent points out, views similar to Wicksell’s were also
held by Henry Thornton in 1802 and by Keynes in A
Treatise on Money. Emphasis on the equilibrium rate-market rate relationship as the proper one in using interest
rates as monetary policy indicators and rejection of price
expectations effects on empirical grounds characterizes re­
cent work of Patric H. Hendershott and George Horwich
(see, for example, “The Appropriate Indicators of Mone­
tary Policy, Part II,” in Savings and Residential Financing:
1969 Conference Proceedings, pp. 42-44).
What is here called the “Wicksell effect” may also be
interpreted as the "liquidity effect” or “impact effect” of
changes in the money stock; similarly, the real GNP variables
reflect the “income effect” or “feedback effect” on interest
rates associated with changes in the money stock (see refer­
ences to works by Friedman and Schwartz, Gibson, and
Meltzer cited above).
39See footnote 34 above.
Page 32



Figu re I

Illustration of Sargent's Identity
interest

income. This solution was then used to measure com­
ponent (a ) in the equations he estimated. Similarly,
having no independent observations for the market
rate, he used another proxy, the current rate of change
in the “real” (deflated) money stock, for the .devia­
tion of the market rate from equilibrium.40
Finally, Sargent estimated geometrically distrib­
uted lags on past price changes as a proxy for price
expectations. Using annual data for 1902-40 (tw o of
the regressions were also run for 1902-54) and taking
for nominal rates Durand’s one-year and ten-year
basic yields, he obtained estimates implying very
long mean lags (twenty years or more for short- and
long-term rates).
In several of his regressions he estimated two sets
of decay coefficients. Both were positive for the long­
term rate; for the short-term rate one was negative
and more quickly decaying, which Sargent ration­
alized as indicative of a “regressive effect” of price
changes on short-term rates (as opposed to the posi­
tive “extrapolative effect” ), that is, price changes
temporarily generate expectations of changes in the
opposite direction (that is, that they will move back
to a “normal” level). The sum of the regressive and
40In Figure I the gap between the equilibrium and mar­
ket interest rates will widen as the portion of real invest­
ment not financed by current real savings (A B) increases.
The rate of change in the real money stock, on the other
hand, should be positively correlated with the magnitude
of AB. As a proxy for ( rm-re) the rate of money change
should have a negative coefficient (that is, be positively
related to an (re-rm) gap).
The entire reduced form for “ real” rates should also
capture the effects of other capital market disturbances,
for example, Government surpluses or deficits and the ways
they are financed (banking system versus nonbank public).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

extrapolative weights did not reach a peak until eight
years and declined even more slowly thereafter
(since the negative component decayed more rap­
idly), so the mean lag would not be much different
from his other results.
The authors have subjected Sargent’s basic approach
to a further test, with the following modifications:
(1 ) Both real saving and investment are assumed to
depend on both real GNP and “ real” market rates
of interest. Thus, there is no a priori expectations
as to the sign of the coefficient for the real GNP
term in the regressions. A negative coefficient
would presumably indicate that shifts in the sav­
ing function in response to a change in real GNP
outweighed shifts in investment, so that nominal
and “real” rates would tend to fall as real GNP
rose .41 A positive coefficient would suggest just
the opposite, while a coefficient near zero might
indicate roughly offsetting effects of saving and
investment shifts.
(2 ) Quarterly and monthly instead o f annual data
are used, and as before, the emphasis is completely
on the entire post-accord period and the 1961-1969
subperiod. The regressions with monthly data
necessarily use proxies for real GNP (personal
income deflated by the consumer price index and,
alternatively, the index of industrial production)
and the GNP price deflator ( consumer price
in d ex ).
(3 ) The interest rate series and distributed lag forms
are different; further, regressions were run with
and without a constant term (Sargent did not
suppress the constant term in any of his regres­
sions ).

