View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FE D E R A L R ES ER V E B A N K
APRIL 1969
O F S T . L O U IS

tonetary Actions, Credit Flows
and Inflation.......... ............................ 2

EIGHTH D
LITTLE RO CK

Monetary & Fiscal Actions: A Test of
Their Relative Importance in
Economic Stabilization — Comment ........ 6
— R e p ly ............. 12
Towards A Rational Exchange Policy: Some
Reflections on the British Experience........ 17

Vol. 51, No. 4




Member Bank Income—

1968 .................. 27

Monetary Actions,
Credit Flows and Inflation

I HE INFLATION of prices and interest rates over
the past four years has resulted from excessive total
demand. Spending growth has averaged 7.7 per cent
per year since 1965, while the capacity of the econ­
omy to produce has been growing at an estimated 4
per cent rate. The Federal budget changes in June
1968 were designed to slow total spending. Late in
the year a policy of monetary restraint was adopted.
Since about mid-January, the growth rates of several
strategic monetary variables have moderated, but
there is no firm evidence that the rate of growth of
total spending has decelerated. If the inflationary
trend of spending is to be checked, the recently ob­
served slowing of growth in Federal Reserve credit,
E m p lo ym e n t
R a tio S c a le

R a tio S c a le

M il li o n s o f P e r s o n s

M il li o n s o f P e r s o n s

S easonally Adju ste d

80

80
^ 7 7 .8
To ta l

+2.5%

*377.___ .
+1 6%

70

-2.37.

+477,

+36%

_ ^ 7 0 .1

60

60

+

Payroll

O c t .'6

Feb 61

1961

1962

1963

1964

Dec 6 5

1965

1966

a

a

Jj

5

It

♦

1967

1ar.69
t

1968

1969

Source: U.S. D epo rtm ent of Labor
Percentage are annua rotes of chonge between periods indicated. They are presented to aid in comparing
mo$t recer tdevelopm snts wilh past "trends."
Latest date plotted:

Page 2

70

+ 0 7 % ^-

larch preliminary




member bank reserves, monetary base and the money
supply must be sustained.

Spending, Employment and Prices
Total spending in the fourth quarter grew at an
estimated 8 percent annual rate, about the same as
the average rate for the past four inflationary years.
Spending growth in the last half of 1968 was at an
8.3 per cent annual rate, compared with a 10.6 per
cent rate in the first half. Though slight moderation

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL, 1969

M o n e y Stock
Ratio Seals
Billions of Dollars
210

Ratio Scale
Billions of Dollars
210

M onthly A v e ra g o t of D o ily Figures

205

205

200

200

+2 3 %

195

194.2

190

195

+6

185

180

180

175

175
A-

f~ _
^

'

170

~

165

165

160
155
150

Monetary Actions in the Last Half of 1968

190

185

170

the Federal budget is now planned to show more
rapid growth of receipts than of expenditures during
1969. Revised fiscal plans may be viewed as pro­
viding slightly more restraint on total spending as
1969 progresses.

Apr.'66

Jan. 67

00
S3

o
S3

Q

5

160
155

11 Iti 11 m 111 Iti 1111111111 11 11111 111 ill 1iti 11 11i 11 1 150
1966

1967

1968

1969

Percentages a re a n n u a l rates of c h a n g e between periods indicated. They are presented
to a id in com paring m ost recent developm ents with p ast "trends."
Latest d ata plotted: M a rc h prelim inary

from early 1968 may be evident, total spending con­
tinued to advance well in excess of the growth rate
of the economy’s productive potential.
Developments since late 1968 show no indication
of a significant decline in the rate of increase of total
spending. Industrial production has risen at a 6.5 per
cent annual rate since September compared with a
5 per cent rise in the previous year. Payroll employ­
ment has increased at a 6 per cent rate since fall
compared with 2 per cent in the previous year. Whole­
sale prices of industrial commodities have risen at
about a 4.5 per cent annual rate since August, com­
pared with a 2.5 per cent rate in the previous year.

Federal Budget Prospects
The influence of the June 1968 fiscal action on
total spending and inflation appears to have been
slight. The restraining effects of the tax surcharge and
the slowdown in Federal spending growth in the last
half of 1968 were offset by stimulative monetary ac­
tions and private anticipations of continued inflation,
both of which provided impetus to private spending.

Judgment differs greatly as to the influence of
monetary factors on the course of total spending in
the last half of 1968 and in early 1969, depending
on which monetary measures are considered and how
they are interpreted. As enactment of the fiscal pro­
gram became assured in late May of 1968, the finan­
cial and business public was persuaded that the
Government’s demand for funds would be reduced.
Private demand for loan funds declined and, conse­
quently, interest rates declined. Lower market inter­
est rates relative to Regulation Q ceilings (maxi­
mum rates which commercial banks are permitted to
pay on time deposits) resulted in a large flow of
funds to banks. The reduction of discount rates in
August was a minor adjustment to lower market in­
terest rates. Ry September and October, the demand
for loan funds was again pushing market interest rates
upward.
The rapid growth of bank credit and money plus
time deposits (Mo) in the last half of 1968 was
caused by the reduced level of market interest rates
relative to Regulation Q ceilings. To the extent that
there was a decline in the rate of growth of demand
M o n e y Stock Plus Time Deposits
Ratio Scale
Billions of Dollars
430
420

420

410

410
/ I

400

400

390




390

23%

380

+98° /

380

Jr

370

370

360

360

350

//

340

Recently announced revisions of budget expendi­
ture plans indicate a more restrictive course for fiscal
actions than was first planned in January. The highemployment budget is expected to rise from a $4
billion annual rate of surplus in the first quarter to
$8 billion in the second quarter, then revert to about
a $6 billion rate of surplus by late 1969. Adjusted
for make-up tax payments in the second quarter,

Ratio Scale
Billions of Dollars
430

M onthly A v e ra g e s of D a ily Figures

350
340

+27%_s

330

330

320

320

310
300

Apr. 66
—

Nov.'6t

1----------------1 _

1966

Q
1111 111 11 1 1

1967

310

M ar '69

1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1, i iti 1 1 1 1 1 1 11

1968

1969

300

Percentages are a nn ual rates of ch an ge between periods indicated. They a re presented
to a id in c om paring most recent developm ents with p ast "trend s."
Latest d ata plotted: M a rc h p relim inary

Page 3

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

deposits and money stock (Mj) after midyear, it
appears to have been fostered by absorption of re­
serves by the increased time deposits rather than by
any tightening of policy.
Monetary aggregates more closely related to central
bank actions, when viewed collectively, did not ad­
vance much differently in the last half of the year
than in the first half. Federal Reserve credit grew
less rapidly in the second half, and member bank
reserves more rapidly. The monetary base grew at a
rather steady 6.5 per cent annual rate throughout the
year. Growth of the money stock was at a 6.8 per
cent annual rate in the first half of the year and at
a 6.2 per cent rate in the last half.

Monetary Actions in Early 1969
There are clear indications that monetary influence
has become restrictive since late 1968. The monetary
base has increased at a 3.4 per cent annual rate in
the past three months, well below the 6.5 per cent
rate of the past two years. Money stock growth has
slowed to a 2.3 per cent rate in the last three months,
after increasing 6.5 per cent in the previous year.
The money stock defined to include U.S. Government
deposits has declined at a 1.2 per cent annual rate in

APRIL, 1969

the past three months, compared with a 6.2 per cent
increase in the previous 12 months.
If the deceleration in growth of money and other
strategic monetary aggregates is sustained, given the
apparent continued strength in loan demand, interest
rates may well continue to rise, but such increases
are likely to be temporary. When the rate of growth
of total spending and inflationary expectations de­
cline, the demand for loan funds will be slowed, and
interest rates may be expected to decline.
Market interest rates have risen well above the rates
which banks are allowed to pay on deposits, resulting
in a channeling of funds outside banks since Decem­
ber, reversing the process of the last half of 1968.
Reflecting these developments, the outstanding
amounts of bank credit and M2 have declined. Such
declines do not necessarily indicate severe monetary
restraint. When banks are restricted by Regulation
Q from paying competitive rates on earning assets,
the demand for time deposits declines. As the quan­
tity of M2 has been limited by Regulation Q, the
demand has declined as well. When the flow of funds
through banks is restrained by Regulation Q, the
flow through other channels is increased correspond­
ingly.

M o n e y M arket Rates
Ratio Scale

Ratio Scale

A Special Restraint on
Commercial Banks
Credit markets in general have been
placed under special pressure due to
the great demand for loan funds, and
since mid-January, by a slowing in the
growth of Federal Reserve credit,
monetary base, bank reserves, and
money ( Mt ). Commercial banks have
been in particular difficulty because
they are subject to the exceptional re­
striction of Regulation Q on the flow of
funds, and more recently to a higher re­
serve requirement on demand deposits.

L a te st d a t a plotted: M a r c h

Page 4



The effect of Regulation Q ceilings
is to reroute the flow of funds away
from commercial banks when market
interest rates rise above such ceilings,
without clearly limiting the marginal
creation of money and credit. If Regu­
lation Q ceilings had been raised in
November, and banks had been able
to retain and gain deposits, there prob­
ably would have been no less over-all
monetary restraint, but unnecessary

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL,

1969

Bank Loan Rates
Ratio Scale

Yields on Selected Securities

□ .M o n th ly a v e r a g e s of d a ily figures.
Latest d a ta plotted: M a r c h

wrenchings of the financial system as funds were
rerouted would have been avoided.

The Discount Rate
As market interest rates have risen since last Sep­
tember in response to increasing demand for loans,
they have also risen relative to the Federal Reserve
discount rate. In September the commercial paper
rate was 57 basis points above the discount rate, and
in March the spread increased to 98 points. Bank
borrowings from Reserve Banks increased from $515
million last September to $750 million in March, and
to over $1 billion just prior to the raising of the
discount rate from 5% per cent to 6 per cent on
April 4.
These borrowings were stimulated by the increas­
ingly advantageous spread between discount rates
and market rates, by the demand for loan funds, by
the deprivation of funds to the banks by limits on
interest rates they can pay, and after mid-January,
by slower growth in strategic monetary aggregates.
The increased borrowing from the Federal Reserve,
in and of itself, has been conducive to the increase
of bank reserves and thereby to expansion of bank
credit, demand deposits and the money supply.



Ratio Scale

Rates charged by commercial banks
have been under strong upward pres­
sure because of buoyant total spending
in the economy. This pressure has been
especially intense because the limita­
tion on interest rates which banks can
pay on deposits has severely limited
the supply of funds to banks. Banks
have been under pressure to increase
their rates even faster than interest
rates have been rising generally. One
way to relieve upward pressure on bank
loan rates would be to reduce limita­
tions on the supply of funds to banks by
raising Regulation Q ceilings. However,
such an action would have little effect
on the basic supply and demand forces
operating on interest rates.

Interest rates, in general, can be re­
duced only by slowing the growth in
total spending and thereby the total
demand for loan funds. Containment of
total spending and inflation is contin­
gent on continuation of reduced rates
of growth of Federal Reserve credit, the monetary
base, bank reserves, and the money supply.

Summary
Commercial banks have been placed under special
pressure by the workings of Regulation Q, though
this does not indicate pressure from the monetary
authority on credit markets in general. Monetary re­
straint comes only from reduced monetary expansion.
There are substantial indications that such a slowing
has occurred, but the impact of these slower growth
rates will be effective only if they are sustained over
a longer period of time.
Experience of the past 20 years indicates that the
effects of monetary action on total spending are not
felt for several months, and that price effects of total
spending are not observed until several quarters after
that. If the recently reduced rate of monetary expan­
sion is continued, growth of total spending is likely
to moderate significantly by midyear. However, even
when firm indications of deceleration of total spend­
ing become evident, significant deceleration of price
increases may not become apparent for several
quarters.
Page 5

E

d it o r ’s

Note:

The following two articles have evolved from the article, titled “Monetary and Fiscal Actions: A Test of
Their Relative Importance in Economic Stabilization,” presented in the November 1968 issue o f this R e v i e w .
Frank de Leeuw is now a Senior Staff Member at the Urban Institute in Washington, D.C. and was formerly
Chief o f the Special Studies Section, Division o f Research and Statistics at the Roard of Governors o f the Fed­
eral Reserve System. John Kalchbrenner is an economist in the Special Studies Section, Division of Research and
Statistics at the Roard of Governors. Their “Comment” presents several important considerations for the reader,
and tends to emphasize the volume of work remaining for economists and analysts interested in the current dis­
cussion of the role of money and monetary policy.
The “Reply,” by Leonall C. Andersen and Jerry L. Jordan, attempts to clarify the areas of disagreement be­
tween them and the authors of the “Comment.” In many instances, clarification consists of answering the specific
questions about their model and reinforcing their original position, rather than adjusting any of the theory and
procedures behind the model.

