View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK
OF ST. LOUIS
A P R IL 1977

S T .L b im

Elr

J‘

LITTLE R Q t K




Inventory Investment in the Recent
Recession an d R e c o v e ry .......................

2

The Effects of C h an ges in
Inflationary Expectations .....................

10

Food: O utlook Favorable for Consumers .... 15

Inventory Investment in the
Recent Recession and Recovery
JOHN A. TATOM

_|_ HE behavior of inventory investment since the
beginning of the 1973-75 recession has been a domi­
nant concern of economic analysts. Initially, this con­
cern was motivated by a recognition that a relation­
ship between inventory investment and changes in
total output and employment has been one of the
most pronounced regularities of the business cycle.
This relationship appears to be such a dominant
factor in previous postwar recessions that they have
been referred to as “inventory recessions.”1 Conse­
quently, inventory behavior is watched closely as
at least a potential indicator of prospective changes
in output and employment. More recently, attention
has been focused upon the 1976 “pause” in economic
growth. One of the principal hypotheses purporting to
explain this situation relies heavily upon inventory
investment behavior.
The 1973-75 recession was the longest and most
severe in postwar experience. Its causes, at least
initially, were unique.2 The behavior of inventory
investment during the recession, while deceptively
similar to that of prior recessions, was also unique.
Inventory investment declined sharply during the
recession, but it remained much higher than prior
experience would indicate. This deviation from prior
experience has had a very significant impact on inven­
iSee for example, Michael K. Evans, M acroeconomic Activity:
Theory, Forecasting and Control: An Econom etric A pproach
(New York: Harper & Row, Publishers, 1969), p. 201;
Thomas F. Demburg and Duncan M. McDougall, M acro­
econom ics: T he Measurement, Analysis, and Control o f
Aggregate Econornic Activity, 4th ed. (New York: McGrawHill Book Company, 1972), p. 367; or Paul W. McCracken,
“Are the Gray Clouds Clearing?”, E conom ic Outlook USA
(Spring 1974), p. 1-3.
2The causes of the recent recession have been examined by
many analysts including Gardner Ackley, “Two-Stage Re­
cession and Inflation, 1973-1975,” E conom ic Outlook USA
(Winter 1975), pp. 6-7; Denis S. Kamosky, “Another Reces­
sion, But Different,” this Review (December 1974); pp.
15-18; Norman N. Bowsher, “Two Stages to the Current
Recession,” this Review (June 1975), pp. 2-8; and Arthur
M. Okun, “A Postmortem of the 1974 Recession,” Brookings
Papers on Econom ic Activity (1 :1 9 7 5 ), pp. 207-21.
2
Digitized for Page
FRASER


tory investment, economic activity, and the views of
policy-makers in the first two years of recovery and
expansion.

INVENTORIES AND ECONOMIC
ACTIVITY
Inventories consist of raw materials, work-in-progress, and finished goods. There are many reasons
for holding items in inventory, such as the cost and
availability of goods required in the production proc­
ess, the length and flexibility of the production period,
and the variability of market demand. The basic
motives may be summarized as transactions, precau­
tionary, or speculative motives.
Firms tend to hold some inventories simply to be
able to meet their expected levels of sales. It is
usually cheaper to acquire large lots of raw material
and finished goods and hold them than to acquire raw
materials as they are used, or to produce goods as
they are sold. Moreover, the length of time involved
in a production process requires an amount of workin-progress inventories which is directly related to the
production rate. This transaction motive is based upon
the requirements of daily activity and the inability to
match receipts of intermediate goods and production
with sales.
The precautionary motive leads firms to hold buffer
stocks of inventory. This motive is based upon the risk
of fluctuations in sales. Unexpected increases or de­
creases in sales may be met by either changing pro­
duction rates or varying inventory levels. Since the
costs of varying production rates can be large, firms
often choose to hold a buffer stock.
The speculative motive for inventory holding rests
upon the possibility of capital gains or future “short­
ages” of raw materials. Firms may gain by buying raw
materials ahead of increases in their prices or holding

APRIL

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

1977

C h art I

Stock o f B u s in e s s In v e n to rie s*

1948 1949 1950

1951 1 9 5 2 1 9 5 3 1 9 5 4 1 955 1 9 5 6 1 957 1 9 5 8 1 9 5 9 1 9 6 0 1961 1 9 6 2

1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970

1971 1 9 7 2

1973 1974 1975 1976

* M e a s u r e d in 1 9 7 2 d o ll a r s .
S h a d e d a r e a s r e p r e s e n t p e r i o d s o f b u s in e s s r e c e s s io n s .
L a te st d a t a p lo tte d : 4 th q u a r t e r

their product for future price appreciation. This type
of inventory holding does not appear to be different
from a precautionary motive, but it remains typical
of the literature to distinguish this motive.3
It is impossible to identify the proportions of inven­
tory held for each reason, but the motives are sugges­
tive of the economic forces which determine the stock
of inventory for the firm or the economy. The single
most important factor influencing the demand for a
stock of inventory is probably the expected sales rate.
A larger rate of sales tends to require a larger stock of
inventory. For example, the stock of business inven­
tory in constant (1972) prices, shown in Chart I, has
equaled 22 to 25 percent of real GNP since 1948. An
increase in expected sales leads firms to engage in
positive spending for inventories or inventory invest­
ment. If the expected growth of sales slows, firms
tend to slow inventory investment. When sales are
expected to decline, inventory stocks would tend to
become excessive so that negative inventory invest­
ment, or disinvestment, may occur.
3See, for example, Evans, M acroeconomic Activity, p. 203.
Evans also includes a backlog of demand as a reason for
holding larger inventories.



Inventory investment, shown in Chart II, is a small
component of- production of final goods and services
(GNP). For example, the largest postwar rate of in­
ventory investment occurred in the fourth quarter of
1973 when it equaled $25.4 billion (1972 dollars) at an
annual rate, or about 2 percent of real gross national
product. However, inventory investment is quite
erratic, and changes in the rate of inventory invest­
ment can be quite large relative to changes in produc­
tion rates, especially during recessions.
The sharpest swings in inventory investment and
the largest positive or negative rates of investment
have occurred since 1973. Quarterly rates of inven­
tory investment over this volatile period (IV/1973
— IV /1976) are presented in Table I. After reaching
its largest postwar rate in the first quarter of the
recession, inventory investment declined. During the
last quarter of the recession (1/1975), inventory in­
vestment became negative as firms depleted inven­
tory stocks at an annual rate of $20.5 billion. Through
the first three quarters of the recovery, inventory
stocks continued to decline, although at slower annual
rates. Inventory investment resumed in 1976 at a
fairly steady annual rate of about $10 billion until
the last quarter when it fell to about $1 billion.
Page 3

APRIL

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

1977

C h a r t II

A c tu a l R e a l In v e n to ry In v e stm e n t*

■ 2 5 ....................
............................................
1 --------------------------— 22121------ ---------- L J = ------------------------------------------------- --------- --------------------L—
............. ............... .............. ............. ............................................ -2 5
1 9 4 8 1 9 4 9 1 9 5 0 1951 1 9 5 2 1 9 5 3 1 9 5 4 1 9 5 5 1 9 5 6 1 9 5 7 1 9 5 8 1 9 5 9 1 9 6 0 1961 1 9 6 2 1 9 6 3 1 9 6 4 1 9 6 5 1 9 6 6 1 9 6 7 1 9 6 8 1 9 6 9 1 9 7 0 1971 1 9 7 2 1 9 7 3 1 9 7 4 1 9 7 5 1 9 7 6
^ M e a s u r e d in 1 9 7 2 d o lla r s .
S h a d e d a r e a s r e p r e s e n t p e r i o d s o f b u s in e s s r e c e s s io n s .
L a te st d a t a p lo t t e d : 4 th q u a r t e r

THE ROLE OF INVENTORY INVEST­
MENT IN POSTWAR RECESSIONS
To some extent, the sharp decline in the rate of
inventory investment during the recent recession was
to be expected. Inventory investment had declined
sharply in the five previous postwar recessions. In­
deed, a major share of the decline in national output
Table 1

Real Inventory Investment
(Constant 1 97 2 Dollars)
Quarters

Inventory Investment

IV / 1 9 7 3

$25 .4

1/1974

11.4

11/1974

9.4

111/1974

5.1

IV / 1 9 7 4

8.0

1/1975

-2 0 .5

11/1975

-2 1 .2

111/1975

-

1.0

IV / 197 5

-

5.5

1/1976

10.4

11/1976

11.1

111/1976

10.2

IV / 1 9 7 6

0.9


Page 4


during these recessions has been reflected in declines
in production for inventory stocks. This is a major
sense in which postwar recessions are said to be
“inventory recessions.”

