The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
Session 88 } JOINT COMMITTEE PEINT THE RELATIONSHIP OF PRICES TO ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH COMPENDIUM OP PAPERS SUBMITTED BY PANELISTS APPEARING BEFORE THE JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE MARCH 31, 1958 Printed for the use of the Joint Economic Committee UNITED STATES GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 23734 WASHINGTON : 1958 For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U. S. Government Printing Office Washington 25, D. C. - Price $2.00 JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE (Created pursuant to sec. 5 (a) of Public Law 304, 79th Cong.) WRIGHT PATMAN, Representative from Texas, Chairman JOHN SPARKMAN, Senator from Alabama, Vice Chairman HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES SENATE RICHARD BOLLING, Missouri PAUL H. DOUGLAS, Illinois HALE BOGGS, Louisiana J. W. FULBRIGHT, Arkansas HENRY 8. REUSS, Wisconsin JOSEPH C. O'MAHONEY, Wyoming HENRY O. TALLE, Iowa RALPH E. FLANDERS, Vermont THOMAS B. CURTIS, Missouri ARTHUR V. WATKINS, Utah CLARENCE E. KILBURN, New York JOHN D. HOBLITZELL, JR., West Virginia JOHN W. LEHMAN, Acting Executive Director JAMES W. KNOWLES, Economist LETTERS OF TRANSMITTAL MARCH Si, 1958.. To Members of the Joint Economic Committee: The papers transmitted with this letter were submitted by 47 leading economists invited to appear before the committee in panel discussions as part of the study: "The Relationship of Prices to Economic Stability and Growth." These papers are presented in advance of the committee's hearings, to be held May 12-22, to provide members of the committee, the contributors, and the public an opportunity to examine the factsr analyses, major issues, and conclusions in the various papers before they are developed in oral statements and discussions at the hearings. WRIGHT PATMAN, Chairman, Joint Economic Committee. in MARCH 31, Hon. 1958. WRIGHT PATMAN, Chairman, Joint Economic Committee, House of Representatives, 'Washington, D. C. DEAR MR. PATMAN : The papers transmitted with this letter were submitted by 47 leading economists invited to appear before the Joint Economic Committee in panel discussions May 12-22 as part of the committee's study: "The ^Relationship of Prices to Economic Stability and Growth." This is in accord with instructions to the staff approved by the committee, October 7,1957. The papers are presented as submitted by the contributors, without additions or deletions. They are arranged by panel topics in the order in which they are scheduled for discussion at the hearings. In connection with these papers and the subsequent hearings, reference may be made to data included in the staff materials, "Productivity, Prices, and Incomes," published by the committee last July. If th& most recent data or revisions in data are not available readily in current publications, supplementary tables are included in the appendix to this volume. JOHN W. LEHMAN, Acting Executive Director, CONTENTS Page Introduction by Wright Patman, chairman, Joint Economic Committee. Contributed papers: I. Employment Act Objectives and the Stabilization of Prices The Employment Act of 1946: The Dynamics of Public Economic Policy, Grover W. Ensley, National Association of Mutual Savings Banks , Employment Act Objectives and the Stabilization of Prices, Edwin G. Nourse, Economic Consultant Price-Level Stability and Employment Act Objectives, Joseph Aschheim, The Johns Hopkins University How Important Is Price Stability in Stable Economic Growth? G. L. Bach, Carnegie Institute of Technology Price Behavior, Stability and Growth, William J. Baumol, Princeton University Economic Stability, Economic Growth and Price Stability, Betty G. Fishman and Leo Fishman, West Virginia University. . II. The Measurement of Price Changes and Price Relationships The Measurement of Price Changes, Kenneth J. Arrow, Stanford University Administered Prices in the American Economy, Martin J. Bailey, University of Chicago The Price Indexes of the Bureau of Labor Statistics, H. E. Riley, Bureau of Labor Statistics, United States Department of Labor Price and Income Measures for American Agriculture, Oris V. Wells, Agricultural Marketing Service, United States Department of Agriculture III. Past Price Behavior Viewed in the Context of Cyclical and Secular Economic Changes The Behavior of Prices, 1890-1940, Clarence H. Danhof, Tulane University An Interpretation of Price Movements Since the End of World War II, Bert G. Hickman, The Brookings Institution Cyclical Changes in Labor Cost, Thor Hultgren, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc Trends in Product Prices, Factor Prices, and Productivity, John W. Kendrick, The George Washington University IV, Interrelationships Among Prices, Demands, and Costs The Supply of Money and Changes in Prices and Output, Milton Friedman, University of Chicago Inflationary Depression and the Regulation of Administered Prices, Abba P. Lerner, Roosevelt University and The Johns Hopkins University The Destabilizing Influence of Raw Materials Prices, Ruth P. Mack, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc Relationships Between Foreign and American Prices, Gardner Patterson, Princeton University Prices, Costs, Demand, and Output in the United States, 194757, Richard Ruggles, Yale University, and Nancy D. Ruggles, United Nations Models of the Pricing Process, J. Fred Weston, University of California, Los Angeles VII xi xin 1 13 23 33 49 61 75 77 89 107 117 131 133 143 211 225 237 241 257 269 285 297 309 VIII CONTENTS V. Interrelationships Among Prices, Employment, Output, Incomes, and Resources The Composition of the Price Structure, Resource Allocation, and Employment Levels, Clark C. Bloom, State University of Iowa Investment and the Price System, G. D. Bodenhorn, University of Chicago Resource Allocation, Economic Stabilization, and Public Policy Toward Prices, Carl F. Christ, the University of Chicago 1 Inflation, the Wage-Price Spiral and Economic Growth, Otto Eckstein, Harvard University Pricing for Stability and Growth, John P. Lewis, Indiana University VI. Private Pricing Policies: Their Formulation and Effects Business Price Policies and Economic Stability, Wroe Alderson, Alderson & Sessions, Inc Prices and Business Cycles, Lawrence E. Fouraker, Pennsylvania State University Retail Price Policies, Stanley C. Hollander, Michigan State University Some Characteristics and Economic Effects of Pricing Objectives in Large Corporations, Robert K. Lanzillotti, State College of Washington Cyclical Implications of Private Pricing Policies, Alfred R» Oxenfeldt, Columbia University VII. Relationships Between Public Policies, Private Pricing Policies, Price Changes, and Price Relationships Price Effects of Tax Changes, George E. Lent, The Amos Tuck School of Business Administration, Dartmouth College Monetary Policy and the Structure of Markets, Warren L. Smith, University of Michigan Government Policy Toward Competition and Private Pricing, Myron W. Watkins and Joel B. Dirlam, Boni, Watkins, Jason & Co., Inc The Effect of Government Spending Programs on Private Price Formation, Murray L. Weidenbaum, Convair Division of General Dynamics Corporation The Influence of the Antitrust Laws and Related Governmental Policies on Prices, Simon N. Whitney, Federal Trade Commission VIII. Formulating Public Policies for Economic Stability and Growth An Economic Policy for Economic Growth and Stability, Oswald H. Brownlee, University of Minnesota The Coordination of Price, Wage, Fiscal, and Monetary Policies in Norway, Sweden, and the United States, Allan Gruchy, University of Maryland The Optimal Mix of Stabilization Policies, Richard A. Musgrave, University of Michigan Price Policy and Economic Growth and Stability, Arthur Smithies, Harvard University General summary A Third Approach to the Analysis and Control of Inflation, Gardner Ackley, University of Michigan Maintaining Prosperity Without Inflation: Objectives, Problems, and Policies, Neil H. Jacoby, University of California, Los Angeles. _ _ Price Level Stability and Economic Policy, Albert E. Rees, University of Chicago A General View of the Inflation Problem, Herbert Stein, Committee for Economic Development Relationship of Prices to Economic Stability and Growth: A Statement of the Problem, Robert C. Turner, Indiana University App endix 319 323 335 345 361 375 397 399 417 425 441 461 477 479 493 513 529 555 573 575 583 597 611 617 619 637 651 665 671 685 CONTENTS; IX CONTRIBUTORS Ackley, Gardner, Chairman and Professor, Department of Economics, University of Michigan, "A Third Approach to the Analysis and Control of Inflation" Alderson, Wroe, Alderson & Sessions Inc., Philadelphia, "Business Price Policies and Economic Stability" Arrow, Kenneth J., Professor of Economics and Statistics, Stanford University, "The Measurement of Price Changes" Aschheim, Joseph, Assistant Professor of Political Economy, The Johns Hopkins University, "Price-Level Stability and Employment Act Objectives" Bach, George L., Dean, Graduate School of Industrial Administration, Carnegie Institute of Technology, "How Important is Price Stability in Stable Economic Growth?" Bailey, Martin J., Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, "Administered Prices in the American Economy" Baumol, William J., Professor of Economics and Sociology, Princeton University, "Price Behavior, Stability and Growth" Bloom, Clark C , Professor of Economics and Assistant Director, Bureau of Business and Economic Research, State University of Iowa, "The Composition of the Price Structure, Resource Allocation, and Employment Levels" Bodenhorn, G. Diran, Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, "Investment and the Price System" Brownlee, Oswald H., Professor of Economics, University of Minnesota, "An Economic Policy for Economic Growth and Stability" Christ, Carl F., Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, "Resource Allocation, Economic Stabilization, and Public'Policy Toward Prices" __ Danhof, Clarence H., Professor of Economics, Tulane University, "The Behavior of Prices, 1890-1940" Dirlam, Joel B., Senior Consultant, with Myron W. Watkins, Vice President, Boni, Watkins, Jason & Co., Inc., Government Policy Toward Competition and Private Pricing" Eckstein, Otto, Professor of Economics, Harvard University, "Inflation, the Wage-Price Spiral and Economic Growth" Ensley, Grover W., Executive Vice President, National Association of Mutual Savings Banks, "The Employment Act of 1946: The Dynamics of Public Economic Policy" Fishman, Leo, Professor of Economics and Finance, and Betty G. Fishman, Lecturer in Economics, West Virginia University, "Economic Stability, Economic Growth and Price Stability" Fouraker, Lawrence E., Professor of Economics, Pennsylvania State University, "Prices and Business Cycles" Friedman, Milton, Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, National Bureau of Economic Research, and Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences, "The Supply of Money and Changes in Prices and Output" Gruchy, Allan, Professor of Economics, University of Maryland, "The Coordination of Price, Wage, Fiscal, and Monetary Policies in Norway, Sweden, and the United States" Hickman, Bert G., The Brookings Institution, "An Interpretation of Price Movements Since the End of World War I I " Hollander, Stanley C , Associate Professor of Business Administration, Michigan State University, "Retail Price Policies" Hultgren, Thor, Research Staff, National Bureau of Economic Research, "Cyclical Changes in Labor Cost" Jacoby, Neil H., Dean, Graduate School of Business Administration, University of California, Los Angeles, "Maintaining Prosperity Without Inflation: Objectives, Problems, and Policies" Kendrick, John W., Associate Professor of Economics, The George Washington University, and Research Staff, National Bureau of Economic Research, "Trends in Product Prices, Factor Prices, and Productivity" __ Lanzillotti, Robert K., Associate Professor of Economics, State College of Washington, "Some Characteristics and Economic Effects of Pricing Objectives in Large Corporations" Lent, George E., Visiting Professor of Business Economics and Director of Research, The Amos Tuck School of Business Administration, Dartmouth College, "Price Effects of Tax Changes" Pag6 619 399 77 23 33 89 49 323 335 575 345 133 513 361 1 61 417 241 583 143 425 211 637 225 441 479 X CONTENTS Lemer, Abba P., Professor of Economics, Roosevelt University, and Visiting Professor of Political Economy, The Johns Hopkins University, "Inflationary Depression and the Regulation of Administered Prices". _ 257 Lewis, John P., Professor of Business Economics and Public Policy, Indiana University, "Pricing for Stability and Growth" 375 Mack, Ruth P., Research Staff, National Bureau of Economic Research, "The Destabilizing Influence of Raw Materials Prices" 269 Musgrave, Richard A., Professor of Economics, University of Michigan, "The Optimal Mix of Stabilization Policies" 597 Nourse, Edwin G., Economic Consultant, Washington, D. C, "Employment Objectives and the Stabilization of Prices" 13 Oxenfeldt, Alfred R., Professor of Marketing, Graduate School of Business, Columbia University, "Cyclical Implications of Private Pricing Policies". 461 Patterson, Gardner, Professor of Economics, Princeton University, "Relationships Between Foreign and American Prices" 285 Rees, Albert E., Associate Professor of Economics, University of Chicago, "Price Level Stability and Economic Policy" 651 Riley, H. E., Chief, Division of Prices and Cost of Living, Bureau of Labor Statistics, United States Department of Labor, "The Price Indexes of the Bureau of Labor Statistics" 107 Ruggles, Richard, Professor of Economics, Yale University, and Nancy D. Ruggles, Bureau of Economic Affairs, United Nations, "Prices, Costs, Demand, and Output in the United States, 1947-57" 297 Smith, Warren L., Associate Professor of Economics, University of Michigan, "Monetary Policy and the Structure of Markets" 493 Smithies, Arthur, Professor of Economics, Harvard University, "Price Policy and Economic Growth and Stability" 611 Stein, Herbert, Director of Research, Committee for Economic Development, "A General View of the Inflation Problem" 665 Turner, Robert C, Professor of Economics, Indiana University, "Relationship of Prices to Economic Stability and Growth: A Statement of the Problem" 671 Watkins, Myron W., Vice President, with Joel B. Dirlam, Senior Consultant, Boni, Watkins, Jason & Co., Inc., "Government Policy Toward Competition and Private Pricing" 513 f Weidenbaum, Murray L., Senior Operations Analyst, Convair Division, General Dynamics Corp., "The Effect of Government Spending Programs on Private Price Formation" 529 Wells, Oris V., Administrator, Agricultural Marketing Service, United States Department of Agriculture, "Price and Income Measures for American Agriculture" 117 Weston, J. Fred, Professor of Finance, Graduate School of Business Administration, University of California, Los Angeles, "Models of the Pricing Process" 309 Whitney, Simon N., Director, Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade Commission, "The Influence of the Antitrust Laws and Related Governmental Policies on Prices" 555 INTRODUCTION BY WRIGHT PATMAN, CHAIRMAN, JOINT ECONOMIC COMMITTEE The Employment Act of 1946 grew out of legislative debate of public and private policies which would promote "full" or "maximum" employment of the Nation's productive resources—human and material. Economic stability and growth were mainly thought of in terms of minimizing fluctuations in employment and of maximizing the growth of real output of goods and services. From its initial organization, the Joint Economic Committee, however, has been concerned also with problems of promoting stability of the general price level and the need for avoiding inflation. At a meeting of the Joint Economic Committee on July 24, 1957, there was general agreement that the -committee should explore the possibilities and problems of conducting a full-scale investigation of prices and price-making processes in relation to economic stability and growth. In accordance with my suggestion, the staff was directed to prepare a specific program for consideration by the full committee at a meeting on last October 7. At the October 7 meeting, the committee reviewed the program proposed by the staff, made several modifications and additions, and then decided to proceed with the study. PURPOSE OF PRESENT STUDY In the present project, the committee's major goal is an objective and authoritative exploration of general economic processes which involve prices, price relationships, costs, and price policies, in the expectation that this will reveal ways in which public and private policies can contribute to attainment of the Employment Act objectives: SEC. 2. The Congress declares that it is the continuing policy and responsibility of the Federal Government to use all practicable means consistent with its needs and obligations and other essential considerations of national policy, with the assistance and cooperation of industry, agriculture, labor, and State and local governments, to coordinate and utilize all its plans, functions, and resources for the purpose of creating and maintaining, in a manner calculated to foster and promote free competitive enterprise and the general welfare, conditions under which there will be afforded useful employment opportunities, including self-employment, for those able, willing, and seeking to work, and to promote maximum employment, production, and purchasing power. (15 U. S. C. 1021.) PREVIOUS AND CURRENT STUDIES The Joint Economic Committee itself has, of course, already made a number of studies in the field of prices. The first hearings ever held by the committee were on current price developments and the problem of economic stabilization, in June and July 1947. In the fall of 1947, working through regional subcommittees, members visited many parts of the country, holding hearings, gathering data, and report- XI XII INTRODUCTION ing on consumer prices. An exhaustive study of profits in 1949, and several earlier and later hearings on prices in the steel industry are also cases in point. Prices, inflation, and controls have, moreover, been recurrent topics for panel and committee discussions in connection with the committee's study of successive annual reports of the President. More recently, acting upon instructions of the committee, the staff compiled a factbook on Productivity, Prices, and Incomes, leaving interpretations and conclusions to the user of the materials. Other committees of the Congress are currently undertaking studies of prices in varying contexts. The Senate Finance Committee, during the session last year, conducted extended hearings on price inflation, and on attempts to control it through monetary and fiscal policy. The Senate Judiciary Committee's Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly has been investigating prices and pricing behavior, especially in the so-called "administered-price" area. A subcommittee of the House Agricultural Committee has been studying the closely related subject of marketing margins for farm products. PLANS FOR THIS STUDY The committee study of prices is being carried forward in four stages. This compendium or collection of research papers, designed to bring together analyses and findings of leading impartial experts and the most authoritative information available, is the first part of the program. The second part will be a series of hearings in the form of panel discussions scheduled for May 12-22. The panelists will be the contributors of the papers in this compendium in which the papers are arranged by panel topics in the order in which they are scheduled for discussion at the hearings. As the third stage of the study, the committee is inviting economists from labor and industrial organization to submit papers for a volume of comments to be published after the May hearings. These papers will concentrate on the analyses and issues raised by the experts contributing to the present compendium and participating in the May panels. The fourth stage in the program will be hearings in the form of panel discussions to be held later in the year. The panelists at that time will be the economists from labor and industry together with some of the contributors to the present compendium. ^ When the experts were invited to contribute to the present compendium they were supplied with a preliminary outline of topics and questions of interest to the committee. The outline was intended only to give the contributors some guide to the scope of the investigation into which their individual papers would fit. The relevant part of that outline is reproduced in each section of this volume directly preceding the papers for that panel. On behalf of the committee, I wish to commend the contributors for the valuable materials they have presented in these papers. Their generous gift of time and resources to the project is an outstanding public service. I am confident their contributions will be reflected in public deliberations on policies for economic stability and growth for many years to come. EMPLOYMENT ACT OBJECTIVES AND THE STABILIZATION OF PEICES / . Employment Act objectives and the stabilization of prices A. What price behavior would be consistent with the attainment of the other policy objectives of the Employment Act "of creating and maintaining, in a manner calculated to foster and promote free competitive enterprise and the general welfare, conditions under which there will be afforded useful employment opportunities, including selfemployment, for those able, willing, and seeking to work, and to promote maximum employment, production, and purchasing power" in both the short run and the long run? Under what conditions would stabilization of prices be inconsistent with attainment of Employment Act objectives ? B. What does "economic stability and growth" mean when used in reference to a dynamic private enterprise economy? C. What changes in the distribution of income and wealth usually accompany changes in the general price level, and what weight should these be given in assigning priorities among the various objectives of the Employment Act ? 1. What are the effects of price level changes upon the different income groups, especially upon the socalled "fixed-income" groups ? 2. How are holders of various types of assets affected by price level changes ? 3. How do various types of debtors—financial and nonfinancial, corporate, individual, farmers, and small-business men—fair under conditions of changing price levels ? 4. What is the effect of changing price levels on the relative position of Federal, State, and local governments, considering their traditional revenue sources, their expenditure programs, and debtor positions ? XIV THE EMPLOYMENT ACT OF 1946: THE DYNAMICS OF PUBLIC ECONOMIC POLICY Grover W. Ensley, Executive Vice President,1 National Association of Mutual Savings Banks INTRODUCTION Twelve years ago, the enactment of the Employment Act introduced into public policy the first specific statement of objectives for the national economy. The language expressing those objectives is broad: * * * creating and maintaining, in a manner calculated to foster and promote free competitive enterprise and the general welfare, conditions under which there will be afforded useful employment opportunities, including self-employment, for those able, willing, and seeking to work, and to promote maximum employment, production, and purchasing power. This broadness of language reflects the necessity for compromise among divergent viewpoints, which is the essence of our democratic political institutions. The machinery set up by the act for implementing its objectives is simple. Both the generalized statement of objectives and the simple machinery of the act have proved to be truly elegant. In the 12 years since adoption of the Employment Act, the Nation's economy has been subject to many and varying stresses and strains. On the whole, it has performed very well, indeed, in providing an increasingly prosperous life for a rapidly growing population. Making due allowance for the recessions of 1949 and 1954, the stated objectives of the act have to a very substantial extent been continuously achieved. One cannot, of course, assert that this success is the unique result of the Employment Act and its machinery, but there is little question that they have contributed very materially. One aspect of our postwar economic history, however, has caused mounting concern. This is the virtually continuous upward pressure on prices, reflected in a 59 percent increase in consumer prices, a 73 percent increase in wholesale prices, and a 60 percent increase in the implicit gross national product price deflators since 1945. Inflation, even the so-called creeping variety, is hardly a new phenomenon. The problems of maintaining a strong, stable economy associated therewith, however, appear to become increasingly trying as our Nation becomes increasingly industrialized. Stabilization of some widely accepted concept of a general price level has more and more commanded attention of those responsible for carrying out the mandates of the Employment Act. At the same time, the persistent rise in consumer prices during the past two and a half years, despite the increasing vigor with which antiinflationary public policies were pursued and the seeming abrupt1 The views expressed are the author's and do not necessarily represent those of the National Association of Mutual Savings Banks or the association's individual members. 2 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH ness with which the economy in the latter part of 1957 slid into sharp recession, has raised widespread questions concerning price-level stabilization. Is price-level stabilization an appropriate objective of the Employment Act ? Can general monetary and fiscal policies achieve such stabilization without simultaneously precluding realization of other ob j ecti ves of the act ? These questions, I believe, may be answered affirmatively if there is continuation of the alertness and flexibility in public economic policies wiiich has been demonstrated repeatedly since the Employment Act became law. In this connection the very broadness of the act's statement of objectives has been one of its major strengths. Greater specification of objectives would, in all likelihood, have unduly circumscribed economic policy, and diminished its effectiveness in contributing to achieving any of the more broadly stated objectives of the act. CHANGING PRIORITIES I N ECONOMIC POLICY OBJECTIVES In the rapidly changing condition of the postwar world, questions concerning the standards the Nation's economy should meet and the costs which may be incurred if these standards are to be met have commanded ever increasing attention. Several criteria have assumed primary importance. The objectives of the Employment Act have, as a result, come more and more to be stated in terms of achieving growth and stability of a dynamic, free, competitive, private-enterprise economy. The apparent paradox in the semantics of public economic policies warrants a brief definition of terms before coming to grips with our principal question: the interrelationship of objectives. Economic growth should be defined as an increase in the Nation's capacity to produce goods and services. A more conventional concept of economic growth is expansion of real per capita gross national product. While increases in capacity and in product are surely closely related over time, in the short run the economy may grow without an increase in total output or, conversely, total output may increase without expansion of productive capacity. I shall leave detailed discussion of these matters in the capable hands of the other contributors. Economic stability means that there is a limited range of fluctuation in the rate at which the Nation's economic capacity, human and material, is used. While stability in a growing economy, therefore, implies a constantly rising level of employment and of total production of goods and services, it does not imply any specific rate of resource utilization. All other things being equal, of course, stability at a high rate is always to be preferred over a low rate of resource use. In the present American economy, as a matter of fact, it is unlikely that the incentives for growth and dynamics would be long maintained without stabilizing resource use around a relatively high rate. "Dynamic" describes perhaps the most outstanding characteristic of our economic life: the frequency and magnitude of the changes in our tastes and preferences, in our effectively expressed demands for goods and services, and in the ways in which resources can most efficiently be combined and used to produce these goods and services. Although we need not be detained by elaboration of the sense of the phrase, "free, competitive, private enterprise," I would emphasize the importance of the word "free." Too often, restraints on freedom of enter- ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 3 prise are thought of primarily as those imposed by government, through the exercise of its regulatory, fiscal, and monetary powers. Such restraints are not to be taken lightly, but they must not be permitted to obscure the frequently more significant limitations imposed from within the private sector of the economy. While a dynamic economy need not be a growing economy nor a stable one, these three characteristics are not mutually inconsistent. Their simultaneous realization, in fact, has become the overall objective of public economic policy. This was not always the case. The Employment Act was legislated in 1945 and early 1946 in an atmosphere of uncertainty and apprehension. Economists—with few exceptions—were persuaded that the postwar era probably would be marked by reemergence of persistent unemployment and economic stagnation. These fears had their origins in the great depression of the 1930's and the failure of public and private programs to restore real prosperity. At the outbreak of World War II, there were still nearly 10 million unemployed persons in the United States. Substantial idle industrial capacity still haunted management after 10 years of virtually no expansion of plant and equipment. Here was economic stability of a universally unacceptable variety. In view of this pessimism at the close of World War II, it is hardly surprising that the Employment Act emphasized the promotion of maximum employment, production, and purchasing power, and the creating and maintaining of conditions affording useful employment opportunities for those able, willing, and seeking to work. There is no occasion for deprecating this early postwar emphasis in economic policy objectives. As of the end of the war, there was little empirical evidence to suggest the strength of accumulated consumer desires nor the facility with which they could be translated into effective demand for goods and services by virtue of the vast wartime accumulations of liquid savings. By the same token, it is difficult to see how economic analysts in 1945-46 could have determined the impact of the rapid wartime exploitation of technological advances on postwar business capital expenditure plans, or have estimated the consequences of high business liquidity for financing the realization of these plans. In short, nothing is harder for the economist to predict than the dynamics of the economy. Prewar experience hardly afforded a basis for such predictions. Emphasis in public policy on maximizing employment and production, without explicit regard for growth or dynamics in the early postwar days, therefore, is quite understandable. The great and generally unexpected burst of business and consumer demand in the early postwar years almost immediately shifted the focus of concern by those entrusted with public responsibility for achieving the objectives of the Employment Act. Widespread upward price pressures originating in excessive total demand made it clear that the stabilization problem was not the "deflationary gap" anticipated by many at the end of the war, but rather a renewal of the "inflationary gap." The first major inquiry of the Joint Economic Committee in June and July of 1947, therefore, was devoted to price developments. 23734—58 2 4 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH The recession of 1948-49 and the outbreak of hostilities in Korea in mid-1950 provided a further test of the flexibility of the Employment Act. Within this 3-year period: Gross national product (in current prices) rose $13 billion—6% percent in a year's time, fell $8.5 billion—3.2 percent in another year, and then rose nearly $50 billion—19.4 percent in the third year. Unemployment increased by nearly 90 percent between the second quarter of 1948 and the fourth quarter of 1949 and fell by 44 percent by the fourth quarter of 1950. Public policy was called upon twice in 3 years to reverse its field— and drastically so. There is widespread agreement that Federal fiscal policy, which at that time carried the major burden of economic stabilization, was on the whole well suited to meet these rapidly changing challenges. A concurrent development in determining the focus of economic policy was the emerging emphasis on economic growth, proceeding largely from increasing awareness of the responsibilities imposed upon the United States as the leader of the free world in the cold war, and of the economy's demonstrated growth tendencies. This emphasis has come to the fore in the post-Korean period and with shocking abruptness since the fall of 1957. The work of the Joint Economic Committee and its subcommittees in this area is a testimonial to their alertness to the importance of economic growth and the diligence of their efforts to bring these considerations to the attention of the Congress, the Executive, and the Nation as a whole. A NEW FRONTIER : STABILIZING THE PRICE LEVEL Without belaboring the details or effectiveness of policy changes in the postwar period, I think it is clear that experience under the Employment Act has demonstrated amply the dynamic quality of public economic policy. The recent past and our present situation suggest quite clearly the basic outlines of a major test to be faced: achieving reasonable stability in the general level of prices without sacrificing growth, stability, and the dynamic characteristics of the economy nor the institutional freedom we prize. Compatibility of public policy objectives Are these objectives inconsistent? The answer is "Yes" only if we choose to regard each objective in some absolute sense. Instead, it must be recognized that the realization of additional gains with respect to any one objective involves costs in the sense of some limitation on the extent to which gains with respect to any other can be achieved. We must, therefore, continually effect compromises among conflicting claims. This is the essence of the basic economic process in any environment in which ends exceed means. We look forward to a higher living standard tomorrow than we enjoy today and recognize that to make this gain possible some sacrifice of today's consumption of goods and services or of leisure is required. We are continually required to choose between the satisfactions derived from variety in consumption and in the ways in which we produce our incomes, on the one hand, and the losses in terms of temporary unemployment, obsolescence, and the disruption of familiar routines involved in shifting to new products and new methods of ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 5 production. We are continuously faced with the need for readjusting these priorities if our first approximations involve too great changes in the rate of use of our resources. The fact that we are, all of us, continually making these compromises demonstrates the compatibility of these objectives rather than their inconsistency. We make these decisions as individuals in the setting of what we hope is a substantially free market place. The aggregate of these decisions reflects the order of priorities accorded by the economy as a whole to various economic objectives. It is to be expected that changing circumstances will lead to changing priorities. Government, through the exercise of its monetary, fiscal, and regulatory powers, provides major conditioning factors which in turn influence our individual decisions. It is in fact virtually impossible to conceive a complex of Government economic policies which would be neutral in its impact on this system of choices. Public-policy makers, therefore, are invested with tremendous responsibility to provide policies which will facilitate, rather than frustrate, the implementation •of the choices registered in the market, without giving way to pressures from speculative excesses nor to irrational responses to minor changes in economic conditions. It also imposes a substantial burden on public instrumentalities to keep the market as free as possible from restraints on the allocation of resources. If these public responsibilities are appropriately discharged, the Nation can be confident of realizing a high rate of economic growth without unduly sacrificing stability or the dynamic characteristics of our economic life. We must avoid, however, underestimating the cost involved, lest we become too rigid in our thinking and our policy attitudes. For example, the more dynamic the economy, the greater will be the problems of maintaining stability in the rate of resource use while continuing to provide the real resources required for economic growth. The more frequent and the greater the changes in technology and in resulting market demand and supply conditions, the more frequent and the greater will be the pressure for changes in the use of resources. Such changes cannot be achieved instantaneously, but in fact may require a considerable lapse of time. The rate of frictional unemployment of both human and material resources, therefore, will tend to be higher in a relatively dynamic economy than in a static economy. An excessively rigid stabilization policy may impair economic dynamics by increasing the real costs of effecting necessary shifts in resources. Achieving a, high rate of growth in a dynamic setting, therefore, requires a flexible approach to economic stabilization. Such an approach has been aptly visualized as a band representing a range of fluctuation in unemployment through time, as contrasted with a line. How wide or narrow this band should be cannot be precisely determined, since our attitudes assuredly will change through time. It should be emphasized, however, that accepting some fluctuation in unemployment rates is perfectly consistent with the stabilization objectives implied in the Employment Act. Moreover, this acceptance does not imply a relaxation of vigilance by those responsible for economic policy. Rapid changes in the employment situation, even though they do not at the moment exceed accepted tolerances, never- 6 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH theless demand alertness to the possibility that they shortly will, and preparedness to deal promptly with an excessive fluctuation should it in fact materialize. The importance of relative price flexibility How is stability of prices related to whatever composite objective of growth, stability, and dynamics may be desired? At the outset, the distinction between stabilizing the prices of particular goods and services and stabilizing the level of prices must be emphasized. Stabilizing specific prices can hardly be justified as a public policy objective for a free-market economy except under the most extraordinary circumstances. Flexibility of prices of individual goods and services is, of course, the specific mechanism a free, privateenterprise economy uses to induce shifts in resources and in economic activity. In the absence of relative price movements, the mechanism for such shifts must be public or private rationing. Either will result in a loss in economic welfare in a private-enterprise setting. Moreover, the more dynamic we wish our economy to be, the more important is mobility of resources, and, consequently, the greater the emphasis we must place on the flexibility of individual prices. If, for whatever reason, the change in the price of a good or service for which supply or demand conditions have changed is restrained relative to the prices of other things, the extent of the shift in resources which otherwise would have occurred will also be limited. Maintaining flexibility in prices of individual goods and services,, therefore, is an important collateral objective of public policy, the responsibility for which rests primarily in the antitrust field. Since such price flexibility is, in part, a concomitant of the uncertainty inherent in a dynamic economy, the inclination of those controlling the use of resources to insulate themselves from price flexibility is readily understood. It must not be overlooked, however, that to the extent this insulation is achieved, the economy will suffer, as a necessary corollary, a loss in dynamics. Antitrust policy which fully recognizes this basic drive toward relative price rigidity and its adverse implications for the character of the Nation's economic life, therefore, is a necessary adjunct of public economic policy seeking the objectives of the Employment Act. Encouraging flexibility in individual prices is in no wise inconsistent with stability in some overall average of prices, at least conceptually. All that is required by the former is change relative to other prices. Theoretically, relative price changes can take the form of increases offset by decreases, leaving the average unchanged; by smaller increases more than offset by larger decreases, with a corresponding declining average level; by larger increases only partially, if at all, offset by smaller decreases, resulting in a rising average leveL In practice, only the latter alternative appears to have been feasible during the postwar period. Distinguishing between relative price flexibility and general price instability It is generally agreed that while relative price flexibility is necessary and desirable for our economy, price-level instabilitv must be minimized. Although conceptually the distinction here is fairly clearr in practice it is considerably more difficult to determine. Other papers ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 7 in this volume will deal with the problems, often extremely technical, of applying the concepts of price-level stability to public policy purposes. It will suffice at this point to suggest only one of the many difficulties policymakers must face. Suppose the price of some basic industrial raw material rises. The factors underlying this type of price change are more often than not extremely difficult to assess with any precision with information of the accuracy and extent now available. Yet, if price level stability is to be maintained, public policy must be based on judgments whether these factors are fairly widespread and, therefore, whether the particular price rise is to be regarded as a harbinger of general upward price pressures. Moreover, public policy must appraise the degree of substitutability for the raw material in question to determine the extent to which its price rise is likely to be reflected in other prices. The greater the substitutability and the more promptly substitution can be achieved, the less need be the concern over extension of the price movement. Public policy, therefore, must depend also on evaluation of market structure, pricing practices, resource mobility, etc., in the affected industries, since without this analysis, it cannot appraise the likely aggregate demand and supply responses with which it must deal. In practice, therefore distinguishing between desirable relative price flexibility and undesirable general price instability is now— and always has been—difficult. Granting this sort of practical difficulty does not, however, derogate price-level stability as a public policy objective. Creefing inflation and economic instability There is no occasion in this discussion for dwelling on the manifest evils of hyperinflation or hyperdeflation. The price-level movements with which public policy in the United States must be concerned are of the "inching" or "creeping" variety. This term, as generally used, may include price movements which are so pronounced as to average several percent a year. Such changes are modest, as compared with the hyperinflation of post-World War I I Hungary and China, for example. It is precisely because of the relative slowness of "creeping" inflation that it is so insidious and difficult to cope with. Over a considerable part of our postwar experience with "creeping" inflation, this type of price movement has been widely interpreted as a reflection of excessive total demand. So long as this assumption appeared to accord closely with the facts revealed by other statistical series, economic stabilization, in the sense of stabilizing the rate of total resource use, and price-level stabilization could be and were embraced as a single objective. In 1946-48 and 1950-51, for example, the need for stabilization efforts was signaled by general price movements, and public policies aimed at restricting total spending were synonymous with restriction of the rate of price-level increases. In other words, so far as anyone could see, the upward pressure on prices originated in excessive demand which also was reflected in strong tendencies toward "overemployment." Since mid-1955, however, it has become increasingly apparent that price-level stabilization and stabilization of the rate of resource use are not necessarily synonymous. Experience during the latter part of 1957 and the early part of 1958 in particular has demonstrated graphically the possibility of divergence of price-level changes from 8 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH changes in the rate of resource use. Timelags undoubtedly account for some part of this divergence. Recently there has been considerable discussion, which will be extended and refined in other papers in this compendium, of other factors which may contribute to it. My purpose in alluding to this divergence is merely to show that economic stability or instability is not necessarily the same as price-level stability or instability as was widely assumed in the past. Price-level stabilization, as an objective of public economic policy, therefore, should be examined, at least in part, on its own merits. Equity aspects of inflation The considerations which strongly support price-level stability as an objective of economic policy can be placed in the rough, but by no means mutually exclusive categories of equity and economics. The familiar equity argument is that instability in the general price level— more specifically, in terms of postwar experience, inflation—diminishes the purchasing power of individuals and business entities with fixed or "sticky" incomes and assets relative to the purchasing power of those whose incomes and assets are responsive to general price movements. Insofar as those with fixed incomes and assets are concentrated at the lower end of the income and wealth distribution or are the small or new business entities, inflation represents a regressive tax. As such, it effects changes in income and wealth distribution which are antithetical to those sought by the explicit provisions of the Nation's tax structure. My fellow panelist, Dean Bach, has directed intensive studies concerning the impact of inflation on income and wealth distribution. I shall not, therefore, attempt to cover this ground with any detailed discussion. Some economists have suggested that these equity consequences of inflation can be and have been substantially ameliorated by appropriate private and public policies. It is argued, for example, that persons retired under public retirement systems have suffered only temporarily from persistent general price increases, since these retirement systems are liberalized periodically to take account of inflation. Industrial retirement systems, it is argued, can turn more extensively to variable annuity devises to hedge the retiree against price-level fluctuations. Individuals and businesses, it is maintained, can change the disposition of their personal savings toward more price-levelsensitive assets, particularly common stocks. The answer to the first argument, of course, is that the losses suffered by the public system retiree are never made good and are, therefore, permanent. Adjusting public retirement system benefits frequently enough to reduce these losses to insignificant proportions would hardly be feasible. The answer to the other contentions is that real costs are incurred by giving up liquidity and safety in seeking inflation hedges. In the absence of such costs, the great savings institutions of this country would never have reached their present stage of development, nor should we now see the great diversity in the character and operations of financial intermediaries. It seems to me to be extremely difficult to justify asking the economically weak to incur these costs to protect themselves from inflation which is in any case regarded as inequitable. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 9 Moreover, it is at least questionable whether the personal thrift patterns which would emerge from these suggestions would contribute so well to providing for the economic growth which is one of the primary objectives of public policy. Personal savings habits dominated by inflation hedging might well result in a perverse reinforcing of cyclical movements and of inflation. Those who save to provide some relatively fixed amount for retirement, for example, might well be inclined to reduce their current savings under boom conditions if their inflation hedging were, in fact, successful, and to increase their savings during an economic decline if inflation-responsive assets were also recession responsive. I do not know what proportion of total personal savings are, in fact, motivated by some fixed total objective, but whether the proportion is large or small, it is difficult to see why we should encourage distortion of these savings patterns as a means of justifying inflation. Inflation and growth According to a widely held view, the rate of economic growth can be expected to respond favorably to mild inflation. The argument rests primarily on the assumption that costs will lag behind prices, so that profit margins rise. Rising profit margins imply a positive shift in the schedule of the marginal productivity of capital which, in turn, serves to increase investment demands. An expansion of capital outlays will be reflected in a multiple increase in total demand which adds to upward price pressures, presumably still in advance of factor costs. Thus, it is maintained, even mild inflation tends to be cumulative, largely through its effects on stimulating growth-generating expenditures. The process presumably comes to a halt when the increase in productive capacity exceeds the increase in effective demand or when factor costs close the gap with product prices and pinch off profit margins. Dean Bach's studies, upon which he reported in this committee's Tax Policy Subcommittee study of Federal tax policy for economic growth and stability, cast some serious doubts about this delineation of the relationship between inflation and growth. It seems to me that an alternative thesis suggests that inflation may impede economic growth more than stimulate it. If product and resource markets were substantially free of restraints or monopolistic elements, a system of monetary and fiscal policies which limited increases in total demand in line with increases in capacity would also provide stability in the general price level. Failure of such a system to prevent general price movements, therefore, indicates imperfections in market structures. If these imperfections are accepted or tolerated by the Nation, the relative price changes necessary to effectuate dynamic impulses in the economy must be reflected either in general price level changes, in instability in the rate of resource use, or in an otherwise undesired shift in the division of resources between growth and current consumption. Suppose that the Nation's composite choices place, as a first approximation, a higher priority on stability in the rate of resource use and on the desired rates of growth and of current consumption than on price-level stability. On what grounds may one conclude that the resulting general movement of prices is undesirable? 10 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH In the first place, inflation cannot finance the attainment of real product objectives for which real resources are inadequate. I t can serve only to change the total product "mix" by shifting effective demand in favor of successfully hedged claimants and to the disadvantage of the relatively unsuccessful. Some sacrifice of the desired rate of growth or of consumption, therefore, will necessarily result. Moreover, such shifts are likely to be difficult to anticipate or to estimate in advance of their actual occurrence. Inflation, therefore, is likely to produce what appear to be haphazard and capricious changes in income positions and in asset and liability values. These effects must serve to increase uncertainty. As a consequence they also must add to the costs of growth by requiring more extensive use of resources for hedging against the increased risks accompanying capital accumulations. Second, inflation shifts resources along the lines of least resistance, so to speak. The sacrifices of claims to resources, therefore, will fall more heavily on economic units lacking the strength of the monopoly elements which give rise to market imperfections. In other words, the weakest economic units—the new or the small business, to take familiar examples—will be required to bear a disproportionate share of the burden of financing in real terms the shift in the use of currently available resources. Failure to control a little bit of inflation, therefore, is quite likely to lead to increasing difficulty in curbing subsequent inflationary pressures. It seems clear that a relaxed policy toward inflation more greatly jeopardizes the economic position of the State or local government or school district, of the new or small business, of the prospective home buyer relying on a thin equity, to use the favorite examples of critics of general monetary controls, than does a, tight-money policy. This, I believe, is the principal basis for asserting that moderate, "inching," or "creeping" inflation always holds the promise of ever stronger inflationary movements. If, finally, after long neglect, opposition to the adverse equity, competitive, and resource-allocating consequences of inflation becomes strong enough, efforts to curb its further extension then are likely to involve more painful consequences in terms of arresting growth and sacrifices of current production and employment than would have been required if the initial modest inflation had been halted. General price level stability, therefore, must be regarded as a necessary collateral objective of public policies aimed at promoting growth and stability in a dynamic, free, private-enterprise economy. FEASIBILITY OF PRICE-LEVEL STABILIZATION AS AN EMPLOYMENT ACT OBJECTIVE Can general monetary and fiscal policies achieve price-level stability without undue sacrifice of growth and stability in the rate of resource use ? Much of the criticism of using general monetary and fiscal restraints to curb inflation depends on the assertion that some business and labor organizations can insulate their price and wage decisions from changes in total demand conditions. General restraints on demand, it therefore is maintained, will impinge only on economic entities lacking this power. Restraints sufficiently vigorous to break through the insulation of big business and big labor, the argu- ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 11 ment runs, necessarily must hold total demand to less than fullemployment levels. I must agree, as indicated above, that if, indeed, such power rests in big business and labor (it should be noted that the validity of this contention has not yet been demonstrated), the consequent limitations on relative price flexibility and resource movement will impede the successful use of general constraints against inflation. I cannot agree, however, that the existence of such power calls for abandoning the use of fiscal and monetary policy for price-level stabilization purposes, or for foregoing price-level stability as an objective of public policy, or for relying on the good faith and intelligence of private power groups to behave in a manner consistent with stability of prices generally. The proposition that the value of the Nation's money depends on the good intentions and behavior of a relatively small private group in the population must surely be abhorrent to any free society. If, in fact, the proposition is correct, it calls for constructive measures to reduce this power. Such measures also would contribute to a more dynamic economy with greater private freedom to be enterprising. Price-level stabilization, therefore, can be a practicable objective of public policy. Indeed, taking the steps required to make it so will also strengthen policies directed toward achieving a high rate of growth and stability in the rate of resource use. As in the case of these latter objectives, precise specification of the objective of price-level stability is not possible. Moreover, I doubt that it would be desirable. After all, our economic stabilization objective does not rule out some fluctuation in the rate of resource use. By the same token, as a practical matter we cannot pursue absolute rigidity in the price level. What we seek is the best possible "mix n of all of our major economic policy objectives. Our best hope for its attainment, I believe, rests in the alertness and adaptability of those charged with responsibility for public economic policy. Our public-policy instrumentalities have shown flexibility and alertness to desirable shifts in emphasis. They have not always, of course, been completely successful. We have had recessions and interruptions of growth. We well may have experienced, without recognizing it, some inhibition of the economy's dynamism. There are many expert observers of the American economy who assert that we have suffered increasing private monopolistic restraints on the freedom of resources and markets. And we assuredly have had inflation. But while we recognize these shortcomings, we should not lose sight of our accomplishments. We have not had a serious depression and we have achieved remarkable progress in raising our living standards since the war's end. I think we can be confident, therefore, that the present language of the Employment Act can continue to provide the framework for the dynamic policies the Nation's economic development demands. This study by the Joint Economic Committee, which carries forward the high standards of those of the past, will, I am sure, contribute to an extended appreciation of the significance of price-level stabilization policy in the context of the Employment Act's broad statement of objectives. EMPLOYMENT ACT OBJECTIVES AND THE STABILIZATION OF PRICES Edwin G. Nourse, Economic Consultant I believe this committee is marking a new milestone in the interpretation and application of the Employment Act by conducting this series of hearings on "The Relationship of Prices To Economic Stability and Growth." Such an inquiry is of utmost timeliness just now, as the policy set forth in the Employment Act is facing its first severe test. And great promise for the outcome of the investigation may be found in the terms in which Chairman Patman's announcement of the hearing stated its purpose—it was to be— an exploration of general economic processes which involve prices, price relationships, costs, and price policies * * * public and private [that] can contribute to * * * maximum employment, production, and purchasing power. The depth and breadth of this definition are in refreshing contrast to some of the oversimplified and overmechanistic concepts of the employment problem that are still current, THE ACT^S STATED OBJECTIVES This opening panel raises the question whether or how the stabilization of prices was included in, or related to, the objectives stated in the Employment Act. Superficial evidence of such a relationship or inclusion is lacking. Nowhere in the act can the expression "price stabilization" or "price level" or even the word "price" be found. This is probably to be explained by the fact that Public Law 304 of the 79th Congress was simply a revised version of the Murray fullemployment bill of 1945. Its specific objective was still stated in terms of jobs—"useful employment opportunities for those able, willing, and seeking to work." There were, however, three other parts of the declaration of policy (sec. 2) that demand attention. (a) The original full-employment objective was expanded to set "maximum purchasing power" alongside "maximum employment and production." Obviously, purchasing power is a price-oriented concept. (&) The declaration of policy also stated that the employment and purchasing-power objective was to be pursued "in a manner calculated to foster and promote free competitive enterprise." Freeenterprise competition takes place in the market, and its outcome is price. Here, again, price objectives are clearly embraced in the mandate of the act even though the words "price" or "price level" are not used, (c) Section 2 of the act further declares that the Federal Government's objective of "maximum employment, production, and purchasing power" is to be pursued "with the assistance and cooperation of industry, agriculture, labor, and State and local governments." I would suggest that this stipulation of assistance from and cooperation with industrial management, labor leadership, and agricultural organi13 14 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH zations has little meaning if it does not relate in the most positive and comprehensive manner to prices, wages, and the market process generally. A trend toward greater emphasis on stability as an objective of the Employment Act, due to fear of inflationary boom leading to deflationary recession, led fo an attempt near the close of the last session of the Congress to write a specific price-stabilization objective into the act. The Bush amendment declared that the previously stated objectives of maximum employment, production, and purchasing power "must be attained, if they are to be meaningful, in an economy in which the cost of living is relatively stable. To this end, the agencies and instrumentalities of the Federal Government must utilize all practicable and available means to combat inflationary pressures as they develop within the economy." In the following section, the President was instructed to include in his Economic Report "current and foreseeable trends in the price level prevailing in the economy and the steps, if any, which have been taken to stabilize the cost of living and to combat inflationary pressures existing within the economy." Finally, the amendment expanded the description of qualifications for membership on the Council of Economic Advisers. They were to be persons competent "to formulate and recommend national economic policy to promote employment, production, and purchasing power under free competitive enterprise and [the new language] in an economy of relatively stable prices." This proposed amendment died in committee, so the question still stands how the objectives as stated in the original act are being or should be interpreted. INTERPRETATION OF THE STATED OBJECTIVES To understand the part that prices play in the interpretation and application of the Employment Act, it is necessary to note a broad analytical difference among those who try to interpret usefully the objectives of the Employment Act or, more basically, the economic philosophies and experimentation of which it is a particular legislative expression. This divergence is one between rival but not mutually exclusive values held by economists and laymen. One group vigorously proclaims itself the exponent of "high-pressure economics" and ever-full (or over-full) employment (more jobs than applicants), with "pressure" to keep it so exerted through positive governmental policy and action, fiscal and monetary. Over against this interpretation of the objectives of the Employment Act are the sober but by no means complacent economists, like myself, who would not care to have the disparaging label "low-pressure economists" pinned on them but might call themselves exponents of safe-pressure stabilization with vigorous growth. We place primary emphasis on such fullness of employment as can stand on its own bottom and, thus, reflect internal stability in the market (where government has now become a major supply-and-demand factor), and believe there is such a thing as inflationary overemployment, a condition in which production is at a destabilizing maximum of inventory surplus, excess plant building, and wage-price "leapfrogging." To take this position is not to espouse the heresy of "general overproduction" but to stress the fact that misallocation of resources de- ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 15 rives from faulty price, wage, and profit adjustments. As such, it is to be attacked through specific market institutions, practices, and policies, not through the blanket devices of interest rates and tax levels, and only in emergencies through the processes of Federal spending. The "high-pressure" group stresses growth—though they are not unmindful that market instability might retard growth. Safepressure economists stress the functional balance of prices and incomes as the surest means to sustained growth in jobs, in production, and in real consumer purchasing power. Advance would be at as fast a rate as can be sustained within a competently administered market and fiscal process. Now this divergence in interpretation of the policy and responsibility of the Federal Government very evidently hinges on price issues. I have suggested above that a mandate for the price-incomeadjustment line of attack on the employment problem is clearly evident at three points in the Employment Acts' declaration of policy. Nor have these phases of the objectives statement been ignored in the 13 Economic Reports of the President which have thus far been submitted, nor in the studies of this committee. In President Truman's first report (January 1947), we read: The Congress, by setting maximum purchasing power as an objective of national policy in the Employment Act, pointed to the importance of purchasing power in keeping our economy fully employed and fully productive. * * * The rise in prices that occurred in the latter half of 1946 greatly reduced the purchasing power of the current incomes received by the large majority of people. * * * How to effect a mutual adjustment of income and prices which will provide purchasing power adequate to sustain maximum production in the years ahead thus becomes a central problem for private enterprise and Government (pp. 1, 2). [Italics added.] In this report I do not anywhere find the word inflation, though the first of several propositions in the closing summary began: Chief among the unfavorable factors is the marked decline in real purchasing power of consumers, resulting from the large price increases in the second half of last year (p. 19). Six months later, the midyear report stated: Price and income adjustments stand foremost in need of attention. * * * There is need to hold the price line in the face of recent developments which revive some fear of another upswing of inflation (p. 2). In January 1948 we read: A year ago I warned against the danger of advancing prices, which would undermine our structure of national prosperity. I strongly urged businessmen to bring prices into line with the requirements of a stabilized economy. I called upon workers to limit their demands for wage increases to those situations where wages were substandard or where wage increases would not necessitate higher prices. * * * The first objective for 1948 must be to halt the inflationary trend (PP. 3, 5). The midyear Economic Report (July 1948) clearly linked price objectives to the mandate of the Employment Act, saying: The policy proclaimed in the Employment Act requires us to devise and adopt positive measures to stop this inflation and secure relative stabilization. * * * I realize that the anti-inflation program I have offered will impede some business plans, will curb some profit opportunities, and may limit some wage advances. It is of the very essence of a plan to counteract inflation that this be done. All groups will ultimately benefit when it is done (p. 2). 16 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH In January 1949 it was noted that the general rise in prices had reached a crest in August 1948, but the Economic Report stressed the point that a— rising spiral [had] created more and more maladjustments among prices, wages,, and other incomes * * * brought higher but uneasy profits to business firms, squeezed the family budget of workers, who in turn sought to press wages upward as the cost of living advanced (pp. i, ii, 4). With a slight recession in 1949, the Economic Report of 1950 keynoted disinflationary price adjustments in recent months, and, with premature complacency, suggested that this created "the relative stability on which firm business and consumer plans can be based." * * * The relatively safe passage from inflation to greater stability was noaccident. Businessmen, workers, and farmers demonstrated much greater judgment and restraint than in earlier similar periods. * * * The effective teamwork between free enterprise and Government confounded the enemies of freedom who waited eagerly, during 1949, for the collapse of the American economy. * * * If we are to continue our economic growth, the major economic groups must all pull together—businessmen, wage earners, and farmers must work toward the same ends. Government, in turn, must carry out the aspirations of the whole people. * * * To promote an environment in which businessmen, labor, and farmers can act most effectively to achieve steady economic growth is a major task of the Government. * * * It must keep open the channelsof competition, promote free collective bargaining, and encourage expanded opportunities for private initiative. The Council at midyear 1949 did not recommend increases in public spending for the puipose of stimulating the economy, and our confidence in its internal recuperative forces has thus far proved justified (pp. 1,6, 7,103). As the Korean war renewed inflationary pressure, the President stressed the need for "increased production of the right kind of goods" and "some sacrifice of domestic consumption." His midyear (1950) Economic Report urged prompt imposition of war taxes, but stressed large dependence— upon business polices * * * fostering production along those lines which are most needed under changing circumstances. It depends upon price and income practices which maintain a balance between full output and buying power, so as toavoid either inflation or deflation. * * * Labor should continue and enlarge its contribution toward increasing productivity. Wage demands of a character which might lead to another inflationary spiral should be avoided (pp. 12-13). Stress on price and income aspects of the employment and production problem and of the importance of private business policies and market processes continued throughout the Truman administration. In the midyear 1952 Economic Report the President observed : Although the longtime rise in prices since before the start of World War I I has not prevented the great economic progress which has been made since then,, we would now be even better off if the price level had been even better held. * * * A further inflation of the price level or diminution in the valueof the dollar can and should be avoided (p. 11). He cited the recent steel strike to highlight the heavy impact of wageprice relations in a basic industry on national stability and growth. He urged that the Congress enact— new legislation which would permit the Government to maintain essential production, to be fair to both sides in the dispute, and to retain the maximum degree of free collective bargaining (p. 14). This, however, was to be emergency, not permanent, legislation. As to the controls of materials, prices, wages, and credits invoked to meet the Korean war pressure, the administration tended to rely on the ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 17 continuance of such procedures rather than to explore institutional changes that might curtail rather than contribute to the built-in inflationary bias of a full employment economy and would permit early removal of controls. The final Economic Report of the Truman administration (January 14,1953) has deservedly been much praised for its stimulating analysis of the economics of full employment. In this analysis it gave extended attention to prices processes and price policies. In an outstanding paragraph it said: Private enterprise, under our free system, bears the major responsibility for full employment. This report has already set forth the basic features of that responsibility, and how its exercise is contributing to the well-being of the American people. The role of responsible Government, while vital, is in a sensa supplemental (p. 18). In amplification of this theme, the report reasoned: Expansion cannot continue smoothly unless it is based on a sound and fair distribution of the increasing product. Our economy is built upon mass markets. Unless each important sector receives a workable share of the expanding output, the expansion will come to an end because the market demand will be lacking. Growing capacity to produce requires growing ability to buy. * * * If business and labor plan their price and wage policies to encourage the balanced expansion of production and consumption, of jobs and markets, then our economic growth can be steady. * * * We must learn more about the value of individual and group self-restraints, about the general economy and its interrelationships, and about the private price and wage policies which may contribute most to a stable and growing economy (pp. 16,17,20). Turning now to the present administration, the five Economic Reports which it has submitted have consistently sounded the theme of "reasonably full employment with a reasonably stable price level." Our economic goal— said President Eisenhower in his letter of transmittal of his first Eco-nomic Eeport— is an increasing national income, shared equitably among those who contribute. to its growth, and achieved in dollars of stable buying power. * * * Government must use its vast power to help maintain employment and purchasing power, as, well as to maintain reasonably stable prices (pp. iii, iv). More specific attention was paid to the objective of free competitive enterprise. The role of competitive markets is as basic to the proper functioning of economic order as the secret ballot is to our political democracy. Government has vital responsibility in this area, immensely complicated by large aggregations of capital under single management and large organizations of labor. Govern-, nient must, nevertheless, remain alert to the danger of monopoly, and it must continue to challenge through the antitrust laws any outcropping of monopoly power. It must practice vigilance constantly to preserve and strengthen competition (p. 5). Competition, however, was stressed primarily as a means of promoting enterprise, improving the allocation of resources, and accelerating growth, rather than as a means of regulating prices or preventing inflation. The 1955 Economic Keport repeated the belief that "Government should persist in its efforts to maintain easy entry into trade and industry, to check monopoly, and to preserve a competitive environ^ ment" (p. v.), but there was no spotting of places where monopolistic tendencies were apparent in the economy. There was a recommenda-. 18 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH tion to "strengthen the deterrent to violation of the Sherman Antitrust Act by raising substantially the maximum fine that may be imposed under the act" (p. 50). The 1956 Economic Report again paid its respects to the general principle of competitive enterprise, which the Government should strengthen "through monetary, fiscal, and housekeeping policies to promote high and rising levels of economic activity; by helping small- and medium-sized businesses overcome impediments to their expansion; and by vigorous measures for preventing monopolistic practices and combination" (p. v.). In elaborating this last point, the report pointed to the work of the National Committee To Study the Antitrust Laws and the "vigorous enforcing of those laws" by the Department of Justice and the Federal Trade Commission. The President made six recommendations for strengthening the antitrust laws governing industrial, commercial, and banking corporations, but made no reference to price policies within the law or to the possible impairment of free competitive enterprise through present institutions or practices of wage making. The 1957 Economic Report was about equally reticent. Its review of economic developments during the preceding year referred briefly to "the advance in industrial prices * * * especially after steel prices were raised following the strike settlement * * * the combination of heavy demands from the investment-goods sector of the economy, rising labor costs, and renewed advances in prices of many raw materials resulted in price increases for a broad range of semimanufactured materials, components, and supplies. And these price increases became cost increases to producers of finished goods, many of whom were also experiencing rising labor costs. * * * Wage and salary rates advanced during the year * * * average hourly earnings of production workers in manufacturing and building construction rose 6 percent and in retail trade 4 percent. While the increases in wage and salary rates were only slightly greater than those in 1955, the improvement in productivity appears to have been substantially less. * * * Total corporate profits before taxes fell from an annual rate of $45 billion the second half of 1955 to * * * $4.1 billion in the third quarter of 1956 (partly because of the steel strike)" (pp. 32-34). In his letter of transmittal, the President said: Government must strive to strengthen competitive markets and to facilitate the adjustments necessary in a dynamic economy. Even more exacting are the responsibilities of individuals and economic groups. Business managements should formulate and carry out their plans so as to contribute to steady economic growth. They must also recognize the broad public interest in the prices set on their products and services. Both management and labor should remove restrictions on the operation of competitive markets * * * and reach agreements on wages and other labor benefits that are consistent with labor-productivity prospects and with the maintenance of a stable dollar" (pp. iii-iv). There was a repetition of recommendations for further legislation to strengthen the antitrust laws but no specific comment on wagemaking institutions or practices. Finally, the Economic Report submitted just a few weeks ago "acknowledges that there is an unfavorable feature in recent economic developments. * * * Four-fifths of the increase in gross national product in 1957 was accounted for by rising prices. There are criti- ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 19 cal questions here for business and labor, as well as Government. Business managements must recognize that price increases that are unwarranted by costs, or that attempt to recapture investment outlays too quickly, not only lower the buying power of the dollar, but also may be self-defeating by causing a restriction of markets, lower output, and a narrowing of the return on capital investment. The leadership of labor must recognize that wage increases that go beyond overall productivity gains are inconsistent with stable prices, and that the resumption of economic growth can be slowed by wage increases that involve either higher prices or a further narrowing of the margin between prices and costs. Government, for its part, must use its powers to keep our economy stable and to encourage sound economic growth with reasonably stable prices" (p. v). There is in this report the familiar pledge of allegiance to the dual objectives of the Employment Act: Economic policy must "strive to limit fluctuations in the rate of overall economic growth to a relatively narrow range around a rising trend" (p. 3). This is followed by an impeccable section on "Free Competitive Enterprise." Here is the emphasis made familiar in previous Economic Reports on the efficacy of free enterprise in guiding the allocation of productive resources, but nothing about competitive adjustment of price and income structures in a day of giant corporations and unions. The report rightly says that "the authors of the Employment Act made it explicit that Government * * * should foster and promote free competitive enterprise." But does this not mean that the Congress should shape business institutions so as positively to induce price competition or minimize monopolistic price controls? History suggests that more is needed than the mere official pronouncement that "policies and practices of individuals and private groups must [sicj contribute to, not hinder, the achievment of economic growth with reasonably stable prices." EFFECTUATING THE OBJECTIVE OF FREE COMPETITIVE ENTERPRISE From examination of the language of the Employment Act (in the perspective of its legislative history) and review of its administration (in the context of contemporary economic thinking), I am led to five conclusions: 1. Both the framers of the act and those who have sought to forward its broad purpose of sustained high-level use of the Nation's productive resources have been quite aware that they must deal with a complex, interrelated process of prices and incomes. 2. There has been general recognition that there are three avenues of constructive approach to the maximum production problem: Fiscal policy, monetary policy, and market (or private price income) policy. Because of preoccupation with the current economic fad of aggregate demand as the antecedent rather than the concomitant of maximum production, there has been undue faith placed in monetary and fiscal policy as the means of attaining the ends of national growth and stability. 3. There is progressive disenchantment with monetary policy as a major means of achieving the objective of the Employment Act, both because of inherent limitations and political back-seat driving. Fis23734—58 3 20 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH cal policy is still recognized as a powerful agency of growth and stability, but one subject to similar political hazards in application. It is a basic limitation of both these types of control that they are aimed at aggregates, or the statistical artifact of a price level, rather than specific functional price and income relationships. They may aggravate rather than correct the specific and local situations where increased costs, disbursed incomes, and price realizations attain or fail to attain so good a balance as to clear the market at full capacity operation. To the extent that such balance is not attained (or approximated), the compensatory or offsetting task thrown on public action (fiscal and monetary) is increased—with resultant failure or desperate resort to authoritarian controls. 4. In lieu of such a drift toward Government control ("creeping socialism" or whatever) we have the alternative deeply rooted in our traditions—"free competitive enterprises." This has two aspects. One is the "economic statesmanship" of corporation pricemaking executives, and a like concern for the welfare of the economy on the part of wage-negotiating officials of large and strategically placed labor unions. Appeals to this important source of business efficiency and economic stability are consistently emphasized through the Economic Eeports of the President from 1947 to 1958. I believe that such appeals are not fatuous. With growing economic sophistication and clearer sense of their responsibility on the part of executives of large industrial, commercial, and labor aggregations, we may hope to move closer toward the self-sustained balance which both President Truman and President Eisenhower have repeatedly stated should be the contribution of private business. They have, I believe, been soundly advised in taking this position. 5. The greatest service this committee and the Congress can render at this juncture is to clarify the meaning of free competitive enterprise in this day of corporation and labor union giants. With the degree of concentration of economic power that has grown up at these centers and the institutional structures they now have it is quite possible for the free competitive enterprise of their leaders to work against rather than for the stabilizing of the economy in a strong growth trend. We need to reestablish conditions of price competition instead of power competition. A full employment economy needs flexibility of its price and income structure to displace the built-in rigidities and ever-widening institution of "escalation," whether of farm-price supports, union contracts, cost-plus procurement, variable annuity insurance, Government pay scales, and even proposed fixedincome bonds. Ten years ago the Economic Eeport of the President said: The policy proclaimed in the Employment Act requires us to devise and adopt positive measures to stop this inflation and secure relative stabilization. That responsibility has not been diligently carried out in the intervening years. Instead, we have followed the easier but dangerous course of accepting what in 19511 called "inflation as a way of life." The present administration, as noted above, has instituted two inquiries into the field of monopoly, and at least three committees of the Congress have been conducting hearings on various phases of the matter. But there has been no comprehensive attempt to relate these specific inquiries to the central purpose of the Employment Act. They ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 21 have been lacking in comprehensiveness also in that none has faced forthrightly the inseparability of price, wage, and profit structures in a free-market economy. In my opening testimony before the Kefauver Subcommittee on Antitrust and Monopoly, I was moved to suggest that "the processes of pricemaking and of wage making are so intertwined in the modern industrial world that neither can be effectively analyzed in isolation from the other. I believe also that the phenomenon known as monopolistic competition or as administered pricing manifests itself in essentially similar ways and with essentially similar consequences in the two cases." There are places in the program of the present hearings at which it would seem that the pricing of labor and its relation to full employment would naturally enter the discussion, but the word "wages" is nowhere used. I anticipate that this gap will in some measure be filled by several of the contributors to the compendium and that the panel discussions as they unfold will not only broaden and deepen our understanding of the nature of free competitive enterprise as an objective of the Employment Act in an age of large-scale technology but will also point to specific measures for buttressing the old faith and giving it modern implementation. PRICE-LEVEL STABILITY AND EMPLOYMENT ACT OBJECTIVES Joseph Aschheim, The Johns Hopkins University INTRODUCTION The postwar period has been marked by a curious asymmetry between widespread economic opinion on the one hand, and official economic policy objectives on the other. Few issues have attracted wider or more recurrent attention over the last dozen years than the problem of full employment versus price-level stability. Yet our basic guide to national economic policy, i. e.? the United States Employment Act of 1946, has remained devoid of any reference to pricelevel stability or to some other desired price-level behavior. One does not have to look far afield for reasons underlying this chasm between public discussion and congressional legislation. The Employment Act came into existence at a time when recollections of the severest depression in the history of the American economy were all too vivid. No less important, the Employment Act was born under the bad omen of the famous, by now infamous, forecasts of substantial unemployment to follow the war. Thus the act bears the unmistakable imprint of the predominant economic views in the context of which it was formulated. The Joint Economic Committee's repeated concern with the relationship of prices to economic stability and growth is but another illustration of the extent to which actual developments over the last 12 years have belied the gloomy expectations reflected in the Employment Act. Under certain conditions, the continued exclusion of a price-stability objective from the Employment Act could be quite appropriate. These conditions include (a) the presence of empirical evidence pointing to a serious conflict between price-level stability and present Employment Act objectives, and (5) the existence of a cogent basis for the claim that it would be more desirable to forego price-level stability than drastically to compromise present Employment Act objectives. Accordingly, we shall first consider the extent of likely conflict between price-level stability and the goals of "maximum employment, production, and purchasing power." In the light of this discussion, we shall subsequently appraise the desirability of adding to the Employment Act the objective of price-level stability. ARE FULL EMPLOYMENT AND PRICE-LEVEL STABILITY COMPATIBLE? There are two facets to the question of the extent of conflict between price-level stability and maximum or full employment in the contemporary American economy: (1) The volume of unemployment which would be required for price-level stability; and (2) the degree of inflationary pressure which a state of maximum or full employment will produce. Let us take up these two subjects in turn. 23 24 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH A. Volvme of unemployment The postwar notion of a Hobson's choice between price-level stability and full employment is no more an accident than the fact that the Employment Act itself reflects no trace of this notion. With the money wage level rising faster than output per man-hour, with the rapidity of adaptation of product prices to higher costs, with the growing importance of wage leadership in the industrial sector of the economy, and with the trade-union movement comprising approximately one-fourth of the civilian labor force, it is hardly surprising to encounter the view that the market structure of the American economy may involve substantial unemployment as a prerequisite for price-level stability. Thus, only a few years separate the pessimistic forecasts of mass unemployment in the immediate postwar period from the almost equally disturbing predictions that future price-level stability would require from 10 to 15 percent of the civilian labor force 1 to be unemployed. Have the latter estimates proven to be more accurate than the former? Does postwar experience to date bear out the expectation that price-level stability will necessitate heavy unemployment ? While the postwar economy has thus far been spared the test of 10 to 15 percent unemployed, we do not entirely lack other relevant evidence as to whether such mass unemployment is prerequisite for price-level stability. The experience of the first two postwar recessions, as indicated by the data in table I, is quite suggestive. During 1949 unemployment averaged 5.5 percent of the civilian labor force. Between December 1948 and December 1949, average hourly earnings of production workers in manufacturing industries rose by 0.6 percent when taken inclusive of overtime or by 0.7 percent when taken exclusive of overtime. Between2 the same 2 dates, the Consumer Price Index declined by 1.9 percent and the wholesale price index fell by 5.0 percent. Manifestly, however one may characterize the behavior of money wage rates during that period, they did not prevent the price level from falling. TABLE I.—Price and wage levels for selected months and years December of year— 1948 1949 1953 1954 Consumer Wholesale price index price index (1947-49=100) (1947-49=100) 103.0 101.0 114.9 114.3 104.4 99.2 110.1 109.5 Average hourly earnings of production workers in manufacturing industries Gross $1,400 1.408 1.80 1.83 Excluding overtime $1,358 1.368 1.74 1.77 Source: for consumer price index: Survey of Current Business, April 1953, p. 23, and Economic Indicators, March 1955, p . 3: for wholesale price index: Survey of Current Business, March 1952, p. 22, and Economic Indicators, March 1955, p. 4; for hourly earnings: Monthly Labor Review, February 1950, p . 234, loc. cit., February 1951, p . 241, Employment and Earnings, May 1954, p . 38, and loc. cit., May 1955, p . 38. Turning to the second postwar recession, during 1954 unemployment averaged 5.0 percent of the civilian labor force. Between *Cf. A. P. Lerner, Economics of Employment (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1951), pp. 193194 ; and A. G. Hart, Money, Debt, and Economic Activity, 2d edition (New York : PrenticeHall, 1953), pp. 247-248. a It is noteworthy that not only the food component of the Consumer Price Index declined but also the apparel and the house furnishings components. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 25 December 1953 and December 1954, average hourly earnings of production workers in manufacturing industries, whether taken inclusive or exclusive of overtime, rose by 1.7 percent. Between the same two dates both the consumer3 price index and the wholesale price index declined by 0.5 percent. Here, too, however one may depict it, the behavior of money wage rates did not prevent a decline in the price level. It seems reasonable to conclude that the minimal volume of unemployment necessary for price level stability is much closer to 5 percent of the civilian labor force than to 10 percent, let alone anything higher. In any event, there exists no empirical basis to date for the contention that unemployment of massive proportions is a prerequisite for price level stability in the postwar market structure of the American economy. This contention is an outcome of the failure to distinguish between a state of high-level employment amid an excess of aggregate monetary demand, such as characterized the years 1945-48, and a state of high-level employment in the absence of an excess of demand. Since the demand for productive factors derives from the demand for output, an excess of aggregate monetary demand is likely to imply an excess of demand for labor. And, indeed, an excess of demand for labor was imminent in the general inflationary conditions of 1945-48. To infer from the behavior of prices and money wages in that context of inflationary demand to a future state of high-level employment in the absence of an excess of aggregate monetary demand was a procedure bound to lead to serious exaggerations. For under general inflationary-demand conditions, there would be grounds for expecting the money wage level to rise in excess of the average increase in output even in largely unorganized labor markets; the substantial increase in money wage rates immediately following World War I is a case in point. Thus to expect labor organizations to restrict their demands for higher money wage rates to the average increase in output per manhour when the pursuit of such a course would imply constant or even reduced real wage rates is to engage in economic fantasies. Amid inflationary demand conditions, the bargaining power of wage earners is at its maximum. In such a context, employers have both the incentive and the ability to translate higher labor costs into higher product prices. In consequence, no exhortations to either labor or management or both to moderate their wage-price policies will stem the tide of inflation in the face of a general excess of aggregate monetary demand. At best, such exhortations are tantamount to locking the barn door after the horse has been stolen; at worst, they deflect from the obligation of government to avert or counteract inflationary demand conditions by means of monetary-fiscal policy. B. Extent of inflation We may now turn to the second facet of the problem of pricelevel stability versus full employment, viz, the degree of inflationary pressure likely to occur under full employment conditions. Obviously, the prediction that the inflationary outcome implicit in a full employment economy may go so far as to disrupt capitalism 4 must involve a 3 Again, there was a decline not only in the food component of the consumer price index but also in the apparel, the transportation, the reading and recreation, and the other goods and services components. 4 Cf. C. E. Lindblom, Union and Capitalism (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1949), p. 139. 26 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH high estimate of the inflationary bias envisioned. Is such an ominous estimate corroborated by the postwar record ? The answer to this question depends not only upon a scrutiny of empirical data but also upon the meaning attributed to the concept of full employment. We shall briefly consider only three out of a spate of possible interpretations of "full employment." First, let us take up the well-known definition provided by Lord Beveridge that full employment is "having always more vacant jobb than unemployed men." Clearly, this definition connotes an excess of demand for labor. And since the demand for labor is derived from the demand for output, the Beveridge definition implies an excess of aggregate monetary demand. Now, as previously noted, we have no reason to doubt that inflationary demand conditions will involve a rise of the money-wage level in excess of the average increase in productivity. Thus, if full employment is taken to mean an excess of demand for labor, full employment and price-level stability are by definition incompatible. And the degre of upward bias in the price level that is implied by such a definition of full employment will vary with the magnitude of the inflationary pressures extant. For example, under the immediate postwar conditions of pent-up demand and excess liquidity, the 1947 monthly average of the Consumers Price Index rose by 14.5 percent above the monthly average for the previous year. In contrast, amid the much milder inflationary demand conditions of more recent years, the 1956 monthly average of the Consumer Price Index was 1.5 percent above the preceding year's level. Strict adherence to the Beveridge definition of full employment is coterminous with the doctrine of "full employment at any price" or more accurately, with "full employment at any price level." The proponents of direct controls will be quick to suggest that this is not necessarily so; with wage and price controls, they will aver, full employment and price-level stability could be rendered compatible. We cannot digress here to discuss the dubious character of this assertion. Suffice it to note that the Beveridge definition of full employment implies a chronic state of open or repressed inflation. Next we may turn to the definition according to which full employment is the maximum level of employment consistent with price-level stability. In this instance, the constraint of a stable price level is built into the definition of full employment; full employment and price-level stability are by definition mutually consistent. The finding that the volume of unemployment necessary for pricelevel stability is of the order of 5 percent of the civilian labor force may suggest to some that the foregoing definition of full employment is socially acceptable. On the other hand, it should not be overlooked that 1949 and 1954 were years of recession, as reflected by the data in table II. Measured in current dollars, 1949 gross national product remained at the level of 1948, and 1954 gross national product was 0.7 percent below the level of 1953; measured in constant dollars the decline for 1949 was 1.0 percent, and for 1954, 1.5 percent. We shall presently revert to the significance of these declines. 27 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE II.—Gross national product and private domestic investment for selected years Gross naGross national prodtional prod- uct (billions uct (millions of 1947 dolof dollars) lars) Year 1948 1949 1953 1954 . 257,325 257,301 3f3,218 360,654 Gross private domestic investment (millions of dollars) Capital consumption allowances (millions of dollars) 41,176 32,549 50,325 48,032 16,494 18,431 26,486 28,760 243.9 241.5 305.3 300.8 Net private domestic investment (millions of dollars) 24,682 14,118 23,839 19,272 Source: Survey of Current Business, July 1956, pp. 10-13. 24-25. Finally, full employment may be defined as the highest possible level of employment without an excess of aggregate monetary demand. In principle, adherence to this definition would be consistent with averting or counteracting inflationary pressures from the demand side whilst acquiescing in inflationary pressures from the cost side. In practice, this definition would be favored by those who would tolerate a gradually rising price level on the assumption that the upward movement can be kept gradual indefinitely. Thus our brief survey of some possible interpretations of full employment indicates that even a rough estimate of the extent of inflationary bias inherent in a condition of full employment will partly depend on what this condition is taken to mean. At the same time it must be noted that the difference in the employment levels implied by the various definitions is, in reality, likely to be relatively small. We must, in any case, expect seasonal unemployment plus "turnover" unemployment (persons moving, for whatever reason, from one job to another) to amount to at least 2.5 percent in the peacetime American economy. Consequently, even the Beveridge definition of full employment encompasses a 2.5-percent unemployment margin. At the other end, the definition of full employment which incorporates the price-stability constraint does not appear likely to entail considerably more than a 5-percent unemployment margin. Even the latter figure could hardly be viewed as awesome by past historical standards. Yet, it does imply some sacrifice of gross national product, and, more important, a relatively larger sacrifice of private investment. The slight decline in gross national product during the 1949 and 1954 recessions has already been mentioned. Much more pronounced was the drop in net private domestic investment (as shown in table II) : in 1949 it was a decline of 42.8 percent from the 1948 level, and in 1954 it was a decrease of 19.2 percent from the 1953 level. Private investment is crucial to the expansion of the American economy's productive capacity. In an international context in which we should hardly want to compromise our economy's growth potential, acceptance of a 5-percent unemployment margin for the sake of pricelevel stability is, to say the least, a questionable approach. This is not to suggest that it would be desirable to insert a maximum-tolerableunemployment figure into the Employment Act. The Employment Act sets forth general targets rather than detailed commitments; it conveys broad directions rather than specific limits. In implementation, at any rate, "maximum employment, production, and purchasing power" have been interpreted as referring to a zone rather than to a 28 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH level. And this is as it should be in an economy in which forecasting tools are still imperfect and in which some flexibility in the use of economic-policy instruments may be desired at all times. I am suggesting, however, that it would be an error to follow a path to pricelevel stability that would also lead to chronic underutilization of the economy's potential for expansion and growth. CAN WE AFFORD GOVERNMENT ACQUIESCENCE I N MILD INFLATION? Where, then, are we left in the matter of price-level stability as a possible additional objective to be specified in the Employment Act? Are we to conclude that a gradually rising price level must be accepted as a deleterious but inevitable byproduct of a state of highlevel employment and uninterrupted economic growth? Is there no practicable alternative to creeping or galloping inflation in the Age of Outer Space? A. Some common observations While high levels of production and employment have obtained since the end of World War I I , the purchasing power of the consumer's dollar has undergone a substantial decline. These concurrent developments have given rise to the view that the Federal Government is more reluctant to check inflation than to counteract the recession. Admittedly, the possible imminence of a recession evokes calls for governmental action from all sides. By contrast, the prospect of a rise in prices is a much less potent factor of organized demands for governmental intervention. Application of restrictive monetary and fiscal measures is likely to elicit vigorous opposition from various groups, whereas the pursuit of expansionary policies is agreeable to most. In general, precipitating a recession appears a more hazardous course than erring on the side of inflation. Furthermore, the existence of a large and widely distributed national debt and the necessity of recurrent refunding operations induce the Treasury to favor low interest rates. And the Federal Reserve, even with the "accord," can hardly be oblivious to the implications of a significantly restrictive monetary policy for Government and private security markets. The upshot is that the Federal Government is commonly regarded as inclined to acquiesce in an inflationary trend over the foreseeable future just as it apparently has over the recent past. B. Adequacy of Government services I submit that the conclusion that a gradually rising price level is the Government's "easy way out" is basically defective. I do so not only on the grounds that it may eventually prove impossible to prevent a gradual rise in the price level from becoming rapid or that a persistent erosion of the purchasing power of the consumer's dollar has inequitable redistributive effects. Rather, I suggest that from the viewpoint of government—National, State, and local—the most adverse effect of a gradually rising price level is the concomitant deterioration in the quality of Government services. In times of high-level employment—when the Government labors under severe budgetary constraints, under powerful pressures against raising already high tax levels, and under pronounced unwillingness among policymakers to add further to existing inflationary pressures—a gradually rising price level ceases to be "the easy way out" ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 29 and becomes "the dangerous way out." Being unable to raise salaries in competition with the private sector without substantial timelags, Government agencies are, in effect, compelled to lower their standards in hiring additional and replacement personnel. In like mannerr being unable to obtain increased appropriations for expansion of essential physical facilities in the face of rising costs, Government must of ttimes resort to elimination or curtailment of such expansion programs, in this instance, too, at the expense of the quality of the services being rendered. Thus, the stickiness of salary levels of teachers, scientists, military personnel, Foreign Service personnel, statisticians, accountants, and other Government employees, as well as the sluggishness in the upward adjustment of expenditures for school construction, new hospitals, improved civil-defense facilities, additional public libraries, more adequate statistical information, and a variety of other projects result in reduced quality and curtailed efficiency of vitally important services which are wholly or partly the responsibility of Government. In a period of acute international challenge, no person or institution could have a greater stake in preserving price-level stability than Government itself. The time has come to remove the existing asymmetry between the Employment Act and the increasing awareness of the hazards of inflation by incorporating into the act the additional objective of pricelevel stability. This change will constitute explicit affirmation of the Federal Government's heightened concern for the maintenance of relatively stable price level amid the mounting needs for expansion of Government activities in several directions. C. Some possible objections Various objections may be raised against the inclusion of a pricestability goal in the Employment Act. First, it has been argued that the objective of price-level stability is, in any case, implicit in the present formulation of the act, which includes mention of "essential considerations of national policy" and "general welfare." But this argument is rather specious; consistent adherence to it would obviate the need for mention of the already stated objectives of "maximum employment, production, and purchasing power," since these may be considered as no less implicit in "general welfare" than price-level stability. Furthermore, to state an important implication explicitly would contribute to the clarity of the act by removing reasons for doubting whether the particular implication was intended or not. Second, and with more justification, it may be contended that the concept of price-level stability is too vague and, therefore, open to interpretations too different to constitute a meaningful objective for national economic policy. It is undeniable that different types of price indexes exist and that their behavior is far from uniform. Thus, the wholesale price index is more sensitive to changes in business conditions than the consumer price index, whilst the latter is closer to an average measure of the economy's final products. Moreover, there are times of divergent movements of the two indexes. In addition, the description "relative" or "reasonable" price-level stability would not indicate the precise extent of upward or downward deviation of the price level that is to be deemed tolerable. In response to the foregoing points, it should be noted that a concept such as "maximum employment" is also subject to different interpretations and yet has not proven to be a source of much confusion in policy formulation or execution. 30 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Indeed, explicit reference to a relatively stable price level would elucidate the meaning of the act by specifying that the stated objectives of "maximum employment, production and purchasing power" are not to be interpreted as condoning a chronic inflation. Third, it may be held that the Federal Government should not assume responsibility for reasonable price-level stability when its ability to achieve this objective may depend on the activities of private groups beyond its direct control in a free-enterprise system. This view is based on the assumption that while Government can control a demandinduced inflation, it lacks the capacity for coping with a cost-induced inflation. However, this assumption is erroneous. An important prerequisite for cost-induced inflation is a monetary policy which validates upward price-level pressure from the cost side by permitting an expansion of the reserve base of the economy's money supply. The fulfillment of this prerequisite is not an act of God, but the expression of discretionary decision making by the monetary authorities. It follows that the occurrence of a cost-induced inflation cannot properly be viewed as a development with respect to which Government is without influence in a free-enterprise economy. Finally, it may be objected that inserting a price-stability goal into the Employment Act would create a dilemma as to which of the goals—maximum employment or price stability—is to be given preference in case it should be impossible to achieve both at the same time. However, as we have pointed out, there is no basis in postwar experience to date for assuming the existence of a serious conflict between full employment and price-level stability, unless full employment is defined as coterminous with an excess of aggregate monetary demand. Furthermore, to set aside a desirable policy objective only because its attainment currently appears as a difficult challenge is a counsel of despair. The present absence of a price-stability goal from the Employment Act is a gap attributable to the historical accident of erroneous forecasting toward the end of World War I I . Whether this gap would be worth perpetuating under normal peacetime conditions is a question which need not be settled here and now. Confronting us are not normal peacetime conditions, but the exigencies of intense international competition in the scientific, technological, military, and economic fields. Meeting this competition is likely to require considerable increase in the extent and quality of Government services in the years ahead. Under such circumstances, the addition of a pricestability objective to the Employment Act is both timely and imperative. CONCLUDING REMARKS (1) We have examined the extent of conflict between price-level stability and present Employment Act objectives in the light of postwar evidence. We have found that price-level stability appears unlikely to require unemployment in excess of 5 percent of the civilian labor force. While much more moderate than some other estimates, a 5-percent unemployment margin is apt to entail a significant sacrifice in terms of net private domestic investment. (2) We have suggested that perhaps the most serious drawback of chronic gradual inflation is a concomitant deterioration in the quality of Government services. Amid the need for improvement and expan- ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 31 sion of various governmental activities, future Government acquiescence in a slowly rising price level is undesirable. (3) In view of the foregoing, we have recommended that the objective of a relatively stable price level be incorporated into the Employment Act. Failure to make this change in the act would be tantamount to impicit admission that the Federal Government is prepared to permit continual, if creeping, inflation. HOW IMPORTANT IS PRICE STABILITY IN STABLE ECONOMIC GROWTH? G. L. Bach, Carnegie Institute of Technology My task is to examine the impact of inflation on the functioning of a private enterprise economy, and to consider the significance of these findings for governmental policy aimed at promoting stable economic growth. In particular, should the objective of maintaining a roughly stable price level be specifically included in the Employment Act of 1946 ? In the first major section below, I shall analyze the impact of moderate (or "creeping") inflation on an economy like ours, drawing both on recent experience and on economic theory. Then I shall consider specifically the question of how important the goal of price level stabilization should be, on the basis of these findings, within the broad framework of our attempt to maintain a pattern of stable economic growth. Briefly, my conclusions are these. The effects of moderate inflation on a private enterprise economy, while much less disruptive and alarming than often claimed, are appreciable and inequitable. Moreover, such inflation provides few, if any, of the stimulative benefits often claimed for it. Persistent inflation in the United States (outside of war periods) will probably occur only as the result of combined income pressures of major economic groups and resulting expansive monetary-fiscal policy by the Government. The resulting inflation would probably nave appreciable disadvantages with few advantages. It is, therefore, important for the Government to emphasize specifically that price level stability is one important goal among the several specified by the Employment Act tor economic policy directed toward maintaining stable economic growth in a free society—and to recognize the correlative role of monetary stability in its policy behavior. This section analyzes the effects of moderate inflation on a modern private enterprise economy, like the United States. By inflation I shall mean simply a rise in the commodity price level, or (what is the same thing) a fall1 in the purchasing power of the monetary unit over commodities. This simple definition considers any rise in the price index used as inflation; a little price rise is a little inflation, and a big price rise is big inflation. It includes price rises when less than full employment exists, because this may be part of the situation we wish to consider. It does not look behind the inflation to see its 1 The Bureau of Labor Statistics indexes of consumer prices or wholesale prices can be used to measure changes in the price level, though in principle a broader based commodity price index would be better. 