View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ON THE DETERMINANTS AND RESILIENCE OF BOND FLOWS
TO LDCs, 1990 - 1995
EVIDENCE FROM ARGENTINA, BRAZIL AND MEXICO

Angelos A. Antzoulatos

Federal Reserve Bank of New York
Research Paper No. 9703

February 1997

This paper is being circulated for purposes of discussion and comment only.
The contents should be regarded as preliminary and not for citation or quotation without
permission of the author. The views expressed are those of the author and do not necessarily
reflect those of the Federal Reserve Bank ofNew York of the Federal Reserve System.
Single copies are available on request to:
Public Information Department
Federal Reserve Bank of New York
New York, NY 10045

ON THE DETERMINANTS AND RESILIENCE OF BOND FLOWS TO LDCs, 1990. 1995
Evidence from Argentina, Brazil and Mexico

ANGELOS A. ANTZOULATOS
International Research Department

ABSTRACT.
Bond flows to Less Developed Countries (LDCs) proved more resilient than expected to the
rising U.S. interest rates during 1994, raising hopes that the current episode of private capital
flows to LDCs may not end in a widespread crisis as its predecessors in the 1920s and 1970s did.
This paper attributes the surprising resilience of the flows to the fact that global bond issuance
was a significant determinant of them, independently of U.S. (and world) interest rates. Briefly,
global issuance, which recovered quickly from the shock of the first interest-rate rise in February
1994, helped oftest the adverse impact of the rising interest rates. The paper also documents
the existence of some speculative component in the flows and of regional contagion effects,
both of which warn of a possible crisis in the future. Compared with previous studies, the paper
identifies an additional determinant of bond flows, i.e., global issuance, documents a remarkable
stability of the estimated coefficients during the period of rising interest rates and in the aftermath
of the "Peso crisis", and makes a better assessment of the impact of global and country-specific
determinants for each sample country.

J.E.L. Classification Numbers: F21, F32, F34

I thank, without implicating, Nilmini Gunaratne and Keith Crockett for able and diligent research assistance; Kate Kisselev for extensive discussions on the subject at an early stage of the project; Frank
Packer for assistance with the collection and interpretation of credit ratings; Linda Goldberg, Jean Helwege, Dorothy Sobol, Young Ho Eom, Matthew Higgins, John Kaskarelis, Tom Klitgaard, Gabriel Perez,
Eric van Wincoop, Kei-Mu Yi, and seminar participants at Baruch College (City University of New York)
and the Federal Reserve Bank of New York for numerous comments and suggestions.
The views expressed here are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of the
Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System.

1

1 INTRODUCTION

The surge of private capital flows to Less Developed Countries (LDCs) in the early 1990s did not
occur in a vacuum. Like its predecessors in the 1920s and 1970s, it was triggered by developments in the borrowing LDCs, as well as economic conditions in the lending industrial countries.
In particular, the post-World War I boom in commodity prices in the 1920s encouraged direct
investment in the resource-rich LDCs, and international bond issues to finance related infrastructure projects. In addition, the reduction in the U.S. interest rates, which started in 1924,
intensified investors search for higher yields and led to the rise of U.S. bond investments abroad
(Eichengreen (1996]). The strong growth in the 1960s and early 1970s, trade liberalization and
the adoption of export-promoting policies, along with the low real interest rates in the industrial
countries and the flood of OPEC's petro-dollars recycled through money-center banks, encouraged the explosion of syndicated bank loans to LDCs in the late 1970s. Lastly, the adoption
of sound economic policies and market-oriented reforms, and the restructuring of the external
debt left over from the "debt crisis" of the previous decade, along with the recession and the low
interest rates in the industrial countries, helped stimulate bond and equity flows to Latin American
(L.A.) and East Asian LDCs in the early 1990s (Calvo et al. (1992], Chuhan et al. (1993], Ooley
et al. (1996], Fernandez-Arias (1996]).
The upshot of all three episodes is that developments in the industrial countries, and especially a rise in interest rates, could adversely affect capital flows to LDCs and precipitate an
external financing crisis. This grim possibility is amply illustrated by the traumatic experience from
the first two episodes. The rise in U.S. interest rates in 1928 increased the debt-servicing burden
of the borrowing LDCs and brought U.S. lending to a virtual stop (Eichengreen (1996]). With
their external financing difficulties exacerbated by the global depression of the 1930s, several of
these LDCs defaulted on their foreign bonds and, paying a heavy price, did not regain access to
the international financial markets for almost forty years (Fernandez-Ansola and Laursen (1995]).
In the late 1970s, the steep rise in real U.S. interest rates set in motion a similar sequence of
events which culminated in Mexico's suspension of debt-servicing in August 1982, the starting
point of the "debt crisis".
The possibility of a similar traumatic experience in the 1990s was stressed by the studies
mentioned above, which noted the parallels among the three episodes. These studies essentially
documented that the cyclically low world interest rates 1 at the beginning of the decade were
instrumental in motivating the flows and improving the creditworthiness of the borrowing LDCs.
Thus, as they implied, a rise in world interest rates, caused by the eventual upturn of economic
1 1n

these studies, as well as In the present one, world interest rates are proxied with U.S. Interest rates.

2

activity, could trigger a capital outflow and cause another external financing crisis even in LDCs
which had adopted sound economic policies.
Fortunately, and to the surprise of many informed observers, this has not happened so far,
the "Peso crisis" of December 1994 not withstanding. 2 Following the Fed's first tightening in
February 1994, bond flows to L.A. fell to $2.1 billion in the second quarter of the year, down from
$5.9 billion in the first and $8.8 billion in the last quarter of 1993 (Figure 1). They recovered,
however, to $2.4 billion in the third quarter and further to $5.9 billion in the fourth, despite the
continuing increases in the U.S. interest rates throughout 1994. As it seems, bond flows to L.A.
during the entire period since the beginning of the surge have followed the ups and downs of
global bond issuance more closely than the changes in U.S. interest rates. This observation is
further supported by the plots of global issuance and bond flows to Argentina, Brazil and Mexico,
the biggest L.A. borrowers, along with the U.S. Treasury-bill rate, for the period January 1990 to
December 1995 (Figure 2).
This visual evidence suggests that global issuance may have been a significant determinant of
bond flows to the three L.A. countries, independently from and perhaps more important than world
interest rates, thus explaining the surprising resilience of the flows. Taking also into account that
bonds constitute by far the most important borrowing instrument for L.A. countries in the 1990s
(see Table A-1 for related figures), the visual evidence further suggests that the current episode
of private capital flows to LDCs may represent a break with the boom-bust cycles of the past.
In short, as long as L.A. countries can issue international bonds, they may be able to weather
temporary external financing difficulties even when other channels of flows which they have no
control over dry-up. Such a channel is equity flows. As a reminder, the dramatic decrease of
2

The element of surprise is still echoed, almost three years after the Fed's first tightening in February 1994, in

authoritative analyses of recent developments in the international financial markets. For example, referring to capital
flows to Latin America, the Financial Times wrote on September 13, 1996: "There were no indications of any exit of
short-term capital, although an eventual increase of US interest rates could lead to an outflow in the second half of
this year. This unexpected increase in capital flows .... ". Also, in the September 1996 Issue of the IMF's International
Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects, and Key Policy Issues (p. 7) It Is stated that "A year ago few observers

expected that by the end of 1995 capital flows would have surpassed their previous peak reached in 1993."
Last but not least, the following passage from the International Banking and Financial Market Developments (Bank
for International Settlements, August 1996, p. 23) not only captures the element of surprise, but also underlines
the significance of this paper's findings: "The global bond market reversal of early 1994, the Mexican crisis and the
turbulence seen in financial markets at the beginning of 1996 have had no more than a temporary and localized
influence on issuance. Whereas in recent years there has been

a close inverse correlation between the level of

interest rates in major industrialized countries and the volume of new international bond issues by developing country
borrowers, the sharp increase in US interest rates and in their volatility in the first quarter of 1996 failed to have any
major impact on such issuance...... This suggests that broader forces have been at play recently." (emphasis
added)