The equations estimated are of the following form:
mt = ao +

2 arhPt-i + ftY* + ft>AY* + /S3AM“
i=o
t
t
t

where P is the annual rate of change in the GNP
deflator (or a monthly proxy), Y° and AY° are the
level and rate of change in real GNP (or a monthly
proxy), and AM * is the average change in the real
money stock (nominal money stock deflated by the
GNP deflator or its monthly proxy). Nominal rates
(rn) are again the four- to six-month commerical
paper rate (rns) and the corporate Aaa yield ( m L),
using quarterly averages of monthly data in the
quarterly regressions. Only results for the 1961-69
subperiod will be reported here, in Chart VII, and
in the appendix.
The explanatory power of price level changes was
changed little when the equations were more fully
4'Sargent obtained negative coefficients in all of his regres­
sions. In his theoretical model he assumed that only saving
was functionally related to the level of real GNP.



DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

specified, and the adjusted RJ’s rose by small amounts.
For example in the equations for the long-term rate
with second-degree Almon polynomials, total lags of
16 quarters (best statistical fit), and a constant term,
the sum of the coefficients on current and lagged
rates of price change actually rose from 0.80 to 0.86,
and the R2 was unchanged at 0.977 when the current
real GNP and real change in the money supply were
added to the regression; further, the mean lag for the
effect of price changes on nominal rates increased
from 3.2 quarters to 5.5 quarters. In other words,
recent price changes alone tend to overstate the
necessary adjustment of nominal rates to account for
the Fisher effect. As would be expected, the coeffi­
cients on current and lagged rates of price change
were redistributed toward the past in the expanded
equations, since the current and last quarters’ price
levels implicitly enter into the other independent
variables.42
Suppressing the constant term in the equation (that
is, forcing “o to zero) forces a redistribution of its
effects over the other coefficients. In the case of the
long-term rate, the constant was not significant, and
suppressing it enhanced slightly the .explanatory
power of real GNP and the change in the real money
supply, lowered the sum of the price change coeffi­
cients (to 0.80) and the acceleration coefficient ( (3a),
left the R2 virtually unchanged, and lengthened the
mean lag (b y three quarters with total lags o f 16
quarters). In the case of the short-term rate, the mean
lag rose from zero to nearly one quarter. Otherwise,
the effects on the coefficients were exactly opposite
to what happened when the constant was suppressed
in the equation for the long-term rate.
Since the expanded equations contain variables not
all measured in the same units, “beta” coefficients
were computed in order to assess the relative con­
tribution of each independent variable to the de­
termination of nominal interest rates. In the equation
for the long-term rate with various lag lengths the
“beta” coefficient for price level changes is nearly
three times as large as for real GNP, which ranks
second in importance.
42The equation was also estimated for various lengths of
total lags without the current rate of price level change
(all of Sargent’s regressions were of this form) to try to
reduce multicollinearity. With total lags of 16 quarters, the
sum of the coefficients on the lagged price changes

2 a i+l I rose slightly, ft. and /32 remained about the
i=°

/
same, £3 declined in absolute value by about 10 per cent,
and the R2 and Durbin-Watson statistics rose slightly.
Page 33

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

C h a rt V II

Estimated Long-Term R eal Interest Rates*
PerCent

PerCent

coefficients were smaller than in the
quarterly regressions, suggesting that
the response of the equilibrium “real”
rate of interest to real income growth
may occur over a substantially longer
period than the current month.44
Thus, the findings reported in this
section appear to support the specifica­
tion of variables in Sargent’s model.
The use of quarterly and monthly data
over post-accord period and the esti­
mation of Almon lags provide better
statistical results than in his study.
The importance of price level changes
in explaining nominal interest rates is
diluted very little by the expanded
equations, and the mean lags are not
sufficiently lengthened to alter the con­
clusions of the earlier sections of the
present study.