Monetary and Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their Relative
Importance in Economic Stabilization - Comment
by FRANK DE LEEUW and
JOHN KALCHBRENNER1
RECENT ARTICLE by Andersen and Jordan
answers many of the criticisms of earlier single-equa­
tion studies of the relation between money and in­
come.2 It makes use of distributed lags instead of fixedpoint lags. It uses high-employment Federal receipts
and expenditures instead of actual receipts and ex­
penditures. It represents monetary policy by the mone­
tary base as well as the money supply. These technical
improvements should make their conclusion that fiscal
policies have no perceptible effect on GNP move­
ments all the more disturbing to those of us who have
been inclined to believe that fiscal policies have power­
ful effects on income.
The purpose of this “Comment” is to examine
whether these conclusions hold up under a careful
examination of the statistical requirements of single­
JW e wish to thank the staff of the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis, especially Messrs. Andersen and Jordan, for
supplying us with data and for making the pages of the
Review available to us. This “Comment” was first presented
at a seminar at the Federal Reserve Board on January 16,
1969, and was followed by a lively and helpful discussion
by Messrs. Andersen, Jordan and other colleagues in the
Federal Reserve System. Responsibility for the statements in
this “Comment” rests, of course, solely with the authors.
2This article, “Monetary and Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their
Relative Importance in Economic Stabilization,” by Leonall
C. Andersen and Jerry L. Jordan, appeared in the November
1968 issue of this Review, pp. 11-24.
Page 6



equation models and their presence or absence in the
Andersen-Jordan equations. We are led, in the course
of the examination, to try some alternative equations
with important differences in results. The alternative
equations seem to us to cast considerable doubt on
the Andersen-Jordan skepticism about fiscal policy.

The Statistical Requirements of
Single-Equation Models
Two different ways of describing the St. Louis equa­
tions bring into focus the central problem that has
concerned us. One way to describe the equations is
to say that they are attempts at using multiple regres­
sion to measure the influence on GNP of certain ex­
ogenous government policy variables. By exogenous
we here mean variables that can be heavily and
directly influenced by policymakers. Variables which
are not easily influenced by policymakers are not par­
ticularly useful ones to have in a regression, except
as they reduce uncertainty about the coefficients of
the policy variables.
A second way to describe the St. Louis equations
is that they are reduced forms of some underlying
more complex model of the economy. In any model
of this kind the current endogenous variables —the
ones the model attempts to explain —depend on past

APRIL,

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST LOUIS

values of the endogenous variables and on the ex­
ogenous variables. By exogenous we now mean vari­
ables which do not respond to current movements in
the endogenous variables.3 By solving for the past
endogenous variables, we can in principle reduce the
system to a relation between each current endogenous
variable and current and lagged exogenous variables.
A linear relation between GNP and exogenous vari­
ables is a simple approximation to such a reducedform relationship. Relations between the general price
level and exogenous variables or some interest rate
and exogenous variables would be other reduced-form
relationships. From a statistical viewpoint, the assump­
tion that the exogenous variables do not respond to
movements of the endogenous variables is crucial. For
if we call exogenous in a GNP equation some “X”
which itself strongly responds to current economic
developments, we don’t know whether we are measur­
ing the influence of “X” on the economy, the economy
on “X,” or some third force on both “X” and the
economy.
These two descriptions of the St. Louis equations
use the word exogenous in two different senses. In
the first description exogenous means a variable sub­
ject to control by policymakers, while in the second,
exogenous means a variable which does not respond
to current endogenous forces. Clearly these two
definitions do not correspond. The best known ex­
ample of a conflict is the case of tax receipts. Tax
receipts are exogenous in the policy sense of being
subject to manipulation by policymakers, but they
are clearly not exogenous in the statistical sense of
not responding to current movements in the en­
dogenous variable income.
The art of learning something from single-equation
regressions of the St. Louis type consists in devising
variables which can be manipulated by policymakers
but which have been adjusted in such a way they are
not terribly sensitive to current movements in the
endogenous variables. If an explanatory variable does
not meet the first requirement, it is not an effective
policy instrument. If it does not meet the second
requirement, then it is impossible to know what is
influencing what, or how serious the problem of bias
is in the equation. Failure to meet this second require­
ment has been a major criticism of regressions of GNP
3The statistical requirement is that exogenous variables be
independent of the disturbance terms of the system. Failure
to meet this requirement implies that an exogenous variable
is not independent of the endogenous variables, and is what
we mean by an exogenous variable “responding” to move­
ments in endogenous variables.




1969

on the money supply.4 Only if we can devise fiscal
and monetary policy representations which get around
this second problem will the single-equation approach
be able to tell us something about the effects of
macroeconomic policies.
Andersen and Jordan are clearly aware of this prob­
lem of devising variables that are exogenous under
both definitions. That is presumably the reason for
using high-employment Federal receipts and expendi­
tures which are clearly much less affected by current
endogenous movements in income than are actual
receipts and expenditures. It also is the most power­
ful reason, it seems to us, for using the monetary base
rather than the money supply. They have clearly
moved in the right direction in both these respects.
Our central doubt about the article, however, is
whether they have gone far enough in purging their
policy variables of the influence of current movements
in economic activity. We feel that both the tax
variable and the monetary base variable may still
reflect the influence of current economic develop­
ments, and this leads us to try to represent monetary
and fiscal policies by time series which are not quite
the same as those of Andersen and Jordan.

The Reduced-Form Approach
Before examining the tax and monetary base
variables, however, we would like to make two gen­
eral remarks about the reduced-form or single-equa­
tion approach. One is that while there is much we
can do in the way of adjusting policy measures for
obvious and measurable endogenous influences, it is
extremely difficult to devise variables which fully
meet both definitions of exogenous. The problem is
not simply that the variables policymakers influence
are also influenced by current economic develop­
ments; part of the problem is that policymakers them­
selves are naturally influenced in their decisions by
current developments. We may conjecture, however,
that the endogenous responses of policymakers are
much less mechanical or predictable than, say, the
influence of income fluctuations on tax receipts, and
are less hkely to be serious sources of bias.
The second remark is that there are a host of other
problems with the single-equation approach. Many
exogenous variables (in the statistical sense) have
to be left out while others are aggregated to crowd
everything into one equation, in spite of likely dis­
4For example, see the criticism of the Friedman-Meiselman
results by Ando and Modigliani in the American Economic
Review, September 1965, pp. 711-13.
Page 7

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST LOUIS

similarities in effects. There is no obvious reason why
these problems should bias the coefficients in one
direction and not in another for the included variables.
If we were trying to devise the most useful single
equation, however, there are other modifications we
would try. We do not do so here in order to stay
within the spirit of the Andersen-Jordan article.

Fiscal Variables
The tax variable is represented in the St. Louis
article by high-employment receipts in current dollars.
Adjusting actual receipts to a high-employment level
is probably as good a job as we can do of eliminating
the influence of fluctuations in real output, but this
fails to eliminate the influence of inflation. That is,
even full-employment tax receipts, when they are
expressed in current dollars, go up faster during a
period of rapidly rising prices than they do during
a period of price stability. The tax variable, then, is
still not exogenous in the statistical sense since it
responds to current movements in the price level.
Fortunately, there is a simple way to eliminate, or
largely eliminate, this source of bias. Instead of using
full-employment receipts this period we can adjust
last period’s receipts to current prices by multiplying
full-employment receipts by a ratio of this period’s
general price level to last period’s general price level.
When we subtract this inflated last-period figure from
the current figure, we get the difference in fullemployment receipts expressed in this period’s prices.
It seems to us that this is a clear improvement over
the Andersen-Jordan variable.

The Monetary Base
Our next, and principal, concern is with the mone­
tary base. The base may be expressed as the sum
of three components: unborrowed reserves (including
the adjustments for reserve requirement changes),
borrowed reserves, and currency. For the base to be
exogenous in a statistical sense, it must be assumed
that the sum of these three components is largely
independent of current disturbances in the endogen­
ous variables. It appears to us that this assumption
is open to debate. We would like to consider whether
a variable with the properties we need could be more
closely approximated by omitting borrowed reserves,
or currency, or both.
Borrowed Reserves —Few would disagree with the
proposition that, at least as the discount window has
been administered for the last fifteen years, member
bank borrowings have responded strongly to current
Page 8



APRIL,

1969

movements in business loan demand and interest
rates. The question of interest, however, is not whe­
ther borrowings are endogenous, since presumably
that would be a matter of common agreement. Rather
the question is whether there is a strong tendency for
movements in borrowing to be offset by movements
in some other component of the base. If there is a
tendency for endogenous responses in borrowing to be
offset by movements in other components of the base,
then the total base contains offsetting endogenous
influences and we should prefer the total base for the
St. Louis regressions. If there is not such a tendency,
then adjusting the base to remove borrowings pro­
duces a better monetary policy variable than the
total base. Inclusion of borrowings in this latter case
might lead to a statistical confusion between the
effects of a high monetary base on the economy with
the effects of a booming economy on borrowing and,
hence, on the base.
The question is, then, whether unborrowed reserves
or currency tend to fall when something happens in
the general economy to make borrowings rise.5 There
are circumstances in which the answer probably is
yes. For example, if the central bank is watching the
rate of growth of bank credit or of the stock of money
as an indicator of its effect on the economy, then an
increase in borrowing which supports a rate of growth
greater than the target rate might provoke a reduction
in unborrowed reserves to put the rate of growth of
credit or money back on target. It is easy, however,
to think of circumstances in which a rise in borrowing
might produce a reinforcing movement in unborrowed
reserves if the level of borrowing itself is one of the
statistics the central bank uses as an index of its
effects, as it was during much of the 1950’s. For then
an increase in borrowing might well lead the central
bank to expand unborrowed reserves in order to get
borrowing back on target. Since it is not hard to think
of unborrowed reserves responding in either direction
to a change in borrowing during the sample period of
the regressions, it seems to us better to represent
monetary policy by a variable which excludes mem­
ber bank borrowing.
Currency —There is a widespread agreement that
the demand for currency responds to movements in
income or some measure of transactions. We can
again, as a matter of algebra, express the reducedform equation for GNP in terms of either reserves
5Note that this is different from the question of what happens
to the components of the base when the Federal Reserve
exogenously changes its policy. Our interest here is in the
response of the base to endogenous forces.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL,

plus currency or in terms of reserves alone. The
question once more is whether there is some strong
tendency on the part of other components of the
monetary base to offset the response of currency to
current transactions or other endogenous influences.
In the case of currency, there is an automatic mech­
anism making for an offset, since the usual procedure
by which the public obtains more currency involves
an initial decrease in vault cash or in bank reserves.
The existence of this mechanism is one argument in
favor of using the sum of reserves plus currency
rather than reserves alone as a monetary policy
variable.

1969

Alternative Single-Equation Results
Table I contains the results of carrying out the
above-mentioned modifications to the St. Louis equa­
tions. They are based upon the same sample period
as that used in the St. Louis regressions, 1/195211/1968, and data furnished by Andersen and Jordan
were used to obtain the modified regressions in our
equations. We used the same Almon technique for
estimating the distributed lags, and we adhered to
the Andersen-Jordan use of fourth degree polynomials
in the estimation procedure. In short, we have re­
mained quite close to the approach used by Andersen
and Jordan, making only those changes which appear
to us relevant to the question of statistical independ­
ence of the independent variables in the regressions.

There is more to the problem, however, than this
automatic response. The reason is that over the
sample period of the regressions, the central bank
The first equation presented in Table I is our repli­
cation of the St. Louis results, using the total mone­
has tended to focus on banking and money market
tary base and unadjusted high-employment expendidata in judging its current effect. It has not paid
particular attention to movements
Table I
in currency. If there is an increase
REGRESSIONS OF QUARTERLY CH A N G ES IN G N P (Current Dollars)
in the rate of growth of currency
O N CURRENT A N D LAGGED CHANGES IN MONETARY AND
— as there was 7 or 8 years ago —
FISCAL POLICY VARIABLES
it is not permitted to cause a lower
(Sam
ple period — 1/1952 to 11/1968)
rate of growth of unborrowed re­
R E G R E SSIO N E Q U A T IO N S
serves unless the central bank hap­
1
2
3
pens to want a lower rate of growth
Using
U sing
adjusted base less
of reserves for other reasons. The
adjusted base,
currency, adjusted
net result is that an endogenous
St. Louis
adjusted high*
high-em ployment
employment receipts
Results
receipts
change in currency may well affect
Length of Lags
the monetary base, and that the
(quarters)
4
4
8
4
8
base excluding currency may be a
M onetary Policy
more suitable variable for the pres­
A b
variable
ABa
ABa
ARu
ARu
ent study.
sum of coefficients
10.4
15.8
2.4
12.3
11.6
(5.5 )

Because of these characteristics
of member bank borrowing and cur­
rency, it seems to us well worth
while to rerun the St. Louis equa­
tions with various alternative defi­
nitions of the monetary policy vari­
able. We are not certain which of
the definitions is preferable; there­
fore, we are not prepared to defend
one set of regression results as
superior to the others. We are, how­
ever, inclined to doubt the validity
of conclusions about policy effects
which are supported under one defi­
nition but contradicted under an­
other.



