View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

u  -E o c o  U &II FEDERAL RESERVE BANK AlLAS BANK OF OF O DALLAS FIRST QUARTER QUARTER 1999  The European System of 01 Central Banks U-;7me Mark A. W)mne  Government's Role In Government's in Primary and Secondary Education Lori L. L Taylor  This publication was digitized and made available by the Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas' Historical Library (FedHistory@dal.frb.org)  Economic Review Fedefal Reserw IIa/'III. 01 Dallas floblrt D. McT•• r, Jr. "",,~ ,  III<..  a._f~  Hillin E. Holcomb hoi ......  ,.......,0.  orr  Harvey RO$enblum .v.. ,....  ."m",-"  "~  W. Michie' en  s.>1lIw. ...... (  fI(eM . .  Stnlor EtclftGmiSb: Ind Assistlnl Vice Presidents SIephen P A BrOWfl  "'" """ Rober!VW Gilmet E~F  KDeni1l  Director, Centtr lor lilin American Economics, Ind ",ull1.nl VlcI Presldenl William C Gruben  Senior Economist Ind Rllul'Ch Ollicer Mmfl K Yucel  Economists RobBtt FOII'I'Ia,nl David M Gould Joseph' ' -  KeIth R PhilliDS !.Wei RosstII .IasoIll Saving  FiDm 0 Sigalla l.OIll layl", lUCinda Vargas AlaI! 0 V~d MifkA Wynne Carlos E J. M Zarmga  R,"ardl woel.tes  i'Jole:ssof Nathan S  Bal~e  ----~"""",*""",,,iII'  I'folwllf Thomas B fcmbV  Plo!essot Gfegory W Hutrl1\al1  Pro!1!$SOf Finn e KV!llano  c...~I"""'"  Prolessor Roy J RulHn  Ib'oot<  "alllo""'"  Elilton  Sle!!t1en P A BroWI'!  [van F KoeniG  PutJllulJonl OIrec1or Ka~C~ne  Copy [1111GB Jenrn1f/ AI"l'fbacIT  """"-  Design' Produenon liur&J Be  canmt 1IiIM-.... 15 ~ ttrrth! ftdeqj " - " " BoN til 0If!cs.. TIle 'MII"i rrPllDd .. to. III ...  _w an  alll'lCll$D1dalQ~IIIIII:th!~OII111 ~  '-  rI DaIIS 01 h feddj Rarnt  ~I Wd . . l>.r..t,1I ~. 01 fNr;r PIe:Dt "'~Ior~n~u. 1C1IPI~. b;d:; tSU5. DI - . , cI\MIQlI$ II IbI NIIIC: WI!; l'IeDw~ f«ItnI AeuI.,. 1IaJ .. 01  Dalla. PO !lor 6559IlI (2141 92'l.!I25l  ~Ias.  TX  ~5905.  ""'deS IIWY ~ 1!1p1'/Wd on lilt ~ IlWlIhe DtId,l...,j M>d l1li IIfsl I~h 0e!'-'I1m!fII Is PlrMdtid '111111 a COfIY IlIIha ~'QIl tOllLlrnmQ It.  iOUIU' l!  fl!II!.flI«In'III~T"  Contents The European System of Central Banks Mark A. Wynne  On January 1, 1999, (he European System of Central Banks (ESCB) began conducting monetary policy for eleven of the fifteen  nations of the European Union, formally creating an economic and monetary union. The ESCB is governed by the decision-making bodies of the European Central Bank (EeB) and manages Europe's new currency, the cum. The stnlcture of the  Esell is  in many ways  Page 2  similar to that of the Federa l Reserve System, with lhe [e B playing a role similar to that of the Board of Governors aod the various national central banks occupying positions flOt unlike those of the regional Reserve Banks. In this article, Mark Wynne compares the (\vo central banks, dra\ving on the insighls of economic thea!)' to shed light on how moneta!)' policy is likely to be made in Europe under moneta!), union. He documents twO key differences between the ESCB and the Federal Reserve System. First, the ESCB has a much stronger price stability mandate. Second, power is much more diffusely distributed in the ESCB. The strong mandate for price stability will enhance the euro's credibility. But the diffuse power structure may make it difficult to resolve conflicts, wh ich will undermine credibility. The moneta!), un ion 's fate depends on which of these two features of the moneta!), policy process dominates.  Government's Role in Primary and Secondary Education  Traditionally, economists ofTer three broad rationales for government participation in education-market failure, externalities, a nd altruism. In this a rticle, Lori Taylor describes the three mtionales, discusses the economic evidence in their support, and examines their major implications for the role of government in prima!)' and seconda!)' education. She concl udes that there is a significant public interest in education. However, the government's role is clearly a subordinate one; fami lies should remain the primary educational decision makers-and the prima!)' educational fina nciers. Finally, he r analYSis of the economic evidence suggests that w hile government has a n interest in ensuring that schools produce desirable socia l outcomes, it does not necessarily have a role in providing educational services or in regulating the way in which private schools provide such services.  Lori L Taylor  Page 15  In the early hours of May 3, 1998, the leaders of the European Union (EU) took the most significant step toward European integration since the signing of the Treaty of Rome in 1957. In giving the green light to the economic and monetary union (EMU) of eleven of the fifteen EU members—the EU11—they took another major step toward a more unified Europe.1 This latest development culminates a process of European integration that began shortly after World War II and that may one day lead to a Europe as politically and economically integrated as the United States is today. The substance of monetary union is that the countries in EMU no longer have distinct national currencies. A new currency—the euro—has replaced them, and monetary policy for the EU11 is no longer determined by their national central banks but by the European System of Central Banks (ESCB). (See Glossary, page 4.) The unprecedented monetary union of such a large and disparate group of sovereign nations will pose enormous challenges to the ESCB, which consists of the recently established European Central Bank (ECB) and the national central banks (NCBs) of EU members. The ECB commenced operations on June 1, 1998, and assumed responsibility for the conduct of monetary policy for the euro area on January 1, 1999. The euro has replaced the national currencies of the EU11, and in 2002 the notes and coins that currently circulate in these countries will cease to be legal tender.2 The ESCB is conducting monetary policy on a continental scale. Table 1 presents comparative statistics for the United States, the EU, the EU11, and Japan. In terms of population and aggregate output, the EU11 is comparable to the United States. Should EMU eventually incorporate all fifteen members of the EU, its economic weight would significantly exceed that of the United States. Table 1 also compares the recent economic performance of the four groups. The most significant difference is the much poorer employment performance of the EU, whose unemployment rate is more than twice that of the United States. The consensus among economists is that the bulk of this unemployment is structural rather than cyclical and reflects the greater rigidity of Europe’s labor market institutions.3 The extent to which the euro can credibly challenge the U.S. dollar’s primacy in global finance will depend largely on the ECB’s success in maintaining the euro’s purchasing power and making it attractive to international investors. The structure of the ESCB is similar in  The European System of Central Banks Mark A. Wynne Senior Economist and Policy Advisor Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas  T  he structure of the ESCB is  similar in many ways to that of another central bank charged with conducting monetary policy on a continental scale—the Federal Reserve System.  2  Table 1  Comparative Statistics on the U.S., EU, EU11, and Japan many ways to that of another central bank charged with conducting monetary policy on a continental scale—the Federal Reserve System. In this article, I review the structure of the new central bank, sketching out key similarities to and differences from the Federal Reserve.  U.S.  THE ROAD TO EMU EMU is the latest step in the move toward greater economic (and political) integration in Europe that began with the establishment of the European Payments Union in 1950. That entity was little more than a technical device to facilitate the reconstruction of Europe following the devastation of World War II. But it can also be seen as the first manifestation of the political will to forge closer bonds between the wartime belligerents so as to preclude future conflict. A more substantive step was taken in 1951 with the formation of the European Coal and Steel Community, which created a common market for these commodities involving Germany, France, Italy, and the Benelux countries (Belgium, Netherlands, and Luxembourg). This entity was supposed to be accompanied by stronger political and military ties (including the creation of a European army), but concerns about loss of national sovereignty led to abandonment of these plans. Instead, the emphasis shifted to greater integration on the economic front, and in 1957 the Treaty of Rome created the European Economic Community (EEC), or Common Market. Coordination of economic policies was always seen as integral to the success of the Common Market, and in 1964 the Committee of Governors of the central banks of the European Community (EC) was formed to coordinate monetary policies. The central banks of Europe have had varying degrees of success coordinating their monetary policies over the past three decades.4 Monetary union of EC members was proposed in 1970 in the Werner Report. While this report envisioned a monetary union by 1980, two key international developments derailed the plan. The first was the breakdown of the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange rates in August 1971; the second was the 1973 oil crisis. The EC responded to the exchange rate turbulence that followed both events with a system of quasi-fixed exchange rates, the so-called snake, but this rapidly collapsed to an arrangement involving only a few members. The second attempt to fix exchange rates, the European Monetary System, was established in 1979. It proved more durable, although it, too, experi-  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  EU  EU11  Japan  Population  263 million  373 million  290 million  126 million  GDP (current dollars)  $6.955 trillion  $8.497 trillion  $6.809 trillion  $5.217 trillion  GDP (constant dollars)  $6.149 trillion  $7.203 trillion  $5.721 trillion  $3.168 trillion  GDP growth  3.8 percent  2.6 percent  2.4 percent  .9 percent  Inflation rate  2.3 percent  1.9 percent  1.7 percent  1.7 percent  Unemployment rate  4.9 percent  11.1 percent  11.7 percent  3.4 percent  SOURCES: Population and GDP for 1995: United Nations (1997). GDP growth, inflation, and unemployment for 1997: OECD Economic Outlook and OECD Main Economic Indicators.  enced a number of major and minor crises. By the mid-1980s the EC had expanded to twelve members, and in 1989, renewed interest in a formal monetary union resulted in the Delors Report. The Delors Report laid out the basic plan and timetable for monetary union that has been followed since the early 1990s. The proposals in the report were incorporated into the Treaty on European Union, which was agreed upon at a meeting of the European Council in Maastricht, Netherlands, in December 1991 and signed in February 1992. This agreement, commonly known as the Maastricht Treaty, was the most comprehensive change in the basic law of the European Community since the Treaty of Rome. It established the institutional framework for monetary policy under EMU, a timetable for the creation of a monetary union, and the criteria for countries’ participation. Many academic economists and others have questioned the wisdom of a monetary union between such disparate countries, but the debate became moot with the decision to proceed.5 However, the points made by the critics of monetary union indicate where stresses may arise in the future and the kind of challenges the ECB may face. INSTITUTIONAL STRUCTURES The Maastricht Treaty established the institutional arrangements for the conduct of monetary policy under EMU. The treaty provides for the formation of the ESCB, which in many ways is indirectly modeled on the Federal Reserve System.6 At the top of the ESCB is the Frankfurtbased ECB, which has a role similar to that of the Federal Reserve’s Board of Governors. The various national central banks play a role similar to that of the regional Federal Reserve Banks.  3  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  Glossary European Economic Community (EEC): Also known as the Common Market, established by the Treaty of Rome in 1957.  tary policy.7 Executive Board members are appointed for nonrenewable eight-year terms, shorter than the fourteen-year terms of Federal Reserve Governors but the same as the terms of members of the Directorate of Deutsche Bundesbank.  European Monetary Institute (EMI): Created by the Maastricht Treaty to carry out preparatory work for EMU; dissolved with the establishment of the European Central Bank. European Parliament: Advises the European Commission and reviews all legislative proposals; members are elected by popular vote. European System of Central Banks (ESCB): Responsible for conducting monetary policy for the economic and monetary union (EMU). The ESCB consists of the European Central Bank and the national central banks of all fifteen EU members. The ESCB is governed by the decision-making bodies of the ECB.  