The importance of inventory investment during
recessions is reflected in the ratio of changes in inven­
tory investment to changes in real GNP. As shown in
Chart III, this ratio is usually quite small. However,
there are a few quarters, primarily during recessions,
when the change in inventory investment is greater
than the total change in production. If output falls
during such a quarter, production for inventory stock
falls more, and other components — such as con­
sumption, other types of investment, government pur­
chases and net exports — increase. Most of the ex­
tremely high levels of the ratio of changes in inventory
investment to output fluctuations occurred during
recessions.
In Table II the decline in real GNP and real inven­
tory investment, from the peak to the trough quarter,
is shown for each of the six postwar recessions. In two
postwar recessions the decline in the production rate
was greatly exceeded by the drop in inventory invest­
ment. In three others, including the most recent

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL

1977

R a t io o f C h a n g e in In v e n t o r y In v e s t m e n t to C h a n g e in O u t p u t

1 9 4 8 1 9 4 9 1 9 5 0 1 951

1952 1 9 5 3 1 9 5 4 1955 1 9 5 6 1957 1 9 5 8 1 9 5 9 I 9 6 0 1961 1 9 6 2 1 9 6 3 1 9 6 4 1 9 6 5 1 9 6 6 1 9 6 7 1 9 6 8 1 9 6 9 1 9 7 0

1971 1 9 7 2 1 9 7 3 1 9 7 4 1 9 7 5

1976

S h a d e d a r e a s r e p r e s e n t p e r i o d s o f b u s in e s s r e c e s s i o n s .
L a t e s t d a t a p lo t t e d : 4 th q u a r t e r

recession, the decline in the rate of inventory acccumulation was about 57 percent of the decline in
production. Even in the 1953-54 recession, about 36
percent of the decline in output reflected a decline in
the rate of inventory investment.4
However, the notion of an inventory recession in­
volves more than the relative size of fluctuations in
inventory investment and real GNP. The more general
concept of an inventory cycle, of which an inventory
recession is only one stage, implies a specific sequence
of changes in inventory investment before, during,
and after recessions.5

The Inventory Cycle Theory
An inventory cycle is a pattern of systematic fluc­
tuations in economic activity associated with inventory
adjustments. These adjustments are alleged to arise
because the desired level of inventory stocks is re­
lated to the expected sales rate. Consequently,
changes in expected sales affect inventory investment.
Moreover, changes in demand for inventory invest­
ment also influence actual and expected sales. In this
theory, such changes in investment spending are
believed to affect output and employment.
Table II

4These figures may understate the role of inventory invest­
ment during recessions. For example, in the first two quarters
of the 1953-54 recession, real output declined $9.8 billion
while inventory investment declined $10.1 billion.
“The first major theoretical attempt to explain inventory in­
vestment and the inventory cycle in terms of a relationship
between desired inventory investment and changes in the
level of sales is L. A. Metzler, “The Nature and Stability of
Inventory Cycles,” Review o f Econom ic Statistics (August
1941), pp. 113-29. A simple explanation and numerical
illustration of the inventory cycle may be found in many
textbooks, including Demburg and McDougall, M acroeco­
nomics, pp. 367-69. A good discussion of the inventory
investment models spawned by Metzler’s work may be found
in Evans, M acroeconom ic Activity, pp. 201-20.



Peak to Trough C h a n g e s in Real Inventory
Investment and Real G N P in Postwar Recessions

Recession

1 9 4 8 -4 9

Decline in Real
Inventory
Decline in
Investment
Real G N P
(Billions)
(Billions)
m

(2 )

$ -1 3 .0

$ - 4.7

Decline in
Investment as
a Percent of
Decline in G N P
[< l) / ( 2 )

X

100]

2 7 6 .6 0 %

1 9 5 3 -5 4

-

6.0

-1 6 .8

35.7

1 9 5 7 -5 8

-

9.9

-1 7 .4

1960-61

-

8.7

-

2.3

56.9
378.3

1 9 6 9 -7 0

-

3.5

-

6.1

57.4

1 9 7 3 -7 5

-4 5 .9

-8 1 .5

56.3

Page 5

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

The following is a scenario of how an inventory
cycle might occur. Some unexpected exogenous force
increases aggregate spending and stimulates a corre­
sponding change in production and employment.
Firms, reacting to their new sales, attempt to change
their inventory levels in the same direction through
inventory investment. Thus, further changes in total
spending, income and employment tend to occur. As
inventory approaches its desired level, firms reduce
their rate of spending on inventories causing aggregate
demand and output growth to slow. The slowing of
output growth is reinforced since it leads to a further
slowing of inventory investment. The reduction in in­
ventory investment brings sales and income growth to
a halt at the cyclical peak. As inventory investment
declines further, the economy enters a recession and
firms may actually attempt to meet sales by selling off
inventory stocks. Inventory stocks fall relative to sales
so firms reach a point where inventory replacement is
necessary, even to maintain the low recessionary sales
rate. Inventory restocking increases demand for goods
and services and provides the stimulus for a recovery
and the ensuing expansion.
Two basic observations about recessions emerge
from an inventory cycle theory. The first is that inven­
tory investment declines before and during the early
stages of such a recession, and often becomes negative
before beginning to recover. Second, inventory invest­
ment tends to recover before the end of a recession.
The pattern of inventory investment in the first five
postwar recession and recovery periods shown in
Chart II conforms to these relationships.6 In the first
four postwar recessions, inventory investment declined
before and during the recession, reached a negative
rate, and recovered before the end of the recession.
In the fifth recession, 1969-70, inventory investment
recovered before it reached a negative rate. In this
case, the rate of growth of inventory stocks slowed,
but firms did not actually reduce inventory stocks as
they had in the prior recessions.7
6This pattern does not demonstrate that these recessions were
“inventory recessions.” It does lend support to the importance
of the link between changes in expected sales and inventory
investment. This link and a monetary theory of recessions
yield the same pattern of inventory investment in recessions
and recoveries as that indicated by the inventory cycle theory.
"Barry Bosworth, “Analyzing Inventory Investment,” Brookings
Papers on Econom ic Activity (2 :1 9 7 0 ), pp. 207-27, argues
that “an inventory cycle is not an adequate frame of refer­
ence” for economic developments in the 1969-71 period.
Most of the argument rests upon the failure of inventory
investment to become negative during the recession although
this is not unusual in light of the extent of the decline in real
output. A pattern of inventory behavior in the 1969-70 period
similar to that in prior recessions may not have been evident
from the preliminary data available in 1970.

