View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

CO

o
GO
O
August/September 1980
Vol. 62, No. 7

CD

QQ

CD
CD
CO
CD

CZ.

a5

TD

CD



2 The Russian Grain Embargo: Dubious Success
9 W hat Happened to the Economy in the
First Half of 1980?
16

Rise and Fall of Interest Rates

The Russian Grain Embargo:
Dubious Success
CLIFTON B. LUTTRELL

O
n January 4, 1980, the President announced an
embargo on grain exports to the Soviet Union in
response to the Soviet armed invasion of Afghanistan.
In announcing the embargo, the President reported:
“The 17 million tons of grain ordered by the Soviet
Union in excess of that amount which we are com­
mitted to sell under a five-year agreement will not be
delivered. This grain was not intended for human
consumption but was to be used for building up
Soviet livestock herds.
I am determined to minimize any adverse impact on
the American farmer from this action. The undeliv­
ered grain will be removed from the market through
storage and price support programs and through pur­
chases at market prices. We will also use increased
amounts of grain to alleviate hunger in poor countries
and for gasohol production here at home.
After consultation with other principal grain export­
ing nations, I am confident that they will not replace
these quantities of grain by additional shipments to
the Soviet Union.”1
Secretary of Commerce Philip M. Klutznick stated
that the embargo was imposed “in order to show the
1“Text of Carter Speech on Soviet Ties,” St. Louis Post Dis­
patch, January 6, 1980, p. 2E.

2


U.S.S.R. in tangible ways that aggression is costly
and will be met with firmness. . . . Thus it was de­
cided that action should be taken to cut off these
significant resources and to exert pressure on the
U.S.S.R. in this area to convince the Soviet leaders
to halt their aggression in Afghanistan and to dissuade
them from making new military thrusts in Pakistan
and Iran.”2

Expected Impact on Soviet Union
Prior to the embargo, Soviet consumption of grain
was projected to be 228 million metric tons (M M T)
for the July/June 1979-80 marketing year. This figure
was approximately 3 MMT less than the previous
year’s consumption due to the Soviet Union’s below
average grain crop in 1979-80. Of their projected
consumption, the Soviets planned to import 35 MMT.3
U.S. exports of grain to the Soviets in 1979-80 were
2Statement by Philip M. Klutznick, Secretary, U.S. Department
of Commerce, in U.S. Embargo of Food and Technology to
the Soviet Union, Hearings before the Subcommittee on Inter­
national Finance of the Committee on Banking, Housing, and
Urban Affairs, 96th Congress, 2 Sess. (Washington, D.C.:
Government Printing Office, 1980), p. 28.
3Klutznick, “Statement,” p. 31.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

expected to total 25 MMT, valued at about $2.3 billion
and equal to about 11.2 percent of Soviet grain con­
sumption for the year, considerably above the 4.8 per­
cent supplied in 1978-79.4
The embargo was designed to limit U.S. grain ex­
ports to the Soviet Union to 8 MMT, an amount to
which the U.S. was committed under the 1975 fiveyear grain sale agreement. Following the embargo,
USDA officials estimated that the Soviets would be
unable to import more than 22 MMT of grain from
all sources.5
The embargo was expected to have its chief effect
on livestock output and the consumption of animalderived foods rather than on human consumption of
grain. The U.S.S.R.’s dependence on U.S. grain re­
sulted from a Soviet decision to improve the people’s
diets. The Soviet Union had maintained a commit­
ment to increase domestic consumption of livestock
and poultry and had achieved a 25 percent increase
in meat production during the past decade.® President
Carter told Congress that the embargo could cause
Soviet meat consumption to drop by 20 percent.7 Vice
President Mondale expressed a similar view: “We
estimate they w ill have to liquidate substantial num­
bers of livestock. . . . W hile this does not affect nutri­
tion levels,” he added, “it w ill undermine the U.S.S.R.’s
objective of supplying high-protein meat to the
Soviet people.”8 Similarly, Secretary of Agriculture
Bergland reported, “it is possible the grain embargo,
if it forces large-scale livestock slaughter in the Soviet
Union, may result in long-term change in U.S.S.R.
diets.”9
Soon after the embargo, specific forecasts of its im­
pact on the Soviet livestock industry were made.
Based on the assumption that the Soviets would ob­
tain an increase in grain supplies of about 3 MMT from
non-U.S. origins in March-July 1980 and reduce their
stocks by 3 MMT, feed use of grain in the March-July
period was forecast at about 44 MMT, down from
a figure of 51 MMT that had been estimated prior to
4Statement by Dale E. Hathaway, Under Secretary for Interna­
tional Affairs and Commodity Programs, U.S. Department of
Agriculture, in U.S„ Embargo of Food and Technology to the
Soviet Union, p. 54.
5Hathaway, “Statement,” p. 53.
6Ibid.
7Irwin Ross, “Who Broke the Grain Embargo?” Fortune (Au­
gust 11, 1980), p. 125.

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

the embargo.10 The 7 MMT March-July cutback
would reduce the intended 128 MMT level of feeding
for the entire 1980 calendar year by 5 percent.
The USDA reported that the cutback in grain avail­
ability for 1980 could reduce U.S.S.R. meat produc­
tion by approximately one million tons. This reduc­
tion represents a cutback of about 7 percent in U.S.S.R.
meat production, which currently totals about 15 mil­
lion tons annually. The expected cutback would be
somewhat greater than indicated by the 5 percent re­
duction in grain, because the imported grain was fed
mainly to hogs and poultry, which have a relatively
high grain-to-meat conversion rate.11 If, as a result of
the feed shortage, the Soviets would decide to liqui­
date herds by increasing current slaughter, they could
defer the cutback in meat production until later in
the year.

Expected Impact on Crain Trade
The embargo has been in effect long enough to
measure its effectiveness in restraining U.S. grain ex­
ports and reducing Soviet grain imports. One way
is to compare the USDA forecasts of U.S. exports and
Soviet imports made immediately prior to the embargo
with forecasts made following the embargo.
As shown in table 1, a summary of the forecasts
from December 1979 through mid-1980 indicates that,
initially, the embargo was expected to have a major
impact on Russian grain supplies. However, subse­
quent revisions indicate that the embargo’s impact
was much less pronounced than originally expected.
For example, in December 1979, net Soviet imports
for the July-June 1979-80 year were estimated at 33.2
MMT. Immediately following the embargo, the Janu­
ary 15, 1980 forecast of imports was reduced sharply
to 24.4 MMT, or 27 percent less than the pre-embargo
total. In succeeding months, however, the estimates
were revised upward until the June estimate of 30.4
MMT was only 2.8 MMT or 8 percent less than the
pre-embargo estimate. The June estimate indicated
that the overall Soviet grain supplies (excluding
changes in stocks) would be down only 1.3 percent
from the pre-embargo forecast.
The pre-embargo supply of grain for livestock feed­
ing for 1979-80 in the U.S.S.R. was estimated at 128
MMT. This estimate was reduced to 122 MMT, down

8Daily Report for Executives (Washington, D.C.: The Bureau
of National Affairs Inc., January 7, 1980), p. L-5.

10Foreign Agriculture Circular (Washington, D.C.: U.S. De­
partment of Agriculture, January 15, 1980), p. 2.

9Ibid.

lxIbid.




3

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

Table 1

U SD A Estimates of Russian Grain Supplies, Utilization for
1978-79, and Forecasts for 1979-80 (Million Metric Tons)
July-June
estimates for

Production

Imports (net)

Production
plus imports

Feed
utilizatior

1978-79

237

12.8

249.8

125

33.2

212.2

128

24.4

203.4

122

Forecasts for
1979-80 as of:
12/11/79

179

1/15/80

179

2/11/80

179

27.5

206.5

125
126

•

3/10/80

179

29.7

208.7

4/10/80

179

29.7

208.7

126

5/09/80

179

29.7

208.7

126

6/11/80

179

30.4

209.4

126

Source: Foreign Agriculture Circular (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture).