3

syndicated loans to L.A. countries in the aftermath of Mexico's suspension of debt-servicing in
August 1982 turned what could have been a manageable recession into a major development
crisis (Diaz-Alejandro [1984]).
It appears, therefore, that a re-examination of the determinants of bond flows to L.A. countries3

is a worthwhile endeavor. In further support of this argument, it is necessary to analyze the
evidence over a complete interest-rate cycle, not just over a period of falling interest rates and
rising flows as most of the existing studies have done. To be fair though, these studies were
conducted before the first rise in U.S. interest rates in February 1994. From a policy point of view,
the value of such an endeavor is highlighted by the potentially disastrous effects of a sudden
capital-flow reversal and the associated need for early warning signs.
In undertaking this endeavor, the present paper tries to avoid the data-related weaknesses of
its precursors. In particular, the paper uses well-defined monthly data on international bond flows
for a period, January 1990 to December 1995, which spans a complete cycle in U.S. interest
rates. This period is long enough for a country-by-country examination of the empirical evidence,
and thus allows a better assessment of the impact of country-specific developments and global
economic conditions on each borrowing LDC. (As discussed below, most existing studies pool the
data for the sample countries to get enough degrees of freedom for the econometric analysis.)
Further, the paper uses Tobit estimation to account for the fact that for several months there
were no bond flows.
The paper is organized as follows. To put the results into perspective and also highlight their
significance, Section 2 begins with a brief literature review. It then proceeds with the presentation
of a general reduced-form model which encompasses the economic variables usually associated
with bond flows. Section 3 analyzes the empirical evidence for Argentina, Brazil and Mexico,
the three L.A. countries for which there are enough non-zero observations for a meaningful
estimation. Section 4 summarizes the evidence and discusses briefly its implications, while an
appendix describes the data.

'The focus on bond flows reflects the fact that bonds are the primary borrowing instrument for L.A. countries in
the current episode, and the empirical finding that portfolio flows -bond and equity- behave differently from direct
investment and debt flows (Chuhan et al. [1996]).

4

2 THE DETERMINANTS OF BOND FLOWS
2.1

Brief Literature Review

As noted in the introduction, the surge of private capital flows to LDCs in the 1990s was triggered
by both country-specific developments and economic conditions in the industrial countries, "pull"
and "push" factors in the descriptive terminology of Fernandez-Arias (1996).
For several reasons, however, the contribution of country-specific developments has been extremely difficult to measure consistently. As several authors have noted, factors like sound fiscal
and monetary policies, debt-servicing restructuring under the Brady Plan, and market-oriented
reforms cannot be readily quantified. Introducing another complication, some countries started
receiving flows long before they introduced economic reforms or completed a Brady Plan (see
Dooley et al. [1996) for an extensive discussion). Also, changes in government policies make
it unlikely that a stable relationship might exist between capital flows and domestic quantifiable .
factors. Such factors are the secondary-market price of a country's debt, the country's credit
rating, the return on the domestic stock market, the black market exchange rate premium (all of
which are used by Chuhan at al. [19931), and domestic interest rates. For example, reducing the
reserve requirements on foreign currency deposits can -everything else equal- induce higher
flows. Further, changes in the degree of sterilization, which most likely have occurred as suggested by the reserve accumulation in the sample countries documented in Figure 3 below, would
further undermine the stability of the relationship between bond flows and domestic quantifiable
factors.
As far as it concerns conditions in the industrial countries, global factors in the terminology of
many studies, attention has primarily focused on interest rates and, to a lesser extent, economic
activity, both of which are usually proxied with some appropriate U.S. variables. Specifically,
Dooley et al. (1996), using annual data from 1986 to 1992 for a panel of twenty LDCs, find
that the ten-year U.S. bond yield is an important determinant of the secondary-market price of
sovereign debt. Interpreting a rising price as an improvement in a country's creditworthiness, they
conclude that the. decline .in.the U.S ..inter.est rates was the.domir:iant factor behind the renewed
access of highly-indebted LDCs to international financial markets in the 1990s. Fernandez-Arias
(1996) reaches the same conclusion using quarterly data for a panel of thirteen middle-income
LDCs, from the first quarter of 1989 to the first quarter of 1993. After adjusting for the favorable
impact of falling international interest rates on the debtor-countries' creditworthiness, he finds that
changes in the U.S. ten-year bond rate can account for 86 percent of the post-1989 increase in
portfolio flows to the sample countries.
5

Further, Calvo et al. (1993) find that global factors account for between thirty and sixty
percent of the variance of reserves in ten L.A. countries over the period 1988 to 1992. Lacking
appropriate data, they use monthly movements in reserves as a proxy for movements in total
flows. Also, to capture the effect of global factors, they use the first two principal components
of various U.S. interest rates, deviations from the trend of the U.S. real disposable income, and
indices on U.S. stock and .real estate markets. Finally, Chuhan et al. (1993) find that global·,,
factors explain about half the bond and equity flows from the U.S. to a panel of six L.A. countries
for the period January 1988 to September 1992. Their proxies for the global factors include the
deviation of the U.S. industrial production index from a time trend, to account for the cyclical
variation in economic activity, and five U.S. interest rates (three short rates, one medium and
one long-term) and their first principal component.

2.2

Modeling Bond Flows

The present study differs from the above in several respects. First, the extended sample period,·
January 1990 to December 1995, covers a complete cycle in the U.S. and international interest
rates, not just a period of falling rates and rising flows. Thus, it provides a better framework
to analyze the determinants and resilience of bond flows. The sample period also includes the
turbulent for Mexico years of 1994 and 1995, during which the attitude of international investors
towards L.A. must have changed. As a reminder, the Chiapas revolution in January 1994, the assassination of the presidential candidate Colosio in March, the presidential elections in August,
and another political assassination in September culminated in the "Peso crisis" in December
1994, which required an extraordinary international rescue operation to avert another "debt crisis" (sparked -like the previous one- by Mexico, the country which led the way back to the
international financial markets in the 1990s for the highly-indebted LDCs).
Second, the relatively large number of observations allows a country-by-country analysis
and, thus, a better assessment of individual-country experience. It also facilitates testing for •
parameter stability and structural breaks in the wake of major policy changes and political events
(a chronology of such changes and events is presented in Table A-2, in the appendix). Third,
the bond-flows data, also described in the appendix, are well-defined. Notably, they exclude
flows related to debt-restructuring. Thus, one does not have to use dummies for the months
Brady bonds were issued, as Chuhan et al. (1993) had to do. Moreover, the data cover total
bond flows, not only from the U.S .. Fourth, noting that for several months the flows were zero,
the paper uses Tobit estimation. Fifth, to avoid difficulties in interpreting the results, it does not
implement complex data transformations, such as, constructing principal components.

6

Most importantly though, the paper tries to account for both the demand and supply conditions.
In contrast, the existing literature reports results which stress primarily the role of the latter.
The extensive list of variables considered is presented in Table 1. These variables are divided into the descriptively named groups Market Access, Supply of Funds, Demand for FundsNeed, Demand for Funds-Cost, Contagion Effects, Creditworthiness, International Liquidity, Pol-.
icy Changes and Major Events, and Quality of Economic Management. The first two groups

have not been considered in previous studies, despite their economic and statistical significance
which is documented in this paper, For each variable, Table 1 reports a brief description, the
symbol used, the expected sign, and related comments. For brevity, more detailed comments
are discussed in the text as need arises.
The paper follows a "general-to-specific" modeling approach, which proceeds in three steps.
Initially, the very general reduced-form Tobit model described by equations (1) through (3) is
estimated for each country.