Experimental Time Series For
The “Real” Rate of Interest

Y ie ld s o n c o rp o ra te A a a b o n d s
Latest d a t a plotted: O c t o b e r

The Federal Reserve Bank of St.
Louis began calculating and publishing
an experimental monthly series for the
expected “real” rate of return on Cor­
porate Aaa bonds in 1966.45 The procedure em­
ployed was to subtract from the actual Aaa yield
a simple average of rates of change in the implicit
GNP price deflator for the previous twelve months
(quarterly price deflator data were interpolated to
obtain an estimated monthly index). Such a proce­
dure necessarily implies that the mean lag is half as
long (six months) as the total lag and that the co-

Sargent’s expanded model was also tested with
monthly data, using alternatively, personal income
deflated by the consumer price index and the index
of industrial production as proxies for the real GNP
(a series derived from the regression using the latter
appears in Chart VII as “real” rate 3 ). The results
closely paralleled those for the equations using quar­
terly data. For example, in the equation for the long­
term rate with a total lag of 48 months, the index of
industrial production as the real GNP proxy, and a
constant term (which was significant in the monthly
regressions), the sum of the price change coefficients
fell from 0.87 to 0.82, the mean lag rose slightly
from 15.6 to 16.4 months, and the R2 went from
0.968 to 0.971.43 The change in industrial production
and the change in the real money supply had the
correct signs but were not significant; one month is
probably too short a period to capture the full “Wicksell (liquidity) effect.” The level of industrial pro­
duction turned out to be quite significant, but the

44It should also be noted that there is another possible source
of mis-specification in all of the expanded equations, namely,
the interrelationship between changes in the nominal money
stock and both price levels and rates of change. In other
words, the monetary authorities would be expected to re­
spond to departures from stable prices. One way around this
problem is to make the policy variable endogenous in a
simultaneously estimated model containing a “reaction func­
tion” for the Federal Reserve ( see Michael W . Keran and
Christopher T. Babb, “An Explanation of Federal Reserve
Actions (1933-68),” this Review, July 1969, pp. 7-20; and
Raymond G. Torto, “An Endogenous Treatment of the
Federal Reserve System in a Macro-Econometric Model,”
unpublished dissertation, Boston College, 1969.

43Results using personal income deflated by the consumer
price index were virtually identical to those using the index
of industrial production as the proxy for real GNP.

45“ Strong Total Demand, Rising Interest Rates, and Contin­
ued Availability of Credit,” this Review, August 1966, pp.
3 and 4.


Page 34


FEDERAL. R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

efficients are constrained to sum to one.48 Shortly
afterward the lag for averaging price changes was
extended to 24 months (mean lag of 12 months),
and the resulting proxy for the “real” rate has been
reported periodically ever since. As a testimonial
to the intuition of the series’ creator, the distributed
lag results in the present study yield estimates of the
magnitude of effect and the mean lag which are
remarkably close to the original “real” rate series.
Chart VII contains the nominal corporate Aaa
yield from 1960 to October 1969 and various estimated
monthly “real” rate series. “Real” rate 1 is the original
series, that is, the nominal rate minus the average of
rates of price change over the preceding two years.
“Real” rate 2 is obtained from the regression using
monthly data for 1961-69, total lags of 48 months,
and second-degree polynomials. “Real” rate 3 is de­
rived from the regression reported in the preceding
section, which seeks to explain the contribution of
“real” rates, as well as price expectations to nominal
rates of interest; “real” rates here are assumed to be
related to the level o f and changes in the index of
industrial production and changes in the deflated
money stock.
Detailed analysis of the movements in these series
will require a separate study.47 Only a few observa­
tions will be made here. The pattern of movement
in all three “real” rate series is remarkably similar.
The old “real” rate 1, however, appears to have over­
stated the price expectations component of the nom­
inal rate over most of the period. What is of particular
interest are the occasions when changes in nominal
rates gave apparently false signals about the nature
of changes in “real” rates and the extent o f agreement
about directions of movement among the three “real”
rate series.
All three “real” rates indicated that credit condi­
tions were progressively tighter during the first half
of 1961, when the nominal rate was virtually un­
changed. The nominal rate was a reasonably good
proxy for “real” rates 2 and 3 during 1962 but not
for “real” rate 1, which rose for most of the year
(the consequence of heavier implicit weights than
the other two series on price changes two years
n
1 .
48Mathematically, Pe = 2 — Pt_j, where n is the length
1
i= 1 n
of the total lag, and there are exactly n coefficients, each of
which equals 1/n (hence, the sum is n *1/n = 1). Moving
averages with equal weights are discussed by Griliches, p.
25.
47A variety of other monthly and quarterly “real” rate series
have been computed, including short-term “real” rates.



DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

earlier and lighter weights on the past year). The
gradual upward creep in prices from 1963-65 caused
“real” rate 1 to creep smoothly downward, generally
opposite in direction to the nominal rate. With the
different pattern of weights, movements in the “real”
rates 2 and 3 were more pronounced, indicating that
underlying price level changes were not entirely
smooth over the interval.
“Real” rates 1 and 2 fell and “real” rate 3 oscil­
lated around a constant level during the first half of
1966, while the nominal rate rose. From late 1966
until early 1967, all rates moved down in step. From
1967-69, the original “real” rate 1 tended to drift
downward and oscillate somewhat ambiguously, al­
though the three “real” rate series fell before nominal
rates declined in the summer of 1968.
“Real” rates 2 and 3 moved upward with the nom­
inal rate from late 1968 until early 1969. For several
months thereafter, nominal rates did not rise by
enough to offset the effects of rapid inflation, with
the consequence that the monthly “real” rates actually
fell from about February until late in the summer.
Such movement in “real” rates could be used to ex­
plain, in part, the strength of the 1969 surge in in­
vestment spending.

Conclusions
Citing the findings by Gibson and Sargent of long
lags in the forming of price expectations, Hendershott and Horwich recently argued:
. . . Their experience contradicts the monetary
voices in government, industry and the acad­
emy that proclaim, but do not demonstrate, that
price level expectations, rather than real forces,
are largely responsible for interest rate move­
ments in this decade .48

In contrast, the present study has shown that, unlike
the earlier historical periods on which most of the
previous studies have been based, price level changes
since 1952 have evidently come to have a prompt
and substantial effect on price expectations and nom­
inal interest rates. In addition, the total effect of
price expectations on interest rates and the speed at
which they are formed appear to have increased
greatly since 1960. This conclusion is invariant to the
form or the term of the flexible classes of distributed
48Hendershott and Horwich, “Appropriate Indicator,” p.
44. Criticizing the earlier “ St. Louis ‘ real” rate,” they con­
tinue, “The Fisherian zeal of that institution would shock
no one more than Irving Fisher, who himself stressed the
fantastically long lags in the formation of price level ex­
pectations and their impact on interest rates in this
country.”
Page 35

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

lags estimated. Most significant is the finding that
price level changes, rather than “real” rates, account
for nearly all the variation in nominal interest rates
since 1961. Furthermore, the addition of variables to
the regressions to account explicitly for the “real”
rate components of nominal rates does not apprecia­
bly alter these findings.
The causes of price level changes over the period
of the study have not been investigated. The pri­
mary concern has been to determine the extent to
which nominal rate movements may be attributed
to expectations about future rates of change in prices,
so that nominal rates may consequently be adjusted
to yield information about movements in underlying
“real” rates.49 The failure to make such an adjust­
ment and the sole use of changes in nominal rates
as indicators of monetary ease or tightness may on
occasion give misleading information about the direc49An interesting attempt to “ neutralize” interest rates with
respect to the impact of movements toward or away from
full employment was reported in Dennis R. Starleaf and
James A. Stephenson, “A Suggested Solution to the Mone­
tary Policy Indicator Problem: The Monetary Full Employ­
ment Interest Rate,” Journal of Finance, September 1969,
pp. 623-641. Unfortunately, the authors did not incorporate
price level changes into their analysis, which is a serious
deficiency in their work.