5 percent, immediately following the embargo. By
June, however, the estimate was raised to 126 MMT,
only 2 percent below the pre-embargo level. The re­
vised estimates of grain for livestock feed were not
based on revisions in estimated production. Produc­
tion estimates remained unchanged at 179 MMT
throughout the period from December 1979 to June
1980. W hile the tight grain supplies in the Soviet
Union resulted in a slower growth of herds and flocks
than was expected earlier, there was no evidence of
liquidation of breeding animals.
Estimates of total United States exports likewise
indicated that the impact of the grain embargo was
declining each succeeding month. January-February
1980 estimates of total U.S. exports of feed grains,
soybeans, and wheat for the marketing year 1979-80
were well below the December 1979 estimates (table
2 ). For example, estimated exports of feed grain for
the 1979-80 marketing year were reduced from 71.1
MMT in December 1979 to 65.9 MMT in JanuaryFebruary 1980, and wheat estimates were reduced
from 1,400 to 1,325 million bushels. By July, however,
these estimates had been revised upward so that they
closely approximated the pre-embargo levels. Corn
exports, estimated at 2,400 million bushels, were some­
what less than the pre-embargo estimate, but the July
estimate of 71.1 MMT for all feed grains was equal
to the pre-embargo estimate. The July estimate for
wheat, at 1,375 million bushels, was only 25 million
bushels less than the pre-embargo estimate.

4


Impact on Grain Prices
Grain prices in the U.S. declined sharply immedi­
ately after the announcement of the embargo, reflect­
ing the expected decline in export demand for grain
(chart 1). The price of cash wheat declined 9 per­
cent, from $4.39 per bushel on January 4, 1980 to
a low of $4.01 per bushel on January 10. Cash com
dropped 10 percent, from $2.56 to $2.30 per bushel,
and other feed grains declined by similar amounts.
Following the low point on January 10, most grain
prices rose rapidly and regained their pre-embargo
levels within less than a month. By February 1, the
price of corn was more than 2 percent above its pre­
embargo level, at $2.62 per bushel, and the price of
wheat, at $4.45 per bushel, was also above its pre­
embargo level.
W hile government purchases of both the contracts
for grain sales to the Soviet Union and cash grain
may have been a factor in the domestic grain price
recovery, such copious supplies often tend to suppress
prices. Furthermore, by July, the government had
resold export rights to 95 percent of the 352 million
bushels of corn that it acquired as a result of the
embargo.12
Monthly movements in grain prices in other non­
socialist nations indicated that a decline in world
v2Farmers Newsletter (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of
Agriculture, August 1980/F-14).

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

Table 2

Estimated U.S. Grain Exports for 1979-80*
Estimate

Feed grains
(mil. metric tons)

Corn
(mil. bu.)

Soybean
(mil. bu.)

Wheat
(mil. bu.)

December 1979

71.1

2,500

825

1,400

JanuaryFebruary 1980

65.9

2,275

815

1,325

March

65.9

2,275

815

1,325

April

69.1

2,400

820

1,325

May

71.0

2,400

820

1,350

June

71.0

2,400

825

1,375

July

71.1

2,400

850

1,375

•Marketing year began October 1 for feed grain and com, September 1 for soybeans, and
June 1 for wheat.
Source: Agricultural Outlook (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture).

grain supplies was expected following the embargo.
Apparently, these nations thought that the 17 MMT
of grain withheld from the Soviets would be withheld
from world markets. By February and March, how­
ever, this expectation was reversed as indicated by
grain price movements in some major market centers.
For example, Canada feed no. 1 rose from $4.40 per

hundred weight (cw t) in December 1979 to $4.51 in
January 1980 and declined to $4.31 in March 1980
(table 3). Similarly, Rotterdam pellets (a livestock
feed) rose in January (following the embargo) and
then declined in February. By February, estimates of
a large U.S. wheat crop were coming in and wheat
prices declined on a month-to-month basis.

C hart I

Specified Farm C o m m o d ity Prices: Before, D urin g, a n d A fter E m b a rgo

JA N U A R Y

FEBRUARY

MARCH

1980
Note: D a ta plotted for perio d s when the market w a s open.




Source: W a ll Street Journal

5

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

Table 3

Prices of Grain in Specified Markets (in U.S.
Dollars at Current Exchange Rates)*
1979-80
December

January

February

March
$2.80

U.S. No. 2 Yellow corn, $ per bu.

$2.93

$2.69

$2.89

Canada feed No. 1, $ per cwt.

4.40

4.51

4.35

4.31

Rotterdam pellets, $ per cwt.

7.71

8.21

7.85

7.17

•All exchange rates are monthly averages.
Source: FAO Monthly Bulletin of Statistics (Rome, Italy: Food and Agriculture Organiza­
tion of the United Nations, May, 1980), vol. 3.

Doubts Expressed About Effectiveness
of Embargo
Opposition in the U.S. to the embargo developed
shortly after its announcement. The Senate Subcom­
mittee on International Finance of the Committee on
Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs began hearings
in late January to “consider whether the embargoes
are an effective means of making the Russians pay
a price for their invasion of Afghanistan, their effect
on the U.S. economy, and prospects for a positive
effect upon Russian behavior. . . ”13 The American
Farm Bureau, while favoring stiff sanctions for the
Soviets, expressed doubt during the hearings that the
embargo would reduce Russian meat production by
more than 3 percent.

Patterns of Trade Changed

grains and wheat are produced throughout much of
the world, and the destination points of American
grain offer little information as to the ultimate avail­
ability of the shipment or of substitute grains to the
Russians. Any nation willing to supply more grain to
Russia and less to other nations (which, in turn, pur­
chase U.S. grain as replacement) would nullify the
embargo. Such nations would not have to be net
exporters of grain. Net importers who would be w ill­
ing to purchase more U.S. grain while simultaneously
selling their own grain to the Soviets would reduce the
effectiveness of the embargo as much as would net
exporters who increase their sales of grain to the
Soviets.
If the embargo was effective, it would result in two
prices for grain in the international market. A rela­
tively low price would prevail among those nations
that cooperate with the U.S. and deny exports to the
Soviets, and another higher price would prevail for
the Soviets and those nations that sell grain to them.
As Robert Gilpin points out, the Soviets can easily
switch their purchases of grain to countries that have
the incentive to arbitrage the two price situations.14

W hile the embargo reduced direct shipments of
grain from the U.S. to the Soviets, it did not succeed
in greatly reducing the availability of grain to the
Russians. Grain is a highly fungible commodity. Not
only can one carload be replaced by another carload,
but one type of feed grain can be substituted for an­
other. Even wheat, which is largely used for human
food, can be substituted for feed grain with relatively
moderate losses in value. Furthermore, most animal
feeds are to some extent substitutes. Hence, tracing
the flow of American grain through various commer­
cial channels to make certain that the embargoed
grain or substitute feed would not ultimately reach
the Soviets would be virtually impossible. Most feed

Although there is insufficient evidence to determine
which nations permitted increased grain shipments to
the Soviets following the embargo, the available data
indicate certain unusual patterns of trade. Table
4 shows a number of countries that sharply increased
grain imports from the U.S. in the first four months
of 1980, compared with the first four months of other
recent years. For example, the Democratic Republic

13Statement by Senator Adlai E. Stevenson, Chairman of The
Subcommittee on International Finance, in U.S. Embargo of
Food and Technology to the Soviet Union, p. 1.

14Statement by Professor Robert Gilpin Princeton University,
in U.S. Embargo of Food and Technology to the Soviet
Union, p. 184.

6



F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

AU G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

Table 4

Estimated January-April Imports of Feed Grains by Selected Countries
(Thousands of Metric Tons)
COUNTRY

1975

1976

1977

1978

1979

1980

Brazil

N.A.

N.A.

0

0

79.6

308.8

1,221.0

1,458.0

Democratic Republic, Germany

N.A.

N.A.

Poland

410.0

849.0

403.2

500.7

341.9

756.0

U.S.S.R.

519.0

4,584.0

1,606.1

4,159.0

1,857.6

2,303.0

Federal Republic, Germany

1,399.3

813.0

376.8

642.6

106.5

98.4

236.0

1,175.5

Spain

1,435.0

849.0

648.7

907.0

871.8

1,649.5

Other

9,707.0

8,397.0

10,383.8

10,060.2

13,226.9

15,152.6

14,369.0

16,635.0

14,924.1

16,777.6

17,579.9

24,113.9

All nations

Source: Foreign Agricultural Trade of the United States (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Agriculture), supplemented
by verbal communications with USDA staff.

of Germany, which had not previously been a major
importer of U.S. grain, suddenly became a major im­
porter in 1980. Other major grain producing nations,
such as Argentina, could have sold less grain to other
grain importing countries and sold a larger portion of
their grain to the Soviets. In effect, this action would
allow the Soviets to import Argentine grain, for ex­
ample, as a substitute for U.S. grain. The data suggest
that a world market for grain continued to function,
but through new channels of trade, following the
embargo’s impediment to established channels.

creasing the grain handling and shipping costs. For
example, part of the grain which ultimately reached
the Soviet Union was shipped initially through nonSoviet ports before finally entering the Soviet Union;
in these cases, this additional step increased shipping
costs and commissions for handling the grain. Both
the grain consumer and the producer pay for such
inefficiencies. Consequently, the U.S. farmer obtained
a somewhat lower price for his grain and the Soviets
paid somewhat more for their food and feed as a
result of the embargo.