In equation (1 ), every right-hand-side term corresponds to one

group in Table 1.
n

BOND;

=

p

q

a+ L,/3iBONDt-i+ L,'YiWBONDt-i+ L,6iNEEDt-i
i=l
m

i=O

i=l

+ L, <iCOST,-i + (LAB ON Dt-1 + 0CREDt + >.RES,-k

(k :2'. 2)

i=l

+ L, µjDU Mt,j + '1

QU ALITYt-k(k :2: 1) + u,

(1)

j

BONDt= { O
BONDt

if BONDt :5 0
if BONDt > 0

(2)

(3)

NEED, can be any of the CAt, %ti.Rt or %ti.Rf"m, while COSTt can be any of the it, r,,

;; or Etfi.ii+1 (twelve permutations). For the first four groups of potential explanatory variables,
more than one lag is used in order to capture their delayed effects. In most cases, however, two
lags were enough.
Next, insignificant variables are identified with a series of Wald tests for joint significance
and dropped, while competing models are evaluated in terms of the goodness-of-fit (measured
by the log-likelihood). In fact, the only competing models involved the U.S. Treasury Bill rate
and the ten-year Government Bond yield for Argentina and Brazil. The two rates are strongly
correlated and produced similar results. For brevity though, the paper reports the results with the

7

higher values for the log-likelihood. In addition, the parsimonious model thus arrived is tested
for normality in the residuals using a moments-based test whose statistic is distributed as x 2 (2).
Finally, to evaluate the impact of the rising U.S. interest rates and of Mexico's difficulties during
1994, the first two steps are performed for both the whole sample and the sub-sample ending in
December 1993. The corresponding parsimonious models are then estimated sequentially with,
samples ending in each of the months between December 1993 and December 1995.
Two aspects of the modeling approach are of particular interest. First, equation (1) encompasses global bond issuance and various interest rates. Thus, it is left to the data to determine
whether the observation that the former is more significant than the latter is true. In addition, the
sequential estimation can help determine whether the direction of influence of variables whose
sign is not certain a priori has changed during the sample period. For example, as discussed in
Table 1, lagged bond flows, BONDt-k (k 2': 1), may have a positive or negative sign. It is also
possible that BON Dt-k (k 2': 1) changes sign over time. However, a relative stable coefficient
over time would be strong evidence against that. The sequential estimation can also detect the
impact of policy changes which are not captured by the dummy variables.
At this point, it should be noted that the correlation between global issuance and bond flows to
individual countries discussed in the introduction could, under certain conditions, be puzzling. To
begin with, changes in global issuance may reflect changes in the supply of funds the borrowing
countries face. (This is a reasonable assumption as L.A. countries account for a small fraction
of total bond issuance. See Table A-1 in the appendix for detailed figures). Consequently, global
issuance should be positively correlated with flows to individual countries, resulting in positive
"lk (k

2': O) coefficients. In the case the borrowing countries face a binding external financing

constraint, they would borrow as much as they could regardless of the cost of funds. But when
the constraint is not binding, factors like the cost of funds and the need to borrow should also
affect bond flows. If not, it would appear that, contrary to any notion of rationality, the borrowing
countries receive some fraction of global bond flows irrespective of their needs and policies,
or the prevailing conditions in the creditor countries. It would also imply that, contrary to past
experience and the findings of earlier studies, international interest rates are not even a factor
determining bond flows.
For the L.A. sample countries, the rising foreign exchange reserves (Figure 3) suggest that
the external financing constraint was not binding. Hence, other factors besides global issuance
should affect their bond flows. The case of Mexico is telling. Despite the substantial and widening
current account deficits, reserves continued accumulating until March 1994, an indication that
total flows were exceeding the country's external financing needs. Mexico's reserves started

8

falling only after the assassination of presidential candidate Celesio undermined foreign investors'
confidence in the country's political stability, which was already shaken by the Chiapas revolution
in January 1994. At the other extreme, Brazil started accumulating reserves in 1992 at a faster
pace than its modest current account surpluses would suggest. Further, countries like Chile and
Colombia had to resort to extensive controls to stem excessive capital inflows and avoid the
-policy dilemmas such inflows create (see Calvo et al. [1993] for a detailed discussion -of these
dilemmas).

3 EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
Table 2 summarizes the empirical evidence. Starting from the left, the first column exhibits
the explanatory variables, while each additional column reports one model. In addition to the
estimated coefficients and their t-statistics (in parentheses), Table 2 reports the standard error of
the residuals, u, the log-likelihood, Log L, and the x 2 (2) statistic for the moments-based test for
normality of the residuals. The discussion begins with Mexico, which presents the most puzzling
evidence, and continues with Argentina and Brazil. For easy reference, a number is provided for
each model, while the best model for each country and sample period is indicated by an equation
number in bold face.

3.1

Mexico

Table A-2 indicates that the likely months for a structural break in the Mexican model are January,
March, September and December (when the "Peso crisis" erupted) of 1994, as well as the
first months of 1995, when the international rescue operation was launched. Several dummies
were tried to capture these events, such as, Du M Chiapas
DU Mcolosio

=

1 from April to September, DU MMassieu

=

=

1 from January to March 1994,

1 from October to December, and

Du M Peso from January 1995 onwards. Since all were insignificant, a new approach was taken;

during the sequential estimation, DUM 1994 and DUM1995 were set equal to one for all months
of the respective years, and their significance was evaluated at each iteration. Surprisingly,
the best results were obtained for a dummy set to one from January to May 1995. Yet, in a
remarkable demonstration of the robustness of the estimated models, the coefficients for the
main explanatory variables are the same with or without this dummy (equations [4] and [5]).
But the surprising results do not end with the lack of evidence of a structural break during the
tumultuous 1994. As the first equation in Table 2 indicates, lagged bond flows, BON Dt-1, and

9

contemporaneous global bond issuance,

w BON Dt,

are the only determinants of the Mexico's

flows for the period January 1990 to December 1993. Neither any measure of the need for
or the cost of funds, nor any measure of creditworthiness, international liquidity or quality of
economic management was significant. Also, the hypothesis of normality in the residuals cannot
be rejected, as the x 2 (2) statistic is not significant at any conventional level.
To illustrate the extensive effort to estimate a model in which other variables are significant,
two more equations are shown. In equation (2), reserves lagged three periods, RESt-J, and
the cumulative real exchange rate appreciation lagged once, %t:l.Rf::'f, are significant at the 10
percent level, while the coefficients and significance of BON Dt-i and

w BOND, decline slightly.

Yet, the Wald test for the hypothesis that the coefficients of the two additional variables are both
equal to zero is only x 2 (2)

= 3.16, which is significant at the 20 percent level.

lagged yield of the U.S. ten-year bond,

u SBON D,_ 1 ,

In equation (3), the

is significantly negative when

w BON Dt

is not included. However, the log-likelihood, which is substantially lower than that in equation (1 ),
and the x 2 (2) statistic for normality in the residuals, which is significant at the 5 percent level,
indicate that equation (3) is not the best model. This conclusion is further supported by the fact
that u SBON D,_ 1 becomes insignificant when w BON Dt is included in equation (3). The same
applies to u SBON Dt, the contemporaneous yield on ten-year U.S. government bonds. In short,
global issuance renders the cost of funds insignificant, instead of the other way around.
Overall, the evidence presented so far confirms the observation that global bond issuance
was a significant determinant of bond flows to Mexico for the period January 1990 to December
1993. It also suggests that the flows were primarily supply-driven. This, in conjunction with
the fact that Mexico was borrowing more that it needed, provides some justification for Dooley's
assessment, although Dooley presents no hard evidence, that the current surge "may have little
to do with the economic fundamentals we usually associate with private capital flows." (Dooley,
1995, p.6). Instead, as he concludes, the flows may reflect foreign investors' belief that they
can earn high returns for a predictable period, by exploiting an implicit government guarantee on
private financial transactions.
In light of the above, and taking into account Mexico's difficulties after January 1994, it is
not surprising that .market. access, BON Dt-b and global issuance,

w BOND,,

remain the sole

determinants of bond flows for the whole sample period (equations [4] and [51). It seems that
Mexico, facing a sharp drop in foreign exchange reserves in the wake of these difficulties, was
borrowing as much as it could, and thus domestic and foreign interest rates were even less
important than before (for a detailed account of this experience, see Sachs at al. [19951).
What is astonishing though is the stability of the three estimated coefficients. Figure 4 ex-

10

hibits them for samples ending between December 1993 and December 1995 (solid line)± two
standard errors (dashed lines) for equation (1 ). As Figure 4 shows, these coefficients remain
well within two standard errors, i.e., within the five percent bounds, of their estimates in equation
(1 ). In fact, for most of the time they remain within one standard error only. For the best model,
equation (5), which includes the dummy, the coefficients are also within one standard error from
their estimates in equation (1) and are essentially the same as in equation (4). The dummy, as
expected, has a negative sign.
One specification whose results seem spurious should also be mentioned. In equation {6),
the inclusion of

u SBON Dt-1, which is significant at the 1 percent level and negative, renders

the Constant and BON Dt-I insignificant. But it only lowers the value and the t-statistic of
W BON Dt, which remains significant at the 1 percent level. Yet, the sequential estimation reveals

that u SBON Dt-1 becomes significant for the first time in November 1994, when Mexico was well
on a crisis path with dwindling reserves and a high

c A deficit.

