View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
ST. LOUIS
AUGUST 1976
■#

I f ' ' . *?'

CO NTENTS
iST.




"

-

‘ v £

....

gggg®

7

ca
> n g ..............

...

\.

x

m

s®

I

Income and Expenses of Eighth District
Member Banks: 1975
JEAN M. LOVATI

J

jIG H T H District member banks experienced a
moderate increase in net income in 1975, a year of
recovery and restoration. The financial strength of
banks in the Eighth District generally improved dur­
ing the year. Capital cushions were built up and
debt was reduced.
In the early 1970s when demand for credit was
strong, many banks expanded their loans but fre­
quently showed little growth in their capital ac­
counts. Increased loan volume was accompanied, in
many cases, by a reduction in cash assets and high
grade short-term securities. However, in 1975 banks
began to reverse previous trends, emphasizing more
liquid instruments in their asset portfolios.
Net income of member banks in the Eighth Fed­
eral Reserve District rose 9 percent in 1975, slightly
less than the 10 percent increase experienced in 1974.1
A major factor accounting for this slower growth
was the smaller volume of loans held by member
banks. The effect on net income, however, was miti­
gated by lower interest expenses, which reflected
both a reduced volume of obligations of member
banks and lower average rates paid on them.
In general, Eighth District member banks fared
better than the average of all member banks. Net
income of all member banks in the nation rose 3.4
percent in 1975, less than half that for District mem­
ber banks. Primarily because of greater declines in
loan revenue, operating income of all member banks
fell nearly 5 percent, unlike that of District banks
which posted a slight gain. Operating expenses in
the aggregate dropped more rapidly than income
despite a 64 percent increase in loan loss provisions.
By contrast, expenses of District member banks showed
little change from 1974. The resulting income of all
member banks before securities gains and losses
increased 1.4 percent, slightly slower than that for
District member banks.
1Income and expense items in this article have been adjusted
to exclude one bank. Inclusion of this bank, which expe­
rienced unusual conditions, would have made the totals for
Eighth District member banks unrepresentative and com­
parisons less meaningful.


Page 2


OPERATING INCOME AND BANK ASSETS
Operating income of Eighth District member banks
totalled $1,581 million in 1975, an increase of less than
one percent over 1974 (see Table I). By comparison,
operating income in 1974 was 29 percent higher than
a year earlier. The smaller rise in income in 1975 was
the net result of several developments. A restraining
force was the 1.3 percent decrease in the volume of
loans held by member banks.2 The smaller volume,
combined with an average rate of return on loans
which remained essentially unchanged during the
year, resulted in a 2.3 percent decrease in bank
earnings on loans. A year earlier, this source of reve­
nue, which is a major portion of total operating
income, increased 29 percent.
The volume of total loans outstanding at member
banks in the District declined $149 million to $11.6
billion in 1975. Commercial and industrial loans, the
largest single category of loans, registered a 3.4 per­
cent decrease from 1974 — to $3.6 billion. Loans to
individuals posted a slight decline; outstanding
automobile installment loans fell by about 1 percent,
while consumer loans remained essentially unchanged.
While real estate loans held by Eighth District mem­
ber banks increased to $3.4 billion in 1975, a rise of
6.8 percent over a year earlier, loan movements were
mixed. Loans on one-to-four-family residences showed
a 10.3 percent increase, but loans on multi-family
property declined by 15 percent.
With the decline in loan volume and an increase
in other investments, loans outstanding of District
members banks, including Federal funds sold and
securities purchased under agreements to resell, ac­
counted for a smaller proportion of total assets in
1975 than in 1974. The share of total assets repre­
sented by loans declined about 2 percentage points
to 54.6 percent. The proportion of loans to total
assets was greater for larger banks than for smaller
banks, ranging from an average of 58.3 percent for
those banks with $100 million or more in deposits to
2AU comparisons of assets, liabilities, and capital in this
article are made as of December 31 of each year.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

AUGUST

1976

Table 1

IN C O M E A N D EXPENSES O F M EM BER B A N K S IN THE
EIGHTH FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICT*
Thousands of Dollars

Percent Change

1975

1974

1973

1974-75

1973-74

Total Operating Income ..................................................
Income from Loans ......................................................
Income from Federal Funds Sold and Securities
Purchased Under Resale Agreement ...........................
Income from Securities ______ __ ________________________
U.S. Treasury Securities ______ _________________ __ ..__
Other U.S. Government Securities ...............................
States and Political Subdivisions .................................
Other Securities .......................... ..........................
Trust Department Income .............................................
Service Charges on Deposit Accounts .............................
Other Operating Income .............................................

$1,581,249
952,675

$1,572,146
974,758

$1,222,821
755,395

0 .6 %
- 2.3

2 8 .6 %
29.0

96,318
344,156
119,096
79,443
138,706
6,911
30,936
31,917
125,247

148,736
292,321
101,020
67,878
117,551
5,872
27,756
30,099
98,475

85,155
257,575
104,116
49,701
97,545
6,213
27,566
27,896
69,233

-35.2
17.7
17.9
17.0
18.0
17.7
11.5
6.0
27.2

74.7
13.5
- 3.0
36.6
20.5
- 5.5
0.7
7.9
42.2

Total Operating Expenses ................................................
Interest on Deposits ....................................................
Other Interest Expenses ............................ ..................
Expense of Federal Funds Purchased and Securities
Sold Under Repurchase Agreement .............................
Salaries, W ages and Benefits ........................................
Provision for Loan Losses .............................................
Other Operating Expenses .......................... ................

1,344,475
610,381
6,443

1,339,036
585,241
13,895

1,006,079
423,456
9,656

0.4
4.3
-5 3.6

33.1
38.2
43.9

111,605
283,602
55,342
277,102

198,481
258,815
37,407
245,197

110,517
226,933
22,581
212,936

-43.8
9.6
47.9
13.0

79.6
14.0
65.7
15.2

Income Before Income Taxes and Securities Gains (or Losses) ...
Less Applicable Income Taxes ........................................

236,774
42,798

233,110
49,322

216,742
51,222

1.6
-13.2

7.6
- 3.7

Income Before Securities Gains (or Losses) ........................
Net Securities Gains (or Losses) After Taxes .................
Extra Charges or Credits After Taxes .............................
Less Minority Interest in Consolidated Subsidiaries ..........

1 93,976
888
2,389
21

183,787
- 2,252
- 119
- 11

165,520
211
- 738
20

5.5
—

11.0

Net Income .................................................

197,232

181,428

164,973

8.7

10.0

70,786

63,404

57,220

11.6

10.8

427

429

430

- 0.5

- 0.2

Cash Dividends Paid ...................................
Number of Banks .............................................

—

—

—

—

—

♦Income and expense items have been adjusted to exclude one bank . Inclusion of this bank would have made the resulting totals for Eighth
District member banks unrepresentative.

an average of 46.7 percent for those banks with less
than $5 million in deposits.3
The proportion of securities in the asset portfolios
of District member banks rose in 1975, emphasizing
the increased importance placed on more liquid
assets. The proportion of Treasury securities increased
2 percentage points to 8.7 percent of total assets, re­
versing the downward trend experienced since 1972.
Other securities, including obligations of U.S. Govern­
ment agencies and corporations and those of states
and political subdivisions, increased to 17.8 percent
from 16.7 percent of total assets.
3Averages for groups of banks presented in this article are
unweighted averages of individual banks’ operating ratios.
Balance sheet items used in constructing these ratios are
averages of the figures from the Reports of Condition of
December 1974 and June and December 1975. Where ap­
propriate, the bank referred to in footnote 1 has been
excluded.




Since there was little change in the average realized rates of return on securities, the increased
holdings resulted in an 18 percent increase in in­
come from this source. Earnings on all securities
totalled $344 million in 1975; this represented 22 per­
cent of total operating income, up from 19 percent
a year earlier. Holdings of U.S. Treasury securities,
which accounted for one-third of all investments,
rose 35 percent over 1974. The average rate of re­
turn on Treasury securities remained about 6.7 per­
cent in 1975.
Earnings from other securities also rose during the
year. Income from U.S. Government corporation
and agency securities grew 17 percent, due partly
to a 6 percent increase in volume and partly to an
increase in the average rate of return — from 6.3 to
6.8 percent. Similarly, earnings from obligations of
states and political subdivisions rose 18 percent over
Page 3

FEDERAL. RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

AUGUST

1976

in the previous year. Income from all other sources,
including other fees and service charges and interest
on time deposits at other banks, increased 27 per­
cent. These items, however, are relatively minor
sources of bank earnings.