(3.4 )

(2.8)

(0.6)

(1.6)

A e

A e

A e

A e

0.4
(0.7)

0.6
(0.6)

1.7
(3.7)

2.5
(4.1)

Federal Expenditures
variable
sum of coefficients

A e
— 0.5
(-0 -8 )

Federal Receipts
variable
sum of coefficients
Constant
R2/SE

A r

ARa

ARa

ARa

ARa

0.5
(0.6)

— 0.3
(-0 .3 )

— 0.5
(-0 .4 )

— 1.6
(-1 .8 )

— 2.8
(-2 .6 )

1.6
(1.2 )

3.6
(2.8 )

3.0
(1.9 )

6.4
(5.3)

5.0
(3.6 )

.51/4.4

.46/4.5

.53/4.2

.42/ 4 .7

.56/4.1

N ote: Figures given are regression coefficients; the “t” statistics appear below each co­
efficient, enclosed by parentheses.
A B = change in monetary base (currency plus total member bank reserves adjusted
for reserve requirement changes)
A B a = change in adjusted base (B less changes in member bank borrowings)
A R u = change in unborrowed reserves (B a less changes in currency, or unborrowed
reserves adjusted for reserve requirement changes)
A E = change in high-employment expenditures, current dollars
A R = change in high-employment receipts, current dollars
A R a = change in high-employment receipts in current period prices (last period’s
receipts multiplied by ratio of current prices to last period’s prices).

Page 9

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Figure I

APRIL,

1969

LAG DISTRIBUTIONS:

REG RESSIO N S OF CHANGES IN GNP ON CHANGES IN POLICY VARIABLES

1. St. L o u i s
Results

2. Usi ng Ad just ed Base,
A d ju s te d Receipts

tures and receipts. The very slight differences of these
results from those of Andersen and Jordan are pre­
sumably due to program and computer differences.
In Table I, we have presented the sums of the
weighted coefficients of the distributed lags of the in­
dependent variables, and the t-ratios of the sums. The
patterns of the weighted coefficients for each regres­
sion are presented graphically in the accompanying
chart. Solid fines portray four-quarter distributions;
dashed lines portray eight-quarter distributions.
The second equation indicates the results of making
two of the changes indicated above. First, member
bank borrowings were deducted from the total mone­
tary base to obtain the adjusted base, Ba. Second,
the high-employment receipts variable was adjusted
for price changes using the implicit price deflator for
GNP. Two sets of results for this variant are pre­
sented, one with four-quarter distributed lags on the
independent variables, and one with eight-quarter
lags. In both cases the results differ from the first
Page 10




3. Using A d ju s te d Base less
Curr enc y, A d ju s te d Receipts

equation in the following manner: (i) although the
monetary policy variable remains the predominant
influence in terms of t-ratios, the monetary multiplier
decreases in size; and (ii) although the two fiscal
policy variables remain insignificant statistically, the
coefficients of the expenditures and receipts variables
have the expected sign. These changes are due
mostly to the adjustment of the monetary base rather
than to the adjustment of high-employment receipts.
The third equation makes use of the monetary
base adjusted to exclude currency holdings as well
as borrowed reserves, leaving unborrowed reserves,
Ru.6 The expenditure and receipts variables are the
same as in equation (2). Results are again shown for
four- and eight-quarter lags.
6This variable is actually unborrowed reserves adjusted for
reserves requirement changes during the period. Fo r a dis­
cussion of the original monetary base and the reserve
requirement adjustment see Leonall Andersen and Jerry
Jordan, “The Monetary Base—Explanation and Analytical Use”
in the August 1968 issue of this Review.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

For the four-quarter lag distributions, the following
changes are observed: (i) the monetary policy variable
becomes insignificant statistically, and the size of the
monetary multiplier decreases markedly compared
with either equation (1) or (2); (ii) the expenditure
multiplier rises to 1.7 with a t-ratio well above 2; and,
(iii) the receipts variable has a multiplier of -1.6 with
a t-ratio slightly below 2 .
The shape of the lag distributions for the fourquarter distributions in equation (3) were such that
it appeared desirable to extend the length of the lags.
With eight-quarter lag distributions, the results are:
(1) the monetary multiplier estimate is once again of
the same order of magnitude as in equations (1) and
(2), and the t-ratio rises to 1.6 ; (ii) the expenditure
variable multiplier rises to 2.5 and retains a high tratio; and, (iii) the receipts multiplier rises to -2.8
with a t-ratio above 2 .
By way of comparison, the multipliers for similar
variables in the Federal Reserve/M.I.T. model are
as follows:7
(i) For unborrowed reserves, the multiplier over
eight quarters varies between 10 and 15,
depending upon initial conditions.
(ii) Although not directly comparable with highemployment expenditures, the Federal pur­
chases multiplier in the model is approxi­
mately 2.5. For average Federal expendi­
tures (purchases and transfers) the multiplier
is between 2 and 2.5. These values, again,
are for eight quarters.
(iii) For Federal personal taxes, the multiplier
is about -1.9. A multiplier including other
taxes has not been calculated. It would
probably also be less than 2.0 in absolute
size for eight quarters for most other taxes,
‘ See Frank de Leeuw and Edward Gramlich, “The Channels
of Monetary Policy,” forthcoming in the Federal Reserve
Bulletin.




APRIL, 1969

but might be higher for the investment tax
credit.
The lag patterns portrayed in Figure I suggest
longer lags for monetary and tax policies than for
expenditures. In fact, in most of the equations con­
temporaneous changes in the monetary base and tax
policies have “wrong” signs. These contemporaneous
coefficients are puzzling, and we have no economic
explanation of them.
The weights associated with the high-employment
expenditure variable fall off rapidly for all of the
four-quarter lag distributions. With eight-quarter
distributions they fall and rise again. Andersen and
Jordan indicate that the negative values at the tail
of the four-quarter distributions are consistent with
the hypothesis that rising Federal outlays “crowd out”
private spending through their influence on interest
rates. We note that the pattern of the weights when
the lag distribution is extended to eight quarters re­
sembles the early stages of a multiplier-accelerator
cycle. It is, of course, impossible to demonstrate the
superiority of either conclusion from results such as
these.

Conclusion
We feel these results cast serious doubt on the
Andersen-Jordan conclusions about fiscal policy. With
alternative and highly plausible measures of Federal
receipts and the monetary base, fiscal policy appears
to exert a significant influence on GNP in the expected
direction. Monetary policy also appears to exert a
powerful influence.
More headway on these problems seems to us to
depend on the development of measures of policy
which we can be confident meet the statistical require­
ments of exogeneity. Possibly a detailed examination
of Open Market Committee records would be helpful
in constructing a better measure of monetary policy.
Perhaps different measures for different policy-making
epochs are necessary. Until we succeed in settling the
statistical questions, extreme caution is advisable with
respect to any economic interpretations.

The Reply to this Comment begins on next page.

Page 11

Monetary and Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their Relative
Importance in Economic Stabilization - Reply
A HE “COMMENT” by Frank de Leeuw and John
Kalchbrenner is in reference to an earlier article of
ours in which we presented evidence bearing on
familiar statements regarding the relative importance
of monetary and fiscal actions in economic stabiliza­
tion. In this “Reply” we present additional analysis
and evidence relating directly to the issues they have
raised.

Summary of Issues Raised
In our November 1968 article we estimated the
response of total spending in the economy (an en­
dogenous or dependent variable) to changes in alter­
native summary measures of monetary and fiscal
actions ( exogenous or independent variables). De
Leeuw and Kalchbrenner suggest two criteria for
choosing exogenous policy variables: ( 1 ) the vari­
ables must be under the control of policymakers;
and ( 2 ) the variables must not be “terribly sensitive
to current movements in the endogenous variables.”
They say that “failure to meet this second require­
ment has been a major criticism of regressions of
GNP on the money supply.” The use of the money
supply as a measure of the influence of monetary
actions will be discussed briefly at the end of this
Reply.
Regarding the measures of fiscal actions, de Leeuw
and Kalchbrenner recommend adjusting the full-employment tax receipts variable for changes in the
price level in order to eliminate the induced upward
bias in tax receipts caused by inflation.1 We accept
xThe desire to eliminate this factor assumes that the gov­
ernment has not intentionally undertaken inflationary poli­
cies in order to finance government spending, as an
alternative to raising tax rates or borrowing. This assump­
tion would obviously not have been valid for post-World
W ar I Germany.
Page 12



this recommendation by de Leeuw and Kalchbrenner
and observe, as they do and as their equation 2
shows, that this modification does not affect the con­
clusion reached in our original article regarding the
relative strength and reliability of monetary actions
versus fiscal actions.
De Leeuw and Kalchbrenner state their principal
concern is with whether or not the monetary base is
exogenous in the statistical sense. They define the
base as the sum of three “components”: unborrowed
reserves, borrowed reserves, and currency. Their
definition of the base consists of a very special de­
composition of the uses of the monetary base, in con­
trast to the usually accepted definition of uses of
the base. They make no mention in their “Comment”
of the sources of the monetary base which shows the
base as being derived from a consolidated Treasury
and Federal Reserve balance sheet. This failure to
distinguish sources of the base from uses is a funda­
mental point of difference between these critics and
ourselves. Before we discuss their conception of the
base further, we will complete this summary of
their procedures and results.
They suggest that reserves borrowed from the Fed­
eral Reserve by member banks might be subtracted
from the monetary base, and they present regression
results in which they have done so. They advance that
the criterion for including or excluding borrowings
as a part of the base depends on whether or not
“there is a strong tendency for movements in borrow­
ing to be offset by movements in some other compon­
ent of the base.” They say that if there is such an
offset tendency, then borrowing should not be ex­
cluded from the base. They then exclude borrowing

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST LOUIS

from the base without presenting any evidence in­
dicating whether or not there is such an offset. Fur­
thermore, the results obtained when they substitute
the base minus borrowing (their equation 2 ) for the
monetary base (their equation 1 and our equation
1.4 in Table I of our original article) do not alter any
of the conclusions we reached regarding the relative
strength and reliability of monetary and fiscal actions.
The more important criticism by de Leeuw and
Kalchbrenner stems from the results they obtained
by subtracting both member bank borrowings and
currency held by the public from the monetary base
in order to obtain an alternative measure of mone­
tary influence, which they call unborrowed reserves
(Ru). They recommend subtracting currency held
by the public from the monetary base for reasons
similar to those for excluding borrowed reserves.
They admit that their own criterion for exclusion of
currency may not be confirmed statisically because
of an “automatic” offset when the public obtains
currency from banks. However, they argue that the
central bank does not pay attention to currency
movements, but rather they imply the Federal Re­
serve has intentionally determined the growth of
“unborrowed reserves” over time and “offsets” any
increased growth in currency by supplying more un­
borrowed reserves. We find this contention a highly
questionable description of the Federal Reserve’s
behavior and intentions. But this issue is irrelevant
because of their failure to distinguish between sources
and uses of the monetary base.
The results obtained by de Leeuw and Kalchbren­
ner by substituting Ru for the base are reported as
equation 3 in their Table I. As that equation shows,
Ru is either inferior to the monetary base as a measure
of monetary actions (the coefficients are statistically
nonsignificant), or if Ru is the appropriate measure
of monetary actions, there is little response of GNP
to such actions. Also, both measures of fiscal actions
( high-employment expenditures and receipts) indi­
cate a stronger influence on GNP when the measure
of monetary actions (Ru) is nonsignificant.

Reply to Issues Raised
The authors of the Comment raise some valid and
important considerations regarding the statistical pro­
cedures employed in Our original study. However,
they overlook some equally valid and important con­
siderations from the point-of-view of economic theory.



APRIL,

1969

Variables used to test economic hypotheses must be
relevant to the hypotheses. Their process of “peel­
ing” the monetary base (first subtracting borrowings
from Reserve Banks and then currency held by others
than banks) in arriving at the concept “unborrowed
reserves” may make sense statistically under special
conditions, but this process has no economic relevance
within the context of the customary body of economic
theory which has evolved around the monetary base.
We now will examine our contention regarding their
use of unborrowed reserves as a summary measure of
monetary actions, as well as some of the statistical
considerations they advance for such use.
Monetary Base —As noted above, de Leeuw and
Kalchbrenner define the monetary base as the sum
of “unborrowed” reserves, reserves borrowed from
the Federal Reserve, and currency held by the public.
They overlook the fact that the base is derived from
a consolidated balance sheet of Treasury and Federal
Reserve monetary accounts and consequently make
no reference to the sources of the base.2 Both the
sources and the customary definition of uses of the
base, along with de Leeuw and Kalchbrenner’s spe­
cial treatment of the uses, are presented in Table I.
The largest component of the sources of the mone­
tary base is Federal Reserve holdings of U.S. Gov­
ernment securities, and variation in this component
over time has dominated the variation in the base.3
It is true that other source components of the base
are not directly controlled by the Federal Reserve,
yet changes in these other components are always
readily known, and the System can, by open mar­
ket purchases or sales, completely “offset” any of
the relatively small movements in any of these other
source components of the base (including discounts
and advances which includes member banks’ borrow­
ings from the Federal Reserve). If the System ob­
serves changes in other source components and
chooses not to offset them, the Federal Reserve has
caused a change in the base the same as when the
System buys or sells securities and other components
are unchanged. Consequently, the Federal Reserve,
through its open market operations, determines the
source side of the monetary base.
-See Leonall C. Andersen and Jerry L. Jordan, “The Monetary
Base — Explanation and Analytical Use” in the August 1968
issue of this Review.
:<For further discussion of and evidence concerning Federal
Reserve control over various monetary aggregates, including
the monetary base, see an article by Michael W . Keran and
Christopher T. Babb, forthcoming in this Review.
Page 13

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL,

1969

Table 1

DE LEEUW-KALCHBRENNER
DEFINITION OF BASE

MONETARY BASE
(December 1 96 8 —

millions of dollars)

Sources
Federal Reserve Credit:
H oldings of Securities*
Discounts & Advances
Float
G old Stock

Uses

52.594
76 5

Borrowed Reserves

10,367

Currency held by
the Public

4 4,3 1 8

Uses of Base

7 3 ,093

6,8 1 0
— 756

Treasury Deposits at
Federal Reserve

— 36 0

Foreign Deposits

— 22 5

O ther Deposits & O ther (Net)
Federal Reserve Accounts

+ 647

M onetary Base

Unborrow ed Reserves1

7 3 ,0 9 3
4,414
7 7 ,5 0 7

Reserve Adjustment
M onetary Base

6,291

4,4 1 4
7 7 ,5 0 7

N O T E: Member bank deposits a t Federal Reserve plus currency held by member banks
equals total reserves (required reserves plus excess reserves).
♦Includes acceptances not shown separately.