Page 36


DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

tion and the extent of movements in “real” rates. The
importance of the Fisher effect to the controversy
over appropriate monetary policy indicators has been
succinctly stated by David Fand:
. . . As w e get closer to a world o f high
employment, and especially if interest rates and
prices are both rising, the money stock may be
a better (less misleading) indicator or target
variable than [nominal] interest rates. Para­
doxically, the current tendency to emphasize
interest rates and to ignore changes in the money
stock would seem more relevant to a society
where interest rates and prices are falling while
the money stock is constant, or rising at a lower
rate than output .50

According to economic theory, changes in “real”
rates should then reflect both shifts in the equilibrium
relationship between real saving and investment and
current capital market disequilibrium. Further, it is
such “real” rate series that should be employed in
studies of the term structure of interest rates and of
the effects of international interest rate differentials
on short- and long-term capital flows.
50David Fand, “ Keynesian Monetary Theories, Stabilization
Policy, and the Recent Inflation,” Journal of Money, Credit
and Banking, August 1969, p. 576.

This article is available as Reprint No. 49.

The Appendix to this article begins on the next page.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUI S

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

APPENDIX

Nominal Income As a Proxy for Prices
Gibson suggested that movements in nominal income
might serve as a measure o f price behavior. His reason­
ing was that the CPI might be unable to accurately
measure short-term price movements since it is a selec­
tive index of prices. Nominal income, on the other hand,
contains an implicit general price index.
Regressions using current and lagged monthly rates
of change of nominal personal income (Py) were run
and the patterns of coefficients are similar to those
resulting from the runs using the CPI. To adjust for the
difference in magnitude between the income and price
index series, “beta coefficients” were computed in Table 1
below .1
T a b le I

SU M O F THE BETA COEFFICIENTS (1952-69)
Short-term rates
•
py

Long-term rates
.
•
py
Pc

•
pc

any deviations due to short-run changes in financial
markets. The series 2 was generated from the following
relationship:
( 1 )

m t

=

“ o

+

a l P ct

+

“ 2 P ct — 1

+

. . . .

+

“ 4 9 P ct — 4 8

T a b le II

REG RESSION COEFFICIENTS
L
m t =

“o +

•
a l P ct +

(J a n u a r y

•
“ 2P ct — 1 +

....

+

•
a 4o P ct — 18

1 9 6 1 - Sep tem b er 1 9 6 9 )
a.
i

t-value

i

t-va lue

i

1

.0 3 5 3

1 2 .0 8 5 8

26

.0 1 5 7

9 .7 3 5 8

2

.0 3 4 5

1 3 .1 2 0 1

27

.0 1 5 0

9 .0 3 6 0

3

.0 3 3 6

1 4 .3 5 2 1

28

.0 1 4 3

8 .4 2 4 6

4

.0 3 7 9

1 5 .8 4 2 1

29

.0 1 3 6

7 .8 8 6 0

i

5

.0 3 2 0

1 7 .6 7 6 5

30

.0 1 2 9

7 .4 0 8 1

6

.0 3 1 1

1 9 .9 8 2 2

31

.0 1 2 2

6 .9812

7

.0 3 0 3

2 2 .9 4 9 8

32

.0 1 1 5

6 .5 9 7 7

8

.0 2 9 5

2 6 .8 7 0 0

33

.0 1 0 8

6 .2512

9

.0 2 8 7

3 2 .1 7 8 6

34

.0 1 0 2

5 .9 3 6 8
5 .6 5 0 1

24

la g s

2 .0 2 0

1.301

1 .5 0 2

1 .2 5 9

36

la g s

2 .0 9 0

1 .5 2 6

1 .6 5 9

1 .5 3 2

10

.0 2 7 9

3 9 .4 3 8 9

35

.0 0 9 5

48

la g s

2 .4 8 9

1 .581

2 .2 3 0

1 .7 6 7

11

.0 2 7 1

4 8 .8 6 9 7

36

.0 0 8 8

5 .3 8 7 6

12

.0 2 6 3

5 8 .1 8 0 7

37

.0 0 8 2

5 .1465

13

.0 2 5 5

6 0 .2 6 7 8

38

.0 0 7 5

4 .9 2 4 3

14

.0 2 4 7

5 2 .6 5 0 0

39

.0 0 6 8

4 .7 1 8 7

15

.0 2 4 0

4 2 .4 8 1 2

40

.0 0 6 2

4 .5 2 8 1
4 .3 5 0 8

The expectational effects of prices on interest rates,
as indicated by movements in nominal income, are larger
than those suggested by movements in the CPI. In ad­
dition, use of nominal income results in somewhat
longer lags, but almost all of the effect still occurs
within two years.