Distribution of Assets
Eight h District M e m b e r B a n k s

OPERATING EXPENSES AND BANK
LIABILITIES
Total operating expenses of Eighth District mem­
ber banks showed little change in 1975, rising 0.4
percent to $1,334 million. This compares to a 33 per­
cent increase in 1974. Greater outlays for interest on
time and savings deposits, wages and salaries, and pro­
visions for loan losses were largely offset by smaller
outlays for borrowed funds.

in c lu d in g

F e d e r a l F u n d s s o ld

and

s e c u r it ie s p u r c h a s e d

u n d e r r e s a le

a gre e m e n t.

1974, with holdings increasing 6 percent and the
average rate of return rising 50 basis points to 4.8
percent. The income provided by these two types of
securities rose to 14 percent of total operating income
in 1975, compared to 12 percent a year earlier.
Income from Federal funds sold (overnight ad­
vances to other banks) and securities purchased
under resale agreements, which accounted for 6 per­
cent of member bank income, fell 35 percent in 1975.
This drop, amounting to $52 million, primarily re­
flected a decline in the Federal funds rate. In 1975
the rate averaged 5.8 percent, compared to 10.5 per­
cent in 1974.
Operating income of banks also includes income
from trust department operations. In 1975, earnings
from this source rose 11.5 percent. While it is a
relatively minor source of operating income for Dis­
trict member banks in the aggregate, contributing
an average of only about 0.6 percent, trust income of
banks with $100 million or more in deposits accounted
for an average of 2.5 percent of their total operating
income.
Earnings from service charges on deposit accounts
grew 6 percent over 1974, only slightly slower than

Page 4


Interest on time and savings deposits, which ac­
counted for 45 percent of member bank expenses,
totalled $610 million in 1975. This represents a 4
percent rise over 1974, compared to an increase of
38 percent a year earlier. The slower growth experi­
enced during the year can be attributed to the slower
growth of time and savings deposits coupled with the
relatively stable average rates paid on these funds.
Total time and savings deposits of District member
banks rose 11 percent in 1975 to $11.2 billion, com­
pared to an increase of 14 percent a year earlier.
The average interest rate paid on these deposits re­
mained essentially unchanged, at 5.7 percent. Sav­
ings deposits, which account for 31 percent of total
time and savings deposits, rose 19 percent over 1974.
Part of this increase may be attributed to a regula­
tory change introduced in 1975 which allowed cor­
porations to hold up to $150,000 in savings deposits.
Despite the slower growth of time and savings
deposits in 1975, the ratio of these deposits to total
liabilities continued to rise, emphasizing the shifting
composition of liabilities. The share of total liabili­
ties accounted for by time and savings deposits in­
creased 3 percentage points in 1975, to 49 percent.
Demand deposits, on the other hand, registered much
slower growth. IPC (individuals, partnerships, and
corporations) demand deposits rose 4.8 percent in
1975, while total demand deposits grew by 2.4 per­
cent. The share of total liabilities accounted for by
total demand deposits declined slightly to 40 percent
of bank liabilities.
Although the amount of interest paid on time and
savings deposits increased in 1975, other interest ex­
penses declined. The interest expense from Federal
funds purchased (funds borrowed from other banks)
and securities sold under repurchase agreements, for

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

AUGUST

1976

in loans, which had been written off earlier but were
recovered in 1975, and $7 million transferred from
capital accounts also contributed to increased re­
serves. Losses charged to these reserves in 1975
amounted to $61 million. On balance, reserves on
loans and securities increased 2 percent. In 1974, the
provision for loan loss reserves increased 66 percent
to $37 million, while losses charged against reserves
totalled $41 million.

Distribution of Liabilities, Reserves,
and Capital Accounts
Eig hth District M e m b e r B a n k s

Additional operating expenses registered increases
during the year. Salaries, wages, and fringe benefits,
a major portion of operating expenses, increased
about 10 percent to $284 million. The increase in
this category, which represents 21 percent of oper­
ating expenses, can be broken down into a 9 percent
increase in total wages and salaries paid and a 12 per­
cent increase in pensions and other employee benefits.
The number of officers and employees rose from
28,804 to 33,442 in 1975. Other operating expenses,
including occupancy, furniture, and equipment costs,
totalled $277 million, 13 percent higher than in 1974.

NET INCOME
1971

1972

1973

1974

1975

example, dropped 44 percent in 1975. This decline
reflects the lower level of interest rates charged for
these funds, as noted earlier. Interest expenses on
capital notes and debentures and other borrowed
money fell 54 percent during 1975. This is due in
part to a decrease in the amount of bank borrowing.
Liabilities for borrowed money, including Federal
funds purchased, fell by 14 percent.
Provision for loan losses is another item classified
as an operating expense. Banks maintain a reserve
fund for loan losses by charging to current earnings
an amount equal to the average of loan losses expe­
rienced over the past several years. In years when
loan losses are small compared to past experience,
provision for loan losses increases the reserve fund
available to absorb larger losses when they occur.
As losses are written off, they are charged against
this reserve instead of directly against current earn­
ings, allowing the loan loss reserve to absorb the
shock of unusual losses in a given year.
Reflecting the recession and uncertain financial cli­
mate, banks have made substantial increases in the
provisions for bad debts in the last two years. In
1975, the provision for loan losses increased 48 per­
cent over 1974, to $55 million. A total of $12 million



Before income taxes and securities gains or losses,
net income of Eighth District member banks totalled
$237 million in 1975, an increase of 1.6 percent over
1974. Income taxes of $43 million were paid, a 13
percent reduction from 1974. Securities gains and
other credits, net of taxes, materially boosted earn­
ings, contributing $3.3 million. After adjusting for
the net effect of taxes, securities gains, and extraor­
dinary items, net income of member banks increased
9 percent to $197 million in 1975.
Member banks paid cash dividends on common
and preferred stock of $71 million, a rise of 11.6 per­
cent over 1974. Cash dividends paid represented 36
percent of net income for all banks, but varied widely
by size of banks. Banks with $5-10 million in deposits
paid cash dividends averaging 18 percent of net in­
come while banks with deposits totalling $100 mil­
lion or more paid dividends amounting to 44 per­
cent of net income.
The average rate of return on equity capital, in­
cluding all reserves, declined in 1975 to 11.2 percent
from 12.2 percent a year earlier. By size of bank,
this rate varied from an average of 6.7 percent for
banks with less than $5 million in deposits to 12.3
percent for banks with $25-50 million in deposits.
Those banks with deposits of $100 million or more
had an average return of 10.5 percent.
Page 5

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Capital Ratios*
E ighth

D i st r ic t M e m b e r

Banks

AUGUST

1976

CAPITAL ACCOUNTS AND BANK RATIOS
Total capital of District member banks increased
7.4 percent in 1975 to $1,777 million. Equity capital,
which accounts for the major portion of total capital,
rose 8 percent. After cash dividends of $71 million
were paid, net retained earnings — the primary source
of equity capital — amounted to $126 million, 7 per­
cent higher than in 1974.
Movements of capital ratios were mixed in 1975.
While total assets grew 5 percent, total capital rose
at a faster 7 percent rate, resulting in an increase in
the capital to asset ratio from 7.9 to 8.1 percent. The
equity capital to asset ratio also posted an increase,
rising 0.2 percentage points to 7.8 percent. These
increases represent the first upward movement in
these ratios in several years. In 1974 these ratios had
leveled off after a period of decline.

* C a p it a l in c lu d e s all re se rve s. C a p it a l ra t io s fo r 1 9 7 3 — 1 97 5 h a v e b e e n
a d j u s t e d to e x c lu d e o n e b a n k w h ic h e x p e r ie n c e d u n u s u a l c o n d it io n s in
th e se y e a r s .

Digitized forPage
FRASER
6


Total deposits, on the other hand, grew more
rapidly than either of the capital measures. This re­
sulted in a slight decline in the total capital to de­
posit ratio to 9.8 percent. The ratio of equity capital
to deposits remained essentially unchanged at 9.5
percent.

The U.S. Dollar in International Markets:
Mid -1970 to Mid -1976
DON ALD S. KEMP

O
n E of the most controversial issues in the area
of international trade and finance has been that of
the relative desirability of fixed versus floating ex­
change rates. Disagreement on this issue is wide­
spread and has been, in the recent past, the major
stumbling block to a general agreement within the
International Monetary Fund (IM F ) regarding the
future form of the international payments mechanism.
This article addresses four issues related to the
recent experience with generally floating exchange
rates between the U.S. dollar and the currencies of
nine of the United States’ major trading partners.1
The intervention activities of the Federal Reserve
System in recent years are analyzed in order to get
some idea of the extent to which exchange rates have
been managed. Next, the question of measuring how
much exchange rates have actually fluctuated in
recent years is addressed. Some criteria are developed
for and employed in evaluating whether the observed
changes should be regarded as excessive. Finally, the
issue of the likely causes of the observed exchange
rate changes is explored.