RELATIONSHIP OF THE ECB AND NCBS While there are many similarities in the structures of the ESCB and the Federal Reserve System, there are also important differences. The Executive Board of the ECB will be in a permanent minority on the Governing Council, whereas the Board of Governors has a permanent majority on the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC). All NCB governors have a vote in all policy decisions of the Governing Council, whereas with a single exception, Reserve Bank presidents participate in FOMC votes every two or three years, depending on which Bank they represent. Indeed, the relationship of the ECB and the NCBs probably bears a closer resemblance to the relationship of the Board of Governors and the Reserve Banks in the early years of the Federal Reserve System than to the situation today. For its first twenty years, power was more diffuse in the Federal Reserve System than it is now. Some critics have argued that this diffuse distribution of power and the struggle for hegemony contributed to the Fed’s inability to deal with the Great Depression (see in particular Friedman and Schwartz 1963).8 Friedman and Schwartz (1963) contend that the distribution of power in the Federal Reserve System was a key contributor to the “ineptness” of monetary policy during the Depression. In the 1920s, the institutional structure did not present a problem as long as all regional Reserve Banks and the Board were willing to accept the leadership of the governor of the New York Bank, Benjamin Strong. But with Strong’s departure in 1928, the structure became unworkable. The other Reserve Banks were no longer willing to accept the domination of the New York Bank, and the Board was not in a position to impose its will on the System. Friedman and Schwartz argue that the Board’s weak position was due to the fact that it had not played a leadership role in the System in the 1920s but had instead functioned primarily as a supervisory and review body. The distribution of power in the ESCB differs from that in the Federal Reserve System in other important respects as well. For example, the Board of Governors exercises a lot more  European Central Bank (ECB): The central bank for the economic and monetary union. The decision-making bodies of the ECB are the Governing Council and the Executive Board. Executive Board: Responsible for the day-to-day functioning of the ECB and the implementation of the single monetary policy. Governing Council: Consists of the Executive Board of the ECB and the governors of the national central banks of the states participating in EMU. Responsible for the formulation of a single monetary policy. National central bank (NCB): The individual central banks of countries in the European Union. European Community (EC): Consists of the European Coal and Steel Community, the European Atomic Energy Community, and the European Economic Community. The EC became the European Union when the Maastricht Treaty took effect on November 1, 1993. European Union (EU): Established by the Maastricht Treaty to deepen economic and political links between the countries of Europe. Council of Ministers: The primary decision-making institution of the European Union; consists of ministerial-level representatives of all EU states. European Council: The name given to the Council of Ministers when it meets in the form of EU heads of state or government. ECOFIN: The name given to the Council of Ministers when it meets in the form of EU economics and finance ministers. European Commission: The executive branch of the European Union; responsible for implementing the decisions of the Council of Ministers and proposing new measures and directions for the EU. Maastricht Treaty: More formally, the Treaty on European Union; signed in 1992 by the EU heads of state, it established the framework for economic and monetary union in Europe. Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank: The statute, appended to the Maastricht Treaty, detailing the structures and mandates of the ESCB and the ECB.  Monetary policy decisions are made by the Governing Council of the ECB, which consists of the Executive Board of the ECB and the governors of the participating countries’ central banks. The Executive Board consists of the president and vice president of the ECB and four other members. The president of the ECB chairs the Governing Council, in essence occupying a position similar to that of the chairman of the Fed’s Board of Governors. Under the Maastricht Treaty, the Governing Council is responsible for formulating monetary policy for the single-currency area, while the Executive Board is responsible for implementing mone-  4  nors’ delegation of much of its supervisory power over the staff and the System to the chairman enhances the position’s authority within the System. And finally, the chairman has the ability to attract votes simply by virtue of office. The president of the ECB also possesses powers beyond those of other Executive Board or Governing Council members. The president chairs meetings of both bodies and casts the deciding vote in the event of a tie.11 He also represents the ECB externally.12 Under Article 109b of the treaty, the president of the ECB may be invited to participate in Council meetings and presents the ECB’s annual report to the Council and the European Parliament. Perhaps the only additional source of power potentially but not currently available to the president is full control over the ECB’s staff. Each of the six members of the Executive Board oversees some areas of the ECB’s operations.13 The Economics and Research Directorates, which employ the bulk of the ECB’s professional economists, do not report to the president but to another board member.  power in the Federal Reserve System than the ECB exercises within the ESCB. One source of the Board’s power is its authority to supervise the Reserve Banks’ activities and approve their budgets and the appointment of their presidents. Furthermore, the Board of Governors appoints three of the nine directors of the regional Reserve Banks, one of whom is designated chairman of the board of directors and Federal Reserve agent.9 The Board also appoints the deputy chairman of the board of each regional Bank. By contrast, the Maastricht Treaty gives the Governing Council control over the Executive Board: The terms and conditions of employment of the members of the Executive Board, in particular their salaries, pensions and other social security benefits shall be the subject of contracts with the ECB and shall be fixed by the Governing Council on a proposal from a Committee comprising three members appointed by the Governing Council and three members appointed by the Council. The members of the Executive Board shall not have the right to vote on matters referred to in this paragraph. (Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank, Article 11)  APPOINTMENT PROCESS All seven members of the Fed’s Board of Governors are appointed by the president of the United States and are subject to Senate confirmation. The Federal Reserve Act requires that “in selecting the members of the Board, not more than one of whom shall be selected from any one Federal Reserve district, the president shall have due regard to a fair representation of the financial, agricultural, industrial, and commercial interests, and geographical divisions of the country.”14 Regional Reserve Bank presidents are nominated by the boards of directors of those banks, but their final appointment is subject to approval by the Board of Governors. The ECB Executive Board is appointed by the European Council, with nominees subject to confirmation by the European Parliament. The Maastricht Treaty does not contain any provisions about the national composition of the Executive Board analogous to those in the Federal Reserve Act. However, the reality of EU politics is such that it would be unthinkable for there to be more than one national of any EU country on the board. While the European Parliament confirms nominees to the Executive Board, in reality Parliament has little real power to reject a nominee. The governors of the NCBs are appointed by their national governments and are not subject to approval by the ECB’s Executive Board.  Also, the principle of subsidiarity (whereby EU decisions are supposed to be made at the lowest possible level of political authority) may pose a fundamental obstacle to centralization of power with the ECB. The importance of this principle in EU decision making should not be underestimated; it is even articulated in the preamble to the Maastricht Treaty. The national central banks could use subsidiarity as a weapon to prevent the ECB from developing expertise in areas the NCBs feel are properly their province. The distribution of power within the ECB differs slightly from that in the Board of Governors. It is generally accepted that the chairman of the Board of Governors is more powerful than any of the other Board members.10 Maisel (1973) attributes the power of the chairman to a number of factors. The first is his role as titular head of the Federal Reserve System and his role as its spokesman; only the chairman speaks for the System as a whole. The second is the role of the chairman as the representative of the System in other forums. The third is the inherent power of the chairman to set the agenda for FOMC meetings. Fourth, the Board of Gover-  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  5  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  ity is a precondition for the objectives of sustainable growth and high employment. In recent years there have been calls for a clearer price stability mandate for the Federal Reserve System. For example, Hetzel (1990) has supported a mandate that stipulates price stability as the Fed’s primary goal. Hetzel favored the Neal Resolution (House Joint Resolution 409), introduced in September 1989, which would have required that “the Federal Open Market Committee of the Federal Reserve System… adopt and pursue monetary policies to reduce inflation gradually in order to eliminate inflation by not later than 5 years from the date of the enactment of this legislation and shall then adopt and pursue monetary policies to maintain price stability.” More recently, the Mack-Saxton bill, introduced in 1995 and reintroduced in 1997, would have made long-term price stability the primary goal of the Federal Reserve System. While several Reserve Bank presidents and the chairman of the Board of Governors have testified before Congress in support of legislation to mandate price stability as the Fed’s sole objective, this legislation has not gotten very far. The reasons for this are unclear: it may simply be that inflation is not currently perceived to be a major problem in the United States and that in the current low-inflation environment it would be undesirable for the Fed to de-emphasize output stabilization in its policy decisions.  MONETARY POLICY OBJECTIVES The Maastricht Treaty is unambiguous about the objective of monetary policy: The primary objective of the ESCB shall be to maintain price stability. Without prejudice to the objective of price stability, the ESCB shall support the general economic policies in the Community with a view to the achievement of the objectives of the Community as laid down in Article 2. The ESCB shall act in accordance with the principle of an open market economy with free competition, favoring an efficient allocation of resources, and in compliance with the principles set out in Article 3a.15 (Maastricht Treaty, Article 105)  This mandate is qualified by an obligation to “support the general economic policies in the Community,” but this support should be “without prejudice to the objective of price stability.”16 Treaty provisions dealing with the objectives of the ESCB are modeled on those in the Bundesbank Act but, interestingly, are a lot more specific about the ultimate objectives of monetary policy than is the German legislation. That act requires that “the Deutsche Bundesbank shall regulate the amount of money in circulation and of credit supplied to the economy— with the aim of safeguarding the currency” (Deutsche Bundesbank 1995, 23). Arguably, the act could be seen as giving the Bundesbank the freedom to choose between stabilizing the internal value of the currency—that is, the price level—or the external value of the currency, as reflected by the exchange rate. The ESCB’s mandate to pursue price stability contrasts with the Federal Reserve’s more ambiguous mandate:  INDEPENDENCE The ESCB is probably the most independent central bank in the world.17 The source of this independence is manifold. At the most basic level, the fact that the charter of the ESCB is an international treaty that can only be changed with the unanimous consent of its signatories makes it very difficult to exert political pressure on the ESCB. Furthermore, the Maastricht Treaty explicitly addresses the relationship between the ESCB and the political authorities in the EU:  The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and the Federal Open Market Committee shall maintain long run growth of the monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with the country’s long run potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices and moderate long-term interest rates. (Federal Reserve Act, Section 2A.1)  When exercising the powers and carrying out the tasks and duties conferred upon them by this Treaty and the Statute of the ESCB, neither the ECB, nor a national central bank, nor any member of their decision-making bodies shall seek or take instructions from Community institutions or bodies, from any government of a Member State or from any other body. The Community institutions and bodies and the governments of the Member States  Maisel (1973, 66) contends that the Fed has traditionally placed more emphasis on achieving price stability than on its other mandated objectives. Many economists believe that price stabil-  6  undertake to respect this principle and not to seek to influence the members of the decision-making bodies of the ECB or of the national central banks in the performance of their tasks. (Maastricht Treaty, Article 107)  inflation that leads to independent central banks and low inflation outcomes. The corollary is that simply granting independence to a central bank is insufficient to generate good inflation performance unless the central bank has significant political support. Attaining such support is one of the greatest challenges facing the ESCB. There is little doubt the Bundesbank’s success in pursuing price stability has been helped considerably by strong public support for the central bank’s policies. The ESCB—at least initially— will not enjoy anything like the same degree of support, and this may complicate the political environment in which it has to operate.19 Central bank independence takes many forms. Fischer (1994) distinguishes between goal independence and instrument independence.20 In his taxonomy, “a central bank whose goals are imprecisely defined has goal independence” (Fischer 1994, 292). Since the Maastricht Treaty makes price stability the primary goal of the ESCB without defining what is meant by price stability, the ESCB enjoys considerable goal independence. Thus, the ESCB could define price stability to mean a stable price level, or a specific (low) inflation rate, or as prevailing when “inflation ceases to be a factor in the day to day decisions of households and businesses.” The European Monetary Institute (EMI) argued that a public announcement of a quantified definition of price stability should be an integral component of whatever monetary strategy the ECB pursues. In October 1998 the ECB announced that “price stability shall be defined as a year-on-year increase in the Harmonised Index of Consumer Prices (HICP) for the euro area of below 2%.” 