Concept of World Grain Market Ignored

SUMMARY

The embargo’s major weakness was its failure to
recognize the fact that there is a world commercial
grain market that continues to function despite gov­
ernment controls and despite trading between govern­
ments that often ignores the market price. Since grain
continues to move from areas where grain prices are
relatively low to areas where prices are relatively high,
the only sure w ay of enforcing a grain embargo on
the Soviets would have been to obtain guarantees
from each nation that it would not export more grain
to the Soviets (produced either in the U.S. or locally)
than it would have exported without the embargo.

Although the embargo on grain sales to the Soviets
was designed with the best of intentions, it had only
a negligible impact on Soviet grain supply and on
total U.S. grain exports. Estimates of the Soviet grain
supply for the year ending in June were only one
percent less than the pre-embargo forecasts. Estimates
of U.S. grain exports were reduced sharply immedi­
ately following the embargo, but rose very soon after
it was announced and, by July of this year, were ap­
proximately the same as the pre-embargo estimates.

The apparent failure of the U.S. grain embargo to
achieve its stated objective does not mean that it
had no impact on U.S. farm income or on the cost of
grain to the Soviets. It undoubtedly had some impact
on both. It interrupted the efficiency of the market
channels from the U.S. to the Soviet Union, thus in­



Domestic prices for grain declined sharply immedi­
ately following the embargo, but regained most of the
loss by early February. The embargo apparently al­
tered world patterns of grain trade, as evidenced by
the sharp increase in imports of U.S. grain by some
nations following the embargo. Hence, there is evi­
dence that large quantities of U.S. grain were shipped
to nations which normally purchase grain from other
7

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

sources, thereby permitting these sources to supply
grain to the Soviet Union.
Nevertheless, the embargo did have an impact on
both the Soviets and the U.S. in that it resulted in

8




A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

less efficient patterns of trade and less efficient means
of marketing. These inefficiencies increased somewhat
the cost of food and feed to the Soviets and reduced
somewhat the returns to U.S. farmers.

W hat Happened to the Economy
in the First Half of 1980?
ALBERT E. BURGER

T

A HE U.S. economy was subjected to severe strains
during the first half of 1980. Beginning in the fall
of 1979, the growth of the money stock (M 1B )
slowed substantially and then declined sharply for
three months in early 1980. The price of oil was
raised substantially late in 1979, and a major selec­
tive credit restraint program was introduced early in
1980. Prices rose sharply, and the long-expected re­
cession occurred with severe effects on specific sec­
tors of the economy, such as autos and housing. In
the space of a few months, interest rates soared to
record high levels and then plunged as quickly. As
market interest rates climbed above Regulation Q
ceiling rates and rates set by state usury laws, finan­
cial institutions experienced difficulties in holding and
acquiring funds and, hence, in performing their tra­
ditional roles in the financial system.
W hen major economic developments occur so rap­
idly, it is difficult to isolate the basic forces that are
driving the economy. Explanations that seem reason­
able one week are apparently negated by develop­
ments that occur a few weeks later. Now that the
first half of 1980 is history, it is possible to present
a coherent explanation of economic developments that
arose during this period, especially in regard to the
role of monetary actions.



Such an explanation requires more than a simple
listing of economic events; it demands a framework of
analysis that ties diverse economic events together
and relates them to policy actions. The first section
of this article presents such a framework.

A FRAMEWORK OF ANALYSIS
The analytical framework presented in this section
relates inflation and changes in the growth of real
output to monetary developments. To explain eco­
nomic events that have occurred thus far in 1980 as
simply as possible, the analysis is presented in sum­
mary form and various relationships are illustrated
through the use of charts and tables.

Money and Inflation
Inflation refers to persistent increases in prices.
Prices denote the rate of exchange between money
and various goods and services. Consequently, an
analysis of inflation must consider the rate of growth
of ( 1 ) the amount of money available to the public,
(2) the amount of money the public is willing to
hold relative to total spending, and (3) the amount
of goods and services available to the public (real
output). The long-run or trend growth of real out­
9

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

C h a ri 1

Influence of M o n e y on Prices

60
1956

1958

1960

1962

1964

1966

1968

1970

1972

1974

1976

1978

1980

•Data p rio r to 1959 are M l.
P ercentages are a n nu a l rate* of change for p erio d s indicated.
Sh ad ed areas represent periods of business recessions.
Latest data plotted: 2n d quarter

put is determined by such factors as the growth and
quality of the labor force, capital formation, technol­
ogy, availability of natural resources, etc. This trend
rate of growth in real output is essentially unaffected
by monetary developments.1
The trend rate of price increases, for a given growth
of real output, depends on the rate of growth of the
money stock and the willingness of the public to hold
money relative to growth in total spending. Conse­
quently, inflation is frequently referred to as a mone­
tary phenomenon. If the rate of growth of the stock
of money exceeds the rate at which individuals are
willing to increase their holdings of money, they will
attempt to eliminate their excess money balances,
and prices w ill be driven up. In the United States,
the long-run or persistent rate of increase in prices
has approximated the trend rate of growth of the
money stock, as shown in chart 1. W hen the money
stock increased at less than a 2 percent rate for a
'As the rate of inflation has risen rapidly, relative to past U.S.
experience, the complete independence of the trend growth of
real output and growth of money has been called into ques­
tion. See Keith M. Carlson, “Money, Inflation, and Economic
Growth: Some Updated Reduced Form Results and Their
Implications,” this Review (April 1980), pp. 13-19.

10




prolonged period, as from the middle 1950s to the
early 1960s, inflation rose at less than a 2 percent
rate. W hen the trend growth of money moved up­
ward, so did inflation. Since the early 1960s, the longrun average rate of increase in prices has slowed only
once — from early 1973 through 1977 — when the
trend rate of money growth also slowed.
Viewing inflation in this long-term monetary con­
text provides a consistent explanation of the average
rate of inflation over the past nine years. From IV/70IV/79, money grew on average at a 6.7 percent an­
nual rate and inflation averaged 7 percent, as shown
in table 1.
However, examination of the data in table 1 reveals
sub-periods within the last nine years in which there
were wide differences between the growth of money
and inflation, including several periods in which
money growth slowed substantially while inflation
accelerated. These circumstances can be explained
within the framework of analysis by showing (1 )
connections between short-run variations in the
growth of money and the growth in real output,
and (2) the effects of supply-side shocks on the level
of prices.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

C ha rt 2

R a te s of C h a n g e of M o n e y Stock (M1B)
Percent

Percent

S h a d e d a r e a s re p re se n t p e r io d s of b u s in e s s r e c e ssio n s.
[1^T w o -q u a r te r rate o f c h a n g e ; d a t a p r io r to 3 r d q u a rte r 1 9 5 9 a r e M l.
[2 T w e n ty -q u a r t e r rate o f c h a n g e ; d a t a p r io r to 1st q u a r te r 1 9 6 4 a r e M l.
L a te st d a t a p lotted: 3 r d q u a r t e r

Table 1

Growth Rates of Money, Prices,
and Real Output
Real
output

Money

Prices

I/73

7.7%

4.6%

6.3%

I/7 3 -

I/74

5.3

8.2

0.0

I/7 4 -

I/75

3.7

11.6

-4.8

Period
IV /7 0 -

I/75 - III/76

5.5

5.4

5.9

III/76 - IV/78

8.1

7.1

5.0

IV /7 8 - III/79

8.5

9.1

0.6
-2.6

III/7 9 - II/80

2.9

9.4

III/ 79 -

I/80

5.6

8.9

1.6

I/8 0 - II/80

-2.3

10.6

-9.0

IV/70 - IV/79

6.7

7.0

3.3

ducers do not immediately adjust prices to changes
in the demand for goods and services that occur when
the public attempts to adjust the amount of money
held to the amount they desire to hold, given income
and interest rates. Consequently, real output bears
the initial brunt of the effects of the public’s adjust­
ments to a substantial change in the rate of growth
of their money holdings.
Fluctuations in short-run money growth relative to
trend money growth offer an abridged way of illus­
trating the severity of short-run monetary develop­
ments.2 Chart 2 depicts two-quarter growth rates of
money relative to a 20-quarter trend. In the past,
each time short-run money growth has fallen substan­
tially below trend, output has slowed substantially,
many times by an amount large enough to classify
that period as a recession.3 In addition, the accelera­
tion of short-run money growth typically provides a
temporary impetus to real output growth that moves
it above trend. For example, the short-run growth of

Money and Real Output
Although changes in the trend growth rate of
money have virtually no effect on the trend growth
of real output, short-run fluctuations in money growth
do affect the short-run growth in real output. Pro­



2For an alternative way of representing monetary acceleration
and deceleration, see William Poole, “The Relationship of
Monetary Deceleration to Business Cycle Peaks: Another Look
at the Evidence,” Journal of Finance (June 1975), pp. 697-712.
3Although not classified as a full recession, the 1966-67 period
has frequently been referred to as a mini-recession.