Fixed Versus Floating Exchange Rates:
The Issues
The theoretical arguments which surround the
issue of fixed versus floating exchange rates are all
well-known and will be discussed only briefly here.2
On one side of this issue there are the fixed rate ad­
vocates who contend that exchange rate changes unxIt is crucial from the outset that the reader recognize that the
recent experience with floating exchange rates differs signifi­
cantly from an experiment with the pure “ freely floating”
exchange rates dealt with in most of the theoretical literature.
For one thing, some of the currencies analyzed in this article
were officially pegged to others during all or part of the period
covered by the study. For another, the rates have been “ man­
aged” through official market interventions rather than left
alone to float completely free in response to nongovernmental
market influences.
2For a discussion of the arguments for and against floating ex­
change rates, see M. O. Clement, Richard L. Pfister, and Ken­
neth J. Rothwell, Theoretical Issues in International Eco­
nomics, ed. Jesse W . Markham (Boston: Houghton Mifflin
Company, 1967), pp. 249-83; and Gottfried Haberler, Henry
C. Wallich, Peter B. Kenen, Milton Friedman, and Fritz
Machlup, “ Round Table on Exchange Rate Policy,” The
American Economic Review (M ay 1969), pp. 357-69.




der a system of floating rates will be largely the result
of speculation rather than the result of changes in
fundamental economic factors.3 This speculation, in
turn, is presumed to be destabilizing. In other words,
instead of dampening fluctuations in exchange rates,
speculation will make the rates unnecessarily erratic.
Furthermore, it is feared that these speculatively
generated exchange rate changes will be so large
and unpredictable as to disrupt international trade
and investment.
On the other side of this issue are the floating
rate advocates, who say that while exchange rates
will change under a floating rate system, they will
do so primarily in response to changes in fundamental
economic factors. These individuals maintain that
while speculation will undoubtedly occur in foreign
exchange markets under a system of floating rates,
such speculation will, on balance, not be destabilizing.
In other words, speculation will have the effect of
dampening fluctuations in exchange rates as they
respond to changes in these fundamental factors.4
If the empirical evidence of the past few years
shows that a significant portion of the fluctuation in
exchange rates has been independent of changes in
fundamental factors, then such fluctuations should be
viewed with concern. On the other hand, if exchange
rates have fluctuated in a pattern consistent with
changes in fundamental factors, there is much less
cause for concern. In such a case, the candidates for
government stabilization actions are not the exchange
rates themselves, but rather the underlying factors
3The fundamental factors affecting exchange rates in the long
run are relative rates of inflation and monetary expansion.
These factors are considered fundamental in the sense that
their impact on exchange rates can be justified on the basis
of economic theory alone.
4For a theoretical discussion of the question of the stability of
foreign exchange markets, see Kurt F. Hausafus, “ Trade Fi­
nance, Capital Movements and the Stability of the Foreign
Exchange Market,” International Economic Review (June
1975), pp. 404-14. For an empirical evaluation of the sta­
bility issue, see Jerome L. Stein and Edward Tower, “ The
Short-Run Stability of the Foreign Exchange Market,” The
Review of Economics and Statistics (M ay 1967), pp. 173-85;
and Michael P. Dooley and Jeffrey R. Shafer, “ Analysis of
Short-Run Exchange Rate Behavior, March 1973 to September
1975,” International Finance Discussion Papers, International
Finance Division, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, No. 76 (February 1976).

Page 7

AUGUST

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

1976

Table 1

TREASURY A N D FEDERAL RESERVE FO REIG N E XC H A N G E O P E R A T IO N S1
March 1971 -— April 1976
(Millions of U.S. Dollars)
Total
Purchases

Time
Period

$301.4

February 1976 — April 1976

$

227.2

August 1975 — January 1976
February 1975 — July 1975

Net
Purchases

Total
Intervention

270.4

$

$

333.7

1,045.0

-1 ,0 45.0

1,045.0

-

742.3

742.3

527.0

-

523.3

530.7

584.2

247.5

March 1973 — July 1973

336.7

831.7

273.5

-

273.5

273.5

-

144.4

554.0

257.8

341.2

October 1972 — February 1973

215.0

339.0

April 1972 — September 1972

299.5

41.7

October 1971 — March 1972

55.0

P

Feb. 1976 — April 1976
Feb. 1 9 7 5 —

$
29.8
16.2

Feb. 1974 — July 1974

21.2

Jan. 1974

36.2

July 1973

Oct. 1972 — Feb. 1973

P

$
45.6
33.7

3.7
510.6

47.0

80.0

$

s
$

55.0

55.0

75.7

75.7

Netherlands
Guilder
P

S

U.K.
Pound

Swiss
Franc
P

S

$19.6 $19.6 $ 33.2 $

106.5

$

740.6

96.3

132.8

43.3

63.6

469.8

2.3

244.6

S
$

4.3

2.9

220.5
20.4

135.0

21.4

299.5
35.0

20.0

March 1971 — Sept. 1971

P

3.1

619.2

318.6
10.2

P

S

$173.7 $250.8

33.1
6.0

April 1972 — Sept. 1972
Oct. 1971 — March 1972

S

Japanese
Yen

German
Mark

149.7

July 1975

March 1 9 7 3 —

P

74.4

Aug. 1974 — Jan. 1975
Aug. 1 9 7 3 —

French
Franc

S

$74.9 $

Aug. 1 9 7 5 — Jan. 1976

-

75.7

March 1971 — September 1971
Belgian
Franc

571.8

102.7

742.3

February 1974 — July 1974

Time
Period

31.0

106.5

3.7

August 1974 — January 1975
August 1973 — January 1974

Total
Sales

75.7

P — Purchases
S — Sales
1Canada and Italy are not listed separately in this table because no data relating specifically to these countries were available.

that contribute to the fluctuations. Indeed, if ex­
change rate changes reflect movements in macroeconomic conditions within countries, such changes
in exchange rates have been beneficial in terms of
dampening the international transmission of economic
disturbances.5

tervention. Such an arrangement has come to be
known as “managed floating”. In fact, many advocates
of a freely floating exchange rate system argue that
the present exchange rate system has been so highly
“managed” that its performance is not a fair measure
of how a “freely floating” exchange rate system would
work if fully adopted.

Intervention Activities

Because of the sparseness of information relating
to the intervention activities of the United States
and its major trading partners, it is difficult to assess
the validity of the above argument. The only offi­
cial source of information regarding foreign exchange
market intervention activities is a quarterly report
issued by the Federal Reserve Board of Governors.0

During the period covered in this article, exchange
rates were neither absolutely fixed at an officially
specified level nor were they allowed to float com­
pletely free of official foreign exchange market in­
5This is a fundamental assertion of the advocates o f flexible
exchange rates. The supporting arguments can be found in
Milton Friedman, “ The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates,”
Essays in Positive Economics ( Chicago: The University of
Chicago Press, 1953), pp. 157-203; and Harry G. Johnson,
“ The Case for Flexible Exchange Rates, 1969,” this Review
(June 1969), pp. 12-24.

Digitized for Page
FRASER
8


BThis information can be found in a series of reports titled
“ Treasury and Federal Reserve Foreign Exchange Opera­
tions.” These reports are usually published in the March,
June, September, and December issues of the Federal Re­
serve Bulletin.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

In addition to being highly aggregated with respect
to U.S. activities, the figures given in these reports
almost completely exclude the activities of other
central banks. Since other central banks have, in
total, intervened in foreign exchange markets with
much greater frequency and in much larger dollar
amounts than the United States, the numbers pro­
vided in these reports underestimate the total amount
of intervention that has taken place. However, since
it is reasonable to suppose that the United States and
other countries take cooperative action and thus in­
tervene on the same side of the markets, these num­
bers should at least give an indication of the general
thrust of worldwide intervention activities during a
given period. The data reported in Table I have
been gleaned from the Federal Reserve reports.
Recognizing these caveats, there are still some in­
teresting patterns which show up in Table I. First,
the currencies in which the System has undertaken
the greatest amount of intervention are those that
have fluctuated the most (see Table II).7 Secondly,
the total amount of intervention undertaken by the
Federal Reserve in the generalized float period ( after
March 1973) is actually greater than the amount
undertaken prior to the generalized float. However,
since this observation is based on data having signifi­
cant shortcomings, firm conclusions should be drawn
with care.