The Real Rate of Interest Series
The “ real” interest rates (series 2 and 3 ) presented
in Chart VII are actually the Wicksellian “market” rate

L

(rmt)

or the long-run equilibrium

interest rate plus

'Arthur S. Goldberger, Econometric Theory (New York: John
Wiley & Sons, 1964), pp. 197-198.



16

.0 2 3 2

3 4 .1 4 1 5

41

.0 0 5 6

17

.0 2 2 4

2 8 .0 1 0 2

42

.0 0 4 9

4 .1855

18

.0 2 1 7

2 3 .5 2 6 2

43

.0 0 4 3

4 .0 3 1 1

19

.0 2 0 9

2 0 .1 7 4 2

44

.0 0 3 7

3 .8864

20

.0 2 0 1

1 7 .6 0 0 6

45

.0 0 3 0

3 .7506

21

.0 1 9 4

1 5 .5 7 4 3

46

.0 0 2 4

3 .6229

22

.0 1 8 7

1 3 .9 4 3 1

47

.0 0 1 8

3 .5 0 2 7
3 .3 8 9 2

23

.0 1 7 9

1 2 .6 0 4 8

48

.0 0 1 2

24

.0 1 7 2

1 1 .4 8 8 6

49

.0 0 0 6

3 .2 8 1 9

25

.0 1 6 5

1 0 .5 4 4 3

C o n sta n t 3 . 3 1 0 2

7 5 .0 6 3 5

R2
Page 37

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. LOUI S

T a b le

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

Using Sargent’s model, real output ( Y ° ), the change
in real output ( A Y * ) , and the change in real balances
( A M ° ) were added to the function, and the following
was estimated:

III

REGRESSION COEFFICIENTS
rn J

=

“ o

a

i
1

a Pc

+

+
(Ja n u a ry

z "

t— 1

+

1 9 6 1 -S e p t e m b e r

a

•

pc

25'