11

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

money was substantially above trend in 1977 and
1978, as shown in chart 2. Table 1 indicates that real
output grew by more than 5 percent during this pe­
riod, substantially more than any prevailing estimates
of the rate that could be maintained over a prolonged
period of time. The growth of real output eventually
had to return to the rate dictated by labor force
growth, capital formation, etc., even if the monetary
stimulus remained very strong.

Monetary Policy Objectives and
Growth of Money
The primary long-run objectives of monetary policy
are to avoid inflation and to encourage growth of real
output. When inflation is low and real output is
growing at what policymakers consider “an acceptable
rate,” these two objectives do not conflict. W hen real
output growth is “too low” or inflation “too high,”
however, these two goals can conflict especially in
the short run.
Real output growth can be temporarily accelerated
above its trend rate by increasing the degree of mone­
tary stimulus. However, if such a policy action is
maintained, greater inflation results, which violates
the other objective of monetary policy. On the other
hand, reducing inflation that is the result of past pol­
icy actions (the monetary rate of inflation) is a long­
term proposition requiring a reduction in the trend
growth of money. If policy actions sharply reduce
the growth of money in the short term, inflation is
not affected, but the growth of real output w ill de­
cline and the economy may slide into a recession.
Consequently, at times when either of the major pol­
icy goals is not being met, the Federal Reserve must
design its policy actions carefully and enforce them
consistently to avoid violating the other policy goal.

Supply-Side Effects, Real Output,
and Inflation
Growth of real output can drop suddenly and tem­
porarily for reasons unrelated to decelerated money
growth. Supply-side shocks, such as droughts, floods,
reduction in the supply of a basic factor input such
as oil, or an unexpected sharp rise in the relative price
of a factor input, can cause sharp declines in real
output.4 If money continues to grow at the same rate

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

that prevailed prior to the supply shock, prices must
rise. As the level of prices adjusts upward, inflation
soars above the rate dictated by the trend rate of
monetary expansion. However, unless the rate of
growth of money also accelerates, inflation returns to
the rate dictated by the trend growth of money, after
the level of prices has adjusted.
Since 1972, the major supply-side shocks affecting
the economy have resulted from developments in the
energy industry. The periodic sharp increases in
energy prices relative to output prices have reduced
the productivity of the existing capital stock and labor
and, hence, have reduced output. The consequences
have been periodic sharp rises in the level of prices
and reductions in the growth of real output, as oc­
curred in 1973-74 and 1979.®

Monetary Policy Objectives and
Supply-Side Effects
Since supply-side effects definitely influence the
measured growth of real output and inflation, they
can obscure the ongoing effects of monetary develop­
ments on these variables. During the transition pe­
riod in which the economy adjusts to supply-side
shocks, it is important to keep in mind what mone­
tary policy actions can and cannot do in relation to
real output and inflation. Monetary policy actions can
create more money; they cannot create more oil,
grain, cattle, or any other real good or service. The
sharp rise in the level of prices accompanying supplyside shocks simply reflects the w ay a market econ­
omy eliminates the shortage of any good. The surge
in prices does not represent a rise in the lasting rate
of inflation; that rate is still being determined by the
cumulative effects of past policy actions on the trend
growth of money. Once the level adjustment of prices
is completed, the measured rate of inflation slows.
This pattern of price movements does not reflect
monetary policy actions, but simply indicates that the
rate of increase of prices is returning to the rate dic­
tated by monetary expansion.6 Attempts to offset the
effects of supply-side shocks on real output by sharply
accelerating the growth of money only cause prices
to rise further.

5See Denis S. Kamosky, “The Link fletween Money and Prices
— 1971-76,” this Review (June 1976), pp. 17-23.
4See Robert H. Rasche and John A. Tatom, “The Effects of the
New Energy Regime and Economic Capacity, Production, and
Prices,” this Review (May 1977), pp. 2-12.
Digitized for 12
FRASER


6See Albert E. Rurger, “Is Inflation All Due to Money?” this
Review (December 1978), pp. 8-12.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U I S

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

C h a rt 3

R e la tiv e Price of E n e rg y *
Inde

barrel in December 1978 to $27.85 per barrel in May
1980. This increase is reflected in the sharp rise in
energy prices relative to output prices, as shown in
chart 3. This rise in the relative price of energy, which
was approximately the same as that in 1973-74, was
the primary cause of the drop in real output growth
from 4.8 percent in 1978 to 1 percent in 1979.7 Its
effects continued into 1980, constraining real output
growth to a 1 - 2 percent rate.
The impact of the sharp rise in energy prices was
not distributed equally across all sectors of the econ­
omy, but was most severe for those industries and
products which were heavy users of energy, such as
automobiles. As shown in chart 4, the relative price
of gasoline rose sharply from the end of 1978 through
1980. The retail price of gasoline rose from about 70
cents a gallon at the end of 1978 to $1.22 per gallon
7See Keith M. Carlson, “Explaining the Slowdown of 1979: A
Supply and Demand Approach,” this Review (October 1979),
pp. 15-22.

C h a rt 4

R e la tiv e Price o f G a s o lin e *

•The Produ cer Price In d ex of Fuels, Power, and Related Products d ivid e d by the Implicit Price Deflator for
the Private Business Sector.
Latest d ata olotted: 2 n d quarter

ANALYSIS OF THE FIRST HALF OF 1980
The two major forces affecting the economy in the
first half of 1980 were a major change in the growth
of the money stock and a continuation of the supplyside effects of increased energy prices. These two
forces both operated to depress real output growth.
The monetary developments had little initial effect on
reducing the basic monetary rate of inflation, while
developments in the energy markets served to raise
the level of prices and push the measured rate of
price increases considerably above the rate of infla­
tion dictated by the long-term growth in money.

Supply-Side Effects
In early 1980, as in 1979, real output growth con­
tinued to be restrained by the large ongoing rise in
the relative price of energy. The composite refiner
acquisition cost of crude oil rose from $12.93 per



• C onsu m e r P rice In d e x o f G a s o lin e d iv id e d b y the G N P Im plicit Price D e flato r
Latest d a ta plotted: 2 n d q uarter

13

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

in April 1980. For someone that owned an auto that
averaged 10-12 miles per gallon, this rise in the retail
price of gasoline increased his annual expenditure on
gasoline by about $700-$800. This development trig­
gered a general decrease in demand for autos and a
shift in preference toward more fuel-efficient imported
autos. Consequently, retail sales of domestically pro­
duced passenger cars fell dramatically from a rate of
about 9 million units at the end of 1978 to a rate of
about 7.5 million units at the end of 1979 and then
plummeted to a rate of 5.2 million units in May and
June of 1980.