How Much Have Exchange Rates Actually
Fluctuated?
In investigating the extent to which exchange rates
have actually fluctuated in recent years, the concern
is not with the net change in exchange rates over
long intervals of time, but rather with how much they
have fluctuated over short intervals. The reason for
concentrating on short intervals (a day, a month, or
a quarter) is that it is the short-term fluctuations
that are most often attributed to destabilizing specu­
lative forces and are of greatest concern to those
engaged in international commerce.
The daily exchange rates between the U.S. dollar
and the currencies of the United States’ largest trad­
ing partners are used to measure the amount of
exchange rate fluctuation that has actually been
experienced during the past few years. Monthly
7The interpretation of this observation is a matter of dispute.
Many floating rate advocates maintain the possibility that the
intervention itself was a source of confusion in foreign ex­
change markets and, therefore, exacerbated exchange rate
movements. On the other hand, many analysts contend that
the rates would have fluctuated much more had the inter­
vention not taken place.




AUGUST

1976

averages of these daily exchange rate levels were
computed for the time period covering June 1970
through June 1976, and quarterly averages of these
monthly levels were computed from the second
quarter of 1970 through the second quarter of 1976.
The statistical distributions of the percentage changes
in these daily, monthly, and quarterly series were
then analyzed.8 The results are presented in Table II.9
The first set of results covers the period beginning
approximately with the floating of the Canadian dol­
lar in June 1970 and ending in June 1976. The second
set of results covers the period June 1970 through
February 1973, just prior to the beginning of the
current generalized float. The last set of results covers
the period of the generalized float (March 1973June 1976).

Evaluation of Measured Variability
Unfortunately, there exists no consensus regarding
what constitutes excessive exchange rate fluctuations.
Hence, there is no standard against which the fluctua­
tions of the past few years can be compared. The
approach adopted here is to assume that the fixed
bands agreed upon in the Smithsonian accord rep­
resent at least a loose consensus on acceptable
short-run ranges for exchange rate fluctuations. The
performance of exchange rates over the past few
years is then compared with these bands.
At the Smithsonian meetings of December 1971,
the members of the Group of Ten agreed to permit
their currencies to fluctuate within a 2.25 percent
range on each side of mutually acceptable central
values. In other words, it was agreed that the value
of each of the currencies of the United States’ major
trading partners would be allowed to fluctuate within
8The distributions of the absolute values of percentage changes
were also analyzed. However, there was no significant dif­
ference between these results and those of the actual exchange
rate changes analyzed in this article.
9It is usually assumed that data on daily exchange rate
changes are normally distributed. Furthermore, upon in­
voking the Central Limit Theorem, the same assumption is
usually made about the distribution of the changes in the
monthly and quarterly averages of daily exchange rates.
However, the assumption of normality of daily exchange
rate changes has been questioned recently by Janice M.
Westerfield, “ Empirical Properties O f Foreign Exchange Rates
Under Fixed and Floating Rate Regimes,” Philadelphia Fed
Research Papers (Decem ber 1975).
An analysis of the third and fourth moments about the
mean of the data employed in this study leads to no firm
conclusions regarding the validity of the normality assump­
tion. However, as expected, the assumption seems to have
greater justification in the case of monthly and quarterly
averages than in the case of daily levels. Thus, the normal
model may not be the most accurate description of the
distribution of exchange rate changes. If it is not, then the
usefulness of the means and variances reported in Table
II is diminished.

Page 9

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

AUGUST

1976

Table li

Distribution of Percentage C h anges in Exchange Rates Between
the U.S. D ollar and the Currencies of Its M ajor Trading Partners
Time Period
and
Time Interval

Statistic

Belgium

Canada

France

Germany

Italy

Japan

Netherlands

Switzer­
land

U.K.

Daily Changes from
June 1, 1970 to
June 30, 1976
(1 49 4 Observations)

Mean
Std. Dev.

0 .01 6%
0.526

0 .0 0 7 %
0.177

0 .01 2%
0.540

0 .02 5%
0.552

-0 .0 1 8 %
0.465

0 .01 3%
0.446

0 .0 2 0 %
0.476

0 .0 3 9 %
0.588

-0 .0 1 9 %
0.389

Monthly Changes
from June 1970 to
June 1976
(73 Observations)

Mean
Std. Dev.

0.335
2.336

0.136
0.715

0.239
2.397

0.507
2.720

-0 .3 8 7
2.120

0.268
1.961

0.415
2.403

0.798
2.576

-0 .4 0 8
1.751

Quarterly Changes
from 11/70 to 11/76
(25 Observations)

Mean
Std. Dev.

1.034
4.316

0.376
1.369

0.760
4.481

1.588
5.090

-1 .1 6 4
4.090

0.773
3.409

1.259
4.174

2.299
4.418

-1 .0 6 8
3.742

Daily Changes from
June 1, 1970 to
February 28, 1973
(669 Observations)

Mean
Std. Dev.

0.035
0.301

0.012
0.208

0.030
0.342

0.038
0.373

0.016
0.195

0.046
0.488

0.037
0.295

0.049
0.301

0.006
0.245

Monthly Changes
from June 1970 to
February 1973
(33 Observations)

Mean
Std. Dev.

0.538
1.255

0.230
0.766

0.458
1.447

0.584
1.286

0.279
0.601

0.799
1.844

0.566
1.335

0.728
1.798

0.038
1.296

Quarterly Changes
from 11/70 to 1/73
(12 Observations)

Mean
Std. Dev.

1.506
2.475

0.620
1.256

1.284
2.577

1.756
2.309

0.747
1.096

2.123
3.109

1.557
2.415

1.931
2.889

0.083
2.592

Daily Changes from
March 2, 1973 to
June 30, 1976
(824 Observations)

Mean
Std. Dev.

0.001
0.654

0.003
0.148

-0 .0 0 4
0.658

0.013
0.662

-0 .0 4 8
0.597

0.013
0.408

0.007
0.583

0.032
0.744

-0 .0 4 0
0.474

Monthly Changes
from March 1973 to
June 1976
(40 Observations)

Mean
Std. Dev.

0.168
2.952

0.058
0.670

0.058
2.969

0.444
3.506

-0 .9 3 7
2.705

0.170
1.968

0.290
3.027

0.856
3.096

-0 .7 7 5
1.994

Quarterly Changes
from 11/73 to 11/76
(13 Observations)

Mean
Std. Dev.

0.598
5.587

0.151
1.479

0.276
5.792

1.433
6.846

-2 .9 2 8
5.033

0.473
3.298

0.984
5.415

2.639
5.580

-2.131
4.393

a 4.5 percent band vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar.10 There­
fore the 4.5 percent band is used here as a standard
for evaluating the degree of the exchange rate
fluctuation during the past few years.11
A review of Table II indicates that in no instance
did the mean of the percentage change in the ex­
change rate of the U.S. dollar vis-a-vis each of the
10While each currency was restricted to a 4.5 percent band
vis-a-vis the U.S. dollar, each could fluctuate by up to 9
percent vis-a-vis a third currency. For example, suppose
currency A was at the top of its 4.5 percent bancl and
currency B was at the bottom of its 4.5 percent band
vis-a-vis the dollar. If these two currencies were to switch
positions within their respective bands, the value of each
would change by 9 percent relative to one another while
changing by only 4.5 percent relative to the U.S. dollar.
For these same reasons, any two currencies of the European
Snake can fluctuate by up to 4.5 percent vis-a-vis one another
under current Snake rules. This point is discussed at greater
length in “ The European System of Narrower Exchange
Rate Margins,” Monthly Report of the Deutsche Bundesbank
(January 1976), pp. 22-29.
1:1The Smithsonian agreement did not specify the appropriate
time interval over which the 4.5 percent constraint was to


Page 10


other nine currencies exceed 4.5 percent over either
daily, monthly, or quarterly intervals. In addition,
in no instance did the standard deviation of the per­
centage exchange rate changes exceed 4.5 percent
for either the daily or monthly data.
In the case of quarterly data for Belgium, France,
Germany, Italy, Switzerland, and the Netherlands,
however, the standard deviation did exceed 4.5
apply. It merely stated that the constraint would be bind­
ing until a “fundamental disequilibrium” arose. Therefore,
in comparing recent exchange rate movements over specific
time intervals (days, months, and quarters) with the 4.5
percent Smithsonian band, the 4.5 percent figure must be
taken merely as a guideline to what may have been con­
sidered acceptable variation over these intervals. One should
also keep in mind that the considerations which led to the
Smithsonian agreement were formed against a backdrop of
inflation that was relatively mild in terms of both levels and
inter-country differences compared to the experience which
has followed this agreement. Hence, considerably greater
fluctuations might have been considered acceptable in these
latter years. Thus, given the economic environment of the
past few years, the 4.5 percent constraint may represent an
unduly restrictive standard of comparison.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

percent during the period of the generalized float.
In evaluating this last finding, one should keep in
mind that the currencies of these countries (with the
exception of Italy) were joined together in a cur­
rency block for much of the generalized float period.
As such, if the major block currency (the German
mark) were to fluctuate relative to the dollar by a
given percent over a given interval for any reason,
all of the other block currencies would automatically
fluctuate in a similar pattern.12