21 The ECB also announced that “price stability is to be maintained over the medium term,” without defining medium term. Fischer considers a central bank to have instrument independence “when it has full discretion and power to deploy monetary policy to attain its goals.” By that definition, the ESCB enjoys full instrument independence. Under Article 109b of the Maastricht Treaty, the president of the Council of Ministers and a member of the European Commission (the executive branch of the EU) have the right to participate as nonvoting members in meetings of the ECB’s Governing Council. Furthermore, the president of the Council of Ministers has the right to submit motions for deliberation by the Governing Council. Article 109b also stipulates that “the President of the ECB shall be invited to participate in Council meetings when the Council is discussing matters relating to the objectives and tasks of the ESCB.”  The reason for granting such strong independence to the ESCB is the overwhelming evidence that independent central banks tend to deliver relatively better inflation performance (that is, lower rates of inflation) at no cost in terms of slower real output growth or higher unemployment. Banaian, Laney, and Willett (1983) were among the first to examine the relationship between central bank independence and inflation outcomes. Subsequent work by Alesina and Summers (1993) shows that the better inflation performance delivered by independent central banks comes at no cost in terms of real economic performance. Numerous other studies (see, for example, Cukierman, Webb, and Neyapti 1992 and Eijffinger and De Haan 1996) confirm these findings. Other provisions of the Maastricht Treaty further reinforce the independence of the ESCB. First, Executive Board members and governors of the NCBs are appointed for relatively long terms. Executive Board members have nonrenewable eight-year terms, while NCB governors are appointed for a minimum of five years.18 The terms of the first appointees to the Executive Board were staggered from four to eight years so that subsequent terms will also be staggered. Second, the treaty states: Overdraft facilities or any other type of credit facility with the ECB or with the central banks of the Member States (hereinafter referred to as “national central banks”) in favor of Community institutions or bodies, central governments, regional, local or other public authorities, other bodies governed by public law, or public undertakings of Member States shall be prohibited, as shall the purchase directly from them by the ECB or national central banks of debt instruments. (Maastricht Treaty, Article 104)  This prohibition is restated in Article 21 of the statute of the ESCB and ECB. It is worth noting that some authors have recently challenged the causal interpretation of the relationship between central bank independence and inflation outcomes. Specifically, Posen (1993) has argued it is popular opposition to  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  7  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  This arrangement echoes somewhat the early structure of the Federal Reserve System. Until 1935, the secretary of the Treasury and the comptroller of the currency were ex officio members of the eight-member Federal Reserve Board, with the secretary of the Treasury also acting as Board chairman. The Banking Act of 1935 removed both officials from the Board. As noted above, the motivation for centralizing power at the Board of Governors was to eliminate perceived ambiguities about the distribution of power in the System that were believed to have contributed to the failure of Fed policy during the Depression.22 While the president of the Council of Ministers does not have the same degree of formal power to influence ECB deliberations as the Treasury secretary had over the Federal Reserve System in its early years, his presence at Governing Council meetings may influence the course of debate in ways that are difficult to anticipate. The ECB arrangement more closely mirrors the provision in Article 13.2 of the Bundesbank Act, whereby representatives of the government have the right to attend (without voting) meetings of the Bundesbank Council. In practice, the only time government ministers do attend Bundesbank meetings is when the annual money supply targets are being set. The independence of the ESCB, or at least its ability to pursue price stability, is circumscribed somewhat by the fact that exchange rate policy remains the province of the Council of Ministers. Article 109 of the Maastricht Treaty stipulates that “in the absence of an exchangerate system in relation to one or more nonCommunity currencies—the Council, acting by a qualified majority either on a recommendation from the Commission and after consulting the ECB or on a recommendation from the ECB, may formulate general orientations for exchange-rate policy in relation to these currencies.” While the article goes on to state that “these general orientations shall be without prejudice to the primary objective of the ESCB to maintain price stability,” it remains to be seen how a conflict between the two goals—fixed exchange rates and price stability—would be resolved. A decision by EU political authorities to fix the exchange rate of the euro vis-à-vis, say, the dollar would seriously compromise the ESCB’s ability to conduct a monetary policy targeted solely at price stability in the euro area.23 A similar situation prevailed in Germany before the establishment of EMU. Apparently, an understanding between the Bundesbank and the German government (the so-called Emminger  Letter) temporarily released the Bundesbank from its obligation to intervene to support fixed exchange rates in the European Monetary System if such intervention threatened price stability in Germany.24 This understanding was invoked in September 1992 when intervention to support the Italian lira threatened the Bundesbank’s ability to hit its money growth targets. However, some argue that laws can only go so far in ensuring a central bank’s independence. What politicians give, they can just as easily take away. Others contend that in relationships between central banks and political authorities, personalities matter as much if not more than laws. Friedman and Schwartz (1963, 228) suggest as much in discussing the early relationship of the Fed and the Treasury. Giovannini (1993) makes a more compelling case along these lines. He argues that the ESCB’s independence, as codified in the treaty and statute, is a necessary but insufficient condition for the successful pursuit of low inflation. Substantial and consistent political support is also required. The Federal Reserve System enjoys significant independence, but, notes Maisel (1973, 24), it is “ill-defined and circumscribed.” The Constitution gives Congress the right “to coin money and regulate the value thereof.” Congress has delegated this authority to the Federal Reserve but could, in principle, revoke it at any time. The Federal Reserve Act has been amended and supplemented several times since its passage in 1913, although typically the changes have given the Fed greater operational independence while simultaneously increasing its accountability to Congress. ACCOUNTABILITY As noted above, the ESCB is the most independent central bank in the world. The Maastricht Treaty ensures that the ESCB will not be torn between pursuing multiple objectives or subject to political pressure to take what it views as inappropriate policy actions. However, the quid pro quo of central bank independence in a democratic society is that there should be adverse consequences for the central bank if it fails to achieve its objectives. Some critics have argued that independent central banks are fundamentally inconsistent with democratic principles (see, for example, Friedman 1962). The Maastricht Treaty imposes minimal reporting obligations on the ECB, requiring only that the ECB submit an annual report to the  8  Council meetings may lead to pressure to vote along national lines rather than in the interests of the euro area as a whole. Issing (1998) argues that the Maastricht Treaty requires keeping the votes of the Governing Council confidential. He cites Article 10 of the statute, which states that “the proceedings of the meetings [of the Governing Council] shall be confidential. The Governing Council may decide to make the outcome of its deliberations public.” Issing contends that insofar as the votes of individual Governing Council members can be considered part of the proceedings rather than part of the outcome, the treaty prohibits their publication. Others argue that the votes could just as easily be considered part of the outcome rather than part of the proceedings and that publication of votes would enhance Council members’ ability to resist domestic political pressures. It remains to be seen whether the ECB’s decisions on confidentiality will foster or impede the development of its credibility.  European Parliament (and ECOFIN—the council of economics and finance ministers, the European Commission, and the European Council). The president of the ECB has indicated his willingness to testify before the European Parliament up to four times a year. The treaty notes that the ECB may decide to publish its decisions, recommendations, and opinions but does not impose any obligation in this regard. The treaty also provides for the ECB president and other Executive Board members to be heard by the relevant committees of the European Parliament. Some prominent members of the European Parliament have called for the ECB to exceed its treaty obligations in communicating with the public. Randzio-Plath argues that in addition to publishing its annual and quarterly reports the ECB should be required to make public its decisions and the reasoning behind its monetary policy actions. The decisions of the Executive Board meetings should be made public on the same day. The Bank should explain why the decision has been taken as well as how the decision is linked to, and affects other policies. Minutes should be published, as should the voting behavior of the members, on the day of the subsequent meeting of the Executive Board. Detailed minutes should be published at the latest five weeks after the meeting. The reasons for decisions should be clear and public. Transparency is needed in a democracy. (Randzio-Plath 1997– 98, 24)  25  STRATEGY A strategy for monetary policy can be defined as a rule whereby a central bank responds to developments in the economy to attain its final objective. After much preparatory work on possible strategies, the EMI concluded that the only realistic options for the ESCB were monetary targeting or inflation targeting. According to the EMI, one of the key attractions of monetary targeting is “that it clearly indicates a responsibility of the central bank for developments that are more directly under its control.” An additional attraction of monetary targeting is that this strategy was successfully pursued by the Bundesbank before EMU. Adopting monetary targeting might therefore help the ESCB inherit some of the Bundesbank’s credibility.26 The strategy’s primary drawback is the high degree of uncertainty about the likely behavior of monetary aggregates in the euro area following the start of monetary union. Inflation targeting is attractive because ultimately price stability is the responsibility of the central bank.27 Indeed, many newly independent central banks, such as the Bank of England and the Reserve Bank of New Zealand, have opted for inflation targets as a means of rapidly acquiring credibility for their commitment to price stability. The primary drawback of an inflation-targeting strategy is the difficulty of forecasting inflation at the relevant horizons. Because monetary policy actions only affect  There is little doubt that transparency is crucial to the success of a central bank. However, how best to achieve this is not always obvious. The FOMC’s current practice is to announce policy changes as soon as they are made. Immediately after each meeting the FOMC issues a statement that a decision was made to lower or raise rates, or merely noting that the meeting ended, if the decision is to leave rates unchanged. The FOMC publishes the minutes of each meeting shortly after the subsequent meeting. The ECB does things differently. For a variety of reasons, there is considerable resistance to publishing minutes and the voting records of Governing Council members. Perhaps the most important reason is the need to insulate Council members from domestic political pressures. While the Executive Board and the NCBs have statutory independence from domestic and Community political institutions, publication of voting records and the minutes of  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  9  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  inflation with a long