Page 6


APRIL

1977

Table III

A Simple Inventory Investment Model
Model:
where

It = a + P (GNPt - GN Pt-i) + £t
I = Constant Dollar Inventory Investment in
‘
Quarter t
xIr) _ Constant Dollar Gross National Product in
GNPt ~ Quarter t
Et = random variable
Sample period: I/1948-III/1973
It = 3.795 +

.374 (GNPt - G N P t-i) e
(5.4275) (5.8513)

R2 = .25
S.E. = 5.229

D.W. = .71

♦Values in Parentheses are “t ” statistics.

In the 1973-75 recession, inventory investment
did not follow the pattern of a typical inventory cycle.
Inventory investment did decline during the recent
recession, but it did not decline prior to the onset of
the recession. Instead, inventory investment rose
sharply to its highest postwar rate during the first
quarter of the recession. Moreover, inventory invest­
ment did not begin its recovery until the third quarter
of 1975, two quarters after the recession trough and
did not become positive until one year after the reces­
sion trough.

Inventory Investment and Output Changes
Since the notion of an inventory recession follows
from a relationship between inventory investment and
sales, it is useful to examine the relevance of this
relationship in the postwar period. This provides a
standard against which we may compare the be­
havior of recent inventory investment. A simple illus­
tration of the relationship between real inventory
investment and changes in real output or spending
(both at annual rates) is given in Table III for the
period from 1948 through the third quarter of 1973.8
While other important factors which influence inven­
tory investment are omitted, the relationship captures
the importance of sales growth inherent in the inven­
tory cycle theory.9
8Changes in real GNP may not be the appropriate measure of
sales, even for such a simple illustration. Several investiga­
tors have used different measures of aggregate sales. See, for
example, the survey by Victor Zamowitz, Orders, Production,
and Investm ent — a Cyclical and Structural Analysis ( New
York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1973), p. 352
and pp. 362-63; or Evans, M acroeconomic Activity, p. 217.
9Current changes in real output “explain" only 25 percent of
inventory investment. Also, the statistics suggest that other
important factors may have been ignored. Adjustment for this
potential problem, however, does not alter the conclusions
drawn from Chart IV.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

The postwar inventory-output relationship in Table
III implies the predicted inventory investment rates
in Chart IV, based on output changes since 1973. The
predicted pattern is very similar to the experience of
previous recessions. However, the rates implied by
this relationship are markedly different from the
actual inventory investment behavior shown there.
During the recession, actual inventory investment
exceeded, by extremely large amounts, the rates im­
plied by the postwar relationship. Beginning in the
last quarter of the recession (1/1975) and continuing
throughout the remainder of 1975, actual inventory
investment was much smaller than the rates implied
by the postwar relationship.
Other factors which affect inventory investment
apparently dampened the severity of the recession by
keeping inventory investment high.10 “Shortages,” the
termination of price controls in 1973, high rates of
inflation, and the fear of new price controls in 1974
probably pushed inventory investment above the
levels normally desired on the basis of output growth
alone. More importantly, firms apparently did not
anticipate the recession, its length, or its severity, and
were slow to lower production rates and inventory
investment. By the end of the recession, its severity
was more obvious and the excess inventory stock be­
came apparent as well. Thus, the forces which dom­
inated inventory investment during the recession also
dominated and dampened the recovery so that
throughout 1975, actual inventory investment was
much lower than the simple investment-output rela­
tionship indicates.
The unusually high rates of inventory investment
which apparently existed during most of the recession
began in the second quarter of 1973. Accumulating
the “excess” of actual investment over the amount
predicted on the basis of output growth from the
second quarter of 1973 yields $19 billion of “excess”
inventory stock by the end of 1974.11 The large rates
at which inventory stocks were depleted in the last
quarter of the recession and throughout the remainder
10Okun, “A Postmortem,” pp. 220-21, argues that forecasters
would have predicted GNP better for the second half of
1974, if they had accounted for the inventory-output rela­
tionship and the inventory cycle. Using seriously erroneous
predictions like those indicated in Chart IV for the second
half of 1974, they would have lowered their GNP forecasts
toward the actual results.
n Since the investment figures plotted in Chart IV are at
annual rates, the actual addition to stocks in each quarter
is one-fourth the indicated amount. Thus, excess inventory
accumulation is one-fourth the amount by which each quar­
ter’s actual investment exceeds the quarter’s estimated
investment.



APRIL

1977

A c t u a l a n d P re d ic te d R e a l In v e n t o r y In v e stm e n t*
B i ll io n s of D o lla r s

at A n n u a l R a te s

30

Predicted
the basis of

i

ii

in

iv

i

1973

ii

ill

1974

iv

i

ii

ill

iv

i

1975

ii

iii

iv

30

1976

‘ M e a s u r e d in 1 9 7 2 d o l l a r s .
S h a d e d a r e a r e p r e s e n t s a p e r i o d o f b u s i n e s s r e c e s s io n .
L a t e s t d a t a p lo t t e d : 4 th q u a r t e r

of 1975 eliminated these “excess” inventories. Adding
the amount by which actual investment fell short of
that implied by the postwar inventory-output relation­
ship yields a runoff of inventory stocks of about
$19 billion.12 Thus, after the first year of recovery
(1/1975 to 1/1976) the errors have cancelled out, and
the simple postwar relationship appears to hold as
well as it did in the earlier period.
The behavior of inventory investment in the recent
recession and recovery supports the view that firms
accumulated excessive inventories (relative to output)
in 1973 and that they continued to invest in excessive
inventories until the end of the recession. Beginning
in the last quarter of the recession and continuing
through the first year of recovery, firms sold off the
excess inventories, with aggregate inventory invest­
ment being negative throughout 1975.13 The rates
of inventory investment in 1976 were to be expected
12The estimates of the excess and run-off of inventories are
intended to illustrate the process which was present in
1973-75 and not the precise extent of the problem. The
actual depletion of inventory stock from the fourth quarter
of 1973 to the fourth quarter of 1974 was $12 billion
(see Chart I).
l:!This unusual behavior of inventory investment
major factor in explaining the unusual changes
portfolios during the first year of the recovery.
Gilbert, “Bank Financing of the Recovery,”
(July 1976), pp. 2-9.

in 1975 is a
in bank asset
See R. Alton
this Review

Page 7

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

as they were consistent with the moderate growth
of sales experienced during the year.

APRIL

1977

C h ari V

G r o w t h in R e a l G N P a n d R e a l F in a l S a le s *

THE 1976 “PAUSE”
An explanation of a “pause” in a recovery in terms
of the inventory cycle is that inventory is rebuilt by
rapid production until firms reach a desired level of
inventory stocks.14 As the inventory stock approaches
its desired level, production in excess of sales in order
to rebuild inventory stocks is no longer necessary so
that both production growth and inventory investment
slow.
Real GNP growth slowed in 1976, from a 7.3 per­
cent rate in the first year of recovery to a 4.2 percent
annual rate during the second and third quarters
of 1976. This was the pause which caused increasing
concern in the second half of last year. However, in­
ventory investment did not slow during the pause.
Instead, it was higher than the negative rates which
prevailed throughout 1975. Inventory investment was
steadily maintained at its higher rate, hovering around
$10 to $11 billion (constant dollars) through the first
three quarters of 1976. Thus, the data are not con­
sistent with the inventory cycle explanation of a
pause.15
Nevertheless, there does appear to be a connection
between inventory decisions and the slowdown in
growth of total output. In two quarters during the
first year of the recovery (III/1975 and 1/1976), there
were large increases in the rate of inventory invest­
ment. In each quarter, the increase in inventory
investment was matched by a sharp rise in production.
In the first case (III/1975), inventory investment rose
$20.2 billion, but remained negative. In the second
instance (1/1976), inventory investment rose $15.9
billion to a $10.4 billion rate.
The distorting effects of changes in inventory in­
vestment on the pattern of the recovery may be seen
in Chart V. Growth of real final sales (the difference
between output and inventory investment) has been
relatively constant since the trough in the first quarter
of 1975. The growth rate of real GNP has been more
14The nature of the 1976 economic slowdown is discussed
more fully by Neil A. Stevens and James E. Turley,
“Economic Pause — Some Perspective and Interpretation,”
this R eview (December 1976), pp. 2-7.
15It may be noted in Chart IV that the predicted inventory
investment rate based upon the earlier postwar relationship
in Table III follows the pattern described by the inventory
cycle explanation of the pause. Following the relatively high
rates of predicted inventory investment in 1975 and the first
quarter of1 1976, predicted investment declines from the first
through the third quarter of 1976.
Digitized forPage
FRASER
8