Causes of the Observed Fluctuations in
Exchange Rates
Much of the discussion about the relative desira­
bility of fixed versus floating exchange rates relates
to questions about the stability of the foreign ex­
change markets. This issue is tied to the question of
whether or not speculation in these markets is de­
stabilizing. With destabilizing speculation, exchange
rate expectations based on fundamental factors are
said to be weakly held and, hence, traders are un­
willing to take large positions on the basis of these
expectations. The resulting exchange rate path is then
dominated by price runs and bandwagon effects and
is, therefore, unnecessarily erratic.
A set of tests were performed to determine how
prevalent such runs and bandwagon effects have been
in foreign exchange markets since June 1970. These
tests examine whether the number of runs observed
in foreign exchange markets can be distinguished
from the number that would be generated by a com­
pletely random process. Such so-called “runs tests”
are useful in determining whether the behavior of
exchange rates has been consistent with the hypothe­
sis that speculation in these markets is destabilizing —
a prevalence of sustained runs (that is, bandwagons)
up or down.13

AUGUST

Table Ilf

Runs Test for Randomness of
Exchange Rate Fluctuations
TIME PERIODS
1

13In this test a run is defined as a sequence of changes of the
same sign that is preceded and followed by a sequence of
changes of the other sign. If speculation is stabilizing, the
runs that do appear are due to changes in fundamental
factors. Since one would expect that changes in these funda­
mental factors occur on a random basis, expectations are that
they would cause neither more nor less runs than would any
random process. For a discussion of the runs test utilized in
this article, see Dick A. Leabo, Basic Statistics, 4th ed.
(H om ewood, Illinois: Richard D. Irwin, Inc., 1972), pp.
545-47.




II

III

Belgium
Daily
Monthly
Quarterly

-0 .0 1 0
-0 .0 5 8
-0.1 14

0.029
-0 .0 7 0
0.392

-0 .0 3 5
-0 .0 4 2
-0 .2 1 2

Canada
Daily
Monthly
Quarterly

-0.0 85
-0.2 82
-0.381

-0 .0 6 0
-0.191
-0 .1 6 3

-0 .1 0 3
-0 .3 6 2
-0 .6 0 3

France
Daily
Monthly
Quarterly

-0 .0 0 4
-0 .2 1 0
-0 .2 3 3

0.012
-0.151
0.392

-0 .0 1 8
-0 .2 5 8
-0 .6 0 3

Germany
Daily
Monthly
Quarterly

-0 .0 2 7
-0 .1 9 7
-0.141

-0.001
-0.121
-0.131

-0 .0 4 4
-0 .2 4 2
-0 .0 8 0

Daily
Monthly
Quarterly

-0 .0 1 9
-0 .1 28
-0 .2 1 8

0.071
0.164
0.174

-0 .0 6 0
-0 .3 0 4
0.095

Japan
Daily
Monthly
Quarterly

0.0
-0 .3 3 9
-0 .3 5 3

0.088
-0 .1 2 9
-0 .6 9 6

-0.031
-0 .3 3 6
-0 .0 8 0

Netherlands
Daily
Monthly
Quarterly

-0 .0 4 7
-0 .0 1 0
-0 .4 5 9

-0.0 52
0.050
-0 .6 5 4

-0 .0 3 9
-0 .0 4 2
-0 .2 1 2

Switzerland
Daily
Monthly
Quarterly

-0.031
-0 .3 0 7
0.012

-0 .0 4 9
-0 .2 2 2
0.131

-0 .0 2 0
-0 .3 7 4
-0 .0 2 8

-0 .0 2 9
-0 .3 9 5
-0 .3 5 5

0.057
-0 .3 0 2
-0 .5 5 4

-0 .0 9 8
-0 .4 3 0
0.097

Italy

U.K.
Daily
Monthly
Quarterly

Runs tests for randomness were performed for
each of the exchange rate series discussed in the pre12While this observation says nothing about the cause of the
comparatively large fluctuations experienced by the block
currencies as a group, it does call attention to the possibility
that the source of fluctuations of any one of these currencies
may lie more in the fact that the currency was a member
of the block, rather than in any other factor.

1976

Daily

1 = June 1, 1970 — -June 30, 1976
II = June 1, 1970 — - February 28, 1973
III = March 2, 1973 -— June 30, 1976

Monthly

1 = June 1 9 7 0 — June 1976
II = June 1970 — February 1973
III = March 1973 — June 1976

Quarterly

1 = 11/1970 - 11/1976
II = 11/1970 - 1/1973
III = 11/1973 - 11/1976

ceding sections of this article. The results of these
tests are presented in Table III. A positive value for
the test statistic indicates that the number of runs
Page 11

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

in the sample exceeds the expected number for a
random ordering. A negative value for the test
statistic indicates fewer than the expected number of
runs. The hypothesis of nonrandom ordering is re­
jected with 95 percent confidence only if the value
of the test statistic lies within a range of ± 1.96.
The data presented in Table III indicate that the
hypothesis that exchange rate changes were generated
by a nonrandom process should be rejected on the
basis of this test and these data. As such, these results
permit conditional rejection of the view that observed
exchange rate fluctuations have been the result of
destabilizing speculation.

What are the Relevant Fundamental Factors?
The data presented in the preceding section cast
doubt on the view that exchange rate changes have
been the result of destabilizing speculation. However,
the alternative hypothesis, that exchange rates
change primarily in response to changes in funda­
mental factors, has not been explicitly developed or
considered.
Exchange rate theory indicates that the predomi­
nant factor determining exchange rate changes in the
long run is the degree of inflationary pressure in one
country relative to inflationary pressure in another
country.14 This theory can be well illustrated by a
simple two-country example. Suppose there are only
two countries in the world, country A and country B.
A high degree of inflationary pressure in country A
relative to that existing in country B implies an
increase in country A’s demand for all products,
including those produced in country B. This increased
demand for country B’s products results in an in­
crease in the demand for country B’s currency in
country A and causes the price of currency B to rise
(in terms of the currency of country A ). In other
words, currency A will depreciate and currency B
will appreciate.15 In addition, if the rate of growth
14The future can be divided into three different time frames —
the long run, the intermediate run, and the short run — dur­
ing which different factors are the dominant influence on
exchange rate movements. Just where one of these time
frames begins and ends cannot be precisely specified. This
analysis concentrates on the long run only, which is defined
here as any period extending for more than a quarter.
15Inflationary pressures are empirically approximated by ob­
served changes in some very broad ana imperfect index of
all prices. These indices attempt to capture increases in the
prices of foreign as well as domestically supplied products.
However, the majority of the items included in these indices
are domestically supplied.
Any increase in inflationary pressures will be reflected in
an increase in the demand for foreign as well as domestically
supplied products. The increased demand for domestically

Digitized forPage
FRASER
12


AUGUST

1976

of a country’s money stock plays a dominant role
in the determination of inflationary pressures, a
strong relationship will be expected to exist between
exchange rate changes and relative rates of monetary
growth.16
The longer the time horizon, the more pronounced
these relationships will be. Inflationary pressures be­
come established only in the long run and the full
impact of differing inflationary pressures on ex­
change rates could be resisted by governments in the
short and intermediate runs. Under a system of freely
floating or loosely managed exchange rates, necessary
adjustments to changes in such fundamental factors
are permitted to occur gradually. However, when ex­
change rates are narrowly fixed or tighdy managed
(as within the European Snake, for example) ex­
change market pressures are not relieved in a slow
and orderly fashion. However, once market partici­
pants sense the presence of pent-up market forces
which favor realignment, taking into account changes
in fundamental factors, exchange market pressures
surge and result in “currency crises” and sudden large
jolts in exchange rates. Thus, while the relationship
between exchange rates and relative inflationary
pressures (as measured by changes in price indices)
may not be strong in the short run, the longer the
time frame, the stronger this relationship becomes.
In order to perform a test of the relative inflation­
ary pressure hypothesis of exchange rate determina­
tion, the following series were constructed. The simple
percentage change in the value of the U.S. dollar
vis-a-vis each of the other nine currencies reviewed
was calculated over the same three time periods
analyzed in the preceding tests. The same computa­
tions were then performed for the simple percentage
changes in two proxies for inflationary pressure (the
consumer price index, CPI, and the wholesale price
index, W PI), and for the money stock in each of the
respective countries relative to the simple percentage
supplied products will result in an increase in the price of
those products. An increase in the demand for products
produced in foreign countries will result in a rise in the
price of the foreign exchange needed to purchase those
products (depreciation of the domestic currency). It is rea­
sonable to expect that the increase in the price of foreign
exchange (which immediately increases the domestic price
of foreign produced products) will occur faster than the
increase in the prices of all of the other products covered
by some overall price index. As such, it is entirely possible
that inflationary pressures will be reflected in exchange rates
before they are reflected in changes in overall price indices.
For this reason, exchange rate changes may precede the
relative movement in price indices in the short run, but this
does not indicate that exchange rate changes have caused
the movement in price indices.
16See Donald S. Kemp, “ A Monetary View of the Balance of
Payments,” this Review (April 1975), pp. 20-21.