and variable lag (of eighteen months to two years), accurately forecasting inflation at long horizons is crucial to the success of an inflation-targeting strategy. However, the two strategies overlap significantly in their implications for the day-to-day conduct of monetary policy. Both strategies are forward-looking in their emphasis and aim to control inflation by acting preemptively. Where they differ most is in their implications for the ESCB’s communications policy—that is, how the ESCB goes about explaining its actions to the general public. Under a monetary-targeting strategy, the ESCB would explain and justify its actions primarily by reference to the behavior of the money stock vis-à-vis some target range. Under inflation targeting, the ESCB would explain and justify its actions by reference to the forecasted behavior of inflation vis-à-vis some target level. Because of the many uncertainties accompanying the start of EMU, it is not surprising that the ESCB opted for a mixed strategy that combines elements of inflation targeting and money targeting. This is the “stability-oriented monetary policy strategy” announced by the ESCB in October 1998, whose key elements are a quantitative definition of price stability, a prominent role for money with a reference value for the growth of a monetary aggregate, and a broadly based assessment of the outlook for future price developments. Adoption of a mixed strategy might seem to defeat the purpose of articulating a strategy in the first place. One of the most important reasons for formulating and adhering to a strategy is that doing so makes monetary policy actions more transparent and easier to communicate to the public. The simpler the strategy, the easier that communication. Under a rigid monetarytargeting strategy, a central bank need only point to money growth in excess of its target to justify increases in interest rates. Under a mixed strategy, the situation would be more complicated because the central bank would have to spell out in detail how it would respond to different scenarios. In particular, the central bank would need to explain what it would do if growth in the money stock were signaling that a tightening of monetary policy would be appropriate, while the inflation forecast was signaling that an easing of monetary policy was appropriate. Having to detail all these contingencies makes it considerably harder to communicate with the general public, and it is only a short step from this to the look-at-everything, respond-to-everything approach to policy.  Again, the contrast with the way the Federal Reserve conducts monetary policy is instructive. At present the Fed does not employ either a monetary-targeting or inflation-targeting approach. Monetary targets have not played an important role in U.S. monetary policy since at least the early 1990s. And the Fed has never formally adopted inflation targeting as a strategy, at least not to the extent that, say, the Bank of England has. However, the Fed is a lot more forward-looking in its deliberations than it was in the 1970s.28 Why the Fed does not feel the need to articulate a strategy for monetary policy is an open question. One reason may be that the Fed has done reasonably well controlling inflation and building credibility without a formal strategy, and as long as that continues, it sees no need to change. This is consistent with the view that debates about strategy are most intense in central banks that need to rapidly acquire credibility for their commitment to price stability. MONETARY POLICY TOOLS The ESCB has three instruments available for the conduct of monetary policy. It engages in open market operations, offers standing facilities, and requires credit institutions to hold minimum reserves. Open market operations play a central role in the conduct of monetary policy. The ESCB has five types of instruments available for the conduct of open market operations, the most important of which is reverse transactions. The ESCB also has the option of using outright transactions, issuing debt certificates, making foreign exchange swaps, and collecting fixedterm deposits. Open market operations are initiated by the ECB but are conducted through the NCBs. The ECB decides on the instrument to be used in all open market operations and on the terms and conditions for their execution. This highly decentralized approach to monetary policy operations is in marked contrast to the Fed’s practice of conducting all operations through the New York Reserve Bank. The ESCB offers standing facilities to provide and absorb overnight liquidity, signal the general stance of monetary policy, and bound overnight market interest rates. These facilities—a marginal lending facility and a deposit facility—are available to eligible counterparties on their own initiative as long as they fulfill the relevant conditions. Only financial institutions subject to the reserve requirement may access the standing facilities (and participate in open market operations based on standard tenders).  10  Sweden, and the UK. All but four members are participating in the first round of EMU. Denmark, Sweden, and the UK are not participating for domestic political reasons; Greece failed to meet the convergence criteria laid down in the Maastricht Treaty but intends to join as soon as possible.  The Fed does not provide comparable facilities. The ESCB transacts in a wide range of financial assets in conducting monetary policy operations. These assets are not necessarily restricted to the debt liabilities of national governments, but they are required to satisfy certain criteria so as to protect the ESCB from the risk of losses on its monetary policy operations. Finally, the ECB has set a reserve requirement ratio at 2 percent, with the reservable components of the liability base consisting of overnight deposits, deposits with agreed maturity up to two years, deposits redeemable at notice up to two years, debt securities with agreed maturity up to two years, and money market paper. The ECB allows financial institutions to deduct a lump-sum allowance of 100,000 euros from their reserve requirement. The ECB remunerates reserve holdings at an interest rate corresponding to the rate of its main refinancing operations, with interest paid on the first business day after the end of the reserve maintenance period.  2  CONCLUSIONS The launching of EMU is probably the single most important development in international monetary relations in the past fifty years. If monetary union succeeds, the euro may one day challenge the U.S. dollar’s dominance in international transactions. The sheer size of the single-currency area will fundamentally alter international monetary arrangements. How the euro fares against the dollar will depend on the relative performances of the ESCB and the Federal Reserve in maintaining price stability in their respective territories. The ESCB starts with the advantage of an unambiguous mandate for price stability based on an international treaty that can only be altered with the consent of all its signatories. However, the diffuse distribution of power within the ESCB may make it difficult to resolve the conflicts of national interests that some academic critics of EMU believe doom the undertaking to failure. By contrast, the Federal Reserve System does not have as strong a mandate for price stability, but its more centralized decision-making structure arguably enhances the monetary policy process in the United States.  3  4  5  6  7  8  NOTES 1  The fifteen members of the EU are Austria, Belgium, Denmark, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, Portugal, Spain,  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  11  EMU countries’ notes and coins will continue to circulate until 2002; however, they no longer exist as currencies in their own right but as nondecimal denominations of the euro. There are several reasons for the three-year transition before the euro acquires a physical form. First, it will take time to adapt the physical payments infrastructure in each of the participating countries to the new notes and coins. In 1995, there were some 3.15 million vending machines and 130,000 ATMs in the EU; such machines will have to be recalibrated to accept the new currency. Second is the magnitude of the task of replacing national currencies. Printing enough banknotes and minting enough coins to replace all the existing notes and coins will take time. In 1994, more than 12 billion banknotes and 70 billion coins circulated in the EU, with a combined weight of 300,000 metric tons. Minting of euro coins began in May 1998. Finally, the transition allows businesses and the general public to become familiar with the new currency before having to use it for all transactions. During the transition, the no-compulsion, no-prohibition principle governs the use of the euro. For a recent analysis of the unemployment problem in Europe, see Ljunqvist and Sargent (1998). For this article, the significance of the Committee of Governors is that the economic unit created to support the committee would subsequently form the cadre for the European Central Bank. For a textbook review of the major issues, see De Grauwe (1997). See also Feldstein (1997) and Wyplosz (1997). Actually, many features of the ESCB are modeled on Deutsche Bundesbank, which is modeled on the Federal Reserve System. See Deutsche Bundesbank (1995). Maastricht Treaty Protocol (no. 3) on the Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank, Article 12.1. The FOMC in its current form, with the Board of Governors enjoying a permanent majority, did not come into being until 1935. When the Federal Reserve System was established in 1914, it was thought discount lending would be the primary tool of monetary policy, with individual Reserve Banks having considerable discretion to set discount rates. It was not until the 1920s that the potential of open market operations was discovered. In the spring of 1922 the Committee of Governors on Centralized Execution of Purchases and Sales by Federal Reserve Banks was established to coordinate the actions of the System. This committee was reconstituted as the Open Market Investment  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  9 10  11  12  13 14 15  Committee (OMIC) in 1923, consisting of representatives of the Boston, New York, Philadelphia, Cleveland, and Chicago Reserve Banks, under the chairmanship of the New York Bank. The OMIC was disbanded in 1930 and reconstituted as the Open Market Policy Conference, composed of representatives from all twelve Reserve Banks. The Banking Act of 1933 established the FOMC, consisting of representatives of the twelve Reserve Banks and the seven Board of Governors members. The Banking Act of 1935 altered the FOMC’s composition to give the seven Board members a vote in open market policy and, more importantly, reduce the representation of the Reserve Banks to five members. This gave the Board of Governors a permanent majority. Federal Reserve Act, Section 4.20. See, for example, the schematic diagrams of the informal power structure of the Federal Reserve System in any intermediate money and banking textbook. Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank, Articles 10 and 13. Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank, Article 13. European Central Bank (1998b). Federal Reserve Act, Section 10.1. Article 2 of the treaty states that “the Community shall have as its task, by establishing a common market and an economic and monetary union and by implementing the common policies or activities referred to in Articles 3 and 3a, to promote throughout the Community a harmonious and balanced development of economic activities, sustainable and non-inflationary growth respecting the environment, a high degree of convergence of economic performance, a high level of employment and of social protection, the raising of the standard of living and quality of life, and economic and social cohesion and solidarity between the Member States.” Article 3a of the treaty states: “A1. For the purposes set out in Article 2, the activities of the Member States and the Community shall include, as provided in this Treaty and in accordance with the timetable set out therein, the adoption of an economic policy which is based on the close coordination of the Member States’ economic policies, on the internal market and on the definition of common objectives, and conducted in accordance with the principle of an open market economy with free competition. 2. Concurrently with the foregoing, and as provided in this Treaty and in accordance with the timetable and the procedures set out therein, these activities shall include the irrevocable fixing of exchange rates leading to the introduction of a single currency, the ECU [European currency unit], and the definition and conduct of a single monetary policy and exchange-rate policy the primary objective of both of which shall be to maintain price stability and, without prejudice to this objective, to support the general economic policies in  16  17  18  19  20  21 22  23  24  25 26 27  28  12  the Community, in accordance with the principle of an open market economy with free competition. 