L a t e s t d a t a p lo t t e d : 4th q u a r t e r

erratic. In the two quarters when inventory invest­
ment increased rapidly (III/1975 and 1/1976), real
GNP growth surged upward. These increases in in­
ventory investment reflected the ending of the inven­
tory stock depletion. The same rate of final sales re­
quired an increased rate of production, since firms
were no longer willing to meet sales by depleting
stocks.
The apparent .slowdown in the rate of output
growth after a year of recovery was the result of
unusually high output growth in two quarters before
the pause. These two surges in output growth were
not due to changes in sustained forces affecting out­
put growth. Instead, they were associated with onceand-for-all production changes required by the ending
of the inventory adjustment. The rate of output
growth during the period of the pause reflected the
very steady moderate rate of growth of sales which
has existed since the beginning of the recovery.

CONCLUSION
The behavior of inventories in the recent recession
and recovery reflects the fact that businesses, like
many economists, under-anticipated the severity and
length of the decline in output. While the inventory
investment rate declined throughout the recession, it
remained positive and large, by historical standards, up
to the last quarter of the recession. After the recession

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

came to an end in early 1975, businesses continued to
adjust to the “excessive” levels of inventory which they
had accumulated. A net inventory run-off existed in
all four quarters of 1975. To the extent that inventory
adjustments cause production changes, it must be said
that inventory investment played a role of moderating
the decline in production and employment during the
recession and moderating the first three quarters of
the recovery.
As the inventory adjustment came to an end, large
increases in production rates were necessary to meet
moderately expanding sales. The aftermath of these




APRIL

1977

one-time adjustments in production rates in late 1975
and early 1976 was the apparent “pause” of 1976.
During the first quarter of 1976, positive inventory
investment was restored and continued at a steady
rate consistent with the moderate real output growth
experienced throughout most of 1976. Production
growth and inventory investment slowed markedly in
the fourth quarter of 1976 and, apparently, in the first
quarter of tjiis year. If the faster growth in final sales
experienced in the fourth quarter of 1976 persists, as
many observers expect, inventory investment is likely
to be higher in the remainder of 1977 than it was in
1976.

Page 9

The Effects of Changes in
Inflationary Expectations
RACHEL BALBACH
The following paper was prepared while Rachel Balbach was a visiting
scholar at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

0

VER the past twenty years, abundant attention
has been given, both in professional journals and in
the popular press, to the wealth redistribution which
occurs as a result of unanticipated inflation. Less
widely known but equally detailed work has been
done on the characteristics and allocative effects of
perfectly anticipated inflation. There have been, how­
ever, few examinations of the effects of revisions in
inflationary expectations and the adjustments which
accompany them. It may be that this is due to the
belief that such revisions take place extremely gradu­
ally, as was indicated by most empirical studies based
on adaptive expectations hypotheses, so that their
effects would be negligible in magnitude. More recent
work suggests that this may not be the case. In par­
ticular, the theory of rational expectations implies that
changes in inflationary anticipations occur much more
rapidly in response to policy changes than was previ­
ously thought. If there is any validity in this view, it
is worthwhile to investigate in detail the nature of the
ensuing adjustments and their effects. If those effects
are deemed to be undesirable, we can add yet another
argument to those which have already been advanced
against a monetary policy characterized by frequent
changes in the rate of money growth.
Whether inflation itself redistributes wealth among
net monetary debtors and creditors depends strictly
upon whether it was correctly or incorrectly antici­
pated. The phenomenon is by its nature ex post, with
any wealth effects which occur the result of past infla­

Digitized forPage
FRASER
10


tion. This paper, addressing a very different question,
argues that a change in inflationary expectations has
its own wealth transfer effect. That redistribution
occurs immediately as a result of a change in the ex­
pected rate of future inflation. Furthermore, it is of no
consequence whether the new expected rate of price
level increase turns out to have been right or wrong.
The adjustment to revised inflationary anticipations
causes shifts in both the nominal rate of interest and
the rate of return on existing real assets, affecting the
relative prices of claims to fixed amounts of money
and of nonmonetary assets according to their respec­
tive terms-to-maturity1 and productive life expec­
tancies. For example, an upward revision in the ex­
pected future rate of inflation will lead to a rise in
the nominal rate and a decline in the real rate. This
occurrence does in general accomplish a transfer of
wealth from monetary creditors to their debtors, an
’ In the case of a bond which provides interest payments over
the interval prior to maturity, there is a difference between
its “duration” and term-to-maturity. It is the bond’s dura­
tion which is the direct determinant of the effect of a change
in the nominal interest rate on its present value. For this
analysis, see Michael H. Hopewell and George G. Kaufman,
“Bond Price Volatility and Term to Maturity: A Generalized
Respecification,” American Econom ic Review (September
1973), pp. 749-53, and Frederick R. Macauley, Some T heo­
retical Problems Suggested by the M ovements o f Interest
Rates, Bond Yields and Stock Prices in the United States
Since 1856 (New York: National Bureau of Economic Re­
search, 1938). In this paper, I use the two terms synony­
mously, implicitly assuming that all bonds are paid interest
only at maturity.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

effect superficially resembling that of unanticipated
inflation. Unlike that situation, however, it is not
necessary in this case that net monetary debtors
(creditors) will gain (lose). What happens to the
individual unit’s wealth position depends on the timedimension characteristics of the particular assets and
liabilities on its balance sheet.

Wealth Transfer Under Unanticipated
Inflation
The term inflation refers to a fall in the value of
money, or equivalently, a rise in the level of prices of
real goods and services. Little, if any, consideration is
given to the relative price changes which may be
associated; usually, it is assumed that the prices of all
such goods increase proportionately.2 The only assets
which do not share in this price rise are claims to
fixed amounts of money, either immediately or in the
future; these are termed monetary assets. Thus, when
an unanticipated inflation occurs, those who have only
real assets and liabilities, or whose money-fixed claims
on others are just offset by monetary liabilities, are
unaffected, since by definition their nominal wealth
has changed in the same proportion as the price level.
Since the inflation had not been expected, no provi­
sion had been made for the lowered exchange-value
of the dollar, thus net monetary creditors, those whose
monetary assets exceed monetary liabilities, have less
wealth than they would in the absence of inflation.
Their loss is reflected in the gains of net monetary
debtors, whose nominal equity rises more than the
price level.
The loss to creditors (and the gain to debtors) is
the same whether the claims they hold are in the form
of cash, 30-day notes or 30-year mortgages, since by
definition an unanticipated inflation has not been ad­
justed for by a change in interest rates. Thus, if we
-Frequently, we encounter an insistence upon distinguishing
between a “once-and-for-all” increase in the price level as
opposed to a “continuous” or sustained rise, with the term
inflation generally reserved for the latter. For the issues
addressed here, that distinction is irrelevant; it is unnecessary
to speak of continuous rates of inflation although we typically
do so, perhaps as a convenient way of dealing with our
ignorance of past or expected future time-paths of price
change.
In the case of unanticipated inflation, the predicted wealth
effects do not at all depend upon the time-path of the rise
from one price level to another. Rather, they are a function
of the fall in the value of money and of claims to fixed
amounts of money in terms of real goods and services; no
systematic, predictable changes in the relative prices of those
goods are implied. Implicitly, the same assumption of constant
relative prices is made in discussions of anticipated inflation.
For this reason again, predicted wealth effects are due only to
the higher cost of holding money.