AUGUST

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

changes in their U.S. counterparts. In other words,
for each time period the simple percentage change
in the CPI, WPI, and money stock for the United
States was substracted from the simple percentage
change in the foreign counterparts of these measures.
A correlation test was then performed to determine
the degree of relationship between the simple per­
centage change in exchange rate series and each of
the other series described above.17 If it is true that
exchange rate movements reflect relative inflationary
pressures and relative rates of money growth among
countries, then the exchange rate series would be
negatively correlated with each of the other three
series. That is, those countries whose currencies ap­
preciated the most relative to the U.S. dollar should
be those countries whose inflation and money growth
rates were smallest relative to the inflation and money
growth rates in the United States.
The results, reported in Table IV, indicate that
for all time periods there exists a statistically signifi­
cant negative correlation between the W PI series and
the exchange rate series. In addition, with the excep­
tion of the June 1970 through February 1973 period,
the correlation between both the CPI and the money
stock series and the exchange rate series is also
negative and statistically significant. These results are
noteworthy in two respects. First, the results which
cover the entire time period since June 1970 indicate
that there does in fact exist a statistically significant
negative correlation between the exchange rate series
and each of the other series. Second, there is a strik­
ing dissimilarity between the results for the pre­
generalized float period and those for the generalized
float period. This indicates that when the exchange
rates had the greatest amount of freedom to respond
to changes in fundamental factors, their observed
movements paralleled relative inflation and money
growth rates most closely. The results reported in
Table IV thus lend support to the hypothesis that
movements in exchange rates, particularly in the long
run, are determined by relative inflationary pressures
and relative rates of money growth.18 In addition
17The particular measure of correlation utilized here is the
Pearsonian Correlation Coefficient.
18The same test which led to the results presented in Table
IV was conducted using data for all OECD member countries
for which data are currently available. This same test
was also performed using data for all of the 46 IMF
member countries which account for about 90 percent of
total U.S. trade and for which data are currently available.
The results of both tests were virtually identical in their
implications, if not in their exact numerical value, with those
presented in Table IV. Thus, the conclusions drawn from
Table IV do not appear to be sensitive to the sample of
countries chosen for analysis.




1976

Table IV

CORRELATION TEST
Percent Changes
in
Exchange Rates
Correlated with:

Relative Percent
Changes in CPI2

Relative Percent
Changes in W PI2

Relative Percent
Changes in
Money Supply2

Time Period
June 1970March 1976
June 1970Feb. 1973
March 1973March 1976
June 1970March 1976
June 1970Feb. 1973
March 1973March 1976
June 1970Jan. 1976
June 1970Feb. 1973
March 1973Jan. 1976

Correlation
Coefficient

Number
of
Observa­
tions1

— 0.7893

9

0.002

9

-0 .9 2 2 3

9

-0 .9 4 5 s

84

-0 . 8 5 8 3

9

-0 .9 4 6 3

8

— 0.6675

76

0.199

8

— 0.8293

8

*The countries covered in this test are Belgium, Canada, France,
Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, Japan, Switzerland, and the
United Kingdom.
2The derivation of these series is explained in detail in the text.
3Significantly different from zero at the 99 percent level.
4The Netherlands was excluded from this test, as well as from the
test covering March 1973-March 1976, because monthly W PI data
are not currently available beyond December 1975.
5Significantly different from zero at the 90 percent level.
6The United Kingdom was excluded from this test, as well as from
the test covering June 1970-February 1973, because monthly money
supply figures are not available for the United Kingdom until
October 1971. Italy was also excluded from this test, as well as
from the test covering March 1973-January 1976, because monthly
money supply figures for Italy are not available beyond September
1975.

to these results, graphic illustrations of the relation­
ships between exchange rate changes and the relative
inflation and money growth series during the gen­
eralized float are presented in Chart I.
The observed negative correlation between relative
rates of inflation and exchange rate changes says
nothing about the direction of causality which under­
lies this relationship. Some analysts claim, for ex­
ample, that changes in exchange rates “cause” changes
in relative rates of inflation. However, evidence in
favor of the alternative argument, that exchange rate
changes were “caused” by the differences in inflation
rates, is given by the last set of results in Table IV.
One body of economic thought holds that relative
rates of monetary expansion are the predominant
factor in explaining relative rates of inflation in the
long run. Applied to the argument advanced in this
article, this view implies a strong negative corre­
lation between exchange rate movements and relative
rates of money growth, as shown in Table IV. On
the other hand, the argument that changes in exPage 13

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

C hart I

R e la tio n sh ip B e tw e e n E x c h a n g e R a te C h a n g e s ,
R e la tiv e R a te s of Inflation,
a n d R e la tiv e R a te s of M o n e y G r o w t h


Page 14


AUGUST

1976

change rates “cause” inflation offers no explanation
of these results.19

Conclusion
The thrust of this article has been an empirical
review of the recent experience with generally
floating exchange rates between the U.S. dollar and
the currencies of the United States’ major trading
partners. The evidence presented herein casts doubt
on the view that exchange rate changes are the result
of destabilizing speculation, even in the short run.
It is also demonstrated that in the long run exchange
rates have changed in a pattern consistent with
changes in fundamental economic factors.
An implication of these findings is that the pros­
pects for a return to a viable fixed exchange rate
regime are remote as long as there remains as wide
a spectrum of economic policies among countries
as has been the case for the past few years. The
unacceptability of such a regime has been amply
demonstrated recently by the futile efforts to hold
together the European Currency Snake and the vir­
tual abandonment by the Common Market of any
plans for a closer Economic and Monetary Union.
It is no coincidence that all but one large country
departed from the Snake and that the dream of an
economically united Europe vanished simultaneously.
The reason is that the Common Market countries
have recognized that no country that believes it has
an option will be willing to subjugate its own eco­
nomic policies to the monetary discipline practiced in
another country (in the current situation the other
country is West Germany). These experiences amply
demonstrate that the time has not yet arrived for the
kind of economic policy coordination that a fixed
exchange rate system requires. While such coordina­
tion may or may not be a laudable goal to strive for,
the world should accept the facts as they currendy
are and admit that, as of now, such an arrangement
is nowhere in sight.
19For some samples of other recent studies which arrive at the
same conclusion regarding the relative inflation and money
growth rate hypothesis of exchange rate determination, see
David Kern, “ Inflation Implications in Foreign Exchange
Rate Forecasting,” Euromoney (April 1976), pp. 62-69; and
D. King, “ The Performance of Exchange Rates in the Recent
Period of Floating: Exchange Rates and Relative Rates of
Inflation,” unpublished memorandum (N ew York: Foreign
Research Division, Federal Reserve Bank of New York,
March 15, 1976). King’s work also provides some evidence
favoring the inflation to depreciation direction of causality.
For an analysis of an earlier period of floating rates, see
John S. Hodgson, “ An Analysis of Floating Exchange Rates:
The Dollar — Sterling Rate, 1919-1925,” The Southern
Economic Journal (O ctober 1972), pp. 249-57.

Housing: A Cyclical Industry on the Upswing
NEIL A. STEVENS

I N f EW housing construction has been on the upswing
since early 1975, following a severe downturn in 1973
and 1974. In many respects the current housing re­
covery is similar to other postwar recoveries, although
apartment construction has not rebounded to the
extent observed over similar periods in the past. Some
perspective as to the nature of the current housing
recovery can be gained by comparing its cyclical
characteristics with those of previous recovery periods
and by surveying the impact of several relevant eco­
nomic variables on recent housing industry patterns.

THE CURRENT HOUSING RECOVERY
IN PERSPECTIVE
Historically, the housing industry has been char­
acterized by recurring upswings and downswings
which generally have been associated with fluctua­
tions in overall economic activity. A sizable fluctuation
in new home construction has been associated with
each of the officially defined general business cycles
in the past thirty years (see Chart I ) .1 In addition,
the housing industry underwent an additional down­
turn in 1966, a period sometimes identified as a “credit
crunch” or mini-recession for the general economy.