3. These activities of the Member States and the Community shall entail compliance with the following guiding principles: stable prices, sound public finances and monetary conditions and a sustainable balance of payments.” Other provisions in the treaty further reinforce the mandate for price stability. First, Article 2 of the statute repeats Article 105 of the treaty. Article 2 of the treaty makes the promotion of noninflationary growth one of the European Community’s objectives. Article 3 of the treaty states that the primary objective of both monetary and exchange rate policy following the start of monetary union “shall be to maintain price stability.” Article 3 of the treaty also states that achieving stable prices is one of the guiding principles of the Community. Alesina and Grilli (1992) evaluate the political and economic independence of the ECB using the same criteria as other authors to construct quantitative indexes of central bank independence. They find that the ECB will enjoy the same degree of political and economic independence as the Bundesbank, which is somewhat more independent than the Fed. Statute of the European System of Central Banks and of the European Central Bank, Article 14.2. Posen (1993) is more sanguine about the ECB’s prospects, arguing that it will have important political support from the European financial community. Alesina and Grilli (1992) use the terms political independence and economic independence to refer to essentially the same things. European Central Bank (1998a). See, for example, Friedman and Schwartz (1963) and Timberlake (1993). As Fischer (1994, 304) notes, “Monetary and exchange rate policies cannot be independent. Under floating rates, monetary policy affects the exchange rate. Thus the government cannot have control over exchange rate policy while the central bank has control over monetary policy. The government should have the authority to choose the exchange rate regime. If it chooses a fixed exchange rate regime, it has then essentially — though not completely— determined monetary policy. While a central bank can be more or less independent of the government in a fixed exchange rate regime, its independent ability to determine the rate of inflation and interest rates is sharply curtailed.” See also Giovannini (1993). See, for example, Ungerer (1997) and Gros and Thygesen (1998). See, in particular, Buiter (1998a, 1998b). Issing (1994) argues along these lines. For analyses of inflation targeting as a strategy for monetary policy, see Haldane (1995), Leiderman and Svensson (1995), and Bernanke and Mishkin (1997). See Goodfriend (1993).  REFERENCES  Perspectives 11 (Fall): 23 – 42.  Alesina, Alberto, and Vittorio Grilli (1992), “The European Central Bank: Reshaping Monetary Politics in Europe,” in Establishing a Central Bank: Issues in Europe and Lessons from the United States, ed. Matthew B. Canzoneri, Vittorio Grilli, and Paul R. Masson (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), 49 – 85.  Fischer, Stanley (1994), “Modern Central Banking,” in The Future of Central Banking: The Tercentenary Symposium of the Bank of England, ed. Forrest Capie, Charles Goodhart, Stanley Fischer, and Norbert Schnadt (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press), 262 – 308. Friedman, Milton (1962), “Should There Be an Independent Monetary Authority?” in In Search of a Monetary Constitution, ed. Leland B. Yeager (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press), 219 – 43.  Alesina, Alberto, and Lawrence H. Summers (1993), “Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative Evidence,” Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 25 (May): 151– 62.  Friedman, Milton, and Anna J. Schwartz (1963), A Monetary History of the United States 1867–1960 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press).  Banaian, King, Leroy O. Laney, and Thomas D. Willett (1983), “Central Bank Independence: An International Comparison,” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Review, March, 1–13.  Giovannini, Alberto (1993), “Central Banking in a Monetary Union: Reflections on the Proposed Statute of the European Central Bank,” Carnegie –Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 38: 191– 230.  Bernanke, Ben S., and Frederic S. Mishkin (1997), “Inflation Targeting: A New Framework for Monetary Policy?” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (Spring): 97–116.  Goodfriend, Marvin (1993), “Interest Rate Policy and the Inflation Scare Problem: 1979 –1992,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly, Winter, 1– 24.  Buiter, Willem H. (1998a), “Independence of ECB Likely to Be Perverted If Council Voting Kept Secret,” Financial Times, September 24, 14. ——— (1998b), “ECB Secrecy Is the Euro’s Fatal Flaw,” Sunday Telegraph, October 18, B6.  Gros, Daniel, and Niels Thygesen (1998), European Monetary Integration: From the European Monetary System to Economic and Monetary Union, 2nd ed. (London: Longman).  Cukierman, Alex, Steven B. Webb, and Bilin Neyapti (1992), “Measuring the Independence of Central Banks and Its Effect on Policy Outcomes,” World Bank Economic Review 6 (September): 353 – 98.  Haldane, Andrew (1995), Targeting Inflation (London: Bank of England). Hetzel, Robert L. (1990), “A Mandate for Price Stability,” Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Review, March– April, 45 – 53.  De Grauwe, Paul (1997), The Economics of Monetary Integration, 3rd ed. (Oxford: Oxford University Press).  Issing, Otmar (1994), “Monetary policy strategy in the EMU,” in A Framework for Monetary Stability, ed. J. A. H. de Beaufort Wijnholds, S. C. W. Eijffinger, and L. H. Hoogduin (Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers), 135 – 48.  Deutsche Bundesbank (1995), The Monetary Policy of the Bundesbank (Frankfurt am Main: Deutsche Bundesbank). Eijffinger, Sylvester, and Jacob De Haan (1996), The Political Economy of Central-Bank Independence, Special Paper no. 19, International Finance Section, Princeton University.  ——— (1998), “Open for Business,” Financial Times, September 22, 16.  European Central Bank (1998a), press release, October 13, “A Stability-Oriented Monetary Policy Strategy for the ESCB.”  Leiderman, Leonardo, and Lars E. O. Svensson (1995), Inflation Targets (London: Center for Economic Policy Research).  ——— (1998b), press release, June 4, “Statement by the Executive Board of the European Central Bank on the Distribution of Responsibilities Among Its Members for the Business Areas of the ECB.”  Ljungqvist, Lars, and Thomas J. Sargent (1998), “The European Unemployment Dilemma,” Journal of Political Economy 106 (June): 514 – 50.  Feldstein, Martin (1997), “The Political Economy of the European Economic and Monetary Union: Political Sources of an Economic Liability,” Journal of Economic  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  Maisel, Sherman J. (1973), Managing the Dollar (New York: W. W. Norton).  13  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  Ungerer, Horst (1997), A Concise History of European Monetary Integration: From EPU to EMU (Westport, Conn.: Quorum Books).  Posen, Adam S. (1993), “Why Central Bank Independence Does Not Cause Low Inflation: There Is No Institutional Fix for Politics,” in Finance and the International Economy 7: The Amex Bank Review Prize Essays, ed. Richard O’Brien (Oxford: Oxford University Press), 45 – 54.  United Nations (1997), Statistical Yearbook 1995 , 42nd ed. (New York: United Nations).  Randzio-Plath, Christa (1997– 98), “Democratic Accountability of the European Central Bank,” Central Banking 8 (Winter): 22 – 25.  Wyplosz, Charles (1997), “EMU: How and Why It Might Happen,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (Fall): 3 – 21.  Timberlake, Richard H. (1993), Monetary Policy in the United States: An Intellectual and Institutional History (Chicago: University of Chicago Press).  14  Public primary and secondary education is big business in the United States.1 As Table 1 illustrates, nearly 90 percent of U.S. children attend public schools, at an annual public expenditure of more than 3.5 percent of gross domestic product. In 1994 government spending on primary and secondary education exceeded $235 billion, or roughly 3.5 percent of GDP. Public education is also big business internationally. In 1994 the governments of Germany, Italy, Japan, and the United Kingdom each spent at least 2.9 percent of GDP on primary and secondary schooling, while the governments of Canada and France each spent at least 4 percent of GDP. Worldwide, public spending on primary and secondary education in 1994 topped $1.275 trillion. The fact that societies around the world spend so much public money on education does not prove that government has an economically legitimate role in primary and secondary education, however. Education’s pervasively public nature could also be interpreted as evidence that special interests around the world successfully use governments to further their own, private objectives. One must look elsewhere for economic insight into the government’s role in primary and secondary education. Traditionally, economists offer three broad rationales for government participation in primary and secondary education (for example, see the discussions in Hoxby 1996 or Poterba 1996). If any of these rationales hold, the only open question is the nature of that participation. This article describes the three rationales, discusses the economic evidence in their support, and examines their implications for government’s role in primary and secondary education.  Government’s Role in Primary and Secondary Education Lori L. Taylor Senior Economist and Policy Advisor Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas  T  his article describes three  rationales for government participation in primary and secondary education, discusses the economic evidence in their support, and examines their major implications for the role of government.  RATIONALES FOR GOVERNMENT INTERVENTION First, many economists believe that imperfections in the capital market cause it to fail to provide the socially desirable level of educational investment. For example, because human capital is embodied in people, it is difficult to use as collateral for a loan.2 Therefore, if the education market were purely private, lenders would charge a premium for educational loans that they would not charge for other types of investment loans. Such a premium leads to underinvestment in human capital from a social perspective. Furthermore, because children, by virtue of their youth, cannot commit to repay educational loans, they must rely on their families to invest appropriately in their educations. Becker and Murphy (1988) argue that parents who do  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  15  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  Table 1  Government’s Role in Primary and Secondary Education in the United States  1990 1991 1992 1993 1994  Public enrollment as a percentage of total enrollment  Public expenditures as a percentage of GDP  88.7 89.0 88.8 88.8 88.7  3.8 3.8 3.5 3.8 3.5  THE EVIDENCE No economist has found a smoking gun that irrefutably supports any of these rationales for government intervention in the education market. Furthermore, because economists generally accept it, the capital-market-failure rationale has been the subject of little or no empirical research. However, a substantial body of work suggests education may generate positive externalities, and a few researchers examining the demand for education have found evidence that could support either the altruism or the externality rationale.  SOURCE: National Center for Education Statistics (1998, 1997, 1996).  not plan to leave bequests to their children also tend to underinvest in their education.3 In their view, “both parents and children could be better off with a ‘contract’ that calls for parents to raise investments to the efficient level in return for a commitment by children to repay their elderly parents” (Becker and Murphy 1988, 6). A system of tax-supported education coupled with transfers to the elderly could function like such a contract. Creating and enforcing desirable contracts that fail to exist in the market could be a rationale for government participation in primary and secondary education.4 Second, some economists argue that education generates positive externalities—that is, benefits to society that exceed the benefits to the students themselves. For example, Friedman and Friedman (1990) argue that “a stable democratic society is impossible without a minimum degree of literacy and knowledge on the part of most citizens.” Because students and their families don’t consider these benefits when they make educational decisions—such as whether to drop out of high school—they tend to invest less in education than would be socially optimal. If increased education is the most cost-effective way to produce externality benefits, society has an interest in encouraging people to invest in more schooling than they otherwise would. Finally, some economists argue that society feels altruistic toward children—especially poor children—and education is a tool for redistributing some of society’s resources in their direction. Although the recipients might prefer cash, society gives education, either because educational transfers are an efficient strategy for ensuring that children—rather than parents—are the recipients of public funds or because educational transfers satisfy society’s taste for charity.5 The latter reason is similar to the argument for why the government gives poor people food stamps instead of cash: society wants the recipients to consume what it thinks is good for them, not necessarily what they think is good for them.  