APRIL

1977

should observe that, overnight or over the course of
the past year, the price level has doubled, just as we
find that the $100 under the mattress still adds up to
$100, so does the bond of whatever maturity which
had a market price of $100 still maintain its nominal
value, and the real wealth reduction associated with
holding either comes strictly from the fact that its
purchasing power has been halved. This is the case so
long as we confine the analysis to that realized, unex­
pected inflation alone, without confounding its certain
effect on wealth with any effect that observations of
past changes in the price level may have on expecta­
tions for the future and so on interest rates. Nor does
the age of the debt affect the size of the creditor’s or
debtor’s wealth change. Rather, the gain or loss is
strictly a matter of how long over the period of rising
prices he holds monetary assets or owes monetary
liabilities of whatever vintage.

Wealth Transfer Due to Changes in
Inflationary Expectations
An upward revision in expectations as to the future
rate of inflation leads to a quite different set of events.
Interest rates adjust, the makeup of portfolios is
altered, and changes in the relative prices of assets
in these portfolios cause wealth transfer. The process
of adjustment involves a complex set of revisions
which occur simultaneously. For the sake of clarity of
exposition, however, we can assume that they take
place in consecutive steps.
We can begin with the commonly cited Fisher
effect which has been the basis for numerous esti­
mates of inflationary expectations.3 When the ex­
pected rate of price level change is zero, market
forces insure that the nominal rate of interest on
money-fixed obligations is equal to the rate of return
on real investment, with appropriate adjustment for
risk. If the expectation of price change is raised to
some positive number, the expected real value of
money-fixed future payments falls; that decline will
be capitalized in the form of lower present values of
existing claims. That is, the nominal rate of interest
will rise to a level which is higher than the real rate
by the amount of the expected rate of price increase,
and is the relevant interest rate for old and new loans
alike.
If we assume the rate of return on real assets to be
unchanged, the lower market price of existing bonds
:lIrving Fisher, The Rate o f Interest (New York:
Macmillan Company, 1907), pp. 77-86 and 356-73.

The

Page 11

APRIL

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

makes the expected real yield to their holders equiva­
lent to the real rate. The loss to bondholders and the
gain to their debtors is realized immediately, and no
further redistribution is envisioned. And the present
loss (gain) is greater the longer the term-to-maturity
of the obligation.4
But this is not the whole adjustment; in particular,
the assumption of a constant rate of return on real
assets is not justified. The perceived cost of holding
money balances is now higher, since their real value
is expected to decline with rising prices. In view of
this, people will attempt to reduce money balances by
shifting into other assets and, as a result, the prices of
those assets will rise. It is important at this point to
specify just what sort of asset substitution will take
place and which prices will rise as a consequence.
Traditionally, treatments of this phenomenon refer to
a one-shot price level surge as people attempt to shift
out of money and monetary assets into real assets.5
The easy inference, and one which apparently is
commonly drawn, is that there occurs an indiscrimi­
nate increase in the demand for real goods and serv­
ices which simply raises all prices proportionately.
But this is not the implication of the portfolio adjust­
ments made as people try to acquire assets whose
value will be protected from inflation. They will not,
for example, be willing to pay more now for current
services or highly perishable goods because they ex­
pect their prices to be higher a year hence; that is to
say, the demand for avocado trees will rise more than
the demand for avocados. Nor is there anything in
economic theory which implies that this behavior is
equivalent to an increase in consumption.6
The decline in the demand to hold money balances
is an increase in the demand for those real assets
4This assumes that the expected inflation rate is constant
through the time-horizon of the longest-term existing bond. If
this is not the case — if, for example, the anticipation is of a
higher near-term rate of inflation which will then be damp­
ened— the relative loss associated with longer term bonds
will be smaller.
5On this point, see Reuben A. Kessel and Armen A. Alchian,
“Effects of Inflation,” Journal o f Political Econom y (Decem­
ber 1962), pp. 521-37, upon which I have drawn heavily in
this article. Also see Martin J. Bailey, “The Welfare Cost of
Inflationary Finance,” Journal o f Political Econom y (April
1956), pp. 93-110, and much of the literature which de­
veloped from that work, surveyed in John A. Tatom, “The
Welfare Cost of Inflation,” this R eview (November 1976),
pp. 9-22.
6Joseph Bisignano, in his article, “The Effect of Inflation on
Savings Behavior,” Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco
Economic Review (December 1975), pp. 21-26, apparently
followed this line of reasoning to conclude that there is an
inverse relationship between the anticipated rate of inflation
and the savings rate.
Digitized forPage
FRASER
12


1977

whose nominal prices and income streams are ex­
pected to change with the price level and for bonds,
whose expected returns are equivalent, given their
now depressed market values. This raises the prices
of both forms of wealth, so that the nominal rate of
interest falls from its elevated level and the rate of
return on real assets also falls below its initial equili­
brium, with the difference between the two rates
continuing to reflect the expected rate of inflation.
The measured price level will, of course, shift up­
ward, but this is the result of a systematic, pre­
dictable change in relative prices.7 Just as the higher
nominal rate of interest means that the present value
of a bond falls by more the more distant its maturity,
so does the lower real rate imply that nonmonetary,
or real, assets will rise more in price the longer their
life expectancy.8

The Two Phenomena Compared
In sum, a rise in the anticipated future rate of infla­
tion causes (1) a rise in the nominal rate of interest
and a fall in the real rate, which changes the relative
prices of monetary and nonmonetary assets, and (2 ) a
rise in the measured price level of real goods and
services, which lowers real money balances for a given
level of nominal balances. This set of adjustments can
result in a transfer of wealth from net monetary
creditors to net monetary debtors, so that if we ob­
serve that such a wealth transfer has taken place
during a period in which prices have been rising, we
cannot safely take this as evidence that the inflation
was inadequately anticipated over that interval. But
the redistribution due to changed expectations is very
different in nature from that which occurs as a result
of realized, unanticipated inflation. As has been noted
above, the latter imposes losses on holders of all fixed
money obligations equally, whatever the form of those
obligations, because their nominal values remain con­
stant while those of real goods rise together. Net
monetary creditors must lose; net monetary debtors
must gain.
"It is this shift which accomplishes the reduction in real money
balances, insofar as the nonbank public cannot affect the
stock of money in existence.
8It may be argued that, given the definition of inflation pre­
sented in the previous section with its emphasis on constant
relative prices, this particular price level increase should be
given a different name. It really does not matter. The sig­
nificant distinction lies in the fact that these price changes
have different implications for wealth transfer than does
unanticipated inflation with its assumed constant relative
prices (see the following section) and that they occur as a
result of changed expectations which themselves take no
account of relative price changes.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL

1977

On the other hand, when the cause of the transfer
is expectation-induced changes in rates of return, the
size of gain or loss, and even its incidence, is deter­
mined by the longevity or terms to maturity of the
assets and liabilities of the individual economic unit.
For example, the smallest loss associated with holding
monetary assets is the one to cash balances, since their
nominal value remains constant. A greater loss to
bondholders must occur insofar as those debts are
existing obligations the terms of which cannot be
renegotiated on demand. Because of this, even a net
monetary creditor may gain (or a debtor lose).