Since the base is derived from a balance sheet as
in Table I and since the uses (liabilities) side of
the balance sheet must equal the sources (assets)
side, the Federal Reserve determines the total size
of the base through its open market purchases and
sales of securities. Banks and the public determine
the allocation between reserves and currency; these
are uses of the base.
The authors of the Comment divide the reserve
uses of the monetary base into borrowed and unbor­
rowed reserves. They then treat currency and these
two reserve classifications as sources4 —that is, a
change in any one of the three magnitudes changes
the base by exactly the same amount —and question
the exogenous character of these so-called sources.
This treatment of uses as sources in discussing the
statistical requirements of regressions using the mone­
tary base leads our critics to accept an irrelevant
exogenous measure of monetary actions. The proper
procedure, if one were interested in finding a relevant
exogenous variable, would be to examine the sources
of the base presented in Table I.
4This confusion is prevalent among economists. In many
studies reserves and currency are summed, providing a quick
and ready way of developing a time series of the base.
Nevertheless, the sum of the sources listed in Table I
actually determines the magnitude of the base.
Page 14




2 8 ,023

2 2 ,484

3,251

Treasury Cash Holdings

Reserve Adjustment

Mem ber Bank Deposits
at Federal Reserve
Currency held by
Banks

Treasury Currency O utstanding

Source Base

(December 1968 — millions of dollars)

752

Currency held by Public
and not part of Reserves

4 4 ,3 1 8

Base

7 3 ,0 9 3

Reserve Adjustment
M onetary Base

4 ,4 1 4
7 7 ,5 0 7

1Vault cash of nonmember banks in­
cluded as reserves by de Leeuw and
Kalchbrenner.

For these reasons we do not accept their procedure
of “peeling” the monetary base in order to arrive at
a statistically pure exogenous measure of monetary
actions. However, we will examine further some of
the arguments they advance.
Exclusion of Borrowings — A reason often given
for excluding borrowed reserves (which have aver­
aged less than one-half billion dollars in recent years)
from total reserves ( presently about $27 billion) or
from the monetary base (presently about $77 billion)
is the contention that the effect of borrowed reserves
on bank credit or deposit expansion is different than
the effect of “unborrowed” reserves. This contention
implies that banks hold more excess reserves when
their borrowings are greater than when smaller.
The “multiple expansion” of deposits by the bank­
ing system does not depend on the source of the
additional reserves acquired by the banking system.
Data for the banking system clearly shows that when
total reserves have increased, deposits have increased
by a multiple. Whether the additional reserves were
borrowed by the banks or otherwise acquired does not
make any discernible difference. Reserves borrowed
by one bank when diffused throughout the banking
system cannot be distinguished by any other bank
from unborrowed reserves.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL, 1969

As noted earlier, de Leeuw and Kalchbrenner ad­
vance a statistical criterion for excluding borrowed
reserves from the base. They do not provide an
economic argument for doing so, nor do they present
any empirical evidence. They merely contend that
if there is an “offset” between “unborrowed” reserves
and borrowed reserves, the borrowing should not
be excluded from the base (or from total reserves).
In order to test whether or not there is a negative
correlation or “offset” between borrowed (Rb) and
unborrowed reserves (Ru) we estimated a regression
equation for the period I/53-II/68 using seasonally
adjusted quarterly data. The results were:
ARu = .1 7 9 - 1.065 ARb.
(

6 .2

)

5

The simple correlation coefficient between ARb and
ARu is —.63 and the R 2 is .40.

they report results indicating the effects of exclud­
ing currency held by the public from the monetary
base, but not excluding borrowings. Subtracting cur­
rency held by the public from the base creates a
measure of “total reserves” which is adjusted for
changes in reserve requirements and includes vault
cash of nonmember commercial banks (a relatively
small and invariant magnitude). Total reserves also
are relevant in many theories in monetary economics
and, therefore, are a potential summary measure of
monetary actions.
The results obtained using this measure of total
reserves (TR) as a measure of monetary influence
instead of the base are reported in Table II along
with the results obtained using the monetary base.
The results for the two equations are very similar,
and the use of total reserves as a summary measure
of monetary influence does not yield any different
conclusions from those presented in our November
article.

These results indicate very clearly that there was
a strong negative “offset” between borrowed and un­
borrowed reserves in the 15-year
test period. Consequently, there is
Table II
no justification, either theoretical or
REGRESSIONS OF QUARTERLY CH A N G ES IN G N P (Current Dollars)
statistical, for excluding member
O N CURRENT A N D LAGGED CH A N G ES IN
bank borrowing from the monetary
MONETARY A N D FISCAL VARIABLES
base (or from total reserves) as a
Sam ple Period - - 1/1952 to M / 1 9 6 8
measure of the influence of mone­
tary actions on economic activity. In
R E G R E SSIO N E Q U A T IO N S
fact, these results indicate that it is
2
1
inappropriate to use “unborrowed
Length of Lags
reserves” as an exogenous measure of
8
(quarters)
4
8
4
monetary actions since a large share
M onetary Policy
of the changes in this variable is
A tr
A b
A b
A tr
variable
associated with offsetting movements
43.7 9
14.94
sum of coefficients
10.53
30.28
in borrowed reserves.
(4 .0 8 )
(2 .6 3 )
(5.17)
(4 .9 5 )

Exclusion of Currency
We argued above that the mone­
tary authorities control the total
monetary base through their control
over the sources components of the
base. Consequently, on theoretical
grounds it is inappropriate to exclude
either member bank borrowings or
currency held by the public from the
uses of the base. De Leeuw and
Kalchbrenner did not report statisti­
cal results indicating whether bor­
rowings should be excluded or not
(as we have done above), nor did
5t-statistic, obtained by dividing the regres­
sion coefficient by the standard error.




Federal Expenditures
variable
sum of coefficients

A e
— .03
(-.0 4 )

A e
.74
(.6 8 )

A e
.77
(1.53)

A e
.62
(-69)

Federal Receipts
variable
sum of coefficients

Constant

rV s e

ARa

ARa

ARa

ARa

— .43
(-5 2 )

— 1.46
(-1 .0 6 )

— .61
(-.8 1 )

— .60
(-.4 9 )

2.55
(1 .8 5 )

4.75
(2 .5 3 )

2.10
(1.5 3 )

.62
(.2 8)

.52/4.44

.57/4.05

.56/4.23

.62/3.83

N ote: Regression coefficients are the top figu res; their “t ” statistics appear below each
coefficient, enclosed by parentheses.
A B = change in monetary base
A T R = change in total reserves
A E = change in high-employment budget expenditures, current dollars
A R a = change in high-employment budget receipts in current period prices I[last period’s
receipts multiplied by ratio of current prices to last period’s prices)

Page 15

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

If de Leeuw and Kalchbrenner had excluded cur­
rency held by the public from the base, but had
not excluded borrowings, their results would have
been sufficiently similar to those obtained using total
base or the money supply that none of the major
conclusions of our original article would be changed.

Other Issues
De Leeuw and Kalchbrenner do not discuss the
use of the money supply as an indicator of monetary
influence because, they imply, the series is sensitive
to current movements in income. Their statement
can be restated as a hypothesis that quarter-to-quarter changes in the money stock are strongly influ­
enced by current or previous changes in income. This
issue ‘has been debated at considerable length on
other occasions and can best be discussed within
the context of a money supply model.6
Another point raised by de Leeuw and Kalch­
brenner is that it is difficult to find variables which
meet both definitions of exogenous since “policymak­
ers themselves are naturally influenced in their deci­
sions by current developments.” An example will
illustrate their point. Assume the monetary base is
under the absolute control of the policymakers and
that there is a very close one-way causal relation from
changes in the base to changes in income. Given
this assumption, if policymakers’ decisions regarding
changes in the base are made with the intent of
achieving some desired growth of income as opposed
to an observed growth, then it can be concluded
that, in a sense, the base is “endogenous” or influ­
enced by current economic developments. We would
accept this contention, but would point out that the
base is still statistically exogenous. Moreover, we sub­
mit that such a distinction is totally irrelevant, since
the policymakers can know in advance what the effect
of their actions will be, and can confidently influence
economic activity without being concerned about any
misleading “feedback” effects on their indicator
variable.
6For example see A. E. Burger, “A Summary of the BrunnerMeltzer Non-Linear Money Supply Hypothesis,” Working
Paper No. 7, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, revised, May
1969. The reader should also consult another article in the
May 1969 issue of this Review, “Controlling Money,” by
Professor Allan H. Meltzer, and an article in the July 1968
issue of this Review, “The Role of Money and Monetary
Policy,” by Professor Karl Brunner (especially pp. 1 5 -1 8 ).
The theory and evidence presented in these papers allow
the authors to conclude that changes in the money stock
are strongly dominated by changes in the monetary base and
that the monetary authorities can exercise very close control
over money through their control over the base.
Page 16




APRIL,

1969

Conclusions
In our original article last November we put forth
the following propositions: “the response of economic
activity to monetary actions compared with that of
fiscal actions is (I) larger, (II) more predictable,
and (III) faster.” We offered a brief theoretical
framework for analyzing the ways stabilization ac­
tions influence economic activity, and evidence bear­
ing on the above propositions was presented. Re­
garding fiscal actions, we concluded that “either the
commonly used measures of fiscal influence do not
correctly indicate the degree and direction of such
influence, or there was no measurable net fiscal in­
fluence on total spending in the test period.” Re­
garding monetary actions, we concluded that in view
of the finding of a strong empirical relationship be­
tween economic activity and the measures of mone­
tary actions, greater reliance should be placed on
this form of stabilization action.
De Leeuw and Kalchbrenner propose, on statistical
criteria only, using “unborrowed reserves,” rather than
the money supply or the monetary base, as a measure
of monetary influence. However, they do not offer
any theoretical rationale showing the link between
this variable and economic activity, or theoretical
superiority of this variable over total reserves, the
monetary base or the money supply. We have argued
that on theoretical grounds unborrowed reserves is
not a relevant measure of monetary influence. De
Leeuw and Kalchbrenner offer statistical criteria for
use of unborrowed reserves as their exogenous mone­
tary measure, but they do not present any evidence
indicating whether this variable meets their criteria.
We have presented tests which show that unbor­
rowed reserves do not meet their criteria for ac­
ceptability on statistical grounds.
Our critics have shown similarities between the
results they obtained by using “unborrowed reserves”
(Ru) as a measure of monetary influence and the
results from the Federal Reserve Board —M.I.T.
econometric model which uses similar variables. In
view of the serious reservations we have presented
regarding the use of unborrowed reserves as a meas­
ure of monetary influence based on both theoretical
and statistical criteria, we have considerable doubt
as to the desirability of using this monetary variable
in econometric models of the U.S. economy.
L e o n a l l C. A n d e r s e n
J e r r y L . J ordan

The Comment and Reply are available as Reprint
No. 37.

E d it o r s N o t e :

The following is a guest article prepared by Professor David C. Rowan, who served as a visiting scholar
with this bank from September to December 1968. Since 1960 he has been Professor of Economics at the Uni­
versity of Southampton, and also has served as Editor of the Bankers’ Magazine. Previously, he was Professor
and Dean of the Commerce Faculty at the University of New South Wales, Sydney, Australia, and also taught at
the Universities of Melbourne and Rristol. He is the author of numerous articles dealing primarily with subjects
in monetary and international economics.
Professor Rowan’s views do not necessarily represent those of the Federal Reserve Rank of St. Louis or
of the Federal Reserve System.