33 34 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH cause, though I shall argue later that some causes are much more likely than others. My analysis covers only relatively moderate ("creeping") inflation, comparable to that experienced in the United States over the last two decades. It specifically does not include massive runaway inflations like those suffered in central Europe and Asia after World Wars I and II. The economfc effects of inflation may be conveniently analyzed here by asking what the effects of inflation are on (a) society's total real output (real gross national product); (i) the distribution of that real output among economic groups; and (c) the distribution of ownership of society's wealth. My analysis, considering only moderate inflation, suggests tentatively that: 1. There is little evidence that relatively mild inflation reduces the current real output of society, though relatively sharp speculative inflation probably does help induce an ensuing price collapse and recession. 2. Neither is there much evidence that relatively mild inflation significantly stimulates current real output, although strong total demand (of which rising prices may be one side effect) helps to stimulate output, especially in periods of substantial underemployment. 3. There is no clear evidence that moderate inflation either increases or decreases the rate of economic growth, although again strong total demand may speed economic growth in an economy that would otherwise be underemployed. 4. The impact of relatively mild inflation in redistributing current income among major economic groups is apparently less than is often claimed. To a considerable extent, major economic groups seem to have adjusted their effective income claims upward at roughly comparable rates in the last two decades of inflation, although the share of wages and salaries in the national income has increased substantially. The income shares of "passive" economic groups who do not sell directly in the market (retired people, employees of government and eleemosynary institutions, and so on) apparently lost most. Within the major economic groups, individuals and subgroups were affected very diversely. 5. Inflation's effect in redistributing control over wealth is substantial over the past two decades. More than half a trillion dollars of purchasing power of creditors was wiped out by inflation. 6. In transferring purchasing power from net creditors to net debtors, inflation in the modern American economy transfers purchasing power mainly from the "household" sector (which is a heavy net creditor in spite of its substantial debts) to governments (which are heavy net debtors). But governments are only intermediate organizations. When they gain as debtors, part of this gain accrues to taxpayers, but much of it (so far as the Federal Government is concerned) is in effect dispersed throughout the economy to all spenders, who gain at the expense of savers in government securities and currency. 7. Nearly all major groups of households are net creditors, and they therefore suffer on this account from inflation. Only very poor families and young people just establishing households (25-34 age group) are net debtors on balance. Conversely, older families and ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 35 high income, wealthy families are heavy net creditors, especially susceptible to loss from inflation. 8. Businesses (corporate plus unincorporated) have seen their relative share of the national income decline slightly under moderate inflation, on the basis of reported profits. In spite of corporations' position as moderate net debtors on balance, rapidly rising wage and other costs have offset, or more than offset, this factor. Moreover, real equity of stockholders in corporations has grown less than reported figures indicate; since depreciation and cost of goods sold are generally underreported in inflation periods, reported profits are larger than they would be if calculated on a replacement cost basis. The evidence for these tentative conclusions is drawn primarily from the experience of the American economy of the past two decades, supplemented by experience abroad and in earlier periods. These historical observations have been supplemented by economic theory, since information on the past never provides a really satisfactory basis for prediction of the future. We can never be sure in the complex interplay of forces just what observed effects in the past were actually caused by inflation; even though some changes occurred with or just following inflation, we cannot know that other third forces were not the causes. Moreover, even if we could identify cause and effect precisely in the past, we can never be sure that the future will be like the past. The following paragraphs indicate generally the kinds of evidence on which the various conclusions rest.2 1, Does inflation reduce current real output? During the past two decades of inflation in America, total real output has risen persistently. This has also been generally true in earlier periods here, and abroad. And there is little a priori reason to suppose that moderate inflation reduces the size of current national output. The common belief that inflation disrupts the economy so as to reduce total output traces back in America largely to the massive hyperinflations of central Europe following World War I, when currency became worthless and the diversion of energy from normal productive work to speculation and rapid expending of funds became a vast drag on the production of real goods and services. Even in milder inflations, it is often argued that erratically rising prices seriously disrupt economic planning and managerial decisionmaking in particular. There is no convicincing evidence on the importance of this effect in the American economy. Since the economy has grown rapidly and relatively stably over the past two decades of intermittent inflation, the disruptive effect on managerial decisionmaking can hardly have been overwhelming. The fact that total real output has increased about fourfold in the past 20 years while prices doubled does not, of course, prove that inflation has not exerted a downward pressure on total output that was persistently overcome by other expansive forces. But the facts of history do indicate that if this was the case, the output-depressive effect of inflation was a relatively weak one. 2 A more complete analysis, underlying this summary, is presented in G. L. Bach, Inflation • A Study in Economics, Ethics, and Politics (Brown University Press, 1958), especially ch. I. Some earlier data and conclusions, on which the present findings partially rest were presented to this committee, The Impact of Moderate Inflation on Incomes and Assets of Economic Groups, in Federal Tax Policy for Economic Growth and Stability (Joint Economic Committee, 84th Cong., 1st sess.). 23754—58 4 36 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH But a short-run depressive effect may result when sharp speculation-based inflation contributes to an ensuing price collapse and recession in employment and output. This can happen. The postWorld War I price inflation and collapse of 1920 is a clear case in point. But even quite rapid persistent inflations have continued over long periods without ensuing collapse and depression. This has, of course, been true in the United States for the past two decades. It has been true in Brazil, for example, which has had substantially continuous inflation averaging over 10 percent per annum for the past two decades while total real output has grown persistently. In the United Kingdom and most of western Europe, more or less continuous inflation over the same period has been paralleled by a generally persistent growth in real national output. It is clear that inflation does not necessarily presage collapse and unemployment just around the corner—certainly not around a very nearby corner—unless the inflation reaches a rapid rate. 2. Does inflation increase current real output? Moderately rising prices have generally been accompanied by rising total output. On the other hand, total output has also risen in periods of stable prices—for example, the period of the 1920's in the United States. Historical evidence alone, therefore, does not indicate satisfactorily whether inflation increases current real output. There is little doubt, on theoretical and empirical grounds, that rising total demand (spending) exerts an expansive force on total output, especially in periods of widespread unemployment of resources. Eising prices may be a side effect of this situation. Thus it is difficult to dissociate what is due to increased total demand and what to rising prices per se. The main arguments that inflation increases current output have been: (a) that inflation induces lagging income groups to work harder and longer; (&) that by pushing up prices faster than costs (especially wages), it increases profits and thereby stimulates investment and output; (c) by stimulating buying and output now, expectation of continued inflation puts a premium on early purchases; and (d) by easing the transfer of resources from declining to expanding industries, inflation helps increase total output. It is agreed that inflation can increase current output greatly only when substantial unemployment exists; only (a) is apt to be important in periods of substantially full employment. (a) Casual observation turns up numerous cases where inflation has driven lagging income groups to work more and harder in order to protect their real incomes—retired men driven back to part-time work, wives of college professors working to supplement their husbands' lagging salaries, schoolteachers driving taxis or working in industry during summer vacations—but it is doubtful that this effect is a major one in creeping inflation. Two factors are critical: How far behind prices do incomes lag, and how important are the lagging income groups in the economy? Recent evidence suggests that in America the major income groups have generally adjusted their income claims upward roughly in proportion to rising prices so money incomes have not lagged far behind prices for most groups. Moreover, those with the most significantly lagging incomes—retired persons and employees of governments and eleemosynary institutions—are neither large in the total potential productive power of the economy ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 37 nor in a position readily to increase greatly the total amount of work in the national output. The labor force has shown no significant tendency to grow during inflation as a percentage of the total population of labor force age, except during the war period when factors other than inflation primarily explain this change. And while the proportion of women holding jobs has risen steadily over the past quarter century, outside the war period there is no significant relationship between the rate of increase and the rate of inflation On the other hand, the recent increase in "moonlighting"—holding a second job— may be partially a result of inflation. (b) The main argument that inflation stimulates current output has been that it increases profits as wages (and other costs) lag behind rising prices, and this in turn induces more investment and output. This wage lag has indeed apparently played a major role in many past inflations. But, as the evidence presented below clearly indicates, wages have not lagged behind prices in the American inflation of the past two decades. During the demand-pull inflation spurts of 194648 and 1950-51, profits temporarily rose faster than wages, but this situation was reversed immediately thereafter. And in the 1955-58 surge of prices, the wage share grew markedly relative to profits. Thus overall wage costs have risen somewhat more rapidly than selling prices with the result that profits have been squeezed. Indeed, wages throughout the western industrialized world seem to be increasingly mobile upward, in many instances linked to rising prices through built-in escalator clauses. Perhaps this situation will change—and clearly a wage lag would be more likely in an underemployed economy—but potent economic and political pressures suggest that the wage lag is likely to be gone for a long time to come. Some other costs may lag in inflation, even though wages do not. Interest charges, rents, many salaries, and other costs are temporarily fixed in dollar terms as selling prices of products rise. But these lags can easily be overcome by only a modest wage lead. A special argument is advanced on the lag of interest costs, that this stimulates borrowing for real investment because the borrowed funds can be paid back in cheaper dollars. This sounds reasonable, but few corporate officials report this as a major consideration in capital-goods planning. Inflation does lead to substantial overstatement of profits under prevailing accounting practices, because depreciation and inventory replacement costs are understated, and this overstatement of profits may induce businesses to invest and produce more than they otherwise would. Partial estimates suggest that this understatement of replacement costs may have approached one-third of corporate reported profits during the decade of the 1940's.3 While most businessmen surely recognize the phantom nature of part of their profits in inflation, it may be that large accounting profits stimulate them to increase output and investment spending beyond that which would be induced by the "real" profit figures. If this force is important, it is surely more so for investment than for total current output, however. 8 See Ralph C. Jones, Price Level Changes and Financial Statements: Case Studies of Four Companies, and Effects of Price Level Changes on Business Income, Capital, and Taxes (American Accounting Association, 1955 and 1956, respectively) ; and George Terborgh, Corporate Profits in the Decade 1947-56 (Washington, Machinery and Allied Products Institute, 1957). 38 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH (c) Expectation of continuing inflation may lead to increased current real output, especially in an underemployment situation, by stimulating buying ahead for inventories and for speculative resale. But people cannot pile up inventories indefinitely on speculation that prices tomorrow will be higher than today. Except as a "shot in the arm," this can hardly be a major effect. (d) Rising prices may make it easier for resources to be shifted away from declining into growing industries, thereby helping to expand output. Without inflation, prices in declining industries may need to fall to force resources out, whereas wTith inflation resources can be bid into growing industries by higher wages and prices. Inflation may thus deserve some credit as a social lubricant. But the historical evidence suggests mainly that resources shift easily when times are prosperous and badly when depression prevails, regardless of whether prices are rising or not. Agriculture is the major historical case in point. Overall, there is little real evidence that moderate inflation increases current real output, though it is hard to dissociate the stimulative effect of strong total demand from the effect of rising prices per se. Certainly rising total demand may stimulate output and employment in periods of underemployment, even though rising prices have little contribution to make. In periods of substantially full employmenty neither seems likely to increase current total output much, and the argument that inflation is a necessary evil to increase output is weakened accordingly. 3. Does inflation stimulate economic growth? Historians have argued that over the centuries inflation has generally shifted income from the poor to the rich and from workers to businessmen. This, they argue, has increased the volume of saving and investment and speeded the rate of economic growth.4 While much evidence seems to support this view, the case is by no means clear. Whatever the lesson of history, more recent experience throws grave doubt on this hypothesis for, as will be shown below, at least in the recent, American inflation the share of profits has not increased relative to wages, nor has the share of the rich increased. The contrary has been true. Thus, the argument that inflation induces more saving and investment via this channel cannot be accepted if recent experience predicts the future. More recently, many economists have argued precisely the contrary—that inflation discourages savings and thereby retards capital accumulation, because inflation erodes the value of accumulated savings and encourages spending on current consumption. There is little doubt that this effect prevails in very rapid, runaway inflation. But for more moderate inflation, the case is not convincing. In almost all the post-World War I I inflations of the Western World, capital accumulation has proceeded rapidly. Inflation obviously militates against saving in most forms, but the motives for saving are many and mixed, and modern society provides some effective saving-investment channels to escape the erosion of inflation, at least for sophisticated savers. * See Earl Hamilton, "Prices as a Factor in Business Growth," Journal of Economic History, Fall 1952. A counter argument is presented by David Felix, "Profit Inflation an<J Industrial Growth," Quarterly Journal of Economics, August 1956. 39 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Conclusion: A Scotch verdict. It is not clear that inflation of modest proportions either increases or decreases substantially the rate of capital accumulation. A concluding note on the relationship between inflation, production, and employment is provided by table 1, which summarizes the changes on these 3 scores between 1952 and 1955 in the United States and 7 major European countries. This table shows no consistent relationship between inflation and changes in production. The largest increase in output and employment occurred iri West Germany, which had no inflation at all; the smallest in Sweden which had an intermediate amount of inflation. The next largest increases in production were in Italy and the Netherlands with intermediate inflation; the next smallest in the United States with very little inflation. Nor can the apparent failure of inflation to explain differing rates of growth and output be explained by introducing such other obvious mtercountry differences as differential increases in the supply of money, differing money wage ratio average to prices, or differing positions on international trade account.5 TABLE 1.—Inflation, production, and employment, 1952-55 * [1952=100] United States Cost of living: 1953 1954 . 1955 _- _ Industrial production: 1953 1954 1955 Employment: 1953 _ 1954 1955 Belgium France Germany Italy Nether- Sweden United lands Kingdom 101 101 101 100 102 101 99 99 100 98 98 100 102 105 108 100 104 106 101 102 105 103 105 110 108 100 112 100 106 114 97 106 117 109 122 141 110 120 130 110 120 128 100 104 110 106 114 119 103 100 102 99 99 101 98 99 100 104 109 118 100 101 103 103 107 109 97 98 100 101 104 107 i Data from J. Herbert Furth, Indicators of Inflation in Western Europe, 1952-55, Review of Economics and Statistics, August 1956, pp. 336-337. See that article for an analysis of the various countries' experiences. 4- Does inflation redistribute income ? Mild inflation apparently redistributes current income among major economic groups less than is often claimed, though the income redistribution may be appreciable. The redistribution that does take place does not correspond very well to some of the common preconceptions about inflation, at least in the recent American economy. Over the past two decades, every broad functional economic group in the United States has gained substantially in real income. Within the rapidly growing total the wage share grew appreciably over the period; wages and salaries, often considered laggards, considerably outdistanced profits as a share of the national income. Farmers, who are commonly supposed to gain most from inflation, saw their share of the national income decline persistently—perhaps in spite of inflation, but decline nevertheless. Corporation profits declined slightly. Unincorporated businesses, usually thought to be gainers from infla5 In the interest of brevity and simplicity, the international effects of inflation are completely omitted. For the United States as a whole, this probably does not distort greatly the conclusions stated. For some sectors of the economy, however, the foreign trade repercussions may be dominant. And for most other countries, more heavily dependent on foreign trade, such omissions would not be tolerable. 40 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH tion, took a substantial cut in their share of the total. The interest share fell drastically during World War II, as interest rates were held down by Government policy, but it has grown moderately back toward its earlier level since then. The rent share has changed little. Nor is there evidence that inflation has shifted income from the poor to the rich. If there was any effect, it apparently was the other way. Figure 1 pictures these changes. CONSUMER'S PRICE INDEX 1947-1949 = 100 ID Ol o % OF NATIONAL INCOME O4 O 1 o 1 o ro ° \\ o oo 1 1 i \\ o o 1 1 <O Ol <O - 3 - ~ - 3 Ol 5 Ol — / V \\ \\ \ I ! x> m I / O) I / 1 1 h 1 1 1 N\ CORP" V NET 1947 I1 1z { ] to —. > -0 30 § 1 is s CO 1/ EFOR 1951 I \ \ z z A m . CO ( -{ 1 1 5 _ Pi -4 // • X - 3 Ol Ol 1 195 - I \ \ 1 o z o • *• o m • 2 m co 1 1 CO Ol i 1 11 • # o -< co " # CO 2 22 o c O o m m I ){)1 a h > 3 2 1 I \ i o I i \ 1 O) X I / 1 / I • • (0 c m • to ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 41 Since inflation penalizes primarily those whose incomes rise more slowly than the incomes of their fellows, it was those on relatively fixed incomes who lost relatively, whether they were rich or poor, young or old, farmer or city dweller. Above all, it appears to have been the older people whose piece of the national income pie suffered most. Their share of the national income dropped substantially as inflation ate away at their largely fixed incomes. Moreover, here it appears that inflation did discriminate against the middle incomes and the poor. Well-to-do retired individuals could afford to diversify the investments underlying their retirement incomes and to include substantial amounts of such variable income assets as common stocks and real estate whose dollar yields increased with inflation. To the lower income families and widows this alternative was hardly open. Social-security payments have been raised greatly, and many older people have jobs. But this does not eliminate the basic fact that inflation is a major blow to this group, living considerably on past savings. The other most important lagging income group appears to have been employees of governments and eleemosynary institutions generally, especially teachers. In some cases, teachers' salaries have lagged so greatly that their real incomes have actually declined during the greatest boom in our history. More generally, it was the "passive" economic groups—those who sold no products on which they could raise the price or who worked under arrangements where their output could not readily be raised in price—who suffered at the expense of the "active" groups in society. A broad generalization is suggested. We may live in a society where the major economic groups are increasingly effective in protecting their own income shares during slow inflation; and where private wage and salary earners are especially successful, at the expense of more passive, quasi-fixed income groups throughout the economy who have neither prices to raise nor sufficient political power to push up their incomes apace with rising prices. 5, 6, and 7. Does inflation redistribute control over wealth? 6 Inflation transfers control over wealth (as contrasted to current income) from creditors to debtors. This is so because the debtor who borrows $100 and repays the same $100 later when prices are twice as high repays only half as much in real purchasing power. As best I can estimate, the American inflation over the past two decades has wiped out in this way well over half a trillion dollars of creditors' claims on debtors (in 1957 prices). All fixed-dollar-value intangible assets (such as bank deposits, currency, mortgages, Government and corporation bonds, life-insurance reserves, and pension and retirement funds) are debts owed to creditors that are susceptible to this erosion by inflation. In 1938 all such assets totaled just over $300 billion. If we calculate the loss of purchasing power on these debts up to the present, and make a similar calculation for the additional net debts of each following year, we obtain the very rough estimate of over $500 million inflationary erosion of real purchasing power of creditors over the period. 6 The impact of inflation on the distribution of wealth was analyzed in my earlier testimony before this committee, The Impact of Moderate Inflation on Incomes and Assets of Economic Groups, in Federal Tax Policy for Economic Growth and Stability (1955), and in G. L. Bach and A. Ando, The Redistributional Effects of Inflation, Review of Economics and Statistics, February 1957. Only a brief summary, therefore, is included here. 42 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Who gained this huge sum of purchasing power which creditors lost ? On balance, households have consistently been heavy net creditors, and governments (especially the Federal Government) consistently heavy net debtors, with the two offsetting each other roughly at something over a quarter of a trillion dollars each. Unincorporated businesses and nonfinancial corporations roughly offset each other as net creditors and net debtors, respectively, but the figures involved are small compared to households and governments. In summary, inflation has caused a huge transfer of purchasing power from households primarily to the Federal Government. But this is clearly not the end of the matter, since the Government is not some separate entity but, rather, an agency for all of us. We must look through the Government to see who are the actual beneficiaries of this inflation-induced levy on creditors. At first blush, it would appear that taxpayers (that is, all of us in our capacities as taxpayers) are the gainers. We now need to give up less purchasing power in taxes to meet payments on interest and principal on the Government debt. But it is highly unlikely that the Government debt will be paid off through taxation in the foreseeable future. Who, then, is the gainer of the purchasing power confiscated from Government creditors by inflation ? The answer is, the buying public as a whole, in proportion to its expenditures. Bondholders' real purchasing power is reduced, thereby increasing the share of the total current output that can be commanded by the rest of the buying public as their incomes rise with inflation. Put in commonsense language, Government bondholders and money holders are partially expropriated by inflation, and the benefit is distributed over the whole population, with the biggest benefits to those who buy the most. What types of households lose most as creditors? All households combined hold about 30 percent of their total wealth in the form of fixed dollar value assets. By contrast, they are in debt up to only a little over 10 percent of their total wealth. The difference is a measure of their net creditor position. Every major group of households is a substantial net creditor by this measure, except for very poor families and young families in the 25 to 34 age range which are heavily in debt as they are setting up families and housekeeping. But the extent to which different groups are net creditors varies a good deal. The heaviest net creditors, relative to their incomes, are older people, especially those who are retired. They hold a larger proportion of their wealth in fixed dollar value assets than do any other major group, largely because of the importance to them of insurance, and pensions and other retirement funds. Moreover, they are least in debt, to reap offsetting benefits on that score. At the other extreme, the very penurious or injudicious who are so heavily in debt as to have a negative net worth and the younger families mentioned above are least susceptible to "creditor loss" from inflation. Very well-to-do families appear to be in a mixed position. They are slightly higher net creditors than the average (relative to their total wealth), and their debts are small. Thus they appear vulnerable to inflation. But they hold an exceptionally large proportion of their total assets in "variable price" form (common stock, real ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 43 estate, and so on), which serves as a partial offset to their exposure as net creditors.7 S. Hoto does inflation affect businesses? Nonfinancial corporations are net debtors on balance, but only to a modest extent. Moreover, on the average about one-third of all individual corporations have been net creditors at any given time over the past two inflationary decades. Thus, nonfinancial corporations stand to gain somewhat on asset account from inflation, but only to a moderate extent. For most companies, other factors apparently play dominant roles in determining the economic well-being of the corporation during periods of inflation. Sales volume and increases in current cosTs relative to selling prices appear to explain changes in the economic position of corporations to a larger extent than do inflation-induced transfers on asset account. As was indicated above, reported corporate profits in the aggregate have maintained a roughly stable proportion of total national income since the beginning of the two-decade inflation period, though they have declined gradually since World War II. "Keal" corporation profits declined appreciably as a share of the national income, since reported profits over an inflationary period are larger than they should be if depreciation charges were sufficient to actually replace wearing out equipment. Moreover, inventory costs are generally undercharged in inflation. Eecent research suggests that such underreporting of costs and resultant overreporting of profits in inflation was enough to eat up over onethird of reported profits in a small sample of diverse companies studied. Thus, on balance nonmanuf acturing corporations as well as unincorporated businesses received a declining relative share of the real national income through the recent inflation, even though they gained moderately as net debtors. ii The economic impact on America of moderate, creeping inflation has been substantial, but hardly disastrous. This case against creeping inflation is clear, if modest. But the stronger case against permitting creeping inflation is that this governmental acquiescence greatly increases the likelihood of more rapid inflation, whose results will be more disruptive and inequitable. And acceptance of inflation as a "price" for maintaining high-level employment will generally be a mistaken choice, since it is unlikely that inflation will in fact produce the desired full employment. The history of America appears to provide little basis for expecting major inflation outside the impact of war.8 If the peacetime inflation danger is now great, there must be a change to account for it. I believe there has been such a change. Bursts of inflation may come from many causes. But the danger of serious continuing peacetime inflation arises fundamentally from 7 For statistical data on the position of different household groups, see Federal Tax Policy for8 Economic Growth, pp. 78-80. Major war would bring inflationary dangers of the first magnitude. But in that event we can anticipate such widespread changes in the entire financial structure and economic arrangements that discussion at the present level may have little relevance. 44 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH two major interacting factors: powerful "excess income claims," and governmental support of high-level employment through expansionary monetary fiscal policy. The danger is that this combination will gradually turn the creeping inflation to a walk and perhaps even to a run. Major economic groups—in labor, business, and agriculture—have come increasingly to demand, through the market place and through the governmental process, larger total income shares than are consistent with maintenance of a stable price level. There is nothing new about the desire for larger income shares. But to this desire has been added both the increased degree of organization of major groups in the market places and, most important, the acceptance of responsibility by the Federal Government for maintaining high-level employment and production. Government acceptance of this responsibility, which has been properly and widely acclaimed, means that if major wages and commodity prices are pushed up faster than is consistent with high-level employment and production, the resulting unemployment and falling sales will be bailed out by expansionary governmental monetary-fiscal policy, either directly or indirectly. A complete Government guaranty of "full employment" would substantially remove the pressure on any particular income group (seller) to moderate its own income claims, by removing the fear of unemployment or lost sales. So long as any group's demands did not get seriously ahead of other expanding claims in the economy, it could count on continued employment and sales at new higher cost and price levels. While inflation would result for the economy as a whole, each income claimant would see a chance of getting ahead of the parade. Moreover, with some relatively fixed income groups in society, there would always be a "rational" basis for excess income claims, since the active claimants would always gain at the expense of passive participants in the economic process. The apparent demonstration of the World War I I period that massive Government spending can create substantially full employment—that the war and the huge deficit spending connected with it did solve the vast unemployment problem of the 1930's—has consciously and subconsciously deeply affected the thinking of the present generation. Since Government monetary and fiscal policy (it appears) can cure unemployment and depression, there is little need to have unemployment and depression. Thus the normal restraint against excess income claims, the fear of pricing oneself out of the market, has been substantially weakened. The danger of persistent inflation is further increased by the pervasive belief that the Government has a considerable responsibility to take care of groups in trouble and that a rather high degree of social security is a desirable public-policy goal. Even more important, the high cost of defense, probably over many years ahead, increases the tendency toward inflation. Taxes are always harder to raise than expenditures, and higher Government expenditures even with a balanced budget probably exert some inflationary pressures. Logically, this analysis leads to a prediction of cumulatively rising inflation as income claimants try to outgrab each other. But in spite of this reasoning, I foresee little danger of truly galloping inflation of the postwar central European variet3^ in the United States short of all-out war. This could only occur through a complete collapse of ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 45 responsible governmental monetary-fiscal policy. While there is little doubt that the public fears unemployment more than it fears inflation, should inflation reach anything approaching runaway levels in an economy like ours, it seems to me overwhelmingly likely that the public would demand and actively support governmental restraint on the inflation both through more restrictive monetaty-fiscal policy and through imposition of widespread direct controls, unpalatable as these may be in less drastic situations. But the likelihood that inflation may go beyond a creep to several percent a year seems by no means remote, if governmental assurance of substantially full employment and maximum production becomes widely counted on as the dominant goal of national economic policy. Under that circumstance, it is easy to see how income claimants, both large and small, can persistently raise their asking prices faster than is consistent with the full-employment output at stable prices, and that these asking prices may be raised cumulatively as time goes on. Indeed, one of the greatest dangers of "moderate" inflation is that it will grow fast enough to generate strong pressure for imposition of widespread direct Government controls over individual wages and prices, under the mistaken belief that this is the only or most effective way to check rising prices. "Creeping" inflation has not recently generated such strong pressure to interfere with private markets. But I suspect that only a small further increase in the rate of inflation would indeed bring a major danger to the preservation of substantially free farkets. Imposing a new regulation always offers the illusion of avoiding the painful restrictive impact of limiting total spending power. Many suggestions have been made to blunt the growth of excess income claims. But to date none of these seems very promising. Exhortation to moderation sounds good, but is a doubtful weapon against self-interest. At least until a better suggestion comes along, the main protection against an increasing "excess income claims inflation" must be a recognition by economic groups (sellers generally) that they do run a risk of pricing themselves temporarily at least out of the market; in other words, that the Government is not committed solely to maintaining full employment and high-level output. The biggest objection raised against this analysis is the widely cited "unemployment versus inflation" dilemma. What if sellers' wages and prices are persistently pushed up and the Government refuses to augment the money supply, directly or indirectly ? Unemployment will result, the argument runs. Only by providing increased purchasing power can the Government prevent unemployment and falling sales. Inflation will result, but this inflation is the necessary price for avoiding unemployment. Such Government-supported inflation may temporarily ease the excess-income-claims inflation. But if my analysis above is correct, only very temporarily. For as assurance grows that Government action will bail out excess-income-claims-induced unemployment and falling sales, the restraining forces against inflationary wage-price demands weaken proportionally. Wage and price demands will be bigger next time around and the Government-supported inflation required to avoid unemployment will be larger. What will stop the inflationary demands and responses from cumulating upward? 46 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Creeping Government-supported inflation does not solve the unemployment versus inflation dilemna which arises from excess-income claims. At best it only postpones the dilemma, and even temporary success becomes increasingly unlikely, even though the rate of inflation is repeatedly stepped upward. The problem of excess-incomeclaims-induced unemployment must ultimately be faced directly. We cannot have full employment without inflation if excess-income claims prevail. Indeed, it may become increasingly difficult to have full employment with inflation, if inflation becomes increasingly accepted and expected. If we must choose between high-level employment and inflation, most people will choose high-level employment. If we could assure full employment by having a little inflation, few would hesitate to incur the inflation. But this is not the meaningful way to state the choice. To avoid inflation without full employment, we must generate and preserve an economic climate where sellers expect Government policy to emphasize both higH-level employment and relatively stable prices. The solution to the unemployment or inflation dilemma is, as with many other dilemmas, not to choose one or the other painful alternative; rather, it is to take steps to avoid having the dilemma arise. In the long run, we will avoid an excess-income claims inflation only if the public really wants to avoid it—only if economic groups are willing, on the whole, to keep their income claims roughly within the bounds of full employment output and stable prices. Ultimately the public must understand the danger of serious inflation and must consider this an important public policy objective if the long-run inflation danger is to be contained. "The Government" or some part of it, such as the Federal Reserve Board, can provide leadership against inflation, and can even restrain inflation counter to widespread public pressures for some period of time. But in the last analysis, no Government agency can enforce a counter-inflation policy on a public which does not want it. ni What are the implications of this argument for the Employment Act of 1946? The case for inclusion of substantial stability of the consumer price level as one objective of governmental policy in the act seems to me a convincing one. The language of the act is general and aimed at the promotion of multiple goals. Maximum employment, production, and purchasing power are central objectives. Addition of substantial stability of the price level would in no sense weaken the importance of the goals already stated, but would recognize specifically another important goal of public policy. It is the responsibility of the Congress and administrative officers of the Government to provide leadership on economic policy, as in other areas. This is critically true in the case of counterinflation policy, since only expansionary Government monetary-fiscal policy can support a continuing excess income claims inflation. Specific inclusion of the price level stability objective would be such an act of leadership. Constant visibility to Members of Congress, to the administrative branch of the Government, and to the public of the price level stability goal along with the presently stated goals of the Employment Act would help to provide a more restraining framework for all in making their public and private economic policies. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 47 It has been argued that the price level stability goal is already implicit in the act. This may be so, and undoubtedly many Government servants so interpret the present langauge. But one of the main factors in the inflation since World War II, and one of the main factors in any future inflation, will be the fact that consumers, union leaders, and businessmen expect prices to rise. Their resulting behavior has contributed substantially to price rises in the past. They may well do so again. A clear warning against such expectations can help at least some; it can hardly do any harm. The major argument against inclusion of price stability in the act is that this would lessen the promptness or vigor with which the Government may act against future depressions. I cannot believe that this is true. The pressures for strong, quick governmental action against unemployment are powerful and pervasive. But by contrast I do believe that specific stable money language might help to strengthen the hand of those in the Government who have the painful and often superficially unpopular task of fighting inflations as they develop. Temporarily our attention has been diverted from the problem of creeping inflation to a serious recession. But if inflation does again grow to more major proportions it will be basically because the Government provides the fuel for the inflationary fire through monetary and fiscal policy, and because the public comes to anticipate the provision of this fuel. Inclusion of an announced goal of substantial price stability is the minimal responsible level of protective action. Treading the precarious path toward stable economic growth is at best difficult, especially with the multiple objectives implied in that general goal. Building a self-reinforcing set of stable money plus high output expectations is at best a slow, hard process in our democratic society. We cannot expect success overnight. But current policy needs to be directed toward this goal at the same time it is necessarily focused also on the instabilities of each present situation. PRICE BEHAVIOR, STABILITY, AND GROWTH1 William J. Baumol, Princeton University When Johnson first arrived in London * * * " 'Thirty pounds a year was enough to enable a man to live there without being contemptible * * *' It may be estimated that double the money might now with difficulty be sufficient."—Boswell I. AN OVERALL VIEW A. The historical persistence of inflationary pressures Among the few things which economists predict with any degree of confidence is that, with some possible exceptional periods, prices will, on the average, be higher in future decades than they are today. This belief is based in part on a remarkably consistent historical record. Scrappy evidence going back to the 13th century apparently indicates that prices in England and the United States were never stable for any protracted period, and that, considering periods of the order of magnitude of 50 years, the price level has risen almost constantly. However, its persistence is not the only reason we have for expecting at least a mild but chronic inflation to continue in the future. The fact is that there are many forces which make for inflation. For example, it is always easier, politically, for a government to increase its expenditures than to increase its taxes and a counterinflationary budget surplus is certainly likely to be unpopular. B. The role of the American firm in economic growth Perhaps more relevant for the present discussion are the relationships between economic growth and the behavior of the price level. First I should like to say something about the nature of the forces which make for growth in our economy. The centers of expansion decisions in a free enterprise economy are its business firms. This is not as obvious as it may seem—conservative business practice could well call for firms to hold the line until rising population and consumption demand created the market for an expanded output. But business enterprises simply do not operate in this way. Schumpeter argued long ago that in order to increase their net worth firms must keep innovating—introducing new products, new sources of supply, new production methods, etc. There are other related reasons for management's preoccupation with growth. Growth can make a firm more attractive to the money market and its products more attractive to customers. The morale of its personnel is likely to be much higher than is the case in a declining enterprise. Only by growth can a small firm hope to enter those lines of enterprise where a large amount of capital is required. Other advantages of growth to the firm can easily be cited. 1 1 am extremely grateful to Lester V. Chandler, Kenneth Galbraith, and Gardner Patterson for their very helpful comments and suggestions. 49 50 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH There is yet another reason why American business enterprise has worked for expansion of our economy—a reason which will play an important role in the discussion later in this paper. So far I have argued that businessmen want their firms to expand because growth helps them to achieve their other objectives—it opens new profit opportunities, it helps with personnel management, etc. But growth is important to the businessman not only as a means to an end. In large segments of American business practice it has become a goal in and of itself. I have had occasion to consult with a number of firms in various industries and of various sizes, and in almost every one this appeared to be the case. In the so-called oligopolistic sectors of our economy, the industries containing a relatively small number of large firms which account for so large a proportion of our Nation's output, among top management's prime yardsticks of success are sales revenue and market share. When a businessman in such a firm is asked how things are going one can be quite sure that he will reply cheerfully that sales (meaning dollar volume) have gone up x percent (or sadly that they have gone down y percent) and that only subsequently, if at all, will he say anything about his profits. This is not meant to deny that those businessmen are in business at least partly to earn money. But so long as profits are at a level which it considers reasonable—enough to keep stockholders satisfied and to contribute to the financing of growth—management will bend its efforts to the expansion of sales revenues rather than to further increases in profits. To summarize, we have in the nature of American business enterprise powerful dynamic forces which can be depended upon to produce a remarkable rate of long-run expansion of our economy. Of course there have been a number of severe and important short-run breakdowns in this mechanism but a glance at the broad outlines of our economic history suggests that expansion and not depression is its preponderant characteristic. C. The effect of growth on price levels Let us return now to the central subject—the relationship between growth and the price level. This is a two-way relationship—economic growth influences price behavior and price behavior influences growth. Economic expansion clearly puts upward pressures on prices. When employment is high and businessmen are bidding against one another for resources which are in short supply it may naturally be expected that the sellers of these resources will raise their prices. Unions will demand higher wages. The owners of natural resources will raise their prices, etc. Furthermore, businessmen will be inclined not to resist these demands too strongly because their experience is that during a period of expansion they can raise their prices accordingly without any serious effects on sales. This is made possible, at least partly, by the fact that the price raising occurs simultaneously with the rise in costs. For increasing costs take the form of higher incomes and higher purchasing power in the hands of the sellers of productive resources who can now afford the higher prices asked by the businessman. Of course any individual businessman might nevertheless do better for himself were he able to resist wage and other cost raising demands so long as no one else ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 51 did so. For then he could benefit from the increased demand for his products which results from the increased incomes of other firms' employees without himself paying any higher costs. But observation suggests that the corporate form, in which management is in a position of stewardship over the property of others, has made the executive highly reluctant to risk good will and public approbation in major battles with the unions. So long as rising costs can easily be passed on management will therefore put up no more than token resistance to wage and other factor price demands. Thus it is clear that either because he cannot help it or because he does not wish to resist too hard, economic growth usually raises the businessman's costs and hence tends to induce him to raise his prices. Occasional exceptions are produced by cost-saving inventions which help to expand sales through reduced prices or by economies of large scale production made possible by growth of the firm. But, by and large, expansion can be expected to create bottlenecks and competition for factors of production whose effect is inflationary. This is particularly so because growth is contagious. It is not likely to occur in one or a few industries at a time. Growth in one sector of the economy creates the income and hence the demand for the products of other sectors. Moreover in any one industry management's concern with market share means that the expansion of any one firm is likeley to be followed by emulatory effort on the part of other companies. Hence we may expect that everyone will be wanting labor, raw materials, and equipment at the same time and that the effect on prices will therefore be as described. D. The effect of price levels on growth Up to a point slowly rising price levels probably act as a stimulant to growth. On the one hand they produce an optimistic atmosphere in which the businessman has confidence in the chances for success of his expansion programs. Moreover, as we have seen, increasing costs do not seem to serve as much of a deterrent to output during such a period. However when the price rises go on for too long or are too sharp they can be expected to act as a drag on real output in a number of ways : 1. Unless the public becomes accustomed to uninterrupted inflation as a way of life people are likely to begin eventually to think that it must some day come to an end. This expectation effect can lead businessmen to liquidate inventories and consumers to postpone purchases, particularly purchases of durable goods. A softening of the market for any increased output (growth) is particularly likely to result if consumers think prices are too high and decide therefore to postpone any purchases which represent increases in their living standards. 2. Rising prices can also deter growth because they eat into the value of an important class of savings. Holders of money and Government securities will find that the value of their accumulations has evaporated and if there is any reason to make up the loss (e. g., saving for retirement) they may be forced to reduce their demands accordingly. This is the familiar effect which has gone under various naries such as the Pigou (and Keynes) effect, the real balance effect, the wealth saving relationship, etc. 3. So far I have discussed the adverse effects of slow chronic inflation on economic growth when it acts as a deterrent to demand. 23734—58 5 52 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH frequently we hear nowadays of the effects on supply but in the long run I think these effects are of at least equal importance. The first of these is related to one that has already been discussed, the effects of expectations on demand. I have already shown that if people are led to expect an end to the inflationary process, demand may be decreased and the steam may be taken out of the growth process. However the alternative can be equally unattractive. If the public gets to feel that the future holds only still higher prices many people may cease saving altogether and so an important source of business financing may disappear. The effect may be a squeeze on the construction of plant and equipment which, in the long run, can seriously reduce national output. However here there may be an important offset in that increased consumer demand may greatly facilitate corporate saving. 4. A more universal effect of inflationary pressure on supply is an extremely serious reduction in quality standards. This applies equally to the quality of labor, of raw materials and of product. The absence of real economic pressures—the universal seller's market which accompanies inflation—means that there is little motivation to preserve standards of workmanship. Why produce a better product if the old commodity can be sold anyhow? Why work hard if employers are short of men and one can always get another job ? This danger is increased by the fact that reduced quality is a convenient way of disguising price rises. If a product has a traditional price it is so much easier to put a little less into the packages, to use shoddier materials, to reduce expenditure on quality control so that the customer instead of paying much more for the same products pays the same or only a little more for a formerly cheaper product. Signs of this are all about us. The candy bar is smaller than it used to be, food products which require it are not aged as long as they used to be and so on. When this process is allowed to go on long enough the economy is transformed into a world of Potemkin villages. Two houses are produced where there was one before—but these two houses are basically well disguised shacks. In other words chronically creeping inflation is likely to turn economic growth into a sham and to produce a blight on the economy and the landscape from which it can take a long time to recover. E. Policy implications I believe strongly that there are right conclusions and wrong conclusions to be drawn from the foregoing analysis. One wrong conclusion is that price rises are going to occur anyhow and there is therefore very little that can be done about it. Equally unacceptable to me is the view that the Government must reconcile itself to some rise in prices partly because they act as a stimulant to growth, but that the role of monetary and fiscal policy in this connection should be to keep the rate of increase small—say to some figure np higher than 4 or perhaps 2 percent per year. I object to this view on two grounds. One is a matter of tactics while the other follows directly from the foregoing analysis. The tactical consideration is that whatever our objective there is some danger that we will fall somewhat short of it. Experience suggests that if we are prepared to do no more than to seek to keep the rate of inflation down to 4 percent per year it is highly likely that prices will ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 53 rise faster than that. Only from a determination to take all measures necessary to put a stop to inflation altogether can we with any confidence expect that there will be much of a contribution to its deceleration. In part, but only in part, this is a consequence of the structure of our political arrangements. It is an inherent and in fact a desirable feature of a political system built about a multitude of checks and balances that governmental plans are likely to come out much less sharp and extreme than they were when first conceived. But aside from this problem of tactics the adoption of a constant slow rate of inflation as a goal can be objected to on the grounds that the adverse effects of inflation on growth which were discussed above can be produced by slow chronic price rises perhaps at least as effectively as they can by occasional sharp increases in the price level. The attrition of savings can occur in either case and the destruction of quality standards may be more complete for having occurred in slow imperceptible steps. To put the matter affirmatively, the promotion of economic stability and growth requires monetary and fiscal policies which can and do prevent uninterrupted inflation. This conclusion is not based on considerations of equity which clearly may by themselves also make it imperative that inflation be brought to a halt. For the question to which I have addressed myself is increased growth of total national output rather than its distribution. Perhaps on either ground it may be argued that we cannot tolerate a policy which passively accepts uninterrupted inflation as an immutable feature of the national fate. II. THE ROLE OF THE MARKET STRUCTURE In an important recent contribution Professor Galbraith has called our attention to the fact that the process by which price changes occur is dependent on the nature of the market structure.2 Prices are set in a different way in those sectors of the economy which are composed of many small firms than they are in industries where there are 5,10, or 20 major producers (the oligopolistic sectors). Galbraith has argued that oligopolistic firms are particularly effective conductors of inflationary pressure (pp. 127-130) and that they are relatively immune to the counterinflationary influences of monetary and fiscal policy (pp. 130-132). From these results of his analysis he concludes that the efficacy of monetary and fiscal policies must depend largely upon their impact on the competitive sectors of the economy which must bear the brunt of the burden of readjustment (p. 132) and points out that this raises serious questions about the effectiveness, the equity, and the wisdom of such policies. In particular this view suggests that much more extreme monetary and fiscal measures may be required to achieve a given disinflationary effect than we would otherwise have thought to be necessary. I must differ with Professor Galbraith on a number of these points. I think it can be shown that the difference in role of the competitive and that of the oligopolistic firm in the inflationary process ip not nearly as great as he would have us believe. To indicate my reasons a J. K. Galbraith, Market Structure and Stabilization Policy, Review of Economics and Statistics, May 1957. 54 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH for this view I must first digress into a discussion of the nature of oligopolistic pricing. A. Galbraith on the oligopolistic firm To Professor Galbraith, as to many investigators, a prime characteristic of the oligopolistic firm is that it does not normally set a price which maximizes profits. So far I am in agreement. But in his analysis there seems to be no alternative explanation of the pricesetting process. Somehow, perhaps by historical accident, the price of each item seems to have been set up, and then for fear of setting off a price war through retaliatory efforts of competitors the oligopolist apparently never changes such a price unless universal cost changes permit him to do so without being misunderstood by business rivals. The executive is apparently taken to be less concerned with the level at which his prices are set than he is in keeping his prices at that level. We are given little indication how those prices happened to be set at those levels in the first place. It would be a very odd coincidence indeed if those prices were to happen to lie at their precise profit maximizing levels. In fact we are told that they will generally lie below those which will maximize profits apparently because inflation calls for rapid upward price shifts as demand increases in monetary terms—price rises greater than those which the oligopolist is willing to permit. Furthermore, according to Professor Galbraith, "A commonplace feature of a firm under inflationary demand is a backlog" (p. 128). This backlog can, of course, be eliminated by a price sufficiently high to cut the quantity demanded down to the quantity supplied, but such a price rise the oligopolist presumably refuses to permit. As a result of all of this, he argues, monetary and fiscal measures may be rendered largely ineffective in the oligopolistic sector. Any rise in costs incurred as a result of interest rate increases need not reduce the oligopolist's profits. For, since he is not maximizing his profits to begin with, he can raise his price and increase his profits sufficiently to make up for the higher interest cost. Any reduction in demand produced by such policies may serve only to reduce the backlog of demand and may actually result in no decrease in sales. The oligopolist will then, according to Galbraith, be able to go on as before, with no loss in profits and perhaps no less in sales. He will have no reason to cut down his investment expenditure. His contribution to inflationary pressure will therefore not be diminished unless monetary or fiscal actions are particularly severe. Not such will be the fate of the competitive small-business man where prices are fixed on the market and where rises in costs and cuts in demand really hurt and hurt at once. Thus, according to Galbraith, besides being less effective than might have been expected, counterinflationary monetary and fiscal policies can serve to increase industrial concentration and help to contribute to the danger of decline of the small-business man. B. Sales maximization, price setting, and the backlog The short run purposes of the large firm can, I believe, be explained somewhat further. There is some logic to the process whereby prices are set, but it is not the logic of profit maximization. As I have already stated, I believe most oligopolistic firms aim to maximize not profits, but sales volume (measured in money terms; sales ^tre what the ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 55 economist is his jargon calls "total revenue"). So long as profits remain at a satisfactory rate, management will devote further effort to increasing its sales rather than its profits. It follows that Professor Galbraith is indeed right in asserting that the oligopolist's profits will not normally be maximized. But the reason is not because he is dominated by fear of making price adjustments, although such fears may also play their role. He will fail to maximize profits also because he has another partially overriding purpose to which he is willing to sacrifice some profits. If this is correct, it follows that we must expect only under extraordinary circumstances to encounter the backlog of orders which Galbraith considers to be a normal feature of oligopolistic operation during an inflationary period. A firm which tries to maximize sales will not hold back on production unless either the expansion of its capacity has been unable to keep up with demand or unless management is so fearful of the future that it hesitates to undertake the required investment commitments. Consider now the effects on such a firm of a rise in costs which might occur, for example, as the result of an increase in wages or in interest rates. As in Professor Galbraith's analysis, this may lead to an increase in the company's selling prices sufficient to prevent any reduction in profits. For otherwise the rise in costs can reduce the oligopolist's profits below that level which he considers to be the minimum uncler which he can operate. But several other consequences follow from this step: In the probably more usual case where there is no backlog of orders, this price rise must mean some cut in the number of items sold, or at least unit sales will not increase as quickly as they otherwise would have. Moreover, if the initial price had been chosen to maximize sales revenues, it is clear that the rise in price must result in a reduction in (or a reduction in the rate of increase of) dollar sales. It follows that— 1. An interest rate or wage increase will also hit the oligopolist where it hurts him—not in his profits but in his sales volume. 2; An interest rate rise need produce no increase in industrial concentration—the oligopolist's sales will decline right along with those of the competitive firm. 3. By reducing the demands for his products or increasing his costs, monetary or fiscal policy can effectively reduce the oligopolist's contribution to inflationary pressure. If his sales fall it will pay him to reduce his demand for factors of production either for immediate use in his manufacturing process or for investment purposes. But this is precisely what a disinflationary monetary and fiscal policy seeks to get him to do.3 Thus in each of these respects I am forced to disagree with Professor Galbraith's policy conclusions—considering the oligopolistic sector alone, fiscal and monetary policy need not on the face of it be inequitable, it need not promote monopolization, nor is it to be expected to be ineffective. 8 Incidentally, I must take exception to Galbraith's assertion that "* * * firms in the oligopolistic sector have the opportunity of offsetting any credit restrictions to which they are subject by increasing their prices and their earned resources and devoting them to investment" (p. 131). It can take several years of increased accumulation out of profits to offsejb a large reduction in credit. Hence this means may well be insufficient to prevent forced postponement of oligopolistic investment which is all the deflationary effect that is usull ht 56 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Even in the case, which I have not yet discussed, in which there is a large backlog of unfilled orders the Galbraith conclusions can be disputed. If the backlog occurs by design because the oligopolist is afraid of the future and he wishes to retain a cushion of demand against contingencies, the rise in price or the reduction in demand which results from anti-inflation policy will cut down on that cushion. The oligopolist may then be expected to hold back even more in his investment plans, thereby contributing once again to a reduction in inflationary pressure. Similarly, if his backlog of demand piled up because he has, so to speak, been unable to get sufficiently quick delivery on expanded plant and equipment a reduction in the backlog can mean partial cancellation of investment orders. C. The competitive sector Yet there is an important observation which I think lies behind Professor Galbraith's discussion. In times of inflation it is true that the firm can frequently raise prices in response to cost changes and get away with little or no observable ill effect. I have already had occasion to refer to that process earlier in this paper. What occurs here is that the cost rise, because it is universal, provides the purchasing power which permits consumers to buy as much as they did before the price rise. This is the mechanism of the familiar wage-price spiral. But here the competitive firm is in no worse a strategic position than is the oligopolist. The demand for the small-business man's products will be raised by increases in wages, both his own and the oligopolist's. Thus the competitive firm is able to participate wholeheartedly in the inflationary process just as is the oligopolist. Indeed, it may almost be suspected that the small firm will in this respect occupy the slightly better position. For in competitive markets the translation of increased costs into higher prices is rapid, impersonal, and automatic. To the extent that the large firm hesitates to change prices even in the upward direction, it may therefore be placed at a relative disadvantage. Of course rises in interest rates differ from wage rises in that they do not all go into increases in money income in the hands of the public, A large proportion of higher interest payments may represent a transfer to banks and insurance companies where they will not immediately be used to swell the monetary demand for commodities. That is essentially why interest rate increases can act as an offset to inflationary pressures while wage rises do not ordinarily do so. But if interest rate rises do prevent increases in demand they will do so equally for the oligopolist and for the small firm. I am not to be interpreted to hold the position that different monetary and fiscal policies all and always fall with exactly equal weight on the competitive and oligopolistic sectors of the economy. Clearly this need not be so. It depends on costs structures, the relative elasticities of demands for the products of the two sectors and many other considerations. My position is just that the relative effects can only be determined after far more careful and detailed investigation of their product lines and related matters, and that I will be very surprised should such an investigation show that all the tools of monetary and fiscal policy consistently favor the one group against the other. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 57 HI. PRICE POLICY FOR GROWTH The preceding section was primarily negative in purpose, seeking largely to deny that there were grounds for expecting a certain type of relationship. Nothing was said affirmatively about the types of policy which can promote price stability and economic growth. In this section I hope to supply this deficiency. A. Growth as a goal As already stated, complete price stability and economic growth are not totally compatible objectives. Growth tends to cause prices to rise. It also has other costs. The most important of these is that rapid growth requires a very high level of physical investment—of construction of plant and equipment, etc. In a period when there is little unemployment and unused capacity an increase in the production of investment goods must involve some reduction in the output of consumers' goods. As is well known this is precisely the sort of decision to which the ruling clique in the Soviet Union has stuck these many years. And, at least in part, this decision has been responsible for their very noteworthy success in expanding Russian military and industrial capacity at so phenomenal a rate. Before effective policies for the promotion of economic growth can be decided upon in this country we must therefore decide first how much we are willing to give up for it. This is no idle question Our overall economic growth has been proceeding by itself at a remarkably high rate and there is reason to believe that, except for occasional interruptions, it is going to continue to do so. It is possible to give up too much for the future like the miser who is starving because he is putting aside every penny he earns. Even the Russian threat must not force us to jump to hasty conclusions on this question. There is much to be said for the view that to meet the competition of the iron curtain countries we need to speed up not our overall rate of economic expansion but the growth of some key outputs—scientific, military etc. Certainly this has been the Soviet strategy. B. Policy for overall growth Suppose it is decided that somewhat more of our national effort should be devoted to speeding up our economic expansion and less to the production of current consumption goods. What can the Government do to promote these goals? I have already argued, for one thing, that strong measures must be taken to prevent uninterrupted inflation. When price rises threaten to get out of hand or to last too long the usual array of weapons—• budget surpluses, tight money, et cetera, must be employed to the extent necessary to put an end to the inflationary pressures. But I do not believe this is by any means the most important measure to be taken to promote growth. In a free enterprise system where the Government seeks to avoid the regulation of production by fiat except in time of national emergency, businessmen must be induced to take the appropriate measures voluntarily. Nor is this a matter for exhortation and propaganda whose effects are doubtful and whose use is usually inappropriate except in times calling for public heroism. Management's responsibilities are too great to run the business 58 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH enterprises with whose operations it is entrusted in accord with the utterances of remote public figures. There is only one dependable way to achieve the desired results— that is to make them pay. And there is one instrument ideally suited to achieve the Government's purposes in this respect—the tax laws. Already the capital gains provisions served to make the retention of corporate earnings attractive to large stockholders. This is an incentive for growth because retained earnings are readily employed to finance plant expansion and other types of investment. In the same way, if Congress wishes to promote economic growth (and, I repeat, there is something to be said on either side on such a decision) it must consider undertaking a revision of the tax laws in a way which favors investment as against current production of consumers' goods. Businessmen, who are already anxious to promote economic growth, will be quick enough to take advantage of any opportunity to reduce their tax burden through increased investment or any other expansionary activities which may be favored. In the case of underdeveloped areas I have elsewhere gone so far as to suggest that firms be offered a tax exemption which is larger the greater is the percentage rate of increase in their production. I do not believe so radical a proposal is appropriate for the United States but it does serve to underline the nature of the policy approach which I am urging. I shall make no attempt to indicate the details of the tax-law revisions which would be in line with this view. That must be left to persons more expert in the tax structure and its legal and economic complications. I hope however that I have suggested one promising avenue for exploration. C. The long-run position of the United States Let us return now to the question of the Soviet challenge although this represents somewhat of a departure from the subject of the rest of this paper. I think it is quite clear that the American industrial capacity is still considerably greater than that of the Eussians. This means that were it deemed crucial, there is little doubt that a crash program could permit us to catch up on the production of missiles, rockets, jet planes, or any other particular weapons on which we are behind. But catching up on special items is not the problem. We cannot plan on just barely keeping up by means of an interminable series of emergency programs conceived in the haste which is engendered by panic. Indeed, it is to be expected that in the normal course of events the Eussians will from time to time come up with developments before we do. The Soviet successes are frightening rather because they suggest we are falling behind in a more fundamental sense—in our supply of ideas and our ability to carry them out. Should we ever lose our lead in the fundamental knowledge which we possess and the skills to produce and use ever more knowledge we will really find ourselves ready prey to the totalitarian world. The difficulty appears to lie partly in our national propensity to favor practicality. American industry, for example, is more than willing to Sponsor researchers and thfcir research, provided that their projects are of a variety which give promise of practical application. From the point of view of the firm this may make good sense although, ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 59 increasingly, management, too, is showing signs of questioning this position. But from the point of view of the Nation's future this represents the most catastrophic sort of shortsightedness. Time and time again it has been shown that some of the most fundamental and revolutionary scientific and industrial developments would not have been possible without the work of the basic researcher, the man who does not know and, at least within limits, could not care less how his results will be applied. Innovations from electricity to the hydrogen bomb bear their debt to the completely impractical investigator. The Soviets have certainly recognized this and their efforts to sponsor both research and researcher are apparently ahead of ours in a number of respects. Their educational system is geared to supply new scientific talent at a very high rate and it is already showing its effects. Though it is perhaps beyond the province of the Employment Act this problem is clearly fundamental for economic growth. Here again congressional action is probably called for. The design of a comprehensive policy is beyond my intentions and my abilities. I should, however, like to call attention to two suggestions which, I hope, merit further exploration. I believe the Government should consider setting up a system of national scholarships on the order of those which were provided by the G. I. bill. These scholarships should be available only for college and university training. They should again permit the recipient to attend and approved school of his own choosing subject to his acceptance for admission by that institution. However, such scholarships should be awarded on the basis of examinations which require of the applicant evidence of training at least equivalent to that offered in a Soviet gymnasium. This proposal is designed to achieve two purposes: to increase the number of able college students and to force a drastic upgrading of standards of our high schools which are notoriously so far behind the equivalent Russian institutions. However, this does not cope with another fundamental problem— the relatively small proportion of able American students who go into research rather than into industrial, legal, and other more lucrative occupations. It is absolutely imperative for this country's future that the research activities be made more attractive. One proposal that has recently been made calls for the setting up in each field of research about 50 well publicized chairs bearing a minimum stipend of $30,000 per annum plus adequate research funds. This would be awarded to the most outstanding members of the research professions and would not be attached to any particular academic institution. Whatever the merits of this particular proposal it points up the need for a dramatic move to increase the attractiveness of a career in fundamental research. Such a conclusion is inescapable if we are prepared to accept two premises: (1) that America's long-run future is at stake and depends on its ability to maintain and increase its supply of knowledge and ideas, and (2) that in a free-enterprise economy coercion is an inappropriate instrument and exhortation an undependable means to promote the goals of our society. Only by an appeal to the profit motive which is so fundamental among the Nation's institutions can we feel confident that our goals will be achieved. ECONOMIC STABILITY, ECONOMIC GROWTH, AND PRICE STABILITY Betty G. Fishman and Leo Fishman, West Virginia University The terms "stability" and "growth" have been used so frequently during the past few j^ears in discussions of the Employment Act of 1946, that a goodly number of intelligent citizens may very well believe that these words were used in the act, to set forth its purpose. Actually, of course, this is not the case. According to section 2 of the act— it is the continuing policy and responsibility of the Federal Government to use all practicable means * * * for the purpose of creating and maintaining, in a manner calculated to foster and promote free competitive enterprise and the general welfare, conditions under which there will be afforded useful employment opportunities, including self-employment, for those able, willing, and seeking to work, and to promote maximum employment, production, and purchasing power. Subsection (c) 4 of section 4 states that one of the duties and functions of the Council of Economic Advisers shall be— to develop and recommend to the President national economic policies to foster and promote free competitive enterprise, to avoid economic fluctuations or to diminish the effects thereof, and to maintain employment, production, and purchasing power. But the words "stability" and "growth" do not appear in the Employment Act either separately or together. The number of years which has elapsed since the passage of the Employment Act, together with the nature and diversity of the economic developments which have occurred during that time are sufficient to justify the conclusion that the language of the Employment Act is remarkably well suited to the general purpose of the act. That language is general enough to provide for flexibility in interpretation and also for the flexibility in action necessary if the act is to furnish a useful guide to economic policy in particular circumstances, the exact nature of which could not be foreseen at the time the act was passed. For example, there is no doubt among either economists or policymaking officials that the Employment Act provides the basis for Government action designed to restrain inflation when such action appears necessary, as well as the basis for Government action designed to mitigate or halt a recession when such action appears necessary. Employment, production, and purchasing power are each highly significant concepts in assessing the adequacy with which the economy is functioning, and in determining what steps, if any, need be taken to improve its functioning. They are also concepts which are generally understood and defined in a similar fashion by economists and policymakers alike. In the case of employment and production, more- 61 62 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH over, policymakers need not confine their attention to the abstract conceptions or to indirect methods of approximating the actual level of these indicators of economic activity. Fortunately, there are available statistical series which provide reliable data on both employment and production with very little time lag. In the case of purchasing power, there is no equally satisfactory statistical series on which those concerned with economic policy may rely. Even here, however, there are data available which, when used with proper discrimination and judgment, can be very helpful. It may be pointed out that implicit in the language of the act is the belief that maximum employment, maximum production^ and maximum purchasing power either are or can be made to be consistent with one another, and also with the objective of avoiding economic fluctuations or mitigating their effects. Whether or not this is actually so under all circumstances may, of course, be questioned. But it is evident that principal emphasis in the act is placed on employment, and this emphasis could furnish a clue to policymakers in what otherwise might prove to be a perplexing situation. II Although the terms "stability" and "growth" have been used for some years now in discussions of the Employment Act both in and out 01 Government circles, those terms have not always been construed or applied in the same way, nor have they always been assigned the same degree of importance or priority. Thus there have been times when stability has been emphasized and growth has received little if any attention. At other times growth has been emphasized and stability, at least overtly, has been substantially neglected. More recently it has been fairly common to link the two together and to talk of "economic stability and growth" together. In general in the years subsequent to 1946, concern about stability and use of the term increased together with signs of actual or impending recession or actual or impending inflation. Under such circumstances, stability was generally not defined clearly by those who used the term. It was, perhaps, sufficiently obvious that they applied it in a negative rather than a positive fashion. In one set of circumstances it meant avoiding recession or at least avoiding a deepening of recession. In another set of circumstances it meant avoiding inflation or at least avoiding a heightening of inflation. During some periods when neither recession nor inflation were present or imminent, attention shifted from stability, and the term "growth" was used more frequently. This term, too, was rarely defined, but it was generally clear that it was held to be integrally related to increasing employment opportunities, and sometimes to increasing productivity, and/or a rising level of production as well. Until quite recently, when both economic stability and growth were discussed in the same paper or in the same public statement, "stability" was frequently referred to as a suitable goal for short-run policy, and "growth" as a suitable goal for long-run policy. In such discussions, also, while the term "stability" was never clearly defined, it was generally applied in the negative sense described above. More recently, however, there has been increasing recognition of the fact that it is impossible to keep short-run and long-run consider- ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 63 ations neatly enclosed in separate compartments in the formulation of public policy. For one thing it has become increasingly apparent that policies which are adopted to cope with so-called short-run problems have a bearing on long-run developments as well, while policies adopted to cope with long-run problems also have a bearing on shortrun developments. Even more fundamental, however, is the fact that in an economy as highly developed and large and rapidly changing as ours, it becomes increasingly difficult to draw and maintain a satisfactory distinction between long-run and short-run considerations. In the not too far distant past many economists might agree that the short run meant any period of time shorter than one complete business cycle. They might agree also that in dealing with the short run, the matter of economic growth could be ignored with impunity, since the amount of growth in the short run was generally negligible. Today, however, a large and increasing number of economists in the United States realize that when an economy as large as ours is growing at an average annual rate of 3% percent, the average growth of a single year accounts for a real increase of approximately $14 billion in net national product and a correspondingly substantial increase in employment. They realize too that with our population and labor force increasing at their current rate, growth must be maintained at all times, if "useful employment opportunities" are to be created7 and maintained for all "those able, willing, and seeking to work.' And they are aware of the corollary of these facts; namely, that even a comparatively short cessation or interruption of economic growth will result in a large increase in unemployment. In other words, we must run just to keep up with ourselves. But, as Roy F. Harrod and Evsey D. Domar have both demonstrated, the rate of speed at which we run is also important. If we proceed too slowly, we will still be faced with increasing unemployment. On the other hand, a sharp increase to a rate above that which can be maintained for a long period of time will result in an unhealthy inflationary situation which paves the way for future contraction or recession. Thus within the past few years it has become increasingly common for public officials to link the words "stability" and "growth" together and to use them as one term in discussing the objectives of the Employment Act and the implementation of the act. The two are conceived of as being closely interrelated, indeed, interdependent. For economic stability is thought of not in the dictionary sense of permanence or absence of change, but rather in the sense of minimum fluctuations around the growth trend. Growth itself is generally equated with the real increase in net national product. It is fairly easy to understand why the 2 words are so often linked together and used as 1 term. Each of them expresses one aspect of the type of economic process which is consistent with the stated objectives of the Employment Act and indeed necessary for achieving those objectives. Yet neither of them by itself is sufficient. The word "stability" by itself is not satisfactory for this purpose. We must know something of the level at which stability is to be maintained. But the level which is satisfactory now will be unsatisfactory a year from now and still less satisfactory a year after that. On the other hand, the word "growth" by itself is not completely satisfactory. Growth must proceed at a rate such that it can be maintained in the long run. Some fluctuations in the rate of growth, it is 64 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH generally realized, must occur and must be tolerated in a free society, but those fluctuations should be relatively minor. In other words, economic growth should proceed at a relatively stable rate. Such usage of the words "stability" and "growth" by public officials is probably in accord with prevailing opinion among reputable economists today. But is this usage really desirable? Attention has already been called to the fact that the meaning generally ascribed to the word "stability" in current discussions of the Employment Act is very different from the dictionary meaning. It is different, too, from the meaning generally ascribed 'to the word only a few decades ago by both economists and policymakers. And it is certainly different from the meaning currently ascribed to "stability9' by economists and policymakers when they discuss price stability. In view of these facts, the current usage of the word "stability" in discussions of the general objectives of the Employment Act is bound to be confusing, at least occasionally. In addition, if the type of growth which is desirable and consistent with the objectives of the act is a stable rate of growth, the use of the word "stability" in the term "stability and growth" is somewhat redundant. If the word "growth" by itself is considered inadequate to convey so complex a meaning, or if we wish to be more explicit on this score, might it not be preferable simply to make use of the expression "a steady rate of economic growth" or "a stable rate of economic growth" in our thinking and talking and writing, rather than "economic stability and growth" ? It would be desirable also for those who use the word "growth" either in theoretical analysis or in discussions of economic policy, to give more frequent explicit recognition to the fact that economic growth is not uniquely determined by technological change and/or changes in the size of the labor force. The rate of economic growth is more properly thought of as resulting from the interaction of a number of factors. Both technological change and an increase in the size of the labor force, whether occasioned by population growth or by change in social conventions and attitudes, are of course important in this connection. But their importance should not cause us to overlook the role played by such factors as newly developed forms of business organization and new business methods, increased accumulation and application of capital even in the absence of technological change, increased utilization of existing capital, an increase in hours worked, or an increase in the availability of natural resources. m Both Domar and Harrod have demonstrated that while growth does not insure stability unless the proper rate of growth is achieved and maintained, it is possible to determine theoretically a stable rate of growth for a free economy under certain specified conditions. But is a stable rate of growth for the economy of the United States actuallv a realizable ideal ? Practically all economists today recognize that there is some relationship between economic fluctuations and economic growth. It is rather generally realized that economic growth does not proceed smoothly or evenly. During some periods growth is retarded. At times it may even stop or be reversed. During other periods growth is accelerated, sometimes slightly, and sometimes considerably more than slightly. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 65 Not all economists agree on the precise nature of this relationship, however. There are probably a large number who, even if they have not followed or do not accept all the details of Harrod's and Domar's demonstrations, nevertheless do accept their general conclusion that a tendency to instability is inherent in the growth process; i. e., that departures from a stable rate of growth will not automatically be corrected, but will instead lead to further departures. But while some economists believe that the fluctuations accompanying growth are necessarily cyclical in character, others believe that this need not be so. The distinguished British economist, Harrod, although he does not believe the existence of cyclical fluctuations in the real world is caused solely by growth, has nevertheless demonstrated that an understanding of the growth process leads to the expectation that economic fluctuations of a cyclical nature will occur. His analysis leads to the conclusion that such fluctuations are not likely to be eliminated completely in a free society, where the actual rate of growth at any time is the result of the combined effect of so many different individual decisions. But Harrod does suggest the possibility of reducing the magnitude of the fluctuations by appropriate policies. The late Joseph A. Schumpeter believed that there is an inherent causal relationship between economic growth and cyclical fluctuations, and that cyclical fluctuations are the mechanism through which growth occurs. Devoted followers of Schumpeter may, therefore, question whether it is possible to maintain growth without cyclical fluctuations, and whether any attempts to eliminate or even sharply reduce cyclical fluctuations may not result in economic stagnation, or at least in a long-run rate of growth much lower than that which might otherwise prevail. Most economists in the United States today, however, do not subscribe to this point of view. A substantial number would probably agree that complete elimination of fluctuations—both cyclical and noncyclical—from the optimum rate of growth is impossible of achievement, at least in a free society, and that maintenance of a perfectly stable rate of economic growth in the United States for an extended period of time is, therefore, equally impossible—especially since the theoretical optimum itself may change from time to time. They would probably also agree, however, that the concept of a stable rate of economic growth is a useful one, not only as a theoretical tool of analysis, but as a guide for policymakers both in and out of the Government. It keeps us moving in the right direction, and while we may never quite reach it, we can certainly reduce the magnitude of fluctuations in economic activity and move closer to the ideal of a stable rate of growth than we have yet come. IV Economists are generally agreed that prices are closely and significantly related to the economic process and the general level of economic activity. They are agreed, too, that the role of prices is complex,, since they are a cause with respect to some economic phenomena, an effect with respect to others, and in many situations may be regarded as either cause or effect depending on the point of view or 66 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH point of departure of the analyst. Moreover, they are agreed that price developments may, and frequently do, have an important influence on the level of economic activity. With respect to the precise nature of that influence, however, opinion is divided. Within the past 2 years increasing attention has been given to the concept of price stability in discussions pertaining to the Employment Act of 1946. A number of economists and public officials have voiced the belief that stable prices are essential to the promotion and maintenance of maximum employment, production, and purchasing power. Some have even proposed that stable prices should formally be made a goal of public policy and that an explicit declaration to that effect should be incorporated in the Employment Act. Among those who have urged that the act be amended in this fashion are Arthur F. Burns and William McChesney Martin. These economists, of course, and others who have voiced similar opinions are concerned not with individual prices or price relationships, or even with prices and price relationships of groups of closely related commodities, but rather with the general price level. Often, however, for reasons which are wholly or largely practical, rather than conceptual in nature, "the level of consumer prices" is accepted either explicitly or implicitly as a substitute for "the general price level." Some economists who are in favor of amending the Employment Act believe that the goal of policy should be "reasonable price stability" ; while others apparently lean toward a more rigid or less flexible application of the concept of price stability by policymakers. In all cases, however, those who propose that the declaration of policy in the Employment Act be expanded to include price stability, use the word "stability" not in the sense in which it is often used in current discussions of the general level of economic activity (i. e., minimum fluctuations around the growth trend), but rather in the dictionary sense (i. e., steadiness, absence of change, permanence). In view of the eminence and prestige of some of the economists and public officials who have suggested that a stable price level be made an explicit goal of public policy by amending the Employment Act, it may seem bold to question the desirability of such action. Nevertheless, the present writers feel that it is important to raise this question. It may be well at this point to call attention to the fact that within the past few years there has been an increasing tendency to use the word "inflation" without defining it, and to'apply the term to any rise in the price level. Such loose usage can only result in a cer.tain degree of confusion and inconclusiveness in discussions pertaining to inflation and the price level, since not all participants are talking about the same thing. In the following pages the term "inflation" is used by the present writers only to describe a rise in the price level which is not accompanied or immediately followed by an increase in total production of at least equivalent significance. In accordance with this usage price rises which are accompanied or immediately followed by an equally significant (or a more than equally significant) increase in total production are not considered or labeled inflationary. The proposal that the declaration of policy in section 2 of the Employment Act be amended to include price stability, is generally based on two assumptions: (1) That in the absence of effective preventive measures, a rising price level will be a basic characteristic of the ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 67 American economy for many years to come; and (2) that effective implementation of the goal of price stability is and always will be consistent with the promotion and maintenance of maximum employment, production and purchasing power. A third assumption, although frequently omitted, or at least not clearly stated, should really also be included here": namely, that from a technical and administrative point of view stability of the price level constitutes a desirable goal of public policy. The assumption that a rising price level is virtually certain to be a feature of the American economy for an indefinitely long time to come is in turn generally based on one or more of the following assumptions: (1) That the expansionary forces which have played so important a role in shaping economic conditions in the United States since the end of World War I I will continue to play an equally important role in the future; (2) that in the future, economic recessions will be relatively infrequent, and also relatively short, and mild: No more protracted or serious than the two relatively minor recessions of 1949 and 1954, for example; and (3) that the Federal Government will deal with future economic recessions swiftly and effectively. The course of action pursued during the 1949 recession and that pursued during the 1954 recession, are frequently cited in support of this point. The future is, as ever, uncertain and in the end it may turn out that these assumptions were justified. Nevertheless, there are at present sound reasons to question the validity of each of these assumptions. If we analyze the forces making for economic expansion during the postwar period, it is apparent that we cannot expect them to operate in the same fashion throughout a future of indefinite duration. At the end of World War I I there was a huge backlog of pent-up demand for many types of consumer goods and capital goods, accompanied by a record volume of liquid savings held by both individuals and business firms. In addition, throughout the postwar period the United States has had a rapid rate of population growth, a rapid rate of technological advance, and a high level of public expenditures. The increase in Federal expenditures is by now a familiar story. It is perhaps less generally realized that from 1946 to 1957 total expenditures by State and local governments increased more than 250 percent. A considerable part of this increase can be ascribed to the backlog of unsatisfied needs which accumulated during World War II, and to the rapid rate of population growth. The backlog of pent-up demand in the private sector of the economy which existed at the end of World War I I persisted in making its effects felt for longer than was originally anticipated. It seems probable that the outbreak and the duration of hostilities in Korea were at least partly responsible for this prolongation. By now, however, the backlog of pent-up demand is, of course, a thing of the past. The rate of population growth continues high. But one of the lessons of the past 15 to 20 years has been that the rate of population growth is less stable than we formerly supposed. For many years the rate of population growth was considered to be subject to such slow, gradual change that the level of population could be predicted with con23734—58 6 68 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH siderable accuracy for some time ahead. More recent developments have routed this belief. As recently as 1940, many economists and public officials were concerned about the economic effects of the declining rate of population growth. There was no hint then of the change which was to occur within a few years. And when the change did become evident, it was for some years considered to be a purely temporary phenomenon. Knowing these things, it would be imprudent for us to base our cifrrent actions and plans on the expectation that the current rate of population increase will be maintained or will rise still further. Technological advance, although certainly an important factor, is notoriously unstable. Continuation and even expansion of the huge research and development programs which have provided the basis for most of the technological advance since World War I I will not insure the continuation of an equally rapid rate of technological advance in the years ahead. Research and development programs may produce inventions. But inventions are not synonymous with technological advance. New inventions result in technological advance only when economic conditions favor their economic exploitation. Schumpeter's theory that the rate of technological advance fluctuates in a cyclical pattern, although inventions may appear in a steady stream, is widely subscribed to by economists. Moreover, technological change does not necessarily result in a net addition to employment opportunities or to income. In many cases, the immediate effect of a labor-saving machine is to displace labor. Only if the surrounding economic conditions are favorable do the displaced workers find other employment opportunities. Similarly, a new product may simply displace an older product without increasing the total level of production. Government expenditures cannot be expected to rise as rapidly in the future as they have in the past 12 years, and it is not even certain that they will continue at their present level. National security expenditures, which accounted for 87.8 percent of total Federal purchases of goods and services from 1946 to 1957, are very largely responsible for the increase in Federal expenditures and for their current high level. Successful disarmament negotiations and/or a lessening of international tension, however, would undoubtedly result in a reduction in national security expenditures. Such developments do not appear probable in the immediate future. It is to be devoutly hoped that these developments will occur before very many years have passed, however. And in a world that is so full of surprises, they may occur much sooner than any of us dare hope at the moment. Even in the absence of successful disarmament negotiations and a lessening of international tension, there is a possibility that national security expenditures may decline in the years ahead. Modern implements of warfare may prove to be less expensive, in the aggregate, than the older implements they are displacing, and they may not become obsolete so quickly. State and local government expenditures will probably level off in the near future, and may even decline. Some States are already actively seeking methods of paring their budgets, and with a decline in the general level of economic activity other State and local governments may be expected to follow suit. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 69 The same arguments just marshaled to support the view that we cannot expect the forces making for economic expansion during the postwar period to continue operating in the same fashion indefinitely, may also be cited in questioning the validity of the assumption that future economic recessions will be relatively infrequent, and also relatively short and mild. Our experience since the end of World War I I gives us some basis ior hope on this score, but it does not provide a satisfactory basis for firm belief. The mildness of the recessions of 1949 and 1954 may very well be related to the strength of the forces we have just been discussing. If that is so, as these forces lose their strength we may once against experience more serious and protracted declines in economic activity. Eecent experience and our hopes for the future should not blind us to the fact that our basic economic institutions are still substantially the same as in the 1920's and the 1930's. The role of the capital .goods sector of our economy is as important as ever, and no foolproof method of eliminating the inherent instability of this sector of our •economy, or neutralizing the effects of this instability has yet been devised and tested. The Federal Government acted wisely and well to help counter the Recessions of 1949 and 1954. Those recessions, however, were essentially inventory recessions which are relatively simple to deal with and which in any case tend to be relatively mild and brief. A sharp decline in public expenditures or in investment outlays, might produce an economic decline of a more serious character. We do not yet know whether the Federal Government can act with the requisite speed and .effectiveness in the face of such a situation. Moreover, in any actual situation it is no longer a question of what tthe political authorities can do but what they will do. Consider the sharp differences of opinion being expressed about the nature and scope of the measures which should be adopted to deal with the present economic recession. When conflicting advice is offered a choice must be made, and the choice may prove to be faulty. If this occurs, even a decline which theoretically could be arrested will not be arrested. J t may instead deteriorate into a genuine depression. VI The second assumption of those who propose amending the Employment Act to include price stability as a goal of public policy, is that effective implementation of the goal of price stability is and always -will be consistent with the promotion and maintenance of maximum employment, production, and purchasing power. If ibis assumption is evaluated on the basis of either history or theory, however, it appears to be of questionable validity. It is generally accepted that economic growth is necessary for the promotion and maintenance of maximum employment, production and purchasing power. And the historical record reveals a remarkably close relation between economic growth and a rising price level., In the past, economic growth has occurred largely during the expanding phase of the business cycle. The tendency of prices to rise 70 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH during a cyclical expansion has been recognized by virtually all economists. Arthur F. Burns himself writes: One of the plainest teachings of history is that rising prices are a recurring feature of the expanding phase of the business cycle.1 Moreover, the work of Simon Kuznets indicates that this relation between rising prices and economic growth is not purely a short-run phenomenon: it holds good in the long run as well.2 Theoretical analysis suggests that the association of rising prices with economic expansion or growth in the past has not been fortuitous, and that a similar association may be expected in the future. Economic expansion or growth occurs when aggregate demand is strong in relation to current output, and gives evidence of increasing further. These are the same conditions which provide the basis for rising prices. When aggregate demand is not strong in relation to current output, and when there is no evidence that demand is increasing, there is no sound basis for rising prices, and at the same time no reason for economic production and capacity to increase. Moreover, a slowly or moderatively rising price level tends to encourage economic expansion and growth. Since interest rates and wage rates tend to lag behind other price changes, a slowly or moderately rising price level is,generally associated with rising profits. In addition, both consumers and business firms tend to satisfy their needs more promptly and even to anticipate them to some extent when the price level is rising, so that the increase in prices tends to enhance demand. Businessmen thus have a double incentive to expand their output and capacity. Nothing herein should be construed to mean that a rising price level is desirable under all circumstances, or that a continuously rising price level is a necessary requisite for continuous economic growth. The conclusion suggested is much more modest—namely, it does not appear likely that price stability will, under all circumstances which may arise in the future, be consistent with promotion and maintenance of maximum employment, production, and purchasing power. VII The assumption that price stability constitutes a desirable goal of public policy from a technical and administrative point of view is seldom, if ever, explicitly stated by those who propose that the declaration of policy of the Employment Act be amended to include maintenance of a stable price level as one of the objectives of public policy. But this assumption must be accepted by anyone who seriously considers the proposed amendment necessary. Here again, however, past experience and theoretical considerations both give rise to several questions. Since it does not appear likely that price stability will, under all circumstances which may arise in the future, be consistent with promotion and maintenance of maximum employment, production, and purchasing power, if price stability is added to the Employment Act, policymaking officials will sometimes be faced with the necessity of choosing between price stability and the other objectives of the act. 1 2 Arthur F. Burns, Prosperity Without Inflation (Fordham University Press, 1957), p. 12. Simon S. Kuznets, Secular Movements in Production and Prices (Houghton Mifflin Co 1930), pp. 200-2. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 71 This will tend to cause confusion and dissension, and may result in other undesirable consequences as well. If price stability is always granted priority, this will greatly limit the flexibility of action which it is desirable and presently possible for policymaking officials to exercise. It may seriously reduce our chances of realizing or approximating the optimum growth rate. If price stability is not always to be granted priority, it does not really constitute a very satisfactory guide to policymakers without some indication of the circumstances under which it is to receive priority or the level at which they should attempt to maintain stability. Would all price rises be regarded as inflationary ? Or would some attempt be made to distinguish between a price rise accompanying an expansion in economic activity following an economic recession, and a truly inflationary situation? If so, how would the distinction be made ? In particular cases, it might well prove necessary to decide when healthy economic expansion ends and when inflation begins. And similarly, would all downward movements in the price level be regarded as unhealthy? If not, how would the distinction be made between those which should be tolerated and permitted to run their course and those which should be halted or reversed ? If the goal of price stability is not to be granted priority except at the discretion of policymaking officials, or if price movements are merely to be one of a number of factors considered by policymaking officials in reaching decisions on public policy, why is it necessary to amend the Employment Act? Surely price movements are already seriously studied and taken into account by those responsible for giving effect to the provisions of the Employment Act. In this connection it is perhaps worth quoting from a paper submitted to the Joint Committee on the Economic Report in 1955 by Alvin H. Hansen: A high degree of stability ill the value of money must be an important consideration of public policy. Yet we are * * * in considerable danger of making a fetish of rigid price stability. This fetish could easily become a serious obstacle to optimum expansion and growth.3 I t seems pertinent also to raise the question of whether price stability constitutes a feasible goal of public policy. Quite aside from any of th.6 finer technical points involved here, is our current knowledge of economic theory, techniques of public policy and the manner in which our economy functions and responds to policy decisions, sufficiently far advanced so that we can realize the goal of price stability ? If the answer be made that although we cannot achieve complete stability, we may nevertheless achieve reasonable stability, it merely raises another question. What is reasonable for this purpose ? If the act does not specify, it must be left to the discretion of policymaking officials. But is that not where the matter stands right now without any amendment ? Actually, current developments as well as those of the recent and more distant past indicate that change or lack of change in the price level does not always constitute a very useful guide to policymakers who must decide what course of action to recommend or pursue. Fedea Tax Policy for Economic Growth and. Stability (U. S. Government Printing Office, 1955>, p. 17. 72 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Prices tend to lag behind changes in underlying economic conditions. Price movements are, therefore, frequently a tardy indicator of the need for action. They may give warning after the event has alreacly occurred, or after the time for successful application of restraining or corrective measures has already passed. Considered by themselves they may even suggest the need for action of a type which is clearly inappropriate in the light of other economic indicators. The continuing rise in the Bureau of Labor Statistics cost-of-living index during the current economic recession is a case in point. The decline in the BLS Consumer Price Index from 1926 to 1929 to another. Similarly, stability of a price index is not always an indication that all is well, nor does it always augur well for the future. Consider, for example, the remarkable stability of the BLS Wholesale Price Index from the beginning of 1927 to the autumn of 1929. A price index may remain stable even if significant fluctuations occur among various components of the index. The relative stability of the BLS Consumer Price Index from 1952 to 1955 was actually the result of a decrease in prices of many commodities and a simultaneous increase in prices of services. The relative stability of the Wholesale Price Index over the same period was actually the result of a decrease in wholesale prices of farm products and processed foods and a simultaneous increase in prices of other commodities. At times, changes in the components of a price index are more significant and more useful as guides to policy makers than relative stability of the total index. Consider also the possibility of a general price decline which might occur as the result of increasing productivity. This is no longer considered a very likely development by most economists. But if it did occur, should the price decline be accepted as an indication that corrective or restraining measures are desirable? Actually, of course, in a technical or statistical sense, there is no such thing as a the general price level." It is well known that although we do have several good indexes which are useful for measuring price movements affecting specific aspects of our economy, we do not have a satisfactory index of general price movements, nor are we likely to have one in the foreseeable future. What, then, should be used as an indicator of general price movements? Since the different indexes useful for specific purposes sometimes move in diverse fashion, they cannot all be given equal considerations in deciding matters of general policy. It is necessary to choose among them. At present there is considerable support for using the BLS Consumer Price Index as an indicator of price movements for general policy purposes. Undoubtedly, this proposal has much to commend it from a political point of view. In the past, however, most economists and statisticians have leaned toward the view that the Consumer Price Index is less useful than the Wholesale Price Index for this purpose. This attitude was based on their recognition that consumer prices tend to lag behind wholesale prices, and that wholesale prices are most basically and intimately related to the economic process than consumer prices. This jpoint of view is quite as valid now as it ever was. These technical and administrative considerations point to the same conclusion indicated by the arguments presented in the preceding two ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 73 sections of this paper; namely, that it would be unwise to amend the Employment Act by adding price stability to the objectives presently included in the declaration of policy. vm It is perhaps worth noting that several times in the past when congressional action has been proposed to make price stability the sole or chief goal of the policies and actions of the Federal Reserve Board, Federal Reserve officials have presented eloquent testimony in opposition to these proposals, and have made use of some—although not all—of the same arguments cited above. Even now, despite Chairman William McChesney Martin's public statements in favor of the proposal that the goal of price stability be incorporated in the Employment Act, the members of the Board of Governors apparently are not unanimously agreed on the desirability of this proposal. Not very long ago, Charles N. Shepardson, a member of the Board of Governors, observed: As is evident, we have not been completely successful in our efforts to contain inflationary pressures. But perhaps we should not be too severe on this lack of perfection. I doubt that perfect price stability can ever be achieved in a free-enterprise system, or any other system for that matter. Furthermore, I am not at all sure that it would be wholly desirable. Some upward drift in prices during periods when demands are pressing against our resources and some decline following these unusual periods of hyperactivity are not only unavoidable but perform a useful function in helping to bring about adjustment of spending and saving decisions in the economy.4 One of the arguments most frequently cited by those who favor amending the Employment Act by adding price stability to the declaration of policy, is that even a slowly or moderately rising price level has uneven economic effects and that it has particularly undesirable effects on retired persons living on past savings, on recipients of pensions or annuities, and other individuals with fixed incomes. In arguing against the proposed amendment to the Employment Act, the writers do not wish to appear unmindful of the validity of this argument. But the validity of this argument does not weaken our position. The point of view expressed in this paper is, first of all, based on the belief that policymaking officials already have ample basis for adopting measures to restrain undesirable price rises. More rigid adherence to the goal of price stability might have undesirable effects on the general level of economic activity and the general level of economic well-being which would far outweigh the possible beneficial effect on the groups referred to in the preceding paragraph. It might even have undesirable effects on some of the individuals in these groups. In a severe economic contraction, individuals sometimes lose all or a substantial part of their savings very quickly. Business firms necessarily reduce or suspend dividend payments and sometimes default on contractual interest payments as well. Many incomes which are customarily regarded as fixed nevertheless do decline during a protracted depression. 4 See his talk before the National Agricultural Credit Conference in November 21, 1957,. entitled, "Monetary Policy in Our Economic Climate," p. 11. 74 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Rigid adherence to the goal of price stability might thus do more harm than good even to the group it was intended to help. I t would seem preferable, therefore, not to rely on price stability for this purpose, but rather to devise new techniques more specifically directed toward the special problems of this group, which would not involve the possibility of such widespread undesirable side effects. II THE MEASUREMENT OF PRICE CHANGES AND PRICE RELATIONSHIPS 75 / / . The measurement of price changes and price relationships A. How do changing technology, changing physical characteristics, changing uses of products and services, affect the significance and usefulness of price comparisons between different time periods ? B. What is the distinction between relative price movements and changes in "the price level" ? C. Given today's markets and institutions, what are the identifying characteristics of "administered" compared with "competitive" prices ? D. What would be the characteristics of a general price index adequate for economic policy purposes ? Would more than one index be needed ? If so, why ? E. When "the price level" enters into decisions about policies to promote economic stability and growth, which of the available indexes would, in theory, be best as a measure of general price movements; e. g., the Consumer Price Index, the Wholesale Price Index, the gross national product deflators, or other ? How could existing indexes be improved to come closer to the ideal ? 76 THE MEASUREMENT OF PRICE CHANGES Kenneth J. Arrow,1 Stanford University In this paper I will be concerned almost exclusively with measurement of the cost of living, or the Consumer Price Index, as it is now called. It is this field of price indexes to which economic theory has made the most important contributions directly. However, I am quite convinced that there are no great differences in principle as far as other price indexes, such as the Wholesale Price Index, are concerned. All commodities in a sense are intended ultimately for consumption and therefore all prices reflect indirectly the valuations placed on them by ultimate consumers (including, in many cases, investors). Stress will be laid on the theoretical contributions. Recommendations as to sources of data and representativeness of sampling can hardly be done effectively by one outside the Government agencies responsible. I. BASIC CONSIDERATIONS A consumers' price index is a measure for one period of time, say 1, with respect to another period, say 0. It is generally defined as the ratio of the expenditures needed in time 1 to maintain a given standard of living, to the expenditures needed in time 0 for the same purpose. The standard of living for this purpose clearly cannot be identified with a fixed basket of commodities. Suppose, for example, that in the base period 0, the price of beef is high, while that of lamb is low, while the reverse is true in period 1 due to, say, a change in supply conditions. We would expect the consumer will purchase a great deal of lamb and relatively little beef in period 0, and the reverse in period 1. If we use as a fixed basket of goods that consumed in the base period, then we will find a rise in the cost of living because the lamb, which has appeared so strongly in period 0, has undergone a price rise. On the other hand, the reverse would be true if we started with period 1 as the base period. There seems no recourse but to recognize frankly that a standard of living is not any fixed basket of goods, but a subjective level of satisfaction. In the example just given, it may well be that the consumer feels about as well off in one period as another since he has had a chance to compensate for the price changes by changes in the proportions in which different commodities are consumed. The Government statistician, for obvious reasons, shies away from the notion of tying the objective-seeming price index to subjective concepts of utility or satisfaction, but in fact there is no escape in this proposition. Any attempt to explain the meaning of the cost-of-living index must eventually come to the notions just described unless we are to stop at banal lf This paper was prepared during the tenure of a Ford Foundation faculty research fellowship. I wish to thank also the Office of Naval Research, whose grant permitted research and secretarial assistance. 77 78 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH tautologies analogous to "national income is that which is measured by national income statisticians." It is, of course, perfectly true that we are not in the position now, and we may never be, to measure the subjective satisfactions of consumers directly. However, as the previous example already hints, economic theory argues that something, at least, can be learned by studying the overt behavior of the individual on the market. The reason is that the individual is motivated to secure for himself the highest utility consistent with his monetary resources. His utilities or satisfactions then are already reflected in market behavior and it is not implausible, therefore, that we may use this behavior to cast some light upon his satisfactions and in particular upon the cost-of-livingindex as defined previously. Unfortunately, as is well known, the inference from quantities and prices observed to the true cost-of-living index is by no means a simple one. Let us consider the simplest inference, a very well-known one. Suppose we wish to know the cost-of-living index defined as the minimum expenditure in period 1 needed to obtain the level of satisfaction of period 0 as a ratio to the expenditure in period 0. One way to make sure to achieve the same level of satisfaction in period 1 as in period 0 is to purchase the same goods. This will, in general, not be the cheapest way of achieving that level of satisfaction. Let p 0 and pi denote prices in periods 0 and 1, respectively, and let q0 represent quantities in period 0. Then the above reasoning shows that— will be at least as great and probably greater than the true cost-of Iiving index. We thus see that price-quantity figures permit some inference as to the true cost-of-living index. In this case, they set an upper bound, but we also see that a simple set of figures does not give a complete determination. In particular, the formula used is a base-year weighted price index (frequently referred to as Laspeyres' formula); that is, it is precisely the formula which is used in most ordinary statistical work. We see, then, that this formula tends to overstate the rise in the cost of living from any fixed base. It is indirectly the realization of this fact which causes the base to be revised as frequently as it is. In the following sections we will suggest the use of additional information other than that used in the formula just given to narrow down the limits which we can place on the true cost-of-living index by inference from price-quantity observations. n . THE USE OF ENGEL CURVES FOR PRICE INDEXES The definition of the cost-of-living index number suggests immediately that it really should not be regarded as a single number. The cost-of-living index number corresponding to one level of satisfaction in a base period may be very different from that in another. This shows up conspicuously when the differences are large, as between poor and rich. The consumption pattern of the rich is quite different from that of the poor and a, shift in prices which increases the cost of living to one may decrease it to another. Thus, if servants' wages rise while ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 79 the prices of manufactured goods fall, it may well be that the expenditure needed by a wealthy person to maintain his standard of living; i. e.? his level of satisfaction, will be going up, while that of the poor person is going down. This fact is implicitly recognized in index numbers which restrict their announced coverage to "middle-income families," but it argues that quite a bit more can be done along these lines. There should be a separate cost-of-living index number for each income level. Empirical data on which any such index numbers are stressed are found in budget studies. For those, we have 2 years, 0 and 1, in which the budgets of individuals over a wide range of incomes have been made available. For each commodity, we can find the average consumption in each income class. The relation between consumption of a particular commodity and income is known as an Engel curve, after the German statistician of the last century, who pioneered in this area. We assume, then, that we have an Engel curve for each commodity in each of the 2 years under consideration. We now construct two new curves which represent, at each income level, the purchases of commodities in 1 year evaluated at the prices of the other. Thus, if Ei represents an expenditure level in year 1, take the average amounts consumed of each commodity by those with expenditure level Ei, and calculate what that bundle would have cost in the prices of year 0. In symbols, if qi(Ei) represents quantities purchased in year 1, when total expenditures are E a , then in the notation previously used, we calculate which will be designated as E 1 0 (Ei). A similar calculation can be made interchanging the roles of the years 0 and 1. Thus, we have a second curve E O i(E o ). For any expenditure level E o in year 0, let q o (E o ) be the commodities purchased by individuals whose total expenditure was E o . Then EOi (Eo) = We will plot the two curves on the following diagram, figure 1 (p. 87). The horizontal axis represents expenditures in year 0, the vertical axis those in year 1. The curve E O i(E o ) will be plotted against the horizontal axis. The curve E 10 (Ei) will be plotted against the vertical axis. The problem of finding the true cost of living is that of matching tip expenditures E o and E x so that for each value Ep we find the corresponding minimum expenditure E x which will yield the same level of satisfaction. We want then a curve relating the two variables. To read a cost of living index number for any given level of satisfaction on this curve, we may take a particular value of E o and find the corresponding value of E x ; the ratio of these two values is the cost of living index corresponding to an expenditure level of E o in the base period. The fact that the curve will not usually be a straight line to the origin shows that the cost of living index number will in general vary by income levels. The question is the determination, or at least the approximation, of this expenditure-equivalence curve- The reasoning of the preceding section shows that for any E o , E 0 i(E o ) is an overstatement of the 80 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH equivalent expenditure in year 1. Reversal of the argument shows that for any expenditure E x in year 1, the number Eio(E;i) is an overstatement of the equivalent expenditure in year 0. Therefore we can say without any further discussion that the expenditureequivalence curve must lie between the two curves E O i(E o ) and E K ^ E X ) . For a verbal reference, we will refer to the first of these as the current-year weighted base-year expenditure curve and the base-year weighted current-year expenditure curve. It is already clear from this discussion how much more information is contained about the cost of living index by the knowledge of the two sets of Engel curves than from simply knowing some kind of national average. The latter at best amounts to knowing one point on each of the two expenditure curves. While there is some information contained in this statement since the expenditure-equivalence curve would have to lie between the two points, it is clear that the restrictions on the location of the curve are not very severe.2 In many cases the two expenditure curves will be very close together so that the expenditure-equivalence curve will be determined quite accurately. An approximation formula has been developed for the interpolation of expenditure-equivalence curve by the late Abraham Wald.3 If we refer to figure 1, we can take any base year expenditure E o and find from the curve E K ^ E J ) that expenditure in year 1 for which the base-year weighted expenditures are equal to E o . In the diagram this value is represented by Ei O *(E o ). It is clear from the diagram that this value is an underestimate of the equivalent expenditure m year 1. We have already noted that E O i(E o ) is an overestimate of the equivalent expenditures. It is natural then to seek for a method of averaging the two. The particular average suggested by Wald is the following: Let aOi be the slope of the upper curve at point B, and let a* (Oi) be the slope of the lower curve at A. In both cases the slope is found with respect to the E0-axis, that is, the way the curves are drawn now. Then Wald's formula is In the present state of theory this seems about as satisfactory a formula as can be found. I t will, of course, be objected that obtaining Engel curves from annual budget studies is an expensive operation. Here, as elsewhere, the rule that you don't get something for nothing is applicable. It seems clear that higher accuracy in the index numbers require greater expenditure by the Government. The value received in terms of ability to make better economic plans will unquestionably repay additional expenditures many fold over. This is especially true in the present context because annual budget studies have many other uses than the improvement of index numbers. (Changing consumption patterns will be detected at a much earlier a The importance of Engel curves for a more accurate determination of price index numr bers was first pointed out by Ragnar Frisch. For a very clear exposition at greater length than the above, see his paper, Some Basic Principles of Price of Living Measurements, Econometrica, vol. 22, No. 4, October 1954, pp. 407-421. 9 Wald's results were first published in A New Formula for the Index of Cost of Living, Econometrica, vol. 7, No. 4, October 1939, pp. 319-331. For a simpler exposition, see K. S. Banerjee, Simplification of the Derivation of Wald's Formula for the Cost of Living Index, Econometrica, vol. 24, No. 4, July 195-6, pp. 296-298. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 81 stage and will find a great deal of use both in private industry and in many Government policies, such as the prediction of revenues from excise taxes; the consumption weights used in national income calculations can be greatly improved. I would further urge that if budget studies were put on an annual basis provisions be made that a major proportion of the families be reinterviewed annually. The value of panel studies—that is, repeated studies on the same individuals has been amply demonstrated in recent work on consumption patterns as well as on sociological phenomena. The effect of income changes and changing age and family composition on consumption can be studied in this way as in no other. The variability of income and expenditures over time will form an important tool in the study of income distributions. There are thus many side benefits to annual budget studies and their analysis in terms of Engel curves, so that one can easily justify the additional expenditure. m . MULTIPLE TIME COMPARISONS The preceding section has dealt with comparisons between 2 points of time, say 2 successive years. However, one of the main functions of an index number is to provide a time series for the cost of living. We would like to be able, in fact, to make all sorts of comparisons including, ideally, comparisons of the cost of living in periods quite remote in time. To begin with, we will consider only the single comparisons based on national averages which are currently used, and abandon the Engel-curve approach of the last section. It has been seen to begin with that the use of quantity weights as of a fixed time period tends to overstate the increase in the cost of living in a subsequent time period. Thus, if 1947 rates are used, the price index of 1955 will be higher with respect to 1947 than it should be. The same will be true of the price index of 1956. The indexes are also used to compare 1955 with 1956. Here it is not clear what the bias will be but it is clear that the 1947 quantity rates may or may not be very useful ones for the 1955-56 comparison. There is a considerable divergence of viewpoint here between the practice of statisticians of almost all governments and the views of index number theorists. In comparisons involving distant points of time, index number theorists generally take 1 of 2 positions: Either they argue the comparison between any 2 years should be based solely on the data for those 2 years and not on any others, or they advocate a chain index. In a chain index comparisons are made only for adjacent years directly. The resulting index numbers for pairs of years are then multiplied together in an obvious way to get index number comparisons between years which are not consecutive. Thus, an index number for 1949 with respect to 1947 would be obtained by multiplying the index for 1948 with respect to 1947 by the index for 1949 with respect to 1948. It is not possible to give a definitive argument on the relative merits of chain index numbers and the more conventional fixed weight index numbers, primarily because neither is a thoroughly accurate solution. Nevertheless, there are some considerations that suggest that as between the two, the chain index number is preferable. 82 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH First, it is clear from the preceding discussion that the difficulty with index number comparisons arises because of the inadequate knowledge of the want structure of the individual. An increase in the number of observations made on market behavior would be expected to increase the possible accuracy of index numbers.4 The upward bias in base-year-weighted index numbers illustrates the inevitable errors due to the use of a limited number of observations— in this case, a pair. A chain index number between 2 points of time separated, say, by 5 or 6 years, makes use of all the intermediate observations. Second, the difficulties and possible errors of index number comparisons are increased when the consumption patterns in the two periods being compared are farther apart. Economic magnitudes tend to change continuously. Comparisons of adjacent years, then, are comparisons between more nearly homogeneous universes. It is more legitimate to use various approximations such as averaging of quantity weights. Indeed, the weights based on quantities in 2 adjacent years will differ less than they will in years taken further apart, as a rule. Therefore, each link in the chain index number will be more accurate than direct comparisons at some distance apart. That these considerations play some role in practice is shown by the relatively frequently changes in base years employed in practice. If the base of an index number is changed relatively frequently, there is in effect a chain index number, calculated perhaps on a quinquennial rather than annual basis. Once the need for changing bases is recognized, it becomes merely a question of discussing the optimal frequency. An attempt at a logical foundation for chain indexes has been given by Frangois Divisia.5 If we write down the statement that total expenditures equals the sum of expenditures on individual items, where expenditures on any one item is equal to the product in price and quantity, E=Spq, then during a small period of time the change in the rate of expenditures can be expressed approximately in the following way: AE=2pAq+SqAp. Here the symbol A means "change in." This formula assumes that in a small period of time prices and quantities can only change by small amounts. The first term represents that part of the change in expenditures attributable to a change in quantities evaluated at the original prices and can therefore be thought of as the change in a certain quantity index. Similarly, the second term can be thought of as attributable to the change in prices using quantities as weights. If we imagine that we have both a price index and a quantity index, it is natural to demand that their product be equal to total expenditures E = PQ and therefore a small change in expenditures will be approximately expressed by A E = P A Q + Q A P . Comparison of the two formulas for AE suggests that the right-hand sides can be identified term for term. Carrying out in detail the reasoning suggested here shows that the price index is a chain index with quantity weights. In each length of the chain, if the links are sufficiently short, * For a more extended discussion of the possibilities and limits of improving index number comparisons by increased observations, see Paul A. Samuelson, Foundations of Economic Analysis, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1947, pp. 146-163. 5 For a description of Divisia's viewpoint, see Erland v. Hofsten, Price Indexes and Quality Changes, Stockholm: Bokforlaget Forum, and London: George Allen and Unwin. 1952, pp. 21-23. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 83 the base-year and current-year quantities will be very similar so that it makes little difference which is used. Ideally, actually, the links should be very short in time indeed but there are some difficulties with seasonal fluctuations which suggest that it is unwise to use periods shorter than 1 year. Divisia's reasoning is plausible but is not closely tied to the definition of a cost-of-living index in terms of expenditures needed to maintain a given level of satisfaction. The connection between the 6two concepts has been investigated to a certain extent by Jean Ville. In general he shows that the chain index does not give exactly the true cost of living index except in the special case where at any fixed set of prices an individual will divide his income among different commodities in the same proportions, regardless of the level of his income. That is, the Engel curves are straight lines through the origin. This case is, of course, unrealistic although it may be approximately valid for relatively small changes in real income. The reasons why the chain index falls short of perfection can be put in different ways. One thing to note is if additional observations are designed to get a better knowledge of the want structure of the individual, then there is no reason to confine oneself to observations in temporal order. All information within a time period in which wants can be regarded as homogeneous should be equally relevant to a comparison between any two time periods. Another point is that if the level of satisfaction of the population is rising as is usual, then the comparison between successive years referred to different levels of satisfactions. After a period of time, then, the chaining involves price changes which are irrelevant to different standards of living. The special case, which Ville discussed, is one in which the consumption pattern is the same at all levels of satisfaction and so no ambiguity arises. One form in which these imperfections may show up is the following paradox: It can happen that prices vary over time in such a way that after a few years, let us say, they return to their initial values^ Obviously in that case, any properly defined price index should be equal to 100 as between the. beginning and end years. Yet it is possible for a chain index number to differ from 100, either above or balow. If, for example, as is usual in seasonal fluctuations, prices tend to be high when quantities are low, and vice 7versa, then in general the chain index will tend to give too high a value. Too much should not be made, however, of paradoxes like this. Virtually any index number known can lead to similar difficulties in suitably unfavorable circumstances. On balance, the case for chain index numbers as opposed to fixed weight aggregates seems strong in spite of the drawbacks just noted.8 However, the case is considerably strengthened if we combine the chain index of this section with the Engel curve methods of the last. Since each pairwise Engel curve comparison gives us a complete set of equivalences between expenditures in one year and expenditures in 6 See his paper, "Sur les conditions d'existence (Tune ophelimite totale et d'un indice dn niveau des prix, Annales de l'l'niversite de Lyon, sec. A (3), vol. 0 (194fi), pp. 32-39, particularly pp. 36-38: translated into English as The Existence-Conditions of a Total Utility tility Function, Review of Economic Studies, vol. XIX (1051-52), pp. 123-128, particularly pp. p. 125-127. »TMss was pointed out by Ladislaus von Bortkiewicz; see v. Hofsten, op. cit., pp. 1415,8 27. This position is also taken by Frisch, op. cit., p. 417, and Bruce D. Mudgett, Index Numbers, New York: John Wiley & Sons, and London: Chapman and Hall, 1951, pp. 70-79, 23734—58 7 84 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH the next, the chaining is quite straightforward. Given any expenditure level in, say, 1947, we can find expenditure in 1948 which gives approximately the same level of satisfaction. Starting with expenditure levels for 1948, we can find the corresponding expenditure levels for 1949. By linking the two pieces of information we can find an equivalence between expenditure levels in 1947 and 1949. This is still a chain comparison subject to the disabilities noted above. It finds its primary justification in the assumption that neighboring comparisons are apt to be more accurate than those at a distance. In terms of figure 1 the two bounding curves are apt to be much closer together than they are for comparisons of several years apart. A more experimental approach to index numbers based on multiple comparisons of time has been originated in a paper by Lawrence R. Klein and Herman Rubin.9 If we have observations for a number of years, we have some possibility of estimating the effect of price changes on the consumption of different commodities. One can hope, at least, to obtain demand functions which express the consumption of any commodity in terms of the prices of that commodity and competitive ones, and the income of the country or of the individual if we have observations on separate individuals. If the demand functions are accurately obtained, it is possible to infer the underlying want structure and therewith to make all desired cost of living comparisons. The problem resides in the difficulty in accurately determining statistical demand functions; nevertheless a great deal of progress has been made on this in recent years. It would seem worth while to experiment with this approach in different w^ays and see how it compares with other, more traditional methods. In principle, it is certainly the most satisfactory since, for example, all observations are treated equally thereby using more information.10 IV. THE PROBLEM OF QUALITY CHANGES One of the greatest problems in any index number comparisons over time is that of changes in the quality of existing commodities or the introduction of new ones. A thorough theoretical analysis of the subject is found in the book of Erland von11Hof sten who has been in charge of the Swedish cost of living index. We will discuss the problem here mainly from the Engel curve viewpoint of section II. It should be made clear that we are discussing this problem at a theoretical level where it is assumed that we have a price for every conceivable commodity, including every variety. We ignore here the 9 A Constant-Utility Index of the Cost of Living, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 15, 1948, pp. 84-87. 10 Klein and Rubin analyzed the particular case where the demand functions are such that the expenditure for any commodity is a linear function of prices and income. They obtain, therefore, a specific formula for the cost of living index number. Paul Samuelson has objected that the linear demand functions are not likely to be found in practice; see Some Implications of Linearity, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 15, 1948, pp. 88-90. However, linear functions have been fitted to British data by J. R. N. Stone; see Linear Expenditure Systems and Demand Analysis : An Application to the Pattern of British Demand, Economic Journal, vol. LXIV, No. 255>, September 1954, pp. 511—527. For an excellent exposition, see Ragnar Frisch, Linear Expenditure Functions, Econometrica, vol. 22, No. 4, October 1954, pp. 505-510. Klein and Rubin assumed that the demand functions needed for their index would be obtained statistically by fitting to aggregate data. If Engel curves were available for each year, the chances of reliable fits would be much improved. In any case, it should be made clear that any statistically derived demand functions which satisfy certain consistency conditions can be used to derive index numbers ; they need not be of the linear form assumed by Klein and Rubin. 11 For reference, see footnote 5. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 85 question of sampling in groups of related goods at a representative price. The splicing method frequently used in discussing quality changes depends in part on a sampling concept as well as a purely theoretical one. The difficulties attached12 to the sampling process have been ably pointed out by von Hof sten. At this level of abstraction there is no logical difference between a different variety of the same commodity and a different commodity. We will assume our classification as fine as called for by the circumstances so that, for example, two different models of Cadillacs are to be regarded as separate commodities. Suppose then we observe, in comparing year 0 with year 1, that a commodity appears in year 1 which was not consumed at all in year 0. Actually, from the Engel curve point of view, the problem might arise at each expenditure level. We may find a commodity purchased only by upper income people in year 0 which is now purchased in year 1 by lower income individuals. We will postulate that the want structure of individuals is the same in the two situations in spite of the introduction of a new commodity. The absence of a commodity in the former period will be explained by the hypothesis that the price at which it could have been produced was so high that the demand for it would be 0. The problem comes in evaluating the lower boundary curve of figure 1, Ei O (Ei). Some of the current year expenditures will be of the new commodity. When reevaluated at base-year prices, what price shall be assigned to it? The theoretically correct answer will be the lowest price which will keep every individual from purchasing the commodity. Unfortunately, this price, unlike the others that have been used to this point, is a hypothetical one, not an actual one, and its use introduces a hypothetical element into the calculations. However, I believe that any rule which will accomplish the end of accounting for quality changes in a price index must involve judgment somewhere and it is deceptive to state an objective-sounding rule which is not based on a logical theoretical foundation. It will be useful to distinguish between several situations. One is that in which a new commodity rather different from any now existing is being introduced-—e. g., automobiles around the turn of the century, or television sets more recently. Here there is apt to be a continuous rise in consumption. The first year in which the commodity is introduced the consumption is probably rather small. Therefore any error committed in attributing to the previous year a hypothetical price will not have a great effect on the base year weighted current year expenditure curve. Here again we have an example of the value of a chain index. There is no point at which the introduction of a new commodity will produce great problems providing the introduction is gradual. Once it has appeared as an item of expenditure, the successive future steps of its growth are accounted for in the price index, just as any other commodity. An even more favorable situation is that in which the newly introduced commodity is a close substitute for one previously existing, say an improved model. If both are available in the second period, then it is reasonable to postulate that the consumer would reject completely 1 or the other of the 2 goods if the price ratios differed very much from that which actually prevailed in year 1. Therefore, a hypo» Op. cit., pp. 53-58, 71-72. 86 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH thetical price for a newly introduced variety in year 0 is so chosen that the ratio of its price to the price of variety in existence in both periods is slightly higher in year 0 than in year 1. This approach to the pricing of new varieties is very similar to the splicing method. However, it meets von Hofsten's strictures so long as all the varieties are counted each time. The difficulty encountered in the splicing method arises because the particular varieties selected may be unrepresentative. A more difficult case is that in which one variety disappears and is in effect replaced by another. The most common instance of this, is the change of models in many consumers' durable goods, notably autoifiobiles. The principle is not altered. However, it is now necessary to have a hypothetical price in both situations. If model A was produced in year 0 and replaced by a more or less equivalent model B in year 1, the index maker must hypothesize a price for model B in year 0 just high enough so that none of it would have been consumed even if it were available. Similarly, he must hypothesize a price for model A in year 1 just high enough, again, to insure that there would have been no consumption even if available. At this point, the index maker will probably start to resort to objective measures of quality of gome kind, such as performance or durability characteristics of the object. He will, in effect, be postulating that the consumer would choose between two varieties if both were available, according as the price ratio exceeds the quality ratio or not. Of course, the only true measure of quality is the satisfaction yielded to the consumer, and the quality ratio used by the index maker must be related to his guess as to the consumer's tastes. The entire argument to this point has been based on the assumption of an unchanged want structure between one period and the next. We have gone so far as to impute tastes for commodities not available in one time period or the other in order to preserve this theoretical foundation. However, as von Hofsten stresses, this point of view cannot be maintained for goods subject to style changes. As we are currently observing with regard to women's dresses, it is possible for styles to change from year to year and return to their starting point. If all prices had remained unchanged during this period, then the change in varieties <^an only be explained by the assumption of a change in tastes. There seems no simple way out of this problem except a judgment by the statistician that the new style performs,an equivalent function in terms of satisfaction to the old one. V. CONCLUDING REMARKS Index numbers are, of course, desired for other purposes than to measure the cost of living. One obvious possibility is to considersome subset of cost-of-living items, such as food. The logic of the preceding argument goes through precisely provided that we assume that the distribution of food expenditures in any period among different foods depends only on the total volume of food expenditures and is independent of the prices of other goods, for any given total volume of foorl expendihirps. This does not deny substitution between foods and other commodities, but we assume that the total effect of this substitution is already reflected in the choice of a volume-of food expenditures. In a broad way, similar considerations apply to the ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 87 pricing of producers' goods which should be interpreted as reflecting indirectly consumers' preferences. However, there is undoubtedly alot more in the detailed working out of the theory that has never been developed. This leads to the final suggestion that considerable effort be put into pure research on the theoretical problems of index number construction. This has to be done, of course, in close context with practical problems and, therefore, through the existing statistical agencies. Either there should be provision for a research unit within existing statistical agencies, or arrangements should be made for contract research by universities under the supervision of the Bureau of Labor Statistics and similar agencies. For real progress, a good deal of freedom must be granted. The possibility of experimental construction of index numbers must be allowed a wide scope. In this research, issues of comparability with the past should not be allowed to dominate too strongly. The most important thing is the collection of the data necessary for price measurements. Even though such data were not available in the past, we should at least now plan for the future an adequate amount of information. E E .0<E0> Figure t ( oi<Eo} ExpenditureEquivalence E|O(E.) l0 ' ADMINISTERED PRICES IN THE AMERICAN ECONOMY Martin J. Bailey, University of Chicago The principal aim of this paper is to examine afresh the issues, both theoretical and practical, involved in the concept of administered prices. Because of the limitation of time and resources, I have had to stick to two limited objectives in preparing the paper: To survey and summarize the conclusions that can be drawn from other people's work in this field, and to make a very modest additional contribution to the facts and theory that have been brought to bear on it. Some of the relevant contributions in this field, including all the most important ones, are listed in the bibliography at the end of this paper. The factual research carried out by the authors listed provides us with a very considerable amount of information about price behavior and the factors affecting it; and the theoretical analysis given by them says about everything that can be said in this area. The factual evidence which has accumulated has not been sufficient, however, to produce general agreement about what the facts are about administered prices, nor has this combined with the analysis presented been able to produce agreement about their practical importance. In general, opinion is divided sharply into two groups: Those who think administered prices or monopoly prices are widespread and extremely important, and those who think such prices are nonexistent or of no great importance, except in public utilities and other enterprises regulated by government. My survey of the opinions and evidencec has led me to find myself more and more firmly set in the second group. It is my opinion that the subject of administered prices in the free or unregulated part of the economy is not of itself a (proper concern of public policy nor a subject worthy of the attention of the Congress. That monopoly as such is a proper concern of public policy, and that the impact of existing public policies on monopoly and on related matters is of great importance to everyone, I am firmly convinced; I do not want anything I say in this paper to convey any impression to the contrary. However, the proper focus of attention in these matters should be on measures to insure and promote competitive marketing of goods and services and the efficient use of resources. Some existing public policies which do not promote these ends are in need of reappraisal and reform. One point on which nearly all observers agree is that there are wide areas in the economy in which prices are administered, but where this is no cause for concern. For example, virtually all retail trade is of this character. It is agreed that retailers' margins are essentially competitive and flexible, although from day to day the retailer has a wide range of discretion within which he could set his prices without immediate drastic shifts in sales. As many consumers are very price conscious, however, very large shifts in a retailer's sales 89 90 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH would definitely take place after a moderate delay if his prices were substantially out of line either way. From a long-run standpoint, therefore, he has practically no discretion about the prices he can charge. Hence, it is generally agreed, this area of administered prices should not b3 a source of public concern. Another important aspect of administered prices is that a misleading or superficial appraisal is painfully easy to give, even by the most careful and well-intentioned observer, because of the shortage of reliable and unambiguous information. Most of the work that has been done in this field has had to use 1 of 2 sources of price and related data: the wholesale price quotations published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics, and the unit value or realized price data obtained from the census of manufactures. Results from both these sources have quite justly been criticized as inconclusive (and the critics have therefore felt free to write their own tickets). The BLS quotations usually relate to narrowly defined specific commodities, which is as it should be; but they refer to quoted prices, without cognizance of discounts, freight absorption, alteration of quality, and other devices for changing the price actually charged for a standard (unchanging) commodity. The census of manufactures data, which avoid this defect by giving information about net unit values received by sellers, unfortunately have such broad commodity and industry categories that changes in the product mix of a serious magnitude may occur unnoticed within these categories and entrap the investigator in false inferences. Although these defects in the available data on past years are difficult to correct, the situation for the future is more favorable. Problems of this nature in the construction of the Consumer Price Index have already to some extent been dealt with effectively. For example, in the pricing of new cars, where trade-in allowances make a mockery of the list-price schedule, the BLS has worked out a successful surveying technique for dealing with the problem. A modest appropriation by the Congress could make possible the extension of this good work, including the development of a corresponding set of techniques for getting realistic wholesale price data. At the same time, research by university people, and others outside the Government, into enterprise sales data and other sources can bring great improvements in our information about the past. Some examples in respect to this latter nos^bility will be presented later in this paper. Keeping firmly in mind the weaknesses of the available factual data, which carry with them subtle problems of interpretation and analysis, we may proceed to a summary of what is known and certain about administered prices in relation to competition, monopoly, and the concentration of industry. At certain points we shall have to conclude that the only thins: that is known and certain is that no conclusion enn properly be reached, but even that is better than nothing, especially in an area where unsupported assertions are frenuently encountered. Insofar as possible, I shall try to make it clear in every ea^e why a definUp, conclusion may or may not be drawn from the information available. 1. Tf a seller actually sells at an administered price; i. e., a price which he may keep unchanged for weeks or even months at a time in the face of changing market conditions, he possesses a degree of mo- ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 91 nopoly power. What economists mean by a degree of monopoly power is that a seller possessing it may raise his price noticeably above the prices at which he does a satisfactory volume of business without a complete or disastrous loss of sales, and may lower it noticeably without thereby making possible an unlimited or enormous increase in sales. If changing market conditions do not force a seller to change his price to avoid intolerable fluctuations in the volume of his sales, this by itself means that he possesses a degree of monopoly power. Gardiner Means, the best known writer on this subject, likes to stress that administered prices may occur in markets that are essentially competitive, that is in which the degree of monopoly possessed by the sellers is not sufficient to imply excessive profits or an injury to the public due to continuous overpricing. In this he helps to emphasize the fact that what economists generally refer to as a degree of monopoly power does not correspond to the notion of monopoly that implies gouging of the public. Nevertheless, as Means also emphasizes, even a very limited and apparently harmless degree of monopoly power, if widespread throughout some sector or sectors of the economy, could conceivably involve a disastrous contraction of output at unchanging prices, rather than the maintenance of output at sharply falling prices, in the face of a contraction in aggregate demand. This might seem to imply that public policy could and should be directed at making even essentially competitive prices less administered and more competitive; Means leans somewhat to this view himself, but qualifies it by saying that administered prices are an inevitable part of the modern industrial economy. Others, such as Galbraith, say instead that because of this prices should be made more administered, by subjecting price changes by big business to prior review by congressional hearings. Two points remain extremely unclear from what has been said so far. In the first place, no one has demonstrated that "administered prices" are in fact widespread or sticky enough to be a matter for public concern. In the second place, it is not clear or generally agreed whether administered prices in fact involve overpricing of an economically significant quantity of goods, to the detriment of the public, in a way that cannot be corrected by vigorous application of the antitrust laws and related measures. Further, in connection with the first of these points, it remains to be answered whether a tendency for outputs instead of prices to fall in the face of falling demand has any special implication for a general national policy directed at maintaining output and employment. 2. Before these major points are considered, one thing must be emphasized : Quoted prices, or list prices, are frequently not the prices actually charged. As was already mentioned, the price that matters to both the buyer and the seller is the net price after discounts, allowances, and so on. These discounts and so on may fluctuate from day to day, or even from hour to hour, although the list quotation remains unchanged for weeks or months; and as they change, so changes the net realized price. Suppose it were true that every observable case of an "administered," or sticky price, was of this kind, where sharp price competition between firms caused net realized prices to fluctuate from day to day without the outside observer's being able to see it because of the 92 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH unchanging list price. Then we would in fact have all the beneficial and desirable characteristics of competition, and any reasoning based on the apparently harmful sticky prices would be wrong and misleading. In particular, the whole structure of Means' treatment of this subject, which has as its foundation the relative infrequency with which many of the prices quoted by the BLS change, would fall to the ground if it could be shown that the actual prices charged, masked by these quotations, change from day to day and from week to week according to the state of the market. As a matter of fact, it cannot be shown conclusively that all or most of these quotations are nominal or that they generally fail to reflect the true frequency of price change. At this point I can only say that a very large question mark has to be placed alongside all the work on so-called administered prices that explicitly or implicitly uses the frequency of changes in quoted prices as a criterion of the sensitivity of these prices to market forces. This question mark will get larger and larger as I go on to consider some important examples of such prices on which definite and conclusive information is available. 3. The theory of oligopoly, industrial concentration, and related ideas are seriously defective, and provide us with no basis for judging whether prices are as senstive as they should be. Oligopoly theory, and related ideas about enterprises occupying a large share of the market for some product, have gained a wide degree of popular acceptance because their logic looks good and their conclusions accord with our natural and to some extent justifiable suspicions of big business. This, however, does not tell us anything about the facts of the case, nor does it by itself even assure us that the logic of the theory itself is adequate or air tight. It is not. The prevailing theory of oligopoly states that a large seller will hesitate to cut his price when he knows that if he does other sellers will follow suit, because he is so large that his action cannot go unnoticed. If all the output of the product they sell is produced by a few large firms, this would seem to imply that no one will cut the price unless demand has fallen to such disastrously low levels that price cutting is obviously preferable even when everyone does it together. The gap in this reasoning is that the circle is not complete unless it can be asserted that every firm in the industry is very confident that if it lets customers get out the door because it refused a price concession, not a single other firm will make the concession and make off with the trade. If a firm has serious doubts on this score, as well it might, and if the current sales and price situation is such that the firm is very anxious to secure the additional trade, it will be sorely tempted to offer the concession. The effect of "oligopoly" will then be that the firm will request that the customer not shout from the housetops about the concession given. The temptation to cut prices covertly in this way will occur any time that the extra costs incurred to produce additional output are substantially less than the going price. Even if the difference between the two does not yield as much as the producer would like toward the overhead, it will come closer to doing so if he can expand volume at the expense of his competitors by a small price concession; and the operating profit will most certainly fall much further short of covering overhead if his competitors expand their volume at his expense. In a situation of this kind, it is obvious to everyone con- ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 93 cerned that a price well above marginal cost is unnatural and difficult to maintain.1 All firms are not of equal size, and smaller ones are less likely to try to keep the price up than are the big ones when this situation affords them the opportunity to make what for them is a big increase in sales. Hidden price cutting is likely to break out any time the natural level is below the going level, and is unlikely to stop until equality between the two is reached. Any attempt by the bigger firms to hold the line, as they are the ones more likely to try it, simply results in all the business going to the smaller firms in the industry. The big firms get no opportunity to recover this lost business in times of booming demand, and so run the risk of gradually being replaced as the largest firms of the industry if they do not yield and follow the market closely. This sort of pattern of behavior is clearly visible in the nonferrous metals industry: In a weak market the smaller firms press sales while the larger firms follow along dragging their heels and complaining all the while. The big firms have not been getting smaller, but only because they meet market prices, however grudgingly. Here as elsewhere the structure of quoted prices, though volatile, understates somewhat the fluctuation of actual prices; discounting is common in a normal market, rife in a weak one, and negative when supplies are tight. In a nutshell, in this market generally recognized to be competitive, we can see a certain amount of oligopolistic protestation alongside truly competitive pricing. That such concessions, discounts, and so on are given in a great many industries in which quoted prices change infrequently is a matter of common knowledge, admitted by everyone except the large firms in those industries themselves. A casual reading of trade publications and business periodicals will convince one that this sort of behavior is extremely widespread, although data on the subject are extremely hard to come by. The problem is simply that the one element of unquestionable truth in the theory of oligopoly is that large firms do not like to talk about sales at prices below the quoted price. If one were to read only the statements of big steel executives, one would be led to believe that no one in the steel industry would ever dream of cut-price sales, as such sales would obviously be detrimental to the profits of steel firms as a group. Certainly they leave no doubt that they wish no such sales were made. This leads to the ironic situation that big firms in truly competitive industries bring floods of criticism and epithets of "monopoly" upon their own heads by their stiff-necked secrecy about their pricing policies. They are so convinced that oligopoly theory ought to be true and applicable to their own situations, and they so wish they could price like oligopolists, that they talk like oligopolists while they price like competitors. This is regrettable as much for the public as for big business, because it distracts public attention from true monopolies, price-fixing arrangements, and misuse of resources. It also makes it difficult for the trained investigator, even if he knows just what he 1 This, of course, does not mean that it is "unnatural" for a firm to make an operating profit sufficient to cover overhead in times of average or high demand. When operating rates are high the extra costs incurred to produce additional output are higher than at low operating rates (because of greater pressure on maintainance staffs, and other factors). A price that covers these extra costs at high outputs will more than cover variable costs for the entire output, therefore, and generally will yield a net profit. 94 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Is looking for, to find where the monopolies and other abuses really are. For the time being we must conclude from this that oligopoly pricing, or any other type of essentially monopolistic pricing by big business, is less common than it would appear by considering quoted price behavior and the public statements of businessmen themselves. Further discussion of this point, from a long-run standpoint, is given in section 6, below. 4. The evidence is conclusive that the prices of steel and petroleum are sensitive to month-to-month changes in market conditions. Steel and petroleum are the two major industries widely believed to be of the "administered price" variety on which I have been able to find some hard factual evidence on prices actually charged. Unfortunately, the evidence on steel dates from 1940 and before, but there is no reason to suppose that the situation has changed in any essential respect. Studies by the TNEC on the sales data of the major steel producers and by the BLS on the purchase data of a large sample of steel users, covering various years up through 1939, show that price concessions on the major steel products averaged some 6 percent off the base price in 1939 and some 50-60 percent off the standard extras, which meant that the base price plus extras was reduced by some 17 percent by these concessions. That most of the concessions were in the extras rather than the base price may be due to the greater ease of concealment in the category of extras. That these concessions fluctuated from month to month was also made clear in these studies. Chart I shows the average monthly mill net in relation to the quoted base price of the United States Steel Co. for the years 1912-39, representing a composite of all their products sold. In most years the net price received was actually less than the base price, which meant that concessions were greater than the extras. (These figures are only broadly representative of what was happening, since small month-tomonth fluctuations may be partly due to changes in the product mix. Individual product studies give the same picture, however, so that there is no reason to suppose that this chart is misleading.) Note that generally on a rising market the quoted or "hoped for" base price shot up far above and ahead of the prices actually received. CHART I REPORTED COMPOSITE PRICE AND COMPOSITE MILL NET YIELD 1926 -100 250 250 225 % \ n i 200 175 150 / 7 1 J 75 175 150 1r f 125 100 22* 200 REPORTED COMPOSITE PRICE <IRON AGO COMPOSITE MILL NET YIELD (TO U.S.S.C. SUBSIDIARIES) «) ce 125 I \ \ -f\ s 17 *\ y \ Z A. 100 x o z 75 A C O §P s t> d 50 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 1931 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 1940 50 Ordinarily the general level of the reported steel prices, as indicated by the Iron Age composite price of steel, reflects the relative level of the mill net yields, i. e., the amounts received per ton by the U. S. Steel Corporation subsidiaries on the various products after deduction of cost of delivery. However, at times the level of the mill net yields has been slightly above or slightly below the relative level of the reported prices, except that during the periods of intense demand during the World War and in 1920 when the prices charged by the Corporation's subsididiarles were beneath the level of the going prices. Factors tending to lower mill net yields with respect to reported base prices are principally (a) reductions from base price, (b) excess of actual cost of delivery over freight added to base price in computing the delivered price, (c) quantity discounts and (d) deductions for quality, size, eic. Factors tending to raise mill net yields with respect to reported base prices are principally (a) extras for special finish, quality, size, heat treatment, etc., and (b) extras for small quantity. CO 96 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH I strongly suspect, therefore, that the "price rise" of July 1957 was largely fictitious; although a recovery in economic activity will very likely save the steelmakers from the indignity of openly rescinding the price increase. The data on the petroleum industry are current, fortunately, and with a little work can be made available for a considerable past period. This industry is frequently alleged to have administered prices for crude oil and for refined products at the refinery and in wholesale markets. It is a straightforward matter to check up on the latter prices by observing daily quotations in newspapers (such as the New York Journal of Commerce) and the monthly figures in the Oil and Gas Journal. The daily quotations posted by regular suppliers in wholesale markets, less reported discounts, change on the average every 3 or 4 weeks; but a more accurate picture is obtained by reading the journalistic reports in the newspaper columns alongside these postings. They report actual market prices, which change every few days, according to the state of the market. When the postings change they appear to change largely to get in line with prices actually charged. Price figures at the refinery level are obtainable from the Oil and Gas Journal and the Independent Petroleum Association. Chart I I and the accompanying table give an average of these figures by months for 1957, along with the BLS series on petroleum products at wholesale for comparison. Both these series understate somewhat the downtrend in these prices from March 1957 onwards, because of the slight lag of movements in posted prices behind prices actually charged; both series are based on postings less published discounts only. TABLE 1.—Monthly prices of petroleum products, 1957 Average BLS quotation for BLS index value refined crude oil (1947-49=100) products 1 (dollars per (dollars per barrel) barrel) January... February.. Marco April May June.. July August September. October.... November. December. 124.9 131.0 130.7 130.4 129.8 128.4 126.4 125.5 125.6 124.6 123.5 123.5 4.13 4.25 4.21 4.17 4.16 4.10 3.99 3.97 3.99 3.97 3.92 3.94 2.82 3.07 3.07 3.07 3.07 3.07 3.07 3.07 3.07 3.07 3.07 3.07 1 Average of figures given by the Oil and Gas Journal and by the Independent Petroleum Association of America (for east of California prices). ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 97 CHART II - MONTHLY PRICES OF PETROLEUM PRODUCTS, 1957 ::::{;•'-1": T^ rT^t i:*r ^z z~. ~ r -rrr :rr: " " *." ~ ~-~ rnr !*~! \J~ " r-~ n ~ " : : —r' ..: — f~—[""F The price of crude oil presents a more delicate problem, because no regularly published data can be found on the prices actually being charged. It is clear that the realized value of crude oil for the' big integrated producers went down, because of the fall in the prices of final products; and since the 22 largest oil firms are net purchasers of crude from smaller producers to the tune of 25 percent of United States crude oil output, it does not seem at all probable that they actually paid the high posted price for crude when the crude wasn't worth it and when a multitude of suppliers were piling up inventories. Late last year an oil company executive was reported in the Oil and Gas Journal as having remarked in a speech that large quantities of crude were moving at cutrate prices. Private inquiry of an oil economist on my part uncovered the information that for some months a major importer of crude has been selling it at prices as 98 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH much as 30 percent below the posted prices, and that price-cutting is quite normal in the trade by various covert devices, such as shipping a higher quality of crude than that for which the purchaser is invoiced. Within the last few months posted prices of crude have at last been falling more into line with actuality, but they are still misleading. 5. Differing degrees of price flexibility in the different sectors of the economy are apparently almost entirely explainable in terms of differences in the behavior of costs, without regard to concentration or monopoly. The work of other researchers, combined with the direct evidence on steel and petroleum which I have presented and with the impressions one gains by reading trade journals and the like for many industries, definitely point in this direction. Means found that a small selected sample of quoted prices did show a weak but definite relation between degree of concentration and list price rigidity, although Tucker and others have questioned whether this can be generalized for the whole economy. I would not be surprised if it can, since maintaining a fiction of a quoted price different from actual prices is behavior, pointless though it may appear, more to be expected in a concentrated industry than in an atomistic one. However, when one turns to realized prices, the prices actually charged, various researchers, especially Neal, Thorp & Crowder, and Tucker, found no relation at all bstw^een concentration and price rigidity or at most a negligible relation. These results tended to show instead that prices vary closely with costs, which explain (even when only crudely measured) some 80 percent to 90 percent of the variation in prices between 1929 and the bottom of the depression.2 However, these studies have to be supplemented with the additional material and impressions which I have put forward, because the product classifications used are so unavoidably crude. Even all this together is not absolutely conclusive, however, and many economists who are familiar with all or most of this material find it possible to continue to give full play to their suspicions about the harmful pricing practices of big business. I believe that a continuing accumulation of evidence may one day convince them that they are overdoing a good thing. 2 Neal (item 21 in the bibliography) found that, between 1920 and both 1033 and 1035, the coefficient of determination (r2) between costs and realized prices was consistently of the order of 0.80 to 0.90, depending on the sample used. The partial coefficient of determination, after allowing for the effect of co«ts. between prices and the concentration ratio was consistently around 0.09 : that is, of the totnl variation of prices, only from 1 to 2 percent was attributable to variation in concentration ratios. Thorp and Crowder (29) found that in their data there was no relation at all between changes in realized prices and concentration, nor between changes in realized prices and changes in concentration. Correlation methods were not applied, but it was evident that, if thoy had >^een, a zero result would have been obtained. Tucker (30) concentrated ^is attention on Means' data, and pointed out that if a lareer sample h^d been used the relation Menns found between list-price rigidity and concentration would 'ar^ely disappear: it would disappear entirely, he said, if allowance were made for the irisleading character of list pricing and its correlation with the degree of concentration. The other two studies te^d to bear him out in this contention. One ot^ev question mark that hns to be put alongside these studies, besides that arising from possible changes in the product mix. is that nationnl concentration ratios do not equally reject degrees of concentration in local markets for all products. Tt is not possible to say how systematic consideration of this factor would affect the result, if nt nV, but such attention as has been paid to it has led to the conclusion that the effect would not, in any case, be large. All this does not denv that a monopolist may have sensitive prices like everyone else, and th^t he mav, nevertheless, suffer a smaller drop in profits during bad times tban do other sellers. This aspect of the matter is best viewed as a part of the problem of longrun overpricing, discussed in the next section. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 99 One other serious qualification must be entered at this point, however, and that concerns the rigidity of the wage structure. There is little doubt that here is a price that is not very sensitive to changing economic conditions. Nourse, among others, has repeatedly cited this factor as a source of excessive price rigidity in the nonagricultural sectors of the economy, and in particular he has tended to indict the labor unions for the existence of this factor. Now, it is true that since the New Deal era wages have shown no tendency to drop in recessions, which they had generally done previously. However, careful studies of wage movements have not tended to find much relation between these movements and the degree of unionization, but rather seem to show differing degrees of reluctance on the part of employers to cut wages. Other aspects of presentday policy than the labor laws, such as unemployment insurance, may have reduced the downward flexibility of wages; but unions do not seem to have made much difference. 6. Long-run overpricing of commodities is not a widespread problem in our economy. In this connection, the histories of the steel and petroleum industries are very suggestive. Both had monopolistic pricing and profits in the first decade of this century, and neither made any secret of the fact that this was the way they wanted it to be. Both monopoly situations fell apart, but for rather different reasons. The United States Steel Co., which on its formation in 1901 controlled the production of some two-thirds of the steel ingots produced in the United States, priced monopolistically for 10 years or so, providing an attraction and an umbrella for the expansion of its competitors. The United States Steel Co., now controls only one-third of the steel ingots produced in the United States. Its control of steel pricing broke down by the advent of the First World War, and never returned, although this has never been admitted. During the depression, the company joined the international steel cartel, accepting a quota for exports by the entire industry with penalties for exceeding the quota; as a result, the company regularly paid penalties as its competitors regularly exported in excess of the quota, and the scheme had no real effect as far as this country was concerned. This incident occurred during a period of especially intense j)rice competition among steelmakers within this country. The only time that United States Steel has had its way on prices since the First World War was during the unfortunate interlude of the NRA, which, mercifully, died quickly except for its labor provisions. Yet to this day the company's executives talk like oligopolists, apparently looking wistfully back over the decades to the time when this kind of talk meant whfit it said. The Standard Oil cartel was a more tough and durable phenomenon, having lasted from around 1880 to 1911, and it required the strong arm of the Government to break it up. Throughout the period of its success, the cartel controlled 80-85 percent of refinery capacity in the United States, and by one dubious means or another kept the remainder in line on prices and output quotas. After the cartel was dissolved by court order and it became obvious that the successor companies could no longer maintain discipline as before, competition expanded rapidly. At the present time the successor companies control only 25-30 percent of the industry's output, and in many markets are in competition with one another. These two histories point up the fact that the public has two major forms of protection from long-run overpricing of products: competi23734—58 8 100 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH tion, potential and actual, on the one hand, and the antitrust laws on the other. By and large, these two forms of long-run protection are adequate over that area of the economy where they are applicable. The paths of history are strewn with the bones of cartel and monopoly schemes designed to gouge the public, and nowhere have they failed more regularly than in the United States. The chances for success in such enterprises have always been slim, even without the antitrust laws, and the failures have been spectacular and costly to their promoters. The main reason that cartel and monopoly schemes tend to fail is indicated by the analysis presented in section 3. An overpriced commodity, one whose price is substantially above the cost of production, presents an overwhelming temptation to existing and potential producers to add to existing output. Hence, a monopoly or cartel which raises the price above its natural level will, in so doing, invite its own destruction unless it can effectively prevent such additions to output. Effective prevention of additions to the monopoly's chosen output requires strict policing of outputs and prices, something which can be done usually only with the assistance of Government (or with the tacit sufferance of Government if it uses strong-arm methods, taking the law into its own hands). Rockefeller failed twice before finally succeeding in attempts to form his oil-refining cartel, because of this difficulty. The notorious methods used by the diamond monopoly in the South African mining areas, employing armored cars, halftracks, and the like, and an extensive secret service, have been sufficient to maintain its control of the diamond market for generations. However, this control is now breaking down because new producing areas nominally cooperating with the monopoly do not police so well. Schemes to raise prices of tin, copper, rubber, and coffee have repeatedly broken down and brought considerable losses on their promoters because of insufficient control over total production. Examples of this kind are legion. It is also true that the price-raising power of any monopoly, even if successful, is likely to be limited by competition from other products satisfying the same basic need or use. For instance, a monopolist in one type of fuel would to some extent have to hold his hand for fear of causing people to change over to other types of fuel. This consideration may explain the recent trend toward moderation in the demands of the coal miners' union, who seem to have seen the handwriting on the wall. Nevertheless, even in the United States, where collusive agreements and the like are especially difficult to police and maintain, there have been some successes, costly to the public. The occasional successes point up the need for the existence and enforcement of the antitrust laws. A similar conclusion is reached if one examines the consequences of widespread monopoly in other countries, where, generally speaking, no such laws exist. By and large, available evidence on corporate assets and profits tends to suggest that the extent of monopoly in the United States ECONOMIC STABILITY AOT) GROWTH 101 economy is much smaller than one would expect if he accepted concentration ratios as a measure of monopoly.3 The main areas in which the public is not fully protected from monopoly in this country are ones in which the Government, usually actively but sometimes passively, has prevented or allowed the prevention of competition and has caused or permitted wrong and inefficient pricing to prevail. Licensing restrictions, franchises, patents, rate regulation, and so on have effectively curtailed competition in many areas of the economy and have permitted gouging of consumers and misuse of resources. The most important by far of these areas is transportation and public utilities, which are subject to rate regulation. Although these rates are usually kept down to a level which only allows a "reasonable return" to capital, the structures of rates set could scarcely be more viciously inefficient and harmful to the public interest if that were their explicit object. Further, the "reasonable return" criterion is not always followed, as in many cases the sole object of regulation is to set minimum rates so as to prevent effective price competition between alternative forms of supply of a basic service. Basic reforms in all the areas where the Government actively or tacitly restricts competition are badly needed. In this particular respect, one may quite properly say that maladministered prices are a real and serious phenomenon, both from a short-run and a long-run point of view. 7. History has shown repeatedly that the only cure for a drastic fall in aggregate demand is for aggregate demand to rise again; the appropriate public policy for stability and full employment, therefore, consists of countercyclical monetary and fiscal policies, combined with a structure of policy that encourages the private economy to maximum growth and stability. Price flexibility has never been sufficient to avoid sharp and undesirable drops in aggregate output and unemployment, and there is no reason to suppose that such flexibility ever will be sufficient to do so. An adequate countercyclical monetary and fiscal policy has never been put to the test, although the performance of such policy in the recessions of 1937,1949, and 1954 was not bad. Most economists are agreed that well-formulated monetary and fiscal policy can be sufficient to maintain output and employment. These remarks are equally applicable whether "administered prices" are a widespread phenomenon in the private, unregulated economy or not. Even if Means' ideas could be accepted at face value, these would still point in the direction of maintaining adequate monetary and fiscal policies as the main defense against undesirable fluctuations in output, employment, and the price level. It would be very convenient if nearly all prices, including wages, were sufficiently flexible that no Government action would be necessary to maintain output and employ3 Harberger's study of this question (10) based on 1925-29 data Indicates that monopoly profits before income taxes are at most of the order of 1% percent of the national income. This would imply, on my own calculation from his data, that from 6 to 8 percent of the national product is under unregulated monopoly control. 'This estimate is made by assuming that all differences in profits are due to differing degrees of monopoly power, i. e., that none are due to the rise and decline of industries with growth and change in the economy. Many of these profit differences must really be due to the latter factor, so that this estimate undoubtedly overstates the amount of monopoly. This estimate roughly agrees with the more conservative of Nutter's estimates (25) based on concentration ratios and on Wilcox study (35). As not all concentrated industries are high-profit industries, nor vice versa, however, these estimates do not agree on which industries are monopolistic. Further, even where they do agree, some of the high profits will be due to the dynamic factors just mentioned. 102 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH ment regardless of fluctuations in aggregate demand. They are not that flexible, they never have been so far as we know, and it is not likely that they ever will be. Government therefore has a useful function to perform in this matter, by meeting such fluctuations with carefully weighed counteraction. The encouragement of the private sector to maximum growth and stability in such a manner that will require the minimum use of countercyclical devices does involve questions of prices and price policies, although these are of a second order of importance in this context. Where Government is involved in the regulation and restriction of private enterprise, this involvement should be such as to promote the highest possible real income through the best possible use of resources. Preliminary study indicates that the reforms I have previously mentioned with respect to such involvements could produce an increase in the real national income of at least 5 percent and perhaps as much as 10 percent.4 Concerning the unregulated private sector of the economy, the role of public policy is more limited but is also important. In my view the Government, apart from preventing monopolization, price-fixing agreements, and blatant price discrmination, should adopt a position of benign neutrality toward the private economy. Where monopoly and artificial restraint of trade are not present, it may virtually be taken for granted that particular products for which the demand falls will suffer an appropriate fall in price. It may almost be taken for granted that products for which the demand rises will enjoy an appropriate rise in price; this may not quite be taken for granted in every case, however, because firms may fear an inappropriate adverse public reaction or even prosecution under the antitrust laws. This is inappropriate because if the scarcity of the commodity relative to demand is real and not artificial, a high price is the only efficient way to ration the scarce supply among its most important and valuable uses. In peacetime the efficiency of the price mechanism is not questioned if the commodity in question is wheat, copper, or textiles; and it is equally efficient if the commodity in question is steel or any other commodity that happens to be produced by big business. As long as the industry is competitive, so that the scarcity is not artificial, the bigness of the firms which will make windfall gains in times of scarcity of their product (and windfall losses in times of plenty) is not relevant to how the price should behave. It would be most helpful to this end if the Congress made it clear to businessmen exactly where they stand—what the limits are to the application of the antitrust laws, and how much freedom they have to price according to the State of the market. Corporate enterprises, both big and little, are an integral part of the highly productive American economic system, and will remain so for a long time to come. Pointless harassment of these enterprises cannot possibly serve any useful purpose, and could be very prejudicial to the objectives of maximum growth and stability of the economy. I also believe it to be true that the measures I endorse, namely appropriate monetary and fiscal policies, reform in the areas of the economy where Government has a direct restrictive or regulatory influence, and benign neutrality in the rest of the economy, are sufficient for 4 These are rough estimates based on calculations by Harberger and myself. ECONOMIC STABILITY AOT) GROWTH 103 maintaining long-run stability of the price level in the face of upward as well as downward pressures. The correctness or not of this belief is of course of considerable importance to long run growth and stability, since many students of the subject have come to the conclusion that stability of the price level and full employment are inconsistent because of the pressure of wage.demands (or of the upward movement of "administered prices"). Certainly one cannot deny that this could conceivably be the case; but in those instances I know of where it demonstrably has happened (i. e., where unions have demanded and gotten wages that were inconsistent with full employment at existing prices) wages have been escalated so effectively that full employment was not possible even with mild or unlimited inflation.5 It is easy to jump to the conclusion, whenever the consumer price index goes up a few points, that someone has been "pushing" it up; and of course big labor and big business are natural targets in this respect. Showing that it has been happening in the American economy is another matter, and I do not believe that it can be shown. The significant inflationary episodes of the past have almost certainly been monetary phenomena, at least in the sense that sufficient monetary restraint would have stopped them effectively without serious unemployment. There is little reason to suppose that the episode of 1955-57 was any different. As Buggies pointed out last year to the Senate Judiciary Committee, the consumer price rises in 1955-57 occurred almost entirely in services and utilities. Prices in the industrial sector could not by any stretch of the imagination be credited with responsibility for the upward movement of the Consumer Price Index. But this is where the rise would have had to have occurred to be consistent with giving big labor or big business the blame. On the other hand, I do not find it difficult to interpret the events of 1955-57 in terms of growing aggregate demand insufficiently restrained by monetary and fiscal policy. These years saw an unprecedented boom in domestic investment, a boom which ought to be expected to place pressure on resources in a fully employed economy. At the same time, expanding consumer incomes were increasingly directed to services, in keeping with a long-run trend. Services, in order to keep employees and attract them away from the booming investment sector, where jobs were plentiful, had to continue even more sharply their long-run tendency to bring their wages (and therefore costs and prices) up toward a level consistent with this. Similarly, so far as one can tell, the rises in prices in the utilities and other regulated areas made sense in terms of rising costs and ample demand. The price movements of the 1955-57 episode are highlighted in table 2, which shows the changes in the general price level (gross national product deflator) and its components. Consumer goods rose the least (3.8 percent) of any of these components, while the biggest rises were in compensation of general government employees (17.9 percent) and in producers' durable equipment (15.0 percent) which had dropped slightly from 1953 to 1954. These movements make a pattern very much in keeping with the interpretation of the episode as a demand inflation generated from the active investment and government sectors. 8 I have in mind the cases of Germany's inflation of the 1920's and Italy's inflation after World War II. In both these cases there was severe unemployment during inflation. 104 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH A more restrictive monetary and fiscal policy would have dampened down somewhat the demands of the investment sector, which in turn would have implied less pressure elsewhere in the economy. I have seen no evidence to suggest that this would have necessitated serious unemployment had the additional restraint occurred while the pressure in domestic investment was still high. After all, we had 5 years of virtual price stability since the end of 1950, and without serious unemployment. I think this can continue. TABLE 2.—Components of the general price level [1947=100] 1954 Gross national product deflator _ Consumer prices Goods Services Construction Producers' durable equipment Government purchases of goods and services Compensation of general government employees 119.9 116.8 112.6 128.1 129.7 128.1 125.2 134.1 1957 129.6 124.0 116.9 137.5 142.9 147.3 142.4 158.1 Percent Increase 1954-57 8.1 6.0 3.8 7.3 10.2 15.0 13.7 117.9 i This item represents the wage and salary level in general government, and is not strictly comparable with the other indexes because of the possibility that there has been technological advance in government as elsewhere. Source: Survey of Current Business, February 1958. BIBLIOGRAPHY 1. Adams, Walter and Horace M. Gray, Monopoly in America (New York: Macmillan, 1955). 2. Backman, Jules, Price Practices and Price Policies (New York: The Ronald Press, 1953). 3. Blair, John M., and Arthur Reeside, Price Discrimination in Steel, TNEC Monograph No. 41 (Washington: Temporary National Economic Committee, 1941). 4. Blair, John M., Economic Concentration and Depression Price Rigidity, American Economic Review, May 1955, p. 566. 5. Daugherty, Carroll R., Melvin G. de Chazeau, and Samuel S. Stratton, The Economics of the Iron and Steel Industry (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1937). 6. Dennison, H. S., and J. K. Galbraith, Modern Competition and Business Policy (New York: Oxford University Press, 1938). 7. Elliott, William Y., et al., International Control in the Non-Ferrous Metals (New York: Macmillan, 1937). 8. Federal Trade Commission, Control of Iron Ore, Report to the Antitrust Subcommittee of the Judiciary Committee of the House of Representatives (Washington: Government Printing Office, 1952). 9. Galbraith, John K., Market Structure and Stabilization Policy, Harvard Business Review, 1957. *10. Harberger, Arnold C, Monopoly and Resource Allocation, American Economic Review, May 1954. 11. Jones, Eliot, The Trust Problem in the United States (New York: Macmillan, 1921). 12. Laidler, Harry W., Concentration of Control in American Industry (New York: Thomas Y. Crowell, 1931). 13. Livermore, Shaw, Concentration of Control Now as Compared With 1890, Journal of Marketing, April 1940. 14. Mason, Edward S., Economic Concentration and the Monopoly Problem (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University, 1957). 15. , Price Inflexibility, Review of Economic Statistics, May 1938 16. Means, Gardiner C, Big Business, Administered Prices, and the Problem of Full Employment, Journal of Marketing, April 1940. ECONOMIC (STABILITY AND GROWTH 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. 31. 32. 33. 34. 35. 105 "industrial Prices and Their Relative Inflexibility," Senate Document No. 13, 74th Congress, 1st session (Washington: U. S. Government Printing Office, 1935). , The Structure of the American Economy, Part I (Washington: National Resources Committee, 1939) Mills, Frederick C, Prices in Recession and Recovery (New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, 1936). National Bureau of Economic Research, Business Concentration and Price Policy (New York, 1954). Neal, Alfred C, Industrial Concentration and Price Inflexibility (Washington: Public Affairs Press, 1942). Nelson, Saul, and Walter G. Keim, Price Behavior and Business Policy, TNEC Monograph No. 1 (Washington: Temporary National Economic Committee, 1940). Nourse, E. G., Industrial Price Policies and Economic Progress (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1938). , Price Making in a Democracy (Washington: Brookings Institution, 1944). Nutter, G. Warren, The Extent of Enterprise Monopoly in the United States, 1899-1939 (Chicago: University of Chicago, 1951). Purdy, Harry L., Martin L. Lindahl, and William A. Carter, Corporate Concentration and Public Policy (New York: Princeton-Hall, 1950). Stocking, George W., The Oil Industry and the Competitive System (Boston: Houghton Mifflin, 1925). Tarbell, Ida M., The History of the Standard Oil Co. (New York: McClure, Phillips & Co., 1904). Thorp, Willard L., and Walter F. Crowder, The Structure of Industry, TNEC Monograph No. 27 (Washington: Temporary National Economic Committee, 1941). Tucker, Rufus, Concentration and Competition, Journal of Marketing, April, 1940. , The Essential Historical Facts about "Sensitive" and "Administered" Prices, The Annalist, February 4,1938. , The Reasons for Price Rigidity, American Economic Review, March 1938. United States Steel Corp., TNEC Papers (New York: United States Steel Corp., 1940), volume II. Weston, J. Fred, The Role of Mergers in the Growth of Large Firms (Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California, 1953). Wilcox, Clair, Competition and Monopoly in American Industry, TNEC Monograph No. 21 (Washington: Temporary National Economic Committee, 1940). f THE PRICE INDEXES OF THE BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS H. E. Riley, Chief, Division of Prices and Cost of Living, Bureau of Labor Statistics, United States Department of Labor In this paper I shall be concerned with some of the practical problems affecting the development and use of two widely Known indexes of price movement: The Consumer Price Index and the Wholesale Price Index of the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Both of these price measures serve two broad areas of need: For general economic analysis and to guide policy decisions by government, business, and the public. Neither index can be completely satisfactory for both theoretical analyses and practical day-to-dajr decision making. In fact, price measures of any kind have certain inherent limitations which must be recognized in any application. Index numbers provide a convenient way of studying price behavior quantitatively. Simply defined, an index number is an average of price changes between two points of time. This implies that there is a universe of items for which we wish to measure the average price change. Since an average is involved, it applies in addition that we know how important each item is in the universe so that we can weight together the measures for individual items. If we know all about the universe of items at both points of time for which we are computing the index of price change, there is no problem—one could define and compute literally an infinity of measures of price change. But no one of these indexes would be right for all purposes. A more important point is that complete quantity and price information is not available at any given moment for any index of significant scope. The census of manufactures, for example, identifies something like 8,000 individual materials and product items, not counting all variations in size, quality, or marketed form. These commodities are changing hands continuously, passing from producer to wholesale distributor to retailer to the ultimate consumer. Each transaction involves a price determination. Any workable plan for a price index, designed to reflect the movement of prices at any level in this complex? must rest on a sampling structure. It requires a sample of commodities, of sellers, and a sample of price quotations or transactions. Thus, in the Consumer Price Index we have a sample of about 300 commodities and services. We have a sample of retail stores and service establishments clustered in 46 cities. From each store we obtain a sample of prices—the price in effect at a point in time for each sample commodity offered for sale. Accuracy in each of the samples is essential for a valid index number. Price can be defined as the amount of money "paid" for a unit of commodity or service, but this formal definition provides no more than a starting point. There are various kinds of transactions and the price, or money payment, may enter into the transaction at dif107 108 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH ferent stages. In some cases different transactors pay different prices for equivalent volumes of goods and services. Therefore, for a price to be useful in statistical measurement, its exact meaning must be understood. For the BLS indexes, the commodities to be priced are defined in terms of more or less exact physical specifications, depending on the item involved. When necessary—i. e., where the price might be affected by these factors—the classes of customer and/or seller involved in the transaction are likewise specified. There is a wide variety of prices that can serve as the basis for statistical measurement; not all are equally good or appropriate. There is what can be called a list, or posted, price. In most stores of this country that is the price at which transactions are made. For some items, including some sold at retail, the list or posted price is very different from the actual transaction price. Witness the haggling which commonly accompanies the sale of a new car. In this case the determination of price is usually further complicated by the fact that the transaction involves cash plus a "trade-in." It is obvious that a realistic measure of price change should be based on actual prices paid rather than list prices, if the two differ. The distinction between list price and transaction price is extremely significant in the case of nonretail prices. The practice in many industries is to maintain a list price for a long time and change the price as market conditions require by offering or withdrawing discounts or "extra" charges. Variations from the list price are made not only over time but also at any given time for different classes of customers. Obviously, in comparing prices for supposedly the same item over time, one of the essentials is to insure that the prices cover equivalent terms. Exactly the same item, for example, may be quoted on an f. o. b. basis or on a delivered basis, or inclusive of installation costs in some cases. Changes in the terms of sale may be used as a device for adjusting real prices without changing published list prices. Generally, the commercial transaction unit is the one used for purposes of price measurement. Thus, the cost for a monthly telephone service with unlimited calls is an appropriate measurement consistent with this concept. A different price, if it could be computed, would be secured if the price per actual phone call made or received was to be considered. Similarly, the price per thousand cubic feet of natural gas is an appropriate price measure, or the price of a ton of coal. Either one of these prices could be converted into price per equivalent quantity of heat, measured by the British thermal unit, which might be a useful concept for some purposes. For some of our series we do, in fact, refer to the B. t. u. content in the specifications of these two items. In most instances, however, it would be impossible to define units of performance in this manner. A basic problem in the measurement of price behavior is that few products remain constant in their physical characteristics over any length of time. In some cases it is possible to adjust the prices available for the two periods being compared to take account of technical differences in individual products, which, it is assumed, are reflected in market valuations. In other cases the products have changed so much that comparisons over time cannot be made except with explicit statement of the basic assumptions involved. Thus, we hear, for example, how the car of today differs from the car of 10 years ago. ECONOMIC STABILITY AXD GROWTH 109 Some of the differences can be accounted for and prices adjusted; for example, automatic shift and power steering. Other differences, however, cannot be evaluated in dollar terms. Some manufacturing changes may have reduced costs and at the same time increased the utility of the product. In very few cases are the ideal conditions for computing the true market evaluation of the differences between an old product and its current modification satisfied. To do this would require that both products be available on the market in significant quantities for an overlap period of suitable length. Of course, new products are continually coming on the market, and others drop out. This constant change in the commodities flowing through the market presents especially difficult problems in measuring average price changes over a long span of time. Computation of an index to represent the average price change between two periods of time requires both price data for individual items and quantity data for the weights by which the prices are combined. Determination of the quantities presents many technical and theoretical problems. In the early days of index number research a great deal of effort went into finding some intrinsically "true" method of weighting which would be best in a general sort of way. We now recognize that the choice of weights depends (1) upon the objective which the index number is designed to serve and (2) the availability of data from which the weights can be derived. Regardless of the objective, however, the availability of data often becomes the dominant criterion in the selection of weights. The interpretation of a particular index number depends not only on £he way in which the price data are combined but on the logic of the weighting structure for the particular purpose to be served by the index number, and the firmness of the statistical foundation oi the weights. In some widely used index numbers, the weights are hypothetical or arbitrary, or are based on very limited data. The weights of our daily spot market index are arbitrary. By averaging the prices without varying the weights we give each quotation equal weight in the computation. This may not impair the usefulness of the index numbers provided users are aware of what the weights mean. For other index numbers, the weights rest upon very broad statistical foundations as well as carefully thought out logical structures. The major BLS price indexes are good examples of indexes with weights derived from comprehensive statistics for a base period. Thus the weights of the Consumer Price Index represent the quantities of the various commodities and services consumed by city worker families as measured in an extensive survey of family spending in 1950. The weights were adjusted to 1952 conditions before being introduced into the Consumer Price Index as issued in January 1953. In effect the Consumer Price Index formula is a variation on the Laspeyres base weighted index, named for the 19th century statistician who developed the original equation. We use the term "fixed basket" in connection with the Consumer Price Index because each monthly set of price quotations is combined by the quantities represented in the basket to derive the current value aggregate. A comparison of this current aggregate value with a similar aggregate value based upon 1947-49 prices gives the index in relation to the standard base period for Government statistics. HO ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH A comparison with a similar aggregate for the previous month gives the percent change shown by the Consumer Price Index since the preceding month. Many statisticians argue that the indexes should be constructed with current rather than base period weights. This is known as the Paasche formula. An index of this type has value for many purposes but, as a practical matter, the necessary data for weights cannot be obtained in time for current computation of price indexes. Moreover, a current weighted index presents a comparison of prices as against a base reference period. Comparison between any other two periods are invalid because the differences in index numbers involves not only changes in price, but also changes in weights. Thus current weighted formulas do not satisfy a maior requirement of BLS price indexes that the indexes be comparable not only as against a base period, but also as against previous months and previous years. Prices indexes derived from careful specification pricing of the tvpe that the BLS builds into its Consumer Price and Wholesale Price Indexes are often compared, with confusing results, with indexes of realized unit value changes. For example, using data from consecutive censuses or annual surveys of manufacures, it would be possible to compute the dollar change in unit value per ton of all steel produced, or of all gasoline. Such comparisons are affected, however, not only by price change of carefully defined types of steel or gasoline sold through specific channels, but also by changes in the product mix. There might be more or less high-grade steel or high-octane gasoline in one period than another, for example. Moreover, the change in unit values may reflect different sources of supply or different customers. An index of unit values derived from purchasers would give a still different result as compared with unit values derived from producers' shipments since changes in transportation and distribution costs, as well as price change, would be involved. Some confusion exists regarding the meaning of the term "base period" as applied to the BLS price indexes. Although the weights for the CPI are based on the year 1950, adjusted to 1952, the index as published describes the change in prices from the average of 194749. The latter reference point might be termed the index base, or base reference period. Ideally, the weight and reference bases should coincide, but in practice this is not always feasible. Basic data suitable for weights are not always available for the standard reference period established by the Bureau of the Budget for all Government statistical series. Moreover, it may be desirable for some index series to change the weighting structure more often than the reference period is changed. For specific purposes it may be convenient to shift the reference base to a period other than the standard one for a given series. Thus a chart of the CPI and its major components on a 1939 base affords a graphic picture of the movements in consumer prices since immediately before World War TT. Of course, as Weslev C. Mitchell demonstrated in the famous BLS bulletin on The Making and Using of Index Numbers,1 shifting the reference base may lead to sizable errors, unless the translation is computed separately for each item in the index. This arises from the fact that as the index is carried further 1 U. S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, bulletin No. 656. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 111 away from its weight base the relative movements of the individual prices become widely scattered. The short method of shifting in effect applies a different set of weights to the individual prices than that which was carefully built into the original index series. I have described in general terms the nature of our Wholesale and Consumer Price Indexes, indicating that each embraces a wide variety of commodities involved in market transactions in a defined stratum of economic activity. The question often arises, How well do these indexes indicate changes in the general price level ? This is difficult to answer, because no one has succeeded in defining the universe of transactions included in a general price level in terms capable of measurement. In its broadest context the general price level embraces all transactions involving transfers of goods, services, money, and financial obligations however expressed. Many of these elements cannot be defined in terms such that a price or value could be determined for purposes of index construction or that weights for combining different elements could be established. The nearest approach to an index of all prices is the implicit deflator which is a byproduct of the translation of current dollar estimates of the gross national product into constant dollars of a base reference period. The GNP implicit deflator is derived by first deflating each component of the GNP by the most appropriate price index from whatever source available. Each component is thus expressed in terms of constant dollars of the desired base period. A comparison of the aggregate of deflated components with the current dollar aggregate provides the implicit price index. If the deflation is carried out in maximum detail the resulting price index has the characteristics of a Paasche, or current weighted index. To the extent, however, that the original deflation is accomplished for larger groups only, using already available composite price indexes, the resulting implicit deflator has a larger component of weights from earlier periods, and loses some of its Paasche characteristics. For most purposes measures of general price movements have more usefulness if limited to a definable transaction level or economic sector. It is in this respect that the BLS indexes provide effective measures of changes in price levels. The Consumer Price Index is a reasonably good measure of retail price trends, representing household purchases of goods and services. By definition the CPI does not measure changes in prices paid by high income or very low income families, farmers, or the self-employed. To a certain degree, however, the index covers the modal range in the entire retail market distribution of household goods. The Wholesale Price Index may be considered a measure of general price movements at the production level of the economy. Although its commodity content is much larger than that of the CPI, it is a less satisfactory general price measure in that it does not include business services, construction, real estate, transportation, and securities. There is a tendency to think of the CPI and the WPI as two comparable measures of price movements at different levels in the economy. In a sense, of course, this is true. But the assumption of similarity leads to erroneous conclusions regarding the relationship between the two. We are often asked to explain why the CPI is rising while the W P I is falling, or vice versa. When the Consumer iMce Index rises 112 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH more rapidly than the Wholesale Price Index, many users leap to the hasty conclusion that the housewife is being victimized by the rapacious middleman. Such a conclusion cannot be supported by comparing the two indexes. In the first place the indexes do not measure prices of similar groups of commodities at two transaction levels. The Wholesale Price Index includes raw materials. It also includes semifabricated parts and components made from those raw materials and the final products incorporating the parts and components. The manufacturer's price of the consumer good may parallel the retailer's price, but in the W P I that price change may be offset by movements m prices of things that never enter the consumer market. This means that comparison of the two indexes will no.t provide a valid measure of trends in price markups or margins. Thus far, I have referred to the Consumer Price Index and the Wholesale Price Index in discussing price index problems and objectives. A more detailed examination of the two indexes will serve to indicate their uses and limitations and provide a background for suggesting needed improvements in and additions to these basic measures of price movement. The Consumer Price Index, inaugurated in essentially its present form in 1918, is defined as "a measure of changes in prices of the goods and 2services bought by families of city wage earners and clerical workers." I t is a price index, and not a measure of changes in family living costs. This distinction is worth emphasizing, because it has significant implications with respect to the use of the index in wage escalation. The CPI is computed by comparing prices from period to period for a fixed "market basket" of goods and services. A cost-of-living index, on the other hand, would be analogous to an expenditures index. The usual concept of cost of living includes the changes in family expenditures which occur when its living habits change, its income rises or falls, and its requirements for food, shelter and clothing change with increases or decreases in the family size. Although the index is not constructed to reflect changes in living costs as thus defined, the market basket items are representative of the things that wage-earner families actually buy. The content and importance of the items in the basket are determined by periodic surveys of family expenditures. The latest of these studies was carried out during the period 1949 through 1952, and resulted in the revision of the index first released in January 1953. The basic index structure has not been altered since that time, although we have changed commodity specifications or substituted new items in the market basket as items originally included were replaced in the market by others. The market basket contains about 300 specific items of goods and services, including foods, clothing, house furnishings, rent, home maintenance, personal and medical care, recreational goods and services, and other items in the consumption pattern of the population group specifically covered by the index. The current prices of these items are weighted to represent all items consumed by the index families. The prices for the index are obtained from representative stores and service establishments, or other appropriate sources, in 46 cities. 2 See BLS Bulletin No. 1168, Techniques of Preparing Major BLS Statistical Series, ch. 9, fojr full technical description of the Consumer Price Index. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 113 The sample of cities includes the 12 largest urbanized areas in the country. An additional 9 large cities, 9 medium-size cities and 16 small cities, each representing a sampling cell in the universe of about 3,000 urban places in the United States, makes up the balance of the city sample. In addition to the national figure, an index is published for each of the 20 largest cities in the sample. For five major cities monthly indexes are provided. Indexes for the other 15 are issued quarterly. This schedule of releases is governed by the frequency of price collection. We cannot collect prices each month in each city for all items in the market basket. Food prices are obtained monthly in all cities, and all items are priced each month in the five large cities. Most of the nonfood items are priced quarterly in the remaining 41 sample cities, on a rotating basis, so that prices are available each month from a subsample of cities of all sizes. The most obvious and important use of the Consumer Price Index today is in wage escalation provisions of long-term labor-management contracts. It is estimated that approximately 4 million workers are employed under such contracts by which their wages are adjusted on a quarterly or semiannual basis for changes in the purchasing power of the wage dollar as measured by the index. In fact, of course, the index is a consideration in virtually every wage determination made in this country, whether by management alone or through collective bargaining. Although the escalation provisions hinge on a single figure, usually the national index, other important uses involve not only the summary figure but the individual item and group series underlying the total. All of these uses have focused widespread attention on the index, raising questions about its meaning, accuracy, and appropriateness in various situations. Many questions arise from misunderstanding, but others point to the need for expansion and improvement in the underlying current price data and additions to the number and types of price measures made available. The increasing need for retail price data in deflating components of the national accounts can be satisfied only by expanding the scope of the current retail price reporting. The appropriate vehicle for this purpose is the current price program of the Bureau of Labor Statistics. There is gi*eat demand for additional individual city consumer price indexes and for comparisons of living-cost differences among cities. For intercity comparisons, the most effective device is the standard budget. Such a budget, described as the content of a "modest but adequate standard of living" for a 4-person city wageearner's family, was developed by the Bureau in 1947 and its cost computed for each of 34 large cities. That budget base is now out of date, but the Bureau is engaged in developing a new budget structure reflecting current standards. If funds can be provided for the necessary additional price collection, it is hoped that new budget estimates, in terms of annual dollar totals, can be issued by mid-1959 for each of the 46 cities in the Consumer Price Index sample. These figures will furnish a direct and easily understood means of comparing living costs among those cities. Standard budgets are also needed for other family types and for various levels of satisfaction. The present Bureau program includes the preparation of a budget for an elderly 114 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH couple, to provide a basis for evaluating the adequacy of retirement benefits and for estimating changes in living costs for retired couples when they move away from the place of former employment. Reference has been made to the fact that the basic structure of the Consumer Price Index has not been brought up to date since 1952. While maintenance of a fixed base for price comparison is essential if the index is to serve as a wage-income deflator, it is recognized that the sample of items and their weights must be reviewed at periodic intervals. While there are some dissenters, it is generally agreed that such review and revision should be undertaken at intervals of not more than 10 years. In view of the time required for the completion of a new consumer expenditure survey, it is essential that a revision program be initiated in the very near future if the index is to be revised on that schedule. As the earlier discussion has indicated, the Wholesale Price Index differs fundamentally in many respects from the Consumer Price Index. In fact, it specifically excludes from its scope sales to household consumers. The term "wholesale" in this instance refers to sales in large lots, not to prices paid or received by wholesalers, distributors, or jobbers. 3 The index does not include Government, services, or constructions. Whenever possible, the prices used in constructing the index are those applying to the first important commercial transaction for each commodity. The index is therefore frequently and more properly referred to as a measure of primary market prices. The Wholesale Price Index is based on monthly price data for nearly 2,000 commodities, ranging from raw materials, such as grains, fibers, and iron ore, to finished products, such as canned foods, clothing, automobiles, and machine tools. For most of the raw materials the prices used are those established in the organized exchanges and quoted in the trade journals. Prices of semifabricated and finished products are generally obtained directly from the producers by mail questionnaire. The weighting structure of the index is designed to account for the value of all commodities sold in the domestic market, including imports. The weighting data are obtained from value of shipments as reported in the census of manufactures, the value of agricultural and extractive industry products are reported by the Department of Agriculture and Interior, and imports as reported by the Department of Commerce. The general policy of the Bureau is to review and revise the weighting structure each 5 years, as the results of the quinquennial Census of Manufacturers becomes available. Although, as I have indicated, the Wholesale Price Index is used as a measure of general price trends, it is the detail underlying the total index that has the widest usefulness. Individual item and group indexes are used in deflating components of the gross national product estimates. Segments of the index are used in escalation provisions of long-term production contracts, commercial leases, and supply contracts. For example, virtually all of the heavy power generating equipment produced is made under an arrangement by which the contract sum is adjusted for changes in the prices of selected materials and components between the initiation and completion of the job. Federal shipbuilding contracts contain similar provisions. s Rf»e Bureau of Labor Statistics Bulletin No. 1168, ch. 10, for full technical description of the Wholesale Price Index. ECONOMIC STABILITY AJSTD GROWTH 115 The wholesale price series are nationwide in scope, with no local detail except for individual item prices as quoted on organized exchanges. Thus, the monthly detailed report provides prices and indexes for potatoes at Boston, Chicago, New York, and Portland, Oreg. Flour, butter, poultry, milk, and other basic foods are reported for several market centers. Central and eastern regional prices are quoted for paperboard. For virtually all other commodities in the index, local detail is not available, chiefly because of sampling problems and the necessity of avoiding disclosure of confidential data. As prices are reported on an f. o. b. point of production or freight equalized basis, the combination of prices originating at different shipping points provides a consistent series. To the individual consumer of industrial products the index may, however, appear incorrect. Thus, the purchaser of, say, finished steel products, may find that the index movement doesn't follow the trends of his own costs. His costs may rise because of freight-rate increases, or because in a period when the terms of sale are changing he is unable to take advantage of better quantity or cash discounts offered by the producers. It has been suggested that a valuable adjunct to the present wholesale price series could be developed through a series based on reports of prices paid by the distributor or industrial consumer. Such an index would reflect fully the effects of changes in freight rates and might also provide a useful check on the ultimate effect of the discounts and allowances offered by producers. The maintenance of a consistent and continuous index of prices paid presents several knotty problems. One of these is the sample of purchasers. Most industrial users of raw materials, components, and capital equipment do not buy all of these items every month. A very large reporting sample might be required? therefore, to furnish sufficient data to establish the average price paid at a point in time. Moreover, the composition of the reporting sample would vary from month to month, which would introduce problems of equating the variations from buyer to buyer in freight costs, discounts, and allowances. The wholesale price series suffers from several deficiencies and inaccuracies, some of which are almost impossible to correct within the present frame of operations. While these deficiencies have little effect on the overall index, they present serious obstacles to the use of many subgroups and special product combinations that are desired for analytical, deflation, or escalation purposes. An important problem area includes heavy industrial equipment, ships, locomotives, and aircraft. Most of these products are manufactured to order, and no "market price" is established for them. Each ship differs from every other ship. Each purchaser of aircraft specifies particular features to be included in his order. The value of these unique products is included in the weight base, but their price in the current index computation is imputed to the price movement of their components or other items of a generally similar type. The use of mail-price reporting has imposed some limitations on our ability to obtain accurate data. There is evidence that some manufacturers may have allowed special discounts or sales rebates to their dealers and have not reported the fact in filling out the monthly price schedule. The solution to this problem appears to rest in regular personal contacts with the firms, to explain the objectives of the price23734—58 9 116 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH index program, to determine the best method of obtaining an actual realized price, and to encourage cooperation in accurate reporting. For some items it appears that direct collection, by personal interview, rather than use of the mail questionnaire, may be necessary. Mention should be made of the need for price indexes on an industry basis. Some types of economic data, such as employment, capitalization, and dividend payments, are available on an industry but not a product basis. Comparable price indexes are frequently needed in the analysis of these series. Industry price indexes are also essential for the development of productivity measures, and for studies of interindustry transfers. The derivation of adequate industry price indexes involves more than a mere regrouping of the present commodity series. Aside from the fact that the output of some major industries is poorly represented in the present series, there are difficult weighting problems. Ideally, the weights should be constructed on a value added basis, so that each industry series would be influenced by the actual value contribution made by that industry to the total output. The present item weights in many instances represent values of groups of items for which price movements are generally similar. This imputation pattern may ignore industry of origin, which means that the value of output for one industry may be included in the weight attached to the product of another. Among the other problems involved are the derivation of adequate weights for secondary products, and the inclusion of interplant transfers, now excluded from the weighting structure. Despite these problems, however, this is one of the gaps in the Bureau's price program which should receive early attention. PRICE AND INCOME MEASURES FOR AMERICAN AGRICULTURE Oris V. Wells, Administrator, Agricultural Marketing Service, United States Department of Agriculture The invitation to prepare this statement was generous: I was to concern myself with the general price level and nonagricultural phenomena only to the extent I so desired, I was not to feel mortgaged to any existing statistical measures simply because they were now provided for, and finally I was not to be overly concerned with theory; rather, I should so far as possible keep the discussion in terms of what appeared to be reasonably practical. There are three comments I should like to make with respect to these terms of reference: First, I am of course aware of and agree with the argument in favor of a stable "general price level." However, I do not know how to measure, at least in any precise way, the general, overall price level nor do I think that any single measure, assuming we were to agree on one, would wholly serve the purpose which the committee has in mind. That is, it never seemed to me in the twenties and early thirties that the Wholesale Price Index measured the general price level even though we often talked as if it did. Nor do I today accept the Consumer Price Index, useful as it is, as a single sufficient measure of the overall concept. Further, except under pressure of great economic strain, and usually then also, it seems to me that many, often the most, of our price problems have to do with differences in price and related economic developments as between different sectors of the economy. Very simply, this means that we are as much interested in sector or partial price level measures as in the direction and magnitude of the total price movement. Second: In discussing price and related economic measures for agriculture, it is difficult for me to start anywhere except with the measures now being used, along with our current recommendations for improvement. Our farm statistics have gradually developed over quite a long time, they have been and are being used to evaluate programs and arrive at decisions, and the problem as I see it has to do with strengthening and improving our current measures, not with designing an entirely new set. Third: Analysis of why prices behave as they do and the effects or implications of such behavior are as important as any set of price statistics. Prices or price indexes by themselves are purely neutraL They only tell in a predetermined way what has happened—not why nor whether it is good or bad, nor what should be done. So I conclude that we should never spend all our funds simply to collect, com- 117 118 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH bine, and release statistics. Appropriate analyses must also be arranged for. There is a good argument that the only really good index or aggregative measure for any practical purpose is one which has been designed to fit precisely and particularly the problem at hand. In fact, I often find myself arguing along the lines of Kenneth Arrow's recent (Econometrica, October 1957) conclusion: "In view of the magnitude of an economic system, it would take only a very small percentage of improvement in economic stability or growth to make almost any conceivable data collection worthwhile" (i. e., the cost of collecting the relevant data would be quite small as compared with the possible gain). But there are practical limits: We must often analyze actual situations and arrive at decisions on the basis of statistics collected in accordance with some earlier estimate of what might be useful while at the same time fiscal administrators and congressional committees are rarely as enthusiastic about statistics as are the economists and the statisticians. So we must design our statistics to supply our analysts and policymakers with as much data as possible bearing on what we believe to be the main questions ahead. There has long been a strong, continuing interest in comparing prices received by farmers with either prices paid by farmers or prices of nonfarm commodities. As a result, we have now been calculating and publishing monthly indexes of (1) prices received and (2) prices and cost rates paid by farmers since the mid-1920's. I should now like to consider these two indexes, omitting, however, any discussion of the parity price calculations which also involve both indexes. There is a double reason for this omission: These are the two basic farmprice measures irrespective of their use in the parity calculations, while the parity problem itself has been recently discussed in a report to the Senate as well as in the statement which I submitted to the Joint Economic Committee only last November.1 PRICES RECEIVED BY FARMERS The index of prices received by farmers as now published by the US DA in our monthly report, Agricultural Prices, is a straightforward aggregative price index, calculated from the base 1910-14=100. The weighting pattern for the period 1910 to 1935 is based on the average volume of farm sales of about 50 commodities during 1925-29, while from 1935 to date the weighting pattern is related to the average sales of 52 commodities accounting for 92 percent of all farm cash sales for the years 1937-41. There are no really difficult problems associated with this index. The commodity mix has not changed so radically over the years as to raise serious questions as to comparability as between even widely separated periods and except for truck crops, some fruits, and tobacco, the accurate measurement of month-to-month changes is not too difficult. 1 See : Possible Methods of Improving the Parity Formula, Report of the Secretary of Agriculture Pursunnt to Section 602 of the Agricultural Act of 1956. S. Doc. No. 18, 85th Consr., 1st sess., February 1, 1957 : and Orvis V. Wells, Parity Prices and Parity Income Formulas, 1933-57. included in Policy for Commercial Acrriculture—Tts Relation to Economic Growth and Rtabilitv, papers submitted by panelists appearing before the Subcommittee on Agricultural Policy, joint committee print, November 22, 1957. ECONOMIC STABILITY ANT> GROWTH 119 There are nevertheless some improvements that would be desirable. We are now primarily dependent upon mail questionnaires for most of our basic data. This leads to certain limitations—limitations which can be removed only by providing for the direct enumeration of a set of dealers selected by modern sampling methods. This would go far to eliminate variations resulting from intermittent nonresponse of mail reporters—i. e., "holes" in the basic sources of price information—and to insure improved representativeness and stability. The data collection procedure for the Consumers' Price Index may be looked upon as something of the pattern toward which we should move. With this development should go the collection of prices for more commodity breakdowns by main classes and main methods of sale. Farm forestry products, which account for several hundred millions of dollars of farm sales, might also be priced. Finally, it would be desirable to shift both the official reference base and weighting pattern for the index to a recent, post-World War I I period. Since American farmers exhibit a strong tendency toward continuing full production, although shifting substantially as between various crops and classes of livestock depending upon relative returns, fluctuations in the prices received index have a relatively high correlation with changes in cash farm sales. Further, since prices farmers receive for most commodities are still flexible, changes in this index, when measured relative to changes in the far more stable jndex of prices and cost rates paid by farmers, give an approximate indication as to the prosperity or well-being of commercial farmers (roughly, the 44 percent of farmers accounting for about 91 percent of all farm products sold). COSTS AND MARGINS Changes in prices received by farmers are also one of the main factors affecting the price of food at retail. However, what the housewife buys at retail is not the raw farm product but rather a combination of the farm commodity along with all of the associated assembling, processing, transporting, and selling services. Since food costs are one of the principal components of consumer expenditures, this means that it is desirable to measure the costs and margins which intervene between farmers and consumers in order that food costs can be broken down into the farm and nonfarm portions. Such calculations are facilitated to the extent that retail prices are collected on such food items as to allow a good composite price to be calculated for comparison with the prices of the raw commodity at the farm level—this is especially true for meat animals, for example. We now estimate the value or retail cost of an average food basket of products grown on American farms. That is, the average quantities of food purchased by an average-sized family, using the same quantity food weighting pattern as used by the Bureau of Labor Statistics in calculating the Eetail Food Price Index, is compared with the estimated farm value of an equivalent amount of the various commodities concerned. Such measurements are essential to understanding the forces affecting both short-run changes and longer term trends in prices of food at retail. 120 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH PRICES AND COST RATES PAID BY FARMERS Commercial farming is a business operation with the farmer's net income depending not only upon prices received, the efficiency of his own labor and management, and the effect of weather upon yields, but equally upon the level of prices and cost rates paid. As a result, efforts to measure prices paid by farmers, or comparisons between farm and nonfarm prices, go about as far back as efforts to measure changes in the average level of prices received. Since the late 1920's the United States Department of Agriculture has been calculating and publishing an index of prices paid by farmers which has gradually expanded into an index of prices and cost rates paid. Compared with the index of prices received by farmers, where the statistical problems are relatively simple, the maintenance and improvement of this index presents some difficult, complex problems. As in the case of the prices received index, the prices paid indexes are still calculated from the official base 1910-14=100. But whereas the general mix of farm commodities sold has remained relatively stable, this index now covers three considerably different periods as it extends back to 1910-14. The first period was characterized by the farming methods which prevailed prior to World War I when horses and mules were almost the sole means of farm power, and is represented in the current calculations by price series representing farmers' purchases for living and production, excluding automobiles, trucks, and tractors, but including allowances for taxes on farm real estate, interest on farm realestate mortgages, and wages to hired farm labor. Then there followed a transition period during which farmers were shifting rather rapidly from horses and mules to automobiles, trucks, and tractors. Accordingly, price series for automobiles, trucks, and tractors, and various automotive supply items were incorporated into the index as of March 1924. The weighting pattern prior to January 1935 was based upon estimated average purchases and outlays of farmers for the years 1924-29. The third period starts in the late 1930's and so far as the index as now calculated is concerned, extends from March 1935 to the present. This period is characterized by the increased use of fertilizer and spray materials, increasing wages to hired farm labor, and the substantial completion of the shift from horses and mules to automobiles, trucks, and tractors. The weighting pattern for this period is the estimated average purchases and outlays by farmers for the years 1937-41. Obviously, the measurement of price changes over periods in which such wide differences have occurred in the actual mix of goods and cost elements entering into farm production and farm family living as have occurred during the last 50 years raises some very real statistical problems. The direct and by all means the most satisfactory solution to these problems is to shift the base and weighting pattern for the index of prices and cost rates paid by farmers to a post-World War I I period. This was one of the chief reasons for the Secretary of Agriculture recommending to the Senate in January 1957 that the official reference base of this index be shifted to the 10-year period, 1947-56. Meanwhile, the Congress did make funds available for a comprehensive survey in 1956 of farmers' expenditures for both production and farm family living purposes covering the calendar year 1955. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 121 We are now analyzing these survey data with a view to calculating a current weighting pattern for the prices-paid index. This should be done whether or not the reference base is changed. But the statistical work would be simplified and the index strengthened if we could dispense with having to trace back through three sets of linkage factors to the original base, 1910-14. In addition to adopting a new weighting pattern and base period for the index of prices and cost rates paid by farmers, it would also be desirable (a) to expand the coverage of the index to include important service or commodity areas not now covered and to strengthen the data for groups now inadequately covered, and (6) to adopt an objective probability sampling procedure combined with enumerative collection of data as already mentioned with respect to prices received. The index of prices and cost rates paid by farmers as now calculated covers (a) prices paid by farmers for 191 items used in farm family living, (&) prices paid by farmers for 199 items used in farm production, and (c) allowances for taxes on farm real estate and farm mortgage interest paid, and wage rates paid to hired farm labor. Actually, prices are now covered for 350 items or commodities since 40 of them are common to both the family living and the farm production subindexes. The prices-paid index is calculated and released on $ monthly basis but the wage-rate data are quarterly and annual rates are used for taxes and interest. The 1955 expenditure survey indicates that our current information covers only about 81 percent of farmers' expenditures for commodities used for both farm family living and farm production. The chief farm family living items not covered are those for medical, dental, and hospital purposes which amount to over $1 billion, or 7 percent of total farm family living expenditures; expenditures for personal insurance of about $400 million, or about 2.5 percent of total living expenditures; and expenditures for recreation amounting to $300 million, or about 2 percent. In the field of farm production, classes of items not now covered include machine hire and work paid for on a custom-rate basis, cash rent, irrigation charges, and marketing expenses for crops and livestock. Representative prices or charges should be collected covering these expenditures. Marketing expenses, for example, account for about $500 million, or 2.5 percent of all production expenditures. In addition, the coverage of some commodity groups already represented in the index should be substantially expanded; e. g., containers for the marketing of farm products and pesticides for the control of insects and fungi. Meanwhile, for many items used in the farm family living field, we ask local merchants to report the average price of the kind of item—e. g., workshirts, overalls, shoes, flour, etc.—most commonly sold. For the more costly items, we do ask for prices according to specifications. We should increase the use of specification pricing although it seems to me that the "most commonly sold" method has some advantages which also need to be considered, especially when dealing with essential, everyday items. These problems of coverage and the use of specification pricing relate in considerable part to the problem of available funds. We are now mostly using mail questionnaires. Widening the 122 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH coverage and enumerative pricing on an objective sampling basis would considerably increase the costs of our price work. INDEX OF FARMLAND VALUES One of the price indexes to which I would like to call the committee's attention is the index of average value per acre of farm real estate. Farm real estate accounts for about 70 percent of the value of farmers' nonfinancial assets, and changes in market values and rates of transfer serve as indicators of the general economic position of agriculture. Although, technically speaking, the index measures only changes in market prices of one productive factor, land, the nature of this resource is such that its price also reflects the confidence or judgment of farmers and others who invest in farmland as to the longer run prospects of agriculture. Consequently, the broad movements that occur in land prices often have significant implications with respect to agricultural credit, rural welfare, and the attainment of f armownership. The regular crop reporters of the Department are the primary source of basic data used in constructing the index of farm real-estate values by the Farm Economics Research Division, Agricultural Research Service. They provide estimates of prevailing market values in their localities as of March 1, July 1, and November 1. Index numbers are computed for States, type-of-farming areas, and special groupings of States as well as for the United States as a whole. Special mail surveys are also directed twice each year to about 10,000 farm real-estate dealers, bankers, lawyers, and others in close contact with local market developments. Data from these surveys provide a check against the crop-reporter estimates as well as a general appraisal of local supply and demand conditions, availability of credit, types of sellers and buyers, and related information. Although the National and State indexes are sufficiently reliable for most purposes, a larger number of reports, particularly by class or type of land, would improve the accuracy of the index in certain States. Steps have been taken in recent years to improve the reporting procedures in New England, Florida, Nebraska, and California with this end in mind. However, a need exists for information as to the level and trend in market prices for areas smaller than States which cannot be met by present reporting procedures. By necessity, a State index often averages significant variations in price movements within the State. A substantial increase in the number of reports for relatively homogeneous areas within States would be necessary to permit the calculation of indexes below the State level. n Price policy is chiefly a means to an end and price indexes themselves rarely measure the final results in which we are chiefly interested. For this reason, it seems necessary to call attention to the need for improving our estimates of farm income and farm expenditures as well as the need for breaking down farm income estimates as between different classes of farms. At the same time, attention is called to the fact that all of the data which we use in deriving average prices and price indexes are also useful and necessary in estimating farm income. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 123 Formerly, farm expenditure and net farm income estimates were made for the United States as a whole with no breakdown either as between different classes of farms or as between the various States and geographic divisions. However, the census of agriculture now classifies farms and tabulates value of production, farm expenses, and related data by farm class. In addition, funds are now available for estimating farm expenditures and farm operators' net income on a State basis. The committee will also recall that during the recent hearings on Policy for Commercial Agriculture, Messrs. Nathan Koffsky and Ernest Grove of the Agricultural Marketing Service were asked to prepare a paper breaking down the national farm income estimates so far as possible between low-production and high-production farms (i. e., farms with annual farm sales of $2,500 or more) for the years 1946 through 1957. We need (1) to strengthen our current farm income estimates wherever possible, especially the estimated income of farm people from nonfarm sources, (2) to substantially improve our estimates of farm production expenditures both by States and for the United States as a whole, and (3) to find ways of breaking down our annual farm income estimates as between classes of farms, especially commercial versus noncommercial farms. Good farm income estimates properly broken down as between the various States and as between commercial and noncommercial farms would, along with a revised index of prices paid by farmers, yield a much better judgment than is now available as to the relative well-being of farm people. Since the committee is chiefly interested in price policy, I shall not endeavor to go into all of the various problems having to do with the estimating of farm income and farm expenditures but they are considerable, and we also need to find some way of getting more adequate annual estimates of both the numbers of farms and of farm population. So far as the aggregative farm income estimates are concerned, the accompanying table does set forth the main aggregates in which we are interested and to which our attention should be directed. Since farm income may be looked at in several different ways, it may be worthwhile to briefly define what each of these aggregates measures: Cash receipts from farm sales or marketings measure the value of farm products sold by farmers during the calendar year. Gross income from agriculture represents the total value of commodities and services produced by farms in the United States, without any deduction for production expenses. In addition to cash receipts from farm marketings, gross farm income also includes direct Government payments to farmers, the value of the net change in inventories of farm products, and noncash income—i. e., estimated allowances for food and fuel consumed directly in farm households and the rental value of the farm dwelling. Production expenses comprise the aggregate costs paid out or incurred by farm operators for production purposes. Current farm operating expenses include wages paid hired farm labor, both in cash and in kind, purchases of feed, livestock, seed, fertilizer, outlays for repair and operation of farm buldings, motor vehicles and other machinery, etc. Charges are also included for depreciation of motor vehicles and machinery, taxes levied 124 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH on farm property, interest paid on farm mortgage loans, and net rents paid to nonfarm landlords. Production expenses do not include an imputed value for labor of the farm operator and his family or for land and other capital owned by the operator. Eealized net income of farm operators from iarming is the balance which remains when production expenses are deducted from realized gross farm income. That is, it represents what farm operator families have available during the year for farm family living and savings on the basis of actual farm sales or family use of farm-produced commodities or services, including use of the farm dwelling. It is not adjusted for the value of the net change in farm crop inventories or numbers of livestock. Total net income of farm operators from farming differs from realized income by the value of the net change in farm inventories. The changes in the physical volume in the various crop and livestock items are valued at the average price of the commodity for the year. This adjustment is added to or subtracted from realized gross or net income of farm operators to convert it to total gross or net income. Both the realized and the total estimates measure returns for the labor and management of the operator and his family and the return on land and other capital owned by the farmer. Net income to all persons on farms from farming adds wages paid for farm work to hired farmworkers living on farms to total net income of farm operators from farming. Income to persons on farms from all sources adds income received by persons on farms from sources other than agriculture to income from agriculture. Farm families on the average receive a fourth or more of their total net income in the form of earnings from employment in nonagricultural occupations or as returns from investment in nonfarm property. Hence the measurement of these items is obviously important as a supplement to the regular measures of farm income. Each of these aggregative or total measures has its appropriate place or use, and the net income estimates when divided by the estimated number of farms or farm population give a much more accurate measure of changes in funds available to farm families than do any of the price indexes. The price indexes do, however, influence and help forecast changes in income, while the index, or subindex, of prices paid by farmers for goods and services used in farm family living is also our best measure of changes in the purchasing power of the farmer's net income dollar. INCOME BY TYPES AND SIZES OF FARMS In addition to strengthening our aggregative measures of farm income and findings ways of breaking them down as between parttime, small-scale, and commercial farms, we also need supplementary analyses indicating the changes that are taking place with respect to different types of commercial farms. The best approach to this that I am so far acquainted with is the costs and returns series for specific types of farms (e. g., central Illinois cash grain farms, Corn Belt hog-beef fattening farms, Cen- ECONOMIC STABILITY ANTD GROWTH 125 tral Northeast dairy farms, central Kentucky tobacco farms, Southwest cattle ranches, Delta cotton farms, etc.) which are now maintained in the Farm Economics Research Division, Agricultural Research Service. On the basis of census, special survey, and other data, representative commercial farming systems are derived for specified types and sizes of farms within given areas. Estimates for these representative farms are then made from year to year as to changes in organization, crop and livestock production, sales, expenses, net income, and related information. These series provide information on year-to-year changes as well as an appraisal as to differences among various types and sizes of commercial farms in major producing areas. So far, such series are available for about 30 types of farms m 16 of the more important type-of-farming areas. To be most useful, the number of farm types or areas for which such series are calculated needs to be sufficiently increased to be representative of broad types of farming (cotton, dairy, etc.) for the United States as a whole. Also, the collection of data from current surveys should be strengthened with respect to such items as hired labor, fertilizer, pesticides, farm machinery, and building repair and improvement. # * * In discussing the various price and income measures in sections I and I I above, I have tried to indicate what the main measures are and discuss briefly the improvements that should be made. The views expressed are personal rather than official. For more detailed information, the committee is referred to volume 1, Agricultural Prices and Parity; volume 3, Gross and Net Farm Income; volume 4, Agricultural Marketing Costs and Charges; and volume 6, Land Values and Farm Finance, of Agriculture Handbook No. 118, Major Statistical Series of the United States Department of Agriculture; How They Are Constructed and Used. United States Department of Agriculture, 1957. 126 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Number and percentage of farms and proportion of market sales, by economic class, United States, 1954 Economic class Commercial farms: With sales of $2,500 and over: Class I Class II . . Class III Class IV Value of sales $25,000 and over.. $10,000 to $24,999 $5,000 to $9,999 $2,500 to $4,999 Total With sales of less than $2,500: Class V._ Class VI _ _ $1,200 to $2,499 $250 to $1,999 i Total _ $250 to $1,199 i Under $250 _. Percentage of all farms Percentage of market sales Thousands Percent Percent 134 449 707 812 2.8 9.4 14.8 17.0 31.3 26.9 20.5 12.1 2,102 44.0 90.8 763 462 16.0 9.7 5.7 1.4 1,225 25.7 7.1 575 878 3 12.0 18.3 .1 1.5 coco Other farms: Part-time Residential Abnormal 2 Number of farms Total 1,455 30.4 2.0 All census farms 4,782 100.0 100.0 » Farms with sales of $250 to $1,199 were classified as part-time if the operator worked off the farm as much as 100 days, or if other income of the operator family exceeded farm sales. * Public and private institutional farms, experiment stations, and S3 on. Based on Bureau of t h e Census data. Adapted from table 2 of Family Farms in a Changing Economy, Agriculture Information Bulletin No. 171, March 1957, USDA, ARS. Selected data relating to farm prices and incomes, United States, 1939 and 19J/.6-58 Food market basket 3 Prices received and paid (1910-14=100) Year 1939 1946 — _ 1947 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 5 19f6: 4th quarter 1957:s 1st quarter 2d quarter 3d quarter ___ 4th quarter 1958: 1st quarter Prices Prices paid received b y farmers' or parityindex i index Parity ratio (percent) 2 95 236 276 287 250 258 302 288 258 249 236 235 242 234 123 208 240 260 251 256 282 287 279 28:1 281 285 296 289 77 113 115 110 100 101 J07 100 92 89 84 82 82 81 237 243 247 241 254 294 296 295 298 302 81 82 84 81 84 Farm value a $172 (I) 467 497 435 432 497 482 445 421 395, 390 400 393 385 395 414 407 Marketing margin Measures of income from farming or to farm people (billion dollars) Cash receipts from farm sales < Realized 485 493 488 527 552 558 565 574 582 607 590 7.9 24.8 29.7 30.3 27.9 28.4 32.9 32.6 31.2 29.9 29.5 30.4 30.0 30.9 10.6 29.3 34.0 34.6 31.6 32.1 37.1 36.7 35.1 33.7 33.2 34.4 34.4 35.2 6.2 14.3 16,8 18.6 17.9 19.2 22.3 22.5 21.2 21.5 21.6 22.3 22.9 22.6 4.4 15.0 17.2 15.9 13.7 12.9 14.8 14.3 13.9 12.2 11.6 12.1 11.5 12.6 597 607 616 607 30.3 30.0 29.8 30.0 34.5 34.4 34.3 34.5 22.8 23.0 22.8 23.0 11.7 11.4 11.5 11.5 a $279 1 Index of prices and cost rates paid by farmers for goods used in faim family living and production including allowances for hired labor and taxes and mortgage interest paid per acre of farm real estate 2 Index of prices received expressed as a percentage of the index of prices paid. 3 The market basket incluies estimated quantities of United States grown foods purchased per urban worker family in 1952. 1939 estimates based en same market basket as for 1947 to date. Comparable data for 1946 not available. Gross farm Production expenses * income 4 Net income of farm operators from farming* Total 4.5 14.9 15,5 17.7 12.9 13.7 16.1 15.1 13.3 12.7 11.9 n.6 12.1 12.0 12.0 12.1 12.2 12.2 Index of farm Income to persons land values on farms (1912-14=100) From farming From ail 5.2 16.7 17.4 19.7 14.7 15.5 18.0 17.0 15.1 14.4 13.6 13.4 13.9 fl () 7.7 21.0 22.3 24.8 19.9 20.8 23.6 23.1 21.1 20.2 19.9 20.1 20.2 («) (6) sources («> 82 141 157 170 177 174 200 221 221 216 224 232 247 ?241 (6 (6 8 247 a •253 7 259 (8 I 3 * Quarterly data are seasonally adjusted annual rates. « Preliminary. * Quarterly data not available. * Nov. 1. s Mar. 1. »July 1. Compiled from Agricultural Marketing Service and Agricultural Research Service data. to 128 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH FARMERS9 PRICES % OF 1910-14 300 200 100 % OF PARITY I 150 Prices received 100" •••••••••••••- ••v 50 1910 1920 1930 1940 1950 * MONTHLY DATA A INCLUDES INTEREST, TAXES. AND WAGE RATES. ANNUAL AV DATA, 1910 23, BY QUARTERS. 1924-36, BY MONTHS, 1937 TO DATE U. S. DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE The indexes of prices received and prices and cost rates paid by farmers are shown in the first section of the above chart. Note that while the index of prices received by farmers remains relatively flexible, the index of prices and cost rates paid by farmers has become increasingly inflexible, showing no real decline from 1952 to date. The relationship between prices farmers receive and the prices and cost rates they must pay—commonly referred to as the "parity ratio"—is shown in the second section of the chart. FARM FOOD MARKET BASKET0 Farm Value and Marketing Margin DOLLARS Marketing margin Farm value 600 1939*'47'48'49'50'51 '52'53'54'55'56'57'58'59 ° BASED ON ESTIMATED QUANTITIES OF FARM FOOD PRODUCTS BOUGHT BY URBAN WORKER FAMILIES, 1952 * ESTIMATES BASED ON SAME MARKET BASKET AS 1947 TO DATE U.S. DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE NEG. 6008-58(3) AGRICULTURAL MARKETING SERVICE ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 129 The above chart breaks the retail value of an average American family's annual purchases of foods derived from American farms into its two basic components—that is, the farm value of the equivalent raw commodities and the total costs and margins which intervene between farmers and consumers. Note that from 1951 into 1956 marketing costs rose relative to farm prices so that the farmer's share of the retail food dollar declined from 49 percent to 40 percent. In 1956 and again in 1957, 60 percent of the cost of the food market basket was accounted for by marketing charges. Falling farm prices tended to offset the increase in marketing costs and margins from 1951 through 1956, but with some increase in farm prices in 1957, along with another increase in marketing costs, prices of food at retail also increased. INCOME OF FARM OPERATORS $ BIL. Realized gross* 40 30 PRODUCTION „ EXPENSES!! 20 10 1930 1935 1940 1945 1950 1955 1960 • EXCLUDING INVENTORY CHANGE, INCLUDING GOVERNMENT PAYMENTS U . S . DEPARTMENT OF AGRICULTURE NEC 443-58(3) AGRICULTL The above chart traces the realized gross and net income of farm operators from farming from 1930 through 1957 and indicates the increasing importance of production expenses as a determinant of net farm income. The rise in production expenses reflects two main influences: First, technological developments have substituted machines and other industrial products for human labor which has brought a high, relatively inflexible cash cost structure to modern American agriculture. Second, persistent inflation during the last decade has had a more basic effect on farmers' costs than on prices of products sold by farmers. In 1957, production expenses accounted for 2 out of every 3 dollars received by farmers from farming operations, as compared with a ratio of only about 1 out of every 2 dollars in 1947-49. Ill PAST PEICE BEHAVIOR VIEWED IN THE CONTEXT OF CYCLICAL AND SECULAE ECONOMIC CHANGES 131 23784—58 10 / / / . Past price behavior viewed in the context of cyclical and secular economic chmiges A. What have been the general price movements based on the various available indexes? What cyclical and secular economic changes have been associated with these price movements ? B. In studying trends, particularly those of recent years, what has been the relationship between price changes and changes in the cost of the various factors of production— 1. To what extent have price changes preceded or lagged behind changes in labor costs ? 2. To what extent have price changes exceeded changes in labor costs? 3. What has been the effect of changes in capital costs—i. e.? interest rates and other costs—on prices? 132 THE BEHAVIOR OF PRICES, 1890-1940 Clarence H. Danhof, Tulane University Information on the movements of prices over time plays an indispensable role in the analysis of economic fluctuations. When employed in conjunction with other indexes of business activity, price series contribute to the appraisal of business conditions. In short-run situations, price trends provide guides in suggesting probable economic developments. Prices play an essential role in the interpretation of data on production and income values and are similarly indispensable in appraising the effectiveness of the economy in supplying real goods and services. They are useful in measuring changes in the relative positions of economic groups. The internal structure of prices—of factors and end products—also invites attention. The possibility exists that analysis of the changing pattern of prices within the total structure may uncover recurring relationships that will contribute and assist in the development of control programs. This paper reviews briefly some of the more significant aspects of price level movements and certain relationships within the structure of prices from the point of view of their relevance to the promotion of an economy operating at maximum effectiveness. Many aspects of the subject will be treated lightly since they will be dealt with more fully elsewhere in this compendium. The period covered is the half century, 1890-1940. The paper is primarily a summary of observations and conclusions of recent research. ROLE OF PRICES A price originates as the money side of a single exchange action involving a buyer, a seller, and a specific good or service. The fundamental function of prices is to make possible the appraisal by buyers of the goods and services available, and the appraisal by sellers of opportunities to offer goods for sale. The system of prices acts to give producers minute information as to the terms of availability of production factors as well as to measure the effective desires of purchasers. Prices are thus the mediums by which the resources allocating and product determining functions are carried out in a free enterprise system. In performance of this service, specific prices are constantly changing, displaying varying degrees of sensitivity, shifting relationships one to another with varying frequencies and differing amplitudes. To effectively analyze prices, whether at a point in time or over a period, they must be merged or consolidated. Thus, we may consider the prices of groups of commodities, classified in some logical relationships as to origin or use; prices of factors of production as contrasted with end-use goods; and prices as a totality, which when viewed as a historical series, constitutes the concept of the price level. Such 133 134 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH groupings may reveal significant trends, obscured in the great mass of historical data. Such groupings are, however, no longer true prices. Each item in such a group of price measures as, for example, the BLS wholesale price series shown in the table, must be envisioned as an abstraction. It is an artificial summarization of a multitude of prices which over the period covered have moved in opposite directions and with varying amplitudes. It is obvious that much of what has actually happened is lost in reducing such activity to a single figure; on the other hand, the essential meaning in the complex of changing prices is approached in a sufficiently simplified form to provide a tool of wide applicability. The changes found in such measures of the general price level may be usefully classified according to the period of time involved, or to conform to some change which is to be interpreted. For our purposes the importance of price movements relates to changes in economic activity and our primary interest is in the referral of price movements to the phases of the business cycle. There exist also movements over time periods longer than the cycle. SECULAR TRENDS The 30 years from the close of the Civil War to 1896 were characterized by a persistent decline in the price level. The wholesale index which stood at 116.3 in 1866 (1926=100) fell to 46.6 in 1896. This downward movement was remarkably continuous, interrupted only by a few short upturns and a few years of stability. From the 1896 low, prices turned upward, moving sharply until 1900, and then more slowly until 1915, at which time prices were 50 percent above the low. War conditions stimulated further sharp increases, prices reaching in 1920 the highest levels of this half century. The peak was short lived. Precipitous declines occurred in late 1920 and in 1921, the fall in the wholesale index from 154 to 98 being by far the sharpest short-term decline in the period. The movement was remarkable for its brevity. Stability was achieved in 1924 at levels well above prewar. There was relatively little movement in prices in the 5 years following. This period of stability was interrupted by a renewed downward movement; the severe declines which characterized the early thirties. The low point came in 1933. Since that time the price level has moved consistently upward, interrupted only by mild reaction in 1937-38. The causes of such long-term secular movements are not likely to be found in analysis of the internal structure of prices. Long-term trends in the prices of individual commodities usually reflect technological developments, changes in raw material supplies, or in consumption patterns and institutional relationships. Long-term swings in the general price level are generally associated with changes in external factors such as wars, technological developments, and institutional changes, particularly those relating to the currency supply. Though the relationship of secular to cyclical changes is the subject matter of a considerable literature, no significant generalization seems possible at this time. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 135 PRICES IN CYCLICAL CHANGES During this half century 14 cyclical movements in economic activity may be identified following the criteria developed by the National Bureau of Economic Kesearch. Cycle peaks and troughs are detailed as shown on the table, and the data grouped accordingly. Some of these cycles were periods of mild adjustment, movements of output and prices ranging narrowly. The major disturbances were those of 1893-97 (two cycles), 1902-4,1907-8,1913-14,1920-21,192933, and 1937-38. Significant declines in production and employment occurred in some of the pre-World War I contractions but price changes were in most instances relatively modest, declines being moderate and quickly recovered. During the contractions of 1899 and 1904 the prevailing rising trend of prices persisted although dampened in 1904 by declines concentrated in the metals and chemicals groups. From 1904 to 1907 metals were much the most volatile price group; suffering the largest decline in 1908. The contraction of 1908 was accompanied by a severe financial crisis, heavy unemployment, and reduced production. The decline of prices was, however, moderate and of brief duration. The contraction of 1911 was accompanied by a general price decline of 6 or 7 percent and a recovery within a year to 1910 levels. The briefer but more severe contraction of i914 made little impression on the general price level though declines in metals and fuels were substantial. Manufacturing activity rose rapidly after 1914, reaching a peak in 1918. Prices followed behind, at first slowly, and then more rapidly, continuing to rise long after manufacturing activity was contracting. The peak was reached in 1920 at a level more than double that of 1910-14, representing an expansion proportionately far greater than occurred in physical production. The rise in prices was shared by all categories though there were marked differences in the timing of peaks and course of the subsequent declines. Chemicals reached a peak in 1918, farm products in 1919, and metals and building materials in 1920. The 1921 contraction, though brief, was one of the most severe up to its date, measured in declines in production or employment. It is noteworthy for the precipitous decline in prices, a large part of the increase of the preceding 5 years being wiped out in an 18-month period. Metals experienced the smallest group decline in 1921 but continued to fall in 1922. All other price groups achieved stability in 1922 at a level about 30 percent above prewar. Some recovery in prices was evident in 1922, the upward movement continuing in 1923. A mild contraction in 1924 proved a minor and temporary setback; prices continued to press upward, reaching a postwar high the following year, the all commodity index standing at 103. A mild contraction in 1927 was accompanied by widespread price drops which reduced the all commodity index by 5 percent. Stability was characteristic of 1928 and 1929, but a decline of about 10 percent occurred in 1930. Further declines in 1931 and 1932 brought the allcommodity index down to 65 in 1932 and early 1933, a drop of roughly one-third in 6 years. Farm products, textiles, fuel, and lighting ma- 136 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH terial led the decline in time and in magnitude; metals and building materials evidenced the greatest resistance to the trend. Prices of raw materials in 1932 were 45 percent of 1926 levels while manufactured commodities were off 35 percent. Marked recovery of prices occurred in 1935 and 1936, leveled off in 1936 and resumed in 1937. Increases were most marked in farm products. A renewed decline then pushed prices back to 1934-35 levels, with farm products and raw materials once again suffering the greatest reduction. Metals and building products successfully resisted the reversal. Prices in 1938-40 remained stable at these levels until 1940, although farm products and raw materials suffered further declines. A much more detailed analysis of price history of this period is readily possible. This brief review serves here as background for analysis which utilizes far more detailed information. Such analysis suggests the operation of some simple but fundamental relationships. It seems reasonable to conclude, for example, that there is no such thing as a "normal" price level; at least none seems to have existed in this half century. There have, however, been glimpses in this period of a desirable structural complex of prices: that is, a pattern of interrelationships which operate in such manner as to permit or induce a rate of maximum output, that maximum being established by resource availability. It also seems clear that increases in the general price level occur when output is moving to higher levels. As the volume of output approaches the capacity of the system, strains develop, and very rapid price increases of considerable magnitude occur. On the other hand, declines in prices are general when productive activity declines. It would seem to be true that many prices can resist declines with sufficient strength so that very sharp reductions in activity may occur with only modest general price reactions. Perhaps of greatest significance is the fact that a low level of output can apparently be maintained alongside of prices stabilized at what seem to be disproportionately high levels. A variety of relationships between prices and output exists within the price level. In agriculture, for example, production is more responsive to physical than to market forces. In such commodity groups as metals or building materials, there appears to exist, on the other hand, a substantial ability to resist price declines despite disproportionate drops in production. SOME CHARACTERISTICS OF PRICE MOVEMENT Economic output consists of goods and services valued at prevailing prices, measurable as an aggregate because of prices. Over time the aggregate value varies as a result of changes in both the prices and! quantities involved. There is, of course, very great diversity in the magnitudes of price and quantity changes but the role of prices in such changes can be roughly identified.1 In the earliest phases of an upturn, increases in quantities seem completely responsible for expanding activity in nondurables, farm products, and consumer products. Prices rise but lag and quantity increases dominate the continuing expansion in all commodity groups. 1 These paragraphs are based upon Frederick C. Mills, Price-Quantity Interactions in Business Cycles, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1946. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 137 Thereafter price rises become a weightier factor in the increasing aggregate of business activity. Increased capacity is being brought into production and quantities increased correspondingly, but price rises continue dominant. In the final stages of business expansion, quantity factors become increasingly important, with accompanying weakness in prices. As contraction develops, prices weaken more slowly than quantities decline. Changes in physical quantities tend to reverse the direction of business movement more frequently than do prices. Price movements differ as to the frequency of change, in the duration of a change in one direction, the magnitude or amplitude of the change, and in the timing of the movement with reference to other prices. Some price series show daily changes as do many common stocks. Others change less frequently: wheat prices characteristically changed about once per month in the period 1890-1925. Still other prices remain fixed for much longer intervals. Steel prices in the same period changed once every 9 months. More recently automobile prices have characteristically changed only with annual model changes. Moreover the magnitude of such changes vary. For example, the annual mean deviation of the price of steel rails was only 2.4 percent in the 1890-1925 period; in contrast, coke prices over the same period deviated 14.5 percent from the annual mean. The amplitudes of price movements are widest for goods at the raw material level and at the consumption levels, less m the intermediate categories. Correspondingly, variations in quantities are greatest in such groups as durable goods. The sensitivity of prices has been intensively investigated by F. C. Mills. Mills concluded that there was a "definite tendency toward a decline in 2the variability of commodity prices during the period 1890-1912." With reference to the years 1922-25, Mills believed that price variability was greater than in the earlier period due to the operation of war induced forces. The nature and significance of variability or flexibility of prices aroused a great deal of interest in the 1930's, the typical point of view being that increased sensitivity of prices would produce greater stability in production.3 The subject is discussed elsewhere in this compendium. From the point of view of the problems of identifying and measuring cyclical movements, these differences in variability are significant. The movements of the BLS Wholesale Price Index of Basic Commodities have been determined by the National Bureau of Economic Research as leading cyclical turns by 2.6 months at the peaks, and 3.2 months at the troughs.4 The BLS Index of all wholesale prices other than farm products or foods, moves in rough coincidence with the cycle. Other price groups lag severely, as in the case of metals. On the whole, price series are useful in cycle prediction only in support of other types of indicators. 2 Frederick C. Mills, The Behavior of Prices. National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1927, p. 156, of 1957-58. 8 A review of the literature is conveniently available in Kenneth D. Roose, The Economics of Recession and Revival. An Interpretation of 1937-38. Yale University Press, New Haven, Conn., 1954, ch. 9. * Geoffrey Moore, Statistical Indicators of Cyclical Revivals andi Recession, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1956. 138 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH PRICES AS COSTS Up to this point our concern has been with certain characteristics of the movement of the price level. Specific product prices reflect the conditions which bear upon the supplying of the goods, and particularly the prices that prevail for labor and raw materials. In the long run the relationship between the costs of the factors of production and the prices at which products are sold, must be such as to leave to the producer a profit sufficient to permit and induce him to continue or make indicated adjustments in his activities. The intensity of resource use, and hence the volume of production of the individual firm, is influenced by its profit position, particularly by the direction of change of profits. Such profit experiences and anticipations are a function of the relationship between the quantities which can be sold at prevailing or anticipated prices and the trend of the cost of providing such quantities. The shifting relationship between product and factor prices invites attention as offering an approach to the problems posed by cyclical fluctuations. There is evidence that the preeminent student of the business cycle, Wesley Mitchell, entertained some such general hypothesis. Profits of some sectors of the business world declined more quickly than those of others, responding to rising costs. Such reduced profits—though profits in general might be rising—would produce declines in capital expenditures, inventory liquidations—and in other ways might induce a retrenchment. Localized, such developments might have little, if any, effect, but if such adjustments became sufficiently widespread, a cycle is established.5 RAW MATERIALS Movements of raw materials prices can be judged only generally for the years 1890-1912. Thereafter BLS wholesale price groupings of raw materials, semimanufactured goods and manufactured products provide more suitable aggregate data. Raw material prices since 1913 to 1940 have characteristically moved in advance of prices of fabricated products in both advancing and declining phases of the cycle. They have also varied more widely. Wholesale prices of semifabricated articles, on the other hand, have tended to rise higher and fall more slowly than manufactured goods. On the basis of a detailed examination, F. C. Mills concluded that changes in materials costs played a neutral part in price movements of 1914-29. Though raw material costs rose somewhat relative to prices of fabricated products, increasing efficiency in operations6 served to maintain material prices in relation to finished products. There is no reason to believe that any significant and persisting change in relations between raw material and finished prices operated during this period. WAGES Wages are a very large part of aggregate production costs. In specific industries, wages may play a smaller role in costs but, never5 Wesley C. Mitchell, Business Cycles, University of California Press, Berkeley, 1913, pp.8 457-514, 562-569. F. C. Mills. Economic Tendencies in the United States, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1932, pp. 104, 216, 388-389, 414. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 139 theless, typically a critical one. As changes in the wage element in production costs differ from product prices, they may constitute a factor responsible for the amplitude of the aggregate cycle. Many influences bear, of course, on the labor costs of production. Aside from hourly costs, there are such factors as labor utilization under or over the standard weekly hours, fringe costs, quality, and efficiency of the labor force. The wage rate is, however, probably the most important factor, particularly when viewing economic activity in the aggregate. Data on average hourly earnings as shown in the table are available, although no single series covers this half century. Dealing with the period 1919-1938, Creamer and Bernstein conclude that the data on average hourly earnings probably reflect wage costs with sufficient accuracy for general analytical purposes.7 Average hourly earnings fluctuate much less, relatively, than manufacturing activity, wholesale prices, and with some exceptions, than prices of semifinished goods. The movements in wage rates lag well behind changes in business activity and in employment. In the period 1919-38, the lag in wage-rate movements, whether for manufacturing as a whole or for component industries, was generally in excess of 6 months and an average 9 months behind business activity. If major turning points are considered the lag was 7 months. Wage rates turned on an average 10 months later than factory employment. Moreover, wage rates do not typically decline to the levels of other measures such as wholesale prices; rather, prices appear to move up to meet the weakening wage rates. In the case of prices of finished manufactured products, the experience is more fixed. However, in general, prices for finished products fluctuate more widely than earnings, particularly on the downswing. Earnings show some tendency to rise more than prices on the upswing. CAPITAL Consideration of capital costs involves a wide range of intimately interrelated factors. To mention a few, these include the policies of the banking system with regard to currency supply, the public's propensity to save, business profit expectations as contrasted with the desirability of liquidity, the relationship of price movements to debt burdens, the relationship of product prices to prices of producer durables, and many more. Interest rates on short-term commercial paper are shown in the table, and data on other types of capital are available. The influences reflected in such prices are, however, exceedingly complex. Probably no relationship between commodity prices and capital costs—our principal concern—can be identified in this period in such a way as to be useful for analytical purposes.8 The costs of capital are influenced on both the supply and demand side by numerous forces unrelated to specific prices though reflecting broad price movements. Fortunately, it can be argued that the price of capital is rarely as important a consideration in business calculations as the costs of other 7 Daniel Creamer and Martin Bernstein, Behavior of Wage Rates During Business Cycles, Occasional Paner 84, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1950. s Frederick R. Mncanlny, The Movements of Interest Rates, Bond Yields, and Stock Prices in t*>» United States Since 1856, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1938, ch. VI. 140 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH productive factors, and that it is frequently sufficiently small to be of no determinate significance. PROFITS In a free-enterprise economy, the entrepreneurial function of committing resources to production hinges upon the profits, which may be anticipated in the light of interpretations of recent experience. Profits are, hence, a social cost of production, and a brief resume of profit experience in recent cycle history is relevant. Quarterly data are necessary to meaningful analysis, and are available for the period 1920-38 for a sample of corporations principally engaged in manufacturing and mining.9 Aggregate profits of the corporate sample move with changes in industrial production. Such profits have the significant distinction of rising and falling more dramatically than any other of the comprehensive indicators of the National Bureau of Economic Research. The amplitude of movement contrasts as follows: Average amplitude of movement—Percentage Corporate profits Industrial production Wholesale commodity prices... of mean values durin g a cycle1 Rising stage Falling stage 168.8 35.2 8.7 174.6 32.5 8.9 i Arthur F . Burns, New Facts on Business Cycles, 30th Annual Report, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1950, p. 20. Changes in profits are the resultant of movements of product prices, factor costs, quantities sold, or some combination. The average amplitude of prices is substantially less than for quantities, as the latter is reflected in such an indicator as industrial production. At the level of the firm, it is typically true that changes in volume of sales, rather than in prices, are the major factor in a change in profits. The firm has no control over sales except insofar as it can achieve a superior price-cost relationship. The possibilities of achieving a superior cost structure is limited, since the firm bids for factors in a competitive market. Faced with a changing volume of sales, the firm may adjust by changes in price, within a limited range, or by varying its production rates. A downturn in business activity usually reveals itself to a business firm as resistance to purchase at prevailing rates; i. e., as a decline in the volume of goods that are taken. The consequence is an unplanned buildup of inventories of finished products and, probably, of semifinished goods and raw materials as well. The firm reacts by reducing its purchases of materials, labor, and, most of all, of producers' equipment. Selling prices may or may not be reduced, depending upon inventories, and the likelihood of reestablishing volume above its break-even point. Available data suggest that the reactions of the firm also describe developments in the aggregate economy. There are, however, important exceptions. The aggregate data obscure the fact that some firms will almost invariably be experiencing trends opposite to those which 9 Thor Hultgren, Cyclical Diversities in the Fortunes of Industrial Corporations, Occasional Paper 32, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York, 1950. ECONOMIC STABILITY A3STD GROWTH 141 characterize the whole. At any point in time, there will be a group of firms within a given industry enjoying rising profits, another suffering from declining returns, if not losses, and a third enjoying stable returns. From the point of view of the cycle, declines in profits will occur for an increasing number of firms well in advance of the peak of aggregate profits. The opposite is similarly true; an increasing number of firms will have expanding profits well before the low point is reached in the profits of all firms. There exist in the total economy at all times significant cross- and counter-currents. In any period of general stability, it would appear that these currents are of equal strength and their forces are canceled out; that is, the effects of the reactions of firms with poor profits upon the materials, capital, and labor markets tend to be wholly offset by the expanding activities of those firms with attractive returns. When, however, the currents run more vigorously in one direction than another, the result must be a shift in the level of aggregative activity. When the number of firms experiencing shrinking demand, and hence profits, is very numerous, and if their size in terms of employment and material purchases is substantial, the forces which produce an aggregative contraction may overcome the opposing forces, thereby transferring the contraction movement to the whole economy. Kelatively little is known of the characteristics of business firms grouped, as suggested, according to their profit trends. The inadequacy of available data and the complexity of the problem make analysis difficult. Nevertheless, further exploration in this area offers substantial possibilities of contributing critical information to our knowledge of the nature of business fluctuations. CONCLUSION This brief paper has attempted to address itself to the question: Is there in the history of the price structure of the half century, 18901940, any evidence that suggests that forces within the price system were responsible for initiating the excessive cyclical fluctuations to which the economy has been subjected ? Tentatively the answer appears to be "no". There has been a substantial increase in our knowledge of the price structure but no pattern of relationship has emerged, either in the data or in abstract generalization, which clearly suggests the presence within the system of prices of a cycle-producing force of an initiating nature and adaptable to controls. It is sometimes held that the business cycle is peculiar to our type of society and, if not a direct product of the increasingly complex nature of our economic order, then closely associated with that fact. To the extent to which such a hypothesis may be true it becomes important to develop a price structure of sufficient sensitivity so as to maintain those relationships which will assure a level of activity close to full employment. The problems of the flexibility of price responses offer some promise. Even in that area, however, nonprice determinants seem too important to suggest that anything more than minor improvements in the price mechanism might be anticipated. By and large the search for controls over excessive economic fluctuations would seem to lie in other directions. 142 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Business activity and prices, 1890-1940 Cycle PJuly.. T May . P January T June P December _ T June. P June T December. P September. T August P May.. T June P January T January P January _ _ T December . P August T April P January TJuly Percent gainful Year workers unemployed 1890 1891 1892 1893 1894 1895 1896 1897 1808 1899 1900 1901 1902 1903 1904 1905 1906 1907 1908 1909 1910 1911 1912 1913 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 1920 1921 1922 1923 P May T July. 1924 1925 P October... 1926 T November. 1927 1928 1929 P June 1930 1931 1932 1933 T March 1934 1935 1936 1937 P May 1938 TJune . 1939 1940 5.67 5.74 1.62 4.78 4.38 1.85 0 2.12 6.27 1.92 1.45 4.06 2.35 2.58 5.56 5.87 .46 o0 0 1.33 11.2 6.79 1.71 4.56 1.81 1.01 3.45 3.88 .89 5.91 14.19 22.71 23.36 19.04 17. 56 15.00 12.15 18.40 16.32 13.08 Average Wholesale prices, 1926=100 Physfullical time output, weekly manu- earn- Interest Fuel Metals Chemfactur- ings, All and Build- icals rates, Farm and ing ing, manu- prime comprod- lighting metal and 1899= factur- com- modiucts mate- prod- mate- allied 100 ing, mercial ities rials rials products 1890- paper ucts 99=100 100 102 115 129 132 124 148 159 161 133 158 168 161 185 198 186 218 259 257 254 222 242 194 249 280 266 298 316 317 332 364 311 262 197 228 252 301 3C3 376 295 374 101.0 100.8 101.3 101.2 97.7 98.4 99.5 99.2 99.9 101.2 104.1 105.9 109.2 112.3 112.2 114.0 118.5 122.4 Index of payrolls. 1939= mo 1UU 103.2 123.5 79.7 85.5 108.4 101 2 106.6 109.9 107.9 109.1 116.4 94.1 71.2 49.2 .52.8 67.8 78.0 90.5 108.2 84.2 100.0 114.5 6.91 6.48 5.40 7.64 5.22 5.80 7.02 4.72 5.34 5.50 5.71 5.40 5.81 6.16 5.14 5.18 6.25 6.66 5.00 4.67 5.72 4.75 5.41 6.20 5 47 4.01 3.84 5.07 6.02 5.37 7.50 6.62 4.52 5.07 3.98 4.02 4.34 4.11 4.85 5.85 3.59 2.64 2.73 1.73 1.02 .76 .75 3.94 .81 ..59 .56 56.2 55.8 52.2 53.4 479 50.4 54.2 49.5 51.3 416 48.8 46.5 46.6 48.5 52.2 56.1 55.3 58.9 59.6 59.7 60.1 61.8 65.2 62.9 67.6 70.4 64.9 69.1 69.8 68.1 69.5 85.5 117.5 131.3 43.9 39.6 42.5 44.9 45 8 50.5 52.8 58.4 55.6 58.5 56.4 57.3 62.2 62.2 69.6 74.3 66.8 72.6 71.5 71.2 71.5 84.4 129^0 148.0 13S. 6 154.4 97.6 96.7 100.6 98 1 103 5 100.0 95.4 96.7 95.3 86.4 73.0 64.8 65.9 74.9 80.0 80.8 86.3 78 6 77.1 78.6 157.6 150. 7 88.4 93.8 98.6 100 0 109.8 100.0 99.5 105.9 104.9 88.3 74.8 48.2 51.4 65.3 78.8 80.9 86.4 68.5 6\3 67.7 38.1 37.0 34.8 35.3 34.3 40.3 39.5 33.9 34.5 41.2 46.3 44.6 51.8 60.3 53.3 49.6 52.0 54.4 53.7 51.6 47.6 46.7 51.4 61.3 56.6 51.8 74.3 105.4 109.2 105.3 92.2 84.0 76.8 65.7 70.4 71.2 65.0 65.3 100.0 98.0 93.1 91.0 90.2 79.9 89.1 102.4 109.8 86.3 84.5 85.2 80.8 89.5 90.8 80.2 86.3 116.5 150.6 136.5 46.5 44.2 41.7 41.6 39.8 38 8 38.9 37.4 39.6 43 6 46.2 44.3 45.3 46.7 45.0 48.1 54.0 56.8 52.0 53.7 55.3 55.3 55.9 56.7 52.7 53.5 67.6 88.2 98.6 73.2 74.0 74.6 72.7 65.5 64.7 65.0 70.9 77.4 81.1 82.1 84.2 86.5 84.1 84.1 82.3 76. S 78.5 79.6 79.9 82.0 81.6 80.7 80.2 81.4 112.0 160.7 165.0 182.3 104.3 163.7 96.8 107.3 97.3 92 0 96.5 100.0 88.3 84.3 83.0 78.5 67.5 70.3 66.3 73.3 37.5 76.2 77.6 76.5 73.1 71.7 130.9 149.4 117.5 102.9 109.3 105 3 103.2 100.0 96.3 97.0 100.5 92.1 84.5 80.2 79.8 86.9 86.4 87.0 95.7 9\ 7 94.4 95.8 115.6 150.1 97.4 97.3 108.7 102.3 101.7 100.0 94.7 94.1 95.4 89.9 79.2 71.4 77.0 86.2 85.3 86.7 95.2 90.3 90.5 94.8 157.0 164.7 115.0 100.3 101.1 98.9 101.8 100.0 96.1 95.0 94.0 88.7 79.3 73.9 72.1 75.3 79.0 78.7 82.6 77.0 76.0 77.0 Sources: Cycle identifications: Arthur F. Burns and Wesley C. Mitchell, Measuring Business Cycles. National Bureau of Economic Research. N. Y. 1947, p. 78. J Percent gainf'il workers employed: Comnuted from data in Historical Statistics of the United States, 1789-1945, Government Printing Office, Washington, 1949, p. 65. 0 indicates that estimated employment equaled or in some years (1903, 1917, 1918, 1919) exceeded the estimated total gainful workers. Physical oitDit: Manufacturing, National Bureau of Economic Research in Historical Statistics, p. 179. Weekly earning: Ibid., n. 66. Interest rate: Ibid., p. 278. Wholesale nrices: Hdnd'iook of Labor Statistics, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Government Printing Office, Washington, 1950, p. 118. AN INTERPRETATION OF PRICE MOVEMENTS SINCE THE END OF WORLD WAR II Bert G. Hickman, The Brookings Institution 1 This paper attempts to identify and analyze the principal factors which have shaped the course of prices during the (past 12 years. The emphasis is upon the interpretation of price movements rather than the influence of price relationships on income distribution, resource allocation, or, for that matter, the level of aggregate business activity, although the grosser sort of expectational effects are considered in the latter connection. For the most part, then, the economic consequences of changes in relative prices are neglected except insofar as they are relevant to the behavior of the overall average of prices. I will not be interested here in questions of equity or responsibility or whether unregulated economic forces should be permitted to establish prices within the going institutional framework, but only in the analysis of why prices behaved as they did. All these other topics are bypassed not because they are unimportant, but because a documented interpretation of price tendencies during a span of more than a decade is a sufficiently lengthy undertaking. A good part of the justification for the undertaking, on the other hand, lies in whatever contribution it may make toward better understanding of the broad issues of cause and effect, equity, and responsibility. The paper is organized chronologically, since the principal task is to interpret price behavior in terms of its several causes, and since this job of synthesis is best handled by introducing particular factors as they become important over time. It will not, however, be necessary to give equal weight to the occurrences of every year—we will be selective on that score—and there is at least one topic of an analytical nature which will interest us continuously: the interaction of prices and wages. A major advantage of the predominantly synthetic treatment of the paper is that it will enable us to see how wage-price interactions differ according to the surrounding economic circumstances. In this way needed perspective will be provided on a topic which is often subject to oversimplification and misplaced emphasis in the form of either-or propositions. A PRELIMINARY LOOK AT PRICES I N THE POSTWAR PERIOD Let us take a moment to decide which aspects of postwar price experience we should most like to understand. A glance at chart 1 reveals a number of intriguing features which merit attention. Foremost is the fact that prices have moved substantially higher over the 12 years spanned by the chart. Thus the Consumer Price Index rose 56 percent between January 1946 and December 1957. The pace of advance was markedly uneven, however, and this is the second major fact that we notice. It suggests at the outset that it would be unwise to ignore developments during the period in an explanation of the increase over the period, and that a search for a single cause of the overall advance would be unrewarding. 1 The views expressed in this paper are those of the author. They do not necessarily reflect the views of other memhers of the Brookings staff or of the administrative officers of the institution. My thanks are due to William R. Belmont, who drew the charts and assisted in the preparation of the paper in countless other ways. 143 144 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 1 Indicators of Prices, Production, and Employment (Monthly, '1946 -1957) 85 75 €5 P T P T 150 140 130 1946 47 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 56 57 Sources" Bureau of tabor Statistics, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks(P) and troughs(T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, except for the peakof August 1957 which was dated by the author. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 145 These initial reflections are strengthened when we observe that the unevenness is of several kinds. First, there are variations associated with the ebb and flow of physical activity during business cycles. Prices increased during the 3 business expansions of the postwar period, but stood firm or declined during the 2 complete contractions included in the chart. There is a hint here of the operation of systematic cyclical factors affecting prices, production, and employment. A goodly amount of irregularity is to be found even during like cyclical phases, however. Thus each successive business expansion saw a smaller rise of average consumer prices, with increases respectively of 33, 13, and 5 percent. The first expansion was clearly inflationary, whether one means by "inflation" a sustained and rapid advance of prices, or a rise which is both substantial, and substantially larger than the concomitant increase of production. The second upswing contains a subperiod which is also definitely inflationary; namely, the 8 or 9 months following June 1950 during which consumer prices increased nearly 1 percent per month. No comparable advance in the cost of living occurred during the most recent expansion. The index began to rise midway in the upswing and increased thereafter at the not inconsiderable rate of 0.3 percent per month, however, and it is both interesting and relevant to note that prices rose, faster than production and employment at that time. Apart from these differences in the speed and magnitude of price increases, there are striking distinctions with regard to the internal patterns of prices and production in the several expansions. Both prices and output rose fairly steadily during 1946-48, and when the one quickened or slowed, so also did the other, and roughly in proportion. A similar correlation is to be observed during the early inflationary phase of the second expansion, but at that point the resemblance ends. Wholesale prices actually fell during the remainder of the expansion, and consumer prices first rose more slowly and then leveled off. Production and employment paralleled these price tendencies from mid-1951 to mid-1952, but rose strongly in the face of stable prices from then until mid-1953. The pattern of the third expansion differed in still another way, with production and employment rising rapidly during the first 18 months and prices changing scarcely at all, only to be followed by an equally lengthy period in which these tendencies were reversed. Again, these variations suggest that different sets of forces, or different combinations of them, shaped the course of prices during one or another phase of the postwar experience. The indexes of chart 1 serve admirably to map the time path of the overall average of prices. They are averages, however, and they sometimes conceal wide divergencies; after all, there would be little need to describe a central tendency by an average were it not for dispersion of the individual observations. Many hundreds of prices enter these indexes, and for present purposes it would be both impractical and uniformative to study them all. We will find it useful to give separate attention to a few major subgroups, however, for the light that they cast on the determinants of the overall price level and for what they reveal about the operation of specific forces. These subgroups are plotted in charts 2 and 3. Notice that the first of these charts begins in 1947 instead of 1946. 146 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 2 Indexes of Wholesale Prices (Monthly, 1947-1957) 100 -, 90 80 P 145 135 T y - 125 Finished Durable Goods 115 .^ f Other Nondurable . Goods 105 •"*" • yiy mm a a* • a*"' ! '-•••.•.•••. .••.•"••.••" ••...•• 95 *•" 'Foods 85 y • 45 45 i 50 i 51 \ i 52 53 54 55 56 57 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, except for the peak of August 1957 which was dated by the author. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. 147 ECONOMIC STABILITY A3STD GROWTH Chart 3 Indexes of Consumer Prices (Quarterly, 1946-1957) Index 1947-49-100 145 P T P T P Services 135 ^ r 125 115 Food 105 Durable Goods ^fr Other Nondurable Goods 95 35 . / 75 / t 0 1946 47 48 i 49 i 50 1 51 < l i i i 52 53 54 55 56 57 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau x>f Economic Research, except for the peak of August 1957 which was dated by the author. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. The dominant feature of chart 2, of course, is the gap that opened between the indexes beginning in 1951. I t will be seen from the upper panel that prices of farm products and processed foods declined irregularly from 1951 through 1955, all the while that "industrial" prices were stable or rising. Since agricultural products are the basic raw materials for many manufactured nondurable goods, it is reasonable to expect the weakness of the former to be reflected in the prices of the latter, though not necessarily to the same degree because of changes in other components of cost or by reason of differential movements of demand at the various market levels. The expectation is confirmed by the breakdown of wholesale prices of finished goods shown in the lower panel. Like all changes in relative prices, these disparate movements had their effect on the distribution of national income. The question which presently concerns us is whether they also influenced the price level. It is surely pertinent to observe that the gap opened and wid23734—58 11 148 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH ened most noticeably during the only extended interval of overall price stability in the postwar period—that is, from about mid-1951 to late 1955 or early 1956. The observation alone is not enough to establish causation, of course. An unsupported claim that prices were stable on the average because agricultural prices fell could with equal arithmetic justice be countered with the assertion that the rise of nonagricultural prices caused the average to remain stable. The error in this kind of statement is obvious, but it is perhaps less apparent that it is also insufficient to show that the movement of, say, agricultural prices is due to factors peculiar to them alone; for this leaves open the possibility that the height of the price level is determined by general causes and that the change in agricultural prices simply induced a counterbalancing adjustment in other prices without affecting the overall average. These matters must be carefully considered at the appropriate points. The classification of prices by durability of product is of interest in yet another connection. It will be seen that the curve of durable goods prices more nearly resembles an ascending staircase than an inclined plane. The steps do not appear in every year, but when they do it is usually after midyear. Traces 6f this tendency for price increases to concentrate in certain months can also be distinguished in the index of prices of nondurable goods excluding foods, but it occurs less regularly there, is centered on the months before and after the turn of the year, and is less pronounced, except possibly in 1955 and 1956. Food prices do not exhibit the tendency, although they seem to be subject to seasonal peaks of their own in the late summer and autumn. An investigation of the causes of the step pattern and its comparative strength among classes of products promises to reveal something about the nature and timing of inflationary processes. The wholesale prices included in chart 2 refer only to goods. A breakdown of the Consumer Price Index includes prices of services as well, and shows that they are much less subject to short-term fluctuations than prices of goods (chart 3). Services reveal in purest form the underlying inflationary cast of the postwar period. Since they are produced as used and cannot be stockpiled, they are unaffected by temporary shifts of inventory demand by households or businesses. At the same time, their persistent upward course is symptomatic of constant pressure from increasing demand, increasing cost, or both. While it is true that their rise relative to prices of goods during the past 7 years must reflect a tendency toward lagging productivity or growing relative demand, their absolute increase need not have occurred if gains in real national income due to advancing productivity had been distributed in the form of general price reductions at a constant level of money income. BASIC CONCEPTS The theoretical apparatus which underlies the subsequent discussion rests on one or two key concepts which can readily be illustrated by examples. First, there is the notion of aggregate supply. If we think of an individual business firm, it is apparent that its costs of production can vary in several ways. If it has unutilized plant capacity, it may be able to increase production considerably without forcing costs up, but as ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 149 it approaches capacity operations, unit costs are bound to rise even when there is no increase in the prices which it pays for labor, materials, or other resources. This is because there is an optimal balance between materials, manpower and equipment, and when that balance is exceeded, the output per additional worker or batch of materials must decrease—it will do little good to put two workers on a machine which can be operated efficiently by one. Costs may also be forced up at higher rates of utilization because prices of resources rise—premium pay for overtime is an important example—or because standby units of inefficient equipment may be pressed into service or it may become necessary to hire persons who are poorly trained or otherwise inherently less efficient than the normal complement of workers. Analogous considerations apply when we think of the economy as a w^hole. When coming out of a period of recession, most firms will be operating well within capacity, and increases of demand will go primarily to stimulate production rather than prices. As national output continues to expand, however, bottlenecks will increase prices of some resources, capacity will be reached in some businesses, overtime pay will increase, and so forth. If demand continues to rise, firms will produce more, but they will also charge higher prices to cover the resultant increase of cost. Now, in actual practice it is always possible to get a little more output with a sufficiently lavish expenditure of resources, but it is a useful simplification to think of national output as having a fixed limit at any given time, at a point corresponding to full man-hour employment of labor. Once the limit is reached, further increases of money demand can only raise prices without inducing more output. That is about what happens during periods of pure inflation. It must now be emphasized that two important cost influences were left out of account in the preceding paragraphs. This was deliberately done, for they are quite different from those discussed thus far. The variations in costs already considered were the result of changes in output which were induced by changes in demand—costs and prices would not have risen had demand not increased. The type of cost change to be considered now can occur at any given output and independently of any change of demand. Physical limitations on output can be gradually overcome, given sufficient time, by construction of additional productive facilities and the growth of the labor force. Technological improvements, moreover, may make possible new methods of production which lower costs no matter what the rate of capacity utilization. In these cases, the same total output as before can be produced at lower prices, or alternatively, a larger output will be forthcoming at the same price level. The second main type of independent cost change is an "autonomous" variation in the price paid for a resource. Wage increases negotiated in collective bargaining may usually be regarded as autonomous, since they are not necessarily induced by an expansion of output and will raise money costs of producing each alternative output. Independent changes may commonly occur also in the prices of raw materials imported from abroad, traded in world markets, or subject to supply interruptions due to the vagaries of weather. Provided demand remains unchanged, autonomous increases in resource prices will raise the prices of goods and reduce their output, whereas decreases will have opposite effects. 150 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Demand will not remain unchanged in the ordinary course of events, however, and this brings us to the next major point—that on an aggregative or economy wide basis supply and demand are not independent, but interact with one another in several ways. Thus in the present instance, an autonomous wage boost may increase aggregate demand in addition to raising costs. This is because wages affect incomes as well as costs, and income is one determinant of demand. Suppose that a general wage increase goes into effect at a time of full employment and when businessmen have no independent reason to be pessimistic about the near-term future of sales. Under those circumstances, businessmen are likely to maintain output, increase prices, and wait to see whether the increase diminishes the physical volume of sales. With higher wages and stable employment, consumer demand will be augmented, though not enough to match the price increase. The increase of wage-earner consumption demand will be smaller than the price increase partly because prices will usually be raised enough not only to cover the wage increase but also to increase profits, and partly because workers will save some fraction of their added incomes. If no increase of demand is forthcoming from other sources, the same physical volume of sales as before cannot be maintained at the new price level, and either prices or production or both must be cut. It should not be assumed, however, that other demands will remain unchanged. Large components of final demand are partly or entirely independent of the current level of income. Under the full employment conditions assumed in our illustration, it is probable that businessmen and governmental units will pay the higher prices now necessary to carry out their previously planned physical investments. There is likely also to be sufficient flexibility in the financial arrangements of nonwage personal income receivers to permit them to increase their consumption outlays and defend their living standards even if their incomes lag somewhat in time or amount. Thus aggregate demand may rise enough to sustain the price increase without any reduction of output. This last result is quite possible and even probable under the assumed conditions, but it is by no means inevitable. To cite a single important exception, financial constraints might prevent the necessary expansion of money outlays for plant and equipment, business inventories, or durable consumer goods. Thus "it all depends"—but that is precisely the point. It will be helpful to distinguish two other types of supply-demand interaction in these introductory remarks. The first occurs when the initial change on one side is conditioned by the actual or expected tstate of the other. Thus unions will ask for larger wage increases If they expect demand to be high or rising, and management will resist a given increase less strenuously if they hold the same expectation. Secondly, there is the interaction occasioned by the fact that an initial adjustment of price or output in response to a primary disturbance may induce secondary repercussions, as when a price rise caused by increased demand induces a wage increase which puts further pressure on prices. In summary, the following points should be kept in mind as we interpret postwar price experience. What happens to prices and production depends on both supply and demand. Under given condi- ECONOMIC STABILITY A3STD GROWTH 151 tions of supply, prices and output will rise and fall together along with demand, and their relative movements will be correlated with the level of economywide resource utilization. Under given conditions of demand, autonomous cost increases will raise prices and reduce output, and vice versa for autonomous decreases. An initial change on either side is unlikely to leave the other unaffected, however, and this means that one must be alert to several forms of interaction between the two. In view of these complexities, inferences about the causes of observed behavior should be drawn with care and assertions that single factors are responsible received with skepticism. POSTWAR INFLATION", 194 6 - 4 8 The economy was still operating under the wartime "disequilibrium system" as 1946 opened. The essential ingredients of the system were simple. Resources were diverted to war use only partly by taxation and the remainder of the transfer was deficit-financed. Since taxes were not used to reduce private incomes proportionately to the supply of civilian goods, it was necessary to control prices and allocate quantities by rationing. Since money incomes far exceeded permissible expenditures at controlled prices, and did so for several years, households and businesses perforce accumulated large holdings of money, Government bonds, and other liquid assets. It was called a disequilibrium system, of course, because the demand latent in the prevailing level of money income and wealth was not allowed to determine prices. So long as prices were controlled, the economy was prevented from seeking a market equilibrium. The removal of controls during the last half of 1946 freed the economy to react to the accumulated demand pressures which had been contained previously by administrative devices. The result was a powerful inflationary shock (chart 1). Effective demand was extraordinarily high at the time of decontrol partly because of the wartime heritage of financial liquidity and deferred demands which characterized alike the household, business, and foreign sectors. It was augmented also by the "first round" of wage increases of early 1946. Higher wage incomes increased the postdecontrol money demand for consumer goods, and since it is unlikely that other income receivers diminished their consumption or investment demands correspondingly, if at all, this meant that prices rose more than they would have at the old wage rates. Thus, although the first round of wage increases was by no means the sole cause of the price inflation of 1946-47, it did contribute to itTo argue that it was the sole cause would be to assert that autonomous wage increases disturbed an initial equilibrium in which there was no excess demand, which is absurd. Similarly, to cite the lag of prices behind wages as evidence of a cost-price spiral is to ignore the fact that the lag was really determined by the timing of price decontrol relative to wage decontrol. The pace of the inflation slowed noticeably in the second quarter of 1947 (chart 1). The index of wholesale prices actually declined somewhat and the average of consumer prices was stable. A corresponding deceleration occurred in physical activity. The period of tranquility was short-lived, however, and with the coming of summer, production recovered moderately and prices again shot upward. If 152 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH the respite is regarded as a temporary equilibrium, two questions come naturally to mind: What conditions produced the equilibrium ? Why was it unstable ? These questions will be answered in turn. The first possibility to consider is that financial stringency may have retarded the expansion of demand in one or more parts of the economy. The essence of the sort of pure inflation now under discussion—that is, a situation where real output is virtually fixed and additional spending goes primarly to raise prices—is, of course, that it results from competition among the various claimants on the national product for the limited supply of goods and services. Gradual increases of supply aside, the inflation will continue as long as some spending units are displeased with their level of real expenditures—their share of total output—and are able to increase money expenditure in an attempt to bid goods and services away from rival spending units. Conversely, it will be halted if all spending units become satisfied (perhaps better, reconciled) with their current real expenditure in the sense that they cannot, or will not, find the means to finance a larger money outlay. Any spending unit, be it in the household, business, Government, or foreign sector, has two sources from which to finance current purchases of goods and services. It can undertake expenditure out of current income receipts; or it can alter its wealth, either by borrowing or by drawing upon its assets. Thus financial stringency could take the form either of an income limitation, or a constraint on the desire or ability to diminish net worth. Let us examine the incomes and expenditures of the major sectors for evidence of monetary constraints on spending (chart 4). The reader will note the continuous rise of personal consumption expenditure from 1945 to mid-1947 and beyond. He will notice also that throughout 1946 and early 1947 expenditure climbed more rapidly than income, a symptom of the excess demand for consumer goods which was released by decontrol and of the determination of consumers to maintain their real purchases after decontrol. Even the diminished increase of disposable income in the first quarter of 1947 and its actual dip in the second quarter failed to deter the rapid expansion of expenditure. The fall in the rate of personal saving during the first postwar wave of inflation was accompanied by some deterioration in the financial position of consumers as a group, of course. The moderate reduction of consumer liquidity during 1946 may have inhibited the growth of spending in theiirst half of 1947, just as the retardation of disposable income may have done, but the fact remains that neither force was powerful enough to prevent further substantial increases of consumer expenditure in those months. We must look elsewhere for signs of flagging demand. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 153 Nor do we fare much better when we turn to the Government and foreign sectors. Government purchases of goods and services did diminish during the first half of 1947, but relatively little in comparison with the increases in other categories of final expenditure. The reduction came entirely in the Federal sector and reflected primarily the further progress of war demobilization rather than any financial constraint. Net tax receipts (receipts less transfer payments) were substantially in excess of Government purchases during the last half of 1946 and in 1947. Incidentally, the Government surplus served as a partial restraint on the progress of the inflation, but it was not, of course, enough. The sharp rise of receipts during 1946 was largely induced by the expansion of money incomes and was therefore, itself, a reflection of the inflation which automatic increases of tax receipts could mitigate but not prevent. No assistance was forthcoming from foreign sources. On the contrary, net foreign investment rose substantially during 1947 Under the spur of postwar needs for relief and rehabilitation in war-ravaged countries. We come finally to domestic investment and its finance. It is apparent from chart 4 that gross private domestic investment fell in the early months of 1947 and remained relatively depressed until late in the year. Since gross retained earnings continued to rise, private deficit financing for purposes of investment was reduced. This last development was effect rather than cause, however, for there was no shortage of external funds to restrict investment during this period. A breakdown of gross private domestic investment reveals that its decline after the fourth quarter of 1946 was due entirely to the inventory component (chart 5). Business fixed investment and residential construction continued to rise along with consumption and net foreign investment. Taken altogether, these facts demonstrate that the lull during the spring primarily reflected diminished demands for inventory and not a deficiency of final demands. There is strong evidence, moreover, that the decline of inventory demand was caused by nonmonetary factors. 154 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 4 The Nation's Income, Expenditure, and Saving By Major Economic Sectors Seasonally Adjusted Quarterly Totals at Annual Rates, 1945-1950 (Billions of Dollars) Consumers 190 - 260 130 Personal Consumption Expenditures Business 105 75 - Excess of Investment Jf Gross Private Domestic Investment 45 \ ^^^•V^ Excess of TT1T U l l \JjJ ore Jm 15 1 Gross Retained Earnings 1/ I 1 0 ^l^^\ 1 \ 4 \ \ III 1 Government 105 Purchases of Goods and Services 75 45 Receipts (Less Transfer Payments) 25 0 Net Foreign Investment 25 1 1 IIM"*1 ~n ^—i—|— T 1 1 1 1ITI 15 1947 1948 1949 1950 1/ Includes undistributed corporate profits, inventory valuation adjustment, and capital consumption allowances. Source: Department of Commerce. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND 155 GROWTH Chart 5 Gross Private Domestic Investment and Its Major Components Seasonally Adjusted Quarterly Totals at Annual Rates, 1946-1950 (Billions of Dollars) P T Gross Private Domestic Investment 30 - 20 - 10 - -10 Components of Business Fixed Investment P T 40 - 30 - Producers* Duralble Equipment —« 20 10 ^ 0 Nonresidential i 1946 Construction i 1947 i 1948 i 1949 1950 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the national Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Department of Commerce. 156 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH The reason for believing that monetary factors had little to do with the behavior of either fixed or inventory investment during 1946-47 is, of course, that the entire economy was quite liquid and bank credit was readily available at generous terms. Since the monetary authorities accepted the goal of stable interest rates, they were unable to act to prevent an expansion of bank credit and the money supply. Any increase in the demand for loanable funds which could not be satisfied from current saving or by dishoarding must needs be met by the banking system if interest rates were to be kept from rising. As it happened, the contribution of additional money supplies to increased spending was comparatively small during the period under review. Thus gross national expenditure increased 12 percent and the private portion of it 15 percent between the second quarters of 1946 and 1947. The money supply, consisting of currency outside banks and adjusted demand deposits, rose less than 3 percent over the same interval. A rise in the income velocity of circulation of money therefore accounts for three-fourths of the increased spending on national output and four-fifths of the rise of private spending. This implies a sharp reduction in the proportion of the money supply held idle. The dishoarding occurred, moreover, at low and stable rates of interest. Here is ample testimony of the involuntary nature of much of the liquid asset accumulation of the war years, which resulted by wars' end in holdings which were considerably larger than desired, given current prices for goods and going interest rates. What, then, does account for the reduced inventory demand of early 1947? It was primarily a reflection of pessimistic short-term expectations. As the President's Economic Report of January 8, 1947, put it (p. 16) : "Threatening the continuation and expansion of business investment is the fear that a drop in general consumer demand may be in the offing." This fear rested upon the knowledge that inflation had diminished the real value of disposable personal income during 1946 and that consumers had maintained real expenditure only by increasing money outlay sharply relative to income. This process obviously could not go on indefinitely and might be near its limit, especiallv since real demands for specific commodities could be expected to fall as the goods became available to rebuild household stocks. The close parallels between the events of 1919 and 1946 had not escaped attention. Each were years of postwar transition during which abnormal domestic and foreign demands had driven prices rap^dlv upward. The deflation which had followed the earlier experience during 1920 was among the sharpest on record. History might repeat itself, and in the circumstances it was wise to pursue conservative inventory policies. Chart 6 indicates how conservative those policies were. The ratio of inventories to sales in manufacturing: was actually reduced during 1946. Retail inventories, in contrast, did rise strongly relative to sales between April and December. It is significant, however, that the ratio remained far below the prewar relationship of 1939-41. This last was true also of the wholesale and manufacturing sectors. Businessmen generally were making do with relatively smaller stocks than in prewar days. 157 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 6 Inventory Sales Ratios (Monthly, 1945-1950) 1.60 A 1939-41 Average 1.30 \*^/~""^ RetaU 1.00 ) 1 f P 5 r 1939-41 Average 1.30 1.00 Wholesale 0.70 t V 2.20 1939-41 Average 1.90 V 1.60 1 Manufacturing 1.30 i 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Department of Commerce. Diminished inventory demands were felt largely by producers of nondurable goods. Some decline of postwar inventory investment was inevitable once stocks were rebuilt sufficiently to provide appropriate selections and acceptable delivery schedules. To judge from the levels maintained in later years, the appropriate "technical" ratio of stocks to sales was approximated by nondurable goods retailers late in 1946. Technical considerations would have been overridden, nonetheless, had retailers expected prices to advance rapidly or sales to spurt strongly. For reasons already discussed they expected neither to occur, or at least they were uncertain enough to play it safe. 158 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Prices of durable goods were not exposed to the same degree of downward pressure from diminished inventory demand as nondurables. Average wholesale prices of finished durable goods rose more during the second quarter of 1947 than in the first, although prices of intermediate durable materials advanced more slowly than before. The latter retardation may reflect some easing in the intensity of demand, since unfilled orders of durable goods manufacturers leveled off in the first quarter and dropped in the second. Perhaps the most interesting development in this sector, however, was the stability of steel prices during the first 6 months of the year. What makes it particularly interesting is that steel prices were not raised at the time of the April increase in wages of steelworkers, and did not rise until 3 months had passed. On no other occasion from then until now have steel prices lagged a general increase of steel wages. Because of their key position in the industrial price structure, the stability of steel prices probably contributed importantly to the shift toward expectations of stable or falling prices which characterized the period. It appears likely that steel and other administered prices were, in turn, strongly influenced by the public attention which was focused on the desirability of voluntary restraint in setting prices in the State of the Union Message and Economic Report of January 1947, and again in speeches made by the President in April. Be that as it may, price stability was short lived in these cases and most others, for it could not persist in the face of the resurgence of demand which soon developed. The next task is to identify the factors back of that resurgence. Reduced inventory demand consequent upon pessimistic expectations about the short-term course of sales and prices was primarily responsible for the precarious balance of aggregate supply and demand in the spring of 1947. The balance was upset and inflationary pressuries revived during the summer partly because a recasting of expectations took place. The reversal of expectations did not, however, occur for independent psychological reasons. Quite the contrary, it was due to a sequence of concrete economic events which first removed the drag exerted by uncertainty about short-term developments and a bit later contributed directly to an acceleration of final expenditure. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 159 First, there was the fact that the pessimism about final demand proved to be unjustified. Consumer expenditures, business investment m plant and equipment, residential construction, purchases of State and local governments, and net foreign investment all increased during the winter and spring. Fears that new homes would be priced out of a market by rising building costs were lessened when new housing starts rose more than seasonally during the spring. It had been anticipated that the drain on gold and dollar assets of foreign countries would soon force a substantial reduction in net exports, but the prospects in this area were improved by the announcement of Secretary of State Marshall early in June that the United States would support a joint program for European recovery. The acceleration of prices did not await actual increases of final demand. Specific factors boosted prices in two prominent sectors during the early summer. Food prices rose during July and August owing to a combination of short domestic and foreign crops and normal seasonal influences. A widely publicized wage increase in coal mining was accompanied by a simultaneous advance in coal prices in July and was followed by a steel price increase in August. These specific increases doubtless fostered expectations of a new wave of generalized price advances, the more so because it now appeared that earlier wage gains would be reflected in prices, as indeed they were. Thus, speculative purchases were partly responsible for the steep rise of manufacturers' new orders and sales which commenced in September (chart 7). Retail sales also spurted strongly in September, however, providing still another stimulus to orders and prices. Legislation passed late in July permitted redemption of Armed Forces leave bonds on or after September 2. Quick advantage was taken of the opportunity to supplement current incomes, as transfer payments leaped more than $10 billion at an annual rate in September and produced corresponding bulges in personal income and retail sales which persisted for several months. The spurt of final demand was augmented by substantial inventory accumulation at the retail level, and although the latter was partly offset by inventory reductions of wholesalers, factory sales and production nonetheless moved strongly upward. As production mounted, so also did earned incomes, further feeding the expansion of retail sales. 160 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 7 Indexes of Personal Income, Retail, Wholesale, and Manufacturers' Sales and Inventories and Manufacturers' New Orders Seasonally Adjusted, Monthly, 1946-1950 Index 1947-49 = 100 1947-49=100 135 - 125 105 • 160 150 130 120 110 130 120 100 Manufacturers* Inventories 50 1946 1948 1949 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research. 1/ Not seasonally adjusted. Source: Department of Commerce. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 161 The expansion was given new vigor by the events just reviewed. The underlying sources of strength which stemmed from backlogs of consumer and investment demand and which had been present all along now asserted themselves for a timx3 without the debilitating offset of inventory disinvestment. When these forces began to weaken, moreover, fresh stimuli came forward to prolong the movement. The year 1948 had scarcely begun before the economy experienced a jolt which raised anew the possibility of imminent deflation. Farm and food prices broke sharply downward in February (chart 2). The reductions were apparently the result of favorable crop prospects at home and abroad, prospects which were disproportionately influential because of expectations that the extraordinary height to which agricultural prices had risen by the end of 1947 could not be sustained under normal conditions. This episode could have touched off a wave of deflationary inventory disinvestment had it created expectations of a generalized price decline, but it did not do so, and industrial prices remained largely unaffected. Expectations remained unshaken partly because the potential decline of agricultural prices was limited by support programs and partly because important shortages of durable goods and materials persisted and the response of prices in those sectors to augmented supplies or diminished demands could be expected to take place slowly in any event. Although final demand was sufficiently high to support prices and outputs of most goods in the face of the agricultural price declines of February and March, and indeed for some months thereafter, the first quarter nevertheless marks the emergence of important deflationary factors. These factors were of more than transitory importance because they reflected a change in the basic conditions which had fostered the inflation. I refer to the weakening of real investment demand in the business and housing sectors and to the acceleration of the decline of net exports which had set in earlier. A survey of anticipated expenditures taken in the opening weeks of 1948 foreshadowed a gradual downslide of real expenditures for plant and equipment by nonagricultural business during the year. The actual peak in physical volume occurred in the first quarter, but when account is taken also of investment by farmers, professional men, and institutions, the peak of total business fixed investment is delayed until the third quarter in physical terms and until the fourth in dollar amount (chart 5). The early decline of nonagricultural business investment was concentrated in manufacturing industries, where it probably reflected diminished needs for deferred replacements and for capacity expansion to meet postwar levels of demand; modernization and expansion programs had progressed more rapidly in manufacturing than in railroading or electrical utilities, to name two important sectors in which investment continued upward during 1948. Some reduction of investment demand was to be expected once firms had attained satisfactory postwar relationships between capacity and output, even if output continued to increase as rapidly as before. Actually, manufacturing production increased rather slowly during 1947, and this fact may have influenced the formation of investment plans at the turn of the year. In some industries the retardation during 1947 was due to inadequate plant capacity or shortages of materials, but in many product lines it must be traced to a diminution of consumer 162 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH demand as households rebuilt their "capacity" to derive current services from durable or semidurable goods. The foregoing reflections serve as a reminder that the inflation was driven throughout by demand elements which were to an important degree independent of the level or rate of change of real national income. Satisfaction of backlog investment or consumption demands would in itself tend to reduce inflationary pressures at any given level of real income and independently of financial considerations. This is not to say that the slowdown of business investment was completely unrelated to financial developments, but the latter influences were secondary at most. Although corporate liquidity had decreased as the inflation progressed, investment funds from current operations improved as the ratio of gross retained earnings to corporate investment increased from 48 percent in 1946 to 69 percent in 1947 and 81 percent in the following year. External funds, moreover, were easily obtainable. Long-term interest rates had been allowed to rise by the Federal Reserve in the closing months of 1947. The increase was moderate, however, and the monetary authorities took the necessary steps then and later to supply reserves to the banking system whenever the stability of interest rates was threatened. The money supply declined fractionally after the first quarter of 1948, but bank loans rose substantially and income velocity and total spending continued to increase. Financial constraints were more important in the areas of home building and foreign trade. The rise of gilt-edge interest rates had the effect of making GI and FHA mortgage loans at fixed rates less attractive to lenders, many of whom tightened up on loan applications. From April 30 to August 10 there was no statutory authority for FHA action on the most liberal type of mortgage for lower priced houses or on mortgage insurance for multifamily rental housing units. Housing starts fell sharply beginning in July, and it appears that tightened purchase terms and reduced availability of lower quality mortgage credit should receive a good deal of weight in an explanation of the decline. Net exports form the third important category of final demand which weakened well before the downturn of aggregate activity. Net foreign investment plummeted between the third quarters of 1947 and 1948 because foreign gold and dollar holdings had been depleted by ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 163 the extraordinary purchases of 1946-47 and because loan-financed aid by the United States Government was slashed (chart 4). Government expenditures in the form of gifts under interim aid and the Marshall plan rose during 1948 and offset a part of the reduction of foreign investment, but the export surplus nonetheless fell substantially, and on an. annual basis accounted for seven-tenths of the total drop of $7 billion in foreign investment. Fortunately, the bulk of the decline in the export surplus came before mid-1948 while other elements of demand were still favorable to the maintenance of physical activity, so that its major effect was to relieve inflationary pressures rather than to initiate a contraction. After this lengthy recital of early developments that sapped the strength of the underlying forces which had fostered the inflation in previous years, the reader who does not have the details of 1948 fixed freshly in mind may be surprised to learn that the indexes of wholesale and consumer prices spurted yet again after March, and by September had risen respectively another 3.5 and 4.6 percent. This last fillip was given to the inflation by the actual and anticipated effects of Government fiscal actions. These included final approval of a new foreign-aid program under the Marshall plan, enactment of a steppedup defense program, and a reduction of personal income taxes effective April 2. The bulk of the substantial increase of Federal expenditures between the first and third quarters of 1948 (chart 8) resulted from foreign aid and the agricultural price-support program. Domestic defense expenditures rose only in the final quarter of the year. The economic stimulus provided by the defense program did not await the increase of expenditures, however, but was partly felt during the spring when its discussion and enactment affected business expectations and when substantial orders for aircraft were placed. The tax reduction could also be expected to have an early effect on retail sales because withholding from wages and salaries would be decreased at an annual rate of $3 billion beginning in May. 23734—58 12 164 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 8 Government Purchases and Personal Consumption Expenditures Seasonally Adjusted Quarterly Totals at Annual Rates ,1946-1950 (Billions of Dollars) P T Log Scale Government Purchases of Goods and Services 60 40 ^ v 30 - Total yT ^ V^^~^ - \ Federal /"" _ ^ ^ 20 > .. State and Local ^ ' ^^^^^ 10 9 i i i Personal Consumption Expenditures 200 150 Total 100 80 Nondurable Goods 60 50 Services 40 30 20 Durable Goods 10 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Department of Commerce. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 165 It was in this expectational context that prices of agricultural products turned upward again in April and that springtime wage negotiations were conducted in the large durable goods industries. Heavy industry had resisted wage increases following the agricultural price break of February, since it appeared that the cost of living would stabilize and that demand pressures were easing.2 When farm and food prices recovered and the defense program and tax reduction were announced, the determination of labor to win wage increases was augmented and that of management to resist them diminished. The result was a series of wage and price increases in major heavy industries between May and July. Thus prices advanced on a broad front from April through July or August, with participation by agricultural and industrial commodities alike. During the second half of the year the forces of deflation gained final ascendancy. The downturn developed gradually from an accumulation of depressing factors, each mild in itself, but in sum sufficient finally to cause a decline of aggregate activity. For reasons already discussed, residential construction eased downward in the third quarter and business fixed investment in the fourth. These developments had earlier origins, but a new depressant was added when retail sales leveled off during the third quarter (chart 7). The retardation affected particularly sales of nondurables, and since stocksales ratios were being closely controlled by retailers, new orders were immediately trimmed to prevent further accumulation of stocks, wholesale trade in nondurables declined after July and factory sales after September, and manufacturing production of such goods eased during the third quarter and again in the fourth. The retardation of retail sales was the more disappointing because it followed the April tax cut. Price and wage increases augmented personal incomes during the second and third quarters, and the tax reduction boosted disposable personal income even more, but these developments had the effect mainly of raising saving instead of consumption expenditure (chart 4). Personal saving increased from an annual rate of $4.2 billion in the first quarter to $10.6 billion in the second and $12.6 billion in the third. The corresponding saving percentages were 2.4, 5.7, and 6.6. Thus the retardation of consumer spending occurred because spending did not keep pace with income and not because income failed to increase as rapidly as before; on the contrary, disposable income increased faster during the spring and summer than during the preceding half year. The decline of consumption expenditures relative to income was a consequence of the diminution of pent-up consumer demands. To the extent that it was an expression of a general easing of demand, it was probably influenced by the progressive decline of liquidity during the preceding years of inflation. Individuals' holdings of liquid assets had increased more slowly than disposable income, inflation had reduced their real value 15 percent between the end of 1945 and 1947, and there may have occurred a shift of assets to firmer hands. Certainly the intense desire to increase expenditures in any and all directions which had characterized the first year or more of the inflation was no longer manifest, and this argues for the presence of some general constraint such as diminished liquidity. 2 Midyear Economic Report of the President, July 1948, p. 33. 166 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Since household stocks of durable and semidurable goods had been replenished by 1948, however, the satisfaction of deferred demands proper may have provided the stronger general constraint. That this is so is suggested indirectly by the behavior of automobile purchases, for this was the principal example of a consumer good still in short supply. The rate of real expenditure depended upon production and showed no signs of flagging during the spring and summer of 1948 or indeed for many quarters thereafter. Consumer credit controls had been dropped in November 1947 and were not reimposed until September 1948. It is probable that had more cars been produced in mid-1948, more would have been purchased, and at higher prices if desired by sellers. Other expenditures would not have decreased correspondingly, moreover, because any current retrenchment of consumption outlays which might be made by families purchasing new automobiles would be smaller than the total outlay for the automobile, the bulk of which would be financed by asset liquidation or new credit. The emerging inventory problems of retailers were not confined to nondurable goods. Expenditures for furniture and household equipment also leveled off in the third quarter and actually dropped in the fourth. Inventories of durable goods were not quite so closely controlled by distributors, however, and factory production of major durable household goods was maintained a few months longer than was true of nondurables, before joining the general decline after October. Thus by the final quarter aggregate activity was being depressed by reductions in business fixed investment and residential construction, by stable or falling retail sales, and by diminished inventory demand consequent upon the latter. About the only important category of demand still expanding was Government expenditure, and this was not enough to prevent a downturn of aggregate physical activity in November or December. Prices fell along with physical activity as inflationary pressures ebbed. The indexes of wholesale and consumer prices led the October peak of industrial production by 1 month. Agricultural prices had started downhill for certain in July because increased production at home and abroad augmented domestic supplies at the same time that retail sales of food and other nondurables stabilized. Retail food prices dropped in concert with farm prices. Wholesale prices of products other than farm commodities and foods did not fall until December, however, and the Consumer Price Index of all items less food also held firm until year end. Reductions of industrial finished goods prices at wholesale and retail awaited the further easing of demand which came after the turn of the year. MORE ABOUT THE INFLATION The many references to demand and expected demand in the preceding pages will not have escaped the attention of the reader. The inflation was started by the discharge of excess demand after decontrol and it was ended when final demand weakened even as real income continued to rise and largely because backlogs were worked off in many lines. This does not end the matter, however, for the progress of the inflation—its duration and magnitude and the timing of the successive waves—might have been quite different in another economic ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 167 •environment. As a bald statement, this is a self-evident proposition, but it is one which is often forgotten in relation to specific historical episodes, where the role of disturbing forces is likely to be emphasized to the neglect of factors which condition the response of the economy to disturbances and which are equally to be regarded as causes of the observed behavior. There can be no doubt, for example, that the inflation could have been terminated earlier and with a smaller overall price rise by sufficiently vigorous monetary or fiscal actions. As it was, external monetary intervention did comparatively little to bring the inflation to a close and fiscal actions actually prolonged its final phase. Not much is to be gained by speculating about what might have been, however, especially since it cannot be known how far alternative policies could have been pursued without producing consequences less attractive than the gradual diminution of liquidity through price inflation and the concomitant gradual elimination of the more pressing physical shortages. What can be done with profit is to inquire more closely into the time path of the inflation, given the fact that external intervention was minimal. We ask why it progressed in 3 waves instead of 1 uninterrupted advance, and why each wave was smaller than its predecessor (chart 1). Let us test first the hypothesis that the successive waves were recurrent phases in a wage-price spiral which was started and kept in motion by a series of wage increases. In that event, the interval between waves would be determined by systematic lags in the process of wage-price-wage adjustment, and the magnitude of the waves would depend upon the size of the successive adjustments. The hypothesis is leant a surface plausibility by the fact that wages led prices during the first two waves (chart 9). Thus average hourly earnings of manufacturing workers increased more rapidly than consumer prices during the first half of 1946. Prices moved ahead of wages after decontrol, however, so that by early 1947 the purchasing power of wages was considerably reduced. Wages spurted again during the spring of 1947, and after a lapse of 2 or 3 months, prices resumed their climb. Up to this point, then, there were alternate spurts of wages and prices. This neat phasing broke down in the third round of inflation, however, when prices and wages rose simultaneously in the spring and early summer of 1948. Apparently there was nothing inherent in the organization of the economy to make prices lag wages. But this reminds us that special circumstances may account for the two earlier instances of lagging prices. That is certainly true of the first round, when prices were decontrolled later than wages. Eecall also the unusual conditions that prevailed at the time of the second lag, when public attitudes and short-term expectations were unfavorable to price increases and when springtime wage increases were absorbed for a few months in steel and other heavy industries. Chart 9 Indexes of Average Hourly Earnings and Prices (Monthly, 1946-1949) Index 1947-49 "100 Index 1947-49'100 P 7 in T Wholesale 105 Prices^^ y 100 95 95. jfj /Average Hourly JF / Earnings 90 ~ I jr (Manufacturing) Consumer M s Prices ?M / 90 M 80 35 0 O o 85 / / f ^r Average Hourly Earnings (Nondurable Goods Manufacturers) 80 a 75 70 Average Hourly Earnings (Durable Goods Manufacturers) 105 100 85 * 110 J.J.U 75 y - 70 65 • i 1946 0 i 1947 1948 1949 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. - > i 1946 1 f 1947 1948 1949 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 169 Apart from timing, there is the question of amplitude. May not the progressively smaller size of the price waves be due to the fact that each round of wage increases was smaller than the last, beginning with a "typical" raise of 181^ cents in 1946 and moving on to 15 cents in 1947 and 10 to 13 cents in 1948 ? The answer must again be "No". The reason may be seen by asking under what conditions the statement might be true. It implies first of all that the role of demand is passive ; that the amount of a price increase is determined by the size of an autonomous wage increase and that demand merely rises enough subsequently to sustain the higher price. Applied to a sequence of damped wage-price movements, it implies secondly that some mechanism exists to make each wage increase smaller than the last, unless, of course, this important fact is left unexplained. A plausible hypothesis for the sort of situation now under consideration is that wage demands are equal to the increase in the cost-of-living since the last wage increase, and that each wage increase induces a less-than-equal rise in consumer prices because of productivity gains, partial absorption of cost increments by manufacturers or distributors, or the sluggish response of prices of consumer services. Now either or both of these assumptions may at times approach realism, but neither can be accepted in the present instance. With regard to the first, it is obvious that the margin of excess demand which existed at the time of decontrol for reasons independent of the wage advance was an important determinant of the size of the initial price wave. Nor was the wage increase of the first half of 1947 as large as the price increase of the last half of 1946. Wages caught up with consumer prices momentarily in mid-1947, but this was partly because they had gained relatively in the 4 or 5 months preceding decontrol and not because they advanced as much as prices in later months. All the same, there is empirical substance in the notion that the amplitudes of the price waves of 1947 and 1948 were approximately determined by the amplitudes of the corresponding wage movements. This does not mean, however, that we have here an example of "costpush" inflation. It is important to recognize the full implications of these last remarks. The crux of the matter is that wages and prices may spiral under conditions of either "cost-push" or "demand-pull." The "costpush" terminology implies that the spiral originates and is kept going by autonomous wage increases because workers are trying to increase their share of real national income, whereas "demand-pull" carries the connotation that prices rise because of demand pressures and induce subsequent wage increases as workers strive to maintain their income position. A spiral may occur in either case, however, and for the same underlying reason—the attempts of contending parties to defend or increase their shares of the national product. These attempts may embrace investment goods as well as consumer goods, and the contenders are not limited to those facing one another across the bargaining table. Since a spiral may occur for either reason, it may be difficult to decide whether a particular experience is caused by one or the other or some combination of the two. The task is complicated by the fact that lags in the process may be short or even nonexistent when current changes on either side are influenced by expected changes on the 170 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH other, and the further fact that independent disturbances may enter the picture as well. Let us nevertheless examine the movements of wages and prices during 1946-48 against the background of the earlier analysis of the period, which should help us around these difficulties. It is easy to detect changes in basic wage rates in the statistics of average hourly earnings for a given industry, since abrupt vertical steps appear in the data whenever such changes occur. Unfortunately, these vertical movements tend to be smoothed out when hourly earnings are averaged for large numbers of industries, because the individual changes are spread over time. The smoothing is not complete, however, for some bunching does occur, and at those junctures the curve accelerates (chart 9). If a close positive relationship exists between changes in wages and in prices, it should be possible to observe corresponding accelerations of prices. For reasons already discussed, we take the timing and amplitudes of prices and wages during 1946 as given, and inquire into the subsequent reactions to this first wave of inflation. The first important retardation of prices came during the second quarter of 1947. Was this the result of a prior deceleration of wages in manufacturing industries, which because of lags in the processes of production and distribution did not affect prices of goods to final users for several months? That is not the explanation, since the retardation was in prices of nondurable goods and especially foods, and since wages had accelerated in the nondurable goods industries in the preceding quarter and had been accompanied at that time by correspondingly rapid increases in prices of finished nondurables at wholesale and retail (compare charts 2, 3, and 9). The cause of the lull in prices was the reduced inventory demand analyzed earlier, coupled with the temporary absorption of springtime wage increases in the durable goods industries at their source. Nor should the resumption of the inflation in the second half of 1947 be interpreted merely as a lagged response to previous wage increases. Prices moved ahead partly under the stimulus of rising demand. This is not to say that wage increases were unrelated to the movement, however. In the first place, they affected its timing. The coal mine wage-price increase of July and the August rise in steel prices helped touch off the new round of price increases in durable goods. Together with the simultaneous increases in agricultural prices, these specific advances contributed to the upward revision of price expectations which stimulated inventory demand. Secondly, the size of the price adjustment was doubtless influenced by the amount of the increase of labor costs under the 1947 wage agreements. Thus average hourly earnings rose 7 percent between April and November. Allowing for the price lag, we find that wholesale prices of finished goods increased 8.5 percent and the Consumer Price Index 7.5 percent between June and January. Expected demand permitting, it is natural to suppose that business firms will increase prices at least proportionately to unit labor costs. The increases may not hold if the necessary demand fails to materialize, but under conditions of high liquidity, easy credit, and strong "real" needs for producer and consumer goods, money outlays will usually rise sufficiently to sustain the increase, and perhaps even more if speculative buying develops during the process. Because ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 171 profit margins may vary firm conclusions are impossible, but it appears likely that had the average wage increase been smaller during 1947, the average price increase would also have been smaller. Notice, however, that this would have meant that wage earners must needs resign themselves to a lower real wage than they had received prior to price decontrol. As it was, their attempt to compensate for the rise in the cost of living was successful for only a month or two during the second quarter of 1947, and once the new wave of price increases got underway wages again fell behind. The wage pattern of 1948 was quite similar to that of 1947, but prices behaved rather differently because independent demand forces assumed greater importance. It will be recalled that one effect of the agricultural price break of February-March was to foster a holdthe-line attitude on wages and prices in the heavy industries. When the tax cut and defense and foreign aid programs were approved, however, it appeared that demand would prove adequate to sustain new price increases, and the result was a simultaneous advance of wages and prices during the late spring and summer. Average hourly earnings in durable goods manufacturing plants and wholesale prices of finished durable goods both increased 6 percent between May and September. Wages rose about as much in the soft goods industries, but in that sector demand was already weakening and prices of farm-produced raw materials were beginning to slide, so that prices of finished soft goods merely held their own instead of rising (chart 2). The same combination of easing demand and enlarged supplies forced food prices downward beginning in September, so that the consumer price index declined and real wages improved correspondingly during the closing months of the year. This third wave is an interesting example of joint and simultaneous participation by demand and supply in an inflationary episode. On the one hand, it appears that substantial wage boosts would not have occurred without the announcement of the new Government programs, and on the other, the wage-price increases did not await an actual increase of final demand, and average prices of durable goods rose just enough to compensate for the average wage increase. Nondurable goods were subjected to approximately the same wage pressure, but present demands were clearly less intense and since the unconcentrated market structure of most of the nondurable goods industries makes prices quickly responsive to market forces, prices did not move up commensurately with wages. We may sum up the principal analytical lessons from the wageprice behavior of 1946-48 as follows. The existence of a wageprice spiral does not in itself show whether it is due "basically" to cost or demand forces. Lags between wages and prices are not necessarily indicative of causal sequences and special factors may sometimes account for their occurrence. When wages rise autonomously and prices are marked up correspondingly, demand must play at least a passive role in sustaining the price increase if output is not to fall. Expected increases of demand may induce wage-price reactions before final demand actually rises, in which case wages and prices are likely to advance simultaneously. An observed sequence of price waves may be the result of the interplay of wages and prices in response to a single initial disturbance, but one must be alert to the 172 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH fact that autonomous forces operating outside of the mechanism of the spiral may exert a decisive influence over the course of events. With regard to the pattern of the inflation itself, it was initiated by the excess demand released by decontrol, revitalized during 1947 by a combination of induced wage increases and largely permissive demand increments (including anticipatory inventory buying which was itself prompted by rising prices), and prolonged in its third phase by an autonomous increase of expected demand which induced a simultaneous wage-price advance. The duration of the waves and the intervals between them were modified by wage behavior, but cannot be explained by systematic lags between wages and prices. The inflation would doubtless have moved faster and with fewer pauses had it been customary to negotiate wage contracts twice a year rather than annually, or had cost-of-living adjustments been written into the contracts. Whether it would have been greater or smaller in overall magnitude depends upon a number of unknown factors, such as the extent to which frequent wage-price revisions would affect price expectations, the vigor of anti-inflationary public policy under the alternative conditions, and the relative importance of real and monetary stimuli to demand under circumstances in which liquidity was reduced more rapidly by price advances, giving less time for the reduction of physical backlogs of demand. PRICES DURING CONTRACTION AND RECOVERY, 1 9 4 9 - 5 0 The truly remarkable feature of the 1949 contraction of business activity was that it was so mild. What factors were responsible for the "* * * unique and fortunate experience of liquidating a major inflation without falling into a severe recession"3 and why was the price decline so moderate in comparison with the increases which came before and after? (See chart 1.) These are interrelated questions, for the moderate price decline was both consequence and cause of the mildness of the contraction in physical activity. What one would like to disentangle if he were sufficiently wise to do so, is the relative importance in the contraction of transient factors specific to it and of more lasting attributes of the postwar economy. It will be helpful to keep this ideal in mind during the subsequent discussion. The contraction was mild enough to be called an inventory recession, and it has often been described by that teim. Insofar as the term is taken to mean that final demand declined little and that most of the moderate fall in gross national product was accounted for by inventory change, it is quite accurate. This leaves unsettled the question, however, of whether inventory investment exerted more than a passive influence over the course of events. The amount of decline of inventory demand depends in the first instance, after all, on the behavior of final expenditures. If these drop only moderately, current production will soon fall below sales, attempts to adjust stocks to the smaller volume of sales will meet with early success, and new orders and production will quickly revert to equality or more with sales. Minor contractions are kept minor by those factors—not 3 The quotation is from The Economic Situation at Midyear 1949, A Report to the President by the Council of Economic Advisers, p. 3, included in Midyear Economic Report of the President; July 1949. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 173 always the same in every contraction—which foster stability of final demand. Let us first inquire what they were in 1949, and then go on to consider the role of inventory investment and whether it was partly an active one. The behavior of the major components of final expenditure is summarized in charts 5 and 8. The following facts stand out: State and local government expenditures rose strongly throughout the contraction, just as they have done every year of the postwar era under the impetus of population growth and migration and because of the stubborn persistence of backlogs of needs for community services. Federal expenditure also increased during the first 6 or 7 months of the contraction, and the subsequent decline of defense spending was small and did not begin until other sectors were assuming active importance in the recovery. Thus autonomous demands on the part of governmental units moderated the decline and favored a prompt upturn. The early revival of residential construction and personal consumption expenditure is also noteworthy. In both cases backlogs of real demand remained large—automobiles were at the forefront in the improvement in retail sales—and easier credit facilitated renewed expansion. Not only was credit eased generally by the cyclical fall of demand for external funds on the part of business and the expansionary monetary policy of the Federal Eeserve System, but selective devices were used to improve terms of home mortgages and consumer installment credit. Indicative of the strength of combined real and monetary demand stimuli is the substantial rise of consumption expenditure which commenced after the first quarter of 1949 and continued even as disposable personal income dropped through the remainder of the year (chart 4). Consumption expenditure would doubtless have increased as a percentage of disposable income in any event, given the special stimuli just discussed and the regular tendency for consumers to defend their living standards against falling incomes, but disposable income actually declined comparatively little, and this meant that expenditures rose rather substantially in absolute amount and became a positive force for expansion. Between the fourth quarters of 1948 and 1949 disposable income decreased about $6 billion and consumption increased $3.5 billion. Automatic stabilizers cushioned the contraction of income and helped foster the expansion of consumption. National income dropped $16 billion, but induced reductions of undistributed corporate profits and corporate profit tax liabilities absorbed about $6.5 billion of the decline, while nearly $2 billion was offset by smaller personal taxes, and as much more by increased transfer payments which supplemented the flow of production income. Business fixed investment led on the downturn, lagged on the upturn, and fell about 12 percent in physical volume between the third quarter of 1948 and the first quarter of 1950. Thus it was by all odds the major depressant of final expenditure at work in the contraction. The point which deserves greatest stress, however, is not that it declined, but that it did not decline much more. This is a good part of the explanation of how the inflation was liquidated without a severe contraction. The inflationary waves of 1946-48 had not engendered overly optimistic long-term investment expectations and had not caused an unwarranted expansion of productive facilities. The available 174 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH data on capital stock in relation to production and on capacity utilization by industry indicate that capital facilities were smaller in relation to output before the contraction began than they had been in 1929 or 1937. This favorable start might have been overcome had other elements of final demand decreased sharply during the contraction, of course, but the independent strength of Government and consumer spending prevented the development of any widespread condition of excess capacity. The situation was much the same with regard to inventory investment. Inventories were not excessive before the downturn began— partly, of course, because they had been watched so very carefully during 1948, with mildly deflationary results during the latter months of that year in the nondurable goods industries. Even by the end of 1948 they were below the prewar relationship to sales in manufacturing and distributing alike (chart 6). Here is rather strong evidence that the restocking of 1946-48 was needed to reestablish normal, working relationships between stocks and sales, and that speculative inventory purchasing in anticipation of advancing prices had not gotten out of hand. This meant that inventory disinvestment during 1949 was confined largely to that required to bring stocks down to the reduced level of sales and production and was uncomplicated by any need to liquidate speculative holdings. Even the feedback effect of inventory disinvestment on production income and hence upon final demand was limited by the automatic changes in profits, taxes, and transfers mentioned earlier. Inventory disinvestment could still have become a powerful independent force in the contraction had adverse price expectations and a psychology of liquidation-at-any-cost developed as it progressed. The initial absence of speculative holdings in itself inhibited such a development, however, and other factors were at work as well, including some significant changes in the institutional structure. I refer to the agricultural price-support programs, the Government commitment to promote full employment contained in the Employment Act of 1946, and the augmented importance and strength of labor unions in the mass-production industries dating from the midthirties. Taken altogether, these factors limited actual and potential price declines, thus undercutting such nascent fears as may have existed about the stability of prices. The price declines which did occur were orderly and conformed to the usual pattern of changes during periods of economic contraction. That is, prices of finished goods fell least and those of materials experienced greater reductions. This is typical of contractions because deflationary impulses are propagated backward with increasing intensity from final sellers to manufacturers and thence to suppliers of raw materials; since, in their desire to trim inventories, firms at each stage of production or distribution curtail purchase orders by more than their own sales decline. The pressure on prices resulting from the magnification of downshifts of demand at each stage is especially powerful in markets where large numbers of sellers are actively engaged in price competition and where output changes slowly in response to demand. And, of course, the more prices of purchased materials weaken at each market level, the greater is the scope for reductions in prices of finished goods. It is in the light of ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 175 these facts that the importance of agricultural supports as a cushion to the price structure should be viewed, since farms supply the basic materials for a large number of nondurable goods. It is relevant also that a good part of the potential decline of farm prices during 194849 occurred before the contraction of aggregate business activity was actually underway (chart 2). Additional support to prices was forthcoming from the downward inflexibility of wage rates (chart 9). Since the same factors which act to depress prices of purchased materials and components during contractions operate in the reverse direction during upswings, the margin between prices of unfinished and finished goods will usually have narrowed during an expansion and will provide room for some reduction of material costs relative to finished-goods prices during the ensuing decline. Under given circumstances, there is only so much scope for cost reductions from this source, however, and, once that limit is reached, unless wage rates are cut, businessmen will prefer to curtail production rather than reduce prices. This fact has several ramifications. First, wage inflexibility retards the decline of finished-goods prices for many months during a contraction. The wage lag provides time for a moderate realinement of prices and inventories before deflationary pressures become intense—and a moderate realinement may prove sufficient if basic growth factors remain favorable to expansion. If wage rates were to fall from the beginning of the contraction, the chances of widespread postponement of purchases in anticipation of future price declines would be greatly enhanced. Wage rigidity during minor contractions is not a new phenomenon confined to the postwar economy. Wages also lagged by long intervals during the business cycles of the interwar period, and responded scarcely at all to the mild downswings of 1923-24 and 1926-27 (chart 10). Hence, it cannot be asserted with absolute confidence that wages were stable during 1948-49 and again in 1953-54 because organized labor was stronger than in prewar years. Wages may have remained firm because the contractions themselves were mild and short lived, so that management determination to seek lower wage schedules was never put to the test and might not have been even in the absence of labor unions. 176 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Average hourly earnings (cents) S 8 S 8 in o io o £ ^ 2 9 ( 0 0 1 : £261 !!-•<*V) ( 0 0 1 : S2-E26I^) luauiAotduw AJOJDOJ That is not the end of the matter, however. If businessmen become convinced for any reason that wage rates will not fall, they are, in the same measure, convinced that substantial price declines are not in the offing. These dual convictions must have been cultivated by the growth in the power of organized labor. Indeed, there is some evidence of this in the behavior of wages and prices during the severe contraction of 1937-38, which occurred after the mass-production industries were organized. It is inconclusive evidence, because the contraction, ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 177 though severe, was short lived, and fell within the range of the normal timelag of wages behind business downturns. All the same, the fact that the wage and price reductions associated with that contraction4 were comparable to those of 1923-24 and 1926-27 rather than 1920-21 is consistent with the a priori prediction of greater rigidity. Granted that businessmen expected greater rigidity, this factor would be particularly important in a contraction such as 1948-49, which followed a sharp inflation. This is because it would modify price expectations which might otherwise become quite pessimistic, and, by so doing, help to prevent the contraction from becoming severe enough ever to press heavily on wages. The final aspect of wage-price rigidity to be discussed is, perhaps, the most important of all in connection with the contraction of 194849. It is doubtful that there existed then or exists now any sizable segment of opinion in business or Government circles that widespread wage reductions are beneficial as a means of combating unemployment, or that a deflation of wages and prices is a necessary though painful penalty for permitting an inflation to run its course. To quote the Council of Economic Advisers in mid-1949: There would be no purpose, and much potential damage, in an attempt to get back to some drastically lower price level by wage cutting, since incomes are now geared to prices substantially higher than before the war or immediately after the war. Such an effort would involve a deep and vastly unsettling decline in wages as the accompaniment to a prolonged period of severe depression. From that, practically no one would gain; the economy would lose tragically.5 This attitude was reflected in the fiscal and monetary policies of the day. It contrasts strikingly with the situation of 1920-21, when deflation was regarded as a necessary evil, and when Federal Reserve actions were taken to tighten rather than ease credit. The differing attitudes toward the inevitability and desirability of wage-price deflation, and the associated differences in public and private actions, go far toward explaining the greater severity of the earlier experience despite the presence of underlying elements of strength similar to those following World War II. In summary, prices declined comparatively little during 1949 because speculative excesses had not Ibeen a feature of the inflation; because institutional factors and public policies minimized actual and expected declines and prevented cumulative deterioration of shortterm price and sales expectations; and because, in those favorable circumstances, the forces for expansion inherent in the postwar population upsurge and remaining backlogs of public and private demand could quickly assert their influence. The deflationary force of inventory disinvestment was largely spent by midyear, and a recovery led by Government spending, homebuilding, and automobiles actually began at that time. The upswing of industrial production was interrupted during the autumn by coal and steel strikes, but expansion was quickly resumed and developed rapidly during the first half of 1950. Prices responded, as they normally do in a period of recovery, with gentle increases for materials but little change for finished goods. * Creamer, Daniel, Behavior of Wage Rates During Business Cycles, Occasional Paper 34, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1950, New York, N. Y., p. 37, table 5. 8 Op. cit, p. 8. 178 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH THE KOREAN INFLATION AND ITS AFTERMATH, 195 0 - 5 4 The normal processes of recovery had carried the economy most of the distance toward full employment by mid-1950, at which time the economic forces set in motion by the Korean conflict intervened to alter radically the character of the expansion. Prices were forced up violently in 2 consecutive waves of forward buying which swept over the country during the first 9 months of hostilities, and, although wholesale prices subsequently receded, the average of consumer prices never did (chart 1). It will not be necessary to follow the events of the inflationary phase of the Korean expansion in detail, since the main facts are easily read from the behavior of expenditures, incomes, and prices during the period. First, we note that military spending was not the sole or even the principal cause of the buying waves, although the placement of defense orders doubtless stimulated business activity during the latter months of 1950. Rather, it was the forward buying of consumers and businessmen in anticipation of potential shortages which created acute inflationary pressures. The speculative nature of the surges of consumer demand is readily apparent from the wide swings of expenditure relative to income, timed as they were with the onset of hostilities and the later entry of the Chinese Communists into the war (charts 11 and 12). The fluctuations of retail trade were duplicated at wholesale and in manufacturers' new orders and sales, so that inventories rose all along the line from factory to retailer (charts 14 and 15 ). A general price and wage freeze was announced on January 26, 1951. From then until early in 1953, prices were under varying degrees of wartime administrative control, but it was a fascinating and unexpected feature of those years that average wholesale prices actually declined substantially and, for many commodities, fell well below legal ceilings. This occurred, moreover, during a period of continuous full employment of labor and while the Government share of real gross national product was increasing from 7.7 percent in 1950 to 15.5 percent in 1952. What happened was that a decline of consumer demand in reaction from the early buying sprees neatly offset the rise of defense spending. This is not to say that price and allocation controls were unnecessary or ineffective, however. By insulating the several sectors of the economy from one another, they gave maximum effect to the relaxation of consumer demand. As 1951 opened, the production of consumer goods was geared to high and rising retail sales. Household stocks had been augmented and personal liquidity depleted during the buying waves, however, and civilian goods appeared to be in plentiful supply and could no longer rise much in price now that controls were in effect. Eetrenchment was indicated under the circumstances, and, beginning in February, retail sales declined suddenly and sharply, causing an equally abrupt and unwanted increase of distributors' stocks during the next few months (charts 14 and 15). The necessity subsequently to work off these excessive inventories magnified and prolonged the deflationary impact of the cutback of consumption expenditure well into 1952, despite a gradual recovery of retail sales after mid-1951. 179 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 11 The Nation's Income, Expenditure, and Saving By Major Economic Sectors Seasonally Adjusted Quarterly Totals at Annual Rates, '1950-1954 (Billions of Dollars) Consumers .260 Disposable Income •230 Personal Consumption Expenditures 170 Business 90 Gross Private Domestic Investment vffn SO it -- L111 ' ' J l^^ft^^ Excess of Investment 7fnTnml '1 1 I [ Gross Retained Earnings £ i Government 90 Receipts (Less Transfer Payments) 60 Purchases of Goods and Service, 30 Surplus Net Foreign Investment + 15 -15 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1/ Includes undistributed corporate profits, inventory valuation adjustment, and capital consumption allowances. Source: Department of Commerce. 23734—58 13 180 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 12 Government Purchases and Personal Consumption Expenditures Seasonally Adjusted Quarterly Totals at Annual Rates, 1950-1954 (Billions of Dollars) hog scale p 90 80 70 Government Purchases of Goods and Services \r ^^ yS*^Total $0 " - — ^ 50 jS S* —*»^ ^ ^ 40 /Federal 30 / ——— ^ 20 -0~~0~~"^ " State and Local i 10 i i i 300 Personal Consumption Expenditures 200 Total 150 ^^ 100 90 80 m*^ nondurable Goods 70 ~~ 60 " Services 50 40 30 - ——- —S ^ -* ^^S Durable Goods 20 i 10 1950 * 1951 i i i 1952 1953 1954 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Department of Commerce. 181 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 13 Gross Private Domestic Investment and Its Major Components Seasonally Adjusted Quarterly Totals at Annual Rates, 1950-1954 (Billions of Dollars) 30 - 20 - 10 - -10 - Components of Business Fixed Investment j 30 P 7 - Producers' Durable Equipment \-X 20 - 10 - "-* wmmmmmm wmmm Nonresidential i 1950 i 1951 Construction i 1952 i 1953 1954 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Department of Commerce. 182 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 14 Indexes of Personal Income, Retail, Wholesale, and Manufacturers1 Sales and Inventories and Manufacturers' New Orders Seasonally Adjusted, Monthly, 1950-1954 Index June 1950 s 100 135 150 - 100 - 1950 P 1951 1952 1953 Index June 1950 -100 T 1954 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau pf Economic Research. Source: Department of Commerce. 183 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 15 Inventory-Sales Ratios (Monthly, 1950-1954) Per cent p :r 170 \^v A Retail y 150 N / 130 0 / i i 120 Wholesale 100 80 0 \ if l i t 195 v 175 \—y\ / \ / Manufacturing 155 V 135 0 I i 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Department of Commerce. 184 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH For a time it was as though two economies existed side by side without touching. The grand division was between consumption and nonconsumption goods. Reduced consumption and inventory demands depressed especially factory production and wholesale prices of textile, apparel, rubber, and leather products from early 1951 to mid-1952. ^Production of consumer durable goods also declined substantially, but their prices remained at ceiling levels. The production cutbacks were required by defense restrictions on materials, but retail demand had eased for durables as well as nondurables, and distributors' stocks remained above the 1949-50 levels, so that supplies were adequate at existing prices. Defense contracts and defense-oriented programs of facilities expansion replaced the business lost in the consumer sector, ;and average prices and production of durable goods were generally stable. The downdrift was ended by mid-1952 insofar as nonagricultural business is concerned. The gap which had opened between income and expenditure with the retrenchment of consumer demand in 1951, narrowed again in 1952 as consumer purchases rose somewhat faster than income (chart 11). Inventory liquidation had substantially improved the position of distributors by early summer (chart 15). Allotments of critical metals to nondef ense purposes were increased as defense requirements began to taper off toward a plateau planned for 1953. The incipient recovery of the consumer sector was interrupted l>y the steel strike of the summer of 1952, but the work stoppage ended late in July, and production, employment, and incomes expanded swiftly thereafter as factories and distributors rebuilt inventories and final sales of consumer goods accelerated. Thus the defense expansion was capped by a vigorous boom in civilian goods as it entered its closing phases. No comparable rise occurred in prices, however. Indeed, the indexes of wholesale and consumer prices decreased somewhat during late 1952 and early 1953—surely peculiar behavior for an economy in which production was high and rising and unemployment was less than 3 percent of the labor force. Nor is it adequate to observe that sharp reductions in foods lowered the average of wholesale prices and that prices of other finished goods actually increased a bit (chart 2), for the recovery of consumer demand might have increased nonfood prices even more were it not for price controls. Let us follow up this thought and inquire into the causes and effects of the price divergencies which developed during the period of price and wage control. Changes in relative prices may reflect a variety of possible forces acting singly or in combination. They may be initiated either by shifts of demand or supply among products; either type of shift may occur for several different reasons; and the timing and amount of the resulting price changes will depend partly on the structure of the affected markets—for example, whether there are many buyers and sellers, or so few as to confer some degree of individual control over price. Now, one obvious fact about the shifts of consumption and nonconsumption demand during the Korean period is that they occurred under conditions in which some prices were not free to move upward in response to market forces whereas others could fall below ceiling prices if demand weakened or supply increased enough. The probable result is that the differential between prices of durable and nondurable goods did not become as large as it otherwise would have ECONOMIC STABILITY A3STD GROWTH 185 done, or alternatively, that the differential would have remained about the same but that prices of durables would otherwise have risen more and those of nondurables fallen less. In either event, the overall average of prices would have been correspondingly higher. Suppose by way of illustration, that no administrative controls had been imposed on prices, wages, or critical materials and that no fiscal or monetary curbs to private expenditure had been in effect when consumer demand declined in 1951. Is it not likely that bottlenecks in metals and metal products would have forced prices higher in those sectors—including prices of durable consumer goods? Consumers might have reacted to this by purchasing fewer cars or refrigerators until prices came down again, or they might have substituted more spending on durables for less on nondurables and depressed the prices of the latter, but it is also quite possible that they would have increased total expenditure even at the same level of money income, thus sustaining a higher price level. More important, of course, is the fact that money income would not have been the same. Money wages would have risen along with prices in the durable goods industries, and the wage increases would have spread to other industries as well, raising the whole structure of prices and money incomes at the given level of real national income. Thus the relaxation of private demand contributed so much to overall price stability partly because it occurred in an institutional complex that constricted the normal channels for transmission of inflationary impulses between sectors and permitted deflationary forces full scope in the affected areas. By the same token, of course, the task of containing inflationary pressures by direct and indirect controls was greatly simplified by the voluntary reduction of consumer demand and the associated inventory adjustments. Perhaps even the preceding discussion has left the reader inadequately prepared for the amplitude of the price declines in nondurables during 1951-52 (chart 16). The reaction was especially severe for prices of intermediate materials—intimately related to basic agricultural commodities—just as the preceding rise had been under the impact of speculative inventory demand at home and abroad. Prices of finished nondurable goods did not fall nearly as much, partly because the demand for finished goods always holds up better than that for materials during periods of declining sales and inventory liquidation, and partly because wages in nondurable goods factories continued to rise along with those in durable goods industries (chart 17). Average hourly earnings of manufacturing workers kept closely in step with the cost of living until the summer of 1952. Consumer prices moved ahead during the first Korean buying wave, but wages responded quickly and by the time of the general freeze in January 1951, had achieved approximate parity with the Consumer Price Index not only for factory workers but for other large groups of employees as well. Wages were under direct control after the freeze, of course, but gradual increases occurred as adjustments were granted to groups whose real earnings had lagged in 1950, and to workers in general to compensate for increases in consumer prices during the period of price control. In this way higher wages became part of the cost-price-income structure of the economy, thereby limiting the price declines in the weaker sectors. With the exception of foods, average wholesale prices of nondurable finished goods never did fall back to the pre 186 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Korean peak of 1948, and not even foods did so at retail (charts 3 and! surged forward during the last phase of direct controls in the latter half of 1952 and early 1953. The rise reflected a breakdown of the hold-the-line policy on real wages, and was part of a general movement to relax direct and indirect controls as it became apparent that this could be done without undue danger to the mobilization program or to economic stability. Substantial advances for steel, copper, and aluminum were permitted under a corresponding relaxation of the criteria for price increases, and metal users were allowed to pass through the resulting absolute cost increases but not to pyramid them by proportional markups. Were it not for the ceilings, prices of finished durable goods would doubtless have risen substantially after the steel strike, under the combined pressure of heavy consumer and inventory demand and the concomitant rise of resource prices. As it was, they increased only fractionally before the final elimination of price controls in April 1953. Increases were small also among nondurables, however, where ceilings had been suspended for a large proportion of commodities, and despite a substantial upswing of wages, production and sales. The principal depressant at work—the emergence of agricultural surpluses—has ueen an important determinant of prices of nondurable^ ever since. In late 1952 and early 1953, increased domestic production and a sharp drop of exports augmented domestic supplies sufficiently to depress prices of food at wholesale and retail and to offset increases of demand for materials important in the manufacture of nondurable goods. During the last phase of the Korean expansion, then, the spread which had developed between prices of durables and nondurables initially because of shifts in relative demands for final products, was kept open with the assistance of shifts in export demand and domestic supply which were in good part independent of current final demands. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 16 Index 1947-49'10$ 150 - 140 - 130 - 120 - 110 - Indexes of Wholesale Prices of Intermediate and Finished Goods (Monthly, 1947-19&7) P T P Materials T A00 150 - 140 - 130 - 120 - 110 - 100 - Consumer Other Nondurable Goods SO 1947 48 49 50 51 52 53 54 55 SB 57 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, except for the peak of August 1957 which was dated by the author. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. 187 Indexes of Average Hourly Earnings and Prices (Monthly, 1950-1954) Index June 1950-100 7 Average Hourly Earnings (Manufacturing) ^ / - O 120 120 Wholesale Prices Average Hourly Earnings (Durable Goods Manufacturers) J [**< 115 / Consu mer Prices 110 110 105 105 0 / r^f^ ]f f I _^i Average Hourly Earnings (Nondurable Goods Manufacturers) /¥ // " , / o J f 115 ^ 1 100 i 125 125 100 I 1950 I 1951 0 I 1952 1953 1954 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. • / 1950 i 1951 t 1952 1953 1954 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 189 The subtitle of the present section—"The Korean Inflation and Its Aftermath, 1950-54"—was chosen advisedly from two points of view. The contraction of 1953-54 was caused partly by the post-Korean cutback of defense expenditures and defense-oriented investment and was in that sense an aftermath of Korea. More directly relevant is the fact that price behavior during the contraction was heavily influenced by the preceding reaction to the inflationary waves of 1950-51. These points will be discussed in turn. The sharp rebound of business activity which came after the steel strike of mid-1952 and under the spur of mounting private demands has already received attention. The rate of recovery of sales and production was rapid indeed during the latter months of 1952, but the pace of expansion slowed materially during the winter and spring of 1953 (charts 1 and 14). Retail sales had increased more rapidly than personal income as consumers stepped up their purchases during the closing months of 1952. Retail trade leveled off early in 1953, however, partly because total consumption expenditure increased only in line with income instead of by more, and partly because this meant a still more pronounced retardation of sales of goods as distinct from services, just as the preceding acceleration of spending relative to income had been for goods rather than services. With sales flagging and inventories still increasing, distributors cut back on their orders, with the result that production of nondurables and of major household durable goods dropped after May, anticipating hy 2 months the downturn of industrial production. Similar retardations appeared prior to the actual 1953 declines of defense expenditure and fixed investment, and probably contributed also to the downslide of new orders which preceded the July peak of aggregate manufacturing sales and production by many months (chart 14). If the foregoing events sound a bit familiar, it is because they are not unlike those of 1948. Retail sales also slackened at that time, although for somewhat different reasons, and helped precipitate the downturn. Again, fixed investment flattened out before actually declining in the earlier period. Other parallels are to be found in the further development of the two contractions. Thus most of the decline of gross national product during 1953-54 was accounted for by inventory change. Just as in 1949, the deflationary impact of inventory adjustment was largely spent after 6 months of contraction (chart 13). Just as then, moreover, a substantial portion of the inventory decline was induced by falling retail sales in the early months of contraction; and as before, inventory disinvestment was quickly arrested because final expenditure held firm after its brief initial lapse. Even the proximate cause of the stability of final expenditure during the last half of either contraction was the same—an early recovery of consumption demand and residential construction which served to offset the further deterioration of final demand for business plant and equipment in both contractions and for Federal purchases in the later one. I have emphasized these parallels as a reminder that "inventory recessions" remain just that only if final demand has independent strength and if short-term sales and price expectations do not deteriorate in cumulative fashion to undermine that strength. This is not to say that final demand held firm for identical reasons in 1949 and 190 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 1954, although there were important common influences even there in the operation of automatic stabilizers, the stimulus imparted to home building and consumer spending by easier credit, and the favorable state of long-term investment opportunities as evidenced by the comparatively minor declines of business fixed investment in both years. A principal difference, of course, was that Federal spending rose in 1949 and fell in 1954, whereas tax reductions stimulated private income and demand in 1954 but not in 1949. Another difference between the two contractions, and one which is a little unexpected because the fluctuations of physical activity were approximately equal in duration and amplitude, is that average prices declined considerably during 1948-49 but edged fractionally higher in 1953-54 (chart 1). Is this evidence that, in the short space of 5 years, prices had become increasingly resistant to business contractions because of structural changes in the economy? Or was the greater stability during the second contraction due primarily to factors peculiar to it ? One possibility is that wages were more rigid than before. This is not borne out by the behavior of average hourly earnings in manufacturing industries, however, which leveled off as usual during contractions (chart 17). There is a point worth noting about the timing of industrial wages and prices in relation to business activity, nonetheless. Although demand was weakening before the business-cycle peak of July 1953, substantial cutbacks in production and sales did not occur until after that date. This meant that wages and prices were decontrolled a few months prior to the actual contraction. The increases which came with decontrol were moderate, but they were firm enough to hold during the ensuing recession, with the result that industrial finished-goods prices averaged higher than in the months preceding the downturn. But price increases during the very months when the economy is in the process of transition from expansion to contraction are not especially surprising if allowance is made for the gradual and gentle form which the transition often assumes. The increases which occurred in prices of finished goods during the latter months of 1948 come immediately to mind (chart 2). It is not the fact that prices went up just prior to the downturn that distinguishes 1953-54 from 1948-^9, but the fact that they stayed up throughout the contraction. Since the decline of final demand was small and wages were firm, the scope for industrial price reductions was limited largely by the potential fall in prices of materials. As we have seen, substantial declines may occur from this source during mild contractions because the demand for materials weakens considerably more than that for final goods. Even this avenue was closed in 1953-54, however, principally because prices of nondurable materials had been forced down previously—the adjustment which ordinarily would come with a general contraction had already occurred because of the isolated contraction in that sector during 1951-52. Producers of intermediate nondurable materials were caught in a wage-price squeeze because their wage scales reflected the general boosts in the economy which came after 1950, but their prices were no higher than in 1948 (charts 16 and 17). Still, these prices did decline a little in 1954, and would have decreased more were it not that prices of crude materials were ECONOMIC STABIIilTY AND GROWTH 191 lent independent support by the agricultural program. Again, agricultural price supports were already providing effective floors by 1953 because of the declines which had gone before, whereas in 1948-49 farm prices could fall much further before they were arrested by supports. It appears, then, that the price stability of 1953-54 was in good part the result of factors peculiar to that contraction, and does not necessarily mean that prices have become permanently more rigid. To the extent that agricultural supports remain a feature of the economic structure, however, and especially when prices have been under support before a contraction begins, they will minimize cyclical declines in prices of important classes of goods. Since any diversion of purchasing power which might arise, if prices of foods and other nondurables were lower in the absence of supports, would during a period of contraction tend to stimulate larger physical sales of durables rather than higher prices for them, it is likely that the overall average of prices would be kept higher by the supports than it otherwise would be. And, of course, the net injection of income from Government sources via the support operation helps to firm demands generally. If the cost of living were, indeed, prevented from falling as much as otherwise, this would reinforce the tendency toward firmness by reducing wage adjustments under escalator clauses. This effect would be comparatively unimportant, however, since downward wage escalation is usually limited bjr agreement during any given contract period, and since small changes in wage rates up or down probably have little influence over administered prices. EXPANSION AND INFLATION, 1954-57 "Expansion and then inflation" would be a more descriptive heading for this section. The business expansion which began in August 1954 lasted exactly 3 years. During the first half of this span, the average of consumer prices kept within a range of 1 index point, but it began rising in March 1956, and has continued upward ever since, with the advance persisting even into the present phase of cyclical contraction. While not as rapid as the vigorous inflations of 1946-48 and 1950-51, the consumer price increases of the past 2 years were at a substantial rate and were more than double the increase of disposable personal income in constant prices. Price stability for finished goods is to be expected during the initial phase of expansion from a cyclical trough. Prices of materials may recover rapidly from the very beginning, but these elements of cobt will have fallen so low during the contraction that increases can be absorbed for a time without encroaching on profit margins. Because excess capacity will have developed during the downswing, owing to the continued growth and modernization of plant and equipment and the decline of production, moreover, real cost savings will accrue as activity expands to make more efficient use of productive facilities and to make use of newly more efficient productive facilities. These real savings will make it possible to pay higher prices for both labor and materials without raising production costs. Purely cyclical factors are npt enough to account for the continued stability of consumer prices into early 1956, however. Industrial 192 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH wholesale prices were fairly steady until mid-1955, but they increased sharply thereafter (chart 2). Leaving this rise unexplained for the moment, we notice that its effects on average consumer prices were minimized by two factors of noncyclical origin. Prices of farm products and foods fell off sharply during the last half of 1955, as agricultural commodities continued in excess supply because of a combination of high carryover stocks and record or near record 1955 farm outputs. Retail food prices declined in sympathy, though by smaller amounts, tending directly to reduce the Consumer Price Index. Consumers probably took advantage of lower food prices partly by increasing their food consumption and partly by increasing other expenditures. If so, the induced shift of demand was insufficient to raise other prices enough to compensate for the decline of food prices, since average prices were stable despite higher personal incomes. One reason for the lack of fully compensating increases was that persistent agricultural surpluses had also weakened prices of basic materials used in other nondurable-goods industries, serving to restrain increases for finished goods in that sector. Another important factor was a fall of retail prices of durable consumer goods in the face of rising wholesale prices (charts 3 and 16). This was not a new development, however, for retail margins on durable goods had been narrowing for several years under the competitive pressures associated with the growth of the discount house and emergence of a buyers' market in automobiles. The potential for retail price reductions from this source appears to have become exhausted about mid-1956. Prices of household appliances did fall slightly over the next 18 months, but furniture prices rose moderately, and those of automobiles more substantially. In future, aside from seasonal changes in dealer margins, significant reductions of retail price tags will probably await or induce corresponding drops in wholesale prices. Let us revert now to mid-1955 and the rise of industrial prices which began at that time. We need to go back, in fact, just a bit further in order to recall 2 important features of the recovery of 1954-55. One was the spectacular reception accorded the 1955 automobile models and the acceleration of consumer purchases of durable goods for which it was primarily responsible (chart 18). The other was the onrush of business plans for capacity expansion during the winter and spring of 1955. These plans were a lagged response to the business upturn, so that business fixed investment did not rise strongly until the latter half of the year (chart 19). The upsurge was foreshadowed during the spring, however, in surveys of investment plans and, even more concretely, in new orders for producer goods. Thus, prospects for 1955 sales and profits were excellent at the time of the wage settlements in major durable-goods industries during the late spring and summer. 193 ECONOMIC STABUJITY AND GROWTH Chart 18 Government Purchases and Personal Consumption Expenditures Seasonally Adjusted Quarterly Totals at Annual Rates, 1954-1957 (Billions of Dollars) Government Purchases of Goods and Services Los Scale 9b 80 70 60 50 Federal 40 30 State and Local Personal Consumption Expenditures P 300 '• 250 — —_ 200 - 150 - — — Total Nondurable Goods __ " — 100 90 80 — — •• -— — Services 70 60 50 40 — 30 —•——— ^ ^ — — Durable Goods 1954 t 1955 i 1956 i 1957 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, except for the peak of August 1957 which was dated by the author. Source: Department of Commerce, 194 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Gross Private Domestic Investment and Its Mayor Components Seasonally Adjusted Quarterly Totals at Annual Rates, 1954-1957 (Billions of Dollars) T 70 - 60 -- 50 - 40 - Gross Private Domestic Investment ^ ^ ^ ^ ~ ^ ^ Business Fixed Investment ~mmmmmmm 20 - Residential —ii 10 •—' Construction , ^ _— - * Inventory Investment i -10 I 1 Components of Business Fixed Investment 40 - 20 - 10 - 1954 1955 1956 1957 Vertical lines indicate bttsiness cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, except for the peak of August 1957 which was dated by the author. Source: Department of Commerce. m 1947-49'100 1 120 - Chart 20 Indexes of Average Hourly Earnings, and Prices of Intermediate Materials and Finished Goods (Monthly, 1954-195® Index 1947-49*100 j Nondurable Goods Manufacturing (Excluding Foods) 120 Average Hourly Earnings r Durable Goods Manufacturing 115 - Average Hourly Earnings no - 105 - Prices of Finished Goods mjj / Prices of Finished Goods i 295 Prices of Intermediate Materials 100 •^Prices of Intermediate Materials 95 o w o - 50 " 90 0 > i i i a 2- Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, except for the peak of August 1957 which was dated by the author, $ource: Bureau of Labor Statistics. CO Chart 21 Indexes of Average Hourly Earnings and Prices (Monthly, 1954-1958) Index_ Vug.l954=100 2 P -J.UU 125 - 125 120 120 - Average Hourly Earnings (Manufacturing) 115 - 110 - 105 - j f Wholesale ^ * ^—m^ A" Prices^/"^""" 100 95 ' P *" 115 - 110 - 105 - Average Hourly EarningsJTT^ (Durable Goods) J r V rjf ^/ -[Average Hourly Earnings jV~ir (Nondurable Goods) 100 - 0 > 95 i t i t Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, except for the peak of August 1957 which was dated by the author. Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics. 0 i 1954 i 1955 j_ 1958 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 197 With product demands high and expected to rise further in many industries, sizable wage increases were demanded and received by employees in heavy industry. Parallel changes occurred in prices of intermediate materials for durable goods manufacturing—comprising principally primary metals, lumber, and plastics—and of durable finished goods (chart 20). Between June and November of 1955, average hourly earnings of production workers in durable-goods factories increased 3.7 percent, and prices of intermediate materials 5.1 percent. Average wholesale prices of finished durable goods increased 3.4 percent between July and December, with consumer durables up 2.6 percent and producer goods 4.3 percent. Were these price raises caused by increased demands or higher costs? The answer can only be: by both. Current demands for durable goods had recovered strongly before the wage advances, and further increases of demand were in the offing and the orders were on the books. These facts certainly augmented the size of the wage increases—contrast the increases of 1954 and 1955—but the timing and magnitude of the price increases were just as definitely influenced by the behavior of wages. Prices of nondurable manufactures also rose during the last half of 1955. These increases were probably occasioned less by wage increases than by current demands. Eetail sales of nondurables moved ahead strongly during 1955 and continued to rise as sales of durables fell during the last few months of the year. For reasons to be discussed later, prices of nondurables as a class are quicker to respond to demand shifts than are those of durables. Thus prices of nondurables dropped in the spring of 1955 despite substantial wage increases, and when average hourly earnings in nondurable manufacturing caught up with those in durable goods factories with a spurt during the spring of 1956, prices were steady and did not rise until late in the year (charts 20 and 21). Nor is the lag of price increases behind wage increases in 1955 and again in 1956 evidence that the latter caused the former. Technical lags in the processes of production and sale cannot explain a wage-price lag on the order of 6 months; and in point of fact, prices of intermediate materials and finished goods moved closely together from month to month, as the chart shows. Wage and cost increases do influence prices, but so also does demand, and in the instance of nondurables both factors operate quickly and may sometimes be offsetting, sometimes reinforcing, so that no simple relationship exists between prices and either factor alone. 198 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH A final feature of 1955 should be mentioned before we move on. The year marks a revival of labor-management interest in the longterm contract which specifies deferred annual wage increases and provides for escalation to protect the real value of wages during the life of the agreement. Such contracts were negotiated in the automobile industry and with General Electric in 1955. They spread to steel, meatpacking, and railroads in 1956. By the end of 1957, the Bureau of Labor Statistics had on file long-term agreements involving fixed wage increases of a deferred nature which covered 4.4 million workers. The deferred increases specified by "annual improvement factors" or "annual productivity increases" are generally in line with the long-term average rate of growth of output per man-hour for the economy as a whole, but that fact does not necessarily render them noninflationary. Even apart from other determinants of price and cost, the annual productivity gains in the industries directly affected by the contracts may change unevenly over time and may deviate widely from the average for the economy, both in any given year and over the long term. And, of course, since the deferred increases set a standard for other wages, they may lift the general level of money wages at a faster rate than overall productivity rises in any particular year, especially since productivity growth is markedly uneven. When this happens the upward pressure on prices from the cost side is increased everywhere, although average prices will not rise commensurately or at all unless demand permits. 199 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 22 Indexes of Personal Income, Retail, Wholesale, and Manufacturers* Sales and Inventories and Manufacturers' New Orders Seasonally Adjusted, Monthly, 1954-1958 Index Aug. 1954 -100 Index Aug. 1954 = 100 , 125 Wholesale Sales (Left Scale) 115 - 105 - 140 Manufacturers* Sales 110 (Right Scale) 100 120 Wholesale Inventories / ,'Manufacturers Inventories f 110 Retail Inventories (Left Scale) Ao 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, except for the peak of August 1957 which was dated by the author. Source: Department of Commerce. 200 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Chart 23 Inventory-Sales Ratios (Monthly, 1954-1958) Percent 170 160 - 150 - Retail 140 i 0 i i i r 120 110 Wholesale r\ S ^* 100 0 > i i i 195 185 175 165 0 V > A / Manufacturing \ J 1 1954 t 1955 1 1956 1957 1958 Source: Department of Commerce. Vertical lines indicate business cycle peaks (P) and troughs (T) as dated by the National Bureau of Economic Research, except for the peak of August 1957 which was dated by the author. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 201 The pace of business expansion slowed notably during the first 6 or 8 months of 1956. Industrial production actually drifted downward, whereas more comprehensive measures of physical activity such as real gross national product merely flattened out. Industrial wholesale prices rose at a much diminished rate, although farm and food prices rebounded from the 1955 lows and the average of all wholesale prices moved ahead faster than in the preceding year (charts land 2). The slowdown occurred because demand pressures eased generally. In two major sectors of the economy final expenditures declined by substantial amounts: consumer purchases of automobiles, which had turned down after the third quarter of 1955, and residential construction, which had reached its peak slightly earlier (charts 18 and 19). Retail sales of nondurable goods did not actually decline during the early months of 1956, but neither did they increase much until May. Hence, automobile dealers took steps to reduce inventories and other retailers to avoid increases, with the ultimate result that inventory investment declined in sympathy with stable or falling retail sales, and production fell off among durable and nondurable factories alike (charts 22 and 23). About the only major component of private demand which was still rising strongly was business fixed investment. The structure of industrial prices mirrors the pattern of relative demands just described. Prices of finished producer goods continued to rise during the first half of 1956, although at a slower rate than during the preceding or subsequent spates of wage-price increase. Average wholesale prices of consumer durable goods were stable as retail prices of automobiles declined moderately. Steady also was the average of consumer finished nondurable goods other than foods in primary markets (chart 16). Granted that easier demands were instrumental in the retardation of price increases during this period, the next question is obvious. The slowdown of demand was in response to events which had occurred during 1955. In particular, the decline of homebuilding and automobile sales during the closing months of 1955 caused production to drop not only in those sectors but in supplying industries as well. About the turn of the year the declines became substantial enough to depress hours and employment of factory workers and slow the growth of aggregate personal income. Increased personal taxes restrained the increase of disposable personal income still further. Nonautomotive consumption expenditures continued to increase, but at a diminished rate and at the expense of a considerable reduction of personal saving. Apparently the retardation of disposable income contributed to easier demand conditions not only in automobiles but in consumer goods generally during the first 3 or 4 months of 1956. Taking the analysis back another step, the decline of homebuilding after mid-1955 was caused primarily by measures employed at that time to stiffen terms on mortgages insured or guaranteed by the Federal Government, and by the concomitant restrictive actions of the Federal Reserve authorities which increased interest rates generally and made residential mortgages less attractive to lenders. Automobile sales, on the other hand, were probably not materially influenced by general credit constraints. The spectacular sales of 1955 models had satisfied the needs of many new-car buyers for at least 2 or 3 years 202 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH ahead, producing a temporary saturation of segments of the new-car market and a corresponding decline of sales of 1956 models. I conclude that the easing of demand in 1956 was partly a lagged response to credit policies which had accomplished the intended purpose and partly the result of an independent reaction from the prior surge of automobile sales. The downward movement in automobiles and housing was prolonged into the summer months, although nonresidential construction offset much of the latter decline. Eetail sales moved ahead during the late spring and early summer, but the increase reflected primarily higher prices for foods, and the physical volume of retail sales continued below the level reached late in 1955. Consequently, production of durables and nondurables alike remained depressed until July, and in that month a sharp though brief curtailment of steel production occurred because of a strike. Industrial production and prices surged forward on a broad front beginning in August. The prime mover appears to have been increased activity in the automobile and ancillary industries as the new models went into production. Federal defense expenditure turned upward as well, however, and an added thrust was lent by restocking demand on the part of metal fabricators whose inventories of materials had been drawn down during the steel strike. The entire fourth quarter was colored by the rebound of automobile production. As it turned out, sales increased less than expected, but in the meantime production was augmented by the inventory accumulations of automotive manufacturers and dealers. The increase of automobile production was superimposed, moreover, on the gentler but steadier rise of machinery production as business expenditures for equipment continued their advance. Since total industrial production advanced, so also did employment and earnings, the latter with an assist from wage increases. In this way, increased production consequent on expanded automobile output served to bolster personal incomes and helped to induce a part of the increased volume of retail sales which had been expected and the expectation of which had started the process. Demand, expected demand, and independent or semi-independent cost increases are again intertwined in the price-output movements of this period. Again there is a close correspondence between the increases of average hourly earnings and prices of intermediate ma^ terials and finished products in the durable goods sector (chart 20). The increases were timed with the wage-price boost which followed the steel settlement. With wages and prices rising all along the line in metal fabricating, and with business demand for equipment still high, prices of finished producer goods rose 3.4 percent between July and October. Increased price tags on new model automobiles were primarily responsible for the abrupt 2.1 percent rise of average wholesale prices of consumer durable goods between September and November. Prices of nondurables, excluding foods, also increased after August, and by year end had risen 1.1 percent. These increases in rimary markets were reflected in retail prices, and the Consumer 'rice Index gained 1.0 percent between August and December despite a slight decline in prices of food over those months (charts 1 and 3). As 1957 opened the expansion was already more than 2 years old. I t gradually lost its momentum as the year progressed, and by autumn P ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 203 a downturn was underway. Interestingly enough, production, employment, and prices behaved much as they had done in 1956 until the period of actual contraction came during the last 4 months of the year (chart 1). For that matter, the contrast after August is found primarily in physical activity, because prices of finished goods rose after the contraction had begun and by amounts that while smaller than in 1956, were still significant (charts 20 and 21). The early resemblance to 1956 is partly due to a repetition of the same deflationary forces that developed at the outset of the former year. Automobile sales increased moderately in the first quarter but fell thereafter. Eesidential construction continued downhill until July. These declines were smaller than in 1956, but a new and ominous depressant was added when business fixed investment tapered off (chart 19). Money outlays for producers' durable equipment diminished fractionally after the first quarter and, since prices kept rising, the decline was somewhat larger in physical terms. Signs of the imminent slackening of fixed investment had appeared a few months earlier, of course, when new and unfilled orders of producers of investment goods entered a decline. Thus, the year had scarcely begun before three important elements of final demand—business investment, residential construction, and automobile purchases—were exerting concerted downward pressure on production. Government purchases and net exports rose, however, with especially favorable results for the aircraft and petroleum industries—the latter because of the foreign demand stimulated by the Suez crisis. Nonetheless, the balance was on the side of contraction in durable goods. Employment, hours, and weekly earnings of factory workers in the affected industries declined along with production, but gains among salaried workers and elsewhere in the economy kept personal income rising until August. Purchases of consumer durables failed to rise along with personal income, but retail sales of foods and soft goods moved ahead strongly during the spring and summer as consumers augmented their total expenditure and shifted its composition in favor of nondurables. Since distributors were watching inventories carefully, however, the new business of nondurable manufacturers did not rise correspondingly and the volume of production was merely maintained instead of increasing. The incipient contraction became actuality after August. What happened was that an economy already balanced on the edge of contraction because of internal developments in the private sector, was subjected to additional, autonomous deflationary shocks from reductions of defense spending and export demands. Neither decline was especially large, but they occurred when the economy was vulnerable to disturbance and hastened a downturn that would doubtless have come soon anyway. Now industrial production dropped more swiftly, nonagricultural employment began to decline, and labor income turned downward and carried aggregate personal income with it. Retail sales decreased as personal income dropped, spreading the contraction to the soft-goods industries. The shifting fortunes of the economy and its several parts during 1957 left their mark on prices as well as production. Since demand had eased generally after the turn of the year, industrial wholesale prices were stable on the average until summer arrived (chart 1). 204 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Even prices of finished producer goods rose comparatively little (chart 16). It is of course true that these prices tend regularly to rise more slowly after the annual wage-price adjustment is completed near the end of 1 year and before it begins in the next, but the diminished intensity of demand for producers' durable equipment is reflected in the small rate of price increase in comparison with the first half of 1956. Among important classes of finished goods, only foods rose appreciably in price during the spring. It is apparent from the indicators of investment preparations— new orders, investment plans, and the like—that demand for investment goods stopped rising in 1957. It is quite another and more complicated issue, however, as to why this came about. Financial constraints were doubtless partly responsible. The Federal Eeserve kept pressure on bank reserves through most of the year, and bank loans increased only half as much as in 1956. Since the demand for loanable funds exceeded the supply from banks and other sources, interest rates rose through October. Overall credit tightness probably limited investments in certain directions, especially when it came time to finance projects already planned. And, of course, financial stringency during 1956 may have affected 1957 investment. Perhaps the early decline of plant and equipment expenditure in the commercial sector reflects restricted access to credit sources on the part of small business. The continued decline of homebuilding until midyear was certainly owing in part to difficulties in obtaining mortgages on favorable terms. Another factor was at work to retard business investment at least in the manufacturing sector, however, and that was the sharp expansion of capacity implied in the high rate of current investment outlays during 1955 and 1956. Capacity utilization rates were still satisfactory at the end of 1956, but the growth of production had slowed in 1956 and could be expected to be gradual in 1957 since the economy was already at full employment. Merely maintaining current capital installations at the level already attained would insure future increases of capacity at a steady, high rate. Such considerations as these probably damped the planned increases in the rate of current investment, and by so doing helped to make capacity more redundant than otherwise, for the slowdown in the rate of investment implied a cutback of orders for producer goods and worked in combination with weakness in automobiles to reduce production throughout the metal and metal using sector of the economy. By September 1957, McGrawHill could report: "For the first time since we began asking the question in 1955 every manufacturing industry is now operating at a lower rate of capacity than it generally prefers," although noting also that no industries reported really depressed levels of business at that time.6 The industrial price stability which had been a feature of the first half of the year was disrupted by new increases for durable goods during the summer and fall. Prices of producers' equipment accelerated after June, whereas the index for consumer durable goods took its usual vertical step later in the year when the 1958 automobiles were introduced at higher prices. The price raises were occasioned, of course, by wage increases. This joint movement is reminiscent of 1948, •McGraw-Hill's Fall Survey of Preliminary Business Plans for Capital Spending in 1958-59, prepared by McGraw-Hill department of economics, p. 3. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 205 when wages and prices advanced together in the durable goods sector just prior to another economic downturn. Actually, the timing itself is not particularly relevant, since demand for investment goods had eased but was still high before both downturns and markets could hardly be described as distressed. The principal difference between the two experiences is that in 1948 management resisted wage increases until expectations were altered by the tax cut and defense program, whereas in 1957 the increases were largely an automatic result of bargaining decisions made in 1955 and 1956. Thus about two-thirds of the 7.5 million workers who received increases under major collective bargaining contracts in 1957, did so because of deferred wage increases under long-term agreements. The present contraction has been underway for about 6 months as this is written. Thus far the prices indexes—available now through February—are still rising. Retail food prices are moving irregularly upward as they have done since early 1956, primarily because of smaller supplies of livestock. Consumer services continue to rise gradually but steadily in price. Apparel has dropped a bit and retail prices of new automobiles were shaved after November but remain several percent higher than before the model changes. In primary markets, durable finished goods have held their gains of late 1957, but average prices of nondurables excluding foods dropped in February and may have entered a cyclical decline in that month. SOME REFLECTIONS ON THE INFLATIONARY PROCESS I N THE POSTWAR AMERICAN ECONOMY The reader must have been struck by the similarity of behavior of durable goods prices during the past 3 years and in 1947-48. (During the Korean war, of course, prices were under control.) In both periods these prices rose swiftly, and in both the advance accelerated in those months of the year when major wage increases went into effect, or shortly thereafter in 1947. This timing relationship is certainly not surprising. Major wage increases are likely to raise unit labor cost in the short run, although productivity increases may offset part of the effect then or later. Prices of many durable goods are administered, moreover. Where industries are sufficiently concentrated so that individual firms recognize mutual interdependence, but there is no collusion, it is advantageous to all if prices are changed infrequently and in response to clearly identifiable factors known by each firm to affect the others in about the same way. When the individual firms are also large and in the public eye, a further advantage accrues if price increases can be attributed to cost increases, even though profit margins may be maintained or augmented in the process. The magnitude of the increases cannot be explained simply by the fact that prices are administered, however. Even administered prices have to be set at some level—and at a level which is profitable to the company. This means that product demand cannot be ignored; it sets limits within which the firm must price if it is to attain profits which are satisfactory or better. By the same token, it sets limits within which costs must be held. These facts apparently are recognized by both labor and management, since the largest wage-price increases occur during periods of rising or high demand for durable 206 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH goods. (Deferred wage increases written into long-term contracts may invalidate this statement in 1958, at least with regard to wages.) The high demand for durable goods during the past 3 years cannot be dismissed from an explanation either of changes in relative prices or of inflation of the price level. Given that demand, sizable wage and price increases appeared feasible and satisfactory at expected levels of production and employment for at least one, and in some cases several years ahead. But the wage increases spread to other industries as well, although often with a lag of several months (chart 21).T Labor costs of production were thereby raised generally, but prices did not rise by the same amount everywhere (chart 16). Why not? First, although wage rates rose about equally through the economy, prices of materials did not. Many raw materials of agricultural origin were in chronic excess supply, with the result that prices were stabilized at levels governed by Federal programs and the entire cost structure of products fabricated from the materials or their substitutes was anchored. Second, relative demands differed among the several product classes. Among durables, this shows up in the fact that prices of producer goods rose more than those of consumer items, and within the latter group,, those of automobiles more than household appliances (these actually dropped at retail), despite the similarities in prices of materials and labor. As between durables and nondurables, the comparative strength of market demands is difficult to gage. The changes in wage rates and unit labor costs—whether fringe benefits and the earnings of nonproduction workers are included or excluded—have been about the same in the two divisions since the end of Korea, but the changes in prices of materials were not, and this may account for most of the contrast in the amounts of average price increase. Largely because many important industries in the division are unconcentrated and prices not administered, average prices of nondurables are rather sensitive to current market demands, so that prices do not always go up when wages do, and vice versa. This distinction rests on characteristics of market structure, however, and not on the relative strength of final demands among products. I do not wish to imply by my emphasis on demand factors that there are no significant differences between 1947-48 and 1950, on the one hand and 1955-57 on the other. For one thing, money wages of factory workers lagged the cost-of-living during the earlier intervals, whereas they moved ahead of it in the last one until 1957. In the former inflations organized labor was reacting to previous price increases and attempting to restore the real value of labor income, whereas in the latter one it was seeking to augment real income. It is this last f actt coupled with the observation that money wages have outrun belowaverage productivity increments and raised unit labor costs, that has led many observers to speak of cost-push inflation during 1956-57. There are two kinds of inflation, it is asserted: demand-pull and costpush—and it is the latter which we have recently experienced. This is misplaced emphasis. 7 Average hourly earnings rose as much or more in most of the nonmanufacturing indus~ tries for which data are available, including building construction, railroads, and trade. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 207 There are not so much two kinds of inflation as two degrees of inflation. The earlier inflationary episodes of the postwar period were more vigorous, and more widely diffused among the various sectors of the economy than the last. Prices tended everywhere to move upward in common surges. One reason for this, of course, was that market demands generally were more intensive and less easily discouraged by price increases than latterly, and this in turn was due to the powerful inflationary potential supplied by deferred demands and postwar liquidity in 1946-48 and by generalized, war-inspired expectations of physical shortages and price advances during 1950. This is not to say, however, that cost pressures and, more specifically, wage increases were unimportant in 1947-48, for they did affect the timing and size of the price waves in those years. They did so not only in the durable-goods industries, and not alone because of the fact that they raised unit labor costs, but also because key wage-price settlements affected price expectations and hence product demands generally. Demand pressures were clearly less intense in 1956-57, but that fact does not render them unimportant in the gentler inflation of those years. If one insists on a distinguishing categorization for this inflation, "bottleneck" may be more suitable than "cost-push." The former term at least carries the connotation of increased demand as well as increased cost in the sectors where prices rise strongly. It also has the virtue of emphasizing the fact that inflationary pressures may originate in particular sectors and spread to others, rather than appearing simultaneously everywhere. That, in fact, is what one must expect under normal peacetime conditions. Widely diffused, powerful surges of excess demand are easily recognizable precisely because they are abnormal. Such abnormal conditions aside, inflationary forces will tend to fan out from initial areas of disturbance. Demand may figure in two ways in the process. First, specific demands may foster individual price and wage advances and serve as inflation starters. Secondly, aggregate money demand will have to rise if prices are to increase in other sectors. If the postwar American economy does indeed have an inflationary bias—and I think that it does—it is because its institutional framework favors the initiation and propagation of inflationary impulses, and guards against their liquidation. With regard to the initiation of inflationary impulses, there is the fact that organized labor groups will press for money wage increases during periods of business expansion, since this is the variable affecting real income over which individual unions have some degree of direct control. Their success in winning wage increases will depend in part upon management estimates of the extent to which wage increases may profitably be passed on in product prices. This will mean that wage levels will tend to be determined by the increases which occur in the industries whose profit prospects are most favorable, and it is at this point that high demands for specific products become crucial in helping to set standards for wage increases. The standard-setting wage increases may or may not exceed the long-term average rate of overall productivity increase, but they are quite likely to do so for any given year and especially during years of full employment expansion. 208 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Apart from acute inflationary disturbances like price decontrol or Korea, a problem of adjustment is posed for the economy each time wages and prices go up in key industries. Confronted with the fact that over much of our basic industry wages and prices are determined at discrete intervals and set for a year or more ahead, the question is whether aggregate money demand will rise sufficiently in response to the specific increases to sustain a higher level of prices and money incomes. This question, be it noted, is the same no matter what the causes of the specific increases themselves: whether, for example, they are heavily influenced by expected demand as in 1948, or are the lagged result of bargaining decisions made 1 or more years previously, as in 1957. The additional money demand will be readily forthcoming when real demands are strong and financial constraints weak, as in 1947. Under those circumstances, increases of current money demand—including speculative inventory demand—will be large enough to raise prices in all markets and hence wage and nonwage incomes in all industries about equally. When current (as contrasted with expected) real demands are weakening, however, as in 1948 or 1957, prices in other sectors, and hence nonlabor incomes per unit of output, will not rise correspondingly. And, of course, sales may become depressed everywhere, so that total wage earnings, profits, and other variable incomes may decline even in those industries where prices went up substantially. The inflationary bias of the economy is apparent also when it comes to this question of the propagation of inflationary impulses. Our money supply is managed, and it is managed with regard to domestic stabilization objectives. This means that monetary controls will be used to curb an expansion of money expenditure under full employment conditions, and this whether aggregate demand is surging forward on a wide frontier because of powerful autonomous forces, or rising unevenly in response to the gentler prodding of demand or cost increases in specific sectors. It means also, however, that monetary (or fiscal) curbs will tend to err on the side of too little restraint, since the goal is not stable prices at any cost, but stable prices accompanied by full employment and economic growth. A distinction is sometimes drawn between demand inflation and cost inflation on the grounds that the former can be stopped at a given level of real income by eliminating excess demand, whereas even if that is done, autonomous cost increases will renew the latter type of inflation and force either a relaxation of the demand constraint or a reduction of output. I suspect that this contrast is more a property of static equilibrium models than of the dynamic economy. In the first place, one should remember that autonomous demand shifts mi£;ht also disturb a stable equilibrium if that were achieved through fiscal or monetary controls—and autonomous demand shifts occur frequently in the real w^orld. Credit controls would have to be tight indeed to prevent a price advance fosfered by new autonomous demands and financed by the activation of idle money balances. Secondly, financial constraints powerful enough to keep prices from rising under demand pressures, would almost certainly prompt a contraction of physical activity. If they did not lead directly to a downturn, they would do so indirectly by retarding or stopping the ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 209 expansion of physical activity, with adverse consequences for real inventory demand and perhaps for fixed investment as well. Such considerations argue for that cautious application of inflationary controls which is observable in practice, no matter what the origin of the inflationary pressures. Finally, our institutions and policies guard against the liquidation of inflationary pressures. Deflation brings not only lower prices but unemployment and lost production, and these are adjudged the worser evils. Instead of forcing credit deflation, the monetary authorities pursue easy money policies during contractions. Expansionary fiscal actions—increased Government spending and tax reductions—are more likely than not. Automatic stabilizers cushion the drop of income and demand. Agricultural supports slow or prevent price declines, and administered prices are preserved by company policy. General wage reductions are neither recommended nor anticipated. In short, the preponderance of public and private economic forces work directly, and in many instances deliberately, against price reductions during business contractions. Since my subject has been price behavior, I have written of inflationary bias in these paragraphs. It is readily to be seen, however, that the bias is largely a byproduct of properties of the postwar economy which most persons would agree were desirable ones. This fact should be kept in mind when judging the performance of the economy during these past years, and it should come to the forefront whenever the benefits of alternative goals and the risks of alternative policies are to be weighed. CYCLICAL CHANGES IN LABOR COST Thor Hultgren, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. The cost of producing a commodity or service puts a floor under its price. If cost rises enough to wipe out the margin of profit at a former price, suppliers will have no motive for furnishing the product to their customers at that price, and either the price will rise or the suppliers will drop out of the market. At least over short periods, however, the relation between cost and price is often very loose. If cost rises moderately, business enterprises sometimes accept a smaller profit margin, at least temporarily, instead of increasing their prices m proportion. If cost falls, they sometimes collect a larger profit margin instead of reducing their prices proportionately. The study of cost is, nevertheless, an essential component in the analysis of prices. At the National Bureau of Economic Research we have been trying to learn something about the relation between cost and the level of production in various industries, and also between cost and the general level of business activity. Costs may conveniently be divided into three classes: materials, labor, and general overhead. Labor cost is the kind on which there is most information and most of our findings pertain to it. These findings have not jet passed through the National Bureau's review procedures, and I am presenting them here on my own responsibility and not as official conclusions of the Bureau. AVAILABLE INFORMATION ON LABOR COST For the analysis of an industry's prices, the aggregate labor cost incurred in the industry is of little significance except as a starting point for calculations. The important figure is cost per unit of product. The word "cost" will be used in this latter sense in this paper. There are few if any industries for which such a figure is published as a routine statistic. Consequently it is necessary to compute such figures. To make that computation we must have figures on the aggregate labor cost as a point of departure. But we must also have figures on the physical volume of production, otherwise we cannot divide aggregate cost by product. Moreover, we need monthly figures on both, since in this particular investigation we are interested in the relations between cost and fluctuations in production or business rather than in long-run trends, and monthly figures are usually far more instructive in the study of such fluctuations. There are many industries for which we cannot get the necessary information. Either labor data, or production data, or both are lacking. We have, however, been able to assemble figures for anthracite and bituminous coal mining, quite a few although by no means all branches of manufacturing, and railroads. The several industries and the periods covered by our monthly data are shown in table 1. For railroads the figures go as far back as the middle of 1921, for some important industries 23734—58 15 211 212 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH they begin in 1932, for others there is no usable information until 1947. Labor cost per unit has two components: the number of hours paid for per unit of product turned out, and the average amount of wages paid per hour. It is instructive to consider hours per unit and labor cost separately. We have therefore computed figures on man-hours per unit of product as well as labor cost per unit of product. In general we use Bureau of Labor statistics data on labor. For many industries that Bureau publishes for a week near the middle of each month an estimate of the number of production workers, the average hours worked per week, and the average hourly earnings. Multiplying the first by the second, we get the aggregate hours worked during the middle week. TABLE 1.—Periods covered by monthly data on man-hours and labor cost per unit of product for various industries Industry Anthracite mining _ Bituminous mining Manufacturing: Meatpacking Confectionery Cigars Cotton Wool Textiles Hosiery Men's and boys' suits and coats. Women's outerwear __ Lumber _ Millwork and plywood Paper and pulp Petroleum refining Tires and tubes Cement _ Steel Iron and steel foundries Aluminum and copper mill shapes. Nonferrous foundries Railroads 1st month January 1932 January 1934 January 1932 January 1939 do. January 1932. do January 1947. January 1934January 1947. do do... do January 1932.. January 1947., January 1932.. January 1947.. January 1933. January 1932-. January 1947.. do.. do July 1921 Last month September 1955. December 1955. December 1949. May 1949. June 1955. May 1949. Do. December 1955. May 1949. December 1955. Do. Do. Do. June 1955. Do. December 1940. July 1955. June 1955. Do. December 1955. Do. Do. August 1955. From this point onward, our procedure depends on what kind of a measure of production we use. In some industries, for example anthracite, production can be measured tolerably well in terms of some simple natural unit, in this instance tons of anthracite mined. In such a case, we multiply the aggregate hours in the middle week by 4.33 to get an estimate of aggregate hours for the month, and divide that aggregate by the total production. In other industries, the diversity of products is so great that we have to use a composite index number as a measure. In that case, we construct an index number of the aggregate hours and divide it by an index number of production. For the latter, in general, we use one or another of the indexes computed by the Federal Reserve Board for various industries. Where we use a production measure in natural units, we multiply man-hours per unit by average hourly earnings to get labor cost per unit. Where we use indexes, we multiply the index of man-hours per unit by an index of average hourly earnings to get an index of labor cost per unit. In the case of railroads our labor as well as our production data come from the Interstate Commerce Commission. We measure pro- ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 213 duction in terms of traffic units, which we define as revenue ton-miles plus 2.4 times passenger-miles. The 2.4 factor is based on the average relative revenue per ton-mile and per passenger-mile over a long period of years. Finally, we adjust both the man-hours per unit figures and the labor cost per unit figures for seasonal variation. If ,man-hours per unit in a particular industry average higher in December than in the year as a whole, for example, we reduce the figures for the various Decembers. IDENTIFYING CYCLES IN PRODUCTION We likewise adjust the figures on production in each industry for seasonal variation. This enables us to determine what cycles, if any, have occurred in its production. By a cycle we mean merely an upswing followed by a downswing, or vice versa. The process can be illustrated with the help of chart 1, which depicts production in one of our industries, aluminum and copper mill shapes, for 1947 to 1955. As often happens, there are numerous minor month-to-month ups and downs in the curve. We disregard these, but try to pick out the larger swings. A helpful rule in this connection, and one that we follow, is that nothing shall be recognized as a cycle unless the up and down swing taken together last for at least 15 months. On chart 1, we find that production of mill shapes reached a peak in July 1948. After that there was a downswing, reaching a trough in May 1949. This was followed by an upswing, which reached a peak in August 1950, and so on. Asterisks indicate the dates of peaks and troughs. CHABT 1. ALUMINUM AND COPPER SHAPES : FEDERAL RESERVE INDEX OF PRODUCTION, JANUARY 1947-DECEMBER 1955 Index (19*»7-*»9«1OO) 19*»7 19*8 19*9 1950 1951 1952 1953 195*» 1955 214 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH LABOR PER UNIT OF PRODUCT OFTEN VARIES INVERSELY WITH PRODUCTION We are now in a position to learn what relation there is, if any, between man-hours per unit of product in this industry and the level of its production. Our first question is, how does man-hours per unit at each peak in production compare with man-hours per unit in the following trough, or vice versa ? In answering such a question, however, we do not like to depend on the figure for a single month. We therefore take an average of man-hours per unit in the month preceding each peak, the actual peak month, and the following month. Likewise, we take an average for each group of 3 months that has a trough month in the middle. Mill shapes is one of the industries for which we use index numbers. Computing 3-month averages, we find that the index of manhours per unit (1947-49=100) was 91.3 in the vicinity of the 1948 production peak and 116.0 in the vicinity of the 1949 trough. We conclude that in this contraction of production man-hours per unit of product increased. At the 1950 peak the figure is 94.8. In the 1949-50 upswing, therefore, man-hours per unit of product declined. So far, it looks as though man-hours per unit were inversely related to production in this industry. But we have data on only three completed contractions and only two completed expansions. This perhaps is not enough to justify a generalization about this particular industry. We do feel, however, that by pooling our data for this and other industries we obtain something more significant. In one industry or another, at one time or another, we have data on 69 expansions of production and 77 contractions. In 62, or 90 percent, of the 69 expansions, we find a net decline in man-hours per unit. In 58, or 75 percent, of the 77 contractions, there was a net rise in man-hours per unit. The pooled data suggest a strong tendency toward an inverse relation between man-hours per unit and total output. When one goes up the other goes down and vice versa. This means that man-hours in the aggregate usually do not rise and do not fall by as great a percentage as output. These results, incidentally, show the superiority of monthly over annual figures. For the same industries and the same periods of time we have, of course, annual figures on production, and we have computed annual figures on man-hours per unit. When we base our conclusions entirely on annual figures, we get a similar result in expansions but not in contractions of output. Man-hours per unit falls in 86 percent of the expansions, but also in 55 percent of the contractions instead of rising in most of them. Note, however, that the majority of declines is much smaller in contraction than in expansions. This reduced majority of declines masks an actual preponderance of rises that is disclosed by the monthly data. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 215 This comparison enables us to extend the statistical basis for our generalization about an inverse relation. There are an additional 197 expansions and 220 contractions in production for which we have nothing but annual data. Man-hours j>er unit fell, according to the annual data, in 84 percent of the expansions and, again, in 55 percent, or a much smaller majority, of the contractions. It seems likely that the small majority of declines in contractions here also masks a preponderance of rises that monthly data, if we had them for these industries and periods, would disclose. Annual figures minimize or conceal the cyclical rises in man-hours per unit because they understate the declines in production and consequently the frequently adverse influence of diminished volume, while they do not similarly understate the effect of technological improvements, which operates to reduce man-hours per unit both in expansions and in contractions. It is true that annual figures also understate the influence of expansions in volume but in that case their influence is reinforced rather than opposed by that of technology. Although such figures obscure the inverse relation between input per unit and production, there are some industries in which the relation is so strong that even annual data convincingly disclose it. We hesitate to generalize about an industry unless we have data for eight or more phases of production. (By a phase, we mean either an expansion or a contraction.) Among industries for which we have that much data (in either annual or monthly form), we find 22 with a strong inverse relation, 9 without any marked relation one way or the other, and none with a strong positive relation; i. e., none in which man-hours per unit rises and falls with volume. LABOR COST ALSO VARIES INVERSELY WITH PRODUCTION, BUT RISES MORE OFTEN We can analyze the direction of change in labor cost per unit of product in the same way that we analyze man-hours per unit. We can average the labor cost figures for the 3 months in the vicinity of each peak in an industry's output and likewise those for the 3 months in the vicinity of each trough. We can then note the direction of change during each expansion or contraction. For example, we find that the index of labor cost for mill shapes rose from 93.5 at the 1948 peak to 122.5 at the 1949 trough, then fell to 106.5 at the 1950 peak. When this is done for the 69 expansions, we find that labor cost declined from the trough of production to its peak in 41 of them, or 59 percent. There was a net rise from the peak to the trough in 70 of the 77 contractions, or 91 percent. Growing production was accompanied in most instances by falling labor cost, and diminishing production by rising labor cost. Like man-hours per unit, labor cost was inversely related to volume. 216 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH But rises in labor cost were more common than rises in man-hours per unit in both kinds of phases. In expansions, the percentage with rises is only 10 for man-hours per unit, but 41 for labor cost. In contractions the percentage with rising man-hours per unit is 75, the percentage with rising labor cost is 91. The reason for the difference is to be found in average hourly earnings. In expansions these have usually risen, and the rise has not infrequently been large enough to more than offset the fall, if any, in man-hours per unit. In the contractions for which we have monthly data, average hourly earnings often rose, although not as fast as in expansions. In some cases these rises were enough to offset the decline in man-hours per unit that did occur in a minority of contractions. The greater frequency of rises in cost than in hours per unit may not have been characteristic of earlier contractions for which we have no monthly data. During contractions of production in the neighborhood of 1920-21 or 1929-32, we know that average hourly earnings fell in many industries, and in these periods falls in labor cost may have been more common than in more recent periods. INVERSE RELATION MORE PRONOUNCED AT THE BEGINNING THAN AT THE END OF SWINGS I N PRODUCTION So far we have confined our attention to the net change in hours per unit of labor cost between the beginning and end of an upswing, or the beginning and end of a downswing in production. But their direction of change is often not continuous during the course of such an upswing or downswing. Chart 2, again for the mill shapes industry, illustrates how the course may alter. The asterisks on this chart no longer represent turning points in production itself; the latter are indicated by broken vertical lines for peaks and solid vertical lines for troughs. The asterisks here indicate peaks and troughs, and mark off cycles, in man-hours per unit. Obviously the direction of change in man-hours per unit is not always consistent throughout a phase of production. During the 1950-51 contraction in production, hours per unit at first rose, afterward fell. (As before, we ignore minor fluctuations and take note only of the longer movements marked by the asterisks.) The decline continued all through the following expansion. On the other hand, both the beginning and the end of the ]ast completed upswing in hours per unit coincide neatly with the beginning and the end of the last complete downswing in output. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 217 CHART 2. A L U M I N U M AND COPPER S H A P E S : INDEX OP MAN-HOURS P A I D FOR PER U N I T OF OUTPUT, JANUARY 1947 TO DECEMBER 1955 Index (19V7-U9-1OO) 130 1955 Broken vertical lines indicate peaks, solid vertical lines troughs in production of aluminum and copper shapes. We have graphs like chart 2 for all our industries. They enable us to classify every production phase according to the sequence of change in man-hours per unit. In the present instance we classify the 1950-51 contraction in output as a case of rise, fall, the 1951-52 expansion as a case of (continuous) fall, and the 1952-53 contraction as one of (continuous) rise. We have classified all our production phases in this manner (table 2). Man-hours per unit declined during the earliest months in a large majority of the output expansions, 58 of 69. In 23 of the 58 instances, however, the initial fall turned into a rise that persisted to the end of the expansion. Still other sequences occurred, but just before the end declines were far less common than at the beginning. Even so they somewhat outnumbered rises, by 36 to 33. 218 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Most contractions, 45 of 77, began with hours per unit rising. Of the rises, 24 were consistently maintained, 20 turned into falls that persisted. Continuous declines also were fairly common. Whatever the sequence, hours per unit were falling at the end in a majority of instances, about as large as the majority of rises in the beginning. In labor cost there was a similar contrast between the earliest and latest months of production phases. Declines were in a majority at the beginning, rises in a heavier majority at the end of expansions. Although rises preponderated at both the beginning and at the end of contractions, the preponderance was much heavier at the beginning. In both kinds of phases, however, and both at the beginning and the end, rises in cost were more frequent than rises in hours per unit. TABLE 2.—Expansions and contractions of production in various industries, classified according to sequence of change in man-hours per uint or in labor cost Number of expansions or contractions with indicated sequence of change Sequence of change In labor cost per unit In man-hours per unit Rise Rise, fall. ... Rise, fall, rise Rise, fall, rise, fall Fall.. . . . Fall, rise Fall, rise, fall _ . Fall, rise, fall, rise Fall, rise, fall, rise, fall Expansions Contractions Expansions 8 3 24 20 18 3 2 29 23 3 2 1 1 23 7 2 12 31 1 2 Contractions 38 26 1 1 8 3 All sequences 69 77 69 77 Rising at beginning _ _ Falling at beginning Rising at end Falling at end 11 58 33 36 45 32 31 46 23 46 53 16 66 11 42 35 ._ The contrary movement of production on the one hand, and hours per unit and labor cost on the other, was therefore much more conspicuous at the beginning than at the end of upswings or downswings in production. Changes can be studied in a more systematic and progressive manner by dividing each upswing or downswing into a standard number of stages regardless of its length. We define the initial, previously described, 3-month trough period of an expansion as stage I, the next peak period as V, and the terminal trough period of a contraction as stage IX. We divide the months between the actual trough month and the next peak and likewise those between each peak and the next trough into three periods, equally long if possible; if necessary we make the middle stage a month longer or shorter than the others. This procedure gives us stages II, I I I , and IV of an expansion or VI, VII, and V I I I of a contraction. We strike an average of, say, man-hours per unit for all the groups included in a stage. In effect, we break each expansion into four successive segments, the first running from I to II, the second from I I to I I I , and so forth; and we likewise break each contraction into four segments. The method is illustrated for one cycle of cement production in table 3. 219 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH The figures for man-hours per barrel on each line of the last column is an average for the months indicated on the same line in preceding columns. (This is one of the industries in which we use "natural" physical units rather than index numbers.) Sometimes an expansion is too short for this procedure; the first and last stage would include almost all the months. In such cases, we restrict stages I and V or V and I X to a single month, the actual peak or trough month. Even so, 1 of our 69 expansions and 2 of our 77 contractions are too short for the application of this method. 3.—Division of 1988-H cycle in production of cement into stages (initial trough in production, February 1988; peak, April 191$; terminal trough, May 19U) TABLE Months included 1st I III IV V VI . VII.._ VIII IX . . January 1938 March 1938 — July 1939 December 1940 _ March 1942 May 1942 January 1943 September 1943. April 1944 Last March 1938 June 1939 November 1940. March 1942 May 1942 __ December 1942__ August 1943 April 1944 June 1944 Number of Man-hours per barrel months 3 16 17 16 3 8 00 00 00 Stage 0.447 .396 .375 .363 .365 .370 .427 .526 .538 In the remaining 68 expansions and 75 contractions, we can now find out how frequent rises and falls in hours per unit were in the various segments. In table 3, for example, man-hours per barrel was 0.447 in I but only 0.396 in I I ; we therefore count the 1938-42 expansion in cement as one of the expansions in which hours per unit fell from I to II. All in all, this happened in 60 of our 68 expansions, or 88 percent of them. Similar percentages for all pairs of stages appear in table 4. We have computed stage averages and percentages for labor cost in exactly the same way; the percentages also are shown in the table. Declines in hours per unit became less and less frequent in expansions. The percentage fell from 88 percent in the first segment to 85 in the second, 74 in the third, and 66 in the fourth. In contractions, the characteristic initial rises likewise became less frequent; the successive percentages are 72, 64, 60, 49. In the case of hours per unit, however, this does not mean that the characteristic change for the phase as a whole was actually reversed in the last segment. True, the percentage of rises is a trifle below 50; but the percentage of declines is only 45; in addition there were a few instances of no change. Declines in labor cost likewise became less and less frequent from segment to segment of expansions. In fact, rises outnumbered declines in the third, and even more strongly in the fourth segment. In contractions, the progression was less regular, as the percentage of rises did not turn down until the third segment; but declines were considerably more common in the fourth than in the first. 220 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE 4.—Man-hours and labor cost per unit of product frequency of rises and falls from stage to stage of production cycles Percentage of expansions and contractions in production in which— From stage To stage Man-hours per unitRose I II II III . Ill IV IV V VI VII V . VII . VIII._ VI VIII.. IX Did not change 9 13 25 34 72 64 60 49 3 2 1 0 0 o3 6 Cost per u n i t - Fell Rose 88 85 74 66 28 36 37 45 Did not change 16 38 54 71 79 84 81 63 0 0 0 1 0 1 2 1 Fell 84 62 46 28 21 15 17 36 PRODUCTION CYCLES VERSUS BUSINESS CYCLES Everyone recognizes nowadays that there are broad upswings and downswings, that is, cycles, in economic activity at large. To go back no farther, there was a general contraction in 1953-54, followed by an upswing that now appears to have ended in 1957. At the moment of writing, we are in another downswing, although just how far along in it we do not yet know. But production in a single industry often follows a different course from that of general business activity. A particular kind of output frequently declines during at least part of a business expansion and rises during at least part of a business contraction. From some points of view, it may be more interesting to compare the changes in hours per unit or labor cost between turning points in aggregate business rather than between turning points in each industry's own production. The National Bureau has worked out a chronology of turning points, and therefore cycles, in business at large, which we may use for this purpose. This means that from here on we no longer compare man-hours per barrel of cement around February 1938 with manhours per barrel around April 1942 (see table 3); instead, for example, we compare man-hours per barrel around May 1938 with man-hours per barrel around February1 1945; these dates are the trough and peak of a business expansion. We have hours per unit and labor cost data for these 2 dates in 10 industries, giving us 10 observations in that business phase. In one business expansion or another and one industry or another, we have 51 observations altogether. We have 61 observations for business contractions. The expansions represented are 1933-37, 1938-45, 1945-48, and 1949-53. The contractions are 1937-38,1945-45,1948-49, and 1953-54. FALLING MAN-HOURS PER UNIT MORE COMMON I N BUSINESS EXPANSIONS THAN I N BUSINESS CONTRACTIONS In 39 of the 51 observations for business expansions, or 76 percent, there was a net decline in hours per unit from the business trough 1 The 1938 date has been revised to June; but to keep our work consistent with other studies we use the old date. The effect on our conclusions is negligible. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 221 to the business peak. In this respect, business expansions resembled production expansions. But in 41 percent of the 61 observations for business contractions or 67 percent, we also find a net decline in hours per unit. In production contractions, on the contrary, there was a majority of rises. The only distinction we can make between business expansions and business contractions is that declines in hours per unit are even more frequent in the former than in the latter. The explanation of the difference between downswings in business and downswings in production is similar to one we have already discussed in other connection. When an industry's contractions fail to coincide with those in business, declines in production measured between business dates are smaller percentagewise than declines measured between production dates. Any adverse effect of diminishing volume is correspondingly minimized, while the contrary effect of any technological improvements is not correspondingly minimized. Consequently, an industry may have a less efficient labor-to-product ratio at the trough than at the preceding peak in its production, and still have a more efficient ratio at a business trough than at the preceding business peak. LABOR COST RISES AND FALLS WITH BUSINESS In the case of labor cost there is a much more striking difference than in the case of hours per unit. In 41, or 80 percent, of our 51 observations for business upswings, labor cost increased. In 35, or 57 percent, of our 61 observations for business downswings, labor cost diminished. In other words, cost appears to be positively related to the level of business activity, whereas it is inversely related to the level of production in the several industries. In the case of upswings, the explanation is connected with the fact that the production expansions were on the average a good deal shorter than the business expansions. At the beginning of the 1933-37 business expansion, the recovery from the banking holiday, and the imminence of the blue eagle and NBA, seem to have stimulated a vigorous wave of buying and production. For many industries the rise proved to be temporary, although a good number had a second upswing after an intervening decline in production. In the 1938-45 business upswing, the construction phase of the war effort reached a comparatively early climax. This meant an early downswing for industries heavily dependent on construction. Manpower shortages apparently caused such a decline in others. In the 1949-53 business expansion, the Korean crisis caused a tremendous upswing in demand from consumers and from business itself; but as inventories accumulated this receded and presently restrictions on materials also limited production in some industries. Consequently there were a number of contractions in production, more or less in the middle of the business upswing, often followed by renewed rises in output during its later stretches. The difference in length is important because the cumulative effect of rising average hourly earnings on cost is greater over the longer periods; in many cases it preponderated over whatever net rise in the scale of production occurred over the same periods. In business contractions, as already noted, technological progress tends to predominate over diminishing volume, bringing about a net fall in hours per unit, while average hourly earnings do not rise as 222 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH vigorously as in business expansions, if they rise at all. The net result was the rather narrow majority of declines in labor cost. FALLING MAN-HOURS PER UNIT MOST FREQUENT I N EARLY BUSINESS EXPANSION AND LATE BUSINESS CONTRACTION Business cycles, like those in production, can be divided into stages on the plan previously described. The 3-month periods in the vicinity of business troughs and peaks become stages I, V, or IX. Intermediate months in a business expansion are grouped into stages II, I I I , and IV, those in a business contraction into VI, VII, and VIII. We can compute averages of hours per unit or cost for each of these for any industries for which we have data covering a business phase. In that phase the stages will refer to the same time periods for all industries. In each phase, we get a number of observations of change between each pair of stages equal to the number of industries. In all four of the business expansions covered, in one industry or another, we get the same number of observations for each pair of stages as for net change over the phase, namely 51. Similarly, we have 61 observations for each pair of contraction stages. As in production expansions, declines in man-hours per unit are very common in the first segment of business expansion and become less numerous thereafter (table 5). There is a slight increase in frequency, however, in the last segment. In contractions of business, as in production contractions, declines in hours per unit are comparatively infrequent in the first segment but become more and more frequent thereafter. In our data, they outnumber rises in the last three segments. DECLINES I N LABOR COST SOMEWHAT SIMILARLY DISTRIBUTED The frequency of rises in labor cost does not increase at all consistently from segment to segment (table 5). They were most numerous in the second segment, next most common in the fourth. The pattern is largely influenced by the peculiar history of average hourly earnings in the 1933-37 expansion. The blue eagle and NRA brought widespread increases in hourly pay; these tended to raise labor cost between I I and I I I . Another round of sharp increases in wage rates tended to boost cost between IV and V. Taking all the observations for all four expansions together, however, the first segment was the only one in which declines in cost predominated over rises. The net declines in labor cost during business contractions were concentrated in the last two segments; it was only in these that declines exceeded increases in number. 223 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE 5.—Man-hours and labor cost per unit of product frequency of rises and falls from stage to stage of business cycles Percentage of observations in which— From stage To stage Man-hours per u n i t Rose I II II III IV V VI vVI III VII VIII IV.._ VII . VIII-. IX 22 33 39 37 54 48 30 30 Did not change 2 0 0 0 2 1 4 0 Labor cost— Fell Rose 76 67 61 63 44 51 66 70 43 86 69 76 62 56 28 36 Did not change 0 0 0 0 2 0 2 0 Fell 57 14 31 24 36 44 70 64 T E C H N O L O G I C A L PROGRESS M I N I M I Z E S C Y C L I C A L R I S E S I N COST In the foregoing discussion a complicating influence, that of technological progress, has been mentioned incidentally. I t deserves a more emphatic recognition. Technological improvements tend to reduce man-hours per unit not only in expansions but in contractions. If it were not for such improvements, declines in hours per unit would not be as frequent as they are in expansions of output, while rises would be even more frequent than they are in contractions. Even in an industry that clearly has an inverse relation between hours per unit and output, technological improvements enable the industry to reduce hours per unit in some contractions. Technical advances likewise maximize the frequency of decline in cost and minimize the frequency of rises in cost. The influence of technology on labor cost reenforces the usual influence of expanding volume and, mostly, to be sure, at other times, the influence of declining hourly earnings; it opposes the usual influence of contracting volume and the influence of rising hourly earnings. MEANING AND LIMITATIONS OF THE COST DATA If we were dealing in each industry with the production of one homogeneous commodity, changes in total cost (labor, materials, and overhead) per unit would necessarily be reflected either in proportionate changes in the average price received by the industry or in altered margins of profit. With a single product, if total cost per unit rises, and the price does not rise by as great a percentage, the margin narrows; if price rises by a greater percentage, the margin widens in spite of the rise in cost. If cost falls, and the price does not fall in proportion, the margin widens; if price declines by an even greater percentage, the margin narrows in spite of the fall in cost. We have presented data for labor cost only. In fact they do not include all of that, for administrative, general supervisory, and central office labor is not included. Total cost no doubt often fluctuates by different percentages than labor cost and may at times move in the opposite direction. Even if the data represented total cost, they would still not pertain m any instance, except perhaps cement, to an industry with a vir- 224 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH tually homogeneous product. Where the product is complex, changes in total cost, based on the measures of production we are obliged to use, might understate or overstate the percentage by which prices would have to be raised or lowered to preserve an initial margin of profit. If the production of high quality coal rises faster than that of all coal, for example, the mining companies, without changing the price of any quality, will collect more revenue per ton of all coal, and hence if cost per ton rises, prices will not have to rise in proportion, and yet the original margin could be preserved. In more serious cases we try to minimize the difficulty by using composite indexes of output. But while those indexes are based in principle on value at constant prices, they do not pretend to reflect the full complexity of pricing. An extremely detailed measure of production, completely reflecting that complexity, might rise or fall from time to time by a greater percentage than the available index. Use of the latter would at such times overstate or understate the size of the adjustment in prices needed to preserve the initial margin. TRENDS IN PRODUCT PRICES, FACTOR PRICES, AND PRODUCTIVITY John W. Kendrick, The George Washington University and National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. This paper is based on estimates of product prices, factor prices, and productivity in the private domestic economy for selected years of high-level economic activity since 1919. The estimates make possible an analytic description of the trends and interrelationships of these variables and of related variables such as the real income per unit of factor input in comparison with productivity, and the changing factor shares of the national income as a result of divergent price and quantity movements of labor and capital inputs. The interrelationships described by the time series are based on identities, and by themselves do not reveal the mechanism by which prices change. They do provide part of the background required for analysis of the mechanism, and some interpretation is given in the paper, but this study is intended primarily to provide one of the key pieces of the mosaic to be built up by all the contributions to these hearings. The estimates on which the analysis is based were prepared by the author in connection with a study for the National Bureau of Economic Research of productivity trends in the United States since the late 19th century. The sources of the estimates will be described in detail in the National Bureau study; a very brief description is appended to this paper. The bulk of the paper is drawn from a preliminary draft of one of the chapters in the Bureau study, but the draft has not been reviewed byn*/vtheVXXXD board of directors of the I/IAO \JLM.a>±v iiao n u yet t j "-f^xi IOVIOVVDU KJ\J<XI.\JL K/JL KXXI. CA;iuia " assumes full " responsibility for the National Bureau, and"" the author here. estimates and his interpretation of their meaning presented he C U l THE TOTAL, FACTOR PRODUCTIVITY CONCEPT AND MEASURE Since the measures of real product and of real factor inputs are basic to the subsequent analysis, and since the concept of "total factor productivity" differs from the more usual "output per man-hour" partial productivity measure, a few words as to underlying concepts and methods are in order. Total factor productivity is defined as the ratio of the physical volume of final output to the physical volume of labor and capital inputs, the units of the various types of output and of input weighted together by their base period unit values. Labor input is measured in terms of the man-hours worked in the various industry groupings, weighted together by base period average hourly earnings. Capital input is assumed to move proportionately with the constant dollar value of the net stock of real capital available for use (land, inventories, and plant and equipment net of depreciation); indexes of real 225 226 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH net capital stock in various industry groupings are combined by baseperiod capital compensation in each. Total factor productivity differs from the conventional "output per man-hour" measures in two respects: (1) Since man-hours employed in each of about 40 industry groups are weighted by base-period average hourly labor compensation, shifts in relative man-hours employed from lower-to-higherpaying industry groups result in a greater relative increase in the weighted "labor input" series than in unweighted man-hours, but do not influence the aggregate productivity measure which is in effect a weighted average of productivity indexes of the component industries; (2) since capital input is counted in the input denominator along with labor input, increases in output per unit of labor input that result from substitution of capital for labor do not show up as changes in productive efficiency; only if final output increases in relation to both corresponding factor inputs can we say that there has been a net1 saving of inputs or cost elements, and thus an increase in productivity. To illustrate the difference in movement of the several conceptually different productivity ratios, as well as to provide background for the later analysis, consider the following average annual percentage rates of change for the period 1919-53. This period is used since the trend rate of increase in total factor productivity in the private domestic economy has been significantly higher than it was in the decades preceding World War I. The average annual rate of increase in real product per man-hour was approximately 2.5 percent, compared with a 2.3 percent rate of increase in real product per unit of labor input (weighted man-hours) ; the 0.2 percentage point difference represents the effect on labor input of shifts from lower-paying to higher-paying industries. The difference between the 2.3 and 2.1 percent average annual rates of increase in real product per unit of labor input and in total factor productivity, respectively, reflects the net effect of substitution of capital for labor over the period. PRODUCTIVITY AND THE PRICES OF PRODUCTS AND FACTORS The general level of prices of the final goods and services produced by the economy must increase to a lesser extent than the average prices of the productive factors (or decline more) in proportion to advances in factor productivity. Increasing productivity means that the quantity of inputs used per unit of output declines, and this decline in unit factor requirements provides an offset against rising factor prices in like degree. Productivity gains thus act as a cushion whereby rising factor prices are reflected to a lesser extent in final product prices; or if factor prices decline, productivity advances are associated with a proportionally greater decline in product prices. The relationship among the three variables may be stated precisely if the terms are appropriately defined. Factor price is the weighted unit compensation of the factor services, obtained by dividing national income (which is the sum of factor cost or compensation) by the sum of real labor and capital inputs (see table 1). The average unit compensation of labor is the compensation per man-hour in the various industries combined by variable man-hour weights. The 1 For further discussion of concept, see John W. Kendrick, Productivity Trends: Capital and Labor, Occasional Paper No. 53 (National Bureau of Economic Research, 1956). 227 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH average unit compensation of capital is, in effect, the product of prices of capital goods and the rate of return on capital (including profit) in the several industries, combined by variable capital input weights. Operationally, the average price of each factor class is obtained as a quotient of the total compensation of each divided by the corresponding aggregate real input measure (see table 2a). TABLE 1.—Private domestic economy—Factor prices, product prices, and productivity Net domestic product at factor cost Current dollars 1929 dollars (1) (2) Factor Factor producinput tivity 1929 index dollars * )) (3) (4) Average price Factors index Products index (5) (6) D+() A. Millions of dollars and index numbers, 1929=100 60,848 82,669 66,433 203,191 268,946 1919. 1929. 1937. 1948. 1953. 56,711 82,669 84,157 135,991 168,562 70,207 82,669 73,720 92,827 102,739 80.8 100.0 114.2 146.5 164.1 86.7 100.0 90.1 218.9 261.8 107.3 100.0 78.9 149.4 159.5 115.3 90.1 243.0 119.6 302.0 93.2 78.9 187.4 106.8 148.6 B. Link relatives 135.9 80.4 305.9 132.4 442.0 1929/19. 1937/29. 1948/37. 1953/48. 1953/19. 145.8 101.8 161.6 124.0 297.2 117.8 89.2 125.9 110.7 146.3 123.8 114.2 128.3 112.0 203.1 O. Average annual rates of change (percentages) 3.8 .2 4.5 4.4 3.3 3.1 -2.7 10.7 5.6 4.5 1929/19. 1937/29. 1948/37. 1953/48. 1953/19. 2.2 1.7 2.3 2.3 2.1 1.7 -1.4 2.1 2.1 1.1 1.4 -1.3 8.4 3.6 3.3 -0.7 -2.9 6.0 1.3 1.2 i Factor input here is derived as the sum of labor and capital inputs in absolute terms. It differs slightly from an index which represents a variable weighted average of indexes of labor and capital inputs. NOTE.—Table,may not be internally consistent due to rounding, Indicated derivations apply to sec. C only if 100 percent is added to the percentage rates of change. TABLE 2a.—Private domestic economy—Average factor prices: Labor and capital [Millions of dollars and index numbers, 1929=100] Labor cost 1919 1929 1937 1948 1953 _ __ Current dollars 1929 dollars Average price of labor index (D + (2) (1) (2) (3) 43,814 59, 749 52,400 154, 769 213,145 51,802 59, 749 52, 221 66,859 70, 743 84.6 100.0 100.4 231.5 301.3 Capital cost Current dollars 1929 dollars Average price of capital index (4)+ (5) (4) (5) (6) 17,034 22,920 14,033 48, 422 55, 801 18,405 22,920 21,499 25,968 31,996 92.6 100.0 65.3 186.5 174.4 In order to obtain an index of final product prices consistent with the factor price measure, it is necessary to compute the quotient of net 23734—58 228 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH private domestic product at factor cost in current prices and in constant prices. As a "net" measure, the implicit price deflator accords a smaller weight to the prices of capital goods than would price deflators of gross product, since capital outlays required to offset capital consumption are excluded. As a measure of the average prices of national product "at factor cost," the effect of indirect business taxes on market price is eliminated. In practice, it is obtained by dividing national income by real net product at factor cost. The latter variable is gotten by extrapolating base-period income by the index of real net product, since the deflated net product at factor cost should show2 virtually the same movement as deflated net product at market price. Now, net national product at factor cost equals national income (Y); when divided by real product as defined (O), a measure of average product price is obtained ( P o ) ; when divided by an index of real factor input (I), a measure of average factor price is obtained ( P ^ . The following equation demonstrates that average product price is the quotient of average factor price and productivity (T=O/I); In table 1, the values of these variables have been entered for key years beginning with 1919. Over the period 1919-53, factor price has risen at an average rate of 3.3 percent a year, productivity by 2.1 percent, and the product price level by 1.2 percent. Thus, productivity advance has mitigated the effect of increasing money demand on factor price by approximately two-thirds. The importance of the cushion provided by productivity against the impact of inflation may be realized more vividly in terms of the aggregate percent changes over the 34 years. If productivity had not grown at all, and all other things had been the same, prices would have tripled—which is what happened to factor price. But actually, productivity doubled, which reduced the price increase to 50 percent. These changes were the net result of divergent tendencies over the several subperiods. In the first decade shown in the table, 1919-29, product prices actually dropped somewhat, despite a 15-percent rise in factor price, as a consequence of the accelerated rate of productivity advance that set in around the end of World War I. Between 1929 and 1937, in the absence of full recovery from the great depression, factor price was 10 percent lower in 1937 than in 1929, but product price was more than 20 percent lower due to the continued, although 2 Cf. John W. Kendrick, The Estimation of Real National Product, Studies in Income and Wealth, vol. 22, N. B. E. R. The implicit price deflators for the net product at factor cost and at market prices do not diverge substantially over the period, as shown below: Implicit price deflators for net private domestic product [Index numbers, 1929=100] At market price 1919 1929 1937 1948 1953 _. __ _.. 108.3 100.0 82.2 144.3 159.1 At factor cost 107.3 100.0 78.9 149.4 159.5 Ratio (l)+(2) 100.9 100.0 104.2 96.6 99.7 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 229 somewhat retarded, advance in productivity. With the wartime and postwar inflationary pressures, unit factor price in 1953 stood almost 3 times higher than the 1937 level, while the product price level had doubled. Continued strong productivity gains had cushioned the effect on prices of monetary inflation, which was accentuated by continuous rounds of wage increases in the postwar period. But it is clear that the magic of technological advance alone cannot prevent significant price rises in the face of major inflationary pressures. At least the 1.3 percent average annual rate of increase in product prices 1948-53 is far lower than the 6 percent rate over the preceding decade. The 1.3 percent rate is close to the long-term rate, and more recent figures indicate that approximately the same rate prevailed from 1953 to 1956. The rate would have been lower in the last 3 years except for an apparent slowing of productivity advance. On the other hand, the rate of advance in factor prices also slowed—a condition not likely to prevail indefinitely for reasons we shall go into in the next section which deals with the individual factor prices. RELATIVE CHANGES I N FACTOR PRICES The index of total factor prices is a composite of the prices of the various component types of factors. Each individual factor price may have changed by more or less than the weighted average of all. Average hourly labor compensation has changed in somewhat different proportions in the various occupational or industry groupings; and unit capital compensation has varied among the several industries. But the interindustry structures of wage rates and of unit capital compensation have been relatively stable over time in contrast to the marked difference in movement between the prices of the two major factor classes, labor and capital. Between 1919 and 1953, average hourly labor compensation increased at an average annual rate of 3.8 percent a year—almost double the 1.9 percent average increase in the price of capital. Over the 34 years, these average rates of increase were associated with a 256 percent increase in labor rates compared with an 88 percent rise in unit capital compensation. Reflecting the heavier weight of unit labor compensation, total factor compensation per unit rose by 200 percent over the period, which reduces to the average annual gain of 3.3 percent. It will be noted that the 1.9 percent average annual increase in the price of capital was somewhat higher than the rate of increase in average product prices generally. Since there was little trend in the rate of return on capital, the explanation lies primarily in a somewhat faster rise in the prices of capital goods, as measured, than in the prices of other final products. Insofar as the quality of capital goods increased more than the quality of other goods, the differential price movement is overstated but cannot be quantitatively adjusted for. During the first decade 1919-29, total factor price rose by 1.4 percent a year—less than half its rate of increase over the whole period. But the average increase in wage rates of 1.7 percent was twice the average increase in the price of capital, as was true for the longer period. Between 1929 and the submerged peak of 1937, wage rates were barely able to hold their own, while the price of capital declined 230 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH substantially as a result of the incomplete recovery from the great depression. The next subperiod, 1937-48, was the only one in which the rate of increase in the price of capital exceeded that in the price of labor—10 as compared with 8 percent a year—due both to the low 1937 base and to the postwar shortage of capital still prevailing at the high 1948 peak. The relationship during this period also reflects the high degree of monetary inflation accompanying the war and continuing well into the postwar period. The relationship between factor prices reversed completely in the following period. Between 1948 and 1953, while the rate of increase in wage rates slowed somewhat to a 5.5 percent annual average, the price of capital actually declined. Here, it would seem inflationary pressure tended to originate on the labor cost side, with mild restraint on the part of the monetary authorities in the latter half of the period resulting in some squeeze on profits. Rough estimates for the period 1953-56 point to a continuation of the same basic situation. Wage rates rose by more than 4 percent a year on average, while a further squeezing of the rate of return on capital more than offset small increases in the price of capital goods and produced a 2 percent average annual decline in the price of capital. Despite the decline in the rate of return on capital in the postwar period, the return was still sufficient to induce a volume of new investment consistent with relatively full employment. But it is obvious that the rate of return cannot continuously decline and still produce sufficient investment demand. Assuming an eventual leveling or rising rate of return on capital, and the same rates of increase in wage rates and productivity as have prevailed in the postwar period, the rate of increase in final product prices would accelerate as unit factor costs, following the current contractions, rise in greater degree than in the period 1948-57. Forces behind relative factor price changes Whatever the rise in unit factor costs, it may be expected that wage rates will rise faster than the price of capital in the future as in the past. In the past, this relative movement has resulted in the labor share of productivity gains and of the national income rising. So it is worth pausing to consider some of the reasons for a relative increase in the price of labor. The variables determining relative price movements of the factors are complex, but two major influences stand out—one relating to the rate of return on capital and the other to the prices of capital goods, the product of which is the price of capital as we define and measure it. With respect to the first influence, the statistics show that net capital formation has been high enough secularly in this country to result in a significantly greater increase in real capital stocks and services than in the labor force and man-hours worked. The law of diminishing marginal productivity tells us that under these circumstances, and in the absence of technological advance, the rate of return on capital would decline both absolutely and in relation to the wage rate. Actually, technological advance has shifted the factor demand curves upward so that there has been no pronounced trend in the rate of return to capital, while real wage rates have risen. 231 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH The second influence relates to the prices of capital goods. Increasing productivity in the capital goods industries as in the economy generally means that capital goods prices fall in relation to wage rates (increase less), assuming relatively full employment and competitive conditions which tend to cause prices to approximate the cost of production per unit, and result in labor being paid in accordance with its (rising) marginal productivity. Since there has been no corresponding offset in a rising rate of return on capital over the long run, the decline in capital goods prices relative to wage rateg is a built-in factor in dynamic economies that promotes the substitution of capital for labor. TABLE 2b.—Private domestic economy—Relative factor prices Price per unit of factor input Year Labor (1) R e l a t i v e factor prices, reciprocal ratios Capital Total Labor to capital (D-K2) Capital to labor (2)-KD (2) (3) (4) (5) A. Index numbers, 1929=100 1919 1929 1937 1948 1953 .. 84.6 100.0 100.4 231.5 301.3 92.6 100.0 65.3 186.5 174.4 86.7 100.0 90.1 218.9 261.8 91.4 100.0 153.8 124.1 172.8 109.4 100.0 65.0 80.6 57.9 109.4 153.8 80.7 139.2 189.1 91.4 65.0 124.0 71.8 52.9 B. Link relatives 1929/19... 1937/29... 1948/37.... 1953/48— 1953/19— 118.2 100.4 230.6 130.2 356.1 108.0 65.3 285.6 93.5 188.3 115.3 90.1 243.0 119.6 302.0 C. Average annual rates of change (percentages) 1929/19... 1937/29__ 1948/37... 1953/48. _. 1953/19... 1.7 .1 7.9 5.4 3.8 0.8 -5.2 10.0 -1.3 1.9 1.4 -1.3 8.4 3.6 3.3 0.9 5.5 -1.9 6.8 1.9 -0.9 -5.2 2.0 -6.4 -1.9 NOTE.—Table may not be internally consistent due to rounding. The quotients in cols. (4) and (5) of part O are derived as indicated only when 100.0 percent is added to the average annual rates of change..1 232 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE 3.—Private domestic economy—Factor shares of national income in current and constant dollars Percent distribution of realfactor cost in 1929 prices Relative factor prices i (1929=100) Year 1919 1929 1937 1948 1953 . Percent distribution of national income in current prices Labor Capital Labor Capital Labor d)X(3) Capital (2)X(4) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) 97.6 100.0 111 4 105.8 115.1 106.8 100.0 72.5 85.2 66.6 73.8 72.3 70.8 72.0 68.9 26.2 27.7 29.2 28.0 31.1 72.0 72.3 78.9 76.2 79.3 28.0 27.7 21.1 23.8 20.7 i Index of ratios of individual factor prices to total factor price (see table 2b). NOTE.—Table may not be internally consistent due to rounding. On the demand side, it is conceivable that inventions might be sufficiently labor saving (that is, require increasing quantities of capital relative to labor, given constant relative factor prices) to cause the demand for capital to increase more rapidly than the demand for labor. But if this has been the case (as distinguished from the substitution of capital for labor as a result of changing relative factor prices), it has not been a strong enough tendency to offset the effect on relative price of the greater increases in the supply of capital than of labor— since the estimates show that wage rates have consistently risen relative to the price of capital in all periods when capital per unit of labor was rising. Factor shares in national income The national income accruing to each factor is the product of the quantity employed and its price (unit cost). Aggregate national income is the sum of the compensations of all the factors. Thus, the share of each factor in total national income will vary in accordance with the net effect of changes in the quantity of the factor employed relative to total input, and the price of the factor relative to average factor price. It was apparent in table 2b that the input of capital rose substantially relative to labor input between 1919 and 1953, and in all subperiods except 1937-48. The ratio of capital to labor input went up by 27 percent over the whole period. As a ratio to total factor input, the increase was only 7 percent—since the marginal rate of substitution of capital for labor was more than 3:1 based on the average weights accorded the two factors over the period. The ratios of the input of each factor to total factor input is shown in the first two columns of table 3. From 1919 to 1953, the ratio of labor to total factor input declined from 74 to 69 percent. But the decline in relative labor input was associated with a more than proportional increase in the price of labor services relative to total factor price. The 18 percent increase in this ratio (derived from the data of table 2 and shown in the third and fourth columns of table 3), is less than the 89 percent increase in the ratio of the price of labor to that of capital alone, again because of the much higher weight of labor. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 233 Only in the subperiod 1937-48 did the relative price of labor decline. But in all subperiods, the relative prices and relative inputs of the two factors moved inversely. It is clear that it was through relative price movements that the different rates of supply of the two factors were absorbed into the productive system. That is, cost economies were achieved by producers in substituting the factor that was becoming relatively cheaper for the one that was growing dearer as a result of changing relative supplies. Over the period as a whole, the ratio of the percent change in relative factor prices to the percentage change in relative factor inputs was — 0.24. The coefficient of substitution varied considerably among the subperiods, however. The last two columns of table 3 show the net effect on income shares of the inverse movement of relative factor inputs and prices. Since the decline in the relative input of labor was significantly smaller than the increase in relative labor price, the share of labor increased from 71 percent in 1919 to 79 percent in 1953. The same percentages may be calculated directly from table 2. Only in subperiod 1937-48 did labor's share in the national income temporarily decline due to the peculiar circumstances described earlier. This implies that in all subperiods except 1937-48, and over the long period, labor received a significantly larger share of the productivity increment to real income (product) than its share of total income at the beginning of each period. RELATIVE CHANGES I N REAL FACTOR COMPENSATION PER UNIT Once the prices of the factors have been calculated, it is easy to compute the real earnings per unit of each of the factor inputs. This involves dividing the factor prices (i. e., the current dollar compensation per unit) by an index of the prices of products for which factor incomes are spent, directly or indirectly. For that index, we use the implicit price deflator for the net domestic product at factor cost. This index is composed of the prices of new capital goods and goods purchased by Government, as well as consumer goods, although consumer goods have by far the largest weight. It could be argued that labor income is distributed in a somewhat different way among these types of goods (i. e., as among spending, saving, and taxes) than is the income accruing to capital, and that to measure the purchasing power of the different types of unit compensation different price indexes should be employed with weights based on the patterns of spending out of each type of income. But both types of income are used for all the major types of final product, and it is statistically impossible to relate patterns of spending to type of factor income since most spending units do not receive a pure form of either. In any case, the results using a different deflator would not differ substantially. Over the long period 1919-53, the consumers' price index increased by only a few percent less than our deflator.3 The results of deflating current dollar unit factor compensation by product price is shown in table 4a in index number form. Since average hourly earnings had increased substantially more than average compensation per unit of capital, it follows that the real increase in the former would also be greater. But price deflation accentuates 3 Conceptually, a market price index would be preferable to our index at factor cost, but the differences between the two are minor and our index has the advantage of permitting precise definition of the relationships between productivity, prices, and unit factor costs. 234 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH the differential movement: between the years 1919 and 1953, real average labor earnings increased by almost 150 percent, more than 4 times as much as the 35-percent increase in real compensation per unit of capital. The gams in real unit compensation of each factor may be compared with the gain in productivity, which is also the gain ill real income per composite unit of factor input. (See table 4b.) The proportionate gain in real average hourly earnings of labor was onefourth greater than the proportionate increase in total factor productivity over the period (although about equal to the rate of gain in real product per man-hour). The proportional gain in real unit compensation of capital was only about one-fourth of the total productivity increase. The marked difference between the increases in real unit earnings of the two factors and the productivity increases is explained by the differential movement in the prices of the two factors. (See table 4b.) The price of capital fell by around 38 percent relative to composite unit factor price, and it was this relative decline that caused the real earnings per unit of capital to rise less than productivity and, conversely, made it possible for the real average earnings of labor to rise substantially more than the proportionate increase in productivity. TABLE 4a.—Private domestic economy—Real factor income per unit [Index numbers, 1929=100] Current income per unit (factor price) 1919 1929 1937 1948 . 1953 - . Labor Capital (1) (2) 84.6 100.0 100.4 231.5 301.3 92.6 100.0 65.3 186.5 174.4 Average product price (3) 107.3 100.0 78.9 149.4 159.5 Real income per unit Labor Capital (2)-f(3) (4) (5) 78.8 100.0 127.2 155.0 188.9 86.3 100.0 82.8 124.8 109.3 235 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE 4&.—Private domestic economy—Productivity and real factor income per unit Year Relative factor prices Productivity Real income per unit Labor Capital Labor (DX(2) Capital (DX(3) (2) (3) (4) (5) (1) A. Index number, 1929=100 1919.-1929.— 1937.-1948.... 1953-... 80.8 100.0 114.2 146.5 164.1 97.6 100.0 111.4 105.8 115.1 106.8 100.0 72.5 85.2 66.6 78.8 100.0 127.2 155.0 188.9 86.3 100.0 82.8 124.8 109.3 126.9 127.2 121.9 121.9 239.7 115.9 82.8 150.7 87.6 126.7 B. Link relatives 1929/19. 1937/29. 1948/371953/48. 1953/19. 123.8 114.2 128.3 112.0 203.1 102.5 111.4 95.0 108.8 117.9 93.6 72.5 117.5 78.2 62.4 C. Average annual rates of change (percentages) 1929/191937/291948/371953/48. 1953/19- 2.2 1.7 2.3 2.3 2.1 0.2 1.4 -.5 1.7 .5 -0.7 -3.9 1.5 -4.8 -1.4 2.4 3.1 1.8 4.0 2.6 1.5 -2.3 3.8 -2.6 .7 NOTE.—Table may not be internally consistent due to rounding. So long as capital increases more rapidly than labor, input and the price of capital rises less rapidly than wage rates, it is apparent that wage rates can rise somewhat faster than total factor productivity and still be consistent with a stable product price level. Beyond a point, however, increases in wage rates are associated with price inflation, if the monetary authorities accommodate the rise of unit costs. This historical survey indicates, at least roughly, where that point lies. TECHNICAL NOTE The estimates of real private product since 1929 are those published by the United States Department of Commerce (National Income, 1954 edition, a supplement to the Survey of Current Business, as revised) carried back to 1919 by estimates of the common components by Prof. Simon Kuznets supplemented by our own estimates of Government purchases of goods and services from private industry, based on Treasury Department and Census Bureau data for Federal and for State and local purchases, respectively. 236 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH The nonfarm employment estimates from 1929 forward are also those published by the Commerce Department inclusive or proprietors, supplemented to include unpaid family workers as estimated by the Census Bureau. The estimates of farm employment, including unpaid family workers, are those of the Department of Agriculture back to 1919. Nonfarm employment was extrapolated from 1929 to 1919 by estimates based largely on Census Bureau sources, and contained for the most part in various studies of output, employment, and labor force published by the National Bureau of Economic Eesearch. The estimates of average hours worked per week in private nonfarm industries needed in conjunction with employment to estimate manhours worked, are largely those of the Department of Labor and the Census Bureau. Farm man-hour estimates of the Department of Agriculture were used with a level adjustment. In establishing levels for some of the nonfarm industries in the early part of the period, use was also made of estimates for the years 1920-22 based on sample surveys by W. I. King for the National Bureau of Economic Eesearch. The estimates of real net capital stocks in the private nonfarm, nonresidential sector are largely those prepared by Raymond Goldsmith and published in A Study of Saving in the United States, volume 3 (Princeton University Press, 1955), subsequently revised and extended since 1945 by Mr. Goldsmith. The estimates of real farm capital are chiefly those prepared by Alvin S. Tostlebe, Capital in Agriculture: Its Formation and Financing Since 1870 (Princeton University Press for the National Bureau of Economic Research, 1957). Estimates of the real net stock of nonfarm residential real estate are based on those contained in the volume by Leo Grebler, David M. Blank and Louis Winnick, Capital Formation in Residential Real Estate (Princeton University Press for the NBER, 1956). The national income estimates, used both as a basis for weighting the factor inputs by type and by industry, and for computation of the compensation per unit of factor input by type, are those published by the Department of Commerce since 1929. They were extended back to 1919 largely by the estimates of Professor Kuznets, National Income and Its Composition, 1919-38, adjusted for consistency with our employment estimates. The net income of proprietors was separated into labor and capital components by imputing the average annual compensation of employees in each industry group to the proprietors. The sum of the imputed labor income of proprietors plus wages, salaries, and supplements make up total labor compensation; the rest of national income equals capital compensation and comprises interest, net rents, and royalties, and profits. IV INTERRELATIONSHIPS AMONG PRICES, DEMANDS, AND COSTS 237 IV. Interrelationships among prices, demands, and costs A. General price movements. 1. Under what circumstances can we expect general price movements—inflation or deflation—to originate in an excess of demand over the supply forthcoming at constant prices? To originate in changes in unit costs? Can a cost-push price movement continue to operate in the absence of an "excess demand situation" ? If so, then for how long, and under what conditions ? 2. Accepting relative price movements as proper and necessary under a dynamic economy, will a change in relative prices induce more general price movements—i. e., are there any individual products or services so important to the economy as a whole that changes in their prices are necessarily followed by widespread changes in prices of other products and services ? In other words, should policies for the control of inflation or deflation be substantially concerned with influencing prices of certain particular goods or services ? 3. To what extent do general price-level changes tend to feed upon themselves, with accelerating or cumulative movements away from a stabilized price level ? B. In short-run situations, do movements of prices of some products and services tend to be determined mainly by changes in demand while others reflect mainly changes in unit costs? If this distinction seems useful, what products and services would you put in each classification, and why ? C. Relationships between prices and— 1. Aggregate demand. (a) What are the relationships between the level of, and changes in, the supply of money, and the level of, and changes in, the general average of prices of goods and services? Of productive factors? (&) How and to what extent are prices in the United States affected by developments in other countries, especially changes in international prices? Under what circumstances does this relationship run in the reverse direction from changes in the United States to changes in international prices ? 2. Consumer demand. 3. Investment demand. 4. Government demand. 238 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 239 D. Relationships between prices and costs. 1. The determinants of costs: (a) How are unit costs affected by the rate of utilization of plants and equipment! Of labor force f Of other resources ? (&) How are unit costs affected by changes in the technical efficiency of productive factors or of the way in which they are combined ? (c) How are unit costs affected by the size and scale of enterprises ? (d) How are unit costs affected by changes in the prices of productive factors? 2. Factors affecting prices of productive resources: (a) What influences the price of productive factors: Wages? Profits? Interest? Eents? etc. (6) How are changes in demand for goods and services related to changes in prices of productive resources ? 3, How are unit costs related to prices in the long run? In the short run? What classes of costs are relevant to the analysis of such cost-price relationships? THE SUPPLY OF MONEY AND CHANGES IN PRICES AND OUTPUT Milton Friedman, University of Chicago, National Bureau of Economic Research, and Center for Advanced Study in the Behavioral Sciences This paper deals with two broad issues that have arisen again and again in connection witli movements in the general level of prices. One issue is the connection between such price movements and changes in the supply of money. The other is the relation between price changes and changes in output. The course of economic history is replete with substantial price disturbances. Whenever such disturbances have occurred, two different explanations have been offered. One, common to all disturbances, is that the price movements reflect changes in the quantity of money, though the source of the monetary changes has varied widely—from clipping of currency to gold discoveries to changes in the monetary standard to the printing of paper money to the creation or destruction of deposit money by central banks and commercial banks. The other explanation has been in terms of some special circumstances of the particular occasion: good or bad harvests; disruptions in international trade; lack of confidence; the activities of "profiteers" or "monopolists" selling goods or of employers seeking to hold down wages; the activities of workers or unions pushing wages up; and so on in great variety. Perhaps the one common core of such explanations is that they generally attribute the price movements to the (socially) misguided behavior of particular individuals or groups. My own view is that these alternative explanations play little or no role in either long range or large movements in prices, though they may in short and minor movements, except indirectly as they affect the supply of money. It is clearly impossible to argue this view in detail within the compass of this paper. My reason for stating it is to make clear that I am putting such explanations to one side and concentrating instead on the monetary forces at work. The relation between the supply of money and prices has been explored so frequently and thoroughly that I can hardly hope to add much that is new on an analytical level. My reason for dealing with it nonetheless is twofold: on the one hand, though it is the essence of the problem of long run and large price movements, it tends to be pushed to one side and neglected—partly, perhaps, because of the desire to be novel; on the other hand, extensive empirical work that is currently underway puts flesh on the analytical skeleton to an extent that has not heretofore been possible. One of the major aims and justifications 1of this paper is to summarize some of the broad findings on this work. I shall do so in section 1 for the longer term changes in money and prices, in section 2, for the shorter term changes. 1 These are based partly on the preliminary results of an extensive study by Anna J. Schwartz and myself under the auspices of the National Bureau of Economic Research on the secular and cyclical behavior of the stock of money in the United States, partly on a series of studies done in the workshop in money and banking at the University of Chicago. The views expressed in this paper are of course my own and are not necessarily those of the organizations sponsoring these studies or of the other participants in them. 241 242 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Discussion of public policy with respect to prices necessarily involves the issue what kind of movements are socially desirable. One major problem is the relation of price movements to economic growth. Is a rising price level favorable or unfavorable to rapid growth in output? No conclusive answer can be given to this question in the present state of our knowledge. Some analysis and evidence to justify this assertion are given in section 3. The final section of this paper presents some implications for policy that are suggested by the relation between monetary and price change and between price change and output change. 1. Relation of stock of money to prices over longer periods There is perhaps no empirical regularity among economic phenomena that is based on so much evidence for so wide a range of circumstances as the connection between substantial changes in the stock of money and in the level of prices.2 To the best of my knowledge there is no instance in which a substantial change in the stock of money per unit of output has occurred without a substantial change in the level of prices in the same direction.3 Conversely, I know of no instance in which there has been a substantial change in the level of prices without a substantial change in the stock of money per unit of output in the same direction. And instances in which prices and the stock of money have moved together are recorded for many centuries of history, for countries in every part of the globe, and for a wide diversity of monetary arrangements. There can be little doubt about this statistical connection. The statistical connection itself, however, tells nothing about direction of influence, and it is on this question that there has been the most controversy. It could be that a rise or fall in prices, occurring for whatever reasons, produces a corresponding rise or fall in the stock of money, so that the monetary changes are a passive consequence. Alternatively, it could be that changes in the stock of money produce changes in prices in the same direction, so that control of the stock of money would imply control of prices. The variety of monetary arrangements for which a connection between monetary and price movements has been observed supports strongly the second interpretation, namely, that substantial changes in the stock of money are both a necessary and a sufficient condition for substantial changes in the general level of prices. But of course this does not exclude a reflex influence of changes in prices on the stock of money. This reflex influence is often 2 "The stock of money" is not of course an unambiguous concept. There is a wide range of assets possessing to a greater or lesser degree the qualities of general acceptability and fixity in nominal value that are the main characteristics of "money." It is somewhat arbitrary just where the line is drawn which separates "money" from "near-money" or "securities" or "other financial claims." For most of what follows, the precise line drawn will not affect the analysis. For the United States at present, I shall treat as "money in the hands of the public" the sum of "currency outside banks," "demand deposits adjusted," and "adjusted time deposits in commercial banks," as these terms are defined in Federal Reserve monetary statistics. I shall note explicitly any point at which the precise definition 3 adopted affects the statements made. The nearest thing to an exception I know of is German experience from the midthirties to 1944. See John J. Klein, German Money and Prices, 1932-44, in Milton Friedman (Ed.), Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money (University of Chicago Press, 1956), pp. 121-159. The qualification, "per unit of output" is needed only to cover movements spanning long periods of time, like the long term decline in prices in the late 19th century. For moderately short periods, even the qualification is unnecessary. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 243 important, almost always complex, and,4 depending on the monetary arrangements, may be in either direction. This general evidence is reinforced by much historical evidence of a more specific character demonstrating that changes in the stock of money, at least when they are fairly large, can exert an independent influence on prices. One dramatic example is from the experience of the Confederacy during the Civil War. In 1864, "after 3 years of war, after widespread destruction and military reverses, in the face of impending defeat, a monetary reform that succeeded in reducing the stock of money halted and reversed for some months a rise in prices that had been going on at the rate of 10 percent a month most of the war. It would be hard to construct a better controlled experiment to demonstrate the critical importance of the supply of money."5 The effect of discoveries of precious metals in the New World in the 16th century and of gold in California and Australia in the 1840's, of the development of the cyanide process for extracting ore plus gold discoveries in South Africa in the 1890's, and of the printing of money in various hyperinflations, including our own Revolutionary War experience and the experience of many countries after World War I and World War II, are other striking examples of increases in thq stock of money producing increases in prices. The long price decline in the second half of the 19th century in many parts of the world is a less dramatic example of a decline 6in the stock of money per unit of output producing a decline in prices. The relationship between changes in the stock of money and changes in prices, while close, is not of course precise or mechanically rigid. Two major factors produce discrepancies: changes in output, and changes in the amount of money that the public desires to hold relative to its income. For the moment, we shall treat output as if it were determined independently of monetary and price changes, postponing to section 3 the relation between them. This is clearly a simplification that is to some extent contrary to fact, but certainly for the longer periods and larger changes that are discussed in this section, the simplification neither does serious violence to the facts nor leads to any significant errors in conclusions. Suppose the stock of money were to remain unchanged for a period of years but total output over the same period were to double. Clearly, one would expect prices to fall—other things the same—to something like half their initial level. The total amount of "work" for the money stock to do, as it were, is doubled, and the same nominal quantity of money could perform the "work" only at lower levels of prices. Eoughly speaking, this is what happened in the United States in the period from the end of the Civil War in 1865 to the resumption of specie payments in 1879: The stock of money was 4 For example, under a gold standard, a rising level of prices discourages gold production and so, after a lag tends to produce a decline in the stock of money. On the other hand, under a fractional reserve banking system, if rising prices lead banks to reduce the ratio of cash to liabilities, rising prices may tend to produce a rise in the stock of money. 5 Mlton Friedman, The Quantity Theory of Money—a Restatement, in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money, p. 17. The quotation summarizes one item from a s-tudy by Eugene M. Lerner, summarized in his article, Inflation in the Confederacy, 1861-65, in the6 same volume, pp. 163-175. The decline in the stock of money per unit of output occurred as a result of (1) exhaustion of then-known gold mines; (2) the shift of many countries from a silver to a gold standard ; (3) the rapid increase in output. 23734—58 17 244 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH roughly the same in 1879 as in 1865—if anything, some 10 percent higher; output grew very rapidly over the period, probably more7 than doubling; and wholesale prices were half their initial level. Thus, for price movements, the relevant variable is the stock of money per unit of output, not simply the global stock of money. The second major factor that can introduce a discrepancy between movements in money and in prices is a change in the ratio that 8the public desires to maintain between its cash balances and its income — the public including individuals, business enterprises other than banks, nonprofit institutions, and the like. The number of dollars an individual wants to keep in cash depends of course on the price level—at twice the price level he will want to hold something like twice the number of dollars—and on his income—the higher his income presumably the larger cash balances he will want to hold. But the price level is what we are trying to explain, and we have already taken account of the effect of changes in output. This is why we express this factor in terms of the ratio that the public desires to maintain between its cash balances and its income, rather than in terms of the number of dollars it desires to hold. Broadly speaking, the public as a whole cannot by itself affect the total number of dollars available to be held—this is determined primarily by the monetary institutions. To each individual separately, it appears that he can do so; in fact an individual can reduce or increase his cash balance in general only through another individual's increasing or reducing his. If individuals as a whole, for example, try to reduce the number of dollars they hold, they cannot as an aggregate do so. In trying to do so, however, they will raise the flow of expenditures and hence of money income and in this way will reduce the ratio of their cash balances to their income; since prices will tend to rise in the process, they will thereby reduce the real value of their cash balances, that is, the quantity of goods and services that the cash balances will command; and this process will continue until this ratio or this real value is in accord with their desires. A wide range of empirical evidence suggests that the ratio which people desire to maintain between their cash balances and their income is relatively stable over fairly long periods of time aside from the effect of two major factors: (1) The level of real income per capita,9 or perhaps of real wealth per capita; (2) the cost of holding money. (1) Apparently, the holding of cash balances is regarded as a "luxury," like education and recreation. The amount of money the public desires to hold not only goes up as its real income rises but goes up more than in proportion. Judged by evidence for the last 75 years in the United States, a 1 percent rise in real income per capita tends to be accompanied by nearly a 2 percent increase in the real amount of money held and thus by nearly a 1 percent increase in the ratio of 7 The basic data underlying this statement are from the National Bureau study mentioned in footnote 1 above. They will appear in a monograph by Anna J. Schwartz and myself that is now in preparation. s9 The reciprocal of this ratio is termed "the income velocity of circulation." On this subiect, see Phillip Casan, The Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation, and Richard T. Selden, Monetary Velocity in the United States, in Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. The statements that follow are based also on additionoal work done in connection with the National Bureau study referred to in footnote 1. For shorter periods, an additional factor enters. Cash balances are apparently adjusted to longer term income expectations ("permanent income") rather than to current income as measured on a monthly or annual basis. This introduces additional changes in the ratio of cash balances to current measured income. (See sec. 2 below.) ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 245 cash balances to income. This tendency is highly regular over the long sweep of time from 1875 to World War I I ; it has not been operative since the end of World War I I but it is yet too soon to judge whether this a fundamental change or simply a reaction to the abnormally high ratio of cash balances that was reached during the war. (2) The cost of holding cash balances depends mainly on the rate of interest that can be earned on alternative assets—thus if a bond yields 4 percent while cash yields no return, this means that an individual gives up $4 a year if he holds $100 of cash instead of a bond— and on the rate of change of prices—if prices rise at 5 percent per year, for example, $100 in cash will buy at the end of the year only as much as $95 at the beginning so that it has cost the individual $5 to hold $100 of cash instead of goods. The empirical evidence suggests that while the first factor—the interest rate—has a systematic effect on the amount of money held, the effect is rather small. The second factor, the rate of change of prices, has no discernible effect in ordinary times when price changes are small—of the order of a few percent a year. On the other hand, it has a clearly discernible and major effect when price change is rapid and long continued, as during extreme inflations or deflations.10 A rapid inflation produces a sizable decline in the desired ratio of cash balances to income; a rapid deflation, a sizable rise. Of course even after allowance is made for changes in real income per capita and in the cost of holding money, the ratio of cash balances to income is not perfectly steady. But the remaining fluctuations in it are minor, certainly far smaller than those that occur in the stock of money itself. Some idea of the quantitative magnitude of the changes in the United States over long periods of time can be obtained by comparing average values of various items over the most recent complete business cycle—that running from a trough in 1949 to a peak in 1953 to a trough in 1954—with those over the earliest for which we have the relevant data—that running from a trough in 1878 to a peak in 1882 to a trough in 1885. The money stock multiplied 67-fold over these seven decades, and real income ninefold, so the money stock per unit of output rose about 7.5-fold. Prices something less than tripled, so the ratio of the money stock to money income roughly tripled. In the initial cycle, the stock of money averaged about 24 percent of 1 year's money income—that is, cash balances were equal to the income of about 3 months; in the terminal cycle, the stock of money averaged about 67 percent of 1 year's income—that is, cash balances were equal to the income of about 8 months. Over the period as a whole, the money stock rose at an average rate of 6 percent per year, money income at nearly 5 percent per year, prices at nearly IV2 percent per year, total output at about 3 percent per year, and population at about iy2 percent per year. Of course, these changes did not occur smoothly. Figure 1 shows the more detailed behavior based on average values for each of the 19 business cycles that we have experienced since 1879. It is clear that there is an exceedingly close connection between movements in the stock of money per unit of output and in prices. The only major dif10 Evidence for this is presented in Cagan, op. cit., and is available also from work by John Deaver on monetary changes in Chile. 246 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH ference is the more rapid long-term growth in the stock of money which in turn reflects the effect of the long-term growth in per capita real income and the associated rise in the desired ratio of money stock to money income. 8. Relation of stock of money to prices over shorter periods Over the longer periods considered in the preceding section, changes in the stock of money per unit of output tend to dominate price changes, allowance being made for the effect of the growth of real income per head. This is less so over the shorter periods involved in the fluctuations we term business cycles, though the general and average relationship is very similar. The reason for the looser connection in such periods presumably is that movements in both the stock of money and in prices are smaller. Over longer periods, these movements cumulate and tend to swamp any disturbance in the relation between desired cash balances, real income, and the cost of holding money; in the ordinary business cycle, the disturbances, though perhaps no more important in an absolute sense, are much more important relative to the movements in money and prices. •ill ;(|t( I l l (1 III II'III III tillIIIllll ll|l 1' PI lill! r Iuiiiiii I llit iiiillli l l i l ll ' mill 'IImil ii! || i11 Illl'l I '• j> ' | • Tn. t •hi || T i |l| !•' T I iii [j!| f r f -\\ f-in "~~"rr • l: r' 1 1ILi j • f (j j II•1 I It1 i||l'III illi"P^> ' IJijjiTi |U It i i I ill' Ijljr inn mil mil ' (i T - - ^ ' -1 i ' *' ujKp if . , .-L, L u L ' J. . . . . 1 ! 1' r • ' i l l 1 j !' ' | || » J 1 ' ' 1 ' i ! [ I * _ i III! (I /I llil I I I I II 1 II U || | || —1 »ullil i l l L. 1 friilll tit \ llliHl III \\M\\\\ ' i 11, TsJUIllT'lll 1 % _i|M , \ 1 1 , py inl l —ifmTryft ' " ' i f i — ' I'llill /III If 1 lill/ill i/l I I 1 • j •• -m--- /mil i i n : : -S; * Tf B1 JI in t| "1M\\ \ " m"" I HI | | II PHI ljj i /|ll | ii|| II|| II Illlllili sj imil 3$|f|I pllirli ' >3||| |;l l l j l l j > | A\ i ' r '-- m 1 F' :::: • .:., i ' tt 1\l1 — ' 1l l1 l i _i 333: 3jn in *31 oLi i' I1'i |i1 II |1 1 I i a J i • " : : : : : : : ___ " : __ _ : ::::-!-::—-i: ; ....: : ... : ..., !.. . _ 247 3•i i1nitilll 1lilli i Eit1 1 I' 1 1* \i HI |||| IIII II1 'iff lilt lllHiirmT UIIIIII Illl I UIIIIII Illl IINUIIIIII IIIUJJIU I Illl III Illlllili llllllll I 1 Illll I 'DM 1 III lufi ' III iiiiii iiiiiy ifflilf II liiitf' ' V IIIIII —Jillli 1 Pfltt • lilil Hi II II II ll III rlFii' III l u l l IIITIIJ 1 II IIIIrPi 11 f \(MM \f 1 i'l'll'' i Ii ll 1 iiln i I I ||)||I|| j imTlrl ' i 1 llllll III 11 inII 1||II 1 || UJ 1 UMJ ll Iffflfipl I'll || l|| I'l | | j | 1, II illlll ll III Illll IIII llllll llllll II II mill |||j lioni III II l l H l r j •< I'l II[iiIII 1 , li'iliiiilli i II 'uiul'i ' t 'r rH "i Eli| li|ijj' |I j l i'|' 'J •' 11 1 T i i r r * !' 1 llllllll i| ' _ i__ .:::::....)..... -ft(!|iP ! h ^ -- I* 1 • 1 I :::::::;a._._:.[ «J iji.. | in '[ 1 J! _ _ 3 11 i|'|| || < I t , D :"":":::::::s_ I :i ...I t \ \ \' i i 1 l''l' 1 HM ' | 1 | , ia l' ' '1 "sl 'ii n I :::: ,, . ,... -^fl- — f| , : : . . : ! . . ! :! .. |1L:[I u "n:— ^ - fUff H ~~ i]Lii: - ! f r f l jj-±-is Output ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH rf| |i • 11 i i ~f~ ' i i ii 1 ' I I l_u- ;1 nx ill 11 H1'' 1 tJ j_ LL ^ nlf rf, J 7ijT~ rt"" -.•:::L1:JLFF^ . S+OCK of r\<x*>ey />er U-nit of ¥:::::: • fft _ __ 1 1 Ilill Illl 1 1 mil I I t t.: _ * lI illil Ml itll f 4 :.:._ t;:__: r t I 5 i , i : j I j ::::::::::::::: I ' I 1 t 4 i : ntj:.-- ,' i_i i j_ 1 Jfjj nj;"""T 1i'1 >. * t t r I " + ' " " ' i 11 i j_i i t i i '' | f ' i p| ! _ iJ-LTitt " a' i l l " " " " " I : : " ** 4 ' 1 111 i yl J 1 4' |J i O ' •' i\ i'[[ 1 [M ' ^"n'T'M '1 5 '' ml ul ' i ' ft " ii i ! <: Ilili ' i tj M ( Hill '!' i ] \\ i L ' IJJil ii'j lii j i h IjTT III 1 1 ' 1 til 1 'L p j L j i j i [ U L U . * --<J|j|} ' l l i i . ' L ^ ' ^ ' i i i i [ti II- : f ' |p [Ii I ji M ||| l| 1 |j ' !t 1 ' i 1 *s ! •' ! i]rf t Ij1 i j *-: [jf • £T" T "" I I > JI ' I 0 :-(-$ ' n rrt• i j i , i M ' FT' • i f j" T ' 1 mil i' ! j1 j *' .i ij 1'./ til: ' | f ] n" 4 L * ;, !jjj St.i > j : . . Kill i ' llllll 1 l l Ijtfjj r i! m ~h^ "77j— "* mil LJ ' ' • i' i rrpjj $ , j , •*• H i • i' f' i• • i l l ' i i IIP i !H • • ' ' Hill ii i ''I ' ! i ' i ' ||fei;::i: l'!' Ill i_J II t IfIl j l j i'Il j j' '[[ | ! l''i i i • LXJ.1' I'.._ rx _ _ ilj||[' : ; ; !! 1 ' ! 2 Vertical scale logarithmic. Source: All series are from unpublished data developed in connection with studies a t the National Bureau of Economic Research. Money figures from study by Milton Friedman and Anna J. Schwartz; output (net national product in constant prices) and price (deflator implicit in computing net national product in constant prices) figures preliminary estimates by Simon Kuznets. 248 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH On the average, prices rise during an expansion phase of a business cycle, fall during the contraction phase. In the usual fairly mild cycle of peacetime since 1879, wholesale prices have on the average risen about 10 percent from trough to peak, and have fallen by somewhat less than half that amount from peak to trough. The general pattern has not changed much except for the relation of the rise to the fall. During the period of generally declining prices from the 1880's to the mid-1890's, prices tended to fall more during the contraction than they rose during expansion; during the subsequent period of generally rising prices, the reverse was the case and in some instances prices continued to rise during part of the contraction; in the 1920's, the rise and fall were roughly the same; in the two postwar cycles the rise was decidedly larger than the fall, as in the pre-1914 period. Taken as a whole, these mild cycles would have imparted a generally upward drift to prices. The failure of such a drift to develop during peacetime was a consequence of the more severe depressions that occurred from time to time. In the five business cycles for which the contractions were most serious and can be designated deep depressions (1891-94,1904-08,1919-21,1927-33, and 1933-38), wholesale prices on the average rose about 10 percent during expansions, about the same as in the mild cycles, but then fell during the contractions over twice as much, ending up on the average some 12 percent below their level at the start of the cycle. It was the price declines during these deep depressions that, as a matter of experience, offset the upward tendency during mild cycles—"creeping inflation" in this sense is by no means a unique post-World War I I phenomenon. The stock of money shows the same relation to these cyclical price movements as that depicted in figure 1 for longer periods. During the mild cycles, the stock of money almost invariably rose during both expansion and contraction, but at a faster rate during expansions than during contractions. On the other hand, during the deep depression cycles listed above, the stock of money invariably fell during the course of the contraction, and there is only one other cycle during which there is an appreciable absolute decline during any part of the contraction (1894-97). This resemblance between the cyclical movement in the stock of money and in prices holds not only on the average but also from cycle to cycle, though of course with more variability for the individual cycles.11 11 One difference between the comparison made here and in the preceding section is that the money series used is the stock of money, not the stock of money per unit of output. The reason for this is the problem referred to in footnote 9 above. Over the longer periods, the stock of money rises more rapidly than money income; an increase in real income per capita leads to a more than proportional increase in real money balances—income velocity falls with a rise in real income. Over the cycle, the reverse relation holds, if money income is measured by a figure like the regularly published national income or net national product estimates. Money stock falls relative to measured money income during expansion and rises during contraction—income velocity rises during expansion and falls during contraction. It turns out that this apparent contradiction can be accounted for, both qualitatively and quantitatively, by distinguishing between measured income and a longer term concept that I have called permanent income and also between measured prices and permanent prices. One implication of this interpretation of the behavior of velocity is that division of the money stock by measured national income in constant prices would yield estimates of the stock of money per unit of output that were formally comparable to those plotted in figure 1 but did not have the same significance and meaning; the latter use an average output figure that is closer to permanent output or income than to annual measured income. Unfortunately, full analysis of this issue is impossible within the confines of the present paper. The forthcoming annual report for 1957 of the National Bureau of Economic Research will contain a somewhat fuller summary ; and the monograph referred to in footnote 7 above, a full analysis. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 249 There can be little doubt on the basis of this evidence that there is a close link between monetary changes and price changes over the shorter periods within which business cycles run their course as well as over longer periods and during major wartime episodes. But three important considerations must be borne in mind if this fact is not to be a misleading guide to policy. The first is that the direction of influence between the money stock and income and prices is less clear-cut and more complex for the business cycle than for the longer movements. The character of our monetary and banking system means that an expansion of income contributes to expansion in the money stock, partly through inducing banks to trim more closely their cash reserve position, partly through a tendency for currency in public hands to decline relative to deposits; similarly, a contraction of income contributes to a reduction or a slower rate of rise in the money stock by having the opposite effects on bank reserve ratios and the public's currency ratio. Thus changes in the money stock are a consequence as well as an independent cause of changes in income and prices, though once they occur they will in their turn produce still further effects on income and prices. This consideration blurs the relation between money and prices but does not reverse it. For there is much evidence—one important piece on timing will be presented in the next paragraph—that even during business cycles the money stock plays a largely independent role. This evidence is particularly direct and clear for the deep depression periods. There can be little doubt, for example, that Federal Eeserve action in sharply raising discount rates in January 1920 and again in June 1920 (5 months after the onset of the contraction in January 1920) played an important role in the subsequent decline in the money supply and unprecedentedly rapid fall in prices or that Federal Reserve policy in the early 1930's played an important role in producing a decline of a third in the stock of money from 1929 to 1933—by far the largest decline in the whole period covered by our data.12 A second, and perhaps more important consideration, has to do with the timing of the changes in the money supply and in income and prices. The generally upward trend in the money supply which accounts for its continuing to rise, though at a slower rate, during most contractions in economic activity as well as during expansions makes it difficult to judge timing relations from ups and downs in the money supply itself. For this and other reasons, we have found it most useful to examine instead the ups and downs in the rate at which the money supply is changing. The rate of change of the money supply shows well-marked cycles that match closely those in economic activity in general and precede the latter by a long interval. On the average, the rate of change of the money supply has reached its peak nearly 16 months before the peak in general business and 13 The other deep depression episodes are a bit more complex. The decline in the stock of money from 1893 to 1894 seems connected with the uncertainty about silver; in 1907, quite clearly with the banking panic which was of course in part a consequence of a prior decline in economic activity but not through the particular channels described above and which once begun very likely served as an important factor in making the contraction as deep as it was; in 1937-38, with the doubling of reserve requirements by the Federal Reserve System in two steps in 1936 and in 1937—the first step coincides with a sharp reduction in the rate of growth of the money stock, the second with the beginning of decline. 250 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH has reached 18 its trough over the 12 months before the trough in general business. This is strong though not conclusive evidence for the independent influence of monetary change. But it also has a very different significance. It means that it must take a long time for the influence of monetary changes to make themselves felt—apparently what happens now to the rate of change of the money supply may not be reflected in prices or economic activity for 12 to 16 months, on the average. Moreover, the timing varies considerably from cycle to cycle—since 1907, the shortest time span by which the money peak preceded the business cycle peak was 13 months, the longest, 24 months; the corresponding range at troughs is 5 months to 21 months.14 From the point of view of scientific analysis directed at establishing economic regularities on the basis of the historical record—the purpose for which the measures were computed—this is highly consistent behavior; it justifies considerable confidence in the reliability of the averages cited and means that they cannot easily be attributed simply to the accident of chance variation. But from the point of view of policy directed at controlling a particular movement such as the current recession, the timing differences are disturbingly large—they mean that monetary action taken today may, on the basis of past experience, affect economic activity within 6 months or again perhaps not for over a year and 6 months; and of course past experience is not exhaustive; the particular episode may establish a new limit in either direction. The long time lag has another important effect. It leads to misinterpretation and misconception about the effects of monetary policy, as well as to consequent mistakes in monetary policy. Because the effects of monetary change do not occur instantaneously, monetary policy is regarded as ineffective. The most recent example is the tight money policy of 1956 and 1957 which coexisted with rising prices but whose delayed effects are with us in the current recession. A similar and even more dramatic example is the tight money policy from early 1928 on and the associated lack of growth in the money supply which coexisted with economic expansion but contributed to both the occurrence and the severity of the 1920 downturn. The fact that these policies had a delayed effect in turn misled the monetary authorities; on those occasions, and even more clearly in 1920, they were induced to believe that still stronger measures were required and so tended to overdo a repressive policy. On other occasions, notably in 1932 as well as earlier in that major catastrophe, the failure of tentative movements toward easy money to have an immediate effect led them to regard their actions as ineffective and to permit and contribute to the sharp decline in the stock of money which occurred and which played so crucial a role in that episode. The third consideration is in some ways a different aspect of the one just discussed. The variation in timing means that there is considerable leeway in the precise relation between changes in the stock 13 The average at peaks is based on 18 observations, on troughs on 19. Of course, instead of interpreting the cycles in the rate of change as conforming positively with a lead, they could be interpreted as conforming inversely with a lag. A number of pieces of statistical evidence, however, argue strongly for the former interpretation. 14 These are for the period since 1907 because our money data prior to that date are annual or semiannual. While the annual and semiannual observations give the same average timing as the monthly, individual observations are not comparable. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 251 of money and in prices over short periods of time—there are other factors at work that lead to these variations and mean that even if the stock of money were to change in a highly regular and consistent fashion, economic activity and prices would nonetheless fluctuate. When the money changes are large, they tend to dominate these other factors—or perhaps one might better say, they will force these factors to work in a particular direction. Thus there seems little doubt that a large change in the money supply within a relatively short period will force a change in the same direction in income and prices and, conversely, that a large change in income and prices in short periods—a substantial short-period inflation or deflation—is most unlikely to occur without a large change in money supply. This is certainly the conclusion suggested by the evidence for the deep depression cycles and for sizable inflations. But when the money changes are moderate, the other factors come into their own. If we knew enough about them and about the detailed effects of monetary changes, we might be able to counter these other effects by monetary measures. But this is Utopian given our present level of knowledge. There are thus definite limits to the possibility of any fine control of the general level of prices by afineadjustment of monetary change. 