Consider now a different story. There arises a new
expectation of future inflation. The portfolio adjust­
ments which ensue cause a rise in the nominal rate of
interest, say, of five percentage points, and a fall in
the real rate which in turn raises the measured price
level by three percent.11 The new balance sheet
reflecting these changes is

Consider only one example. Suppose we construct
a simple balance sheet for a net monetary creditor,
again defined as one whose claims to fixed amounts of
money exceed his money-fixed liabilities. His net
monetary assets of $100 comprise the difference be­
tween monetary assets held in the form of cash
($1100), and his monetary liability, which is a note
promising to pay $1100 in one year. Assuming that no
charge in the price level is anticipated and that the
market rate of interest is ten percent, the present
value of the note is $1000. His balance sheet is pre­
sented below:9

His real assets, assumed to comprise a representative
basket of goods, rise in nominal value with the price
level; the present value of his future liability, now
discounted at a 15 percent rate, immediately falls to
$957. The nominal value of his equity is $246, his real
wealth — that is, the value of his equity deflated by
the rise in the price level — has increased to $239,
and the net monetary creditor has gained.

Assets
Cash
G oods

Liabilities
1 10 0

Note

1000

100
Equity

200

Suppose there occurs an unanticipated increase in
the price level, but that the new level is expected to
persist. The market rate of interest will not be
affected; hence, only the nominal value of his real
assets will change, rising in proportion with the price
level, and his total real wealth (the constant-dollar
value of equity) must fall.10 Thus, if the price level
has doubled, the only entries on his balance sheet to
be affected are “goods,” the nominal value of which
becomes $200, and his equity, which consequently
rises to $300. Adjusted for the price level change, this
equity is $150, representing a fall in his real wealth of
25 percent.
“This balance sheet and those presented below differ from the
typical accounting balance sheet in that they record the
present values of both assets and liabilities, in order to reflect
their current market values and thus the actual present
wealth of the individual. The usual balance sheet, which
values assets at their historical costs and liabilities at maturity
(the note, for example, would be recorded at $1100), fails to
do this.
10For numerical illustrations of the wealth effects of unantic­
ipated inflation on net monetary creditors and debtors, see
Nancy A. Jianakoplos, “Are You Protected from Inflation?”,
this Review (January 1977), pp. 2-8.



Assets
Cash

Liabilities
1 10 0

G oods

Note

957

Equity

246

103

One small change in his original balance sheet will
alter considerably the effects of the same events. Let
his net monetary position remain constant, but sup­
pose that instead of holding all his monetary assets in
the form of cash, he lends out $1000 at the original
ten percent rate to be repaid at the end of two years;
compounded annually, his future claim is to $1210.
Given the same change in expectations with its con­
sequent adjustments, his new balance sheet is as
follows:
Assets

Liabilities

Cash

100

Loan

91 5

G oods

103

Note

957

Equity

161

His nominal equity, or wealth, has fallen by $39;
when his equity is expressed in constant-dollar terms,
the decline in real wealth is $44.
A similar exercise could be gone through for debtors
or considering real assets of different life expectancies
whose nominal values rise more or less than the price
level with consequent varying wealth effects. It would
serve merely to further point up the fact that the
phenomenon we are examining is more basically one
of relative price changes rather than price level
changes.
1'This price level rise implies neither that the rate of return
on real assets has fallen by 3 percent nor that the expected
inflation rate is 8 percent. The change in the average of all
prices due to a given change in the real rate depends upon
the distribution in terms of the productive durability of
existing goods and services.
Page 13

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Conclusion
If the adjustments consequent to a revision in in­
flationary expectations turn out to have reflected a
correct prediction, no further wealth transfers will
occur. But the accuracy of price level anticipations is
a whole separate issue; the change in expectations
itself, right or wrong, has behavioral, price and wealth
effects which should be acknowledged and identified.
This paper has dealt only with expectations of accel­
erated inflation; a downward revision in inflationary
anticipations will have symmetrical and opposite re­
distributional effects. That is, if the members of the
economy decide that the future rate of inflation will
be lower than they had before expected, the nominal
rate of interest will fall, the real rate will rise, and
corresponding changes in the values of monetary and
nonmonetary assets and liabilities will occur.
It follows from the foregoing discussion that a
monetary policy which is characterized by frequent
changes in the rate of money growth and thus insta­
bility in the rate of price change over time cannot


Page 14


APRIL

1977

avoid wealth transfers even if each rate change is
correctly anticipated before it occurs — even, indeed,
if it is announced in advance. It would be difficult to
characterize these transfers as anything but unin­
tended in terms of any generally accepted goals. The
deleterious effects on the economy of the increased
uncertainty engendered by such a policy have been
pointed out often. More recently, the proponents of
rational expectations have suggested that a counter­
cyclical monetary policy is ineffective in achieving
desired goals. In addition to these criticisms, the
apparent inevitability of unplanned wealth transfers,
whether as a result of incorrect anticipations or revi­
sions in them, provides a persuasive argument against
such a policy and in favor of stable money growth.12
12If the market’s expectations are of successful countercyclical
policy, such that the long-term anticipation is of a stable
price level (or a stable trend rate of inflation), it may be
that the wealth transfers will be negligible in size. The
valuation of long term assets then might be affected insig­
nificantly, while the impact on short-term assets in any case
is small. Presumably, in such a case, uncertainty also would
not be increased. It is by no means clear, however, that
expectations are indeed characterized by such confidence.

Food: Outlook Favorable for Consumers
NEIL A. STEVENS

TA HE 1977 outlook for food is generally favorable for
consumers. Despite damage to certain fruit and vege­
table crops last winter, large supplies and relatively
stable prices are in prospect for most foods.1 This was
the forecast of the U.S. Department of Agriculture at
its annual outlook conference and in recent releases.
The generally favorable outlook for food this year is
in contrast to the years 1973-75 when sharply reduced
supplies and unexpectedly large increases in export
demand resulted in sharp increases in domestic food
prices. The developments in those years led to a de­
cline in per capita food consumption and an increase
in the proportion of disposable income spent for food
— both of which were opposite to long-established
trends. With two years of large crop harvests as well
as an expansion in supplies of livestock foods begin­
ning in late 1975, consumers are again enjoying a
resumption of the long-run movement toward greater
per capita food consumption, and a declining propor­
tion of their income spent on food.

Agriculture Adjusts to Shocks of Early 1970s
The agricultural sector of the U.S. economy was
subjected to a number of disturbances in the early
1970’s which affected the demand for and supply of
food. These events included adverse weather condi­
tions both at home and abroad, major realignment of
international currencies, embargoes on grain ship­
ments, price and wage controls, and the oil embargo
and subsequent large increases in the price of energy.
As a consequence smaller quantities of food were pro­
duced for domestic consumption, and large increases
occurred in food prices.
In the past two years, the food sector has been
untangling itself from these destabilizing events. Agri­
cultural production was largely freed from Govern­
1See U.S. Congress, Senate, Committee on Agriculture and
Forestry, 1977 U.S. Agricultural Outlook, (Papers Presented
at the National Agricultural Outlook Conference Sponsored
by the U.S. Department of Agriculture, Washington, D.C.,
November 15-18, 1976, National Food Situation, U.S. De­
partment of Agriculture (March 1977) and Agricultural Out­
look, U.S. Department of Agriculture (March 1977).