t — 24

m. = 181Y 0 + ft>AY* + ftiAM* + 2 “ i+ iP t—i
t
t
t
i=o

1969)
a

i

.1 0 0 4

t-value

i

8 .5 1 9 6

14

.0 2 7 0

i

5 .0272

t-value

2

.0 9 3 2

9 .5 9 5 1

15

.0 2 3 2

4 .1 0 4 4

3

.0 8 6 1

1 1 .0 7 3 1

16

.0 1 9 7

3 .3 9 3 2

4

.0 7 9 4

1 3 .2 0 8 0

17

.0 1 6 6

2 .8 2 9 1

5

.0 7 2 9

1 6 .4 7 5 1

18

.0 1 3 6

2 .3 7 1 2

6

.0 6 6 7

2 1 .6 7 0 9

19

.0 1 1 0

1 .9 9 2 3

7

.0 6 0 8

2 8 .6 4 7 7

20

.0 0 8 6

1 .6 7 3 7

8

.0 5 5 2

2 9 .5 4 6 7

21

.0 0 6 5

1 .4 0 2 3

9

.0 4 9 8

2 1 .5 1 0 8

22

.0 0 4 6

1 .1 6 8 2

10

.0 4 4 7

1 4 .7 5 5 7

23

.0 0 3 1

0 .9 6 4 3

11

.0 3 9 8

1 0 .6 1 7 3

24

.0 0 1 8

0 .7 8 5 2

12

.0 3 5 3

8 .0147

25

.0 0 0 8

0 .6 2 6 6

13

.0 3 1 0

6 .2 6 8 2

C o n sta n t

2 .4 1 1 1

2 5 .8 9 5 7

r 2 =

The first two terms on the right determine the equilib­
rium interest rate (r e t ) . The real-balances term yields the
deviation o f real market rates from equilibrium, and the
last term captures the price expectation effect.
Quarterly data were used, and real GNP served to
measure real output. The annual rate of change of the
GNP deflator was used to measure price movements and
also to deflate the quarterly changes in the stock of
money. Table IV compares these results with the earlier
regressions which included only prices as arguments.
The first set of regressions in Table IV apparently
has not overstated the total effect of price movements
on long-term interest rates, as the sums o f the “ j co­
efficients are unchanged in the more completely speci­
fied functions. Current and most recent price changes
apparently captured some of the effect of contem po­
raneous output and changes in real balances, however,
since the mean lag is more than twice as long in the
second set o f regressions.

.9006

which was estimated by the Almon lag technique, using
data for the period January 1961 to September 1969.
The series presented is the difference between the actual
Aaa yield in each month and the cumulated effect of
past prices, or
(2 )

L

L

49

2

rmt = mt —

i=l

There appears to be some merit in the more exten­
sive specifications. However, inclusion o f the additional
variables did not drastically alter the conclusions of the
original regressions. The mean lag, while longer, is still
much shorter than other studies have found. In addition,
the real market rates implied by each set of regressions
are very similar and suggest that price expectations
account for a great deal of the movement in nominal
rates since 1961.

•

a i+ iP ct-i

The “ i are the estimated coefficients in equation (1 )
above and Pct is the annual rate o f change of the con­
sumer price index:

Table
<

»

-

=

(

§

b

)

“

IV

-

SU M M AR Y O F R EG RESSIO N S
Notice that the constant ( ao) in equation
1 does not appear in equation 2. The esti­
mated coefficients
are presented in Table
II. Estimated coefficients for the short-term
interest rate are presented in Table III.

( Q u a rt e r ly d a ta , 1 9 6 1 - 6 9 )

rn L

Page 38



+

“ o

“ iP t

"t"

°2 P t—

1

a n + lP t-n

n

Further Tests of Sargent’s Results
The regressions presented so far at­
tempted to measure the effect o f price ex­
pectations by regressing nominal interest
rates on current and past prices only. Thus
the effects of all other factors affecting
nominal rates were averaged into the con­
stant term. This approach carries with it the
danger of misinterpretation, if the excluded
factors affect both the dependent and in­
cluded independent variables. T o test for
this possibility, Sargent’s approach of ex­
plicitly considering some of these other
factors was applied.

=

t
rt

Z a +
i= 0

m ean la g

<*

16

.8 0 3 1

3.1

3 .3 5 3 9

20

.7 9 8 8

3 .0

3 .3 5 8 9

.9 7 6 7

24

.7 9 3 4

3.1

3 .3762

.9 7 6 4

r n L z — P iY *

t

R2

-f- (32A Y *

t

-) -

p 3A M t

-J- ° 1Pt - j -

a2Pt— i

Pi

$2

t

.9 7 6 8

+

■ • • • + “ n : ] P ;—n

n

n

1

“ i+1

m ean la g

R2

i= 0
16

.7 8 5 1

8 .6

.0 0 5 8

.0 0 8 2

-.0 9 9 8

.9 7 3 6

20

.8 0 3 8

8.1

.0 0 5 6

.0 0 9 8

-.0 7 7 8

.9 7 4 4

24

.8 3 3 5

7 .7

.0 0 5 4

.0 0 9 1

— .0 6 7 4

.9 7 6 4

DECEMBER 1 9 6 9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

FEDERAL RESERVE SYSTEM ACTIONS
DURING 1969
Federal Reserve Credit
Annual Rates of Change

12/68
to
11/69 p.