3. Changes in prices and changes in output over longer periods Over the cycle, prices and output tend to move together—both tend to rise during expansions and to fall during contractions. Both are part of the cyclical process and anything, including a monetary change, that promotes a vigorous expansion is likely to promote a vigorous rise in both and conversely. The preceding section implicity assumes this connection. Over the longer period, the relation between price changes and output changes is much less clear and in the first section we took the behavior of output for granted. Now this seems clearly valid, not only as an expository device but also as a first approximation to reality. What happens to a nation's output over long periods of time depends in the first instance on such basic factors as resources available, the industrial organization of the society, the growth of knowledge and technical skills, the growth of population, the accumulation of capital and so on. This is the stage on which money and price changes play their parts as the supporting cast. One proposition about the effect of changes in the stock of money and in prices that is widely accepted and hardly controversial is that large and unexpected changes in prices are adverse to the growth of output—whether these changes are up or down. At one extreme, the kind of price rise that occurs during hyperinflation seriously distorts the effective use of resources.15 At the other extreme, sharp price declines such as occurred from 1920 to 1921 and again from 1929 to 1933 certainly produce a widespread and tragic waste of resources. So much is agreed. The more controversial issue is the effect of moderate change in prices. One view that is widely held is that 35 However, even open hyperinflations are less damaging to output than suppressed inflations in which a wide range of prices are held well below the levels that would clear the market. The German hyperinflation after World War I never caused anything like the reduction of production that was produced in Germany from 1945 to the monetary reform of 1948 by the suppression of inflation. And the inflationary pressure suppressed in the second case was a small fraction of that manifested in the first. 252 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH slowly rising prices stimulate economic output and produce a more rapid rate of growth than would otherwise occur. A number of reasons have been offered in support of this view. (1) Prices, and particularly wages, are, it is said, sticky. In a market economy, the reallocation of resources necessitated by economic growth and development requires changes in relative prices and relative w^ages. It is much easier, it is argued, for these to come about without friction and resistance if they can occur through rises in some prices and wages without declines in others. If prices were stable, some changes in relative wages could still come about in this way, since economic growth means that wages tend to rise relative to prices, but no changes in relative prices, and, of course, there would not be as much scope even for relative wage changes. (2) Costs, and in particular, wages, are, it is argued, stickier than selling prices. Hence generally rising prices will tend to raise profit margins, giving enterprises both a bigger incentive to raise output and to add to capital and the means to finance the capital needed. (3) The most recently popular variant of the preceding point is that costs are not only sticky against declines but in addition have a tendency to be pushed up with little reference to the state of demand as a result of strong trade unions. If the money stock is kept from rising, the result, it is claimed, will be unemployment as profit margins are cut, and also a higher level of prices, though not necessarily a rising level of prices. Gently rising prices, it is argued, will tend to offset this upward pressure by permitting money wages to rise without real wages doing so. (4) Interest rates are particularly slow to adapt to price rises. If prices are rising at, say, 3 percent a year, a 6 percent interest rate on a money loan is equivalent to a 3 percent rate when prices are stable. If lenders adjusted fully to the price rise, this would simply mean that interest rates would be 3 percentage points higher in the first case than in the second. But in fact this does not happen, so that productive enterprises find the cost of borrowing to be relatively low, and again have a greater incentive than otherwise to invest, and the associated transfer from creditors to debtors gives them greater means to do so. In opposition to this view, it has been argued that generally rising prices reduce the pressure on enterprises to be efficient, stimulate speculative relative to industrial activity, reduce the incentives for individuals to save, and make it more difficult to maintain the appropriate structure of relative prices, since individual prices have to change in order to stay the same relative to others. Furthermore, it is argued that once it becomes widely recognized that prices are rising, the advantages cited in the preceding paragraph will disappear: escalator clauses or their economic equivalent will eliminate the stickiness of prices and wages and the greater stickiness of wages than of prices; strong unions will increase still further their wage demands to allow for price increases; and interest rates will rise to allow for the price rise. If the advantages are to be obtained, the rate of price rise will have to be accelerated and there is no stopping place short of runaway inflation. From this point of view, there may clearly be a major difference between the effects of a superficially similar price rise, according as it is an undesigned and largely unforeseen effect of such impersonal events as the discovers of gold, or a designed result of deliberative policy action by a public body. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 253 Some who believe that slowly rising prices are adverse to economic growth regard stable product prices with slowly rising wage rates as most favorable, combining the advantages of stable price expectations with some easing of frictions involved in relative wage adjustments. Others view gently falling prices and stable wages as most favorable, arguing that additional problems in wage adjustments would be balanced by the stimulus to thrift and accumulation. Historical evidence on the relation between price changes and output changes is mixed and gives no clear support to any one of these positions. (1) In the United States, the period from 1865 to 1879 was a period of exceedingly rapid progress; and during the same period, prices were cut in half. True, neither price changes nor output changes proceeded regularly within the period. Output apparently grew most rapidly during the cyclical expansions in the period when prices rose mildly or were roughly stable; most of the price declines occurred during cyclical contractions. Yet the problem at issue is less the cyclical relation than the longer period relation and there can be no doubt that during the period as a whole prices fell sharply and output rose sharply. (2) The period from 1880 to 1897 was a period of generally declining prices, from 1897 to 1913, of generally rising prices; taken as a whole, the second period has generally been regarded as displaying more rapid growth than the first. But it is not clear that this is a satisfactory interpretation. The period of great monetary uncertainty in the early 1890's was associated with generally depressed conditions and was followed by a rapid rebound. If both are excluded, the remaining periods show about the same rates of growth in real output per head, although prices were generally falling during the 1880's and rising after the turn of the century. Moreover, the period from 1908-14 is one of relatively slow growth despite rising prices. (3) The decade of the 1920's, after the recovery from the deep depression of 1920-21, was a decade of rapid growth and prices were relatively stable. (4) In Great Britain, output per head apparently grew at a definitely higher rate during the period of generally falling prices before the mid-1890's than16 during the subsequent period of rising prices up to World War I. (5) On the other hand, the attempt to achieve mildly falling prices in Britain in the 1920's was associated with considerable economic difficulties and something close to stagnation. AH in all, perhaps the only conclusion that is justified is that either rising prices or falling prices are consistent with rapid economic growth, provided that the price changes are fairly steady, moderate in size, and reasonably predictable. The mainsprings of growth are presumably to be sought elsewhere. But unpredictable and erratic changes of direction in prices are apparently as disturbing to economic growth as to economic stability. ^. Policy implications The preceding account of the relation of money to prices over long and short periods and of price changes to output changes has some fairly direct and immediate implications for public policy with respect both to growth and stability. 16 See James B. Jefferys and Dorothy Walters, National Income and Expenditure of the United Kingdom, 1870-1952, Income and Wealth Series V, table III. 254 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH (1) In order for the price level to be reasonably stable over the decades ahead, the total stock of money will have to grow to accommodate itself to the growth in output and in population. In addition, if past patterns continue, it will have to grow to satisfy the desire of the public to increase the ratio of cash balances to income as their real income rises. Past experience suggests that something like a 3 to 5 percent per year increase in the stock of money is required for longterm price stability.17 (2) An essential requirement for the avoidance of either substantial inflation or substantial deflation over the coming decades is the avoidance of a substantially more rapid or a substantially less rapid increase in the stock of money than the 3 to 5 percent per year required for price stability. A substantially more rapid rate of growth in the money supply will inevitably mean inflation; conversely, continued inflation of substantial magnitude cannot occur without such a large rate of growth in the money supply. A substantially slower rate of growth m the money supply, let alone an absolute decline, will inevitably mean deflation; conversely, continued deflation of substantial magnitude cannot occur without such a small or negative rate of growth in the money supply. (3) A highly fluctuating price level is as disturbing to economic growth as to economic stability. Given that this is avoided, it is not clear what pattern of long-term price behavior is optimum for economic stability—whether a roughly stable price level, a gently rising price level, or a gently falling price level. It does seem clear that any of these is consistent with rapid economic growth. If it is necessary to state objectives in terms of a price level goal, then a stable price level has the very great advantages of (a) ease of public understanding, (b) definiteness rendering successive alterations in the precise goal less likely, and (c) probably the closest approach to equitable treatment of the various members of the community. However, the difficulty of assuring the close attainment of any price level goal suggests that it might be better to express the immediate policy goal in terms'of some variable other than the price level, for example as being the attainment of a steady 4 percent per year rise in the stock of money, and then to let the price level be whatever would be consistent with this money goal. The resulting price level behavior could hardly depart much from relative stability and would certainly not be violently unstable. (4) For cyclical movements, a major problem is to prevent monetary changes from being a source of disturbance. If the stock of money can be kept growing at a relatively steady rate, without erratic fluctuations in short periods, it is highly unlikely if not impossible that we would experience either a sharp price rise—like that during World Wars I and I I and after World War I—or a substantial price or output decline—like those experienced from 1920-21, 1929-33, 1937-28. 17 This range is for the stock of money as defined in footnote 2, namely, currency outside banks plus adjusted deposits, demand and time, of commercial banks. For a narrower definition, currency outside banks plus adjusted demand deposits, the required rate of growth is less; for a broader definition, the preceding plus all time deposits, in mutual savings banks and the postal savings system as well as commercial banks, the required rate of growth is greater. The reason is that time deposits have been growing relative to demand deposits and currency, and, until 1957, mutual savings deposits relative to other time deposits. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 255 (5) A steady rate of growth in the money supply will not mean perfect stability even though it would prevent the kind of wide fluctuations that we have experienced from time to time in the past. It is tempting to try to go farther and to use monetary changes to offset other factors making for expansion and contraction. Though the available evidence demonstrates a close connection between monetary change and price and income change in the course of business cycles as over larger periods, it also casts grave doubts on the possibility of producing any fine adjustments in economic activity by fine adjustments in monetary policy—at least in the present state of knowledge. The evidence suggests that monetary changes take a fairly long time to exert their influence and that the time taken varies considerably. In terms of past experience, for example, action taken now to offset the current recession may affect economic activity in some 6 months or not again for over a year and 6 months. The tight-money policy of late 1956 and most of 1957, which was taken to offset the then existing inflationary pressure, almost surely had little effect on that situation and is only now exerting its influence and contributing to the current recessionary tendencies; the inflationary pressures in 195(> may well themselves have been in part a delayed consequence of the expansionary monetary policy taken to offset the 1953-54 recession. There are thus serious limitations to the possibility of a discretionary monetary policy and much danger that such a policy may make matters worse rather than better. Federal Reserve policy since 1951 has been distinctly superior to that followed during any earlier period since the establishment of the System, mainly because it has avoided wide fluctuations in the rate or growth of the money supply. At the same time, I am myself inclined to believe that in our present state of knowledge and with our present institutions, even this policy has been decidedly inferior to the much simpler policy of keeping the money supply growing at a predesignated rate month in and month out with allowance only for seasonal influences and with no attempt to adjust the rate of growth to monetary conditions.18 (6) To avoid misunderstanding, it should be emphasized that the problems just discussed are in no way peculiar to monetary policy. Fiscal action also involves lags. Indeed the lag between the recognition of need for action and the taking of action is undoubtedly longer for discretionary fiscal than for discretionary monetary action: The monetary authorities can act promptly, fiscal action inevitably involves serious delays for congressional consideration. It has been argued that this defect of fiscal action is counterbalanced by a shorter lag between the action and its effects. This may well be, though there is little concrete empirical evidence that I know of; the belief is based 18 This is not intended to be a full statement of the optimum monetary structure. I would prefer automatic arrangements that would reduce the area of discretion. One particular set of such arrangements is suggested in my A Monetary Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability, reprinted in my Essays in Positive Economics (University of Chicago Press, 1953), pp. 133-156. The extensive empirical work that I have done since that article was written has given me no reason to doubt that the arrangements there suggested would produce a higher degree of stability ; it has, however, led me to believe that much simpler arrangements would do so also ; that something like the simple policy suggested above would produce a very tolerable amount of stability. This evidence has persuaded me that the major problem is to prevent monetary changes from themselves contributing to instability rather than to use monetary changes to offset other forces. On the issues in question, see also my 'The Effects of a Full Employment Policy on Economic Stability: A Formal Analysis, reprinted in the same book, pp. 117-132. 256 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH on general considerations of plausibility, which can be a misleading guide. And there are certainly no reasons for believing and no empirical evidence to show that the lag, whatever its average length, is any less variable for fiscal than for monetary action. Hence the basic difficulties and limitations of monetary policy apply with equal force to fiscal policy. (7) Political pressures to "do something" in the face of either relatively mild price rises or relatively mild price and employment declines are clearly very strong indeed in the existing state of public attitudes. The main moral to be drawn from the two preceding points is that yielding to these pressures may frequently do more harm than good. There is a saying that the best is often the enemy of the good, which seems highly relevant. The goal of an extremely high degree of economic stability is certainly a splendid one; our ability to attain it, however, is limited; we can surely avoid extreme fluctuations; we do not know enough to avoid minor fluctuations; the attempt to do more than we can will itself be a disturbance that may increase rather than reduce instability. But like all such injunctions, this one too must be taken in moderation. It is a plea for a sense of perspective and balance, not for irresponsibility in the face of major problems or for failure to correct past mistakes. INFLATIONARY DEPRESSION AND THE REGULATION OF ADMINISTERED PRICES By Abba P. Lerner, The Johns Hopkins University and Eoosevelt University Inflation, by which I mean a condition of rising prices, may be the result of action either by buyers or by sellers. We are much more familiar with inflation caused by buyers trying to buy more goods than are available, that is, spending more money than can buy (at current prices) the available supply of goods. When this happens, prices are bid up to the level at which the buyers are no longer trying to buy more than is available. The market is then cleared with every buyer able to buy as much as he wants to buy. If, as a result of this development, there arises a still further increase in the amount of money spent by the buyers, perhaps because they have received more money as sellers of something else, we have a continuing inflationary process. Such a process cannot go very far unless there is an increase in the supply of money. Otherwise, with the rising prices, the public finds that the stock of money is too small for the greater volume of transactions, in monetary terms, that is going on. Many people then reduce their buying or increase their selling (so as to hold on to or to get hold of more money) and this, tends to stop the inflationary process. But if the monetary authorities increase the supply of money, or permit the supply of money to be increased, then the inflationary process can continue. Because we are much more familiar with this particular type of inflation, we have tended to assume that it is the only kind. This has led to the habit of considering an increase in the supply of money not as merely one of the necessary conditions for an inflationary process to be able to continue, but as the cause of the inflation, which it need not be. Our overoccupation with this particular type of inflation has also led many economists, including myself, to use the word "inflation" not only to stand for the condition of rising prices, but also to stand for "excess demand," the attempt to buy more goods than are available at the current prices, which is the cause of this type of inflation. This extension of the meaning of the word inflation would be quite harmless if it were true, as it apparently was assumed to be true, that rising prices could come about only as a result of excess demand by buyers. This usage furthermore had the advantage of permitting the condemnatory word inflation to be used for attacking a condition in which prices were prevented from rising, as by price controls, when the economy would be better served if they were permitted to rise. Such price control under conditions of excess demand could then be called a kind of inflation—repressed inflation—which can be 257 258 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH even more harmful to the economy, and to society in general, than an open inflation with rising prices. So it seemed like a good idea to identify inflation with a condition of excess demand, whether the resulting tendency for prices to rise was permitted to express itself or not. Repressed inflation could therefore be called a certain kind of inflation and given a blacker name, and this seemed harmless even though it was something like calling an anti-Communist a certain kind of Communist. But excess demand by buyers is not the only possible cause of a condition of rising prices. Prices may rise not because of the pressure of buyers who are finding it difficult to buy all they want to buy at the current prices. Prices may rise because of pressures by sellers who insist on raising their prices even though they may find it not especially easy to sell. We would then have not a buyer-induced inflation but a, seller-induced inflation. To distinguish this from the kind of inflation we have discussed above, and which we may call a buyers' inflation (or demand inflation), we may call this kind of inflation a sellers' inflation. If sellers' inflation is possible as well as buyers' inflation, it is not such a good idea to use the word "inflation" to stand for excess demand. That use of language tends to suggest that if there is no "inflation" in the sense of excess demand, there can be no inflation in the sense of rising prices. It leaves us with no way of describing the kind of situation in which we find ourselves when prices are rising because of upward pressure by sellers, and the authorities, in endeavoring to stop the rise in prices, have taken steps which have been very effective in removing excess demand, but which have not removed the upward pressure on prices from the sellers' side. Indeed such measures as budgetary restraint and tight money can be so effective in removing excess demand that they can overdo this and remove some demand that is not in excess. They would bring about a condition of deficient demand, or not enough demand to enable us to make full use of our productive potential. Nevertheless, prices may keep on rising. The net result would be both inflation and depression at the same time—prices rising—even though we are not fully utilizing our available labor force and productive potential. This appears paradoxical only because of our habit of using 1 word, "inflation," to represent 2 different things, rising prices and excess demand, that do not necessarily have to go together in the actual world. The distinction between buyers' inflation and sellers' inflation is related to but is not exactly the same as the distinction between demand inflation and cost inflation. While demand inflation seems to be synonymous with buyers' inflation, cost inflation suggests that there is a difference between cost, on the one hand, and profits, on the other, in their operation on price. This is especially true when the phrases "cost-push inflation" or "wage-cost inflation" are used as synonymous with "cost inflation." The impression is given that the whole of the blame falls on labor or on trade unions. When trade unions raise wages bv more than can be absorbed by increasing productivity, costs rise. The employer then seems to be completely innocent of "profit inflation" in passing on the increase in costs as long as he does not increase his rate of markup, i. e., as long as he does not increase the prices he charges for the product in a greater proportion than his costs have increased. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 259 There is, however, no essential asymmetry between the wage element and the profit element in the price asked for the product. A sellers' inflation could just as well be started by an increase not in the wage asked, but in the percentage of markup of price above cost. Prices would rise and wages would then be raised by workers in attempts to maintain (or restore) their original buying power. Business would then "innocently" raise their prices again only in proportion to the increase in their costs, and we would have the inflation upon us as well as boring discussions about who started it first and the famous chicken and egg. The "who started it first" debate is a complete waste of time because there is no original situation in which there was a "just" or "normal" distribution of the product between wages and profits. Any increase can be seen either as the disturbance which bears the full responsibility for the inflation, or as nothing but the correction of an inequity perpetrated in previous history—all depending on the point of view. The term "sellers' inflation," by treating wages and profits on exactly the same footing, avoids the fruitless game of mutual recrimination. Sellers' inflation takes place whenever wage earners and profit takers together attempt to get shares that amount to more than 100 percent of the selling price. When the sum of what they try to get comes to more than 100 percent of the selling price it is futile to ask whether this is because the wages demanded are too high or whether it is because the profits insisted on are too great. No matter where justice may lie between the 2 claims, the only significant thing for our problem is that the sum of the claims is more than 100 percent. That is what causes the inflation. It is, of course, impossible for the two parties to succeed in getting more than 100 percent of the proceeds between them, but it is precisely on an impossibility such as this that any continuing process depends. Buyers' inflation is similarly built on an attempt to reach the impossible. In that case, it is the attempt of buyers to buy more than 100 percent of the goods than can be made available. Their attempt bids up prices, but since that does not (and cannot) succeed in enabling them to obtain more than 100 percent of the goods that there are available to be got, they continue the attempt and we have the continuing process of buyers' inflation. In our case, the impossibility that generates the process is the attempt of wage earners and profit takers between them to get more than 100 percent of the money proceeds from the sale of the product. Each increases the part he tries to take, by increasing wages or by increasing prices. Since they cannot succeed, they keep on raising wages and prices and so we have the continuing process of sellers' inflation. There is great resistance to recognizing the possibility of sellers' inflation. Sometimes, this takes the form of saying that there must have been some excess buyers' demand or prices could not have risen. This begs the whole question. Since it assumes, without apparently thinking it necessary to provide any support for the assumption, that the only possible cause of rising prices is excess buyers' demand, the argument assumes what it wants to prove. A more sophisticated version of this argument points out that if output shrinks by less than the increase in prices, and this is usually the case during a sellers' inflation, there must have been an increase 2373 1—58 18 260 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH in the total amount spent in buying the output. The arithmetically irrefutable increase in expenditure is then triumphantly exhibited as the excess buyers' demand that is responsible for the inflation. Expenditure is the same thing as buyers' demand, but an increase in expenditure is not the same thing as excess buyers' demand. An increase is not the same thing as an excess. An excess of demand by buyers induces the price increases—it is the cause of the price increases. An increase in expenditure could be induced by—it could be the result of the increases in prices brought about by the pressure of sellers. If there is no increase in expenditure the number of units of goods bought must fall in the same proportion as the price per unit is raised by the sellers. A 10 percent increase in prices would thus result in a fall in output of about 10 percent. This involves depression and unemployment that the authorities naturally seek to remedy by monetary and fiscal measures. Such remedies all involve increases in money expenditure, so that even if only a part of the unemployment is corrected (and this is usually the case because of the authorities' reluctance to undertake inflationary measures when prices are rising), we would observe an increase in total expenditure. Buyers' demand, however, instead of being excessive, could still be deficient, i. e., it could still be insufficient to enable the potential output of the economy to be sold (at the prices demanded by the sellers). An observed increase in total expenditure is therefore no proof that the price rise is due to excess buyers' demand. The increase in expenditure could have been induced by attempts by the authorities to keep down unemployment induced by price increases imposed by the sellers. In a sellers' inflation, an increase in expenditure is perfectly compatible with deficient buyers' demand. A still more sophisticated argument along the same lines goes on to claim that even if prices are being raised by the insistence of sellers rather than by the pressure of buyers, the orthodox measures of reducing total demand would still check the inflation. By reducing total expenditure, or perhaps by merely refusing to permit the increase in total expenditure needed to accommodate the increased prices, the authorities would bring about depression and unemployment. This would stop the sellers from increasing prices. The question then resolves itself into how much unemployment would be necessary to stop the sellers' inflation, and whether it is morally desirable or politically possible for the authorities to induce or permit unemployment of the required volume and duration. I t has been suggested that even if the authorities are not really prepared to bring about the degree of depression necessary to negate the pressure of sellers' inflation, they could still do the trick by solemnly announcing a policy of refusing to provide the increase in expenditure called for by a continuing sellers' inflation. The threatened unemployment would then sober the sellers into calling off their inflationary wage and price increases. I t seems pretty certain first that such declarations would not be believed and that the bluff would quickly be called. But, even if it were believed as regards the economy as a whole, that would not prevent any specific wages or prices from being raised while the local conditions still permitted this. It would perhaps even aggravate the wage and price increases as each tried to get his increase quickly, while the local going was still good. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 261 All this brings us to the perhaps only too obvious conclusion that sellers' inflation cannot be cured or prevented by measures directed against excess demand by buyers. It can be successfully treated only by attacking the pressure on prices by sellers.1 Before we can consider just how one can attack the pressure on prices by sellers, it would be desirable to get a perspective on the whole problem by a quick look at the general theory of inflation and deflation. A somewhat schematic formulation of the development of thought on this subject shows four theoretical models of the operation of the economy. Model A assumes perfectly flexible prices and wages, so that any excess of buyers' demands makes prices and wages rise, and any deficiency of buyers' demand (through the unemployment that results) makes prices and wages fall, until price stability and full employment are restored. Both monetary policy and fiscal policy are unimportant, or even unnecessary. As long as the volume of money is kept fairly stable by some automatic device such as the gold standard, the price level will automatically adjust itself so as to yield full employment with price stability and without inflation. Model B embodies the recognition that we do not have the degree of price flexibility in the downward direction to make complete laissez faire a satisfactory monetary and fiscal policy. Unemployment (caused by deficient buyers' demand) does not reduce the wage and price level quickly enough to the level needed to restore full employment. The process is rather complex. To achieve the task, unemployment must reduce the wage level, and thereby the price level, to the degree necessary to increase the value of the existing stock of money (as each dollar becomes more valuable) to the extent necessary to increase expenditure in real terms (as each dollar spent constitutes more real purchasing power) to the volume necessary to give a satisfactory level of employment. This process can last for years, during which time prices and wages are falling as different resistances to the reductions are gradually overcome. Meanwhile, there continues an expectation of price and wage reductions still to come. This expectation induces investors as well as consumers to postpone their expenditures as long as prices are still falling, so that buyers' demand is reduced still further and the depression can get very much worse before it gets better. The recognition of the nature of such a process leads to the abandonment of laissez faire in monetary and fiscal policy. Instead of 1 In an outstanding article which concentrates on showing the inadequacy and superficiality of proposals to prevent inflation by monetary and fiscal policies and declarations, Prof. Sumner H. Slichter seems to suggest that the distinction between buyers' inflation and sellers' in^ation is a futile fantasy. Thus he says (using a somewhat different terminology), "Much time has been wasted in recent years in discussing whether inflation is demand inspired or cost inspired. (Some 70 or 80 years ago, the Austrian theory of value produced a similar debate as to whether demand or cost determines the value; the argument ended suddenly when it dawned on the economists that each blade in a pair of scissors cuts)" (On the Side of Inflation. Harvard Business Review, September/October 11)57, p. 32). However, the inapplicability of this analogy jumps to the eye in his very next sentence which shows that it can make sense to distinguish between the blades, since he goes on to say. "Thus changes in the price level may originate either with shifts in the demand schedules or with shifts in the supply schedules," and in another article. Professor Slichter definitely alines himself with the sellers' inflation blade in declaring t h a t : "There is no evidence that prices are rising ahead of costs and are pulling costs up. The evidence is all the other way: that prices are being sluggishly adjusted to slowly rising costs" (Government Spending Can Reduce Taxes. Harvard Business Review, July/August 1957, p. 106). 262 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH waiting for the price level to fall until it has adjusted itself to the volume of money expenditure, a policy is developed of adjusting the volume of money expenditure to the existing price level, so as to reach and maintain a satisfactory level of employment at the current prices. This switch from laissez faire to an active monetary and fiscal policy is also applied in the opposite direction to deal with excess buyers' demand. Although there is not the same resistance to price and wage increases as there is to price and wage decreases, the necessary adjustment to excess buyers' demand by rising prices still takes time. It is no instantaneous adjustment (if only because of the existence of long-term contracts, and because of attempts to stop profiteering by preventing the necessary price increases) and so it causes disturbances that are unjust and reduce the efficiency of the economy. The policy is therefore applied in both directions, providing for increasing the volume of money expenditure whenever necessary to prevent or correct an insufficiency of buyers7 demand; and for decreasing the volume of money expenditure whenever that is necessary to prevent or correct an excess of buyers' demand. The volume of expenditure may be adjusted either by working on the stock of money (by monetary policy) or by working on the velocity of circulation of money (by fiscal policy), or by some combination of the two. Model B, which is, of course, the Keynesian general theory of employment policy, differs from model A primarily in incorporating a policy of increasing or decreasing demand, if it should become too little or too great. (It has a steering wheel to keep the car on the road.) Because of this difference, a secondary distinction arises. With policy coming into the picture, it becomes important which of two instruments of policy is to be used, monetary policy or fiscal policy. Model B makes use of both instruments. (The car can use either kerosene or gasoline.) Model C is not really a new model. It rather consists of a series of publicity releases of model B dolled up to emphasize one or another of its qualities as if this were a new invention that made model B obsolete. One very crude pamphlet of this series emphasizes the ability of model C to cut down on demand, if it becomes excessive or threatens to become excessive, seeming to imply that model B was a depression model, which could work only in the direction of increasing demand, if it became deficient or threatened to become deficient. (Model C has a steering wheel that can be turned to the right.) A more refined variant of model C, let us call it model C*, is concerned with the relative effectiveness of monetary policy and of fiscal policy in different circumstances. An economy may be so saturated with money so that further increases in the stock of money would not be effective in increasing expenditure^ and reductions in the stock would have no significant effect in reducing total expenditure. (This is sometimes expressed, though not explained, by saying that changes in the money supply would be offset by opposing changes in the velocity of circulation.) Monetary policy is then useless and expenditure can be increased or decreased only by fiscal policy—by the Government increasing or decreasing its own expenditure, e. g. on public works, or permitting others to spend more by reducing taxes or forcing them to spend less by increasing taxes. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 263 It is then suggested that model B works only in this case which is called the Keynesian case. It should more properly be called Keynesian special case (of the Keynesian general theory) when it is appropriate to concentrate entirely on fiscal measures to increase or decrease expenditure on consumption and investment. (Only gasoline can be used.) In this kind of situation, even extreme price flexibility is unable to restore or maintain the desired level of real demand, because it operates, after all, as nothing but a roundabout way of increasing or decreasing the real volume of money in terms of buying power. It is a kind of automatic monetary policy which is useless for the same reasons as other monetary policy is useless, when the economy is so saturated with money that changing the quantity has no appreciable effect. When the economy is at the other extreme from being saturated with money, and money is very tight, the situation is naturally reversed. Fiscal measures for increasing expenditure on consumption or investment are ineffective, because an increase in expenditure anywhere in the economy, say in Government expenditure on public works, results in an increase in demand for money to hold in connection with the increased volume of transactions. In the very tight money situation, this raises the rate of interest, or in some other way reduces expenditure somewhere else. Similarly, a decrease in expenditure anywhere releases holdings of money which permit an increase of expenditure somewhere else. Fiscal policy then is helpless, and what is called for is monetary policy to increase or decrease the money supply. (Only kerosene can be used.) This case is then called the Classical Case, as if it were one in which the Keynesian theory does not apply and where model B should be replaced by model C* (which can burn kerosene). This case should more properly be called the Classical Special Case (of the Keynesian general theory). The Keynesian theory (model B) covers both situations in which fiscal policy is strategic (when model B uses gasoline), and situations in which monetary policy is strategic (when model B uses kerosene), as well as the more normal situations when both policies are effective {when model B can make use of both fuels, mixing the proportions to suit the terrain). Model D is a genuinely different model, in which unemployment not only fails to make prices and wages fall quickly enough to serve as a cure for the unemployment, but is even unable to prevent prices and wages from continuing to rise. When we have strong trade unions with the power to raise wages, strong corporations with the power to set prices administratively, and a general atmosphere in which it is considered normal, natural and only fair for wages to be increased regularly, and by amounts greater than the average increase in productivity or in the share of the product that labor can obtain, prices increase, and the economy is subject to sellers' inflation. It is now no longer a question of whether fiscal policy or monetary policy is more effective m regulating the volume of buyers' demand or expenditure, since the inflation is caused not by excess buyers' demand, but by the existence of powerful institutions and mores that enable sellers to insist on and obtain continually higher prices. The widespread and generous feeling that workers are entitled to the increases 264 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH in wages that they get is made much easier by a, recognition that any raise need not be taken out of profits, since it is possible, as well as proper, to "pass it along" to the ultimate purchaser in higher prices. Indeed, it is usually considered only right that profits, in dollars, should be increased so as to protect real profits from the declining value of the dollar. We have already mentioned the argument that a really firm refusal on the part of the monetary authorities to prevent the volume of money from increasing, no matter what happened, would bring the sellers to their senses. Eealizing, or discovering, that they will not be able to sell so much if they raise their prices, they will refrain from raising prices, and they will not grant, or ask for, wage increases that raise costs by more than can be squeezed out of profits. There are several reasons why this is not practical. In the first place, the policy of firmly or obstinately holding the money supply constant does not prevent excess buyers' demand from coming about. It does not even prevent an increase in total expenditure. This is because the policy of holding the money supply constant is essentially a kind of monetary policy, and we may be in the Keynesian special case where monetary policy is not effective. That we are at the present time in such a situation is suggested by the fact that, while the supply of money has been held fairly stable in recent years, the volume of expenditure has continually increased. (Another way of expressing this, which is more common perhaps because it sounds like an explanation, is to say that the velocity of circulation has increased and that this has frustrated the restrictive monetary policy.) There is, of course, a limit to the degree to which expenditure can increase without an accompanying increase in the money stock, and if the inflation were a buyers' inflation it would come to an end when this limit was reached (i. e., when the velocity of circulation could not increase any more). But where the inflation is a sellers' inflation, it does not stop at that point. After the increase in prices has absorbed all the increase in expenditure that is compatible with a constant money stock (i. e., that can be attributed to an increase in the velocity of circulation) it continues to increase. The increase in prices goes on further until it has reduced real expenditure and employment sufficiently to overcome the institutional forces that enable sellers to demand higher and higher prices. The question is how strong are these institutions ? or, in other words, how severe a state of depression and unemployment would have to be maintained in order to destroy these institutions or to induce sellers not to use their power to raise prices; and how able and willing the authorities would be to bring about and maintain this degree of depression and unemployment ? The continuing increase in wages and prices in the present depression would be some indication that it would require quite a severe and prolonged depression to change people's notions of what is the proper development of wage rates (and of the corresponding prices, since the right of wages to increase goes together with the right of profits at least not to fall). It would take perhaps an even more severe level of unemployment to destroy the power of labor to force the wage increases on more reluctant employers who grant wage increases only when they feel they are forced to—i. e., that they would lose more from the strikes and other weapons of the trade unions than they would lose by agreeing to the higher wages (and passing them on). ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 265 At the same time, a policy of full employment seems to have won a firm place in the country's economic policy (even though its application may be rather shaky), not only because of the general acceptance of the desirability of prosperity, for human as well as for international political reasons, but because neither political party can afford the blame for even a mild depression. With such a setup, there is no need to worry whether the cure is worse than the disease—whether the depression would be more harmful than the inflation that it would prevent. This cure is not one that any government would carry out or even seriously attempt to carry out. None of the problems of sellers' inflation or of inflationary depression could arise in a perfectly competitive economy, because in a perfectly competitive economy, we cannot have the institutions and mores that give sellers the power to push prices uj). In a perfectly competitive economy, all that is needed for stability of the price level is a monetary and fiscal policy to keep buyers' demand from becoming either excessive or deficient. No one holds back any product from the market—or can establish a price which results in some of the potential product or the available labor not being taken off the market, so that unless there is excess buyers' demand, prices cannot rise, and if there is a deficient buyers' demand, prices must fall. Unless there is full utilization of resources, we cannot have inflation, and if there is a depression (or recession), we will have deflation (i. e., falling prices). In a perfectly competitive economy, we cannot have inflation and depression at the same time. But where prices are administered by decrees of large firms, and wages are administered by joint decrees of powerful unions, together with powerful employers or employer groups, the situation is different. Sellers' inflation is a byproduct of the process; and, together with sellers' inflation, we can also have depression—indeed we will have depression with our sellers' inflation, just to the degree that the authorities try to cure the inflation by reducing ("excess") demand. In an economy where there are both administered and competitive sectors, the phenomenon of sellers' inflation can spill over from the administered to the competitive part. It can even happen that the contagion of sellers' inflation in the competitive sector is more pronounced than in the administered sector. There is then a tendency to assume that the sellers' inflation thesis has thereby been disproved. Actually, this does not prove anything either way in the debate that can rage as to whether the inflation is a sellers' inflation or a buyers' inflation. The contagion can be explained as follows. Prices and wages being raised in the administered sector but not in the competitive sector, there will be a switch in demand from the products of the administered sector to the products of the competitive sector. There is then a deficiency of demand in the administered sector and an excess of demand in the competitive sector. With factors of production immobile, there is unemployment in the administered sector, but there it does not cause either prices or wages to fall so that the unemployment persists. Attempts to reduce total spending, so as to check the rise in the overall price level, would increase still further the unemployment in the administered sector (while removing some, or all, of the excess demand in the competitive sector). Pressure is then put on the Government 266 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH to alleviate the depression; and, in doing so, it must create enough demand to maintain the higher price level in both sectors. As the economy gets used to such a process, in which wages and prices are rising all the time, an increase in strategic or key prices or wage rates in the administered sector come to be recognized all over the economy as presaging a general rise in prices. The competitive sector then does not wait for the excess demand to appeal. Its workers demand higher wages, its employers expect to be able to get the higher prices out of which to be able to pay the higher wages, and they grant the increases and raise the prices. They do not have to go into the calculations of what output and elaborate price maximize profit. They have the businessman's rough rule of thumb of a more or less traditional markup on their cost. This brings them straight away to the position that would be reached after the excess demand has materialized and has been validated and adjusted by the monetary policy undertaken by the authorities to cure or prevent the unemployment threatened by the increase in wages and prices in the administered sector. The economist is tempted to draw diagrams showing the point of maximum profits of a firm, competitive or monopolist, and to demonstrate, in classical vein, that an increase in wages will move that point to the left, reducing the optimum output of the firm and causing the firm to restrict output and to raise the price by less than the increase in cost. This should cause unemployment which, in the competitive sector, would restore the previous price and wage levels. The sellers' inflation has disappeared into thin air. The answer to this, in classical vein, is that the demand will not remain the same, because the phenomenon is not happening only to an individual firm (in which case it would be proper to assume the conditions of demand to be unchanged), but that the monetary and fiscal authorities, in providing additional overall demand to cure or prevent the unemployment in the administered sector, will raise every demand curve so that the firm will be able to sell as much as before and provide the same employment as before, even though the price is sufficiently higher to enable the higher wage to be paid. Profits, or the gap between cost and price, will also be higher, of course, although in real terms, allowing for the fall in the value of the dollar, everything will be just the same as in the beginning. The answer in the businessman's language is that he has to increase his price in proportion to the increase in costs, in applying his regular markup; and his experience is that since this is happening to everybody, including his competitors, and employment in the country is more or less being maintained, he will be able to pass it on to the consumer. Although the infection starts with the administered sector of the economy, there is no reason why the epidemic should not hit the competitive (and nonadministered monopolistic) sectors of the economy sometimes more severely and sometimes less severely than it hits the administered sector. This is why th$ observation that prices rise more or rise less in the unadministered sector than in the administered sector proves nothing at all either way as to whether the inflation is a buyers' inflation or a sellers' inflation But only a sellers' inflation is compatible with a depression. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 267 The inflation and the inflationary depression that result from administered wages and prices have important similarities to, and are no less socially harmful than, the monopolistic exploitation that would result from the administration of excessive prices by public utilities. We have gone a long way toward eliminating the latter evil by the regulation of prices that may be set by public utilities for the services they supply. The same kind of device can be used to eliminate the former evil. Just as the public utility prices can be and are being regulated so as to prevent monopolistic exploitation, so administered prices and wages can and should be regulated, so as to prevent sellers' inflation and the depression it may bring with it. The regulation of administered prices and wages so as to prevent sellers' inflation would have to follow somewhat different lines. It would not be directly concerned as to whether there is more than or less than a fair rate of return on investments. That would be left to the strong competitive forces that still prevail in our economy. Nor would any other regulations whatsoever be involved other than price regulation. The function of the regulation here proposed would be only to prevent restrictive prices or wages from being administered. A restrictive price is one that results in the demand for a product falling below capacity output. A restrictive wage is one that results in less than full employment in the specific labor market to which it applies. With a monetary and fiscal policy concentrating on the maintenance of adequate buyers' demand for full employment at a constant price level, while preventing buyers' inflation, it would be possible for wages per hour to rise on the average at the same rate as productivity per hour, with aggregate profits rising too at the same pace as aggregate wages and aggregate output, (except that increases in the degree of competition, which might be induced, could reduce the share going to profits and increase the share going to labor). The regulatory body would therefore have to follow a set of rules which would do the following things: (1) They would permit an administered price increase only when production and sales are at capacity. Such price increases should not be withheld on account of profits being high. (2) They would enforce decreases in administered prices whenever production and sales are significantly below capacity. A price decrease should not be waived on account of profits being low, or even negative on this item in the firm's output, as long as the price more than covers current operating costs (more strictly short period marginal costs). (3) They would permit increases in administered wages in general at a rate equal to the average trend of increase in national productivity. (4) They would permit increases in administered wages greater than this wherever the labor market is tight—with say less than half the national average rate of unemployment. (5) They would permit only smaller increases in administered wages, or no increases at all, where the labor market is slack— with say more than twice the national average rate of unemployment. (The expected continuing increase m product per head makes it possible to avoid reductions in money wages although it is unavoidable, for price stability, that some prices must fall if others rise.) 268 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH This is, of course, not a fully worked out solution ready for immediate application. There remains much to be developed—such as generally acceptable criteria of capacity of different firms and industries and generally acceptable measures of slackness or tightness in particular labor markets, or measures for dealing with possible attempts by monopolistic industries to restrict the installation of capacity, if they are prevented from restricting the utilization of existing capacity. (This would bring out the existence of a specific monopoly situation that calls for treatment quite apart from the problem of inflation.) The intensification of competition which the regulation would enforce would also, in some instances, lead to the elimination of high cost competitors. While the public would benefit from the increased efficiency of the economy—in higher wages and lower prices—such elimination of competition would conflict with certain existing so-called antitrust policies that have become in effect anticompetition policies and need to be reconsidered. There remain also important problems of organization and administration of the regulatory body, as well as the need for widespread and intensive public discussion to bring about the familiarity with, and the understanding of, the nature of the proposed regulation which is essential for its effective operation in a democracy. And in the course of such examination and debate, important developments, changes and improvements are to be expected. Nevertheless, the general lines indicated seem to be inevitable if sellers5 inflation is to be attacked directly and if we are not to depend on irrelevant nostrums or pious exhortation because we do not dare to attack the problem at its roots. THE DESTABILIZING INFLUENCE OF RAW MATERIALS PRICES Ruth P. Mack, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. Spot prices and other prices of many raw materials fluctuate in a sensitive and extreme fashion. They are at the tail end of the price structure and swing widely. The question that I want to explore is the extent to which the tail wags the dog and, particularly, thereby helps to drive him uphill. To put the matter in another way, is it possible that the response of all prices to swings in sensitive prices tends, under conditions that presently characterize our economy, to foster an upward trend in the price level ? It seems highly probable that the answer is "Yes." SUMMARY OF THE ARGUMENT Over the past decade and in earlier years, as well, the prices of manufactured goods have tended to show an upward trend relative to those of the raw materials of which they are constituted. Increases in labor costs do not account for the growing spread. Doubtless, more extensive processing, packaging, and increased distributing costs, and certain social costs borne by the manufacturer, have filled the gap. But in spite of their diminishing importance over considerable stretches of years, it seems probable that the gyrations of raw materials have contributed materially both to the fluctuation and to the upward trend in the price level. The reason is that, on the one hand, their extreme fluctuations are transmitted to later stages of production. On the other hand, the price of fabricated goods responds more agilely to a rise in crude materials prices than to a fall. Sensitive materials prices, in other words, operate on the price level like a rachet jack. Change in the price of crude materials, like any cost, affects the price of the fabricated product. It also affects other prices by influencing expectations about prospects for prices and delivery conditions. The resultant change in short term demand-supply relationships affects prices at the later as well as at the earlier stages of production through which the basic product passes to the final consumer. It is the contention of this paper that these two avenues whereby the price of crude demand-oriented materials influence other prices— the avenues of cost and of their implication in buying or inventory waves—join to cause rises in crude prices to be promptly and liberally reflected in rises in other prices. However, the rigidities of other aspects of the cost structure, along with common interpretations of the influence of price reductions on short-term demand, cause the response to falling sensitive prices to be far less wholehearted. 269 270 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH In view of the built-in resistance to downward pressures, reduction of upward movements is in the public interest. The analysis of process has implications about how such reduction might be achieved. THREE CHARACTERISTICS OF THE TEMPORAL ASSOCIATION OF RAW- AND PROCESSED-GOODS PRICES Chart I shows an index of spot-market prices of 13 industrial commodities. They include scrap prices for copper, lead and steel scrap, tin, zinc, print cloth, cotton, wool tops, burlap, hides, tallow, rosin, and rubber. Just below it is the Bureau of Labor Statistics' price index for wholesale prices of crude materials other than foods and fuels. This index covers the many such items priced by the Bureau and weights them according to their sales to manufacturers. The third line is the Bureau of Labor Statistics' index of wholesale prices of intermediate materials. The fourth covers all manufactured commodities other than farm and food products. Correspondence in cyclical fluctuation The chart shows that many of the fluctuations in any one series are also found at about the same time in the others; these common movements are marked by an X placed at their peak and trough months. (Other not generally shared reversals in direction are marked by O, and are discussed later.) The correspondence lessens as the eye moves down the chart, but even where the locations of maximums and minimums are not found at the same time in raw and in processed goods there seems to be a good bit of almost immediate response at the intermediate stage to price changes of crude materials. The association is clearer in rate of change. For individual commodities, of course, the association is considerably closer in spite of the fact that price indexes of partly finished or finished goods are notoriously imprecise images of the prices (including allowances for changes in terms and quality) at which sales are actually made. CHART I. INDEXES OF WHOLESALE PRICES OF COMMODITIES AND MANUFACTURED GOODS OTHER THAN FOODS (1947-49=100) 13 Spot Market Conmodities O I a s to 19W 19^9 1950 1951 1952 1953 195^ 1955 1956 1957 272 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Greater amplitude of fluctuation in crude-materials prices The chart also shows that spot prices move more widely than all crude non-food-materials prices and a great deal more widely than wholesale prices of goods that have undergone manufacturing processes. If, for each series, we add the falls from the peak to the subsequent trough to the rise from the trough to the subsequent peak (turns marked with X on the chart), the average rise or fall per month for spot prices is 2.4 percent of the level in 1947-49. The corresponding figure (excluding foods throughout) for crude materials is 1.2; for intermediate goods, 0.6; for all manufactured goods, 0.4; and for finished manufactured goods, 0.3. Crude materials other than foods constituted in 1947 about 6.9 percent of the value of the sales of all industries other than food industries. If we exclude the duplication of sales among manufacturing industries, crude materials constitute about 18.5 percent of shipments other than foods to the final-demand sectors such as export, Government, gross private capital formation and consumers. The relatively heavy fluctuation of crude prices can account for a very large proportion—an average of 57 percent—of the cyclical fluctuation of the price of finished manufactured goods other than foods during the 11 years, 1947-57.1 Upward trend in processed—relative to crude-materials prices Over stretches of years there has been a tendency for prices of fabricated products to rise more (or fall less) than those of the crude materials of which they are made. Information for two periods may be reviewed. Continuous indexes, those shown in chart 1, are available beginning January 1947. They show price trends after the immediate disruptions of wartime controls and decontrols have spent their force. From January 1947 to December 1957 the index of spot-market prices showed a net fall of 15 percent of the 1947-49 level. (Taken to its peak at the end of 1955, there was a net fall of 10 percent.) All crude material other than food and fuel rose 16 percent of their 194749 level, labor cost per unit of output rose about 15 percent and, even if calculated along a trend line that covers 25 years (on the assumption that employers tried to adjust for wartime changes), rose only about 27 percent of the 1947-49 level during the last 11 years. The price index of all manufactured goods other than foods, on the other hand, rose 34 percent of the 1947-49 average, and of finished manufactured goods other than foods, 33 percent. 1 1 am indebted to Beatrice Vaccara for providing the estimates of the proportion that crude materials constitute of gross and net manufacturers' shipments, as explained in the text. To estimate the percentage of cyclical fluctuation in finished-goods prices that can be due to fluctuation in crude materials, I add the cyclical rises to the falls ("rises" and "falls" are marked by X in chart 1) in crude materials prices and apply it to the crude sector—18.5 cents on 100 cents' worth of finished goods. This accounts for 57 percent of the rises and falls (analogously marked) in the price of finished manufactured goods other than foods. This figure for the whole period averages very different relations for each expansion and contraction. For contractions, the figures are a great deal higher than for expansions. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 273 The differential trend of raw and manufactured goods prices after World War I I was not the result of 1 or 2 freak movements, nor of differences in the date at which turns occurred, nor of the behavior of labor costs. Comparing movements that are shown as matched on chart I, the ratio of rises in spot-market prices to corresponding ones in margin over labor costs 2 is always larger during contractions than during previous and following expansions in spite of the fact that expansions in manufactured prices were usually longer than in raw materials and contractions shorter. This was also true when crude materials, rather than spot prices, were compared with margins. Another way of describing these relations is to say that when spot prices or crude-materials prices rose, manufacturers raised prices more, even after allowing for the probable increase in labor costs, than they lowered prices when materials prices fell, assuming that here, too, they would wish to allow for the movement of labor costs. Failure to allow for labor costs increases the difference. It would be useful to test whether the same tendency appeared for matched pairs of prices for particular industries. But I have not tried to assemble these comparisons for the postwar decade. There is, however, an interesting group of well-matched prices for raw products and finished-goods prices for 18 industries, 1913 to 1935. These annual figures were collected by Solomon Fabricant many years ago. They, like the aggregate data for the recent decade, exhibit the tendency for finished prices to rise more over the years than the price of the major constituent, crude materials. Figures are given in table I. They make rough estimates of trends by using trough-to-trough measurements. Ratios over 1.00 in columns 2, 4, and 6 indicate the presence of the lesser trend change of crude materials. The second column shows that this differential trend occurred in 15 of the 18 industries over the 20 years between about 1913 and 1933. Labor costs could not have been responsible, since cost per unit seems to have been about the same at the two dates. Columns 4 and 6 show that the same differential trend was present in 15 or 16 of the 18 industries when additional trough-to-trough measures are used to break the period into change during and after World War I. 2 The allowance for labor costs was based on changes in a 12month moving average of production-worker payrolls per unit of output as estimated in Productivity, Prices, and Incomes, materials prepared for the Joint Economic Committee by the committee staff, table 52. In determining margin, it was assumed that labor cost constituted 40 percent of the total cost of manufacturing. 274 TABLE ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH I.—Trend in prices of manufactured goods compared to that in prices of crude materials, 18 industries, 1913-38 Prewar trough to 1932-33 trough i Prewar trough to postwar trough i Postwar trough to 1932-33 trough i Ratio, Ratio, prices of prices of Percent manufac- Percent manufac- Percent change tured goods change tured goods change to crude to crude materials materials (1) Bread and products Flour and grain mill products Butter, cheese, and processed milkMilk, raw at farm Meat packing products Livestock and poultry Sugar, granulated Sugar, raw Tobacco pr- ducts Tobacco leaf Cotton goods Cotton, raw __. Woolen and worsted goods Wool, raw Silk hose Silk, raw Boots and shoes Hides and skins Auto tires and tubes Rubber, crude Paper Wood pulp Fertilizers, mixed Fertilizer materials Petroleum products Petroleum, crude Linseed oil and meal Flaxseed Simple processed iron and steel Pig iron Copper products Copper ingots. Lead pipe Pig lead Zinc sheet Zinc slab 140.0 55.0 77.5 70.9 89.6 63.1 93.7 83.5 128.0 51.7 118.9 64.2 113.9 60.6 64.4 45.6 158.0 39.4 26.4 5.4 154.0 82.8 76.5 84.2 66.3 121.8 103.2 87.6 128.1 131.7 64.8 41.6 115.3 82.0 117.1 61.7 (2) (3) 2.55 1.09 1.28 1.12 2.48 1.85 1.88 1.41 4.01 4.89 1.86 .91 .54 1.18 .97 1.56 1.41 1.90 171.0 119.5 137.4 137.0 123.8 113.6 139.2 133.3 176.8 169.7 198.9 148.2 178.5 107.1 157.1 177.2 180.0 83.8 74.4 25.4 180.0 129.0 141.2 130.6 158.7 281.8 151.7 137.1 155.1 177.6 104.3 94.2 125.6 117.6 107.3 97.5 (5) (4) 1.43 1.00 1.09 1.04 1.04 1.34 1.67 .89 2.15 2.93 1.40 1.08 .56 1.11 .87 1.11 1.07 1.10 81.9 46.0 56.4 51.8 65.1 55.5 67.3 62.6 72.4 30.5 59.8 43.3 63.8 56.6 41.0 25.7 87.8 47.0 35.5 21.3 85.6 64.2 54.2 64.5 41.8 43.2 68.0 63.9 82.6 74.2 62.2 44.1 91.8 69.7 109.1 63.3 Ratio, prices of manufactured goods to crude materials (6) 1.78 1.09 1.17 1.08 2.37 1.38 1.13 1.60 1.87 1.67 1.33 .84 .97 1.06 1.11 1.41 1.32 1.72 1 The prewar trough was located at the lowest figure reached by each index, 1913 to 1915, inclusive. The postwar trough wasjocated at the lowest figure reached by each index, 1921 to 1922. Source: National Bureau of Economic Research; compilations of annual price indexes, 1913 to 1935. T H E CAUSAL ASSOCIATION B E T W E E N PRICES OF CRUDE, D E M A N D - O R I E N T E D M A T E R I A L S A N D PRICES OF PROCESSED GOODS The fact that raw materials have tended to rise less over the years than the prices of fabricated goods may seem to absolve them from responsibility as a potential inflationary force. But to do so is, I believe, to misunderstand the process whereby raw, particularly spot market, prices affect other prices. We live in a world in which there are few free competitive markets in the sense defined in Economics IA. Most prices, at least for processed goods, respond to other forces as well as to those of free competition. Businessmen make explicit decisions about them; product prices are in part "administered." Changes in crude materials prices bear on the character of decisions about product prices. In the context of this investigation, the point of chief interest is that they are likely to bear in a somewhat different way when prices are going up and when they are going down. To describe the character of this difference, it is necessary to concentrate ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 275 on sensitive prices for which changes in demand rather than extreme changes in supply are the primary source of usual market variation. A large proportion of basic industrial materials are of this sort. Characteristically, prices tend to rise and fall with rises and falls in orders and output. To see how this fact, and some others that I shall mention, bear on pricing strategy, it is necessary to consider two chief ways in which materials prices can affect product prices. Crude materials as a cost Raw materials are first and foremost a cost of production. When raw materials prices rise, the price of the goods in which they are incorporated must also rise if profits are not to be reduced. The amount that they need to rise depends on the relative importance of raw materials in the cost structure and what is happening to other costs. Say materials are 30 percent of the total cost of an article that sells for a dollar. Suppose other costs do not change and materials rise by4 10 percent. Then profits can be shielded by a rise of only 3 percent. I want to underscore the character of this calculation; it is the absolute change in a cost that must be recovered, not its percentage change. The change in finished prices that is likely to accompany a given rise or fall in materials prices depends in part on whether other costs are likely to be rising or falling at the same time. In recent years, labor cost seems to have risen, at least over a good part of the time, when materials prices rose, though its relation to cyclical fluctuation is not very systematic. But for goods whose basic materials prices parallel changes in demand, one type of cost does bear a systematic relation to the price of materials—the overhead or burden type of expense. Since these expenses are not a function of the months' or often even the years' output, they tend to represent a larger cost per unit when output is low than when it is high. Industry has also tended to add to other costs when opportunity arose—those associated with further processing of product, packaging, research, marketing and the like. These facts suggest that it might be wise strategy to raise finished prices, when raw materials prices and demand rise, by more than the sum of the increase in materials cost plus any increase in actual labor costs and minus the decrease that had been experienced in actual per unit burden and overhead expense. The extra recovered margin would then provide for expected further increase in labor cost and changes in product, in distribution and the like—changes believed to strengthen the competitive position of the company. When materials prices and output decline, the fact that overhead expense per unit is increasing is a reason for prices not to decline by the absolute amount of the decline in materials. I have analyzed how sensible business pricing policy might generate a stipulated association of changes in the price of crude and of processed materials. But why should the asymmetrical association to rises and to falls in materials costs be attributed to fluctuation in materials prices any more than to the character of the other costs and the drive to improve product and strengthen competitive advantage? Of course, it is foolish to isolate any one factor in a total situation and say it governs the rest. I claim merely that sensitive demand4 Ten percent of 30 cents is 3 cents. 23734—58 19 Three cents is 3 percent of a dollar. 276 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH oriented raw materials prices play a more important role in the causal nexus than their position as cost justifies. One reason for this is their publicity value. Since, these days, pricing policy is defended at the labor bargaining table, at the lecturn and in the press, publicly reported costs—those of materials prices—that are rising swiftly provide a valuable talking point. But a more important reason for assigning materials prices a strategic role in this process is a second avenue of impact of these prices on those of processed goods. Materials prices and buying waves The prices of demand-oriented sensitive raw materials, particularly prices quoted daily on open markets, provide a basis for expectations about market conditions. The expectation involves delivery conditions, selections, and price, and, typically, all three factors change together. A change in the price of a sensitive crude material often bespeaks changes in supply conditions in markets in which the crude material, semifinished goods made from it, and often even finished goods are bought by manufacturer or distributor. The appropriate response to an expectation that prices will rise, deliveries lengthen, or selections thin is that of extending the number of weeks' supply of materials held on hand and on order. A fall in the price of crude materials can have the opposite implications at any or all stages of a vertical sequence of production operations. Needless to say, the buying associated with optimistic expectations influences the price of the raw product just as changes in its price, via the expectations based upon it, influence buying. Moreover the process as a whole is affected by conditions of final demand. These processes, like most social processes, are partly circular. The point is simply that this circular process is one that links sensitive prices, via buying waves for intermediate goods, to the prices of manufactured goods. Price fluctuation in raw commodities is increased by the buying waves and fluctuations of finished prices are also thereby increased. I shall come next to why the upward fluctuations may well ba more augmented than the downward one, but, first, can one demonstrate the association of sensitive prices and buying waves? As evidence on this point I submit three charts. The first applies to hide prices in the interwar years. The monthly course of hide prices was "predicted" by two variables: (1) Shipments of leather to leather-goods manufacturers and (2) a ratio depicting what may be thought of as a tug-of-war between buyer and seller to acquire inventories of hides and of leather. I call it the "stock-location ratio"; purchased and in-process inventories (leather in the hands of leathergoods manufacturers and raw or in-process hides in the hands of tanners) are divided by finished stocks (leather in the hands of tanners and hides in the hands of packers and dealers). The ratio depicts the efforts—stronger at some times than at others—of customers to buy stocks away from sellers. The calculations indicate that these efforts have an important impact on hide prices, just as expectations about hide prices must influence buying behavior. CHART II. CONTRIBUTION OF EACH TWO VARIABLES TO THE ESTIMATION OP HIDE PRICES, 1922-39 1 Dollars ptr hide Dollars per htdt O o I 8 g a 1922 1923 1924 1925 1926 1927 1928 1929 1930 Estimated prices are computed by the following formulas developed by the method of least squares : 1922-31 : P=— 3.98 + 6.089 i2+1.657# 1932-39 : P=— 2.46 + 2.534 12+2.4435 where P is price per hide in dollars R is the stock-location ratio S is leather shipments by tanners in millions of equivalent hides. 1 1932 1933 1934 1935 1936 1937 1938 1939 Coefficients of multiple correlation a r e : 1922-31, 0.86 ; 1932-39, 0.81. Regression coefficients exceed their standard errors of estimate by between 6 and 18 times for the two values of the two variables. Source: Consumption and Business Fluctuations: A Case Study of the Shoe, Leather Hide Sequence, by Ruth P. Mack, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1956, pp. 225, 226. 1931 to 278 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Similarity in the course erf stocks, orders, and prices is also indicated in charts I I I and IV. Chart I I I makes comparisons for a group of semidurable industries. In the first 2 lines, an index of 9 spot prices may be compared with orders received by the manufacturers but not yet shipped to their customers. Unfilled orders, of course, increase as buyers try to provide further ahead; they decline as buyers return to a hand-to-mouth position. The third line is the stock-location ratio—purchased materials and in-process stocks of semidurable-goods manufacturers divided by their finished-goods stocks. Chart IV shows just the same three series for manufacturers of primary metals. In general, the three series seem to show a strong similarity within the industry sequence and. sharp differences when the two sets of prices are compared.5 Similar differences apply to the two sets of unfilled orders and to the stock-location ratios. Note how the semidurable series all decline throughout 1948 whereas metals do not decline sharply until the beginning of 1949. The 1949 trough is earlier and sharper in the semidurable group than in two of the metals series. The post-Korean peak is sharp and occurs early in 1951 in semidurable manufacture. In metals it spreads out through much of 1952 as the huge defense contracts stimulate the metals industries, though price ceilings affected the course of prices in 1951. The trough in both sets of data seems to locate in 1954, but the nondurable group rises to a peak in 1955 and starts to decline, whereas metals continue to rise well into 1956. It seems proper to conclude that the charts suggest an intimacy between buying waves and the most sensitive prices in the vertical sequences of industries concerned. I have little doubt that finer analytic tools and deeper understanding of the process would make it possible to sharpen the demonstration. 5 To some extent the price series is an element in the other two, but its influence could not be responsible for the basic similarities. The spot prices included in the price index apply at most to only a small part of the purchased stock since these are purchases at all stages of manufacture and of all materials that are used. The raw materials deflators calculated by the Department of Commerce have far gentler contours than the spot price indexes. In the stock-location ratio, the presence of a price element in both numerator and denominator further reduces the impact of prices on the course of the ratio. CHART III. PRICES AND INDICATORS OF BUYING WAVES IN SEMI-DURABLE-GOODS INDUSTRIES 9 Spot Market Prices (scale at left) if t o - ffrr-ft O 1 M Unfilled Orders (scale at right) 3000 MIL td — 2000 o Stock-Location Ratio (scale at left) \ 19^6 19^9 1950 1951 1952 1953 195^ 1955 1956 to 1957 280 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH i ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 281 Asymmetry in the response to rises and to falls of crude prices I come now to why sensitive materials prices seem to have a special responsibility in furthering an upward trend in price. The reason involves why their upward fluctuations are more willingly reflected in selling prices than their downward ones. The causal association between prices of crude, demand-oriented materials and prices of processed goods involves materials as an element in cost, that is, the relation of rises and falls in materials costs to the total cost structure. It concerns also the association between sensitive prices and buying waves for those commodities for which supply factors are not subject to abrupt autonomous change—demandoriented sensitive prices. Changes in prices arouse expectation about further change; buying intended to lengthen or shorten market positions results at any or all of the vertically related stages; buying affects prices. Thus the buying wave, more popularly called an inventory cycle, is inextricably involved with sensitive materials prices. It is involved in several ways. The first way involves the effect on demand of a change in price. We know from Economics A l that the maximization of utility implies that a rise in price alienates demand and a fall stimulates it, other things the same. The previous section indicated how "other things" undergo systematic shifts because of price-associated expectations. A man will buy materials to lengthen his market position when he expects markets to tighten; he will buy less when he expects them to slacken. My point now is a further one: he is more willing to pass on the rise than the fall in materials prices to his own customers because he expects the demand of his customers to be, like his, stimulated by an expected rise and discouraged by an expected fall in price (providing, of course, he believes that his competitors, having experienced the same buying problems as he has, will handle their selling problems in the same way). Thus he has two reasons for raising prices—the fact that costs have increased; the fact that he expects that short-term demand will, if anything, be stimulated rather than repelled. The impetus to pass on a fall in costs ordinarily comes more from the pressure of the buyer than from the spontaneous wish of the seller. This is true particularly since the argument of the previous paragraph applies in reverse—a price reduction in and of itself can be expected to discourage expectation-related demand. But the sellers' resistance to reducing prices may be paralleled by less than insistent pressure to do so on the part of his customers. When tight markets have continued long enough for stocks of purchased materials to have built up, the owner of the stock is wary of setting a downward spiral in motion by forcing price concessions from his supplier. The accounting law of cost or market, whichever is lower, means that loss on inventories will follow a reduction in materials prices. It may be better strategy to decrease buying and use up stocks before pushing for lower prices. The argument suggests that prices of manufactured goods would lag sensitive materials prices more persistently at peaks than at troughs. The scanty number of observations covered by appropriate, readily available price statistics shows manuf actured-goods prices lagging sensitive prices at each of the four major peaks that the data 282 ECONOMIC STABILITY A1SID GROWTH cover6 whereas at troughs, they lead once, synchronize once, and lag once. The line of thought that emphasizes the link between sensitive prices and buying waves and the asymmetrical influence on pricing policy for rises and falls should be subject to test. One implication is that were it possible to hold other relevant factors constant, commodities having a high degree of cyclical variability of raw prices should tend to have finished-goods prices that have a trend rise far greater (or fall far less) than that of the price of the major raw materials of which they are composed. Small differential trends would be associated with low cyclical variability. The only data that could readily be used for the test were the 18 industries for which Fabricant had prepared price indexes for two or more stages of fabrication. These figures seem to exhibit the sort of correlation between variability and differential trend that one would expect, though the te$t can only be thought of as highly tentative and requiring further substantiation.7 PROBLEM AND THERAPY In industries in which short-run changes in the prices of basic raw materials respond primarily to changes in demand rather than to sharp autonomous changes in supply, there is a triple causal association between materials prices and product prices. First, materials prices are a business cost which, like other costs, must be recovered in selling price. Second, the fact that many crude materials prices are promptly and publicly reported gives them an instrumental value in recovering actual and expected increases in labor costs or increases in other costs which are expected to improve the competitive position of the company. Provision for increased complexity of product, packaging, marketing, research, are cases in point. Third, materials prices are linked with buying waves, and the associated inventory cycles, as cause and effect. These several causal links between prices of crude materials and of products are relevant to the subject of this inquiry in two ways. In the first place, materials prices impart cyclical instability via all three causal links—enough to account for a large part of the cyclical fluctuation in the price of finished goods. The three causal links contribute to this result in various ways. As cost alone, the high per« Comparisons are for 1937, 1939, 1948, 1949, 1951, 1953, and 1957. The data used a r e : Bureau of Labor Statistics price indexes: all manufactured goods prices (excluding crude materials) since 1947 and combined semimanufactured and finished goods prices, 1935 to 1946. For this earlier period, sensitive prices were represented by an index of spot-market prices of 28 commodities and beginning in 1947 by spot-market prices of industrial commodities (shown in chart I ) . The lag ( + ) or lead (—) of manufactured prices relative to sensitive prices i s : at peaks + 5 , + 8 , + 1, +28, and troughs 0, + 5 , or 7—10. For the 15 industries in which raw-materials prices rose less or fell more 1913 to 1932 than did finished prices, average year-to-year differences in price indexes of raw materials, adjusted for the trend component, give a rough measure of cyclical price variability. We rank these figures from greatest to lowest variability and compare the rank standings for each industry with a second set of rank standings that are based on the spread between raw and finished goods prices between the trough in 1913, 1914, or 1915 to the trough in 1932 or 1933. Of course, other variables that ought to be controlled include differences among industries with respect to the trends in productivity, importance of materials as a cost, and peculiarities of supply conditions; institutional characteristics that influence the capacity to administer prices and the objectives to be thereby served. None of these matters could be controlled; but two industries, sugar refining and linseed oil and meal manufacture, had very few firms and low materials costs. Omitting these, the rank correlation for the 13 industries was 0.60 which is significant at the 5-percent level. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 283 centage fluctuation of crude prices is watered down because they constitute only a fraction of all costs. Also the slow leaching of costs through the productive process delays the impact of raw on finished prices. Their involvement with buying waves, on the other hand, increases the promptness and extent to which changes in crude materials prices reappear in other prices, since the short-term shifts in demand-supply conditions that accompany buying waves have a direct impact on prices not only of crude materials but also on prices of intermediate and finished products. Second, materials prices act as agent in facilitating an upward trend in the price level. Here again all three causal links play a part, but that of instrumental value and, especially, buying wave is particularly important. The impact of buying waves on the advantage of buyer and seller during periods of tightening demand is such as to further a rise in product prices relative to materials prices which is proportionately greater than the relative fall dictated by the advantage of buyer and seller during periods of hesitant or slackening demand. The line of thought that I have outlined suggests that crude materials prices is an advantageous point at which to take steps to reduce cyclical fluctuations in prices and to curb their upward trend. What steps may be advisable ? The direction of the cure is implicit in the analysis of the process. It involves the damping of buying waves. This would reduce fluctuations in the price of demand-oriented crude materials. It would reduce the impact of fluctuation in materials on later stages of manufacture. It would reduce the ratchet-jack aspect of the process. Though we know far less than we need to know about the alternating over and under buying of stock in trade, it seems clear that one element that generates this alternation is fear of scarcity. In connection with certain materials, it may be feasible to diminish fear of scarcity by the presence of reserve stocks handled in the interests of price stability. But perhaps the most promising attack on actual scarcity is to lessen imagined scarcity which tends to validate imaginings. It is therefore reasonable to suppose that better and more complete information about stocks and orders—new and outstanding orders—would reduce surges and cessation in buying. Specifically, we need information on orders received and orders placed by the same firms; we need information on unfilled orders and orders outstanding of the same firms. We need this information for vertical sequences that are continuous from the first to last processor. Information in physical units is more useful than in dollar units but is often too difficult to obtain. This committee has shown active interest in businessmen's expectations about sales and inventories. Yet businessmen are not clairvoyant and the the value of orders they receive and of unfilled orders on their books must certainly be a major determinant of expectation about sales and stocks. Order information is often much easier to get and much more reliable than information on expectations. The several inquiries about statistics instigated by this committee and executed by the Federal Reserve Board 2 years ago were unable to cover data on orders; unfilled orders were not covered by the inventory committee and new orders were not systematically covered by the Gainsbrugh committee on expectation. It 284 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH seems distinctly in the public interest to improve such information both because of its value in forecasting general economic conditions and because it would help industry in its own interest to lessen fluctuation. RELATIONSHIPS BETWEEN FOREIGN AND AMERICAN PRICES Gardner Patterson, Princeton University The task assigned me was briefly to survey the problem of the interrelationships among American and foreign price levels from the long-term point of view. I was specifically asked not to deal with the immediate international problems arising from the present United States recession. My concern is with the problems arising from a persistent uneven pace of inflation among nations, and both "persistent" and "uneven" are important qualifications. To properly assess the relationships between foreign prices and the American economy one must have some notion as to the importance of our international economic transactions. There is no simple measure of this. On the most general level, it can be said that as compared with many domestic economic activities the numbers are relatively small but that they are not so insignificant as to be safely ignored by those formulating policies to cope with the problems facing this committee. I . RELATIVE IMPORTANCE OF INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC TRANSACTIONS 1 Excluding military aid, our exports of goods and services have in recent years been running in the neighborhood of 5 to 6 percent of our gross national product, or some 9 percent of our movable goods production. Our imports (f. o. b.) have been equal to from 3 to 4 percent of our gross national product, or equal to some 6 percent of the estimated value of movable goods produced in the United States. Looked at from another angle, it has been estimated that about 7 percent of our labor force gain their livelihood, in one way or another, from foreign trade. For many sectors of the economy, foreign trade—and so price changes abroad compared to those at home—is much more important than these overall averages indicate. For example, foreign sales in recent years have, on the average, accounted for about 20 percent of our production of trucks, 25 percent of our output of construction and mining equipment, 10 percent of our machine tools, and from 25 to 40 percent of such agricultural products as cotton, wheat, rice, fats and oils, and tobacco. For some industries, on the other hand, exports are of very little importance: printing and publishing, clothing, manufacturing, food processing, and so forth. Similarly, in many areas the importance of imports is much greater to our economy than the above overall averages suggest. We are now depending upon foreign sources for about a quarter of 1 For more details on most of the points in this section, see U. S. Congress, Committee on Ways and Means, Foreign Trade Policy, Compendium of Papers on United States Foreign Trade Policy (1957), pp. 15 ff. See also U. S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of Foreign Commerce, annual bulletins on Exports in Relation to United States Production, in its World Trade Information Service, and, in the same Service, Contribution of Imports to United States Raw Material Supplies. 285 286 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH our consumption of iron ore, a third of our copper and fish, half of our raw wool and sugar, and most or all of our tin, nickel, lead, zinc, bauxite, chrome, manganese, cobalt, and so forth, to say nothing of our coffee and bananas. From the aggregative point of view, it may be said that, by and large, the greater the excess of exports over imports the greater net financial boost or push (not always desired) our economy gets in the first instance from its foreign trade. The size of our current account export surplus—the excess of exports of goods and services over imports, or the excess of our foreign sales over our purchases from others—varies from year to year. Since 1950 it has averaged, excluding military aid, less than 1 percent of gross national product and was almost exactly 1 percent during 1957. This is a small percentage. But in absolute amounts, again excluding military aid, it averaged $2.5 billion for the period 1950-57, and was over $4 billion in 1957. That is to say, last year this was only a little less than most of the recent (March 1958) estimates of the anticipated decline in 1958, as compared with 1957, in the value of business investment in plant and equipment about which there has, quite properly, been much serious concern of late. Perhaps this is enough to indicate that there are important structural and financial relationships between the American and foreign economies. Moreover, it seems likely that these interrelationships and interdependencies will increase in the years ahead. As our income goes up, the variety and quantity of goods which we demand grows and so our interest in foreign products; the evidence seems quite conclusive that foreign sources of raw materials will become increasingly attractive as our production grows and as the more cheaply exploited domestic sources are used up. Corollarily, the volume and value of our exports, especially of manufactured goods, also seem likely to increase as foreign incomes improve. These forces making for growth of trade seem likely to be more powerful than the drives toward protectionism which have been such a prominent part of our landscape in recent years. I I . TRANSMITTING PRICE CHANGES ACROSS FRONTIERS The effects on one nation of price movements in another, and the ways in which these effects are transmitted, are so complex that they are not known with precision. At the outset, it should be noted that price changes in some goods or services in one country may have virtually no discernible impact on prices elsewhere. This is the case for price changes in those many items which do not move across frontiers—haircuts, house rents, and so on. There may, of course, even here be indirect repercussions, especially through wage rates, but they are likely to be small. Probably more significant are the cases where price changes in one country serve to offset or counteract other economic changes and so are not transmitted in any clearcut way. Thus, an increase in the prices abroad of goods we import may have little impact on our economy if it is matched by a decrease in the cost of transportation. Or a decrease in prices abroad may largely be offset by a rise in our tariffs. Moreover, it may often be that the markets for certain goods are so poorly organized, or the goods so differentiated, that great divergences in prices can take place for quite some ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 287 time as between nations before consumers shift their sources of supply or before the new prices make themselves felt abroad in other ways. Our chief concern here is with general price levels, not just selected individual prices, and it can be said that any substantial change in the price level in one country will have a noticeable impact on other countries. For purposes of illustration, assume that prices of most goods—and so the general price level—rise abroad faster than they do in the United States; as we shall see later, this seems to have been the common pattern in the past decade or so. To some degree these price rises will be transmitted directly to Americans by the simple fact that we are likely to continue to import at least some of these goods and the cost per unit, or price, goes up. If the price rise abroad is great enough we may reduce the quantity of our imports and rely more on domestic producers. But under these circumstances the domestic producers can usually obtain a higher price than before and so, here too, prices have increased in the United States. Another aspect of this is that since rising prices tend to lessen the danger or force of import competition, one of the moderating influences on price increases at home is removed. But this is not all. If foreign prices go up faster than ours, there is a tendency for buyers all around the world to shift to lower-price sources; this will mean an increase in demand for many United States goods and so more pressure is applied to our prices. A bit more complicated, but fully as important, is the transmission of inflation, by which term I mean a general rise in prices, via what is called the "income effects." As inflation mounts in one country, money incomes also tend to rise. As money incomes rise, the money demand there for all sorts of goods increases. Included as the object of this enlarged demand are likely to be at least some of the domestic goods formerly exported plus all kinds of imports. More specifically, still assuming the pace of inflation abroad is greater than ours, this means an increase in our exports and a decrease in our imports. Now if we have lots of unemployed resources, these developments will give a welcome boost to our economy and may well increase total production and employment. But if we are already fully employed—and are ourselves already suffering from rising prices, though more moderate than other areas—these changes will aggravate our inflation. The actual ability of others to buy more and sell less depends on the previous balance of trade, on the state of their reserves, on the availability of unilateral transfers and loans, etc. If the first were unfavorable, the second low, and the last very limited, then the situation cannot long continue. But this state of affairs would raise some important policy issues for us which will be noted later. It was suggested earlier that changes in the overall inflationary pressure (wanted and unwanted) put on one economy by inflation in another via these income effects can roughly be measured in the first instance by the changes in the size of the export surplus; the absolute inflationary impact on the more stable economy over time, however, will be some multiple of this surplus, inasmuch as a large part of the additions to its national money income represented by the surplus of foreign sales over purchases will be spent again and again inside the country and only a part will "leak out" through domestic savings, higher taxes, and larger imports. 288 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Inflation also is sometimes quickly spread among nations via the speculative channel. This is most likely to affect countries for which raw materials bulk large in imports (as the United States) or in exports (as many of the underdeveloped countries). Once the prices of raw materials start rapidly upward, for whatever reason, the fact of increase tends to encourage users to accumulate inventories, these goods typically being storable. The supply of most raw materials tends to be price inelastic, which means that any such increase in demand tends to have a very great effect upon prices. Thus both the importing and the exporting countries tend to inherit inflationary pressures from one another. Similarly, of course, once raw material prices start to fall they tend to fall far and fast. The international transferral of inflations also takes place via its effects on a nation's terms of trade. An increase in the price of imports as compared with exports—a deterioration in a nation's terms of trade—means that the nation suffering such an adverse movement must increase the physical quantity of her exports to maintain the previous quantity of imports. This means (unless the worsening terms of trade are the result of at least a proportionate increase in productivity in the production of the exports) that, as compared with the previous situation, there are fewer goods available for purchase inside the country and this, of course, is inflationary. This phenomenon has had great quantitative significance for England in recent years, especially after Korea. It has been less important, though not negligible, for the United States inasmuch as our relative dependence on imports is much smaller. I I I . RECENT PATTERNS OF RELATIVE PRICE MOVEMENTS If inflations do spread across frontiers, as has just been argued, then it is important to know whether, in fact, in recent years inflation has proceeded at different rates in different countries, and, if so, where the United States has stood on the ladder. Price data are not available for some countries and international comparisons of price movements are fraught with possibilities of error, stemming from the wide differences of items covered, gross inaccuracies in observation, incomparability of many items whose prices are compared, the irrelevance of differences in prices for certain comparable goods and services, and so forth. Nonetheless, readily available data for most of the countries which now supply 1 percent or more of United States imports do show such great differences in the relative price movements that one can conclude, in the light of what has been said above, that a source of problems for the United States exists here. The actual comparison varies much, depending on the year chosen for the base of the price indexes used. In the early postwar years, 1945-48, as the United States abandoned its controls more quickly than other nations, prices here very often rose faster than in many foreign countries where price controls were retained. For the decade since then, however, a substantial majority of countries appear to have more inflation than the United States, as the table below shows. That is, for the years 1948 through 1953 these data indicate the United States was subjected to serious inflationary pressures from 289 ECONOMIC STABILITY ANI> GROWTH abroad. Since 1953 the rate of inflation has tapered off in most countries and the degree of difference has declined, but inflation still continues and it continues imevenly. TABLE I.—Comparison of domestic inflations, autumn 1951 1953=100 1948=100 Wholesale prices Chile Argentina Indonesia Brazil Japan Peru Colombia Mexico Australia Prance 1,880 372 291 274 __ _ _ TTnftp.fi K"ingr|nrn Sweden Netherlands West Germany Canada Belgium United States India _. _ Switzerland l Philippines Italy Venezuela Cuba 205 204 183 159 150 143 117 115 113 113 108 103 103 99 97 Cost of living 1,650 590 347 342 195 209 206 200 201 185 153 147 152 117 127 115 118 115 111 104 132 120 90 Wholesale prices Chile Brazil Argentina Indonesia _.. _ Colombia Peru _ ._ Mexico France Sweden _ __ _ _ Australia United Kingdom Netherlands _ _ _ United States Belgium Denmark Japan West Germany. _ _. __ Switzerland Italy Canada-. _.__._ _ India Philippines Cuba -_ Venezuela 696 195 160 136 135 119 108 108 107 107 107 106 105 105 105 105 103 101 101 101 100 99 Cost of living 636 212 182 163 140 127 143 111 113 113 118 117 106 109 113 111 108 107 114 107 106 106 97 102 i 1950=100. Source: Calculated from data published in United Nations, Monthly Bulletin of Statistics, various 1957 issues. To us in the United States foreign prices have meaning only when translated into dollars and this requires a foreign exchange rate. A good many foreign countries have devalued their currencies during the past decade and so the above prices do not accurately reflect the prices to us in terms of dollars. Indeed, often devaluation was necessary in large part precisely because other countries had more inflation than the United States. Thus, another very rough indication that most other countries have suffered more inflation than we have is the fact that of the countries included in table I above all save Canada, Cuba, the Philippines, Switzerland, and Venezuela have officially reduced the value of their currency in terms of the dollar at some time or other since 1948. But it is also noteworthy that only the following have officially cut the dollar value of their moneys since 1953: Bolivia, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, France, and Mexico. Table I I takes account of these official devaluations and expresses foreign wholesale price indexes in terms of United States dollars. According to this calculation, the extent of inflationary pressure which was probably applied to the United States from abroad is much less than table I indicated. However, it must be remembered that most countries today follow a so-called "adjustable-peg" exchange rate policy; that is, their exchange rates are not allowed to fluctuate from day to day or even month to month in response to market forces, but are held fixed over long periods of time and then, if found inappropriate, undergo major adjustment in one fell swoop. This means that the impact of relative differences in degree of inflation tends to be felt for a relatively long period before the rate is adjusted. 290 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE II.—Comparison of wholesale prices, expressed in United States dollars, autumn 1957 [1948 = 100] Japan 1 Brazil Australia Peru 2 West Germany 2 Canada France United States United Kingdom 2 Philippines Switzerland Sweden Colombia3 Netherlands Belgium Venezuela Chile 4 Mexico Cuba 5 Italy India [1953=100] 290 185 142 134 123 123 121 113 104 104 103 102 99 99 99 98 97 95 90 89 78 Brazil * Peru Chile Sweden France Australia United States Netherlands United Kingdom Belgium Canada West Germany Switzerland Japan India Philippines Italy Cuba Venezuela Mexico 3 Colombia * - 123 120 117 109 108 108 107 107 106 106 106 105 105 104 103 102 100 100 100 95 94 1 "Coffee export rate" used in converting domestic prices to dollar basis. 2 1950 = 100. 3 Index of "Home and Import Goods" prices. Exchange rate used was "Other principal export rate." *5 Average exchange rate of 40 pesos per dollar used for 1948 and 110 for 1953. Cost of living index. Source : International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics, December 1957, various tables. Another common indication of relative price movements is provided by the so-called terms-of-trade index, the ratio of the prices of the commodities a nation exports to the prices of the commodities it imports. A commonly used measure of this is to divide the unit value of exports of United States merchandise by the unit value of United States imports for consumption, the unit values being those calculated by the United States Department of Commerce. These calculations are based on actual prices paid and received, rather than on general price indexes, and take into account changes in the exchange rate. Using 1936-38 as equal to 100, the index shows a fairly steady deterioration from 1945 through 1951 and then a slight improvement, with a fairly stable relationship since 1954. Again, the possibilities of errors are great and the recorded decline could be the result of a series of factors other than more domestically generated inflation abroad than in th'e United States. For example, important changes in the kinds of goods imported or exported could cause changes in the index even if prices for each good remained constant. Or, the higher prices for imports may have been the result of an increase in American demand for the goods. Still, when considered along with the other evidence this does lend support not only to the thesis that prices have moved unevenly among nations but also to the hypothesis that during much of the postwar period the United States has imported some inflation. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 291 TABLE III.—United States terms of trade index—Unit value of exports of United States merchandise divided oy unit value of United States imports for consumption [1936-38 = 100] 100 1951 97 1952 107 1953 91 1954 88 1955 85 1956 83 1957 (January-September) 74 1936-1938 1940 . 1945. 