Credit Market Developments
Housing was the other sector of the economy that
suffered most severely from developments in the first
half of 1980. Housing starts fell from an annual rate
of about 1.5 million units at the end of 1979 to an
annual rate of approximately 900,000 units in May
1980. The collapse in activity in this market was due
primarily to a sharp rise in mortgage costs and greatly
reduced availability of mortgage credit. For example,
mortgage rates rose from 10.5 percent in April 1979
to 12.9 percent in late 1979 and, finally, to 16.3 per­
cent in April 1980.
The demand for credit, especially short-term credit,
surged during the early months of 1980. In January
and February, for example, business loans at com­
mercial banks increased at a 24 percent rate, after
rising at only a 6.6 percent rate over the previous
three months. Part of this large increase in credit de­
mand resulted from anticipations of a program of
selective credit controls. Borrowing that would ordi­
narily have taken place later in the spring took place
early in the year, because potential borrowers were
uncertain about their ability to acquire funds at a
later date. Consequently, as the Federal Reserve
sought to constrain the resulting explosion in money
and credit, short-term interest rates soared upward by
3 to 4 percentage points in the span of about two
months. The rise in market interest rates resulted in
a rapid outflow of savings deposits, which forced sav­
ings and loans to hold and acquire deposits by issu­
ing money market certificates that bore much higher
interest rates than passbook savings. At the same time,
savings and loans were frequently constrained on the
mortgage rates they could charge due to ceilings set
by usury laws. The consequent sharp rise in mortgage
rates and reduced credit flow to the housing market
led to the severe drop in housing construction that
occurred in early 1980.
Digitized for14
FRASER


A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

Monetary Developments
Even if monetary stimulus had continued at the
rate that prevailed during most of 1979, the combined
effects of the adjustment of the economy to oil price
increases, the resulting special structural problems in
the auto industry, and the special credit market de­
velopments affecting housing would have resulted in
a decline in real output in the first half of 1980. How­
ever, the degree of monetary stimulus (as measured
by growth of money) did change substantially during
this period. In October 1979, the growth of M1B be­
gan slowing. From October 1979 to February 1980,
growth of M1B averaged about 6 percent, compared
to its 8.3 percent rate of growth over the first nine
months of 1979. If this reduction in the growth rate of
money had continued, it would have exerted a mod­
erate restraining effect on real output growth, adding
to the downward pressures being exerted by those
factors mentioned above.
Beginning in March of this year, however, mone­
tary stimulus moved from moderately restrictive to
very restrictive. For three months, March-May, the
money stock declined at an annual rate of approxi­
mately 5 percent. Chart 2 helps place this recent
reduction in money growth in historical perspective.
It shows that the slower than average money growth
from September through February was rapidly pull­
ing money growth in line with its trend rate. The fol­
lowing three-month decline in M1B, combined with
the previous slowing, plunged it far below its trend
rate. As shown in chart 2, when the growth of money
slowed so abruptly in the past, real output and em­
ployment likewise slowed substantially. In line with
this past experience, industrial production fell very
sharply after February, growth of employment came
to a halt and then declined sharply, and the unem­
ployment rate rose from about 6 percent early in the
year to 7.7 percent in May.

Was the First Half of 1980 Unique?
The events that took place in the first six months
of 1980 are not unique, but have become all-too-frequent occurrences. In many aspects, the period from
III/79-II/80 represents a compressed version of what
occurred in the 1973-74 period.8 In both periods, the
economy was forced to adjust to oil price shocks
that resulted in special problems for autos; at the
same time, soaring interest rates created special prob­
8See Norman N. Bowsher, “Two Stages to the Current Reces­
sion,” this Review (June 1975), pp. 2-8.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

lems for housing. Monetary developments were also
analogous in both periods, although they were some­
what more extended in 1973-74 than in the most re­
cent period. The behavior of real output, employment,
and prices was also strikingly similar in both periods.
Consequently, a brief comparison of what happened
recently to real output, employment, and prices with
what happened to these same variables in 1973-74
adds to our understanding of the economic events
that occurred in the first half of 1980.
Although real growth and employment slowed in
1973 and early 1974, these variables did not evidence
a sharp decline until monetary stimulus moved from
moderately restrictive to sharply restrictive (1/741/75). Prices also behaved similarly in both periods.
In 1973-74, as in the three-quarter period ended 11/80,
prices soared upward, even though the degree of
short-run monetary stimulus was markedly reduced.
The behavior of the economy in the first half of
1980 further illustrates that excessive short-run fluctu­
ations in the growth of money in either direction have
serious economic implications. In the situation that
prevailed from late 1976 through late 1979, sharp ac­
celerations in money growth increased the trend rate
of money growth and, hence, were inconsistent with
a policy objective of reducing inflation. Since late 1979,
a sharp deceleration in money growth, combined with
supply-side effects that adversely affected real output,
caused a severe slowdown in real output. Slow money
growth over the three-quarter period ending 11/80
reduced the trend growth of money (the 16- to 20quarter average) by only about 0.5 percent. Although
the monetary deceleration had only a minimal effect
on inflation, the effect on the growth of real out­
put was large. Consequently, economic events in the
last three quarters further support the proposition
that pronounced fluctuations of money growth are
inconsistent with a policy aimed at progressively re­
ducing inflation while minimizing the contractionary
effects on real output.

What W ill Happen Now?
Interpreting what happened to the economy after
1974 is helpful because it gives some indication of
what effects alternative monetary developments might
have on the economy. The recovery in real output that
began in 1975 did not require a very large monetary
stimulus. From 1/75 to 111/76, growth of M1B




A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

averaged 5.5 percent. Real output grew at a rapid
pace of 7.5 percent for a year, then slowed to a rate
of 3 percent, which was in line with the long-run
potential growth rate of real output. Growth of em­
ployment was renewed in early 1975 and the un­
employment rate began to decline, falling from a
peak rate of 9 percent in mid-1975 to 7.5 percent
by the end of 1976.
The sharp surge in the growth of money that
started in late 1976 stimulated a renewed growth of
real output that lasted through 1978, with real growth
averaging 4.6 percent. However, after 1978, con­
tinued monetary stimulus was no longer able to
sustain real growth above its long-run potential.
It is also instructive to note that the surge in in­
flation in 1973-74 that was caused by supply-side
shocks to the economy did not last. The economy
adjusted to a new higher level of prices, absorbing
the energy price increases. Since the growth of money
continued at a reduced rate, the rate of inflation fell
below a 6 percent rate and this rate was maintained
over the next year and a half. Only when the trend
rate of growth of money was substantially raised as
a result of the persistent 8 percent growth of money
that began in late 1976 did inflation again surge
upward.
Since May, there has been a very substantial in­
crease in the money stock, offsetting the sharp decline
that occurred earlier this year. Such a sharp reversal
in the degree of monetary stimulus should act to
correct the effects on real output of the earlier de­
cline in money. Consequently, the recent growth of
money is consistent with a policy objective of gradu­
ally reducing inflation subject to the constraint of
not inducing a deep and prolonged recession.
The recent rapid growth of money w ill become
inconsistent with both policy objectives if it is main­
tained for any prolonged period of time. Most econ­
omists expect real growth to remain slow for the
next few quarters, as the economy continues to ad­
just to oil price increases and as special structural
problems persist in the automobile and housing in­
dustries. Maintaining rapid money growth under these
circumstances w ill add little to real output growth,
but w ill erode the small gains that were made against
inflation as a result of the three-quarter reduction in
money growth from 111/79 to 11/80.

15

Rise and Fall of Interest Rates
NORMAN N. BOWSHER

M

ARKET interest rates have moved over a wide
range since mid-1979. In the last half of 1979 and in
the first three months of 1980, interest rates rose to
unprecedented levels. Rates on highest grade corpo­
rate bonds, for example, increased from 9.3 percent
in June 1979 to 13 percent in March 1980. Over the
same period, yields on 4-month prime commercial
paper jumped from 9.7 percent to 16.8 percent, while
the prime rate on business loans at large banks rose
from 11.5 percent in mid-1979 to 20 percent in early
April 1980.
Because credit and interest rates play a crucial role
in our economic system, the substantial rise in interest
rates had wide implications. Sales of residential hous­
ing, which are particularly sensitive to interest rate
movements due to the existence of usury rate ceilings
in many states, were sharply curtailed. For those busi­
ness activities that maintained operations, costs rose,
in some cases substantially. In fact, some analysts
believe that higher interest rates were a major cause
of recession.1 On the other hand, savers received rec­
ord high returns on funds lent.
1“A Carter Recession: How Soon, How Deep?” U.S. News and
World Report (March 31, 1980), pp. 23-29; “The Credit Vise
Tightens,’ Time (April 14, 1980), pp. 78-79; and “High In­
terest Rates Start to Hit Home,” U.S. News and World Report
(March 24, 1980), pp. 23-24.
Digitized for16
FRASER


A marked reversal has occurred in the financial mar­
kets since early April 1980. Highest grade corporate
bond yields decreased from 13 percent in March to
12 percent in September, and yields on commercial
paper fell from 16.8 percent to 10.9 percent. Large
banks lowered the rate charged on loans to prime
business customers from 20 percent in early April to
13 percent in late September.
Since the decline in interest rates occurred at a
time when the country was facing two serious domes­
tic economic problems — continued rapid inflation
and rising unemployment — there were disparate
opinions about its desirability. Some argued that the
lower interest rates would stimulate business and
consumer spending, while others contended that the
campaign to resist inflation and to defend the value
of the dollar internationally was being abandoned too
soon.2
This article attempts to place the recent fluctuations
in interest rate levels into perspective by discussing
both the function of interest rates and the economic
significance of their levels. In addition, it reviews re­
cent developments that impinge on interest rates.
2See “Inflation-Fighting Must Be No. 1 Priority Despite Deep­
ening Slump, Miller Insists,” Wall Street Journal, June 5, 1980,
p. 8.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

environment. It is the rate of interest that would be
observed if inflation was expected to be zero and if
there were no special differences (risk, tax advantages,
etc.,) among various credit transactions. During the
last century, the real rate of interest has generally
moved within a rather limited range.