ment production controls in 1973, and thus has.been
able to adjust fairly rapidly to the changing market
conditions. The enviornment for adjustments in the
food industry has been enhanced by the absence of
further severe shocks in the past two years. Export
demand has stabilized, domestic wage and price con­
trols have been removed, and embargoes have not
been used extensively.
Adjustments have occurred in both crop and live­
stock production. Disappearance of the major crop
inventories in 1972 and 1973, despite relatively high
crop production in these years, was followed by con­
siderably higher grain crop prices. Farmers responded
to the higher prices by increasing the acreage planted
to crops. The total acreage devoted to crops increased
over 10 percent from 1972 to 1976, but overall crop
production rose only about 8 percent. The failure of
crop production to rise as rapidly as the acreage de­
voted to crops reflects both somewhat less favorable
growing conditions in 1976, and the fact that new land
brought into production was generally less productive
than land previously in cultivation. Crop production
in the past two years, however, has been consider­
ably above the production in the drought-stricken
year of 1974.
Major adjustments in the livestock sector have also
occurred. Substantially higher feed prices in 1972 led
to an interruption in the upward trend in livestock
production. Such production declined in 1973, in­
creased somewhat in 1974, but fell again in 1975 as
the effects of the 1974 crop failure worked itself
through the livestock industry. Feeding operations
were cut back and animals were fed and marketed at
lighter weights for shorter periods of time. In 1976
total livestock production rebounded as production
was stimulated by higher livestock prices and lower
feed grain prices, as well as herd liquidation.

Food Demand Will Be Moderately Strong
in 1977 . . .
Demand for food is expected to increase in 1977.
One important source of fluctuation in growth of de­
Page 15

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

mand for food is the rate of gain in disposable income.
Incomes grew somewhat less rapidly in 1976 than
many analysts had hoped, but overall, the pace of the
recovery and disposable personal income gains have
been similar to those of other postwar recoveries.2
Expansion of disposable personal income is generally
expected to continue through 1977 as monetary and
fiscal policies have been generally consistent with
further economic expansion. Despite the cold weather
and natural gas shortages which hampered production
in the first quarter, real economic growth is expected
to average around 5 percent in 1977.3 Thus the de­
mand for domestic food is expected to expand again
this year.
Exports are also an important source of demand
which greatly influence the domestic food picture,
with farm exports now accounting for about 25 per­
cent of U.S. crop production. Export demand has
been rising rapidly in recent years as a result of
several factors including the realignment of interna­
tional currencies, some crop failures abroad, growing
world population, increased per capita incomes, and
the decision of the U.S.S.R. to increase livestock pro­
duction by importing grain from Western countries in
bad harvest years.
Growth of export demand is likely to be slowed
somewhat this year by a 10 percent increase in grain
production outside the United States. While the value
of U.S. agricultural exports is expected to edge above
the $22.8 billion in fiscal 1976, the volume of exports
is forecast to drop to 99.4 million metric tons from the
107 million metric tons in fiscal 1976.

... But

Food Supplies Will Also Expand

The dominant feature of the food outlook is the
supply of livestock and crop foods which has already
been produced or now is in the production process.
The general outlook is for the production of most foods
in 1977 to equal or exceed 1976 levels. This outlook,
of course, is subject to the vagaries of weather influ­
ences which could substantially alter crop output and
animal production patterns.

Crop Foods
Crop food supplies for the first half of 1977 have
been largely determined by 1976 harvests and stocks
2See Neil A. Stevens and James E. Turley “Economic Pause —
Some Perspective and Interpretation,” this Review, Decem­
ber 1976, pp. 2-7.
Agricultural Outlook, U.S. Department of Agriculture, January-February 1977, p. 4.

Page 16


APRIL

1977

carried over into the new marketing year. Total crop
production of food used for human and animal con­
sumption was the same in 1976 as in 1975. With sub­
stantially larger stocks carried over from the large
1975 harvest, total crop supplies available for con­
sumption this year were boosted above last year’s
level.
Cereals such as wheat and rice are among the most
plentiful crops. Wheat production in 1976 was about
the same as the record crop in 1975 and almost 20
percent above 1974. With larger stocks carried over
from the previous year, total wheat supplies for the
1976/77 year are almost 10 percent above 1975/76.
Hence, wheat supplies are adequate despite the un­
favorable crop conditions over much of the winter
wheat growing areas during the fall and winter. Rice
acreage and production was down last year, but a
five-fold increase in carry-in from the previous year
has resulted in a 14 percent increase in available sup­
plies in 1976/77. Farmers are planning to reduce rice
acreage this spring, but even with smaller production,
this season’s large inventories will keep supplies ade­
quate throughout the year.
Prospects are for a significant increase in supplies
of world sugar in 1976/77. The world sugar crop was
about 96 million short-tons, up 6 percent from a year
earlier. Consumption of sugar is expected to increase
less than the increase in production; hence, carryover
stocks at the close of the year is likely to be higher
and is expected to represent about one-fourth of world
consumption. However, the tariff on imported sugar
was increased from 62.5 cents per cwt. to $1.87 per
cwt. last fall and the price of raw sugar is not likely
to change much from current levels.
Oil crop supplies are dominated by soybeans. Last
year’s 18 percent reduction in soybean production has
reduced oil supplies for much of 1977. However, in­
creasing lard and cottonseed oil production will par­
tially offset the decline in soybean oil. Currently,
favorable soybean prices are expected to boost acre­
age this spring and with favorable weather conditions,
soybean supplies should be somewhat more plentiful
by late this year.
Coffee supplies have been sharply reduced as a
result of a severe frost in Brazil in 1975 and coffee
prices have been rising ever since. The world crop in
1976-77 is estimated at 62 million bags, down from 73
million bags a year ago. Furthermore, coffee produc­
tion is expected to be hampered for at least another
two years as trees recover from the severe freeze and
new trees reach maturity.

APRIL

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Supplies of fresh vegetables were sharply reduced
by the severe weather conditions of this past winter
as well as reduced acreage of some crops. Florida
crops such as tomatoes, peppers, snap beans, cucum­
bers, and eggplant were severely damaged by a freeze
while some other crops such as cabbage, celery, let­
tuce, escarole, radishes and sweet corn escaped much
of the damage. In addition, Texas vegetable crops
such as cabbage and carrots were reduced due to cold
and wet weather conditions as well as planned acre­
age reductions. As a result of the smaller supplies of
fresh vegetables, the fresh vegetable component of the
food price index in the first quarter was approximately
20 percent above a year earlier, which translates into
approximately a 1 percent increase in grocery store
food prices.
Replanted vegetable crops scheduled to be mar­
keted this spring are expected to lead to sharply
falling fresh vegetable prices. However, the vegetable
situation, both fresh and processed, could be further
complicated this summer by lack of irrigation water in
some parts of the western states. The impact of the
western drought, however, may not be too severe.
Current water supplies in the southern California pro­
ducing areas generally are adequate, while conserva­
tion of water supplies and smaller acreages of less
valuable crop such as rice, alfalfa and other field crops
in other areas will allow the scarce water supplies to
be applied to the more valuable vegetable and fruit
crops.
Supplies of processed vegetables, measured by
stocks of canned and frozen vegetables early this year,
are below the relatively high levels of a year ago, but
potato supplies are quite large as the fall crop was at
a record 300 million cwt. The 1976 dry bean crop was
slightly below a year ago but availability of other
relatively cheap animal proteins has resulted in the
sluggish demand for this crop.
Prospective supplies of fresh and processed fruits
are mixed. Citrus crops were expected to be at a
record level this year, about 17 percent above last
year’s record crop. Substantial freeze damage has re­
duced the Florida citrus production to around 183
million boxes, just slightly above last year’s crop.
However, the juice yield will be down so that the
amount of frozen orange juice from the Florida crop
may be 6 to 9 percent below last season. Total citrus
production from all producing areas was slightly
above the previous season’s production.