It seems unlikely that international

interest rates became at that junction more important than before, when Mexico did not need to
borrow urgently, and so more important as to prevent borrowing which was necessary to avert
the fast-approaching crisis.

3.2 Argentina
For Argentina, the likely months for a break are March 1991, when the unified exchange rate
system was replaced with a peg to the U.S. dollar, January 1993, when checking accounts
denominated in U.S. dollars were allowed to be opened by residents and used for domestic and
international financial transactions, January 1995, following the Mexican crisis, as well as the
months of a change in the credit rating. It turns out that a dummy variable that takes the value
one from January 1995 to June 1995 gives the best results. To avoid an unnecessary proliferation
of dummies, Table 2 shows the essentially similar results obtained with Mexico's dummy (which
takes the value one from January to May 1995). In addition, a variable based on the S&P credit
rating seemingly captures sufficiently the improvements in Argentina's creditworthiness. This
variable takes the value zero before August 1993 and four thereafter (four corresponds to 88rating, with one corresponding to 8-, the lowest rating in the S&P scale, and zero corresponding
to no rating at all. See Cantor and Packer [1996] for details). Finally, it should be noted that
long delays in the publication of current account data preclude the use of CA as a measure
of external financing needs. For example, as of July 1996, the International Financial Statistics
reports

c A data up to the second quarter of 1994.

Table 2 reports five equations for Argentina, two with the sample ending in December 1993,
11

and three for the whole sample. In the first, equation (7), w BON Dt, u ST BI LLt-I and CREDITt
are significant at the 1 percent level and have the expected sign. But BON Dt-I and REGIONt-I
are not significant at any conventional level, while a Wald test indicates that the hypothesis that
their coefficients are both zero cannot be rejected at any conventional significance level. Equation
(8) reports the corresponding more parsimonious equation. There is, however, strong evidence
against the normality hypothesis for the residuals, as the x 2 (2) statistic is significant at the 1 .
percent level.
Both BON Dt-l and REGIONt-I are significant for the whole sample with (equation [9]) or.-.
without (equation [11]) the dummy for the first five months of 1995, while the normality hypothesis cannot be rejected. Further, as Figure 5 indicates, once the sample is extended beyond
December 1993, BON Dt-l is mostly significant at the 5 percent level and REGIONt-i at the
1O percent level. Dropping them form the model, as in equation (10), does not affect significantly
the coefficients of the remaining variables,

w BON Dt,

USTBILLt-1 and CREDITt. However,

it worsens the fit of the model relative to equation (9), while the x 2 (2) statistic for the normality
test becomes significant at the 1O percent level.
Overall, the Argentinean evidence is consistent with the economic fundamentals associated
with private capital flows and the presumed role of regional contagion effects. Briefly, both
the supply conditions, WBONDt, and the cost of funds, USTBILLt-I, affected bond flows.
Also, lagged regional flows and Mexico's difficulties are significant and have the expected sign.
Moreover, the downward trend in the coefficient of u ST BI LLt-1 indicates that the interest-rate
sensitivity of Argentina's flows was increasing over time. A possible explanation is that, as the
country was accumulating reserves and the external financing constraint was becoming less
relevant, cost-of-funds considerations were becoming more important. Lastly, the precipitous
decline of the coefficient of the credit rating in early 1994 suggests that, as foreign investors
became more familiar with and confident about the country, the rating declined in significance as
an indicator of Argentina's creditworthiness.

3.3

Brazil

For Brazil, the most likely months for a break are March 1994, when the automatic authorization
for issuing bonds, commercial paper and other fixed-income instruments abroad was terminated;
November 1994 following the increase in the financial transaction tax on foreign investment in
fixed-income instruments from 5 percent to 9 percent; and the months the credit ratings changed.
From all of them, a dummy set to 1 from November 1994 onwards produced the best results. Its
positive sign suggests that S&P's upgrade of Brazil's credit rating in November 1994, which was
#"

12

followed by Moody's upgrade the following month, dominated the negative effect of the increase
in the financial transaction tax. Hence, the dummy variable is denoted as CREDITt,
Since the results for Brazil are consistent with both the economic fundamentals usually associated with bonds flows and the findings of other studies, only two equations are reported:
equation (12) for the sample ending in December 1993, .and equation (15) -which includes the.<,
dummy- for the whole sample. In both, lagged bond flows, BON Dt-I, have a significantly
positive coefficient, while the lagged U.S. Treasury Bill rate,

u ST BI LLt-I,

has a significantly

negative coefficient. There is; however, evidence against the normality hypothesis, as the x 2 (2) :.,,,.
statistic is significant at the 1 percent level for equation (12), and at the 10 percent level for equation (13). On the other hand, the lack of any regional contagion effect attests to the significance
of country-specific factors.
Finally, as with Mexico and Argentina, the estimated coefficients exhibit remarkable stability
over time. As Figure 6 indicates, they mostly remain within one standard error from their estimates
for the sample ending in December 1993. Worth also pointing out, the interest-rate sensitivity of
the Brazilian bond flows increased in 1995. But so did the constant term, despite the inclusion
of the dummy for the post-November 1994 period.

4

EPILOGUE

Essentially, the empirical analysis explains why the rise in U.S. interest rates in 1994 failed to
have any major and lasting impact on bond issuance by LDCs, and identifies one of the "broader
forces at play", to use the terminology of the Bank for International Settlements (in footnote 1).
This "force", global bond issuance, recovered quickly from the shock of the first interest-rate
rise in February 1994, and thus helped offset the adverse impact of the rising throughout-theyear interest rates and of Mexico's difficulties. This is the case for Argentina. For Mexico, and
possibly other LDCs not included in the sample, U.S. interest rates were not even a determinant
of the flows; global issuance, together with lagged flows, was the only quantifiable determinant,
suggesting the existence of .some.speculative.component.in .these flows. FO[.Brazil though, for
which global issuance was not significant, the adverse impact of the rising rates was seemingly
offset by the positive effect of the improvement in the country's credit rating.
The empirical analysis also documents a remarkable stability of the estimated coefficients
during the period of rising U.S. interest rates and in the aftermath of the Peso devaluation,
and illustrates the uniqueness of each country's experience. This uniqueness, which justifies

13

the paper's country-by-country estimation, is reflected on the significance of the credit rating
for Argentina and Brazil, the fact that Mexico's difficulties -the so-called "Tequilla hangover''affected Argentina's bond flows but not Brazil's, and the different levels and starting time of the
flows to each country.
In addition to explaining the surprising resilience of bond flows to LDCs, the significance
of global issuance provides ample ex-post justification for the extraordinary rescue operation
launched after the Peso devaluation. This operation gave Mexico some breathing space until
it could tap the international bond market again; and reassured international investors who,
otherwise, might have withdrawn from the country and the region as a whole turning a temporary
liquidity crisis into another development crisis. Moreover, the stability of the estimated coefficients
suggests that the rescue operation could have been justified ex-ante as well.
Yet, although the significance of global issuance leaves some hope that the current episode
of capital flows to LDCs may not end in a crisis as its two predecessors did, it cannot rule out this
possibility. On the one hand, as long as the process of international diversification continues to
fuel global issuance, bond flows to LDCs may withstand the shocks of cyclical interest rate rises
and country-specific difficulties. On the other hand, however, external financing difficulties in a
major LDC may lead to a downward shift in the supply of funds for all of them and, eventually, to
a drying-up of flows even when global bond issuance continues expanding. Strengthening the
case for caution, there is evidence that several LDCs borrowed in the early 1990s more than
they needed, an allusion to some "over-borrowing syndrome" (McKinnon and Pill [1994]) and a
warning of future debt-servicing difficulties. Consequently, policy makers must remain watchful
despite the positive influence of rising global issuance and the adoption of sound economic
policies in the borrowing LDCs.