F ig u r e 1
In t e r e s t ra te

Special terms and conditions accompanying the ex­
tension of credit w ill produce differences among
nominal interest rates. Differences in rates due to
this source reflect variations in financial risk, length
of loans, locality, costs of servicing, tax status, and a
variety of other factors.
Because of inflation and inflationary expectations,
the market rate of interest can differ considerably
from the real rate.4 This differential exists because
lenders seek to protect the purchasing power of funds
lent, and borrowers are willing to pay a higher rate
if they expect inflation to enable them to repay the
loan with cheaper dollars.
N o t e : T he d e m a n d (D) fo r lo a n fu n d s s h o w s th e a m o u n t of
lo a n s d e m a n d e d a t a lt e rn a tiv e p o t e n tia l in te re st rates.
T he s u p p ly (S) o f lo a n fu n d s s h o w s the a m o u n t of lo a n s
s u p p lie d a t v a r io u s ra te s o f in te re st. In e q u ilib riu m , a s
illu stra te d in the fig u r e , the a m o u n t of lo a n s w ill b e (LQ)
a n d the in te re st

Interest Rates

—

rate w ill b e (iQ).

Real and Nominal

The rate of interest, which represents the price paid
for the use of credit, reflects the interaction between
the supply of credit and the demand for credit ( figure
l ) . 3 The supply of credit arises from the willingness
of income-eamers to save, that is, to postpone con­
sumption in the immediate period. The demand for
credit arises from private business firms’ investment
demand (reflecting the marginal productivity of real
capital goods), consumers’ desire to borrow for con­
sumption purposes, and government borrowing to fi­
nance deficits.
Hundreds of different interest rates are quoted
simultaneously in financial markets. These nominal
(or m arket) interest rates, although different from
one another, consist of the same three components:
the “real” rate of interest, the expected rate of infla­
tion, and a composite of the additional factors which
differentiate one yield from another.
The real rate of interest is determined by the mar­
ginal productivity of capital in a “riskless” economic
3For a more extended discussion of interest rates, see Armen A.
Alchian and William R. Allen, University Economics (Bel­
mont, California: Wadsworth Publishing Company, 1972)
pp. 426-438.



For example, if borrowers and lenders anticipate a
9 percent inflation per year over the period of the
loan, they w ill incorporate this expectation in the
nominal rate of interest for the loan. Thus, if the real
interest rate is 3 percent, loans w ill be extended at
an annual nominal rate of 12 percent; that is, the 9
percent anticipated inflation w ill be added to the 3
percent real return.
Studies suggest that market participants tend to
extrapolate past experience to estimate future rates of
inflation. Although they place primary emphasis on
the most recent past, they will reach back several
years for evidence.5 Regardless of past experience,
however, a substantial change in monetary or fiscal
policy w ill alter expectations of future inflation.®
Charts 1 and 2 illustrate the relationship between
prices and market interest rates for the periods 19721980 and 1960-1980, respectively.
Most of the increase in market interest rates since
the mid-1960s resulted from rising inflationary expec­
tations. From 1959 to 1965, annual inflation, as meas­
ured by the GNP price deflator, averaged 1.5 percent.
4David H. Resler, “The Formation of Inflationary Expectations,”
this Review (April 1980), pp. 2-12. Also, see “Inflation’s Im­
pact on Borrowers and Lenders,” U.S. News and World Re­
port ( March 10, 1980), p. 28.
“See Irving Fischer, The Theory of Interest ( New York: Mac­
millan, 1930); and William P. Yohe and Denis S. Karnosky,
“Interest Rates and Price Level Changes 1952-69,” this Review
(December 1969), pp. 18-36.
8Charles Pigott, “Expectations, Money, and Forecasting of In­
flation,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Economic
Review (Spring 1980), pp. 30-49.

17

AU G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

C h a ri 1

In fla tio n a n d Short-T erm Interest R a te s
Parcel!

1972

P er c e n t

1973

1974

1975

197*

1977

1 97 1

1979

1980

Q .C o m po u n de d a n nu a l rates of chan ge of the consumer price index (seaso nally adjusted) over the
previous si* months. CPI for U rb an W a g e Earners an d Clerical W orkers.
[2 P rior to N o v e m b e r 1, 1979, rates a re for 4- to 6-m onth prim e com m ercial p a p e r; b e g in n in g
N o v e m b e r 1, 1979, rates a re for 4-m onth co m m e rcial p aper.
Latest d a ta plotted: A u g u st

If expectations of inflation were based closely on pre­
vious actual rates, the expected rate of inflation in
the mid-1960s was approximately 1.5 percent. In con­
trast, from 1973 to early 1980, the GNP price deflator
rose at nearly an 8 percent rate, and, in view of the
13 percent rates of increase in both consumer and pro­
ducer prices in the 18 months ending March 1980,
long-run inflationary expectations were probably in
the 9 to 10 percent range in early 1980. The accelera­
tion of price increases in late 1979 and early 1980 led
to even higher short-run inflationary expectations at
the end of March 1980.

Functions of Interest Rates
Interest rates serve a number of significant func­
tions. First, they provide investors with a guide for
allocating funds among investment opportunities. As
funds are directed into projects that have higher ex­
pected rates of return (risk and other factors taken
into account), the funds are optimally allocated from
the viewpoint of both consumer and investor, since
highest returns prevail where effective consumer de­
mand is strongest. Unless an investment opportunity
promises a return high enough to pay the market
rate of interest, it does not justify the required capital
Digitized for 18
FRASER


outlay. The money market, by channeling funds into
projects that have an expected return in excess of the
interest rate, provides a valuable service to investors,
borrowers, and society as a whole.
The interest rate also provides a measure of the
relative advantage of current consumption compared
to saving. By adjusting the available market rate for
expected inflation and taxes, an individual can deter­
mine the real amount of additional future consump­
tion that can be obtained by postponing current
consumption.
Similarly, interest rates help businessmen decide
among alternative production methods. Suppose a
product can be made either solely with labor or with
a combination of labor and machinery. By calculating
the capital cost of the machine (the interest rate
times the dollar amount invested in the machine),
the expected labor-plus-capital cost can be compared
with the labor-alone cost to determine the less ex­
pensive means of production.
Finally, interest rates that are free of legal restric­
tions can respond to changing demand/supply situa­
tions and, thus, contribute to economic resiliency and
high employment. If, for example, a government

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

A U G U ST /S E PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

C h a rt 2

Long Term B o n d Y ie ld s a n d Price C h a n g e s

Q_ A n n u a lly a v e r a g e d M o o d y 's S e a s o n e d A a a b o n d yie ld s.
12. R a te o f c h a n g e o f t h r e e -y e a r m o v in g a v e r a g e o f G N P d e fla t o r p la c e d on la st ye ar.
N o te : 1 9 8 0 d a t a a re a v e r a g e s o f first tw o q ua rte rs.

spending program is trimmed, the initial result w ill be
unemployment and idle factories. Everything else be­
ing equal, however, reduced government spending
w ill eventually lead to less government borrowing and
lower nominal interest rates. At these lower rates, more
funds w ill be demanded by the private sector, thus
generating increased private sector jobs.