Towards A Rational Exchange Policy:
Some Reflections on the Rritish Experience
1_ HIS PAPER is deliberately subtitled “Some Reflections . . . ” to emphasize that it does not aim at
providing either a detailed account of the events
which led up to devaluation or a full review of
Britain’s external problem. What it presents is an
attempt to derive some lessons of lasting benefit from
the failure of British external policy, and in partic­
ular, British exchange policy during the Sixties, and
from the concurrent, less recognized, failure of the
world’s international monetary authorities.

do the relative importance attached to these objec­
tives and price stability, these aims are shared by
most developed countries.
It is equally a commonplace that in Britain, as in
other countries, these aims must be pursued subject
to a balance-of-payments constraint, and that in Bri­
tain this constraint has repeatedly imposed checks to
growth because of the emergence of severe balanceof-payments deficits.

The Consistency of British Exchange Policy

Scarcely less familiar is the proposition that an ob­
served deficit in the balance on current and long­
term capital accounts reflects three conceptually dis­
tinct elements: the first of these is the long-run or
secular position of current and long-term capital ac­
counts which we shall call the “fundamental balance”;
the second is the cyclical position; the third is a
“catch-all” which takes account of such random fac­
tors as strikes, climatic disturbances and political un­
certainties. The second and third elements we shall
call short run. In addition, of course, the observed
balance may reflect short-term capital movements
arising either from interest rate differentials, the in­
cidence of random factors, or from speculative flows
based upon private assessments of the fundamental
balance on current account.

It is a commonplace that the objectives of British
economic policy are to achieve, at a level of capacity
utilization which corresponds to “full employment,”
an “acceptable” rate of growth in real Gross Domestic
Product (GDP), usually put at between 3 and 4 per
cent per year. Moreover, though the definitions of
“full employment” and “acceptable growth” differ, as

In this paper we shall define the fundamental bal­
ance as the balance of payments on current and long­
term capital accounts which would exist if the coun­
try was growing ( in terms of real GDP) at its accept­
able rate, and if it was maintaining continuously a
level of capacity utilization corresponding to full
employment.

These reflections are organized under three prin­
cipal headings:
(1) the consistency of British exchange
policy;
(2) the inadequacy of British exchange
policy;
(3) the general applicability of British
experience.
Together these topics amount to a single theme
— the tendency for most national economic policy­
makers to neglect economic theory and, a conse­
quence which is at least professionally gratifying, the
distressing results of this neglect.




Page 17

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Clearly, provided both conditions are met, the fun­
damental balance will be functionally related to the
exchange rate. The exchange rate which would give
a fundamental balance of zero can be defined as the
“equilibrium rate of exchange.” Rates of exchange
which do not satisfy this condition are, by definition,
rates which involve “fundamental disequilibria.”
Given this framework, we shall now argue that the
consistency of Rritish exchange policy in the Sixties
with that of the Twenties lies in the fact that, in
both periods, the authorities sought to maintain a
disequilibrium parity even though to do so involved
the sacrifice of both growth and employment.
It is worth noting that this argument entails two
propositions. The first is that the pound rate of $2.80
was incompatible with fundamental equilibrium dur­
ing the period 1960-67 and thus involved a funda­
mental disequilibrium. The second is that the exis­
tence of this fundamental disequilibrium was demon­
strable. We shall return to these issues later.
Consider the period 1925-31. In 1925 Britain re­
turned to the gold standard at the pound rate of
$4.86. At the time the free market rate, at £, = $4.40,
was about 10 per cent lower. Insofar as the chosen
rate was not compatible with a fundamental balance
of zero, that is, with fundamental equilibrium, domes­
tic prices and costs had to be forced down to adjust
to the new parity. The costs of the attempt to do this,
in the face of considerable price-wage rigidity, were
industrial strife, unemployment, lost output and the
souring of industrial relations to a degree which is,
even now, probably a significant factor in Britain’s
economic situation. In practice, despite severe defla­
tion, adjustment was slow and still incomplete when
the gold standard was abandoned in 1931.
The significance of this period is that it was an
instance, and with the benefit of hindsight, a pecu­
liarly glaring one, of an attempt by the British au­
thorities to force domestic economic conditions to
adjust to an exchange rate; or, what amounts to the
same thing, it was a refusal by the authorities to
admit the inappropriateness of the selected parity.
Because political constraints now limit the extent of
deflation, the costs of essentially the same refusal in
the Sixties have been less severe. The British au­
thorities again struggled to maintain the existing dis­
equilibrium rate of $2.80 and deliberately chose to
accept avoidably long periods of relative stagnation
and relatively high unemployment.
In both 1931 and 1967 the disequilibrium parities
which the British authorities sought to maintain were
Page 18



APRIL, 1969

abandoned. It is doubtful, however, whether these
devaluations, when they came, reflected a belated
and possibly reluctant recognition that the ruling rate
was not an equilibrium rate and thus required modi­
fication. Even in 1967, when additional international
support for sterling was available, it seems more rea­
sonable to believe that the British authorities recog­
nized that the 1967 crisis, if overcome, would simply
be followed by others; in short, that the probability
of recurrent speculative attacks and short-term out­
flows made devaluation inevitable. Thus, the devalu­
ations were not autonomous acts of policy. They
were seen by the authorities largely as defeats and,
indeed, not infrequently described as such. Our in­
terpretation of the evidence of 1925-31 and 1959-67
therefore suggests that a planned adjustment of the
sterling rate —in order to eliminate a fundamental
disequilibrium —is virtually unthinkable.
The reluctance to regard the rate of exchange as a
discretionary policy variable, and the consequential
readiness to try to adjust domestic conditions to the
given rate, probably have two origins. The first and
presumably less important origin is some memory of
the advantages of following the gold standard game.
The second is a misreading of the experience of the
Thirties.
In the period 1925-31, British policy was based
upon a coherent version of the classical gold stand­
ard theory. By 1931, this theory was widely recog­
nized as unhelpful. Unfortunately no systematic
theory immediately took its place and the British
monetary authorities, like the monetary authorities
elsewhere, had to face the stresses of the Thirties
with no coherent macroeconomic theory to guide
them. One result was that the decade prior to World
War II was one of competitive devaluations.1 These
were either “beggar-my-neighbor” attempts to export
unemployment, or retaliation to such attempts. The
experience of this decade, including the competitive
-devaluations, their accompanying uncertainties and
“hot” money flows, and the extension of exchange con­
trol, reinforced the British (and other) monetary au­
thorities’ instinctive preference for fixed rates of ex­
change. Indeed it is arguable that they were inter­
preted to mean that discretionary exchange adjust­
ments, or the adoption of floating rates, were invita­
tions to monetary chaos, and hence that fixed ex­
change rates were the path of wisdom.
As we shall see, this interpretation was erroneous.
Nevertheless it had a profound effect upon the post!R . Nurkse, International Currency Experience (League of Na­
tions, 1 9 4 4 ), pp. 210 and 211.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

World War II monetary arrangements agreed to at
Bretton Woods, and a no less profound, but consid­
erably more harmful, effect upon the way in which
the Bretton Woods scheme has been operated.

The Inadequacy of British Exchange Policy
In a multilateral trading world in which each
country is seeking (though admittedly with varying
degrees of success and with greater or lesser strin­
gency of definition) to maintain both acceptable
growth and full employment, it is clear that the
emergence of any fundamental disequilibrium on ex­
ternal account must either be met by an adjustment
of the rate of exchange or by the specification of
some alternative method of eliminating the funda­
mental disequilibrium. This obvious proposition,
which has been sadly neglected, is clearly implied
in the following quotation from a speech by Lord
Keynes to the House of Lords.
In May 1943, speaking on the subject of interna­
tional currency plans, Keynes said:
The exchange value of sterling cannot remain
constant in terms of other currencies, unless our
efficiency-wages, and those other costs of pro­
duction which depend on our social policy, are
keeping strictly in step with the corresponding
costs in other countries. And, obviously, to that
we cannot pledge ourselves. I hope Your Lord­
ships will believe me when I say that there are
few people less likely than I not to be on the
lookout against this danger. The British pro­
posals (for the IMF) nowhere envisage ex­
change rigidity. They provide that changes of
more than a certain amount must not be made
unless the actual state of trade demonstrates
that they are required, and they provide further
that changes, when made, must be made by
agreement. Exchange rates necessarily affect
two parities equally. Changes, therefore, should
not be made by unilateral action . . . ,2
A year later, speaking in defense of the Interna­
tional Monetary Fund, Keynes argued:
We are determined that, in future, the external
value of sterling shall conform to its internal
value as set by our own domestic policies, and
not the other way round. Secondly, we intend
to retain control of our domestic rate of interest,
so that we can keep it as low as suits our own
purposes, without interference from the ebb and
flow of international capital movements or flights
of hot money. Thirdly, whilst we intend to
prevent inflation at home, we will not accept
2J. M. Keynes, House of Lords, May 18, 1943.




APRIL, 1969

deflation at the dictate of influences from out­
side. In other words, we abjure the instruments
of bank rate and credit contraction operating
through the increase of unemployment as a
means of forcing our domestic economy into
line with external factors.3
In both passages Keynes’ argument is that, in the
event of a conflict between the maintenance of a
given parity and domestic policy objectives, it is the
exchange rate and not domestic conditions which must
be adjusted. Moreover, from the emphasis which
Keynes gave to the issue, it is clear that he did not
regard a conflict between domestic and external ob­
jectives as unlikely. He thus, by implication at least,
denied the existence of any quasi-automatic mechan­
ism tending to eliminate fundamental disequilibrium
in the balance of payments. In addition, it could be
argued with little exaggeration that he largely foresaw
the British post-war external problem. Finally, Keynes
saw that the experience of the Thirties provided a
case against unilateral exchange changes but not
against exchange changes.
By contrast, as we have seen, the British authori­
ties have been markedly reluctant to adjust the ex­
change rate. Thus, even if they did not reject the
theory underlying Keynes’ policy recommendations,4
their policies during the last decade, like their policies
from 1925-31, implied such a rejection. Logically this
can only suggest that they were either unconvinced
of the existence of a fundamental disequilibrium
or able to specify an alternative adjustment mech­
anism not requiring changes in rates.
It is difficult to trace in British official publications
any clear admission of the existence of a fundamental
disequilibrium or statement of the mechanism upon
which the British authorities were relying for balanceof-payments adjustments in the presence of a fixed
rate of exchange and a relatively stringent full-employment constraint. However, it is possible to dis­
cern, notably in the publications of the N.E.D.C .,5 a
suggestion that the existence of a fundamental dis­
equilibrium was implicitly accepted as well as the
elements of two theories of adjustment.
3J. M. Keynes, House of Lords, May 23, 1944.
4It is worth noting that, in his last article, Keynes took a
stronger position, arguing that the “classical medicine” could
not be relied upon and that “we need quicker and less pain­
ful aids of which exchange variation and over-all import con­
trol are the most important.” See J. M. Keynes, “The Balance
of Payments of the United States,” Economic Journal, June
1946.
5N .E.D .C. denotes the National Economic Development Coun­
cil, an official research agency of the British government.
Page 19

APRIL, 1969

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

On the first issue, it is surely significant that the
N.E.D.C., after calculating that the 4 per cent “target”
rate of growth in GDP required a 5 per cent rate
of growth in exports, argued that this required “. . . a
small relative fall in the prices of British manufac­
tures.”6 In later publications by the same body the
same diagnosis recurs with greater emphasis.7 Thus
the publication Export Trends gives considerable em­
phasis to the role of relative costs and prices in in­
fluencing export performance, sets out a short and
generally favorable interpretation of the French de­
valuation of 1957, and concludes that the required
growth in exports might .. not be forthcoming un­
less the prices of manufactures on the home market
fall relatively to foreign export prices.”8
It thus seems reasonable to interpret these docu­
ments as guardedly admitting the existence of a fun­
damental disequilibrium. They are, however, consid­
erably less easy to interpret on the issue of the
mechanism of adjustment.
Two interpretations are permissible of these
N.E.D.C. documents. The first is that the N.E.D.C.,
in its emphasis on relative price adjustments, was
coming as close to the open advocacy of devaluation
as its official position permitted. The second is that,
though probably favoring an exchange adjustment,
the N.E.D.C. was, as a second-best alternative, pre­
pared to support the official line which seems to have
been founded on a particular version of what might be
called the “neo-classical first difference theory.”
At its crudest, the classical theory envisages the
downward adjustment of the level of prices in
deficit countries through deflation and, though less
firmly, the upward adjustment of prices in surplus
countries. In some versions this, was seen as the
quasi-automatic outcome of specie flows. The funda­
mental hypotheses of this theory were the absence of
both wage-price rigidity and official neutralization
policies. After the experience of the Twenties and
Thirties, neither hypothesis was any longer acceptable.
The classical theory thus visualized the adjustment
process as modifying price and cost levels. The new
version accepts that price and cost levels are inflexi­
ble downwards. However, since costs and prices are
generally rising throughout the world, it replaced
price and cost levels by their rates of change. On this
6N .E.D .C ., Growth of the United Kingdom Econom y to 1966
(H er Majesty’s Stationery Office [H.M .S.O.], 1 9 6 3 ), para­
graph 280.
7N .E .D .C .,
Conditions
Favourable
to
Faster
Growth
(H .M .S.O ., 1 9 6 3 ), Section D and F and paragraphs 201 and

211 .