14

--k

APPENDIX: Data Description
With the exception of bond flows, all data are retrieved from the International Financial Statistics (IFS) database. The average exchange rate (line rt in IFS), end-of-period foreign exchange

reserves minus gold (line 1Ld), consumer prices (line 64), and interest rates are available at
monthly intervals, while the current account (line ?Bald) is available at quarterly intervals. The
interest rates used are determined by data availability. These are the lending rate (line 60p) for
Argentina, the bank rate (line 60) for Brazil, and the average cost of funds (line 60n) for Mexico.
In line with previous studies, the U.S. Treasury bill rate (line 60c) and the ten-year government
bond yield (line 61) are used as proxies for international interest rates.
Monthly bond flows come from the OECD's Financial Statistics Part I and include gross public
and private placements of euro-bond and foreign bond issues, with a maturity of one year or
longer. Table A-1 shows bond flows and syndicated bank loans for the years 1990 through 1995,
for the world, Latin America, and the sample countries. As Table A-1 indicates, bonds are the
primary borrowing instrument for L.A. countries in the 1990s. They account though for a small
share of global issuance, an indication that the latter is a good proxy of the supply of funds L.A.
countries were facing.
Finally, Table A-2 presents a chronology of the major post-1989 events which might have
affected bond flows to individual countries. This chronology guides the construction of the dummy
variables used in the econometric estimation.

15

REFERENCES
1. Bank for International Settlements (1996). International Banking and Financial Market Developments, August.
2. Calvo, Guillermo A., Leonardo Leiderman and Carmen M. Reinhart (1992a).
Capital Inflows and Real Exchange Rate Appreciation in Latin America: The Role of External Factors.
IMF Working Paper, WP/92/62, August.
3. Calvo, Guillermo A., Leonardo Leiderman and Carmen M. Reinhart (1992b).
Capital Inflows to Latin America: The 1970s and the 1990s.
IMF Working Paper, WP/92/85, October.
4. Calvo, Guillermo A., Leonardo Leiderman and Carmen M. Reinhart (1993).
The Capital Inflows Problem: Concepts and Issues.
IMF Paper on Policy Analysis and Assessment, PPAA/93/10, July.
5. Calvo, Guillermo A., Leonardo Leiderman and Carmen M. Reinhart (1996).
Inflows of Capital to Developing Countries in the 1990s.
Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 10, No. 2, pp. 123-139, Spring.
6. Calvo, Guillermo A., Raina Sahay and Carlos A. Vegh (1995).
Capital Inflows in Central and Eastern Europe: Evidence and Policy Options.
IMF Working Paper, WP/95/57, May.
7. Calvo, Sara and Carmen M. Reinhart (1995).
Capital Flows to Latin America: Is There Evidence of Contagion Effects?.
mimeo, World Bank & IMF, April.

s.

Carneiro, Dionisio Dias and Marcie G.P. Garcia (1995).
Private International Capital Flows to Brazil.
mimeo, Department of Economics, Pontifical Catholic University of Rio de Janeiro.

9. Chuhan, Punam, Stijn Claessens and Nlandu Mamingi (1993).
,.Equity and Bond Flows to Asia and Latin America: The Role of Global and Country Factors.
. Working Paper, WPS 1160, The World Bank, July.
10. Chuhan, Punam, Gabriel Perez and Helen Popper (1996).
International Capital Flows: Do Short-Term Investment and Direct Investment Differ? .
Working Paper, The World Bank, June.

16

11. Culpeper, Roy (1994).
Resurgence of Private Flows to Latin America: The Role of American Investors.

mimeo, North-South Institute, February.
12. Diaz-Alejandro, Carlos F. (1984).
Latin American Debt: I Don't Think We Are in Kansas Anymore.

Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, No. 2, pp. 335-403.
13. Dooley, Michael P. (1994).
Are Recent Capital Inflows to Developing Countries A Vote For or Against Economic Policy .
Reforms?.

Working Paper, No. 295, University of California at Santa Cruz, May.
14. Dooley, Michael P., Eduardo Fernandez-Arias and Kenneth M. Kietzer (1996).
Is the Debt Crisis History? Recent Private Capital Inflows to Developing Countries.

World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 10, No. 1, pp. 27-50, January.
15. Edwards, Sebastian.
LDC Foreign Borrowing and Default Risk: An Empirical Investigation, 1976-80.

American Economic Review, Vol. 74, No. 4, pp.726-734, September.
16. Eichengreen, Barry (1996).
International Lending in the Long Run: Motives and Management.

manuscript, presented at the conference on The Future of Emerging Market Capital Flows ·
at the STERN Scool of Business, New York University, in May 1996.
17. Fernandez-Ansola, Juan Jose and Thomas Laursen (1995).
Historical Experience with Bond Financing to Developing Countries.

IMF Working Paper, WP/95/27, March.
18. Fernandez-Arias, Eduardo (1996).
The New Wave of Private Capital Inflows: Push or Pull?.

Journal of Development Economics, Vol. 48, pp. 389-418, March.
19. Fernandez-Arias, Eduardo and Kenneth M. Kietzer (1996).
The Surge in Capital Inflows to Developing Countries: An Analytical Overview.

World Bank Economic Review, Vol. 10, No. 1, pp. 51-77, January.
20. Financial Times (1996). Capital Set to Flow into Latin America, (September 13).
21. Gooptu, Sudarshan (1993).
Portfolio Investment Flows to Emerging Markets.

17

Paper, presented in the World Bank Symposium Portfolio Investment in Developing Countries, September 9-10.
22. Greene, William H. (1995). LIMDEP User's Manual (Version 7.0), Econometric Software,
Inc ..
23. International Monetary Fund. Exchange Restrictions and Exchange Arrangements, various
issues.
24. International Monetary Fund. International Financial Statistics, various issues.
25. International Monetary Fund. Private Market Financing for Developing Countries, various
issues.
26. International Monetary Fund (1996). International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects,

and Key Policy Issues, September.
27. Kaminsky, Graciela L. and Alfredo Pereira (1994).

The Debt Crisis: Lessons of the 1980's for the 1990's.
International Finance Discussion Paper, No. 481, Board of the Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, September.
28. McKinnon, Ronald I. and Huw Pill (1994).

Credible Liberalizations and International Capital Flows: The Over-Borrowing Syndrome.
Working Paper, Department of Economics, Stanford University, May.
29. Rojas-Suarez, Liliana and Steven Weisbrod (1995).

Achieving Stability in Latin American Financial Markets in the Presence of Volatile Capital
Flows.
Working Paper Series, No 304, Inter-American Development Bank.
30. Rosenda, Francisco (1995).

Handling Capital Inflows: Some Comments on the Chilean Experience.
mimeo, Catholic University of Chile, June.
31. Sachs, Jeffrey, Aaron Tornell and Andres Velasco (1995).

The Collapse ofthe Mexican Peso: What Have We Learned?.
NBER Working Paper, No. 5142, June.
32. Yang, Jiawen (1996).

U.S. Interest Rates and Portfolio Investments in Latin America.
Working Paper, School of Business and Public Administration, the George Washington
University.

18

TABLE 1.
Potential Explanatory Variables for Bond Flows
Symbol
Description
1. Market Access
BOND
Lagged
Bond Flows

2. Supply of Funds
WBOND
Global
Bond Issuance

Expected
Sign
Not Certain

High BON Dt-k (k :::: 1) may indicate high access to the international financial markets and, thus,
better familiarity of international investors with the borrowing country. In this case, BON Dt-k (k :::: 1)
should have a positive sign.
On the other hand, high BON Dt-k (k :::: 1) may reflect excessive borrowing in previous periods
which may be compensated for by lower current borrowing, BON Dt- Here, BON Dt-k (k :::: 1)
should have a negative sign.