Analyses of Externalities Educational externalities fall into two broad categories—second-best externalities and firstbest externalities. Second-best externalities arise when education generates nonprivate benefits as a consequence of an unrelated and distortionary government policy; first-best externalities arise independent of such policies. Because the nonprivate benefits associated with second-best externalities would not exist (or would be private benefits) if the distortionary policy did not exist, second-best externalities are not as persuasive as first-best externalities for justifying government intervention in the education market. Second-Best Externalities. The tax code is a major source of second-best externalities from education. Because incomes increase with education, income tax payments increase with education. The increased earnings and consumption of educated individuals also lead them to pay more in sales, payroll, and property taxes. Although the magnitude of the effect is unknown, education may also produce a second-best externality through its positive effect on a community’s tax base (Weisbrod 1964, Hirsch and Marcus 1969, Holtmann 1971). An increase in the average level of education generally raises the income of the community, which (because housing is a normal good) tends to lead to higher property values. High levels of educational attainment appear to attract firms (see, for example, Fox and Murray 1990, Bartik 1989, Carlton 1983), which also positively affects property values. This externality is a purely distributive one, rearranging the business environment in the local best interest at the expense of another, less attractive locale. Furthermore, to the extent that communities tax business property at a higher rate than residential property, attracting new businesses can increase the tax base even if aggregate property values remain unchanged. With a larger tax  16  there are first-best externalities from education. For example, in analyzing the forty-eight contiguous states, Wasylenko and McGuire (1985) find that the level of educational attainment contributes to employment growth, independent of its effect on wages. Fox and Murray (1990) analyze Tennessee counties and find that for a given wage, the firm entry rate (number of new firms/ number of active firms) increases as the educational attainment of a county increases, implying that the educational attainment of a county enhances firm productivity. Because all private productivity benefits from education should be internalized by the labor contract and be incorporated into the wage, these findings suggest education may generate externality benefits. The pattern of international capital flows also suggests there may be education externalities. Capital should flow to the countries where it can earn the highest rates of return, which, according to neoclassical growth theory, should be the countries with the lowest capital–labor ratios. However, we do not observe strong capital flows into poor countries with low capital–labor ratios. Although both discuss other possible explanations, Lucas (1988, 1990) and Gundlach (1994) explore the hypothesis that externality benefits from human capital could explain this discrepancy.8 Examining data on India and the United States and assuming that the total stock of human capital grows at the same rate as that part of the stock accumulated through formal schooling, Lucas (1990) finds that “taking the external effects of human capital into account…entirely eliminates the predicted return differential.” Gundlach (1994) finds similar results for rate-of-return differentials between the United States and South Asia, Latin America, and other Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development countries. A number of other cross-country studies also examine the important contribution human capital makes to economic growth (for example, see Engelbrecht 1997 and Benhabib and Spiegel 1994 or the discussions in Carlino 1995, Sala-i-Martin 1994, and Barro 1992). Unfortunately, such cross-country evidence does not build a persuasive case for externality benefits from primary and secondary education. As Levine and Renelt (1992) illustrate, the results of cross-country growth models are disturbingly fragile.9 A number of models that do not incorporate human capital externalities also seem to fit the cross-country data equally well (see, for example, Benhabib and Jovanovic 1991 and the discussion in Jorgenson 1998). The researchers usually do not rule out the possibility that the  base, local governments can generate a given level of tax revenues with lower tax rates. Because the deadweight loss associated with taxes generally falls as the marginal tax rate falls, government activities can be less distortionary in communities with higher tax bases. The social safety net is the other major source of second-best externalities from education. Educated individuals are less likely to receive welfare, Medicaid, or unemployment compensation (McMahon 1987). They and their children tend to be healthier (Grossman and Kaestner 1997), which should reduce their use of the public health system. Their children are less likely to become teenage mothers, live in poverty, or suffer from severe child abuse (Maynard and McGrath 1997), all conditions that are not only personal tragedies but also drains on the public purse. First-Best Externalities. Most of the firstbest externalities the literature examines are related to productivity and economic growth. Such externalities arise whenever education enhances productivity or economic growth in a way that is not reflected in the private returns to education. Thus, whenever wages do not capture the full effects of a worker’s education, externality benefits may arise. Similarly, if patents do not fully capture the benefits of scientific or technological discoveries and education fosters such discoveries, part of the productivity gain from technical change would also represent externality benefits from education. Rauch (1993) observes that if educational externalities enhance worker productivity, “economically identical workers will tend to earn higher wages in human capital rich, rather than human capital poor,” regions. Migration in response to the higher wages will bid up rents in such areas until worker utility is equalized across the country. “Cities with higher average levels of human capital should therefore have higher wages and higher land rents” (Rauch 1993). Using data from the 1980 census to test this hypothesis, Rauch finds that the average level of education in a standard metropolitan statistical area (SMSA) has a significant, positive effect on both wages and rents.6 His estimates suggest that “each additional year of SMSA average education can be expected to raise total factor productivity by 2.8% with a standard error of estimate of 0.8%.” The estimates also imply that “the social return [to formal education] exceeds the private return by a factor of…roughly 1.7.” 7 Rauch examines factor prices, but a number of other researchers examining factor quantities have also found evidence suggesting that  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  17  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  by choosing to live in a place that offers a particular mix of taxes and educational services. Of interest here are studies that differentiate between private and social demands for education. Such studies incorporate the premise that households not directly benefiting from educational spending would only be willing to pay for it if school spending satisfies some social objective. Because that social objective could be either redistribution or the production of externality benefits, a finding of significant social demand for education can support either of the two rationales for government intervention in the education market. In one such study, Wyckoff (1984) examines survey data about a referendum in Michigan. Voters were asked to choose one of six possible tax rates, each of which would support a different level of educational spending per pupil. The survey contains information about which of the six tax/expenditure levels the voter preferred, the household’s tax price of educational expenditures, whether the voter is employed by the local school district, the number of children the household has in local public schools, whether the voter believes increased school spending affects school quality, and other characteristics of the household. Wyckoff hypothesizes that the preferences of households with children in the local public schools reveal information about private demand for education, while the preferences of households without such children reveal information about social demand for education. Like other researchers (for example, Rubinfeld and Shapiro 1989, Lankford 1985, Rubinfeld 1977), Wyckoff finds evidence that households with children in public schools favor higher spending on education than households without such children. However, he also demonstrates that, all else being equal, households without children in the local schools seem willing to pay for public schooling. Evaluated at the mean of all other characteristics, households with no children in the schools were willing to pay $1,222 per pupil, while otherwise equal households with one child in school were willing to pay $1,532 per pupil.12 Wyckoff concludes that at the margin, 9 percent of the benefits from educational expenditures accrue to households without children in school. However, he notes that because his sample is small and the estimation is imprecise, the social portion could be as low as zero or as high as 50 percent. Weisbrod (1962, 1964) originated a line of analysis that uses expenditure, rather than voting, data to evaluate the social demand for edu-  growth benefits of human capital are fully private. In addition, much of the recent literature explicitly dealing with externality benefits focuses on spillovers from research and development or learning by doing, both of which only loosely relate to primary and secondary education. Furthermore, as Behrman and Rosenzweig (1994) discuss, international variations in the completeness of the data and in the measurement of enrollment and literacy can make cross-country data on education very problematic. Similarly, cross-country data on educational attainment are problematic because they do not control for potentially large differences in school quality.10 Finally, as noted education researcher George Psacharopoulos (1996) put it in discussing the use of cross-country data to evaluate education externalities, “Beyond the quality of such data, countries differ in many other respects than the general level of education of their labor force or population for the desired effect to be credibly picked up in such analysis.…Thus, the externality in question might just be another name for our ignorance on what really determines economic growth.” Some have argued that in addition to its apparent effects on growth, education might also generate an externality by deterring crime (for example, see Usher 1997 or Haveman and Wolfe 1984). Unfortunately, as with analyses of cross-country growth, the empirical evidence is unpersuasive. In her survey of the literature on crime and education, Witte concludes that “most crime is committed by young men during their adolescent years” and that “neither years of schooling completed nor receipt of a high school degree has a significant effect on an individual’s level of criminal activity. However, greater amounts of time in school are associated with lower levels of criminal activity” (Witte 1997, 233). Apparently, custodial supervision reduces the opportunities to offend. Thus, the evidence does not support the hypothesis of externality benefits from primary and secondary education per se, but rather one of externality benefits from keeping teenagers off the streets.11 ANALYSES OF THE DEMAND FOR EDUCATION Analyses of the demand for education use information about voting and expenditure patterns to tease out information about the public’s willingness to pay for education. The underlying premise of all these studies is that households reveal their preferences for education either by choosing to vote in a particular way or  18  Subsequent tests of Weisbrod’s hypothesis have yielded mixed results. Hadley (1985) updates the analysis, excluding the intergovernmental aid and demographic variables and measuring personal income per capita rather than per pupil.14 He confirms Weisbrod’s hypothesis for the 1959–60 school year but rejects it for the 1976–77 school year. Greene (1977) and Holland (1974) observe that local data are more appropriate than statelevel data for testing Weisbrod’s hypothesis. Their results are also mixed. Using 1960 data and treating state aid as endogenous (but, like Hadley, excluding student demographics), Holland finds no relationship between migration and per-pupil expenditures in Oklahoma State Economic Areas. Using 1970 data and including data on both intergovernmental aid and student demographics, Greene finds that expenditures by New York school districts positively correlate with immigration and negatively correlate with emigration. A common shortcoming of all these studies is that they rely on migration data ill suited to the analysis. The data do not differentiate the emigration of those educated in the region from the emigration of those educated elsewhere, nor do they indicate the human capital endowments of the migrants. Furthermore, none of these analyses adjusts the emigration data for the presence of parents with school-age children. A search for school quality could lead parents to migrate in direct response to the level of school spending—attracted to communities with high expenditures and repelled by communities with low expenditures. Because this migration pattern mimics the negative correlation between expenditures and emigration expected under Weisbrod’s hypothesis, data that include the emigration of parents with school-age children are biased in favor of the hypothesis and should not be used to test it. Another shortcoming these studies share is that they treat emigration and immigration as exogenous when they clearly are endogenous. Research on migration and labor finds that the number of years of schooling significantly and positively correlates with the propensity to migrate (Borsch-Supan 1990, Myers 1972, Schultz 1982). By extension, there should be a similar correlation for educational quality. To the extent that school quality is attributable to school spending, local expenditures on education will influence the future migration patterns of students. At the very least, characteristics of the local labor market that help determine a community’s ability to pay for schools also deter-  cation. He hypothesizes that any social benefits of education accrue primarily to the community in which the