Timing
Housing starts, a measure of new home construction
activity, have generally led aggregate economic ac­
tivity in both the downswing and upswing phases of
the business cycle.2 In the recessions experienced
since 1945, housing starts turned down from three to
thirteen quarters before the economy in general, and
turned up simultaneously with or as much as three
quarters before overall economic activity. With re­
gard to the current recession/recovery period, housing
starts peaked in the fourth quarter of 1972, some four
iThe definitions of aggregate economic turning points are
those determined by the National Bureau of Economic
Research (N B E R ).
2Housing starts, which are recorded at the beginning of ex­
cavation of the foundation of a building, are a measure of
additions to the housing stock, though not a perfect measure.
Housing starts, for example, do not include mobile homes
which have become an increasingly important part of the
housing stock. Also, housing starts are not standardized units
with regard to size and quality. And of course, a housing
unit started does not necessarily yield a housing unit com­
pleted.




quarters before the peak in the general economy. The
trough in housing starts was reached in the first
quarter of 1975, the same as the apparent bottomingout point for the economy.3

Strength
Although somewhat more rapid than many analysts
had anticipated earlier, the rate of overall economic
recovery has been about average when compared with
other recoveries.4 The current housing recovery, how­
ever, has been regarded by some as average and by
others as below average, depending upon the par­
ticular statistical comparison which is made.
Measured in terms of the percentage increase in
the number of housing units started, the housing re­
covery through the second quarter of this year (a
period of five quarters) has been about average when
compared with similar periods in other postwar hous­
ing recoveries.5 The 46 percent increase in housing
starts in the past five quarters is essentially the same
as the 47 percent average increase recorded in the
first five quarters of other postwar housing upturns.
On an individual basis, housing recoveries have
ranged from a 15 percent increase in the first five
quarters following the housing trough in late 1960 to
a 72 percent increase following the trough in early
1949 (see Chart II and Table I).
Despite the appearance of a fairly typical upturn
in percentage terms, the level of housing starts in the
second quarter of this year was below the average
of previous recoveries at the five-quarter mark. At
a seasonally adjusted annual rate of 1.43 million units
in the second quarter of 1976, the housing recovery
to date is below the average level of 1.71 million starts
for the same number of quarters in other postwar re­
coveries. In addition, the second quarter level of
housing starts is 41 percent below the previous peak in
late 1972 (see Table I). While such comparisons give
3The NBER has not, as yet, selected the trough point for the
aggregate economy in the last recession. The first quarter of
1975 is used here as a tentative date.
4For a discussion of the current economic recovery, see Roger
W . Spencer, “ Inflation and the Economic Recovery,” this Re­
view (June 1976), pp. 2-10.
“The duration of housing recoveries has varied widely, ranging
from four quarters in two recoveries to eleven quarters in two
other recoveries.

Page 15

AUGUST

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

1976

C h art I

N e w Privately O w n e d H o u sin g Units Started

Source: U.S. Department of Commerce
The first five shaded areas represent periods of business recessions as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research. The last shad ed area is tentative, and has been defined by the FRB of St. Louis.
Latest d a ta plotted: 2nd q uarter prelim inary

the impression that the current housing upturn is
rather weak, it should be remembered that the peak
in housing starts in late 1972 represented the highest
level attained in the postwar period and that the
trough in late 1974 represented the second lowest
level.
C h a rt II

H ousing R ecoveries
Percent

Pattern of Single- and Multi-Family Housing
The current housing upturn has been dominated
by construction of single-family dwellings, with the
increase in single-family housing starts being over
three times the increase in multi-family housing starts
in the first five quarters of the present recovery.6 The
gains in the two markets were considerably more
equal in the three previous housing recoveries.

Percent

The recent paucity of multi-unit construction can be
seen more clearly when viewed from a different per­
spective (Chart IV ). Multi-family housing starts had
trended upward relative to single-family starts over
the 1959-73 period; then the ratio of multi- to single­
family construction plummeted from 83 percent in
the third quarter of 1973 to 32 percent in the first
quarter of 1975. In the current expansion, this ratio
has, on balance, remained at this low level, register­
ing only 31 percent in the second quarter. In the
three previous housing recoveries this ratio had gen­
erally risen.
Trend Over 1959-73 — These movements in relative
quantities of single- and multi-family housing reflect

‘ A v e r a g e ot re c o v e rie s la st in g five o r m ore qua rters.


Page 16


Condominium s, or owner-occupied apartments, have become
an important share of multi-family housing starts, especially
in the 1970s. In principle at least, such dwellings allowed
owners to benefit from tax advantages and possible increased
roperty values while retaining the amenities of apartment
ving.

g

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

AUGUST

1976

Table I

PO ST W AR RECOVERIES IN H O U S IN G STARTS

Trough Quarter
to
Peak Quarter1

Duration
(Quarters)

Percent
Increase
from
Trough to
Succeeding Peak

Annual Rate
of
Increase from
Trough to
Succeeding Peak

Percent
Increase
in First
Five Quarters

Percent of
Total
Increase
Attributed to
First Five
Quarters

Five Quarters
Following Trough
Quarter as a
Percent of
Previous Peak

IV/1946 - IV / 1947

4

+ 5 6 .6 %

+5 6 .6 %

1/1949 - 11/1950

5

+ 7 2.3

+ 5 4 .6

+ 7 2 .3 %

100%

+ 3 2 .0 %

111/1953 - IV/1954

5

+ 2 8.2

+ 2 2.0

+ 28.2

100

-1 4 .8

1/1958 - 1/1959

4

+ 4 6 .1

+ 4 6 .1

N.A.

N.A.

N.A.

11

+ 4 1.1

+ 13.3

+ 14.9

36

-1 7 .4

IV/1960 - 111/1963

N.A.

N.A.

N.A.

IV/1966 - 1/1969

9

+ 8 0.2

+ 29.9

+ 5 6 .3

70

-1 3 .0

1/1970 - IV/1972

11

+ 9 6 .1

+ 27.8

+ 6 3.4

66

+ 20.4

Average
1/1975 - 11/1976

+ 6 0 .1
5

+ 3 5 .8
3

+ 4 7 .0 2
+ 4 5.8

742
N.A.

- 6.02
-4 1 .0

3

Source: U.S. Department o f Commerce, Bureau o f Census.
1Peaks and troughs are those identified with housing starts, not the general economy.
2Average o f recoveries which last five or more quarters.
3Peak as yet undefined.
N .A. — not applicable.

changes in both demand and supply factors. In the
1959 to 1973 period, demographic factors were work­
ing in favor of increasing the demand for apartment
housing relative to single family homes. Reflecting the
post W orld War II baby boom, the num­
ber of people in the 15-29 age group
rose from 35 million to about 58 million
from 1960 to 1975.7 As a result, a large
number of new households were formed
among ages favoring apartment living.
Rising income and changing social
values also encouraged the formation
of a greater number of single house­
holds. Apartment construction around col­
leges and universities, for example, pro­
liferated in the latter 1960s and early
1970s, and “singles” apartments became
commonplace.
While such demand factors help ex­
plain the relative increase in multi-family
starts during the 1959-73 period, a decline
in the price of multi-family housing rela­
tive to single-family housing was also
observed during this period. The rent
component of the consumer price index,
for example, rose 37.5 percent from 1959
to 1973, compared with a 74 percent rise
in homeownership costs. This change
7See George H. Brown, “ Demographic Pressures
for Change,” University of Michigan, Survey
Research Center, Economic Outlook USA
(Spring 1976), pp. 30-31.




reflects, in part, different supply factors in the two
markets. Little difference in cost of production can
be attributed to such factors as labor or materials
or from differences in production technique. How-

Chort III

N e w Privately O w n e d H o u sin g Units Started

1959 I9 6 0 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977
Source: U.S. Department of Commerce
The first two shaded areas represent periods of business recessions as defined by the National Bureau of Economic Research.
The last shad ed are a is tentative, and has been defined by the FRB of St. Louis.
Latest d ata plotted: 2nd quarter prelim inary

Page 17

AUGUST

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Chort IV

Prices and Production of Multi- and Single-Family Housing
Percen t

1976

gested that one of the sources of the weak­
ness in demand for apartments is related
to these younger apartment dwellers simply
returning home or “doubling up.”8