+

As Table A-1 in the appendix documents, L.A. borrowers account for a small fraction of the funds
raised in the international financial markets. Consequently, w BOND constitutes a good proxy of
the supply of funds they face.
Since a higher supply would, everything else equal, lead to more bond flows, w BOND is expected
to have a positive sign.

3. Demand for Funds- Need (NEED}
Likely CA
Current
Account

Real
Exchange
Rate
Appreciation

%t.R

Cumulative

%t.Rcum

%t.R

Comments

Likely+

Likely+

On the demand side, a deteriorating negative c A indicates a higher need for external financing and
more flows, suggesting that c A should have a negative coefficient.
But, on the supply side, a high and persistent c A deficit may undermine investors' confidence and
thus lead to lower flows, in which case c A should have a positive coefficient.
Taking into account the optimistic expectations before the "Peso crisis", it seems that a negative
coefficient is more likely.
Since CA figures are available at quarterly intervals, CAt/3 is used as a proxy of monthly external
financing needs.
%t.R,

= %t.Pt -

%t.Pt - %t.e1

where:
• t.: difference operator
• P: domestic Consumer Price Index (CPI)
• P*: U.S. CPI, a proxy of foreign prices
• e: exchange rate, local currency per U.S. $.
A real exchange rate appreciation may lead to a c A deterioration and higher external financing
needs. Thus, according to the previous analysis, %t.R is likely to have a positive coefficient.
Cumulative since January 1990. %t.Rcum may be a better proxy of the external financing needs
than %t.R.
For its sign, see the discussion on %t.R.

TABLE 1. - Continued (a)
Description

Symbol

Expected
Sign

4. Demand for Funds - Cost (COST)
i
Domestic
Interest Rate

+

Domestic Real
Interest Rate
International
Interest Rates

Expected
Interest-Rate
Changes

r

+

·•

-

Ett..i;+l

+

'

Comments
Lower i should lead to lower external borrowing by domestic agents, when the external financing
constraint is not binding. Note that the reserve accumulation is an indication that the sample
countries were borrowing abroad more than their external financing needs.
Not applicable to Argentina and Brazil where bouts of hyperinflation caused wild fluctuations in ;
during the sample period.
rt= it - %f>.Pt
For its sign, see the discussion on i.
Controlling for global bond issuance, w BOND, a decrease in ;;_k (k 2': 1) should lead to higher
borrowing, and vice-versa.
;• is proxied by the U.S. Treasury Bill rate and the U.S. ten-year government bond yield, respectively
denoted as UST BILL and USBOND.
Taking into account the time elapsing between the negotiation of a deal and the actual disbursement
of funds, ;• should be lagged at least one period. Nevertheless, the results are virtually the same
when the contemporaneous rates are used.
E is the usual expectations operator.
Since countries might rush to borrow before an expected rise in interest rates, its sign should be
positive.
This variable is proxied by the difference between the U.S. 10-year government bond yield and
Treasury bill rate, US BON Dt-1 - USTBILLt-1•

5. Contagion Effects .
LABOND
Lagged Flows
to Region

+

LABO ND is equal to total bond flows to L.A., inclusive of flows to countries like Chile and Colombia
which are not in the sample due to insufficient number of non-zero observations for BOND. Calvo
and Reinhart (1995) model regional contagion effects in a similar way.

6. Creditworthiness
CRED
Credit
Rating

+

Everything else equal, an increase in the credit rating should lead to a lower cost and higher supply
of funds, both of which imply higher bond flows.
Two measures are used:
• ordinal: a different dummy variable is used for each credit rating (see Cantor and Packer [1996]
for a complete list of credit ratings by Moody's and Standard & Poor's).
• cardinal: a value is assigned to each credit rating, starting from zero for no rating and moving up
to sixteen for the highest rating at increments of one, as described in Cantor and Packer (1996).
The credit ratings of the sample countries are listed in Table A-2, in the appendix.

TABLE 1. - Continued (b)
Description
Symbol
7. International Liquidity
Lagged
RES
Reserves

Expected
Sign
Not Certain

8. Policy Changes & Major Events
DUM
Dummies
Depends

Comments
On the demand side, high reserves may mitigate the need for external borrowing. In addition, the
fiscal cost of carrying high reserves may tamper the authorities' desire to sterilize the inflows. In
this case, the inflows will lead to an expansion of domestic money supply and lower domestic rates,
and through the latter to lower foreign borrowing. (The fiscal cost reflects the higher interest rate
LDCs pay on their outstanding foreign liabilities (debt) relative to the interest rate they receive on
their holdings of foreign-government securities.)
But on the supply side, high reserves may enhance foreign investors' confidence and thus lead to
higher bond flows.
Since reserves correspond to end-of-month figures, while actual flows occur sometime after a deal
is negotiated, RES must be lagged at least two periods.
Dummies are used to capture the impact of major political events and changes in economic policies
(especially those pertaining to capital controls), which may affect the supply or the cost of funds to
domestic agents.
The dummies are based on the chronology of major post-1989 events outlined in Table A-2, in the
appendix, and are discussed extensively in the main text.

9. Quality of Economic Management (QUALITY)
Variance
var Jrt
var
is equal to a moving twelve-month variance of inflation, from month t to month t - 11.
of Inflation
Taking into account the lags in reporting inflation figures, this variable should be lagged at least two
periods.
As in Edwards (1984), lower variance indicates better macroeconomic management and, thus,
should lead to better access to the international financial markets and lower interest rate spreads.
Hence, both the demand and the supply sides indicate that var _rr,'s coefficient should be negative.
var_%~e,
Variance
The variance of exchange rate depreciation is constructed in a similar way as var -"t·
of %~e,
Since e is the monthly-average of the exchange rate, this variable must be lagged at least one
period.

-

-

_,r,

TABLE 2.
The Detenninants of Bond Flows to L.A. Countries, 1990-1995

Explanatory
Vartables
Constant

(1)
-602.27
(-4.60)*..

(2)
-244.32
(-1.05)

BOND,-,

+0.4028
(3.68)***

+0.3741
(2.98) ...

WBOND,

+0.0264
(5.81)***

+0.0223
(3.90)***

RESt-3

-0.0558
(-1.75)*

%6.Rf.:i

+40.986
(1.77)*

Mexico
(3)
(4)
-530.49
+1944.8
(4.07) ... (-4.24)***

+0.2252
(1.41)

Argentina
(5)
-527.55
(-4.43)***

(6)
+702.49
(1.37)

(7)

+0.3942
(3.94)***

+0.3263
(3.34)* ..

+ 0.1683
(1.49)

-0.4412
(-1.30)

+0.0229
(5.85) ...

+0.0246
(6.50)* ..

+ 0.0189
(4.43)***

+0.0121
(2.60)***

-237.42
(-3.94)***

USBOND,-1

(8)

(9)

(10)

-0.4432
(-2.42) ..
+0.0139
(3.34)***

(11)

-0.4265
(-2.20)**

+0.0130
(2.84)"'

+0.0150
(3.53)***

-672.58
(-2.35)**

-708.20
(-2.44) ..

Brazil
(12)
(13)
+759.92
+854.95
(4.03)***
(4.17)* ..

+0.4000
(2.03)**

+0.3344
(2.28)**

-156.36
(-4.08) ...

-186.68
(-4.08)* ..

+0.0129
(2.65)* ..

-138.30
(-2.44)**

DUM, = 1
for t=95:1-95:5

-495.11
(-2.83)* ..

-457.38
(-2.76)***

UST BIL£,_,

CREDIT,

-101.35
(-3.36)***

-107.58
(-3.42)***

-120.10
(-3.94) ...

-123.47
(-3.91)*··

-135.46
(-4.10)* ..

193.17
(3.39) ...

172.17
(3.85) ...

142.41
(3.99)* ..

132.74
(4.05)* ..