educated person lives. Although Weisbrod does not put it in these terms, his premise could also be seen as implying that society feels altruistic only toward locals who remain local. In either case, a community’s willingness to pay for education should correlate with expected migration patterns. Everything else being equal, if a community’s willingness to pay for schooling arises from the expectation of social benefits, educational expenditures should follow a particular pattern. Communities anticipating high emigration of locally educated individuals should be less willing to pay for investment in education because they are unable to capture externalities produced by the education of those who subsequently move away; it is not rational to pay for benefits not received. On the other hand, if educational expenditures attract new residents who are already highly educated, then, all else equal, communities that experience high immigration of educated persons should be more willing to pay for schooling. Finally, if school spending is not a strong attraction for the educated, communities that anticipate high immigration of educated individuals should substitute this “imported” human capital for the locally produced variety and be less willing to pay for schooling. Weisbrod (1964) constructs a simple linear regression model that explains current educational expenditures at the state level (circa 1960) by total personal income (both in per-pupil terms); the percentage change in state population from net immigration and net emigration (separate variables); the fractions of expenditures attributable to state and federal aid, respectively; and by certain characteristics of the student body.13 He finds the state and federal aid percentages insignificant at the 5 percent level in explaining differences in educational expenditures for the forty-eight contiguous states. Personal income per pupil is a significant and positive explanatory variable, as is the percentage of public school students in high school. Weisbrod attributes the explanatory power of the latter to the higher cost of teaching high school students. Net migration has an asymmetric effect on expenditures. While net immigration has no statistically significant effect, net emigration has a significant, negative effect on current expenditures. Although cautious about reading too much into his results, Weisbrod concludes that his analysis supports the case for significant nonprivate benefits from education.  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  19  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  mine the likelihood of migration for reasons of employment. Taylor (1992) refines these studies by examining the relationship between migration and educational expenditure when both emigration and immigration are endogenous rather than exogenous. Her analysis focuses on the emigration of locally educated high school graduates who are unlikely to have school-age children and the immigration of high school graduates. She also incorporates an educational production function to reflect efficiency differences in producing human capital. The analysis is conducted across a subset of states, using school-level data on expenditures and including a wide variety of student demographics. Taylor finds that the emigration of locally educated individuals does not reduce local willingness to pay for schools, but the immigration of individuals already endowed with at least a high school education does negatively influence expenditures. This pattern implies that locally produced and imported human capital are substitutes, and if a great deal of human capital moves into an area, it may be unnecessary to pay to produce it locally. Thus, while her analysis of community spending patterns suggests significant nonprivate benefits to education, it also suggests that communities expect those benefits to arise from adult migrants rather than from locally educated children.  by empirical or theoretical evidence, all three rationales give the government a subordinate role in primary and secondary education. The marketfailure rationale implies that the government should efficiently ensure families have access to credit and that they pay no more for education loans than they would for any other type of investment loan. However, this rationale does not imply education should be subsidized or the government should determine the amount of education students receive. The externalities rationale implies education should be subsidized, but it also implies the subsidy should be proportional to the externality. Because the private benefits from education greatly exceed the nonprivate benefits,15 families should pay the lion’s share of educational expenses. (For a discussion of the U.S. family’s role in education finance, see the box entitled “How Families Pay for Elementary and Secondary Education.”) Finally, the altruism rationale implies that society wishes to transfer resources to the young, but it does not imply that society cares more than parents about the welfare of their children or that society’s transfers to their children should be large relative to the parents’ transfers. One important consequence of this primacy for parents is that parents retain control over the level of educational spending. Onesize-fits-all financing, wherein society tries to equalize expenditures or sets a very high floor on spending per pupil, violates this principle. Issuing an overly generous school voucher—or any type of voucher that parents are not allowed to supplement—would also violate this principle. The second guiding principle follows directly from the notion that government has a significant financial interest in primary and secondary education. To the extent that the government has money on the table, it also has a legitimate interest in monitoring the outcomes of the educational process. Thus, if the government subsidizes education because education generates positive externalities, it should ensure schools behave in a way that produces such externalities. For example, if the externalities arise from the scientific literacy of the population, the government should confirm that schools promote scientific literacy. Similarly, if the externalities that justify government subsidies arise from socialization and the development of common values, the government should make eligibility for public funds contingent on producing such outcomes. Even if the government is only responding to market failure by acting as an educational lender, it is obliged  THE IMPLICATIONS Considered individually, each piece of the empirical evidence provides only modest support for the government’s role in primary and secondary education. However, taken together, the sheer volume of evidence is rather persuasive. Furthermore, any gaps in the empirical evidence may indicate a complex measurement problem—or a lack of research on the issue— rather than the absence of significant social benefits from education. Finally, there is little doubt in economic circles that capital market imperfections would lead to some degree of underinvestment in education in the absence of government intervention. For the sake of argument (if nothing else), assume a significant public interest in education. What guidance do these underlying rationales offer for government’s role in primary and secondary education? The first guiding principle is that families should remain the primary educational decision makers—and the primary educational financiers. Unless taken to extremes that are unsupported  20  How Families Pay for Elementary and Secondary Education Although the true extent of their burden is unknown, families pay for the education provided by “free” public schools in a variety of ways. The value of the time students bring to the classroom represents an enormous share of our educational resources. At the high school level, between one-half and two-thirds of U.S. school resources come from the students themselves in terms of opportunity costs.1 Another direct source of revenue from the family to the school is the school taxes individuals pay on their residences. Whether they own or rent, residents usually foot the bill for property taxes, although landlords may bear some portion of the tax burden for rental property (Martinez-Vazquez and Sjoquist 1988, Roche 1986). In addition, research suggests that homeowners are willing to pay a premium to live in a neighborhood with good schools (Hayes and Taylor 1996, Black forthcoming). Any such premium represents a payment for public schooling, whether or not that payment is captured by the schools in the form of higher tax revenues. Finally, families with children pay for schooling by picking up much of the school tax burden that originates at the business level. Because capital must earn a comparable after-tax rate of return in all parts of the world, taxes on business capital are actually paid by the parents and the nonparents who work for the firm or buy its products. Furthermore, landlords seldom bear the full burden of taxes on business real estate. For example, Man (1995) finds that Phoenix property owners pay only 60 percent of the property taxes on commercial real estate while property users pay 40 percent. Similarly, McDonald (1993) finds that Chicago landlords pay only 55 percent of property taxes on commercial real estate, while the remainder is passed through to tenants in the form of higher rents. For the same reasons taxes on business capital are passed through to workers and customers, rent differentials resulting from property taxes also tend to be passed through to workers and customers.  to monitor the use of its funds. Just as a prudent private lender has an obligation to make sure that car loans are used to buy cars, the government has an obligation to ensure education loans are used to buy education. Monitoring educational outcomes does not imply controlling the production process, however. The final guiding principle is that government does not necessarily have a role in providing educational services or in regulating the manner by which private schools provide educational services. The market-failure rationale is silent on this issue, as is the altruism rationale. Some economists have argued that public provision of education generates externality benefits (such as socialization and the promotion of democracy) that the public finance of education alone cannot generate because public schools provide a “common educational experience that cannot be left to the vagaries of individual or family choice.”16 However, there is no empirical evidence this effect outweighs the possible inefficiencies associated with the public provision of education17 or that private schools are less cost-effective than public schools at generating such effects. Furthermore, as West (1991) points out, there is little commonality of practice among public schools in the United States. If providing a common educational experience were the rationale for public provision of education, we would expect more homogeneity in the public school system. Absent significant externalities that are uniquely generated by a public school system, no economic rationale requires the public provision of education.  1  know the full extent of their responsibility for education finance because the tax code assigns that responsibility to an array of parties, and pundits see no dissonance between pursuing expanded subsidies for education and opposing government plans to gather and disseminate information about educational outcomes. Education policy in the United States is apparently about something other than economics.  CONCLUSIONS Economic theory provides three broad rationales that can warrant a role for government in primary and secondary education, and a substantial body of research provides empirical support for these rationales. Some degree of government participation in the education market is clearly appropriate from an economic perspective. It is hard to justify the pervasive nature of government participation in the current system, however. On the basis of these rationales, government’s role in primary and secondary education should be subordinate to the role of families and primarily focused on assisting in education finance and ensuring that schools produce desirable social outcomes. Instead, we have a long history of public provision of education wherein the vast majority of school-age children attend public schools, parents cannot  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  In 1996, average annual earnings were $15,478 for 18- to 24-year-old males with less than a high school diploma who worked full time (U.S. Bureau of the Census 1997). Therefore, assuming a nine-month school year, the opportunity cost of a year of school would be $11,609. Alternatively, the minimum wage in 1996 was $4.75. Again assuming a nine-month school year and full-time employment, the opportunity cost of a year of school would be $7,125. Average expenditures on public elementary and secondary schooling for the 1996 – 97 school year were $5,957 per pupil (U.S. Department of Education 1998). Comparable calculations cannot be made at the grade-school level because child labor laws make it impossible to observe potential wages for younger children and because very young children are not only unemployable but also require costly supervision.  NOTES  1  2  3  21  My thanks to Steve Brown, Jason Saving, and Alan Viard for helpful comments and discussions. Of course, all remaining errors are my own. The data on educational expenditures are from National Center for Education Statistics (1997, 1998). Even if lenders could legally enforce long-term labor contracts, there are substantial principal – agent problems associated with forcing people to use their human capital. “Some altruistic parents do not leave bequests because they get less marginal utility from consumption by their adult children than from their own con-  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  sumption when elderly. They would like to raise their own consumption at the expense of their children’s, but they cannot do this if unable to leave debts to children.