Major Factors Influencing Interest Rates
As pointed out above, interest rates are determined
by the demand for and supply of credit, both of
which are affected by specific factors. As these factors
change, interest rates change accordingly. The more
important factors include saving, business and con­
sumer investment, monetary actions, government defi­
cits or surpluses, and income tax rates.
Saving is the source of credit and, consequently,
the amount of savings is one of the prime determi­
nants of the level of real interest rates. As saving in­
creases, downward pressure is exerted on interest
rates. Conversely, as individuals and businesses save
less, or actually dissave, upward pressure is exerted
on interest rates.
Financing business inventories and capital invest­
ment constitutes a major credit demand and, because



this demand is quite variable, it contributes materially
to changes in interest rates. W hen economic activity
is expanding and the outlook appears favorable, busi­
nesses aggressively seek more funds to finance addi­
tional production, plants, and equipment. On the
other hand, when sales are sluggish and the future
seems grim, investment plans are sharply curtailed
and the demand for credit falls.
Similarly, consumers demand a substantial amount
of credit to finance homes, automobiles, and other
durable goods as w ell as to increase current consump­
tion. This demand for credit also fluctuates widely as
business conditions and the economic outlook change
and, therefore, contributes significantly to interest
rate movements.
Governments can either supply credit by running
surpluses or demand credit to finance operating defi­
cits. Since federal government expenditures have ex­
ceeded receipts in every fiscal year since 1969, the
government has become a large demander of credit,
contributing to upward pressure on interest rates. In
contrast, the federal government operated at a surplus
during the mid-1920s and, despite expanding business
investment in that period, interest rates drifted lower
on balance.
19

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

Expansions or contractions in the stock of money,
for example, can temporarily influence real interest
rates and permanently affect nominal market rates.
If the Federal Reserve System expands the supply of
money and bank credit faster than borrowers and
lenders anticipate, the additional loan funds tempo­
rarily drive both market and real interest rates below
what they otherwise would have been. If rapid mone­
tary expansion continues, it will eventually be en­
tirely reflected in a higher rate of inflation and a
higher level of nominal interest rates.

and a 2% percentage point tax liability). Despite the
sharp rise in market rates to 14 percent in early 1980,
the after-tax real interest rate was lower than the mid1960 rate and even negative. Assuming inflationary
expectations of 9 percent per year and a tax bite
of 7 percentage points, the 14 percent market in­
terest rate implies a negative 2 percent after-tax
real return.9 As the demand to borrow increases and
the supply of credit falls, interest rates tend to surge
upward until the expected real rate is positive.

People make economic decisions by taking into ac­
count all available information that has a significant
bearing on the future consequences of their decisions.
Hence, in recent years, it is likely that investors and
savers began anticipating the longer-run impacts of
monetary actions on interest rates sooner than they
did in previous periods of marked and sustained
change in the growth of monetary aggregates.7

Analysis of Interest Rate Rise —
Late 1979, Early 1980

Income tax considerations also influence market in­
terest rates.8 Since borrowers are allowed to deduct
interest payments in computing taxable income, the
more relevant after-tax cost of funds is less than the
stated contract rate. Lenders must include interest
received as taxable income, making their after-tax re­
turn less than the contract rate. Therefore, income tax
causes market rates to be higher than they would be
otherwise. As market interest rates have increased in
recent years along with rising inflationary expecta­
tions, the absolute impact of taxes has also risen
greatly. An example w ill help clarify this fact.
Assume that federal and state income taxes have
placed both the borrower and the lender in the 50
percent marginal bracket. If, as in the early 1960s,
market rates were 5 percent, income taxes reduced
the return by 2.5 percentage points, leaving a 2.5
percent after-tax interest rate. More recently, as mar­
ket rates fluctuated around 14 percent, income taxes
reduced the return to 7 percent, leaving a 7 per­
cent after-tax yield.
In the mid-1960s, the after-tax real interest rate was
about 1 percent ( based on a market rate of 5 percent,
less assumed inflationary expectations of P /2 percent
7See “Rational Expectations — Fresh Ideas^ That Challenge
Some Established Views of Policy Making,” Federal Reserve
Rank of Minneapolis Annual Report 1977, pp. 1-13; and
Thomas J. Sargent, “A Classical Macroeconomic Model for
the United States,” Journal of Political Economy (April 1976),
pp. 207-37.
8John A. Tatom and James E. Turley, “Inflation and Taxes:
Disincentives for Capital Formation,” this Review (January
1978), pp. 2-8.

20



Market interest rates, although already high relative
to most previous periods in this century, rose sharply
from mid-1979 to early April 1980. For example, threemonth treasury bill yields averaged 5 percent in
1976, 5.3 percent in 1977, and 7.2 percent in 1978. By
June 1979, the yield was 9.1 percent but, by early
April 1980, it had jumped to 14.8 percent. Virtually
all other interest rates also recorded sharp increases
in the late 1979-early 1980 period, with the increase
being more pronounced for shorter-term than for
longer-term maturities. Many forces combined to drive
up yields.
Although personal income continued to rise in late
1979 and early 1980, personal saving declined substan­
tially in that period, placing strong upward pressure
on rates. In the first six months of 1979, personal sav­
ing grew at an $83 billion annual rate; in the last six
months of 1979, it declined to a $65 billion rate; and
in the first quarter of 1980, it again decreased to a $64
billion rate. This decline in personal saving occurred
for a number of reasons. Tax burdens rose more
sharply than income, and inflation rapidly increased
the cost of most consumer goods. W ith expectations
of future prices being revised upward, the incentive
to consume immediately was strengthened.
In this same period, investment in business plants,
equipment, and inventories and in residential struc­
tures increased slightly on balance, creating an addi­
tional small upward pressure on rates. In the aggre­
gate, gross private domestic investment inched up
from a $385 billion annual rate in the first half of
1979 to a $390 billion rate in the last half, and then
drifted to a $388 billion rate in the first quarter of
1980. Fixed business investment rose, but this was
9Tom Herman, “Even Today’s Steep Interest Rates Appear
Low if Taxes and Inflation Are Taken Into Account,” Wall
Street Journal, April 3, 1980, p. 40.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

largely offset by cutbacks in housing and in inventory
growth.
Both saving and investment decisions were heavily
influenced by accelerated inflation and inflationary
expectations. Consumer prices, for example, rose at
an average 4.3 percent annual rate from 1960 to 1977,
7.7 percent in 1978, 11.3 percent in 1979, and 18.1 per­
cent in the first quarter of 1980. The rates of increase
for producer prices were 3.9 percent, 7.8 percent, 10.9
percent, and 19.3 percent, respectively.
The marked increase in inflation during 1979 re­
flected both monetary and nonmonetary factors. From
the third quarter of 1976 to the third quarter of 1979,
the money stock rose at an average 8.3 percent annual
rate compared with a 5 percent rate in the previous
three years. This acceleration in monetary expansion
caused an increase in the trend rate of inflation. More­
over, strong forces pushed the current measured rate
of inflation considerably above the trend rate during
1979 and early 1980. Chief among these forces was a
substantial increase in the price of oil by OPEC,
which caused a major rise in the cost of energy and,
in turn, placed large cost-push pressures on many
other prices.
Federal government deficits increased in late 1979
and early 1980, placing further upward pressure on
rates. Deficits, as recorded in the national income ac­
counts budget, rose from an annual rate of $9.4 bil­
lion in the first half of 1979 to $12.7 billion in the
second half and to $22.9 billion in the first quarter
of 1980.

A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

denly began falling. The three-month Treasury bill
yield, which was 14.8 percent in early April, averaged
10.3 percent in September. Other rates followed a
similar course and, again, securities with the shortest
maturities showed the widest movement.
One of the chief underlying factors responsible for
this reversal was the lagged effects of the new mone­
tary policy that was announced in early October 1979.
This policy caused money to expand at a slower rate
and, initially, placed upward pressure on rates because
credit growth slowed. However, the secondary and
more powerful effects of this action offset its initial
impact after a few months.
One delayed result of supplying money to the mar­
ket at a gradually slower rate was a dampening of
economic activity. W ith less money being supplied,
relative to the demand to hold money, spending grad­
ually moderated. Nevertheless, credit demand con­
tinued strong for a time because consumers and busi­
nesses were uncertain about how long the pause in
spending would continue and how long the Federal
Reserve would continue to restrain money growth. As
sales, production, and employment began falling, de­
mand for business and consumer credit sharply
declined.

In early October 1979, the Federal Reserve an­
nounced that it would provide only enough money to
accommodate production at a gradually reduced rate
of inflation. The uncertainty about how this new
monetary policy would be implemented contributed
to higher market interest rates for a time. Previously,
from the third quarter of 1976 to the third quarter of
1979, money (M 1B ) had risen at an 8.3 percent an­
nual rate. Then, from the third quarter of 1979 to
the first quarter of 1980, money growth slowed to a
more moderate 5.6 percent pace. In March and April
1980, money actually contracted. The short-run impact
of the reduced money growth followed by the actual
decline in money was a reduced supply of credit,
which placed additional strong upward pressure on
interest rates.