110.48
(3.18)* ..

0.1127
(1.19)

REGION,_,

0.1542
(1.77)*

500.35
(3.57)***

0.2152
(2.43)**

Diagnostics
93:12

Sample Ends

95:12

"Log L

263.64

253.12

302.78

-271.94

-270.39

-278.72

x 2 (2)

1.78

0.66

8.93**

93:12

95:12

93:12

95:12

321.40

305.40

291.66

328.47

342.99

406.95

434.40

428.90

247.55

341.99

-433.72
4_53•

-429.48

-426.62

-188.60

-330.45

-333.29

-333.49

-205.89

-363.98

1.69

1.85

-187.55
24.54...

19.23***

1.04

5_52•

1.29

18.92,.,.*

5.98.

Notes:
1. For vartable definitions, see Table 1.
2. The best model is identified by an equation number in bold lace.
3. c;: standard error of the residuals; Log L: log-likelihood.
4. t-statistics are shown in parentheses below the estimated coefficients. Significance Levels: 1 (... ), 5 (.. ) and 10 (') percent.
5. x 2 (2): from a moments-based test for normality of the residuals. Critical levels: 4.61 at the 10%, 5.99 at the 5%, and 9.21 at the 1% significance levels. ,

TABLE A-1.
Private Capital Rows - Debt-Creating
International Bond Issues

u_,., MIiiion

syndicated Loans

u.,.. Million

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

1990

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

229,935.0

308,729.9

333,693.3

480,997.8

428,628.1

460,658.1

124,524.9

116,025.2

117,869.0

136,676.4

236,221.7

408,401.8

Latin America

972.9

4,942.4

8,112.2

24,709.2

16,251.1

17,489.7

3,217.0

849.6

910.2

2,168.4

1,724.5

4,133.0

of which
Argentina
Brazil
Mexico

0.0
0.0
622.3

750.0
1,461.6
2,149.5

1,529.2
2,830.0
2,923.4

6,097.1
6,120.4
9,531.3

5,081.2
3,782.4
6,515.5

5,018.1
5,883.7
5,358.6

0.0
0.0
1,580.0

0.0
18.0
616.6

0.0
180.0
175.2

376.0
209.0
400.0

634.5
0.0
710.0

1,513.0
351.0
758.0

I Global Issuance
of which

Source: OECD Financial Statistics Monthly.

TABLE A-2.
Sample Countries - Chronology of Major, Post-1989 Events
Credit Ratings

• Moody's: 83 until July 1992, 81 thereafter.
• S&P: BB- from August 1993, none before.

Argentina

Exchange Rate
Arrangements:
Major Changes

• December 12, 1989: The foreign exchange market was unified under a freely floating system;
swap transactions and forward exchange operations were permitted.
• January 29, 1991: A target range for exchange rate intervention was announced.
• March 19, 1991 The unified floating exchange rate system was replaced by a peg to the U.S.$.
• January 1, 1992: The Peso replaced the Austral at the rate of 1 Peso to 10,000 Australs.

.

• announced on December 1, 1992, but effective in early 1993: Current account deposits in U.S.$
would be permitted; the same reserve requirements would apply to foreign and domestic currency
deposits; domestic financial institutions would be allowed to extend credits in local currency against
these deposits, except those in a savings bank or a fixed-term account, up to 25 percent of their
capital, subject to the regulations governing their net overall foreign exchange position.
• January 1, 1993: Checking accounts denominated in U.S.$ allowed to be opened by residents
and used for domestic and international transactions.
Credit Ratings

• Moody's: 82 until November 1994, 81 thereafter.
• S&P : B on December 1994, B+ after July 1995.

Brazil

Exchange Rate
Arrangements:
Major Changes

• February 28, 1994: The regulations on the financial transactions tax were revised whereby up
to 25 percent may be applied on the issue of bonds abroad and on foreign investments in fixedincome securities, when the government considers it necessary to raise the tax rates from the
prevailing levels of 3 and 5 percent, respectively.
• March 2, 1994: The automatic authorization for issuing bonds, commercial paper, and other
fixed-income instruments abroad was terminated.
• October 19, 1994: The financial transaction tax on foreign investment in fixed-income instruments
was increased to 9 percent from 5 percent.

Credit Ratings

o Moody's: Ba2 since 1990.

• S&P: BB+ since 1992, BB after February 1995.

Mexico

Exchange Rate
Arrangements:
Major Changes

• May 28, 1990: The rules governing the establishment of the exchange rate of the Peso were
modified, whereby the rate would be depreciated daily against the U.S.$ by the pre-announced
amount of 0.80 Pesos.
o November 12, 1990: The rate of daily depreciation changed to 0.40 Pesos.
o November 11, 1991: All controls on exchange transactions were abolished, and the Controlled

Exchange Rate Market was eliminated.
o June 22, 1992: It was announced that a new Peso, equivalent to 1,000 old Pesos, would be

introduced on January 1, 1993.
o October 21, 1992: The daily depreciation of the selling intervention point was increased from 0.20

to 0.40 Pesos per U.S.$.
• January 1, 1994: NAFTA became effective.
o December 20, 1994: The upper limit of the exchange rate band was raised to 3.99 Pesos per

U.S.$, representing a devaluation of 15 percent.
• December 22, 1994: The Peso was allowed to float, and the exchange rate regime based on the
crawling peg was abandoned.
Major Political
Events
during 1994

'

o January: Chiapas revolution.

• March: Assassination of presidential candidate Colossio.
o August: Presidential elections.

'

• September: Another political assassination (of J.F. Ruis Massieu).
• December: President Zedillo takes office.
Note: The information on foreign exchange arrangements comes from various issues of the IMF's annual publication "Exchange Arrangements and Exchange Restrictions'.

Bond Flows to L.A. & Global Issuance (Million, US$)
Figure 1.

Bond Flows to L.A.

Global Issuance

10,000

160,000
140,000

8,000
120,000
100,000

6,000

80,000
4,000
60,000
Bond Flows to L.A.

40,000
2,000
20,000
0 I fi'iffl 'i=il M= ,-, IR1ffi wniffil
91:1
90:1

92:1

93:1
QUARTER

94:1

0

95:1

New Bond Issues (Million, $US} & U.S. Treasury Bill Rate (%}
Figure 2.

WORLD
Mn, US$

Percent

10
8

:

UST-Bill
Rate

I- L-..._

ti

1
'

:

~

61-i

4

70,000

!
!
:
!
i

" n

!

•

j

NewBond l~ues

60,000

l

i
i

i

Iij

I

:

:

'

New Bond
Issues

-ra

2,000

[New Bond
!issues
--,

I

I !

I

o·.

•i

\I

1 500
•

I r1 1•000

ii II Al

:

rn ram

lil[fllill:II I lfllil lli1Wlli11i1Wlill

1990

1991

rnrn

[I

~

ffi fil -l 500

@I

1992

lllliilrlli:llli1111!ilml~lr111ilnllllodliill il,lllllli1Wliil~lilil I

1993

1994

WW lall,lljJlilil IQ

1995

MEXICO

Percent

10 :

8

Mn, US$
2,000

UST-Bill
Rate

-

New Bond
Issues
-1
1,500

1,500

6

6

1,000

1,000

4

4
500

500

2

2

0

~ i

10,000

Mn, US$

i
j

t!
4
2

0

BRAZIL

8

UST-Bill
Rate

8

30,000
20,000

;•~;;awe=·;99~ww .

UST-Bill
!----Rate

2,000

6
40,000

,m9~=~'""""";';~;-"•~;m""'"";;;;=••••..

10
Percent

Mn, US$

!

50,000

2 I- UilLliBlmlil!!llll!II_IRl_mmim1m■-l!IIB-lliffl■ l
0I

10

:

••me mmL11

llm ~"j fl'ilUl■llllilallllllll

ARGENTINA

Percent

1990
~~

199_1

0

1992

1993

1994

1995

QI IMW

MMM

1990

M

1991

1992

1993

1994

1995

0

Current Account & Foreign Exchange Reserves (Million, US$)
Figure 3.
BRAZIL

so,ooo

ARGENTINA

20,000

50,000
15,000

------------------~

~ 10,000

1=
:ii

40,000

..