1977

Livestock Foods
Production decisions made last year and early this
year have insured relatively large supplies of live­
stock products for the first half of 1977. Supplies of
red meats, particularly pork, are expected to remain
relatively large in the first half of 1977, despite un­
favorable profit margins for cattle and hog producers
last year. Beef production in the first half of the year
is expected to be slightly below a year ago, but pork
production will likely be one-fifth above year earlier
levels and will more than offset the decline in beef
output. Broiler production is expected to increase
further during the year although less favorable profit
margins should slow the rate of gain. Overall livestock
production in the first half of the year will likely ex­
ceed that of a year ago.
Milk production is expected to remain somewhat
above year-earlier levels in the first half of this year.
But as was recently pointed out by the Federal Re­
serve Bank of Chicago, the consumer is not likely to
enjoy any gains, in terms of lower milk prices, from
the expanding output.
Higher dairy support prices becam e effective today
(April 1, 1 9 7 7 ) in line with the recent announcement
by the Administration. T he increase boosts the sup­
port price for manufacturing milk to $9 per hundred­
weight, up from the $ 8 .2 6 level that had prevailed for
the past six months and $ 8 .1 3 imposed one year ago.
T h e rise in the support price comes in the face of
increasing production, stagnating consumption, and
mounting government stocks — trends that will no
doubt b e reinforced by the higher support prices.4

Prospects for livestock production for the second
half of 1977 are for increases in pork production to
slow as lower hog prices than a year ago will tend to
discourage farmers from rapidly increasing farrowings
this spring. By the fourth quarter of 1977 pork pro­
duction may be 4 to 6 percent above the relatively
high fourth quarter of 1976. Beef output is expected
to taper off later this year to about 6 to 8 percent
below a year ago. Beef output will be constrained by
a reduced inventory which early this year stood 6.8
percent below the level of two years ago. Broiler and
egg production is expected to make only moderate
gains in the second half of the year. On balance, live­
stock production in the second half of the year is ex­
pected by the U.S.D.A. to fall somewhat below year
ago, however, production for the entire year will
likely average slightly above last year.
4See Gary L. Benjamin, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago
Agricultural L etter (April 1, 1977).
Page 17

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL

Food Prices May Rise Only Moderately
Rising food prices were of great national concern in
1973 and 1974 as these prices rose more rapidly than
prices of other goods and service. Retail food prices
increased over 14 percent in both 1973 and 1974, while
retail prices of items other than food increased 3.9
and 9.9 percent, respectively. This situation has re­
versed in the past two years with more abundant food
supplies and a slower growth in export demand. Re­
tail food prices increased 8.5 percent in 1975, slightly
less than the 9.3 percent increase for items other than
food. In 1976 food prices increased only 3 percent
over 1975, about one-half the rate of increase of other
retail prices. Domestically produced foods purchased
at grocery stores rose only about lV i percent in 1976.
Imported foods and food eaten away from home
contributed the remainder of the higher cost of food
last year.
Food prices will likely rise less rapidly than other
prices this year. Although winter damage to vegetable
crops, along with greater than seasonal increases in
prices of coffee, eggs, and fish has increased the food
costs early this year, large supplies for most foods will
keep food price increases at a moderate level. Some
of the large increases in food prices early this year,
particularly fresh vegetables, should prove temporary,
as these prices are expected to decline sharply with
Retail Food Prices
1967=100

1967=100

1977

Table 1

PER C A P IT A F O O D C O N S U M P T IO N
(1 9 6 7 =

1 00 )

Year

Anim al Products

Crops

Total Food

1967

100.0

100.0

100.0

1968

101.5

101.1

101.2

1 96 9

101.2

102.0

101.5

1 97 0

102.5

103.1

102.8

1971

103.8

102.8

103.3

1972

103.6

104.1

103.8

1973

99.1

105.3

101.9

1974

101.9

103.8

102.8

1975

99.9

104.9

102.2

1976

103.7

106.8

105.1

Sou rce: Agricultural Outlook,
(March 1977), p. 28.

U .S .

Department

of

Agriculture

the harvesting of spring vegetables. The U.S. Depart­
ment of Agriculture projects that retail food prices at
grocery stores for all of 1977 will average 3 to 5 per­
cent higher than in 1976. Also, contributing to an
increase in overall retail food prices will be price
increases for food eaten away from home. Such prices
may rise somewhat more than grocery store prices,
possibly around 6 percent. Increased prices of coffee,
fishery products, and other imported foods are ex­
pected to account for approximately one-half of the
rise in retail food prices this year. The remainder will
be associated with higher marketing margins as aver­
age farm prices will likely remain unchanged from a
year ago.
This range for food prices reflects varying assump­
tions of weather conditions. The 5 percent estimate
takes into account some possible underestimation of
the impact on prices from the bad weather this winter
as well as problems which could result from continued
drought conditions in the West. Drought in livestock
producing areas could alter the pattern of livestock
prices as forced liquidation of herds would lower
prices around mid-year followed by higher prices later
this year. On the other hand, the 3 percent projection
assumes more favorable weather conditions during
this year’s growing season resulting in large crop har­
vests both in the U.S. and abroad.

*C P I F o o d d iv id e d b y C P I A l l Ite m s L ess F o o d




So u rce: U.S. D e p a rtm e n t of L a b o r

As a result of the favorable price and supply condi­
tions for food last year, per capita consumption of
food rebounded sharply from 1975. U.S. per capita
consumption of all foods increased almost 3 percent
in 1976 with the strongest gain coming from animal
products. But per capita consumption of crop food
also made gains (Table I). Per capita consumption of

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL

Table II

Percent o f D isp o sa b le Personal Incom e Spent on Food
Food for Use
at Home

Food A w a y
from Home

Total
Food
Expenditures

I9 6 0

1 6 .1 %

4 .1 %

2 0 .2 %

1965

14.2

4.0

18.2

1 97 0

13.4

3.9

17.3

1971

12.7

3.7

16.4

1972

12.5

3.8

16.3

1973

12.5

3.8

16.3

1 97 4

13.1

3.9

17.0

1 975

13.0

4.1

17.1

12.7

4.1

16.8

1 97 6

Source: Agricultural Outlook,
(March 1977), p. 9.

U .S.

Department

of

the 16.3 p e r c e n t in 1972. The percent of total dis­
posable income spent on food this year will probably
be slightly less than last year.

Summary
Food prices in 1976 rose less rapidly than the over­
all inflation rate in contrast to the 1973-75 period.
Consumers found that they spent a smaller percentage
of their income on food while buying increased quan­
tities. This favorable situation resulted from increased
supplies as normal weather conditions, relatively free
pricing, removal of production controls, and lack of
other shocks to the agricultural economy led to sig­
nificant gains in production.

Agriculture

food is likely to make some further gains this year
although the increase will likely be less than in 1976.
Not only did U.S. consumers buy more food, but
they spent a smaller percent of their disposable in­
come on food in 1976 than a year earlier. Table II
shows that U.S. consumers from 1960 through 1972
spent less and less of their income on food. Consumers
spent 16.8 percent of their income on food last year,
down from 17.1 percent in 1975, but still higher than




1977

The reasonably good crop harvest in 1976, and
livestock production already in progress assures fairly
large supplies of food, at least in the first half of 1977.
The staple foods such as cereal crops, livestock foods,
potatoes, and sugar are in plentiful supply. On the
other hand, several fruit and vegetable items, fishery
products, and coffee are in short supply. However,
supplies of most vegetables are expected to return to
normal this spring. On balance, relatively large sup­
plies of food are expected to limit increases in grocery
store food prices to around 3 to 5 percent during 1977.

Page 19