More recently, available evidence suggests
that the demand for apartments has begun
to increase. Vacancy rates have declined
somewhat, and rents have risen at a 5.5 per­
cent annual rate in the past six months,
somewhat faster than the 3.1 percent rate
of increase for homeownership costs. As the
recovery continues, with rising real incomes
1959 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977
and falling unemployment rates, the desire
Sources: U.S. Department of Labor and U.S. Department of Commerce
The first two shad ed areas represent periods of business recessions as defined by the National Bureau of tconomic Research.
of younger persons for separate living quar­
The last shad ed are a is tentative, and has been defined by the FR8 of St. Louis.
Latest d a ta plotted: 2nd quarter
ters will likely be reasserted. Such events
ever, the amount of land used per unit varies sub­
will, in turn, encourage the rent adjustment neces­
stantially between single- and multi-family construc­
sary if the construction of multi-family housing is
tion. As the demand for housing in general continued
to make substantial cyclical gains.
to rise, the price of attractive building sites rose
Demographic trends, however, argue against multi­
sharply, tending to shift relative costs in favor of
family units regaining the prominence of the late 1960s
apartments, as they are less land intensive.
and early 1970s. Based on Bureau of the Census pro­
jections, the 30-44 age group, which favors single­
Recent Cyclical Movements — An interesting prob­
family homes, will rise sharply over the next fifteen
lem with implications for the future of the current
years. Meanwhile, the number of people in the
housing upturn is the further decline in rents relative
15-29 age bracket is expected to decline slightly over
to homeownership costs concurrent with the sharp
the
next fifteen years. Considering this trend factor
decline in multi-family construction (both absolutely
alone,
the demand for single-family homes will
and relative to single-family housing) in the 1973-75
benefit
relative to apartment demand over the com­
period (see Chart IV). This phenomenon suggests
ing
years.
On the other hand, the likely continuance
an “overbuilding” of multi-family housing in the boom
of
the
upward
trend in land prices will tend to favor
period in 1971 and 1972. Such overbuilding was par­
apartments
relative
to single-family homes.
ticularly noticeable in condominium projects, but gen­
eral apartment vacancy rates did increase somewhat
during the boom period, from 5.2 percent in late 1970
to 5.7 percent in early 1973. But why did apartment
vacancy rates remain relatively high in 1975, despite
the tremendous decline in the construction of multi­
family units, the attractiveness of renting versus
homeownership costs, and generally improving eco­
nomic conditions in the second half of 1975?
The evidence seems to imply that the excess sup­
ply situation in the multi-unit housing market was
exacerbated by an unexpected decline in the demand
for apartments, both absolutely and relative to single­
family type housing during the recession period. The
young people who were able to move out on their
own in the late 1960s and early 1970s as incomes
rose were probably more severely affected by the
economic decline in 1974 and early 1975 than the
public in general. Real incomes declined for several
quarters and unemployment among the young was
much higher than for those who typically comprise
the home-buying public. Some analysts have sug­

Page 18


FACTORS INFLUENCING
HOUSING CYCLES

Government Policy Influences
Fluctuations in new housing expenditures are closely
associated with fluctuations in the general economy,
but the factors which underlie such general economic
fluctuations are a source of considerable disagree­
ment among economists. Evidence has been accumu­
lated which points to changes in the growth rates of
monetary aggregates as a consistent factor underly­
ing business fluctuations.9
8See Alan R. Winger, “ Whatever Happened to the Apartment
Dwellers, . . .,” Federal Home Loan Bank of Cincinnati,
Quarterly Review (Second Quarter 1976).
9See Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz, A Monetary History
of the United States, 1867-1960, Princeton University Press,
1963; Milton Friedman, “ Money and Business Cycles,” Re­
view of Economics and Statistics, pp. 32-64, Supplement,
February 1963; Michael Keran, “ Monetary and Fiscal In­
fluence on Economic Activity — The Historical Evidence,”
this Review (November 1969), pp. 5-24; Leonall C. Andersen

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Most economists would agree that monetary forces
have important effects on the short-run behavior of
the housing industry. A study by Francisco Arcelus
and Allan Meltzer, for example, found that interest
rates and the rental price of housing were principal
factors determining the demand for new housing
starts, while the chief factors determining the supply
of housing starts were interest rates and labor costs.10
In that study, cyclical changes in interest rates of plus
or minus 0.5 or 0.6 percent around a mean 5 percent
market rate of interest were found to induce changes
of 15 or 20 percent in the amount of new housing
demanded.11
In view of this alleged link between interest rates
and housing, aiming Government policies at keeping
interest rates “low” and stable in order to encourage
home building seems appropriate to many individuals.
The pursuit of such policies, without regard to the
growth of the monetary aggregates, however, prob­
ably will lead to periodic economic recessions and
inflations12 — both of which have damaging effects
on housing.
Homebuilding, like the general economy, benefits
temporarily from stimulative monetary policies, even
if resources are essentially fully employed. But as
these burgeoning demands for resources compete for
the limited quantities available, upward pressures on
prices result. In the competition, the demand for credit
rises, partially reflecting inflationary expectations, and
interest rates begin to increase, not fall as was orig­
inally intended. Indeed, it is during these so-called
boom periods that the downward phase of the hous­
ing cycle typically has begun as the rising interest
rates encourage consumers to postpone housing
expenditures.
Public frustration with an unexpectedly accelerat­
ing advance in the price level leads eventually to
policies designed to lessen the inflationary pressures.
Monetary growth is reduced and, temporarily at least,
interest rates rise even higher. The cutback in mone­
tary growth leads to a reduction in aggregate spend­
ing, and temporary declines in income, employment,
and production.
and Jerry L. Jordan, “ Monetary and Fiscal Actions: A Test
of Their Relative Importance in Economic Stabilization,” this
Review (November 1968), pp. 11-24.
10Francisco Arcelus and Allan H. Meltzer, “ The Markets for
Housing and Housing Services,” Journal of M oney, Credit
and Banking (February 1973), pp. 78-99.
11Ibid., p. 86.
12For a recent discussion of some of these arguments, see
William Poole, “ Interest Rate Stability as a Monetary Policy
Goal,” Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, New England
Economic Review (M ay/June 1976), pp. 30-37.




AUGUST

1976

Housing, as was pointed out earlier, usually begins
its recovery well before the upturn in the general
economy. As the recession proceeds, general demand
for credit recedes and interest rates begin to decline.
As a result, during the latter stages of a recession and
early months of the business recovery, housing his­
torically has made its largest gains.
This process is exaggerated by several artificial
restrictions on market behavior. For example, Gov­
ernment regulations on rates that thrift institutions
can pay on time and savings deposits or rates these
institutions can charge on loans have an important
effect on housing activity. Housing is largely financed
through credit extended by thrift institutions; there­
fore, when interest rate ceilings become effective ( that
is, in periods of “high” interest rates) and funds are
redirected into unregulated market instruments, the
amount of credit available to finance housing expen­
ditures is restricted. Similar effects result from the
usury laws of various states. Credit naturally flows
out of the regulated markets when market interest
rates rise above the usury ceiling.
Although the cause and effect relationship is prob­
ably overemphasized, a high degree of correlation can
be found among the amount of deposits at thrift insti­
tutions, changes in mortgages outstanding, and the
number of new homes built. Even in the absence of
interest rate restrictions, the rates offered by thrift
institutions tend to adjust upward more slowly than
market interest rates during periods of rising interest
rates. Thus, the public tends to reduce its assets held
at thrift institutions and to increase its assets held in
other market instruments. Also, as interest rates rise,
consumers tend to postpone housing expenditures
and reduce their demands for mortgage credit. Thus,
the positive relationship between changes in nonbank
thrift deposits and changes in housing expenditures
is observed without necessarily implying that one
causes the other.13

External Influences
Recently, nonmonetary events also have led to
fluctuations in economic activity by suddenly and
unexpectedly affecting such economic variables as
income, wealth, and relative prices. For instance, the
sudden increase in oil prices in late 1973 and 1974
resulted in U.S. citizens having to export more goods
and services for the same amount of oil as was previ­
ously received. Such a loss of wealth by U.S. citizens
13See Arcelus and Meltzer for a further articulation of this
view.

Page 19

and the accompanying one-time increase in the price
level caused consumers and businesses to alter their
spending decisions and thus contributed to the initial
stages of the recent recession. Naturally, housing ex­
penditures were also adversely affected by the losses
in income and wealth.

SUMMARY AND OUTLOOK
The housing sector is currently undergoing a recov­
ery from the most severe decline since W orld War II.
The current housing upswing did not lead the general
economic upturn as in other recoveries, but, on
balance, the percentage increase in housing starts to
date is in line with the average of other postwar
recoveries. The upturn has been primarily in the
single-family type market, while the market for multi­
family units, although posting some gains, has been
sluggish.



Historically, the housing industry makes most of its
gains in the late stages of the business recession and
early quarters of the general economic recovery.
Based on these historical patterns, the largest gains
in the housing sector may have already been achieved.
Yet, housing starts have not reached the level usually
attained at this stage of the business cycle, particu­
larly multi-family housing starts. A strong upturn in
this market appears to depend on a further increase
in the demand for such housing, which will signal
increases in rents and induce a change in the quantity
of housing starts. Over the coming decade, however,
demographic factors are expected to favor increases
in the demand for single-family homes. Age groups
tending to prefer single-family dwellings are projected
to increase substantially in the coming years, while
age groups tending to favor apartments are expected
to remain essentially unchanged.