8N .E.D .C ., Export Trends (H.M .S.O ., 1 9 6 3 ), paragraphs 27-58.
Page 20



basis the adjustment process required the discretion­
ary reduction of the rate of increase in British costs
below the rates of increase ruling in her principal
competitors. Provided policy could achieve this, then,
after a sufficient period of time, the necessary adjust­
ment would be brought about.

E mployment-Wage Trade-Off
One of the principal conclusions of empirical re­
search into the interrelationship between price and
cost changes in the United Kingdom is that a func­
tional relationship exists between the percentage of
the work force unemployed and the rate of change
of money wages. The relationship is usually called
the “Phillips curve” and is to be interpreted as a
labor market adjustment curve. Though the interpre­
tation of this curve in the United Kingdom is still to
some extent a matter of dispute, its existence seems
to command general acceptance.9 The neo-classical
first difference mechanism, which specifies discre­
tionary operation on the rate of change of money
wages, thus requires interpretation in terms of this
relationship. In practice there seem to be three policy
variants:
( 1 ) the “excess-capacity” view usually associated
with the name of Professor F. W. Paish;
(2 ) the “incomes-policy” view; and
(3) the view of which seeks to combine (1) and (2).
The basic assumption of the excess-capacity view
is that the Phillips curve is a stable relationship
which can be relied upon as a means of formulating
policy quantitatively. Given this, the objective is to
operate the economy at an average percentage of
unemployment (usually estimated at 2 -2% per cent)
which will generate (assuming the rate of productiv­
ity increase to be invariant) the desired rate of
change in wage costs per unit of output.
The basic assumption of the incomes-policy view
is that the Phillips curve is not stable, has shifted, and
can be shifted again by an appropriate incomes pol­
icy, so that, for a given percentage of unemployment,
a lower rate of increase in wage costs will result.10
9The literature on this relationship is extensive. Excellent gen­
eral surveys and bibliographies are to be found in: J. C. R.
Dow, T he Management of the British Econom y: 1945-1960
(Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1964), chapter
X III; R. E . Canes et aL, Britain’s Economic Prospects (W ash­
ington: The Brookings Institution, 1 9 6 8 ), chapter 3; and also
see George McKenzie, “International Monetary Reform and
the ‘Crawling Peg’ ” in the February 1969 issue of this
Review.
10Dow, pp. 402 and 403.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST LOUIS

The combination of the two views accepts that the
Phillips curve is shiftable but appears to believe that
the essentially political exercise of an incomes policy
would have a better prospect of success if the un­
employment percentage was kept, on average, be­
tween 2 -2% per cent rather than (say) between l %-2
per cent.
Of these three views, only the first, even on its
own assumptions, is readily quantifiable, for the
other two necessarily involve shifts in the Phillips
curve and thus the specification of the severity of
incomes policy. Moreover, though the incomes-policy
view does not, the other two involve costs in terms
of additional unemployment.
There is little systematic evidence of the quanti­
tative impact of incomes policy in the United King­
dom. What evidence there is suggests that in practice
it has been, in the short run, an unreliable device.11
Hence the two relevant policy variants are probably
the excess-capacity view and the combination view,
and a choice of these and an exchange adjustment
can be made rationally only on quantitative grounds.
Any attempt to assess the combination view in quanti­
tative terms must be highly tentative, for the meaning
of an incomes policy is far from clear, and consid­
erable uncertainty attaches to its performance.
By contrast the mechanism of adjustment through
exchange variation has been extensively studied by
economists. The theory of adjustment is relatively
well understood and there is a considerable body of
quantitative information. Admittedly much of this is
imperfect, and estimates of the relevant elasticities
vary. Nevertheless, there is more reliable and rele­
vant quantitative information about exchange-rate ad­
justment than about the policy mix actually selected
by the British authorities, which was a combination
of “some” additional unemployment (excess capacity)
and “some” incomes policy, or what we have called
the combination view.

Policy Response
In retrospect, therefore, it seems that from 1960
to 1967 the British authorities preferred to base policy
upon a loosely specified policy mixture about which
little was known quantitatively, rather than upon the
extensively studied mechanism of exchange adjustment.
As a result, policy has been basically irrational in
the sense that it has been based not upon an estimate
11Caves, chapter 3, and also see the National Board for Prices
and Incomes, Third General Report (H.M .S.O., July 1 9 6 8 ),
particularly Appendix A.




APRIL, 1969

of the extent of the fundamental disequilibrium and
the calculated capacity of the selected policy mix to
eliminate it, but on the hope that whatever degree
of adjustment, the chosen mixture brought about
would prove to be quantitatively adequate. An im­
mediate consequence of this has been that, in prac­
tice, British economic policy has been based not upon
rational calculations about the state of the fundamen­
tal balance, which economics suggest to be the rele­
vant concept, but upon the state of the observed
balance in the external accounts. This is not the
relevant concept for exchange policy for, in the short
run, markets may not be cleared; excess demand may
exist at home or abroad; cyclical fluctuations at
home and abroad may not be in phase; the flow of
goods may be interrupted by industrial disputes, po­
litical uncertainty or even climatic disturbance, so
that the flow of payments is influenced by these fac­
tors as well as by speculation about the existing
exchange rate. As a determinant of long-run exchange
policy, the observed balance is therefore likely to be
a poor and misleading guide. Concentration upon it,
and this concentration amounts in the United King­
dom almost to an obsession, inevitably tends to con­
fuse short-run and long-run positions and thus shortrun and long-run policies.
The confusion was particularly marked in the
United Kingdom during the Sixties when the state
of the observed balance dominated short-run policy
regarding the control of demand. Purely temporary
and cyclical improvements have been confused with
improvements in the fundamental balance. As a re­
sult, temporary observed surpluses have encouraged
temporary expansions which have led to the emer­
gence of large deficits. And these large deficits have,
in their turn, made it necessary to impose further
periods of slow growth.
Thus it seems clear that the British authorities’
attachment to exchange rigidity, which arose in
large measure because of a misinterpretation of the
experience of the Thirties, led not only to the rejec­
tion of the received “classical” theory of international
adjustment, but also to the neglect to specify an
alternative adjustment process. As a consequence, at­
tention has been focused upon the observed balance
rather than the theoretically relevant fundamental
balance and policy has been based upon pseudo­
solutions.
These criticisms, if valid, require that the theoreti­
cally relevant concept of the fundamental balance
should be quantifiable. To this issue we must now
turn our attention.
Page 21

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

Quantification and the Fundamental
Balance
To calculate the fundamental balance, on the as­
sumption of a given level of capacity utilization and
a given target rate of growth, theoretically requires
a complete and quantitatively estimated model of
the British economy and at least its principal
trading partners. The parameters of such a model
need to be independent of the problem under exam­
ination. No such model exists. Until such a model is
complete we can make only a rather crude first
approximation to the information we need to formu­
late a rational exchange policy under a regime of
fixed exchange rates.
Where no structural model exists, it remains pos­
sible to derive information from forecasting models.
Such models are inevitably crude. Their relation to
economic theory is not always clear and their para­
meters are not always readily related to the para­
meters of a structural model. Nor are they necessarily
independent of the problem under investigation.
Nevertheless, information to be obtained from a fore­
casting model provides a useful check on policy and,
in particular, on the assumptions underlying British
exchange policy. Accordingly, in what follows we
present some calculations, derived from an elemen­
tary forecasting model, of the fundamental balance
on visible trade and current account for the United
Kingdom.
The structure of this model is very simple and
the load of assumptions it carries is correspondingly
heavy. There is no suggestion that it is the best fore­
casting model which could be constructed. Refine­
ment might or might not be worthwhile. We have
not attempted it because the purpose of these es­
timates here is to suggest orders of magnitude rather
than precise numerical values.
We begin by dividing real imports into two com­
ponents: those which are primarily inputs to the
domestic production process and those which are
primarily finished goods. This gives us the identity:
I

=

Ii

+

Ii = oc0 + ccjY -)- ocoAS -|- 0C3 ^ -p- J

where Y = real gross domestic product;
AS = real investment in inventories;
Ph, Pf = home and foreign materials prices.
Page 22

For imports of finished goods we postulate a simi­
lar function, though in this case we include a dummy
variable (Z3) designed to take account of the liber­
alization of trade in 1957-58 and the apparently de­
creasing nonprice competitiveness of British manu­
facturers. This gives:
If = a 4 -f- 0C5Y -f- a 6AS -f- oc7 £

a 8Z;j

where Phf, Pf( = home and foreign prices of finished
goods;
Z;i = proxy for the influences of liberaliza­
tion and nonprice competitiveness.
Applied to annual data for the years 1953-66, these
equations perform surprisingly well, at least in the
sense of providing high correlation coefficients and
little evidence of serial correlation in the residuals.
Moreover, the parameter values are generally sig­
nificant and the signs are as expected. The results of
the regressions, together with the implied marginal
propensities and price elasticities, are in Table I.
If these results are accepted as a reasonable basis
for forecasting, we can now estimate the “full-employment”, “acceptable-growth” import bill by assum­
ing:
1 ) that full employment is defined by an un­
employment percentage of 1.6 %;

2) that GDP grows at an acceptable rate of
either 3 per cent or 4 per cent; and
3) that the home and foreign prices of ma­
terials and finished goods are the actual
prices ruling in each year.
To do this we must find some way of estimating
the rate of planned investment in inventories. To do
this we write:
S° (t) = A Y(t)
where

S* = the planned level of stocks, so that

AS* (t) = X[Y(t) - Y(t-l)} .

If

We seek to explain imports of inputs by three
variables, real gross domestic product, the rate of
inventory accumulation, and the relative prices of
British and overseas goods entering the input classi­
fication. Assuming a linear relation this gives:




APRIL, 1969

On this basis, given the regression equations and
the observed values of Pf and P(f for all t years, we
can calculate the “fundamental” import bill at cur­
rent prices.
On the export side we take both the real demand
for exports and their prices to be independent of the
domestic level of activity and rate of growth. These
rather heroic hypotheses allow us to treat export re­
ceipts as exogenous with unchanged exchange rates.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL, 1969

Table 1

REGRESSIONS OF IMPORTS O N INCOME, PRICES A N D INVENTORIES

Dependent V a ria b le ---- ^

Equation Number 1

Equation Number 2

Sum

Imports of
Finished G oods

Imports of
Inputs

Total Imports

Marginal
Propensities of
Total Imports

Elasticities of
Total Imports1

( 1+ 2 )

Independent Variables:
Real G D P
Inventory Investment
Price Ratio
Dummy Variable (Import Liberalization)
Constant

0.100

0.059
(4.0690)

(6.3694)

0.394
(7.3783)

0.221
(1.4444)

- 5 .5 4 9
(-4.2391)

-5.901
(-1 .4 1 7 5

89.527
(8.8317)
104 .316

0.159

0.159

0.615

0.615

-11.4 5 0

0.79

-0 .2 7

89.527
1502.84

R2

0.998

0.951

D -W

2.183

1.788

1607.656

Note: Regression coefficients are the top figures; their “t ” values appear below each coefficient, enclosed by parentheses. R 2 is the percent of variations in the
dependent variable which is explained by variations in the independent variable. D-W is the Durbin-Watson statistic,
i Evaluated a t the sample mean.

We are thus able to calculate the full-employment,
acceptable-growth balance of trade for each year.
We now adjust these figures in two ways. First, we
add an estimate of the invisible balance; second, we
add an amount, taken to be £ 6 0 million a year, to
allow for a systematic underestimate of current re­
ceipts thought to occur in the British accounts. This
gives us a figure for the estimated “fundamental cur­
rent balance.”
Finally, we take account of the fact that an appro­
priate definition of fundamental equilibrium in the
British case must make allowance for a “normal” net
outflow of long-term capital and the need to provide
for some measure of reserve accumulation and/or
debt repayment. A figure of £.300 million a year,
now probably an underestimate, has, in the past,
achieved some degree of official acceptance.12 Hence
we define the condition of fundamental equilibrium
as follows:
Exports (f.o.b.) - Imports (f.o.b.) + Net Invisible
Balance + £ 6 0 million — £300 million = 0
In Table II we give an estimate of the “funda­
mental deficits” and the “fundamental current ac­
count deficits” for each year from 1953 to 1966 for
both assumed “acceptable” growth rates.
12Essentially this figure makes little or no allowance for the
need to repay the debt arising out of the cumulative deficits
of 1964 to 1968.