12/67
to
12/68

8.3
5.1
- 2 .3
3.2
-1 .7

Federal Reserve Holdings of Government Securities
Federal Reserve Credit ___________________________
Monetary Base ________________________________
Reserves Available for Private Demand Deposits

7.4
10.2
7.8
6.5
7.0

p. - preliminary

Discount Rate (FRB St. Louis)
In effect January 1, 1969 _______________________ ______________________
April 4, 1969 __________________________
In effect December 15, 1969 ___________________
"

5%%
6

Reserve Requirements1
Percentage Required
Net Demand Deposits
_____ up to $5 Million
Reserve City Other MemBanks
ber Banks

16%
17
17

In effect Dec. 15, 1969

12
12%
12%

Net Demand Deposits
in Excess of $5 Million
Reserve City Other MemBanks
ber Banks

17
17%
17%

Time Deposits
up to $5 Million
Time Deposits
& Savings Peps, in excess of $5 mil.

12
13
13

3

6

3

6

M argin Requirements on Listed Stocks
80%
80%

In effect January 1, 1969 ------------------------------------------------------In effect December 15, 1969 _________________________________

Maxim um Interest Rates Payable on Time & Savings Deposits
Type of Deposit

Savings Deposits __________
Other Time deposits:
Multiple maturity:
90 days or m o re ___
Less than 90 days
Single maturity:
Less than $100,000
30-59 d a y s________
60-89 days________
90-179 days
180 days and over

In effect
Jan. 1, 1969

In effect
Dec. 15, 1969

4%

4%

5
4

5
4

5
5%
5%

5
5%
5%

6

6

6Vi

6Yi

'Beginning October 16, 1969, a member bank is required under Regulation M to maintain, against its foreign
branch deposits, a reserve equal to 10 per cent of the amount by which (1 ) net balances due to, and cer­
tain assets purchased by, such branches from the bank’s domestic offices, and (2 ) credit extended by such
branches to U. S. residents exceed certain specified base amounts. Regulation D imposes a similar 10 per cent
reserve requirement on borrowings by domestic offices of a member bank from foreign banks, except that only
a 3 per cent reserve is required against such borrowings that do not exceed a specified base amount.




Page 39

REVIEW IN D E X — 1969
Month
o f Issue

Title o f Article

Jan.

Saving Flows in the Current Expansion
Growth — Metropolitan vs. Nonmetropolitan
Areas in the Central Mississippi Valley

Feb.

Stabilization Policy and Inflation
Operations of the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis — 1968
International Monetary Reform and the ^Crawling P eg”

Mar.

Restraining Inflation
Relations Among Monetary Aggregates
A Program of Budget Restraint
The Relation Between Prices and Employment:
Two Views
Farm Income Prospects

A pr.

Monetary Actions, Credit Flows and Inflation
Monetary & Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their
Relative Importance in Economic Stabiliza­
tion — Comment
— Reply
Towards A Rational Exchange Policy: Some
Reflections on the British Experience
M ember Bank Income — 1968

Month
o f Issue

Title o f Article

July

Credit Flows and Recent Interest Rate Trends
An Explanation of Federal Reserve Actions
(1933-68)
International Monetary Reform and the Crawl­
ing Peg’ ’ — Comment
— Reply

Aug.

Inflation Continues
The Influence of Economic Activity on the
Money Stock —
Comments on the “ St. Louis Position”
Reply
Additional Empirical Evidence on the
Reverse-Causation Argument
M eat Prices

Sept.

Adjustment of D em and Deposit Series
Stabilization Actions in 1969 — How Much
Restraint?
Controlling Inflation
A Historical Analysis of the Credit Crunch of 1966

Oct.

Recent Interest Rate Developments
Revision of the Money Supply Series
Elements of Money Stock Determination

May

Restraining the Growth of Total Spending
Federal Open M arket Committee Decisions in
1968
— A Year of Watchful Waiting
Controlling Money

N ov.

Progress in Controlling Inflation
Monetary and Fiscal Influences on Economic
Activity — The Historical Evidence
The Effects of Inflation (1960-68)

June

Real Growth and Prices
Monetary Policy and Inflation
The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates, 1969

Dec.

1969 — Battle Against Inflation
Selective Credit — No Substitute fo r Monetary
Restraint
Interest Rates and Price L evel Changes, 1952-69
Federal Reserve System Actions During 1969
R eview Index — 1969


Page 40