Another result of the new monetary policy was its
delayed effect on inflationary expectations. Since the
rate of inflation is largely determined by the average
rate of growth of money over the previous five years,
the first few months of a new rate of money expan­
sion has little effect on the five-year average growth
trend and, hence, little effect on actual inflation. More­
over, since in the current situation there was uncer­
tainty as to how long the Federal Reserve would
maintain the more moderate money growth in view
of the rapidly rising interest rates and the expansion­
ary federal budget announced in January 1980, there
was little or no downward revision of future infla­
tionary expectations.10 The February to April 1980
money contraction, however, changed the situation
dramatically. Since market participants began to be­
lieve that significant steps were being taken to reduce
inflation (evidenced by the continued restraint on
money growth despite the business downturn and ex­
tremely high interest rates), future inflationary expec­
tations diminished.

Analysis of Interest Rate Decline —
After Early April 1980

In mid-March, the government imposed a number
of credit controls to restrain credit demand. Since
they applied to many new areas (e.g., credit cards

The financial “crunch” ended in early April 1980.
Interest rates, which had been rising sharply, sud­

10The Kiplinger Washington Letter, February 1, 1980.




21

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

and money market funds), they were poorly under­
stood. In addition, they were untimely because they
were imposed just after the economy began an eco­
nomic downturn. These controls, combined with other
developments, caused consumers to reduce credit de­
mands further which, in turn, contributed to the fall
of interest rates after early April 1980.
W ith inflation still intensifying and interest rates
rising in the first quarter of 1980, the Administration
and many members of Congress felt that it was man­
datory that the government follow a less expansive
fiscal policy and, consequently, efforts were made to
present a “balanced” budget. Although most analysts
still felt that expenditures would continue to exceed
receipts in fiscal 1980 and 1981, the concern of public
officials and their announced intentions to trim out­
lays contributed to a reduction in inflationary expec­
tations and in interest rates.11

Interest Rates as a Measurement of
Monetary Action
Market interest rate levels and movements have
been used as guides to monetary actions, particularly
by financial commentators and participants in money
and capital markets.12 High and rising market interest
rates generally reflect monetary restriction, whereas
low and declining rates indicate monetary ease. How­
ever, market interest rates may be rising while the real
rates are falling, and it is the real rates that are im­
portant in terms of economic activity. Expansions or
contractions of money and credit can force the real
interest rate, as w ell as the market rate, to rise and
fall, at least temporarily. Such changes in interest rates
influence the cost of investing and, hence, the course
of economic activity.
Notwithstanding, it is virtually impossible to iso­
late and interpret the effects of monetary actions on
market interest rates. Not only are investment deci­
11The Kiplinger Washington Letter, March 21, 1980.
12At times, the Federal Reserve System has also used interest
rates as a measure of monetary action. For example the 66th
Annual Report of the Board of Governors of the Federal Re­
serve System states that, “Monetary policy in 1979 sought to
curb inflationary pressures. . . . Early in the year, when . . .
incoming economic data provided some indications of soften­
ing in economic activity the Federal Reserve avoided meas­
ures that would have led to a marked rise in interest rates or
would have severely reduced the availability of credit. But
expenditures for goods and services strengthened as the year
progressed, in part because of heightened inflationary expec­
tations. Consequently, the System adopted a progressively
less accommodative stance, allowing the federal funds rate
to rise and increasing the discount rate in several steps.”
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System 66th An­
nual Report, 1979, p. 14.

22


A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

sions and saving/consumption choices (among other
factors that influence interest rates) in constant flux,
but monetary actions themselves have an ambiguous
impact on rates due to the various lagging effects of
these actions.13
If the stock of money is expanded unexpectedly, for
example, the supply of available funds is aug­
mented, real and nominal interest rates are initially
depressed, and the economy is thereby stimulated. If
the new course of rapid monetary expansion is con­
tinued for approximately a year, further stimulative
effects on total demand w ill occur. At the same time,
however, inflation and interest rates w ill also begin
to move upward. If the same rate of money injection
is followed for approximately five years, the effects of
this expansive monetary action will be fully reflected
throughout the economy. Interest rates w ill have
reached a level which exactly reflects the real rate
plus the long-run expected rate of inflation. Continu­
ation of the faster monetary growth would have no
further effects on real economic activity or the rate of
increase of the price level.
Since, at any one time, market interest rates reflect
the monetary actions taken over various past periods,
they have been a less reliable guide to monetary ac­
tions than rates of growth of the monetary aggre­
gates.14 More often than not over the past 60 years,
when monetary expansion has been relatively rapid
long enough to stimulate economic activity, interest
rates have risen rather than declined. The chief reason
is that inflation and inflationary expectations also in­
crease when monetary expansion is substantial enough
to drive the economy at a quicker pace. The greater
activity and the revised inflation outlook raise the
demand for credit even faster than the monetary ex­
pansion increases the supply. Similarly, when mone­
tary contraction is continued for more than a few
months, interest rates usually fall — not rise — since
the monetary contraction eventually causes an even
larger decline in credit demand by depressing total
nominal demand for goods and services.
From this analysis, it can be concluded that from
the third quarter of 1976 to the third quarter of 1979
monetary actions were expansive because money was
increasing at a relatively rapid rate. During this pe13Michael J. Hamburger, “The Lag in the Effect of Monetary
Policy: A Survey of Recent Literature,” Monetary Aggre­
gates and Monetary Policy, Federal Reserve Bank of New
York (October 1974), pp. 104-113.
11 William Poole, “Optimal Choice of Monetary Policy Instru­
ments in a Simple Stochastic Macro Model,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics (May 1970), pp. 197-216.

F E D E R A L R E S E R V E B A N K O F ST. L O U IS

riod, business activity increased and inflation inten­
sified in response to the monetary stimulus. The higher
interest rates reflected the greater economic activity
and rising inflationary expectations that the monetary
expansion fostered.
From the third quarter of 1979 to February 1980,
monetary actions, as measured by money growth,
gradually became less expansive. Since interest rates
rose in this period, the two measures of policy tempo­
rarily gave similar signals of restraint as they fre­
quently do around cyclical turning points in business
activity.
From February to June 1980, money contracted —
an indication that monetary actions were extremely
restrictive. Until early April, interest rates continued
to increase but then fell sharply, indicating to some
people that a shift toward monetary ease had oc­
curred. Business activity, however, declined sharply
and inflation slowed after the first quarter of 1980.
This decline in business activity and some downward
revision in inflationary expectations were largely re­
sponsible for the fall in market interest rates.

Conclusions
Market interest rates have been moving gradually
upward since 1976. One principal cause of the rise in
rates over the longer period was an upward revision
in inflationary expectations caused both by monetary
developments and by an increase in oil prices by the
international cartel. In addition, income tax implica­
tions for both borrower and lender and the continu­
ously heavy borrowing by the government to finance
operating deficits contributed to higher yields.




A U G U ST /SE PT E M B E R 1 9 8 0

From mid-1979 to the end of March 1980, interest
rates surged to unprecedentedly high levels. The main
reasons for this rise were the slowing of money growth
by the Fed, the acceleration in private borrowing
( perhaps in anticipation of credit control restrictions),
and the increase in government borrowing.
From September 1979 to June 1980, money (M1B)
expanded at an average 3 percent annual rate, down
from the rapid 8 percent average of the previous
three years. Such a marked and sustained slowing in
monetary growth temporarily placed strong upward
pressure on interest rates. As the effects of this slower
money growth were reflected in reduced spending and
as the public gained confidence that a slower growth
path for money might be continued, inflation and in­
flationary expectations began to recede. These devel­
opments, combined with the imposition of the credit
restraints, caused market rates to fall abruptly after
early April 1980.
A marked shift in monetary policy toward restraint,
such as the one that occurred from September 1979
to June 1980, has mixed implications for the economy
and future interest rates. On the one hand, the ex­
pected rate of inflation is reduced, at least temporarily.
In addition, economic activity is depressed much more
drastically during the transition to more stable prices
than it would be if money growth were slowed grad­
ually. This dramatic decline in economic activity
pushes down interest rates. On the other hand, the
lower sales, production, and employment during the
adjustment period increase the chances that high
monetary growth may be resumed and inflation may
accelerate in the future. This would lead to an in­
crease in interest rates.

23