Obviously the calculations underlying Table II
are crude and carry a very heavy load of assump­
tions.13 Three points in particular should be noted.
1) The application of the target surplus of £300
million to the year before 1959 may some­
what overstate the fundamental deficit for
those years.
2) The prices used in the calculation for the
early years reflect the unusually unfavorable
terms of trade which followed the outbreak
of the Korean War.
3) The 4 per cent acceptable growth rate has
been applied cumulatively from 1953. It
would probably be more reasonable to as­
sume an acceptable rate of slightly above
3 per cent from 1953 to 1963 and a 4 per
cent rate thereafter. The “compromise” fig­
ures of columns (3) and (6) provide an esti­
mate of this.
In addition, the 4 per cent growth rate implies a
rate of increase in productivity greater than Bri­
tain actually experienced. On the usual assump­
tions about the cost/price process in the United
Kingdom, this would imply a somewhat slower rise
in domestic prices/cost than actually occurred. Hence,
13Full details of the data, assumptions and calculations on which
this section is based are available on request from Professor
David C. Rowan, University of Southampton, Southampton,
England.
Page 23

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL, 1969

real exports (which we have taken as exogenous)
might be expected to be larger and real imports
smaller than Table II suggests.
It seems, therefore, reasonable to argue that the
calculated fundamental deficits for the years 1953-57
are probably overestimates, and that the calculations
for the 4 per cent growth rates are also overestimates.
Despite these limitations, it seems a reasonable in­
ference from Table II that the United Kingdom was
probably in fundamental deficit by 1959, if not by
1958. Moreover, the estimates suggest that from 1959
onwards the fundamental deficit grew very consid­
erably. Finally, it is reasonable to assume that by 1967
the fundamental deficit was between £1160 million
(which is certainly an overestimate) and £410 million
(which is very probably an underestimate) with a
reasonable guess putting it around £750 million.
As we have seen, no great claims can be made for
this simple forecasting calculation. Other more refined
and possibly more reliable forecasting techniques
could doubtless be devised. Nevertheless, unless the
calculations can display a very significant bias, they
do suggest that the United Kingdom, during the
period 1960-67, was suffering from a fundamental
disequilibrium sufficiently large to be identified, with
some confidence, by rather crude techniques.

Finally, in Table III we give the observed current
account deficit taken from the official figures, and
the fundamental current account deficits calculated
for each “acceptable growth rate.”
Extensive comment on Table III is unnecessary.
It does, however, serve to show how poor a guide
to long-run exchange policy the observed current
balance may be. For example, the very substantial
observed surplus in 1958, amounting to £344 million,
was, on even a 3 per cent growth basis, due very
largely to the low level of economic activity. Never­
theless, there can be little doubt that this largely
illusory observed surplus was an important factor in
the British expansion of 1959-60 and the Conserva­
tive electoral victory of 1959.
Again the much smaller observed surpluses of 1962
and 1963 were due primarily to slow growth and
increased unemployment. Nevertheless they were un­
doubtedly factors which encouraged the British ex­
pansion of 1963-64 and the very substantial deficit
of 1964.
Finally, it should also be clear that the observed
deficits frequently overstate the fundamental deficits.
They mislead, in fact, in much the same way as do
the observed surpluses.
Though the arguments in this section can be no
better than the simple regression model underlying

Table II

ESTIMATED CURRENT A N D FUNDAMENTAL ACCOUNT BALANCES FOR U.K.
With Alternative Growth Rates in Real GDP
(Millions of Pounds)
Estimated Current Account
Balance with
4 % Growth
Rate

3 % Growth
Rate

138
-8 5
-8 8
57
-6 1
-1 1 5
-2 6 2
-3 4 7
-3 5 5
-3 7 5
-4 6 5
-7 8 3
-677
-7 1 4
-9 1 7

172
-2 3
8
187
109
81
-28
-72
-4 2
-22
-5 3
-323
-137
-1 0 6
-250

1953
1954
1955
1956
1957
195 8
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1 96 4
196 5
1966
1967

Composite1
Growth
Rate
172
-2 3
8
187
109
81
-2 8
-72
-4 2
-2 6
-1 3 9
-4 3 0
-3 1 0
-3 2 4
-5 1 4

IThis is defined as growth in real GD P of 3% for 1953-61 and k% for 1961-67.

Page 24



Estimated Fundamental
Balance with
4 % Growth
Rate
-1 0 2
-3 2 5
-3 2 8
-1 8 3
-3 0 1
-35 5
-5 0 2
-5 8 7
-5 9 5
-6 1 5
-7 0 5
-1 0 2 3
-9 1 7
-9 5 4
-1 1 5 7

3 % Growth
Rate

Composite1
Growth
Rate

-6 8
-2 6 3
-2 3 2
-5 3
-1 3 1
-1 5 9
-2 6 8
-3 1 2
-282
-2 6 2
-2 9 3
-5 6 3
-3 7 7
-3 4 6
-4 9 0

-6 8
-2 6 3
-2 3 2
-53
-1 3 1
-159
-2 6 8
-3 1 2
-2 8 2
-2 6 6
-3 7 9
-6 7 0
-5 5 0
-5 6 4
-7 5 4

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL, 1969

Table III

ACTUAL AND ESTIMATED CURRENT ACCOUNT
BALANCE FOR U.K. WITH DIFFERENT
GROWTH RATES
(Millions of pounds)
Estimated Current Account
Balance with
4 % Growth
Rate
1953
195 4
1955
195 6
1957
1958
1959
1960
1961
1962
1963
1964
1965
1 96 6
1967

138
-85
-88
57
-6 1
-1 1 5
-2 6 2
-3 4 7
-3 5 5
-3 7 5
-4 6 5
-7 8 3
-6 7 7
-7 1 4
-9 1 7

3 % Growth
Rate
172
-2 3
8
18 7
109
81
-2 8
-7 2
-4 2
-2 2
-5 3
-323
-1 3 7
-1 0 6
-2 5 0

Composite1
Growth
Acutal Current
Rate
Account Balance
172
-2 3
8
187
109
81
-2 8
-7 2
-4 2
-2 6
-1 3 9
-4 3 0
-3 1 0
-3 2 4
-5 1 4

145
117
-1 5 5
208
23 3
34 4
143
-2 6 5
-4
112
111
-3 9 9
-91
15
-4 0 4

IThis is defined as growth in real GD P of 3% for 1953-61 and 4%
for 1961-67.

our calculations, it does not seem an overly strong
position to adopt that:
1) there is evidence that considerably before

1967, and possibly as early as 1958, the
United Kingdom was suffering from an identi­
fiable fundamental disequilibrium;
2 ) in the absence of any other well-specified
method of adjustment, devaluation came be­
tween nine and seven years later than was
required; and
3) the observed current balance is an unreli­
able indicator of the fundamental current
position.

The General Applicability of
British Experience
This paper has argued that British exchange policy
during the Sixties was misguided in that it sought to
retain an external value of the pound incompatible
with fundamental equilibrium. Moreover, we have
suggested that the existence of a significant funda­
mental disequilibrium was identifiable many years
before the pound was reluctantly devalued in No­
vember 1967.
We have also argued that the decision to retain a
disequilibrium parity at the cost of slower growth
and periods of reduced economic activity came, in
the main, from a misreading of the events of the
Thirties, and involved an implicit denial of the theory



of internal adjustment. In place of this theory, no
new analysis was developed. Instead, a variety of
poorly specified solutions were canvassed. These cul­
minated in the argument commonly used to defend
the 1963-64 expansion; that is, if the United Kingdom
expanded demand and output faster, then, after an
initial period of external deficit to be financed by
borrowing, the balance of payments would, in some
way not clearly specified, attain equilibrium. After
the exposure of this panacea in 1964, Britain was
virtually without a long-run external policy until 1967.
It is also the case that, though the British experience
has been the most dramatic, the reluctance of the
British authorities to alter a disequilibrium exchange
rate has its counterparts elsewhere. At the moment
of writing, the German authorities are refusing to
revalue a probably undervalued mark, and the French
authorities are refusing to devalue a probably over­
valued franc. It has also been suggested in some
quarters that the dollar itself is overvalued. Thus the
attitude of the British authorities, though not the ex­
perience of the British economy, is far from atypical.
National governments and monetary authorities, or so
at least it seems, are reluctant to undertake planned
exchange adjustments. Since exchange adjustments
ultimately cannot be avoided, the outcome has been
that crucial adjustments, because they have been un­
necessarily delayed, have been unnecessarily large.
Moreover, most adjustments have been undertaken
only when national monetary authorities have been
compelled, usually by speculators, to recognize the
inevitable. As a result, the international monetary
system created at Bretton Woods has, on a number
of occasions, been brought close to collapse.
The system established at Bretton Woods reflected,
though admittedly imperfectly, the Keynesian con­
cept of managed flexibility of exchange rates. Under
the Bretton Woods arrangements, limited changes in
parities (defined as less than 10 per cent of the pari­
ties existing in 1944) could be made unilaterally. It
was also envisaged that countries in fundamental
deficit would adjust their exchange rates by inter­
national agreement, thus avoiding competitive de­
valuations like those of the Thirties. Finally, a country
in chronic “fundamental surplus” which was unwilling
to appreciate could have its currency declared
“scarce” —a declaration which permitted its trading
partners to discriminate against it.
Unfortunately, the system has never been allowed
to operate as the theory on which it was based re­
quired. The principal reason for this has been the
Page 25

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

attachment of central bankers and financial commu­
nities to rigid parities.
It is, however, doubtful whether central bankers,
even if disposed to favor exchange adjustments, could
always persuade their governments to take such ac­
tions. Politicians and even financiers seem to attach
national prestige to particular parities, and many per­
sons who are not central bankers seem to regard an
external surplus as a sign of economic virtue and a
deficit as a sign of economic vice.
Furthermore, it should not be forgotten that cen­
tral bankers usually attach considerable (and not
necessarily excessive) importance to price stability.
A regime of fixed exchange rates tends to insure
that a domestic inflation is accompanied by an ex­
ternal deficit. To this extent it increases the ability
of central bankers to urge deflation. Unfortunately,
the concurrence of domestic inflations and external
deficits has, in some cases, encouraged central bankers
to diagnose fundamental deficits which are structural
in origin as due to macroeconomic mismanagement,
and thus to urge deflation rather than exchange
adjustment.14 It is, indeed, hard to escape the impres­
sion that many of the international gatherings of
central bankers at Basle and elsewhere are neces­
sitated by the need to find temporary solutions to
problems created by their own attachment to ex­
change rigidity rather than by the alleged refusal of
deficit countries to deflate sufficiently.
The result has been that, instead of the managed
flexibility with relatively small but frequent adjust­
ments which Bretton Woods required, we have had
the worst of all possible worlds —large, infrequent
and usually long-delayed exchange changes as well as
periods of considerable uncertainty and speculation.
The present problems of the mark and the franc (and
possibly the dollar and the pound) reflect the in­
ability of the central bankers and international mon­
etary authorities to accept the need for smaller and
more frequent exchange adjustments.

Towards A Rational Exchange Policy
The British experience is valuable not only be­
cause it emphasizes the incompatibility of rigid ex­
change rates and domestic economic objectives, but
also because it suggests the length of time which
14For an example of this position together with an optimistic
assessment of the ability of the monetary authority to dis­
tinguish between external imbalances due to macroeconomic
mismanagement and structural maladjustment, see Otmar Em minger, “Practical Aspects of the Problem of Balance of Pay­
ments Adjustments,” Journal of Political Economy, August
1967.


Page 26


APRIL, 1969

may have to elapse before a national monetary au­
thority can be persuaded to face this incompatibility.
Inevitably this strengthens the case for some form
of exchange flexibility. Theoretically there is a power­
ful case for permitting the rates of the principal
developed countries to float, and experience with
floating rates, in Britain after 1931 and in Canada
from 1950 to 1962, does not destroy this case. In
practice, however, primarily because of the attitudes
of central bankers and financial communities, it may
be wiser to aim at a system which permits countries
to change their rates by a small percentage each
year (the “crawling peg”).15
From the present system it should be possible to
move to the “crawling peg” system and finally to
floating rates. This evolutionary approach should have
the merits of encouraging the appropriate develop­
ment of a forward market in foreign exchange and,
by giving experience with continuous but small ad­
justment, removing some of the exaggerated fears
of exchange flexibility.
In advocating development along these flexible
lines, three points need to be made clear.
1) Limited flexibility is less likely to work well
if it is introduced into a system in which some
key countries are in marked fundamental dis­
equilibrium as they probably are at present. It
may be necessary, therefore, to begin with an
agreed realignment of key rates based upon the
best estimates which can be made of the equilibmium rates.
2) Limited flexibility should be viewed as a stage
in the movement towards fully floating rates —
not as a means of establishing parities which can
subsequently be pegged.
3) It must be realized that limited flexibility,
whether based upon discretionary or automatic
adjustment, is not a panacea. It will not elimin­
ate temporary crises, movements of “hot” money
arising out of the capacity of financial communi­
ties to frighten themselves, or the need for
reserves.
Limited flexibility, therefore, should be seen as a
“second-best” choice preferable to the present system
because it offers a means of bringing about relatively
smoother movements in the exchange rate, and
thus is a way of eliminating the lengthy tragedy of
errors which appears to have been the British
experience from 1960.
15McKenzie, pp. 15-23, presents a fuller review of the “crawling
peg.”

This article is available as Reprint No. 38.