…Selfish and weakly altruistic parents would like to impose a large debt burden on their children.…  the survey of $825 per pupil. Twenty-seven percent of survey respondents chose the minimum level of expenditure. 13  Parents who cannot leave debt can substitute their own consumption for their children’s by investing less in the children’s human capital and instead saving more for old age. Therefore, in families without bequests, the equilibrium marginal rate of return on investments in children must exceed the rate on assets saved for old age; otherwise, parents would reallocate some resources from children to savings. These parents underinvest in their children” (Becker and Murphy 1988, 5 – 6). 4  5  6  7  8  9  10  11  12  14  15  Because college students are overwhelmingly adults, this argument does not apply to postsecondary education. Alternatively, de Bartolome (1988) argues that “inkind transfers may be a necessary instrument of redistribution” when household wealth is unobservable: “A family ‘reveals’ its wealth by its choice of house size and education level: redistribution may be effected by linking tax policy to housing and educational choice. Cash transfers alone cannot be used to effect redistribution because all families appear alike.”  16 17  The demographic variables are the percentage of the school-age population in public schools, the percentage of public school students in high school, and the percentage of public school students who are nonwhite. Hadley does not explain why he excludes the variables on state and federal aid and student demographics. While the aid variables are insignificant in Weisbrod’s original estimation, the nonracial demographics are individually significant at the 5 percent or 10 percent level. (Weisbrod does not report a test of joint significance.) Even if one postulates that the benefits from education arise primarily from signaling productivity to potential employers rather than from the creation of human capital, the private benefits clearly outweigh the nonprivate benefits of such signaling. Levin 1991, 139. For a discussion of such inefficiencies, see Grosskopf, Hayes, Taylor, and Weber (1997).  REFERENCES Barro, Robert J. (1992), “Human Capital and Economic Growth,” unpublished manuscript (Harvard University).  On the other hand, Maré (1995) demonstrates that Rauch’s results can be sensitive to the inclusion or exclusion of metropolitan areas, the choice of discount rate, and the specification of metropolitan area characteristics. His analysis also suggests that educational externalities (if any) arise from postsecondary education rather than from primary or secondary education.  Bartik, Timothy J. (1989), “Small Business Start-Ups in the United States: Estimates of the Effects of Characteristics of States,” Southern Economic Journal 55 (April): 1004–18. Becker, Gary S., and Kevin M. Murphy (1988), “The Family and the State,” Journal of Law and Economics 31 (April): 1–18.  In this context, the social return includes the private return. Other possible explanations include imperfections in the market for physical capital and variations in political risk.  Behrman, Jere R., and Nancy Birdsall (1983), “The Quality of Schooling: Quantity Alone Is Misleading,” American Economic Review 73 (December): 928 – 46.  Levine and Renelt find that although the initial secondary-school enrollment rate enters their basic model of growth in real, per-capita GDP with a significantly positive and robust coefficient, it is insignificant in models with a richer set of explanatory variables (Levine and Renelt 1992, 950). For example, Behrman and Birdsall (1983) find that in Brazil quality differences are as important as attainment differences for understanding variations in earnings and that analyses of attainment alone can be misleading. Donohue and Siegelman (1998) find evidence that preschool enrichment programs targeted to at-risk students can cost-effectively reduce crime. Because “the available evidence does not demonstrate any delinquencyreduction effect for Head Start” (a general enrichment program for preschoolers), their results are unlikely to extend to general primary and secondary education.  Behrman, Jere R., and Mark R. Rosenzweig (1994), “Caveat Emptor: Cross-Country Data on Education and the Labor Force,” Journal of Development Economics 44 (June): 147– 71. Benhabib, Jess, and Boyan Jovanovic (1991), “Externalities and Growth Accounting,” American Economic Review 81 (March): 82 –113. Benhabib, Jess, and Mark M. Spiegel (1994), “The Role of Human Capital in Economic Development: Evidence from Aggregate Cross-Country Data,” Journal of Monetary Economics 34 (October): 143 – 73. Black, Sandra (forthcoming), “Do Better Schools Matter? Parental Valuation of Elementary Education,” Quarterly Journal of Economics.  Wyckoff does not indicate whether the $1,222 is significantly greater than the lower bound expenditure on  22  Borsch-Supan, A. (1990), “Education and its DoubleEdged Impact on Mobility,” Economics of Education Review 9 (1): 39 – 53.  Haveman, Robert H., and Barbara L. Wolfe (1984), “Schooling and Economic Well-Being: The Role of Nonmarket Effects,” Journal of Human Resources 19 (Summer): 377– 407.  Carlino, Gerald A. (1995), “Do Education and Training Lead to Faster Growth in Cities?” Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review, January– February, 15 – 22.  Hayes, Kathy J., and Lori L. Taylor (1996), “Neighborhood School Characteristics: What Signals Quality to Homebuyers?” Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Economic Review, Fourth Quarter, 2 – 9.  Carlton, Dennis W. (1983), “The Location and Employment Choices of New Firms: An Econometric Model with Discrete and Continuous Endogenous Variables,” Review of Economics and Statistics 65 (August): 440 – 49.  Hirsch, Werner Z., and Morton J. Marcus (1969), “Intercommunity Spillovers and the Provision of Public Education,” Kyklos 22 (4): 641– 60.  de Bartolome, Charles A. (1988), “Public Education as an Instrument of Redistribution,” C. V. Starr Center for Applied Economics Economic Research Report no. 88-38 (New York, November).  Holland, David W. (1974), “The Impact of Benefit Spillovers upon Economic Efficiency in Public School Finance,” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 56 (May): 300 – 05.  Donohue, John J., and Peter Siegelman (1998), “Allocating Resources Among Prisons and Social Programs in the Battle Against Crime,” Journal of Legal Studies 27 (January): 1– 43.  Holtmann, A. G. (1971), “Migration to the Suburbs, Human Capital and City Income Tax Losses: A Case Study,” in Investment in Human Capital, ed. B. F. Kiker (Columbia, S.C.: University of South Carolina Press), 590 – 600.  Engelbrecht, Hans-Jürgen (1997), “International R&D Spillovers, Human Capital and Productivity in OECD Economies: An Empirical Investigation,” European Economic Review 41 (August): 1479 – 88.  Hoxby, Caroline Minter (1996), “Are Efficiency and Equity in School Finance Substitutes or Complements?” Journal of Economic Perspectives 10 (Fall): 51–72.  Fox, William F., and Matthew N. Murray (1990), “Local Public Policies and Interregional Business Development,” Southern Economic Journal 57 (October): 413 – 27. Friedman, Milton, and Rose Friedman (1990), Free to Choose: A Personal Statement (San Diego: Harcourt Brace).  Jorgenson, Dale W. (1998), “Investment and Growth” (Paper presented at the Eighth International Conference, “Monetary Policy in a World of Knowledge-based Growth, Quality Change and Uncertain Measurement,” Institute for Monetary and Economic Studies, Bank of Japan, Tokyo, June 18 –19).  Greene, Kenneth V. (1977), “Spillovers, Migration and Public School Expenditures: The Repetition of an Experiment,” Public Choice 29 (Spring): 85 – 93.  Lankford, R. Hamilton (1985), “Preferences of Citizens for Public Expenditures on Elementary and Secondary Education,” Journal of Econometrics 27 (January): 1– 20.  Grosskopf, Shawna, Kathy J. Hayes, Lori L. Taylor, and William L. Weber (1997), “Budget-Constrained Frontier Measures of Fiscal Equality and Efficiency in Schooling,” Review of Economics and Statistics 79 (February): 116 – 24.  Levin, Henry M. (1991), “The Economics of Educational Choice,” Economics of Education Review 10 (2): 137– 58. Levine, Ross, and David Renelt (1992), “A Sensitivity Analysis of Cross-Country Regressions,” American Economic Review 82 (September ): 942 – 63.  Grossman, Michael, and Robert Kaestner (1997), “Effects of Education on Health,” in The Social Benefits of Education, ed. Jere R. Behrman and Nevzer Stacey (Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press), 69 –124.  Lucas, Robert E., Jr. (1988), “On the Mechanics of Economic Development,” Journal of Monetary Economics 22 (July): 3 – 42.  Gundlach, Erich (1994), “Accounting for the Stock of Human Capital: Selected Evidence and Potential Implications,” Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 130 (2): 350 – 74.  ——— (1990), “Why Doesn’t Capital Flow from Rich to Poor Countries?” American Economic Review 80 (May): 92 – 96.  Hadley, Garland R. (1985), “Interstate Migration, Income and Public School Expenditures: An Update of an Experiment,” Public Choice 46 (2): 207–14.  Man, Joyce Y. (1995), “The Incidence of Differential Commercial Property Taxes: Empirical Evidence,” National Tax Journal 48 (December): 479 – 96.  FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF DALLAS  23  ECONOMIC REVIEW FIRST QUARTER 1999  Maré, David C. (1995), “Living with Graduates: Human Capital Interactions in Metropolitan Areas,” unpublished manuscript (Harvard University).  Rubinfeld, Daniel L., and Perry Shapiro (1989), “Microestimation of the Demand for Schooling,” Regional Science and Urban Economics 19 (August): 381– 98.  Martinez-Vazquez, Jorge, and David L. Sjoquist (1988), “Property Tax Financing, Renting and the Level of Local Expenditures,” Southern Economic Journal 55 (October): 424 – 31.  Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (1994), “Cross-Sectional Regressions and the Empirics of Economic Growth,” European Economic Review 38 (April): 739 – 47. Schultz, T. P. (1982), “Notes of the Estimation of Migrations Decision Functions,” in Migration and the Labor Market in Developing Countries, ed. R. H. Sabot (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press), 91–126.  Maynard, Rebecca A., and Daniel J. McGrath (1997), “Family Structure, Fertility and Child Welfare,” in The Social Benefits of Education, ed. Jere R. Behrman and Nevzer Stacey (Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press),125 –74.  Taylor, Lori L. (1992), “Student Emigration and the Willingness to Pay for Public Schools: A Test of the Publicness of Public High Schools in the U.S.,” Public Finance/Finances Publiques 47 (1): 131– 52.  McDonald, John F. (1993), “Incidence of the Property Tax on Commercial Real Estate: The Case of Downtown Chicago,” National Tax Journal 46 (June): 109 – 20. McMahon, W. W. (1987), “Externalities in Education,” in Economics of Education Research and Studies, ed. George Psacharopoulos (Oxford: Pergamon Press), 133 – 37.  U.S. Bureau of the Census (1997), Money Income in the United States: 1996, Current Population Reports, Series P60-1970 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office).  Myers, R. G. (1972), Education and Emigration: Study Abroad and the Migration of Human Resources (New York: David McKay Company).  U.S. Department of Education (1998), Public Elementary and Secondary Education Statistics: School Year 1997– 98 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office).  National Center for Education Statistics (1996), Digest of Education Statistics 1996 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office).  Usher, Dan (1997), “Education as a Deterrent to Crime,” Canadian Journal of Economics 30 (May): 367– 84.  ——— (1997, 1998), The Condition of Education (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office).  Wasylenko, M., and T. McGuire (1985), “Jobs and Taxes: The Effect of Business Climate on States’ Unemployment Growth Rates,” National Tax Journal 38 (December): 497– 511.  Poterba, James M. (1996), “Government Intervention in the Markets for Education and Health Care: How and Why?” in Individual and Social Responsibility: Child Care, Education, Medical Care and Long-Term Care, ed. Victor R. Fuchs (Chicago: Chicago University Press), 277– 304.  Weisbrod, Burton A. (1962), “Education and Investment in Human Capital,” Journal of Political Economy 70 (Supplement, pt. 2): 106 – 23. ——— (1964), “External Benefits of Public Education: An Economic Analysis,” Princeton University Economics Department, Industrial Relations Section Research Report no. 105 (Princeton, N.J.).  Psacharopoulos, George (1996), “Economics of Education: A Research Agenda,” Economics of Education Review 15 (October): 339 – 44. Rauch, James E. (1993), “Productivity Gains from Geographic Concentration of Human Capital: Evidence from the Cities,” Journal of Urban Economics 34 (November): 380 – 400.  West, Edwin G. (1991), “Public Schools and Excess Burdens,” Economics of Education Review 10 (2): 159 – 69. Witte, Ann Dryden (1997), “Crime” in The Social Benefits of Education, ed. Jere R. Behrman and Nevzer Stacey (Ann Arbor, Mich.: University of Michigan Press).  Roche, Ellen (1986), “Property Taxation in Local Finance: Differences in the Tax Price Between Renters and Owner Occupants,” (Ph.D. dissertation, University of Maryland, College Park).  Wyckoff, James H. (1984), “The Nonexcludable Publicness of Primary and Secondary Public Education,” Journal of Public Economics 24 (August): 331– 51.  Rubinfeld, Daniel L. (1977), “Voting in a Local School Election: A Micro Analysis,” Review of Economics and Statistics 59 (February): 30 – 42.  24