Foreign Exchange Reserves

Foreign Exchange Reserves

~ 30,000

1j
5,000

1- -

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-/-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

-

20,000

-

10,000
0

-5,000

I

EEJ EtBI

o I WM! WJI ==(Wj
-10,000

~---'----...L.~~~~~~~~...L.~~~~-~~~...L.~~~~~~~~

90:1

90:3

91:1

91:3

92:1

92:3

93:1

93:3

94:1

94:3

95:1

90:3

91:1

91:3

92:1

MEXICO

30,ooo

Foreign Exchange Reserves
20,000

ll!
::,
110,000

:ii

-10,000

I

Current Account
bQf.=!k.4\11'4¾

~~~...L.~~~~~-~-'--~~...L.~~~~~-~-'---'--~...L....L.-'

90:1

90:3

91:1

91:3

92:3

93:1

QUARTER

QUARTER

0

em

__ fJ":Jlifill
fiidlWJ

92:1

92:3

93:1

QUARTER

93:3

=rn[§l lffiHI

~-'--~-'-----'-------'-------'-------'------'------'---~-1...~_L~_j_~_____l~_J_J~_J~L_.c.....J

90:1

95:3

Current Account
mm

94:1

94:3

95:1

95:3

93:3

94:1

94:3

95:1

95:3

MEXICO -- Sequentially-Estimated Coefficients
Figure 4.

-300
-400

Lagged Bond Flows
0.8 r-:-,- - - - - . , - - - - - - : - - - - - - - , - - - - - - - - , - ,

Constant

-200

,..••• i

0.7

~········-···------···-···:---·-.........--~. ·. •··..·····--------··--~-.•........•·..........···

0.6

I-'.--·.........•················•··············-·········........·················-··•.....~·····•........................,

-500
0.5
-600
0.4 ~;_:__,,,----.;..--..____;......-----:
-700
-800

·-······-··-•...••····...••·······

-·············-._..._.......~..........................-·····,

-900
-1,000 ......~~~~~_.__.__.__.__._...........' - - ' ' - - ' ~ ~ - ' - - ' - - ' - ~ ~ ~ . . u
1993:12
1994:6
1994:12
1995:6
1995:12
Sample End

0,3

1-:

0.2

t- ~-••••••••••. ••••••••••••••••:•-•

0.1 ~~~..............................' - - ' ~ ~ . . . . J . - ' - - ' - ~ ~ ~ . . 1 . . . ..............._'--'__u
1993:12
---··-- .. 1994:t>
1994:12
1995:6
1995:12
Sample End

Global Bond Issuance
0,04 ,-,-,- - - - - , - - - - - - - , - - - - - - , - - - - - . , . ,

0.035

r••···-·------....~.......

------ '••-----··--........~·· .................... ······'
___

0.03
0.025
0.02

,.

••H•o~•••••••••••••••••••..•••-••-~••·...••• ....•••-•••••••··•••••,

....------------·························-···-········:...·-----.......,..--------..._____..,_·..~----

0.015
0.01 ~~................'--'~-'-~~~...............'--'~--'-~~................u
1993:12
. -- . 1994:6
1994:12
1995:6
1995:12
Sample End

Samples Begin in 1990:1
Dashed Lines show the 95% Confidence Bounds: Coefficient +/- 2 Standard Errors

•

ARGENTINA -- Sequentially-Estimated Coefficients
Figure 5.
Lagged Bond Flows

Global Bond Issuance

0.4 . . . . - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - . - ,

0.2 t-\

.,
'\

0

. .--·-·••4·-.

0.025

......

_

~.

·-----------------------··•f ..·------..--··

\ .....----

-0.2

0.03 ..-.- - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - ,

~--._........-··--··-----:......._______...

•···••,

;

-0.4

____ ··············•-.............-...\

.,.....

.

...

0.02
0.015

-0.6
0.01
-0.8

-1

----- ·-~------.....•.;./\\.·······-......./

.

---······ ··-··---:·••.....

~---··.··

·1.2 ......
1993:12

0.005

~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~

1994:6

1994:12
Sample End

1995:6

1995:12

Lagged U.S. Treasury Bill Rate
0

-50

~•••-•-••••••..•••••-•••;••••-•-••••-••••••••-••------ •••••••••~••••••••...••••••••••••h•••,

0 ......~~~~....1...~~~~_,_~~~~....1...~~~~...u
1993:12
1994:6
1994:12
1995:6
1995:12
Sample End
Credit Rating

350

.

1-:

·····--'----.. _..:~--.........___··•..···'.

300

~--·· ·•.

··--....

250

-1001----,-~----,-------

r-;..•-···--····..........................................

-200 1-:

·-..•.....:........__········-······..,.---------.....___...------------······,

200
~

-150

\_
\

.....................•·····-.

..

_ ;

·-.-·

.250 u...~~~~J_~~~~J_~~~~-'-~~~~...u
1993:12
1994:6
1994:12
1995:6
1995:12
Sample End

Samples Begin In 1990:1
Dashed Lines show the 95% Confidence Bounds: Coefficient +/- 2 Standard Errors

150

100
50

I-;.•·--··•......\ ..•......···'.············..•········---

······~---....--···-·..·.....-..-.:

o'-'-~~~~_,_~~~~_,_~~~~J_~~~~...u
1993:12

1994:6

1994:12
Sample End

1995:6

1995:12

BRAZIL- Sequentially-Estimated Coefficients
Figure 6.
1,400

1,200
1,000

,

Lagged Bond Flows

Constant

1r------------------------,

------------------/\;,~~/~

0.6

800

0.4

600

0.2

200

0

..............-~···············-----···········. •·.......-----..._________...-·--..········•'

400

u..~~~~~.,_.,_.,_~~..__..__'-''-'~....................~~~-'-'

1993:12

1994:6

1994:12

1995:6

r- -·-······-·-··········-··'····-····-········-···-····:-······-·····-··············'.······.•••···········•.•., .....

0 .8

' ••••••••• ···-··············:···

-0.2

1995:12

.......~~~............~ ~ ~ . , _ ~ J . . . _ ~ ~..........--L.J

~~~.,_~~

1993:12

Sample End

·-···-·-···•••.•••.•••••-···-\. /~···-····-···-····· •••••...•,

·--·1994:o

·--··1994:12
Sample End

Lagged US Treasury Bill Rate

_____.......

-50 , - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - ~
-••'

_.__

······-~...

.......•·················--·-..._...,

·-

·100

.150

h...

-'----:'-----,
.
~

-

'

~
-200

---·-·····. •·--·-······•·7··························-~- •..~••

oHoo••••

\

\

-250

'\.-------------·······-\

.......

-300 ~~~.,_.,_..__'-'__..__..~~~~.,_~..__'-'__..__..~~~..u
1993:12
1994:6
1994:12
1995:6
1995:12
Sample End

Samples Begin in 1990:1
Dashed Lines sho\lf the 95% Confidence Bounds: Coefficient +/- 2 Standard Errors

1995:6

1995:12

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF NEW YORK
RESEARCH PAPERS

1997

The following papers were written by economists at the Federal Reserve Bank of
New York either alone or in collaboration with outside economists. Single copies of up
to six papers are available upon request from the Public Information Department,
Federal Reserve Bank of New York, 33 Liberty Street, New York, NY 10045-0001
(212) 720-6134.

9701. Chakravarty, Sugato, and Asani Sarkar. "Traders' Broker Choice, Market Liquidity and
Market Structure." January 1997.
9702. Park, Sangkyun. "Option Value of Credit Lines as an Explanation of High Credit Card
Rates." February 1997.

To obtain more information about the Bank's Research Papers series and other
publications and papers, visit our site on the World Wide Web (http://www.ny.frb.org). From
the research publications page, you can view abstracts for Research Papers and Staff Reports and
order the full-length, hard copy versions of them electronically. Interested readers can also view,
download, and print any edition in the Current Issues in Economics and Finance series, as well
as articles from the Economic Policy Review.