Member Bank Income - 1968
1^1 ET PROFITS at member banks in the Eighth
Federal Reserve District rose moderately in 1968. Net
income after taxes (net profits) was up about 5 per
cent for the year, compared with increases of 8 and
14 per cent in 1967 and 1966 respectively and an aver­
age annual rate of 7 per cent in the eleven-year
1957-68 period.1
Operating revenue rose 16 per cent in 1968, re­
flecting both a larger volume of earning assets and
a higher average rate of return on assets. Expenses
were up 18 per cent, rising more rapidly than reve­
nue, although by a smaller dollar amount. Net current
earnings (operating revenue less operating expenses)
climbed 11 per cent compared with 4 per cent a year
earlier. However, the net effect of additions due to
recoveries, transfers from reserves, and profits, and
deductions due to losses, charge-offs and transfers to
reserves, was a deduction from net current earnings of
$25.6 million, or 16 per cent, compared with a deduc­
tion of $19.6 million, or 13 per cent in 1967.

ernment securities of $97 million was up 18 per cent
and that on other securities rose 22 per cent to $65
million in 1968. Revenue from all other sources totaled
$66 million, an increase of 18 per cent from the previ­
ous year.
Loans rose from an average of $5.9 billion in 1967
to $6.4 billion in 1968, an increase of 8 per cent.
This increase is similar to the trend growth in loans
from 1957 to 1968 of 8 per cent per year. Holdings
of U.S. Government securities rose 9 per cent in 1968,
compared with a trend growth of only 1 per cent
annually since 1957, and other securities rose 15 per
cent, somewhat above their 13 per cent trend rate.
The rate of return on all types of earning assets
increased. Returns on loans in 1968 averaged 6.7 per
cent, compared with 6.3 per cent in 1967. Returns on
U.S. Government securities averaged 4.8 per cent and

Net profits at all member banks in the nation were
7.5 per cent higher in 1968 than in 1967, somewhat
more than for district member banks. Operating reve­
nue rose slightly faster in the nation than in the
district, and expenses increased more slowly. The
net effect of security transactions and other profit
and loss adjustments on loans and other assets at
member banks in the nation was a reduction from
net current earnings of $1.2 billion, or 24 per cent
in 1968, compared with a reduction of $0.7 billion,
or 17 per cent in 1967.

Revenues
Operating revenue at district member banks to­
taled $655 million in 1968, or 16 per cent above the
previous year. The $428 million revenue on loans rep­
resented an increase of 14 per cent. Interest on Gov­
1Throughout this article 1957 is used as the base year in
calculating trend rates, since that year was more typical
of bank operations than 1958.




Page 27

APRIL, 1969

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

REVENUES AND EXPENSES OF EIGHTH DISTRICT MEMBER BANKS
M illio ns of Dollars

Revenue on Loans ................................
Interest on Securities
• U.S. Government ..............................
Other ...............................................
Service Charges on Deposit Accounts .....
Trust Department ..................................
A ll O ther Revenues ..............................

Per Cent C hange
A nnual
Rate
1 9 5 7 -6 8

1968

1 96 7

1 96 6

1957

...... 428 .2

374 .2

334.3

140.8

14.4

11.9

10.6

82.7
53.4
20.5
16.7
18.2

75.7
43.5
18.6
15.1
15.1

47.6
12.7
9.3
6.6
10.2

17.5
22.3
10.7
9.0
35.2

9.2
22.8
10.2
10.6
20.5

6.7
16.1
8.5
9.7
8.3

......
......
......
......
......

97.2
65.3
22.7
18.2
24.6

1 9 6 7 -6 8

1 9 6 6 -6 7

Total O perating Revenues ........... ......655 .2

56 5 .7

502 .3

227 .2

15.8

12.6

10.1

Salaries, W age s, and Benefits .............. ......149.5
Interest on Time Deposits .......... ............ ____ 202 .4
O ther Expenses ................................... ......139.8

132.4
171.7
113.8

118.8
138.4
102.8

6 3.7
22.6
50 .7

12.9
17.9
22.8

11.4
24.1
10.7

8.1
22.1
9.7

Total O perating Expenses ........... ...... 4 9 1 .6

4 1 8 .0

360.1

137.0

17.6

16.1

12.3

Net Current Earnings ----------------- ------ 163 .6

147 .7

142.3

90.2

10.8

3.8

5.6

15.9

20.2

5.2

— 12.0

— 21.3

9.4

Recoveries, Transfers from Reserves,
and Profits ....................................... ......
Losses, Charge-Offs, and Transfers
to Reserves ....................................... ......

14.0

35.5

45.1

16.7

1 1.5

— 21.3

8.2

128.1

117.3

78 .7

7.7

9.2

5.2

41.1

36.1

32.1

33.1

13.9

12.5

2.0

96.9

92.0

85.2

45.6

5.3

8.0

7.1

38.5

35.0

32.8

18.2

10.0

6.7

7.0

1.9
480

*

39.6

Net Income (Before Income Taxes) ..... 138 .0
Taxes on Net Income ............................ ......
Net Income (After Income Taxes)
Cash Dividends on Common Stock
Interest on Capital Notes and
Debentures1 ..................................... ......
Num ber of Banks ..................................

2.2
474

2.0
47 8

491

inclu d es small amount of cash dividends on preferred stock
♦Less than 0.05

4.5 per cent in 1968 and 1967, respectively, and those
on other securities were 3.6 per cent and 3.4 per cent.
While total revenue increased more rapidly than
loan revenue, the latter accounted for six-tenths of
the increase in total revenue from a year earlier.
Interest income from both U.S. Government securi­
ties and other securities (mostly issues of state and
local jurisdictions) rose somewhat more rapidly than
loan revenue during 1968. Revenue from securities
accounted for about three-tenths of the rise in total
revenues. Revenue from service charges on deposit
accounts, up 11 per cent, and trust department reve­
nue, up 9 per cent, rose more moderately than other
sources of revenue.
Although accounting for only a minor portion of
the total, miscellaneous revenues were the most ra­
pidly rising source, increasing from $18.2 million in
1967 to $24.6 million in 1968, or 35 per cent. This
gain reflects the proliferation of nonlending services
being offered by commercial banks in recent years.
Some of the income items included in this category
are rental of safe deposit boxes, income from leased
property, and income from foreign departments.

Page 28


Operating revenue at district banks has risen at
an average 10 per cent annual rate during the past
eleven years, from $227 million in 1957 to $655 mil­
lion in 1968.2 In addition to an increase in total assets,
the growth in revenue reflects a marked rise in the
general level of interest rates and a shift in the
composition of assets to more of the relatively
higher-earning types.
Total resources of district member banks grew from
$6.6 billion in 1957 to $12.9 billion in 1968, an average
annual increase of 6.3 per cent. Since the proportion
of assets in the form of cash declined slightly, earning
assets grew somewhat more rapidly, rising from $5
billion in 1957 to $10.3 billion in 1968, a 6.7 per
cent rate.
The composition of banks’ portfolios has changed
sharply since 1957 to include proportionately more
higher-earning assets. Holdings of U.S. Government
securities dropped from 28 per cent of assets in 1957
to 16 per cent in 1968. Meanwhile, loans rose from
2These data are not adjusted for changes in total number
of banks, resulting from new member banks or withdrawals
from memberships. The effect of such changes on the
total shown would be small.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL, 1969

relationships prevailing in much of 1968, banks found
it profitable to increase their borrowings despite the
rising rates paid on borrowed funds. During portions
of 1968 market rates were above the rates which
banks were permitted to pay on deposits under Reg­
ulation Q, and as a result banks relied more heavily
on borrowings to meet their loan demand. The rapid
increase in furniture and equipment expenses reflects
increased mechanization and automation in com­
mercial banking. Banks have been able to increase
efficiency through increased use of data-processing
equipment in performing the numerous clerical tasks
associated with banking operations.

40 per cent to nearly 50 per cent of assets, and
securities, other than U.S. Governments, rose from 8
to 14 per cent.
The average rate of return on bank assets has
trended upward. The average return on bank loans
increased from 5.3 per cent in 1957 to 6.7 per cent in
1968, while the average return on Government secu­
rities rose from 2.6 per cent to 4.8 per cent during the
same period.

Expenses
Operating expenses at district member banks to­
taled $492 billion in 1968, 18 per cent more than
the previous year. As in most other recent years, ex­
penses grew at a more rapid rate than revenue. Inter­
est payments on time and savings deposits accounted
for the largest dollar amount of increase in total
expenses, but miscellaneous expense was the most
rapidly rising item. Interest payments rose from $172
million in 1967 to $202 million in 1968, an increase of
18 per cent. Wages, salaries, and employee benefits
rose from $132 million in 1967 to $150 million in 1968,
or 13 per cent, as the number of officers and em­
ployees rose 6.4 per cent and average compensation
per person increased 6 per cent. All other expenses
rose 23 per cent from $114 million to $140 million.
The rapid rise in miscellaneous expenses was
largely due to larger payments for borrowed money
and for furniture and equipment. At the interest rate



Since 1957 operating expenses of member banks
in the district have risen from $137 million to $492
million, an average annual increase of 12 per cent.
Reflecting a generally rising demand for loanable
funds and competition among financial agencies to ob­
tain such funds, interest paid by banks has increased
sharply during the past decade. Interest expense rose
from $23 million in 1957 to $202 million in 1968, an
increase of 22 per cent per year. The volume of time
and savings accounts rose from $1.3 billion in 1957 to
$4.7 billion in 1968, or 12 per cent per year, while
the average rate paid on these accounts rose from
1.7 per cent to 4.3 per cent. Other expense items
have risen, but less rapidly than interest expense.
Salaries, wages, and fringe benefits rose at an average
annual rate of 8 per cent, and all other expenses
rose at a 10 per cent rate.

Net Earnings and Income
Net current e a rn in g s of m e m b e r banks in the
Eighth District totaled $164 million in 1968, an in­
crease of 11 per cent from a year earlier. This was
about double the average annual increase of 5.6 per
cent during the 1957-68 period. The net effect of
adjustments for losses, charge-offs and transfers to
valuation reserves in 1968, however, resulted in net
income being $25.6 million less than net current earn­
ings, compared with a $19.6 million difference in 1967.
Much of this increase in the earnings/income differen­
tial resulted from losses on securities sold.
Net income after taxes at district member banks
totaled $97 million in 1968, an increase of 5.3 per
cent from a year earlier. This was somewhat below
the trend rate of 7.1 per cent per year since 1957. In
comparison, net income after taxes for all member
banks in the nation rose 7.5 per cent last year and has
risen at an 8.3 per cent rate since 1957.
Page 29

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL, 1969

total increase in capital of $63 million, 6.3 per cent
above year-end 1967.
Since 1957, capital at district member banks has
risen at a 6.5 per cent rate. In the late 1950’s capital
was rising more rapidly than either deposits or assets.
As a result the capital-to-assets and capital-to-deposits
ratios both rose. Since 1962, however, these ratios
have had a downward trend. In comparison, the ratio
of capital to loans has declined from about 20 per cent,
prevailing in the 1957-62 period, to 16 per cent in
1968. Some analysts view these declining ratios as
an increase in banks’ exposure to risks, and viewed in
this manner, risk exposure has increased somewhat in
recent years.

Member banks distributed $38.5 million in divi­
dends on common stock in 1968, an increase of 10 per
cent from the previous year. Net retained earnings at
these banks totaled $56 million. These undivided
profits, of course, are the primary source of increased
capital in banks. In addition, member banks in the
district raised a net $6.7 million of other capital, for a

Page 30



FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF ST. LOUIS

APRIL,

1969

REVIEW I N D E X — 1969
Month
of Issue

Month
of Issue ___________ Title of Article___________________________

Title of Article

Jan.

Saving Flows in the Current Expansion
Growth — Metropolitan vs. Nonmetropolitan
Areas in the Central Mississippi Valley

Feb.

Stabilization Policy and Inflation
Operations o f the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis — 1968
International M onetary Reform and the
"Crawling Peg”

Mar.

Restraining Inflation
Relations Among Monetary Aggregates
A Program of Budget Restraint
The Relation Between Prices and
Employment: Two Views
Farm Income Prospects

Apr.

Monetary Actions, Credit Flows and Inflation
Monetary & Fiscal Actions: A Test o f Their
Relative Importance in Economic
Stabilization — Comment
— Reply
Towards A Rational Exchange Policy: Some
Reflections on the British Experience
Member Bank Income — 1968

WORKING PAPERS
T

hE

FOLLOWING two working papers have been added to our working

paper series. Single copies are available to persons with a special interest in
these research areas, and any discussion or comment would be welcomed by
each author. For copies write: Research Department, Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis, P. O. Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166.

Number

8

9




Tide of Working Paper

Release Date

The Market For Deposit-Type Financial Assets
(205 pages)

March 1969

Impact of Changing Conditions on Life Insurance
Companies (23 pages)

March 1969

Page 31

SUBSCRIPTIONS to this bank’s

R e v ie w

are available to the public without

charge, including bulk mailings to banks, business organizations, educational
institutions, and others. For information write: Research Department, Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis, P. O. Box 442, St. Louis, Missouri 63166.