1946 1947 1948 1949 1950 71 74 71 72 72 75 Source : Calculated from data in U. S. Department of Commerce, Business Statistics, 1957 edition, and Survey of Current Business, January 1958. IV. WHAT ARE THE PROSPECTS FOR THE FUTURE ? What is likely to happen is always more interesting than what has happened and it is to that we now turn. In my judgment, most other countries are likely to witness steady and serious inflation in the foreseeable future. Whether this will be at a faster rate than in the United States depends on our internal policy, and I leave consideration of this to others. My point is only that if our objective is to have stable prices our policies must make allowance for some, probably moderate but unremitting, inflationary pressures from abroad. For some of the industrialized countries with whom we have contact, these inflationary pressures will arise in part from the defense burdens they have assumed. Much more important, I anticipate, will be the conjunction of (1) a vigorous pursuit by these governments of full employment policies, (2) the existence of strong and aggressive labor unions, and (3) the fact that much of the public now generally believes that by energetic use of monetary and fiscal measures any unwanted slack in demand or employment can be successfully combated. If, as seems to be the case in many countries, the politically and socially acceptable levels of unemployment are now very small, then tremendous upward pressure will be exerted on prices for the many well known reasons that apply to our internal situation. One way to insure full employment is for the Government, in one way or another, to stand ready to increase monetary demand whenever any slack develops, thus putting a floor under wages and leaving them no place to go but up. A full employment policy by the Government serves to increase the strength of unions, one of whose jobs is to increase the wages of members. Moreover, trade unions are becoming more powerful in most nations and their attempts to raise wages pari passu with productivity increases tend, as many have pointed out, to be inflationary, particularly (a) if the increase in wage rates tends to follow that of the more progressive industries, leaving those whose productivity is rising less no alternative but to meet the higher labor costs through higher prices, and/or (b) if the increase in productivity has been made possible by increased capital costs per unit of output, leaving management no choice but to raise prices if it is to cover costs. Another aspect of this is that full employment decreases the resistance of employers to wage increases, inasmuch as in an economy with full employment and rising wages management finds it easy to pass on its rising costs in higher prices to its customers. This may be even easier to do in economies where the form of business organiza23734—58 20 292 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH tion, tradition, and the laws encourage monopolistic-like actions by businessmen. Furthermore, anticipation of full employment and rising prices encourages businessmen to invest and this can be inflationary in a full employment situation. Of course, all industrialized countries do not, and will not, act in the same way on this or any other problem. Evidence of the past decade indicates, however, that the governments of many of the other highly industrialized nations, including for example the United Kingdom, Austria, and Norway, have felt compelled to push employment to levels well in excess of those determined as politically necessary to the United States Thus, for example, in England, even under the Conservative Government, unemployment greater than iy2 to 2 percent of the labor force has become a matter of grave concern calling for remedial action. In the United States unemployment of these dimensions would mean less than 1.5 million jobless. Italy, on the other hand, has tolerated year after year a level of unemployment greater than we have now. In many of the economically advanced countries governments have been assuming growing responsibility for providing social and welfare services at steadily increasing levels. Most indications are that this trend will continue. Such activities are, to some extent, an additional demand on the available resources, thus tending to push up prices. There is an accompanying tendency, frequently reported, of individuals saving less, inasmuch as some of their future needs are otherwise being provided for. This, too, is inflationary. Many observers believe that another fundamental factor making for inflation in both the richer and the poorer foreign countries is the so-called "demonstration effect" of the higher and growing United States levels of living, increasingly made known to others as communications of all types improve between ourselves and others. The essence of the argument here is that as others watch us constantly increase the quality, the variety, and the amount of things we consume, their appetites are whetted and they are tempted to try to "live beyond their means." That is, the peoples of other nations attempt to consume more than there is for sale at the present prices. The result is inflation. Economists are not in complete agreement on this; some argue that the"demonstration effect" of Americans' higher living standards may encourage others to work harder, to save more, and to produce more, with the consequence of disinflation. The latter certainly could happen. But it is my hunch that in more cases than not the effect is inflationary. Another factor making for a persistent rise in prices in both developed and underdeveloped countries is that once inflation has gone on for any length of time, as it now has in most foreign countries, to say nothing of the United States, nearly all persons come to expect further rises, and their attempts to hedge against this—by getting out of fixedincome assets, asking for escalator clauses in wage contracts, and so on—act as a forceful propellent to further inflation. There are special grounds for fearing that in the years just ahead inflation is even more likely to occur in the so-called underdeveloped areas than it is in the highly industrialized countries. In addition to the factors just cited, the governments of most of these underdeveloped areas are firmly committed to programs of economic development—that is, to rapidly and drastically altering the structure of their economies and to attempting to industrialize them. The ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 293 reasons for the adoption of this policy are well known to Congress and need not be explored here. Let it be acknowledged at once that economic development does not of necessity lead to serious inflation. But it has done so in most cases since World War I I ; and it seems more likely than not to do so in the foreseeable future. The reasons are simple: changing the pattern of production of a country and increasing total production and productivity are likely to be relatively slow processes, not only because of technical problems but also because they usually must be accompanied by a great many fundamental social and cultural changes. Moreover, most of these areas are poor and so their ability quickly to raise large amounts of additional real capital internally is low. And, as is well known, the amount of available foreign capital also tends to be low compared to the demands or wishes of these countries. At the same time, the governments of these countries often find it to their immediate political advantage to hold out great promise to their peoples on these matters and so to increase the public's expectations of rapid improvement. This complex of considerations has, in most instances, created for the authorities an irresistible temptation to attempt a level of capital formation and economic development well in excess of the physically available goods and resources. The important aspect of this in the present connection is that the favorite devices used have been "monetary" ones—budget deficits, easy construction credits, expanded agricultural-aid programs, etc. Often such programs are very successful at first. There are quite a few unemployed resources, not only labor but also land and, sometimes, capital, that can be put to work; the public is often willing substantially to increase its holdings of cash for a while; until labor is better organized—such organization is often one of the desired components of an economic development program—• wages can be held down in spite of serious rising costs of living; and, for a time, past accumulations of foreign exchange holdings can be spent, which action soaks up some of the new domestic cash. The very fact of early success tends to be heady and all too often encourages an ever more ambitious program. But once these early "advantages" are exhausted, serious inflation begins. At this danger signal most economists advise the governments to trim their sails and reduce their economic development efforts. But this is asking more than can be expected of the governments of most poor countries—often nations with rather unstable political institutions. To them, and to many other thoughtful persons, inflation, especially if it can be kept fairly moderate by local standards—say, no more than 10 percent per year— appears a far less serious problem than having a rate of economic development less than might be the case. In practice, the inflation often gets completely out of hand, but that is beside the point for our present purpose, which is merely to note some of the reasons why we may expect prices to rise significantly—say, something more than 7 percent per year—in the years ahead in the poorer countries of the world. These countries supply many of our imports and the markets for a good bit of our exports. 294 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH V. IMPLICATIONS FOR UNITED STATES POLICY My thesis up to now has been that price changes can be expected to move among nations; that in the period since World War I I inflation has characterized the economies of virtually every country with which we have important economic relations; that the pace of these inflations has varied a great deal; and that for most of this period the United States, on balance, has probably imported a substantial amount of inflation, but this has decreased in recent years. Finally, it has been argued that there are strong forces at work making for continuing inflation in both the other industrial economies of the world and in the so-called underdeveloped ones. I would like now, briefly, to turn to some of the policy implications of all this for the United States. First of all, it seems clear that, in order to achieve internal price stability, the United States will have to overcompensate for the purely domestically generated inflationary pressures. That is, we will have to devise and pursue more rigorous— and probably more unpopular—antiinflationary policies than our own excesses would dictate. This is important, for it is always tempting to pursue policies on the assumption that some of our domestic problems will be solved by the actions of others. In this field our problems will be bigger than they appear when looked at only from the inside. Perhaps the next most important implication is that these considerations argue for the United States pursuing a more liberal import policy than it now does. The fact of rising prices abroad will itself tend to curtail our imports and those that do come in, it was asserted earlier, will tend to raise our prices. But for them not to enter our market would make our inflation even more severe. One of the most efficient ways of restraining inflation is to increase the amounts of goods and services in a market while reducing the amount of money looking for goods to buy. Increasing imports does precisely that. By the same token, any United States Government action designed to keep out imports has direct inflationary effects. The price-raising effects of restricting imports may be in some small part offset if other countries retaliate and reduce their markets for our exports, but it is clear I think that a worldwide policy of curtailing trade all around makes for lower real incomes for everyone in the longer run. There are of course a host of other considerations relevant to the formulation of our international trade policy; most of those also argue for a reduction of American import barriers but a consideration of them is outside the present assignment. Third, if there continues to be inflation abroad and the United States is able to stop inflation at home, or if the pace of inflation abroad is faster than here, the attractiveness to foreigners of American goods will increase and the attractiveness of their goods to us will decline. As a consequence, one may anticipate the emergence in some form or other of what has been called the "dollar shortage," that is, severe pressure of the balances of payments of other nations. As a consequence of this, one must expect an increase in barriers and in discrimination against United States exports. Although a raising of such barriers against our exports is to be regretted, we must refrain from retaliating in kind, for this would only enlarge the problem and add to inflationary pressures here in t\e United States. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 295 The inflationary impact on us of rising prices abroad will tend to be less as the price of foreign currencies goes down in terms of dollars. From the point of view of maintaining stable prices in the United States, the above analysis indicates that our policy should be to encourage other nations to make more frequent adjustments in their foreign exchange rates than has been their usual practice, or at least to widen considerably the margins about parity within which the exchange rates can fluctuate. Indeed, these considerations indicate that the United States Government should reconsider its past policy of supporting an adjustable-peg system of exchange rates with very narrow margins which, in practice, means that the rates are virtually fixed, i. e., the peg is adjusted only after long intervals during which time others undervalue the dollar, and should seriously consider encouraging other countries to adopt a system of more flexible exchange rates. A policy along this line would seem to require an important change in the policies of the International Monetary Fund, in whose deliberations the United States exercises great influence. What can the United States properly do to help other nations avoid inflation ? Probably not much. The most important thing would be to prevent inflation at home. If we can do this, at least we will not add to their price level problems, which, in turn, add to ours. We also can refrain from such speculative stockpiling orgies as characterized 1950 and 1951, although those foreign countries providing strategic and critical raw materials found our eagerness to buy at almost any price welcome enough at the time. A continuation of our policy of helping to share the military burdens of our allies may in some cases give relief to inflation, but in others it is likely that our help "encourages" them to make greater domestic military efforts than they otherwise would and so, while strengthening the free world's defenses, it also adds to inflation. In any event, our military-aid policy should not be importantly changed because of this consideration. Probably the most important thing we can do to prevent inflation abroad is to resist the temptation to try to win friends in the poorer countries of the world by building up their expectations that, by undertaking elaborate economic development programs, they may achieve a rapid and large-scale improvement in their economic wellbeing. To do so is indirectly to encourage irresponsible inflationary policies. At the same time, if their expectations are already aroused, either by us or by someone else, then the amount of inflation they suffer, and so in part at least pass on to us, will be less as (1) we help these foreign governments resist resort to excessive money creation, and (2) as we provide, through both public and private channels, some oi the capital they need to carry out their economic development efforts. It must be acknowledged, however, that, as respects (1), we can expect to have virtually no influence and, as respects (2), while enough aid will stop inflation abroad, not only does aid add directly to the inflationary pressures in the granting country (if it is operating under fairly high levels of employment) but it sometimes actually encourages the recipient to attempt to live even more beyond his means. Still, on balance, a strong case can be made for providing some help to the underdeveloped countries in their investment programs. And there are a couple of clear-cut general guidelines as to the sort of investment that should be encouraged by us to the extent 296 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH that our aim is to reduce inflation abroad: the favored projects should be ones promising fairly quick returns—and so leading to fewer frustrated expectations; and they should make use of resources with which these countries are most favorably endowed rather than those that they only wish they had. A policy of discouraging unduly ambitious development efforts and of facilitating those where there is good prospect for genuine economic advantage is admittedly most delicate and difficult. But the problem of coping with inflation is difficult— and important—too. My conclusions from all this are that the problem of stabilizing prices in the United States will be made more difficult in the years ahead, as it has for many of the past several years, by the fact that serious inflation is likely to characterize for the indefinite future manyr if not most, of the other economies with whom we deal. Although the impact on our domestic economy of foreign trade and of disparate international price movements is of much less importance for us than such matters as our internal wage rates, productivity changes, defense costs, Government fiscal policy, etc., it is much too important to be ignored. The more important implications of this for our domestic policies are that we must take even sterner internal anti-inflationary measures than our own excesses would require; we should adopt more liberal foreign trade policies; we should not retaliate when others discriminate against us in trade matters; we should discourage overambitious development efforts by the poorer countries of the world; and, while we should not try to solve their inflationary problems by aid, we should continue to help them in certain of their efforts to expand output. Fortunately, these policies can be defended on the basis of our national interest even if inflation were not one of the most serious economic problems facing us. PRICES, COSTS, DEMAND, AND OUTPUT IN THE UNITED STATES, 1947-57 Richard Ruggles, Yale University, and Nancy D. Ruggles, United Nations In the postwar American economy, the view has been widely held that it is excessive demand that has forced prices up. Yet a review of the period reveals that the only periods when demand was really excessive were the 3 years immediately following World War I I (1946, 1947, and 1948) and the Korean war year of 1951. The peacetime American economy has, if anything, been suffering from a lack, not an excess, of effective demand. In the last 10 years there have been 3 years in which output has actually declined below the previous year: 1949, 1954, and again in 1958. The periods we tend to think of as unparalleled prosperity are those which have followed immediately upon the years of decline, when the increase in output was mainly due to regaining a fuller use of available equipment and manpower. Why, then, is it that the sense of excess demand persists ? There are a number of reasons. The level of employment in the postwar period has been continuously high; and the great depression of the 1930's created in people's minds a lasting impression that employment could be used as a barometer of the economic health of the economy. Furthermore—and this is probably more important—there has been a general feeling that prices have been rising relatively rapidly throughout the period, and that this coupled with full employment meant pressure on available resources. But this last premise cannot be accepted at face value without exploring in some detail exactly what has been happening to prices. It is, of course, possible to find price indexes that will show almost anything one wants to show, and it is difficult to obtain measures of price behavior that are unequivocal and do reflect honestly what is taking place in the economy. For the present purpose, the most general price indicators are those which result from the computation of gross national product in constant prices. These are called the implicit price deflators of the gross national product. They represent the difference between gross national product and its various components in constant prices, or real terms, and in current prices, or money terms. They are given in table 1 below. 297 298 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE 1.—Implicit price deflators for gross national year percentage changes) 1946 1947 Consumer goods 7.8 Durable 1.8 Nondurable 9.7 5.0 Services Producer goods: Residential construction 8.3 Other construction. 8.6 10.2 Equipment Government: Federal 20.7 State and local 8.6 Total 10.2 Consumer price index 8.5 Gross Government product price index 18.0 Gross national product in constant 1947 prices. _ -12.5 10.7 8.5 12.9 7.6 (year-to- 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 5.7 - 1 . 0 4.3 5.9 -3.4 5.9 2.8 1.3 0 1.0 2.3 6.9 6.6 8.6 4.2 1.6 -.6 1.1 3.4 1.3 .4 -.4 4.2 0.8 -2.3 .4 2.6 0.3 -.7 1.7 1.7 .7 1.4 6.9 3.2 3.2 3.2 3.2 -2.5 1.0 4.8 4.2 1.7 2.1 6.9 8.8 8.6 2.7 2.4 2.0 4.3 1.1 2.4 1.6 1.6 5.0 4.4 4.4 2.0 4.9 5.5 3.8 1.5 1.0 3.2 1.5 1.0 1.0 11.0 7.8 7.7 8.0 5.1 1.4 2.3 -1.3 .8 .3 2.4 2.0 3.9 2.0 1.1 3.2 5.6 3.1 1.5 4.0 4.5 3.8 3.3 3.6 2.9 5.4 3.4 4.0 6.1 5.6 5.3 9.6 6.9 3.8 3.9 -1.5 7.2 2.4 .8 1948 20.0 20.0 14.4 12.0 10.9 8.1 8.5 12.6 11.7 14.5 10.8 5.5 9.6 4.5 -.5 product, 4.8 -1.0 6.2 -1.0 -2.3 3.1 1.2 1957 Source: Economic Report of the President, January 1958, table F-5, p. 122, table F-39, p. 161, and table F-2, p. 118. THE MEASUREMENT OF PRICES The implicit price deflators shown above are based primarily upon price information collected by Government agencies. This price information cannot always be a valid reflection of the true behavior or prices in the economy. Prices are obtained for commodities of fixed specifications. In fact, however, new items continually appear on the market, and old items change in quality. When improvements in quality cannot be measured, or new products appear which are more desirable than those they replace, price indexes which must leave these factors out of account will show too much price increase. In pricing consumer goods, the Bureau of Labor Statistics does attempt to take into account those changes in the nature of the product that result in an upward change in price. But improvements in quality may occur at no increase in cost, so that the consumer gets more value for his money. In such cases, no adjustment is made in prices, and the price indexes do not reflect the quality improvements. I t would indeed be interesting if price comparisons taking quality improvements into account could be made between periods. This question might be asked another way. Suppose an individual were given $1,000 and a choice of ordering goods either from an early postwar Sears, Koebuck catalog (say 1948) or a current (1957) catalog. If he were permitted to spend the money in terms of only one catalog, which catalog would he choose ? The 1948 catalog has substantially lower prices, but also less advanced products. If the 1957 catalog were chosen, it could not be said that prices rose from 1948 to 1957, despite the evidence of the price indexes. Different people would undoubtedly answer this kind of question differently, but it is by no means certain that an overwhelming majority would choose to spend their money under 1948 price and product conditions rather than under 1957 conditions despite the fact that the implicit price indexes for consumers' goods have risen about 7 percent since 1948. The measurement of consumer services is even more difficult. Generally speaking, the compensation of the person performing the service is taken as the major indicator of price. Thus the cost of domestic ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 299 servants, of haircuts, and of professional services all tend to be measured by this criterion. It is obvious, however, that the quality of any of these services may improve. Thus, for example, medical service is better than it used to be, but this is not taken into account. Similarlyy quality changes in such services as housing and education cannot be measured. It is a serious error, as a moment's reflection will indicate, to assume that if teachers do not improve, education as a product does not improve over the years. We have only to ask ourselves whether we would be content to give children today exactly the same education as was given 50 years ago, using the same books and the same fund of knowledge . Education, like other products, is a combination of factors of production, and should not be assessed only in terms of an intuitive judgment about the contribution of any one of these factors of production. Nor are consumers' goods and services the only area that presents pricing problems. For producers' durable goods, it is well recognized that equipment produced today is far more productive than that produced even 5 years ago, but such increases in efficiency are extremely difficult to take account of in price indexes. In terms of the ability of capital goods to yield productive services, there can be little doubt that the increase from year to year is substantial. But price indexes of producers' durable equipment generally reflect changes in costs of production, rather than changes in the performance of the equipment itself. Residential and commercial construction also poses problems. Again, price indexes are constructed by determining what a structure of standard specifications would cost. Here again, improvements in design and cost-reducing changes in specifications are not taken into account in the price comparison, so that the price index tends to have an upward bias. Finally, the pricing of goods and services purchased by Government presents considerable problems. For military equipment, it is often impossible to determine what happens to prices when design changes radically. For the services of Government employees, like services in general, it is assumed that there is no change in the efficiency or output per man, so that all increases in salary are, in effect, increases in the price of Government gross product. By this measure, the price of Government services as measured by the pay of Government employees has risen by an average of over 5 percent a year since 1946. There is good reason to believe, however, that the productivity of Government workers has increased substantially in this period. For one thing, the introduction of data handling machines and computers speeds up the operations of many stages of Government work. Statistics in the Government are now in large part handled mechanically rather than by clerks. The mechanization which is so characteristic of current developments in business is also occurring in Government. There is thus an upward bias in the price indexes for almost every category of expenditure. For commodities it exists because quality changes and new products cannot be integrated adequately into the price data. For services it exists because by and large the value of services is assumed not to increase, although there is strong evidence that it does. 300 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH THE BEHAVIOR OF PRICES 19 4 7 - 5 7 If this upward bias in the price indexes is taken into account, a rather interesting picture emerges. The large price increases of the three post-World War I I years and the Korean war period stand out. However, up through 1955, the other years exhibit overall price changes which probably are smaller than the overall quality improvement, so that, in fact, from 1948 through 1955 the American economy did not show an overall upward price movement in any period except the Korean boom. For the 6 years involved, the average annual price increase was only 1.1 percent; for consumer goods alone it averaged 0.6 percent. For 1956 and 1957 the picture is quite different. Price increases were considerably more pronounced, and at the same time the growth in output was slowing down. In fact, even now, with a decline in output, prices are still rising. Given this pattern of price development in recent years, how has it been related to cost and demand, and what kind of price behavior can we expect in the future ? In the early postwar period and during the Korean war, the existence of excess demand is sufficient to explain the price movements that occurred. Immediately after the war, the combination of long postponed expenditures and accumulated liquid funds resulted in a rapid increase in demand for consumer goods which were still in short supply in an economy that had not fully converted from war production. During the Korean war, expenditures by the Federal Government on national security increased from $18.5 billion to $37.3 billion in 1 year alone, thus pumping into the economy almost $19 billion of additional expenditures. At the same time the increase in the Armed Forces reduced the civilian labor force, so that the normal increment of manpower from population growth did not occur. In a period of 2 years the real output of the economy rose by over 17 percent, and employment rose only 4 percent. Under such conditions, it is not at all surprising that the increase in real output could take place only with rising prices. But the absence of a significant price rise on average in the other years prior to 1956-57 did not mean that there were no rising prices anywhere in the economy. During this period agricultural prices were generally falling. These falling agricultural prices were offset in most of these years by rising wages, so that prices on average were quite stable. From 1951 to 1955, there was a decline of almost 19 percent in wholesale prices of farm products, while average hourly earnings in manufacturing rose by 18 percent. In the commodityproducing industries, furthermore, wage cost rose more slowly than hourly earnings because productivity increased. In manufacturing as a whole, wage cost rose only 2 percent. Thus the pattern of price behavior in these years can largely be explained in terms of the behavior of agricultural prices, wages, and productivity. The movement of agricultural prices and productivity growth tended to hold down the increase in product prices, by keeping materials costs and labor costs below what they otherwise would have been. Wages, on the other hand, exerted an upward influence, increasing somewhat more than in proportion to the productivity gain. The net result overall was comparative price stability. The evidence of the forces 301 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH at work can be seen, however, in the changing price structure, as revealed by the components of the cost-of-living index or by the implicit price deflators of the gross national product. These indexes show that prices of durable goods, where productivity increases were greatest, have actually declined since 1951. Prices of nondurable goods using agricultural materials—e. g., food processing and clothing—have been relatively stable; although productivity gains in these industries probably were not as large as in the durable-goods industries, agricultural raw-material costs fell. In such areas as construction, productivity gains were less pronounced and material costs, being mainly nonagricultural, did not fall. Prices in this sector therefore rose since 1951 by 10 to 15 percent, a considerably greater price rise than that exhibited by the other commodity-producing sectors. The largest price increases occurred in consumer services and Government services; here price increases since 1951 have ranged from 15 to 27 percent. Services, in fact, have accounted for most of the upward price movement that has occurred in this period. Prices rose faster in 1956 and 1957 for 2 major reasons. First, the decline in farm prices stopped, for all practical purposes. Second, the general softness of the economy meant that the rise in output per manhour was considerably less than in previous years. The increase in output per man-hour for the private sector of the economy is estimated to have been in the range of 1.3 to 1.7 percent per year for 1956 and 1957, as against an average of 3.1 to 3.5 percent for the previous 4 years. Thus the two important elements that had been offsetting the increase in wages disappeared, and the result was increasing costs, which were passed along as increasing prices. PRICES AND COST It has frequently been charged that rising prices in these years were the consequence of monopolistically administered prices, that producers have been taking advantage of wage increases and other increases in costs to raise prices even more. If this were the case, profits should be increasing faster than wages. The evidence shows, however, that the reverse is true. Profits have been decreasing in relation to wages. This is shown in table 2 below. TABLE 2.—Relation of corporate wages and profits Corporate wages and salaries 1948 1949 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 85.0 83.1 91.3 105.0 112.5 121.9 119.1 128.9 139.7 Corporate profits and inventoryvaluation adjustment 30.6 28.1 35.1 39.9 36.9 36.0 33.1 40.7 40.4 Profits as a percentage of wages and salaries 36.0 QO Q 38.4 37.8 32.8 29.5 27.8 31.6 28.9 Source: Survey of Current Business, July 1952, table 12, p. 15 .and National Income Supplement, 1954 edition, table 12, p. 75. 302 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH The decline in profits relative to wages is a further confirmation that demand has not been excessive. When excess demand does exist, it tends to pull prices up. Costs are raised, in such a situation, by producers bidding against each other for existing resources. But the increase in costs will lag behind prices, since the demand for resources is essentially a derived demand and exists only because the prices of final goods are higher than costs. Nor does it follow that an increase in wages will always lead to excess demand that will result in a wage-price spiral. A given increase in wages, unaccompanied by any change in the rate of productivity increase, must be passed on as a price increase by the producer if he is to maintain his profits per unit at the same level. This means, however, that prices must rise in exact correspondence with the increase in wages. In order to sustain a wage-price spiral, therefore, an increase in spending would be required equivalent to the increase in wages. In a great many situations, such an increase in spending would not occur. In the first place, wage earners do not receive as spendable income all that producers pay them; taxes are paid to the Government, and additional funds may be siphoned off by contributory pension schemes and other fringe benefits. Furthermore, wage earners may decide to save a portion of their increase in wages. There is no reason to expect nonwage-earning groups to increase their spending to make up for the lack of spending of the wage earners, so that the volume of expenditure in real terms may actually decline. Similarly, the increase in prices of plant and equipment may mean that the real volume of investment will be reduced, since many producers have a fixed amount of money to spend for plant and equipment. This point is in a sense the reverse of the well-known Pigou effect, which states that a price decline will lead to a rise in real expenditures because of the increased real value of cash holdings. The rise in prices means that individuals' and businesses' cash holdings have a smaller value in real terms and this will tend to decrease the amount of real expenditures which they can and will make. It is quite possible, therefore, for wage increases to have a dampening effect on output. Such a situation is not the familiar wage-price spiral postulated by orthodox economics, but it seems quite likely that this is what has in fact occurred quite often in the United States economy. The increase in wages in 1937 (over 12 percent in manufacturing), may have contributed to the 1938 recession, which occurred even though the economy never reached full employment. Large wage increases also occurred from 1947 to 1948, from 1952 to 1953, and from 1956 to 1957. The recessions of 1949 and 1954 were not very severe, but nevertheless the rise in wages in the previous period may have had a dampening effect upon output. In 1956 and 1957, the rise in prices has been much sharper, and it also appears that the current decline in output may be more serious. THE BEHAVIOR OF WAGES From the foregoing discussion it might seem logical to conclude that the culprit in the present situation is wages, and that everything would be all right if the rate of increase in wages were slowed down. Such reasoning really assumes that wages throughout the economy follow key wage rates which in turn result from specific union bargains. A look at the data, however, reveals that the increase in E€ONiOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 303 wages has not come solely in the industrialized or unionized portions of the economy. The implicit deflator for Government services, for instance, rose 58 percent from 1947 to 1957, while prices in general rose only 30 percent. In private services also, the rise in wages has been very considerable. In certain occupations the supply of labor is not increasing as fast as the demand for it. In industries where output has been expanding and productivity increasing, furthermore, there is a natural tendency for wages to rise faster than in the lagging industries, both because the increase in wages is necessary to attract more labor and also because producers can pay higher wages and at the same time enjoy increased profits, owing to falling unit costs and increased output. If we are to permit adjustments of this sort to take place and if we do not want to reduce wages somewhere else, it is obvious that on average wages will increase. If the growth of productivity is small, the average increase in wages may exceed that in productivity. But stopping the increase in wages would necessarily involve either suppressing the natural readjustments in wages among various groups in the economy, or bringing about actual declines in wages in sectors of the economy where productivity increases were slower than the average or where the supply of labor was greater. This would imply, for instance, that Government employees, instead of enjoying a 58 percent increase in wages since 1947, might have suffered a decline at least in real terms, since Government service is an area where the supply of labor is not limited, and where, according to our statistical treatment, productivity does not increase. Such a procedure as this, however, would run counter to the considerations of equity which influence private producers and Government alike. The concepts of fair wages and fair prices do exist even though they may not be fully justifiable in the strictest economic sense. There is no assurance, furthermore, that tampering with wages would automatically correct the situation. Over the long run, the rate of increase of productivity might be affected, since it is at least in part the increase in wages and the expectation of future increases that induce producers to plan for and install the labor-saving devices that increase productivity. Moreover, even if the overall price level were lower, there is no guaranty that real purchasing power would be sufficient to keep the economy operating at full capacity. The maintenance of a close correspondence between growing purchasing power and growing capacity is a much more delicate problem than we have believed heretofore; there is no necessary reason why a reduction in. wages should assure equilibrium between expenditures and productive capacity over any extended period of time. Tampering with wages would attack only the surface phenomena, and in the process our normal price mechanism would be seriously disturbed. The roots of the present difficulty are much deeper, and we must seek a solution that will reach the heart of the problem without constituting a serious interference with the market mechanism of price determination. THE ROLE OF DEMAND The level of demand in the economy has, obviously, an important role in reaching such a solution, because of its repercussions on price, cost, and output behavior. A high level of demand which absorbs most of the capacity of the economy is a necessary condition for a 304 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH high level of investment. An economy operating considerably below full capacity does not provide the incentive for producers to expand. They do not expect that an increase in output would press upon their capacity or require additional plant and equipment, and uncertainty regarding demand makes even long-range planning difficult. The high rate of technological change (and consequently obsolescence) generally makes producers wary of long-range commitments except in circumstances where even obsolete capacity could be utilized profitably. It takes time, of course, before the capacity created by investment is available for productive purposes. But if, when the increased capacity does become available, demand does not or cannot increase to keep pace with it, investment may be curtailed, or at least it will increase at a lower rate. This will intensify the insufficiency of overall demand, and a cumulative decline may result. Thus, the seeds of a cumulative decline are potentially present in every period of high demand. In Schumpeterian terms, growth comes about in cycles, and a period of underutilization of capacity follows inevitably from a boom. In more recent years, this same phenomenon has been discussed in terms of the growth rates and the levels of investment that would be necessary to sustain capacity •operation. Given the increased absolute amount of-savings-that accompanies a growing economy, it is obvious that the absolute amount of investment will have to increase if demand is to keep pace with capacity. If the economy is geared to an increase in the relative level of saving as income rises, the relative amount of investment must also increase. A failure of investment to absorb all the income that people would like to save will result in the underutilization of capacity. In the 1930's, much the same subject was discussed in terms of secular stagnation. It was argued that profitable investment opportunities were drying up, so that the aggregate demand was bound to fall. Today one no longer hears much about this secular stagnation thesis, but if we had a severe depression, it might well emerge again as an explanation of the behavior of the economy. This relationship between the level of demand and investment has important implications for productivity change over time. In periods of rising demand, the apparent productivity gain will be substantial as underutilized capacity is employed more efficiently. Many sectors of the economy operate with decreasing costs. The distributive trades, for instance, can ordinarily sell a larger volume of goods with the same amount of resources. Similarly, mass production industries, such as consumer durable goods, generally have decreasing costs. A relative expansion of output in these sectors of the economy will therefore result in an increase in output per man-hour for the economy as a whole. On the other hand, true technological productivity increase will be relatively low in such periods, because of the relatively low level of investment in the immediately preceding periods when excess capacity existed. In periods of downswing, the technological productivity gains resulting from the relatively high level of investment in the preceding boom begin to appear, but they are somewhat obscured by the inefficiency of less-than-capacity operation of industry and the necessity for spreading fixed costs over a smaller output. Much of the real investment made during the boom goes unutilized, and the productivity gain resulting from it is wasted. ECONOMIC 'STABILITY AND GROWTH 305 In other words, because investment fluctuates the average level of productivity gain is very much reduced. This means that the influence of productivity increases in offsetting increasing wages and thus lowering costs is reduced, and price rises tend to be greater. A more stably maintained high rate of investment and a fuller use of capacity might well result in a considerably greater rate of increase in productivity, and so in a lowering of costs. This in turn would have a beneficial effect on prices as well as on output. It is often argued that wages, and therefore prices, will rise faster under full employment conditions, and that the only way to keep the increase in wages and prices under control is through the maintenance of some unemployment. This argument leaves out of consideration the impact of slackening demand upon productivity. There is good reason to believe that investment is more sensitive to the level of operation of the economy than are wage rates. It is true that a decline in profits tends to make producers resist wage demands more strenuously, and a decline in employment makes labor less adamant in its demands. But, as has been pointed out above, the same falling profits and the same expectation of excess capacity have important repercussions on investment. The slower increase in productivity through failure to utilize capacity and low investment may over time lead to a greater increase in wage costs than would have occurred had demand and investment been higher. To consider the effect of changes in demand on wage rates alone therefore leaves out half the problem. For the producer, the important consideration is not wage rates, but wage costs. THE CURRENT SITUATION There can be little doubt that the American economy is now operating considerably below full capacity. The Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System has prepared a combined index of the degree of capacity utilization in industries producing such major materials as iron and steel, aluminum, copper, cotton yarn, synthetic fibers,, cement, wood pulp, paper, petroleum products, coke and industrial chemicals. At the beginning of this year, combined capacity in these industries exceeded output by about 35 percent. It is true that these are some of the industries that are hardest hit, but they represent a substantial portion of the private economy. The Federal Reserve Board index of industrial production indicates that the first quarter of 1958 industrial output was at a level which had previously been attained 5y2 years before (the last quarter of 1952). Furthermore, when fewer goods are produced, the output of retail and wholesale distribution will also fall. By now (April) the degree of underutilization of capacity in the materials-producing industries would be greater than 35 percent. For the economy as a whole, it is not unrealistic to suggest that output is a good 20 to 25 percent below physical capacity. At current prices, this means that we could be producing $100 billion in goods and services more than we are. Given an estimate of this magnitude, the question naturally arises whether we would have the capacity in terms of manpower, as well as plant and equipment, to produce such an additional volume of goods. Unemployment is now in the neighborhood of 7 or 8 percent of the labor force. The length of the average workweek, however, has dropped by another 4 or 5 percent, so that the total level of unem- 306 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH ployment, taking part-time work in account, might be as high as 10 or 12 percent. Moreover, the labor force has grown more slowly in the last year, owing to lack of employment opportunities, than would be normal for good times. During 1957, the labor force increased by only 0.6 percent. With full employment, an additional 2 percent increase in the labor force might be expected. Taking all of these figures together, man-hours could probably increase at least 10 or 12 percent without exceeding the full employment level; this would still leave 2 or 3 percent frictional unemployment. Could such a 10 to 12 percent increase in man-hours result in a 25 percent increase in output if, as already suggested, the physical capacity to produce such output exists ? An answer to this question may be sought by looking at the relationship between the changes in manhours and the changes in output that have actually occurred in years of recovery from a recession or depression. Table 3 below shows the data for five such periods. TABLE 3.—Relation of changes in man-hours to changes in output in post-recession periods [Percentage change from preceding year] Year 1922 1935 1939 1950 1955 Man-hours employed in the private sector Real private gross product 8.6 5.5 5.3 2.4 3.5 16.3 13.2 9.4 10.1 7.9 Ratio of col. 2 to col. 1 1.9 2.4 18 4.2 2.3 Source: Prices, Productivity, and Incomes, Joint Economic Committee Print, 85th Cong., 1st sess., table 5, p. 91. In the most striking instance, a 2.4 percent increase in man-hours in 1950 achieved a 10 percent increase in output. In the least favorable case, a 5.3 percent increase in man-hours in 1939 resulted in a 9.4 percent increase in output. The increase in output generated per manhour exceeded that which would be needed to produce an increase of $100 billion in output given our present unemployment in 3 of the 5 periods, and in both of the postwar periods. It is true, of course, that such an increase in output could not be achieved in a short space of time; increases in output of the magnitude of 25 percent cannot take place quickly. Even the most rapid rates of increase seldom go beyond 15 percent a year. But it would not be unreasonable to expect a 10-percent rate of increase to be maintained for several years. In this connection it is interesting to note that the increase in private gross product in constant prices for the 2-year period from 1922 to 1923, following the recession of 1921, was 31 percent. If some of the increase in output were plowed into productivityincreasing investment it is reasonable to suppose that after 2 years of 10 percent growth sufficient additional capacity and productivity would have been generated to make a continuing 5 or 6 percent growth rate possible, instead of the 3 percent growth rate that the economy has been averaging over good times and bad. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 307 If it is true that the economy is operating at a level of $100 billion below capacity at the present time, it is obvious that our most important task is to get the economy back to full capacity operation. The amount we are losing by operating at our current level is more than the total expenditure of the Federal Government. Even more serious than the waste of resources by idleness is the effect that underutilization of capacity has on investment, and therefore on long-term growth. As other countries continue to grow, we are likely to slip behind. The impact of the underutilization of capacity is not so much in the immediate present as it is upon future increases in productivity. Future levels of consumption and investment will be correspondingly reduced. The cost of idleness is much greater than, for instance, the cost of as much as $50 billion a year in foreign aid. It has already been noted that the price-cost-output situation in the United States at the present time is not unique in the history of our economy. It is also true that many of the other industrial countries are currently having much the same problem of rising wage costs and prices without excess demand. In Sweden this price-cost problem is most severe; Norway, the Netherlands, Canada, and the United Kingdom have had difficulties of this nature but in somewhat less degree. Even in Germany, where unemployment has been a major problem throughout the whole postwar period, wage rates in the last year or two have risen more than productivity. France is the only one of the western European countries that has recently been experiencing demand inflation. Belgium and Italy are still suffering from some unemployment, and wage costs in these two countries have been falling. In terms of growth of output since 1950, three countries stand at the bottom of the list: Denmark, the United Kingdom, and the United States. CONCLUSION There is no automatic mechanism that will keep the economy operating at full capacity. Left to chance, there will be fluctuations, resulting in considerable underutilization of capacity over time. The fluctuations will not occur around the full capacity level. Excessive demand will normally be of short duration and concentrated in periods of large defense expenditures or other abnormal demand. The periods of underutilization of capacity will be long, and although they may not be reflected in unemployment they will result in general softness, slow growth, and slow productivity increase. This chronic underutilization of capacity results not from the drying up of investment opportunities or from the maturing of the economy but from a failure of purchasing power to keep pace with potential production. The problem is that at the levels of output that would utilize capacity fully, the saving that consumers and business will want to do will exceed the investment that would normally occur at this level of output. There are two alternative approaches to this problem. First, a stimulation of consumption (either private or public) would reduce, at least in real terms, the amount of saving people want to do; and thus restore equality between saving and investment at capacity output. Alternatively, it would be possible to stimulate investment and thus bring it into equality with the saving individuals and business would want to do at capacity output. A free 2,3734—58 21 308 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH choice solution to the problem of the long-run full utilization of the economy does not exist. Either consumption or investment, or both, must be increased to take up the slack m the economy. This means that the decisions of either consumers or those purchasing producers' durable goods, or both, must be altered by tax cuts or other incentive measures. It would always be possible to achieve full capacity utilization by providing more purchasing power to consumers, but this entails the danger that the level of investment may be lower, and growth and productivity increase smaller, than we as a nation would choose given the opportunity to evaluate the true alternatives. In such a situation accumulated liquid assets in the hands of individuals, and the national debt, would tend to be large, but capital in real terms would be small. Stimulation of real investment, on the other hand, would yield greater increases in productivity and growth, and thus would result in a larger amount of real capital. The price-cost behavior in the economy is not the primary cause of the underutilization of capacity. The main cause is that at full capacity the economy does not operate in such a way that it continues to generate sufficient expenditures to purchase the output that can be produced. There is no automatic mechanism that will assure stability and full utilization of capacity. In the last analysis, the satisfactory operation of the economy is the responsibility of the Government. To the extent that the economy operates at less than full capacity, to this extent the Government has failed in its obligation to maintain the health of the economy. Monetary policy is not a sufficiently powerful tool to accomplish this task. There is considerable danger that in an attempt to prevent rising wages and prices there will be agitation to atomize both labor and business. The solution is not to be found in this direction. What we need are positive steps toward solving the problem, not negative steps. Nor is it an adequate solution for the Government simply to return purchasing power to individuals to be spent on consumer goods. By such a device, the Government would merely be thwarting the decision of the private economy to save. It is true that providing stronger incentives to invest will not necessarily insure full capacity utilization; it will create more capacity which, in turn, will demand either further increases in the purchasing power of consumers or further increases in investment. This, however, is not a cause for discouragement; it is merely the hallmark of increasing productive potential. Instead of despairing at the increase in our productive capacity, we should utilize it for an increasing standard of living and our future growth. MODELS OF THE PRICING PROCESS 1 J. Fred Weston, University of California, Los Angeles One set of papers in this compendium deals with the relative importance of demand versus cost factors in explaining recent price behavior in the United States. Another delineates the effects of prices on employment, output, and factor returns (incomes to factors of production). The basic function assigned to this paper is to provide a connecting link between these two sets of forces uy showing the interrelationships between them. This paper seeks to achieve its objective by three stages. First, it will illustrate the interrelationships by reference to the controversy over dichotemization in the pricing process. Second, it will review recent developments in the theory of macroeconomic factor returns which illumine the issues under consideration. Third, it will draw on empirical materials to test some of the ideas set out. I. DICHOTEMIZATION OF THE PRICING PROCESS One of the complaints lodged by the new economics was the indeterminacy of the absolute price level in classical economic theory. The indeterminacy was said to have resulted from a dichotemy in the analysis of the economic process of monetary economy. The dichotemy said that the commodity markets are dependent on and determine relative prices, but that the monetary sector is dependent upon and determines absolute (money) prices. Following the pattern set by the scholarly literature on this subject, the present paper analyzes these issues by an 11-equation model of the economic system. This model has simple numerical parameters. It is not strictly empirically based, for such systems are too complex for easy exposition. The use of a simple model with illustrative numbers accomplishes several things. Since many factors are involved, a literary discussion typically ends in the same disagreements which provoked the initial debate, because the interactions between the many elements operating in an economic process cannot be handled in an orderly fashion. On the other hand, econometric analysis must limit the number of variables to be manageable. For some situations, the key factors may have been omitted. Both literary and econometric discussions often have many unspecified, but implicit, assumptions which are crucial for determining the essential properties of the operation of the economy. 1 Support of studies of this and related topics by the committee on research, University of California, Los Angeles, is gratefully acknowledged. 309 310 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH The parameters of the equations in the present model are illustrative. But they make explicit the assumptions of the nature of behavior relationships. Different assumptions are readily made by changing the number and selection of variables and the values of the parameters of the equations. The system is set out completely in table I. TABLE I.—A model for investigating dichotemization of the pricing process I. THE FUNCTIONS (la) M»=Ji» (16) M»=M* (r,Y) (2a) M*=kY (26) Md=L (r,Y) (3) Af*=M<* (4) I=I(r,Y) (5) 8=8 (r,Y) (6) £=/ (7) Y=PR (8) R=R (Nd) (9) N*=F ^ (10) W=W+pf(N>) .P (tOa) a=0,/3=l (106) a = l , 0 = 0 (11) #<*=#• M,rf=»supply of money M =»demand for money F= national money income r representative interest rate level /=»investment (private) 5=saving jj-an index of physical output II. THE EQUATIONS (la) M«=200 (16) M'=2f 2f (2a) Md=2/5Y (26) M<*=.5F-12.5r (3) (4) /=.15y-4.5r+20 (5) £ = . 2 F + . 5 r - 2 5 (6) (7) Y=PR (8) 72=8.5 N*-.025N** (9) N*= 170-20. (10) (10a) A['=8O-5O/t0 (106) TF=5.29 (ID SYMBOLS P=index of the price level iV"d=labor demand w=real wage rate=^— iV«=labor supply W= money wage rate=wP 11 equations and 11 unknowns The system contains 11 equations and 11 unknowns. The values of the solutions are close to current national income accounts figures. The nature of the equations will be briefly described. l he system begins with two alternative money supply functions. Equation (la) is money supply given at $200 billions. This reflects the assumption that the money supply is determined by "banking policy" unrelated to economic variables in a clear or systematic fashion. Equation (lb) states that deposit creation through commercial bank lending policies is influenced positively by the level of business activity. Furthermore, at higher rates of interest more loanable funds are offered. The interest rate is meant to be representative of the complex of interest rates. The level of interest rates is most significant as an index of the kinds of credit standards and credit terms currently employed by lenders—in short, an index of the availability of loanable funds. Equation (2a) is an expression of the quantity theory of the demand for money. The quantity theory in its most familiar form is M V = P T . V, transactions velocity, can be expressed as 1/k which is the income velocity of money. The equation becomes M=kPT. If real output, R, is substituted for T, the total volume of transactions, the equation becomes M=kPR. PR is the same as money income, Y. The equation becomes M = k Y where k is the proportion of income command over which people desire to hold in the form of money. In equation (2a) the value of k is set at 2/5. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 311 An alternative formulation of the demand for money is the liquidity preference theory. This states that the demand for money is influenced by 2 sets of factors instead of 1. The demand for money is influenced by the level of economic activity through the transactions motive for holding cash balances. In addition, cash balances are held for precautionary and speculative motives. The amount of liquidity people will buy is influenced by its cost—interest rates. The cost of liquidity is the interest which otherwise could have been earned by the cash balances by investing them. The fourth equation is the investment function. It has a segment which indicates that investment depends upon output (sales), a form of the acceleration principle. Since profits before taxes are correlated with the level of economic activity, this segment of the investment function may also be said to reflect the profit variable as well. The sign and value of the interest term states that investment is negatively interest elastic. Autonomous investment of $20 billion per year is the final segment of the equation. The savings equation contains the same variables as the investment equation. The amount saved will reflect the level of business activity. Savings may also be stimulated by the payment of higher interest rates. Since savings is equal to investment by equation (6) and investment is income less consumption, consumption is also income less savings. Thus the implied consumption function is C=25+.8Y—.5r. The negative 25 in the savings equation reflects the positive intercept of the consumption function. The foregoing six equations complete the monetary subset of the system. Alternative forms of the money supply and money demand equations will be used in observing the solution process of the complete system. The last five equations represent the commodity or "real" subsector of the system. Equation (7) states that the price level is the ratio between money income and real output. Equation (8) is an aggregate production function. It expresses real output as a function of the quantity of labor input. The constants in the equation reflect the stock of capital in the economy and indicate that this is a statical model. The parameters of this equation, reflecting the quality and quantity of the capital stock, determine the productivity of labor. Equation (9) is the demand for labor function. It is obtained by taking the first derivative dof the production function, equation (8). The result is w=8.5 —05N . When this expression is rearranged in the form of a demand for labor, it becomes equation (9). Equation (10) is the labor supply function. We have two forms. Equation (10a) is the classical labor supply function which states that the supply of labor is an increasing function of the real wage. Equation (10b) is a Keynesian labor supply function. It depicts a situation in which labor union policy establishes what the level of money wages will be. We have now the complete equation system of the economy. It seeks to represent practical and realistic elements of the economy and to show how they interact. Specific assumptions about the behavior characteristics of the economic process are made unambiguous. 312 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Situation I: Classical forms The operation of this system can first be illustrated by the selection of the classical forms of the equations where alternative forms are presented. This is not a complete classical system because to conserve space, the classical formulations of the investment and savings functions are omitted. Accordingly, equations (la), (2a), and (10a) are used with the remaining 8. Equation (3) becomes: (3) 200=2/5Y This equation is readily solved, Y is equal to $500 billions. Equation (6) is: (6) .15Y-4.5r+20=.2Y+.5r-25 Since Y is equal to $500 billions, r can be evaluated at 4 percent. Thus investment and savings are equal at $77 billions. We observe therefore that the monetary subsector can be solved to obtain the money values of income, investment, savings, and the interest rate. Income is obtained from the two monetary equations. This level of income, along with the interest rate, determines the level of investment and savings. The solution to the commodity market equations proceeds independently. Equation (11) is: (11) 170 - 20w=80 - 50/w The value of the real wage is $5,000, a rough estimate of the average level of wages. With the real wage established, the demand for labor and supply of labor are 70 million people. The value of the demand for labor, 70, is used in equation (8), the aggregate production function, to obtain real output of $472.5 billion in constant dollars. This amount is divided into money income of $500 to obtain a price level of 105.8. We observe that employment, real wages, and output were determined in the commodity subsector without reference to the monetary subsector. Money income from the money sector was used to determine the absolute price level. Thus, in classical economics, money was indeed a veil and had no effect on the real factors in the economy. To increase the money supply would be to increase money income, but not real output or real wages and employment. Since the demand and supply of labor determined real wages, there was no scope for the establishment of a wage policy outside the boundaries defined by these conditions. The Keynesian formulation finds an interrelationship between the monetary and real sectors. What characteristics of the Keynesian system bring this about ? Situation II: Keynesian monetary equations, classical labor functions We begin with a complete money-supply equation (lb). This is taken in conjunction with the liquidity preference form of the demand for money equation (2b). Equation (3) now becomes— (3) % 5 Y+20r=.5Y-12.5r (6) .15Y-4.5r+20=.2Y+.5r-25 ECONiOMIiC STABILITY AND- GROWTH 313 Since two unknowns are involved, we need equation (6) to obtain the values of income and the interest rate. These are, respectively, $500 billion and 4 percent. The numerical solutions under all the alternative assumptions will be identical so that attention will be focused on the solution process. In this set of relationships, it is necessary to have the money supply-and-demand equations to obtain the money value of savings and investment. Also, the savings and investment functions are needed to determine income as well as interest-rate levels. In the real subsector, nothing has been changed. Hence, the solution would proceed in the same fashion as under the completely Classical case. Thus the liquidity-preference function is neither a necessary nor sufficient condition for the monetary subset to have an influence on real output, wages, or employment. Situation III: Keynesian labor-supply fwwtions We now combine the Keynesian labor-supply functions with either form of the monetary subset. Since the monetary subset is solved independently under either set of assumptions, we may take the solutions from the monetary subset as obtained under either situation I or II. We then solve the real sector. To use equations (9) and (10b) in equation (11), we change equation (9) into the form: (9) ]ST d =170-^ We now solve for W. Equation (11) becomes— (11) 5.29= Solve for N in terms of P. (11) Nd=170d This value of Nd is substituted in equation (8), which reduces to— 279.84 (8) #=722.52 P In order to obtain solutions for the commodity sector, it is necessary to have the value of money income, Y, from the monetary subsector. Equation (7) then reads: (7) 500= We can solve for P, which is 105.8 as before. The solution process with a Keynesian labor-supply function demonstrates how the monetary and real sectors may become interdependent. Other relationships would bring about the same result. For example, the "Pigou effect"—consumption will increase at enhanced real values of cash balances—could be incorporated into the savings function to read: (5) 5=.25Y+.4r-.13M-20 P 314 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Or the investment function may include a negative response to rises in real wages— (4) I=.2Y-5w-4.5r+20 Other assumptions about economic behavior functions could be reflected in the set of equations to determine their consequences. Or problems, other than the dichotemization of the pricing process, could be investigated. In this connection, the Keynesian position on the "flaw" in the price system—its inability to bring about adjustments to restore the economy to a full-employment equilibrium could be studied. In general terms, the flaw argument can be briefly stated. Planned savings exceed planned investment, so income and output fall. The declines in output give rise to wage cuts; reduced income leads to less consumption, so the price level falls. Thus, the real quantity of money falls, its value rises. People bid for other assets, so that the rate of interest falls. Investment might rise toward the full-employment equilibrium level, but may fail to do so for one or both of two reasons. One, investment may not respond to declines in interest levels—a negative rate of interest may be necessary to call forth the necessary increase in investment. Two, at some lowered level of interest rates, the cost of holding cash balances has become so small that people may be willing to hold indefinitely large balances— the liquidity trap. As a consequence of either situation, equilibrium would settle at less than full-employment levels. This description of the flaw in the price mechanism does not depend on rigid wages, as the interdependence analysis did. The rejoinder to the "flaw in the price mechanism" argument is the Pigou effect. Pigou argued that, as the price level falls, the value of cash balances rises and, as a consequence, consumption increases to bring the economy back to full employment equilibrium. This process does not depend on lowered interest rates to call forth more investment. Thus, the effect of wage changes or monetary policy on prices, real output, and employment depends upon which of the alternative assumptions about the nature of the behavior equations is the most realistic approximation to actual conditions. This is an area requiring further empirical materials. The system of equations presented above for analyzing the pricing process illustrates the operations of the economic system. It provides a framework for analyzing the relationship between prices, output, employment, and real wages. However, more recent literature has used a different approach to study wage policy. n . A MODEL FOR STUDYING THE MACROECONOMIO THEORY OF WAGES Recent literature has centered attention on the income and spending aspects of wage increases. Gross national product from the spending side or demand side is related to gross national product representing the summation of factor returns. These relationships are shown in table 2. Equations 1 through 5 are spending or demand functions. Equations 6 through 15 represent aspects of factor incomes. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 315 TABLE 2.—A model for studying the macroeconomic theory of wages D equals GNP spending 1. Y=C+I+G 2. C=.65 + .G(Y-Tx) 3. Tx=.2Y 4. 7=20+.15F 5. G=$100B 6. P = - 8 - K l l F 7. CTX=.5P 8. D=.6Pa 9. CS=APa 10. Pa=P-CTx 11. *+r+p = $73 12. de=.OSY 13. tix=-10+.1Y 14. TT= 15. « , - f = ^ = M > 2 8 6 F equals ^AT'P factor incomes B. Symbols C= Sales to Individuals (consumption) / = Gross Private Investment (r=Spending by Government Tx=Taxes P— Corporate Profit before taxes Pa= Corporate Profit after taxes D=Dividends CS= Corporate Saving CTX= Corporate Taxes i—Interest Income r=Rental Income W— Wages and Salaries L=Labor Force U= Unemployment N= Employment w=Average wage per worker de=depreciation P=unincorp. business profits Us=indirect business taxes With a wage increase, factor incomes rise. Potentially, the aggregate demand function increases as well. Figure I illustrates the forces set out in table 2. FIGURE I The increase in wages raises factor returns from F to F 2 . Whether employment increases or decreases depends upon changes in effective demand. Employment will either decrease, increase, or remain the same depending upon the relative shifts of the F and D functions. Unfortunately, we have little empirical material on the spending propensities of different categories of income receivers in relationship to income changes of the kind suggested by the above analysis. The movement of the F and D functions will result from the operation of forces which the recent literature on the subject has only cataloged, but not adequately identified. i n . PRODUCTIVITY, PRICES, AND INCOMES Numerical models of the economic system are assuredly less powerful and informative than recent empirical, dynamic models of the 316 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH economy. Yet they possess the advantage of relative simplicity of exposition and force a clear statement of assumptions. These simple models demonstrate how complex the economic process must be and illustrate how numerous variables interact. The models could be used to make specific assumptions about behavior relationships and then reason to a conclusion about the consequences of wage changes, changes in monetary policy, changes in tax policy. Recently, studies have been made of the time j)aths of response of selected variables to changes in tax policy.2 Similar studies are needed for analyzing the response of the system to changes in wages and prices. Still another approach has argued that an analysis of market structure is necessary to provide "the first wholly satisfactory integration of the wage-price spiral with aggregative demand and price analysis." 3 My emphasis would be the reverse, that most analyses of postwar wage and price behavior have neglected macroeconomic considerations of the kind suggested by the models presented in the previous two sections. For the macroeconomic approach provides a framework for encompassing the effects of economic change on factor returns and their consequences for the rate and pattern of spending. Partial equilibrium studies of wages, profits, productivity, and prices are characteristically incomplete. Much emphasis has been placed on the following relationship: ["Percent ~| ["Percent ~| |~Percent "1 "Percent change in I equals change in I less I change in I plus change Lpriees J Lwages J LproductivityJ in profit margin on sales However, the causative mechanism is not portrayed by this set of relationships. In the short run, the absolute level of productivity is a function mainly of the capital stock employed in an industry. Changes in productivity overtime are highly correlated with changes in output.4 But increases in output have differential price consequences. The demand pull which calls forth output increases is a price rising influence. Increased output spreads overhead over a larger number of units and is a cost reducing factor. The net result depends upon the elasticities of supplies of products, as well as elasticities of demand, including market structure effects. 2 Arthur Goldberger, Properties of an Econometric Model of the United States, Econometric Society, Philadelphia, December 30, 1957. 3 J. K. Galbraith, Market Structure and Stabilization Policy, The Review of Economics and 4 Statistics, XXXIX (May 1957), p. 129. Trends in Output Per Man-Hour and Man-Hours Per Unit of Output—Manufacturing, 1939-53. BLS report No. 100, p. 314. 317 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE 3.—Behavior of selected economic variables for manufacturing industries, 1949-36 (l) Industry Lumber and wood products Furniture and fixtures Stone, clay, and glass Primary metals Fabricated metals Machinery (not electrical) Electi ical machinery Transportation equipment Miscellaneous manufacturing. _ Food and kindred products Tobacco manufactures Textile mill products Apparel Paper and allied products Chemical and allied Products of petroleum and coal. Rubber products Leather and leather products.. (2) (3) Percent Percent increase increase in pro- in hourly duction, earnings, 1949-56 1949-56 35.2 28.4 56.4 25.5 39 2 5L5 111.2 89.5 46.9 15.3 4.9 6.1 12.0 62.2 73.5 35.6 38.5 41.0 35.5 43.4 47.2 40.4 43.1 36.8 38 0 38.1 44.2 49.5 21.2 26 5 433 44.8 41.9 39.9 31.6 (4) (5) Percent inPercent creases net increases profits to sales, 1949-56 in prices (1947-49), 1956 Before After taxes taxes 25.4 24.8 26.9 53.4 32.7 41.7 37.6 29.1 -9.0 6.1 15.5 -12.1 -.3 27.2 7.2 17.3 45.8 -.7 -27.2 11.9 12.2 28 8 -10.3 2.8 -16.1 -20.2 8.1 -9.1 50.7 -24.3 43.2 13.2 15.4 17.5 50.9 10.3 -33.9 3.0 —4.7 13.6 -21.6 -15.6 -33.3 -35.7 0 -27.3 16.3 -36 6 23.8 -6.2 -2.4 20.2 15.8 -4.5 (6) Average level of concentration of employment, 1950 27.7 25.3 50.2 53.8 39.9 41.6 59.6 60.4 38.4 42.3 57.3 31.5 -.3 33.5 51.6 40.3 75.0 24.2 Sources: Cols. 2-4, Federal Reserve Bulletins. Col. 5, Federal Trade Commission, Securities and Exchange Commission, Quarterly Financial Report for Manufacturing Corporations. Col. 6, Federal Trade Commission, Report on Changes in Concentration in Manufacturing, 1935-47 and 1950, pp. 132136. Calculated by taking unweighted arithmetic average of concentration ratios of the 4-digit products included under the industries listed above. Table 3 illustrates some of the problems of the microeconomic approach. With the data, matrices may be made of the influence on prices, wages, or profits or changes in production at different levels of concentration. These matrices show that for increases in production, price rises would be larger, but not uniformly so. For the same increases in production, larger increases in hourly earnings result in larger price rises, but not in a consistent fashion. Profit changes are most directly connected with increases in output, but numerous exceptions are found. Increases in production haw a greater influence on price increases than the average level of concentration in manufacturing industries. Small production increases are associated with lower levels of concentration and large production increases are associated with higher levels of concentration. This explains why the incautious or determined will find with selected data an association between levels of concentration and price level changes. Also impressive is the clustering of wage increases during the period at the 40- to 45-percent level, except for industries where production (sales) increases have been small. Where production increases have been lower, wage rises have also been smaller. These data show that the many simple generalizations explaining recent price changes are subject to considerable reservation. Cost push does not explain price increases, because hourly wage increases and price increases have been smaller where production increases have been smaller. Administered prices do not explain price increases, since prices increases are small even among concentrated industries where production increases have been small, e. g., tobacco manufacturers. 318 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH Little relationship can be found between profit increases and price increases when these are stratified by groups of percent increases in production or in hourly earnings. Thus the macroeconomic models depicted in the early part of the paper will not perform the complete task of explaining price changes; neither will the usual kind of partial analysis. Both are needed. But we cannot be content with the easy aphorisms suggested by the need for both approaches and the need for separating the influence of different kinds of forces. Individual institutional developments as well will have a substantial impact. Two illustrations will demonstrate this. The Revenue Act of 1954 which liberalized the rate at which depreciation could be charged against income for tax purposes reduced the cost of capital equipment, i. e., increased its probable return. This change was doubtless a significant factor in the capital equipment boom of 1955 and 1956 and related price effects. The lengthening of terms in auto installment contracts to 36 months during 1955 was equivalent to a substantial reduction in automobile prices as expressed by required monthly payments. This effective price decrease had an important influence on the 7.9 million production achieved in 1955 with its consequent influence on the projected levels of productivity in the automobile industry, the large wage increase and its subsequent spread through American industry. IV. CONCLUSIONS This paper has sought to show the interrelationships between the cost-demand influences on price on the one hand, as well as the impact of price changes on economic aggregates and factor returns. To do this it sketched the framework of macroeconomic systems which exhibited these relationships. To show the operation of the relevant forces in clearer focus, empirical data on production, hourly earnings, prices, profits and concentration were brought together. The data controvert the easy generalizations which have been used to explain recent price behavior in the United States. The crucial role of institutional changes further limits the validity of monistic explanations of causative factors. INTERRELATIONSHIPS AMONG PRICES, EMPLOYMENT, OUTPUT, INCOMES, AND RESOURCES 319 V. Interrelationships among prices, employment, output, incomes, and resources A. Price changes and the allocation of resources. 1. What may impede shifts in the proportions in which factors are used when changes in their relative prices call for such a shift ? How can the mobility of resources be increased ? 2. It is often said that in a dynamic economy highprofits opportunities are needed in order to attract additional resources to industries with rapidly expanding demand and thus bring down prices and profits in the long run. Does existing evidence show that industries and corporations making "high" profits tend to expand production and productive capacity more rapidly than industries and corporations making "lower" profits ? 3. Do prices behave differently where capacity is being expanded rapidly from industries where capacity is more stable or declining ? If so, why ? 4. What are likely to be the effects of price level changes upon patterns of real investment and the allocation of resources? 5. To what extent are past and prospective price changes likely to affect personal consumption and savings patterns ? 6. To what extent and under what circumstances is the choice of personal investment patterns of individuals affected by past and prospective changes in the general price level ? B. Relationship of prices to aggregate economic activity. 1. How, and to what extent, are aggregate employment and output affected by the direction and rate of change in the general price level? In relative prices? 2. Does inflation tend to generate an ensuing collapse of employment, production, and purchasing power, as well as of prices? If so, by what process ? Does the rate of increase in prices influence the outcome ? 3. What are the effects of price changes on profit margins, on rates of return, on investments, and on the stimulus for technical progress and expansion? 4. What effects do general price level changes have upon the size and composition of the labor force, and upon labor and managerial incentives ? 320 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 321 5. What are the effects of price level changes on business financial structures—on depreciation of fixed assets, on requirements for working capital versus those for fixed assets, etc. ? What are the effects on ability to finance technical improvements which make possible greater productivity and improved products ? On ability to finance expansion ? What are the characteristics of an "ideal" financial structure for a business enterprise— internal versus external funds, equity versus debt, etc? From existing data, what can be stated about the relative amount of investment by firms of various sizes in each industrial segment and about the principal sources of capital utilized by each size of firm? THE COMPOSITION OF THE PRICE STRUCTURE, RESOURCE ALLOCATION, AND EMPLOYMENT LEVELS Clark C. Bloom, State University of Iowa THE SIMPLE VIEWS Flows—Of output and of expenditures The price-market-organized economy of the United States today produces both a flow of expenditures and a flow of output. The flow of expenditures is largely fed by the flow of income but varies therefrom by (1) decisions to hold more or less money, or (2) decisions to borrow from, or to repay loans to, a fractional reserve banking system and thus to expand or to contract the supply of money. The flow of output is motivated by the flow of expenditures and thus represents the response of producers, usually private businesses, thereto. This flow of output is functionally related to the employment of inputs and the generation of income. The two flows are thus obviously interrelated. Flows to maximize output At any point in time, a price is determined for each unit type of each factor of production, human or material. At this price, some units will not seek employment either because of the greater psychic value of leisure that would have to be given up or because of money costs associated with that employment which reduce net compensation to zero or below that level at which leisure seems more attractive. To force the employment of these voluntarily idle resources obviously involves either a waste of resources or a dictation of a real consumption rather than a leisure choice for the individual. Both are usually seen as undesirable. On the other hand, a society which attaches a positive value to expanded real output will certainly wish to provide employment at the existing factor price to each factor unit seeking employment at that price. The maximum flow of output is that made possible by the full utilization of resource units seeking employment at existing factor prices. If this maximum output flow is held desirable—or, alternatively, if the unemployment of resources is held undesirable in its own right because of the unsatisfactory redistribution of income which it implies, or because of its social consequences, then desirable also is that flow of expenditures which calls forth thisflowof output. Policy for maximum output flow In the simple view now being discussed, the existence of unemployment which signals a failure to maximize output requires action. Required is either an expansion of the flow of expenditures (via (1) reduced money holdings or (2) expanded borrowing from the banks) or an expanded physical volume response by producers to a given 23734—58 22 323 324 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH expenditures flow (via a changed functional relationship between the flow of expenditures and the employment of inputs). Assuming prior maximizing behavior and its continuance under static conditions by private individuals and businesses, only government can generate an expanded expenditures flow. It can do so by either reducing its cash balances or—and more importantly—by bank borrowing to cover deficits resulting from either (1) tax cuts, which increase private incomes, or (2) increased purchases by governmental units themselves. Since tax cuts may result in either (1) increased money holdings, or (2) the repayment of bank loans by individuals in lieu of increased expenditures, a given deficit is usually thought more stimulating of employment and output when it results from spending on goods and services by government rather than from a tax cut. Prices and maximum output flow Prices are implicit in this simple view. Implied is the orthodox model of micro economics in which (1) outputs are rationed among customers via price, (2) inputs are rationed among producers via price, (3) output volume changes are signaled by changes in the relationship between revenues (related to output prices) and costs (related to input prices), and (4) input volume changes are signaled by changes in the price thereof. But, in this simple view, these prices, once determined by market forces, are seen as unchanging, so that the real value of the expenditures flow and the real quantity of the output flow remain unchanged so long as the dollar values thereof remain unchanged. Indeed, the only conceivable explicit treatment of a price in this simple view is with regard to the rate of interest. This rate can be seen, sometimes is seen, as varying with (1) the desire to hold money, or (2) changes in the supply of money, actual or potential, by the banking authorities. Thus, an "easy money" policy (via (1) lower rediscount rates, (2) open market purchases, or (3) reduced reserve requirements) increases supply and lowers the rate of interest. The decline in this price (relative to all others seen as unchanging) is seen as increasing borrowing and as expanding the flow of expenditures by borrowers (usually ignoring its impact on the desire to hold money or an asset values). However, this increased borrowing and its consequent expansion of the flow of expenditures is frequently seen as not sufficient to overcome any substantial failure to maximize output because of unemployment. Action via Government deficits is still seen as the more important policy position. Certainly, the simple view does not explicitly take account of such price changes as might be expected to occur in the face of a substantial unemployment or a failure to maximize output. Neither does it explicitly consider whether or not these changes contribute to a growth in output (and employment) or to a further decline in output (and employment). The causes of recession (depression) The simple view, focusing on flows of expenditures and output but ignoring (or minimizing) the impact of price movements, must find the causes of recession in either (1) a decline in flow of expenditures, or (2) an increase in the supply of the factors. A decline in the flow of expenditures will follow upon the substitution of money holdings or bank-debt retirement for goods as the result ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 325 of (1) expectations with respect to such price movements as are anticipated, particularly with respect to the rate of interest and related securities' prices, (2) tastes or preferences for goods, particularly important for durable goods when timing of purchases can change drastically, and (3) bank policy which may be pointed toward a reduction in the money supply, and hence a reduction in bank loans outstanding. An increase in the supply of factors obviously does not mean a decline in output. An increasing supply of factors in the face of constant employment means instead (1) a growing margin between actual and potential output, and (2) increasing problems relating to unemployment directly. A failure to expand a flow of expenditures and output thus spells recession. A recession is not only a decline, but a failure to grow. The avoidance of recession, therefore, requires a broadening of the flow of expenditures with an increase in factor supplies which, in the simple view, can come only with a substitution of goods for money accompanied by an expansion of bank loans. In this view, it is worth emphasizing that recessions do not develop as the consequence of, and are not accompanied by, general or relative price movements. PRICE MOVEMENTS—THE SIMPLE VIEW Introduction I t is, of course, perfectly possible to deal with price movements, their causes and their consequences, within the simple situation of the preceding section. This is now to be done. This discussion is to be divided into three parts as follows: (1) An indication of the kind of price movements which can be expected either to accompany, or to cause, a movement away from a full-employment equilibrium situation; (2) an analysis of subsequent price movements which accompany, or cause, either a further movement away from equilibrium or a return to it; and (3) a look at the kind of policies suggested by the specific consideration of the role of prices. Price movements and the onset of the recession Accompanying output price movements.—A narrowing of the flow of expenditures (via an increased holding of money, repayment of bank loans outstanding, or reduced borrowing from banks) implies a diminution in demand for most outputs. Under competitive conditions, this means a short-run decline in price and in volume as existing firms reduce output. This will be followed, in the long run, by a rise in price toward original levels but with a further decline in output accompanying a withdrawal of firms. Under monopoly conditions (including conditions of monopolistic competition) for firms a,ware of their demand and cost functions and motivated to maximize profits, the narrowing of the flow of expenditures usually results in both lower prices and reduced output. Under monopoly conditions (including conditions of monopolistic competition) for firms pricing on a "full cost" basis (i. e., setting price at average cost plus a conventional markup), the narrowed flow means sharply reduced volumes and possible price increases as average costs rise with the movement of outputs back from "capacity" (i. e., minimum average cost) levels. Under oligopoly conditions, a tendency to set prices on a "full cost" basis plus tacit or informal agreements which cause 326 ECONOMIC STABILITY A1STD GROWTH prices to be "sticky" are likely to yield price stability and sharply reduced outputs. In each case, however, a narrowing expenditures flow means reduced volume. Accompanying factor price movements.—When output diminishes with a narrowing of the flow of expenditures, the demand for factors diminishes. Under competitive conditions in the factor market, this means both lower factor prices and reduced employment thereof. Under conditions of noncompetitive factor supply wherein factor prices are given and unchanged, employment in response to a given expenditures flow declines more sharply. In either case, however, the result is a diminished volume of factor employment. Similarly, if factor supplies increase while expenditures flows and factor demand held steady, competitive conditions in the factor market will mean lower factor prices and expanded employment while noncompetitive conditions mean factor-price stability and stability of employment in the face of mounting unemployment. Causal output price movements.—Given a flow of expenditures, autonomous output price increases (via such developments as (1) a change in market structure which replaces a competitive with a higher monopoly price, (2) a reduction in supply consequent upon a technological change which moves marginal cost curves of firms to the left, or (3) an increase in conventional markups for "full cost" prices) reduce the real value of such flows. Physical output flows are diminished with a consequent diminished use of factors. Incidentally, autonomous price increases of the kind noted above do not seem likely of frequent occurrence. They do not seem likely to be a usual trigger for a recession. Closely related to such autonomous output price movements are those movements which stem from autonomous shifts in demand. Suppose for example an autonomous change in preferences in favor of a specific good. In most market situations, the price of this goods will rise and additional resources will be required for its expanded production. At the same time, the demand for substitute goods will fall, their price will fall, and fewer resources will be required for their diminished production. In this case, two relevant possibilities exist. First, there is the possibility that the changed situation may lead to a diminished flow of expenditures. This is likely if the preferred goods are conventionally purchased out of income while the disadvantaged oods are conventionally purchased with the aid of borrowed money, uch a set of facts may well lead to the retirement of debt without an offsetting decline in money balances and thus yield a reduced expenditures flow. A reduced flow of expenditures is also likely if the supply curve for the preferred goods is quite inelastic (so that expenditures thereon rise relatively little) while the similar curves for disadvantaged goods are quite elastic (so that expenditures on them fall rapidly). In either case, a reduced-expenditures flow will pinch volume. Second, a given flow of expenditures now motivates a different pattern of output and the use of a different "bundle" of factors. This flow may motivate an output which does not fully utilize the existing supplies of any factor and may certainly leave supplies of certain specific factors unemployed. It is thus possible that price changes accompanying autonomous shifts in demand may lead to a diminished expenditures and output flow; although, of course, the opposite effect is also possible. § ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 327 Causal factor price movements.—Given a flow of expenditures, autonomous increases in factor prices will motivate higher product prices, reduced outputs, and diminished factor use. Such autonomous increases are most likely via a change in market structure which replaces a competitive with a higher monopoly price. Price movements as recession correctives The preceding section notes price movements which accompany or trigger a narrower real flow of expenditures. More interesting and more important than these price movements already noted are those which accompany or motivate processes which (1) return the economy to full employment, (2) push the economy to lower levels of employment and output, or (3) leave the economy in equilibrium at less than full-employment levels. A basic situation.—Assume a previously presented situation in which the expenditures flow narrowed for reasons unrelated to a price change. Price consequences were lower prices for some outputs (i. e., those outputs sold competitively or by noncompetitive firms which know demand and cost functions and move to maximize profits) and lower prices for some factors (i. e., those sold in competitive markets). Consequences also included a reduced volume of output and reduced factor employment. Viewing this situation further, the lower factor prices mean lower costs. These lower costs will mean lower output price, greater output volume, and diminished declines in factor employment provided that the expenditures flow does not narrow further. Indeed, if the factorsupply schedule is sufficiently inelastic, or if it shifts sufficiently to the right to take account of a growing real income provided by given wage rates as outpmt prices decline; factor prices (and hence firm costs) will fall rapidly enough so that the economy's real output and employment will have declined but little. On the other hand, if the factor-supply schedule is elastic, factor prices (and hence firm costs) will fall so slowly that the economy's real output and employment will remain at low levels. The key conclusion, however, is that output and employment do not regain levels attained prior to the initial narrowing of the expenditures flow. The foregoing assumes that the new, narrowed flow of expenditures can be maintained. If it can, the economy will stabilize at the new, lower levels of output and employment. On the other hand, if the flow of expenditures narrows further, additional declines in output and employment are in prospect. Or, if the flow of expenditures does now rise, then growth in output and employment toward full-employment levels can be anticipated. The important question has to do with the relative likelihood of either a decline or an increase in the expenditures flow. Pressures toward decline are strong. They include (1) the immediately preceding decline in money income (by definition as the expenditures flow narrowed) and in real income (as output diminished) which may well lead to protective action designed to increase money holdings or to retire debt, both reducing the expenditures flow, (2) the immediately preceding decline in factor employment which may well suggest still further efforts at protective action, (3) the immediately preceding decline in output prices which may well lead to the anticipation of further declines and a consequent postponement of 328 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH purchases, and (4) the immediately preceding likely unfavorable bank experience in the face of declining incomes which will probably motivate decline, rather than increase, in bank lending and the resultant money supply. If these strong pressures do, in fact, further narrow expenditures flows, market adjustments—of which price changes are a part—are inadequate to stem the recessionary tide. However, an increase in the expenditures flow is not impossible. If (1) the immediately preceding price declines are deemed only temporary and the anticipation of future increases stimulate purchases, (2) efforts are made to protect living standards in the face of lower incomes by reducing money balances or by bank borrowing, (3) the increased real value of money balances or fixed dollar value asset holdings when output prices decline so meet liquidity requirements that buyers are willing to spend a larger portion of current income or to borrow more, and (4) if bank policy looks toward maximum lending, the flow of expenditures will expand. If this expansion does, in fact, occur, then market adjustments—of which price changes are a part—are adequate to stem the recessionary tide and to return the economy to full employment. Market adjustments, price adjustments, are thus not always adequate to restore a maximum flow of output. Indeed, on balance, it seems unlikely that they will usually be so. If they are not, policy suggested by the simple view in which prices were taken as given still seems desirable. Other situations.—A flow of output at less than full-employment levels has previously been seen to appear with a constant expenditures flow but (1) growing factor supplies, (2) autonomous output price rises, or (3) autonomous factor price rises. Each of these situations can be analyzed similarly to the basic situation. In each case, stability at new, lower output and employment levels will accompany the maintenance of the constant expenditures flow. A decline in the flow will mean a further decline in output and employment and the inability of market adjustments to stem a downturn. An increase in the flow will mean an upturn in output and employment to full-employment levels and an ability of market adjustments to restore a position of maximum output. In the first case (growing factor supplies), a further view of the situation discloses lower factor prices, lower costs, lower output prices, greater output volume, and at least some increases—although not to full employment levels—in factor employment if the expenditures flow is just maintained. In this case, pressures toward a decline in the expenditures flow seem less strong and an increase more likely. While total money and real income both declined in the basic situation, money income now holds constant and total real income rises. While employment actually declined in the basic situation, in the present case it is growing. While bank experience was unsatisfactory in the basic situation, it is unlikely to have been generally so with the better-income positions here viewed. Only the immediately preceding decline in output prices, which may well lead to the anticipation of future declines and a postponement of purchases, really point to a reduced flow. Countering this is the possibility that increased factor supplies mean increased labor supplies, a growing population, a more rapid rate of family formation, and an increased implied stimulus to borrow for consumer and civic durable items which this more ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 329 rapid population growth and rate of home formation implies. On balance, the chances are good in this case that market adjustments will lead to a widened expenditures flow and the achievement of maximum output levels. In the second case (autonomous output price rises), reduced output and reduced factor use will again mean lower factor prices, lower costs, a decline of output prices toward—but not to—levels prior to the exogenous increase, an increase in output volume toward—but not to—the prior level, and at least some recovery toward—but not to—full-employment levels if the expenditures flow is just maintained. In this case, pressure toward a decline in the expenditures flow seem less strong than in the basic situation but stronger than in the case of growing factor supplies. As compared to the basic situation, money income has remained constant rather than declined and output prices have risen rather than fallen. Both of these developments argue for reduced pressures for a decline in the expenditures flow and make a possible increase easier of visualization. In the third case (autonomous factor price rises), higher factor prices are followed by higher costs, higher output prices, reduced volume, and reduced factor employment if the expenditures flow is just maintained. As in the second case, and for the same reasons, pressures toward a decline in the expenditures flow seem less strong than in the basic situation and make a possible increase therein easier of visualization. Price movements and policy Market adjustments, in which price movements are*an important factor, are capable of restoring maximum output and full employment only when they permit, and are accompanied by, a widening flow of expenditures. Any policy which encourages this broadening of flow is thus to be desired. Such policies certainly include (1) the inculcation of attitudes favorable to the viewing of price declines as temporary and likely to be followed by increases, (2) the maintenance of the broadest possible market for, and maximum liquidity of, securities holdings to reduce to the minimum the desire to add to money stocks or fixed-income securities or to encourage a partial liquidation thereof, and (3) the encouragement of banks to pursue a vigorous policy of loan expansion, perhaps with the cooperation of Government via loan guaranties. It should also be pointed out that at any given level of expenditures flow, the greater the downward flexibility of output and factor prices, or conversely the less the autonomous upward movement of output and factor prices, the better is volume of output and employment maintained. Price flexibility does serve to maintain output and employment except as it encourages a narrowing of the expenditures flow (as has been shown likely in the basic situation). Autonomous upward price movements do serve to reduce output and employment except as they encourage a widening of the expenditures flow (as has been seen to be quite possible, but not necessary, in a preceding section). 330 ECONOMIC STABILITY AtfD GROWTH PRICE MOVEMENTS—A MORE COMPLEX VIEW Flows are not homogenous Thus far, the flow of expendituies and the flow of output have each been seen as broad homogenous flows. This view is, of course, unrealistic. Expenditures flows are for thousands upon thousands of different products. These flows are not easily interchangeable. For examples, a flow of expenditures for commercial aircraft is not easily rechanneled into aflowof expenditures for guided missiles, a flow of expenditures for machine tools is not easily rechanneled into a flow of expenditures for automobiles, or a flow of expenditures for television sets is not easily rechanneled into a flow of expenditures for television repair services. Output flows are similar of thousands and thousands of different products. These flows too are not always easily interchangeable. For examples, the same men and machines in the same locations may not shift easily from the production of commercial aircraft to the production of guided missiles, from the production of machine tools to the production of automobiles, or from the production of television sets to the provision of television repair services. Flows must be mutually consistent In terms of output.—The many expenditures flows must call forth many output flows which are mutually consistent therewith if the flows are to persist at a given volume. Thus, aflowof expenditures on, and a flow of output of, new machines must not so expand capacity of the industry using the new machines that the flow of expenditures on its product is incapable of motivating a full employment of the expanded resources available to it. Similarly, a flow of expenditures on, and a flow of output of, product to be added to stocks (inventories) must not become excessive relative to the flow of expenditures on, and the flow of output to, final users. Continuing, a flow of expenditures on, and a flow of output of, any product cannot be inconsistent with the flow of expenditures on, and the flow of output of, any complementary product. Any disarticulation of output flows like those pointed to above will lead to the narrowing of an expenditures flow and—even with price flexibility—a reduced volume of output and employment, reduced money and real incomes, and reduced expenditures flows on other products as a consequence of these reduced incomes (except as the depressing effect of the decline in income is offset by reduced money holdings, reduced bank-debt retirement, or expanded bank lending). In terms of factors.—The many expenditures flows must call forth many output flows which are consistent with the available supplies of inputs. It is perfectly possible that a particular intended (ex ante) expenditures flow may be frustrated by a shortage of a necessary input, this frustration following either rationing of limited output by producers or rising prices coupled with elastic demand. Or this particular intended flow may be widened by the shortage of a necessary input and rising prices coupled with an inelastic demand. The shortage of a particular input, if it results in a narrowed actual (ex post) expenditures flow, spells unemployment of cooperating factors not in short supply, reduced incomes, and, again, a tendency for reduced ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 331 expenditures on other products because of these reduced incomes. The shortage of a particular input, even if it results in widened expenditures on the product in which it is included, spells decline since (1) cooperating factors not in short supply will be unemployed, and (2) the widened expenditures here must be in the face of narrowed expenditures for other outputs (unless such expenditures are maintained by, again, reduced money holdings, reduced bank-debt retirement, or expanded bank lending). Such disarticulations in factor requirements thus also create a tendency toward the narrowing of expenditures flows and recession. In terms of income distribution.—Even if the many expenditures flows mesh well together, even if they call forth a pattern of resource use consistent with patterns of supply, disarticulation is possible if income is distributed according to a pattern which is inconsistent with the maintenance of the original expenditures flow. For example, if income yielded by a specific pattern of expenditures and output flow emphasizing expenditures on, and output of, durable consumers goods, is accumulating to income receivers not likely to emphasize expenditures on such items, then expenditures thereon are likely to narrow with the unfortunate consequences already frequently cataloged. Of course, the income receivers with expanding incomes may widen expenditures flows elsewhere with stimulating consequences to the economy as a whole. It should be noted, however, that a full offset requires that expenditures elsewhere increase by the amount of the decline in durable consumers goods purchases, a requirement which means that persons with growing incomes save no part thereof. Disarticulations of income distribution with respect to flows of expenditures and output may, therefore, also lead to declines in output and employment. Price changes and disarticulations The arguments of the section entitled "Price Movements—the Simple View" indicate that price changes and market adjustments (1) accompany changes in a flow of expenditures or (2) cause changes in a flow of output in response to a given flow of expenditures. These arguments are equally valid here. Price changes and market adjustments both accompany the changed expenditures flows stemming from disarticulations and cause the changed output flows which result in disarticulations. Disarticulations thus give rise to narrowed real expenditures flows via either (1) narrowed money flows, or (2) constant money flows at higher output prices. Conventional price changes and market adjustments do not restore real flows (outputs) no matter how flexible prices may be. Any narrowed real expenditures flow is likely to spread via the pressure of reduced incomes and reduced expenditures to other flows and through the entire economy unless, at some point, money holdings are reduced, bank-debt retirement is slowed, or there is net new borrowing from banks. Income distribution and disarticulations Introduction.—The view that there are a good many flows of output and expenditures also allows explicit consideration of the impact of changes in the distribution of income. Thus, a disarticulation which 332 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GRiOWTH leaves a flow of income without an immediately desired flow of output and, hence, adding to money balances or reducing bank indebtedness is depressing (via a reduced expenditures flow) and points to the possible desirability of redistributing the income flow in directions where there is an immediately desired flow of output and which will encourage the activation of idle balances and new borrowing rather than debt retirement to widen the flow of expenditures. A specific and important instance of the kind described generally above occurs when a flow of income to businesses and individuals which normally goes to purchase capital goods (or inventories) is not so spent (perhaps because of output disarticulation). Indeed, in this area, it is likely that not only does current income go unspent, but new borrowing is replaced by debt retirement. This situation is frequently held to point to the desirability of immediately and consciously changing the flow of income away from these recipients who frustrate its translation into an expenditures, an output, and an employment flow, to those whose flow of expenditures would be stimulated thereby. The latter are usually seen as lower income bracket consumers or as small-business men with a great expansion potential but little current income or borrowing potential. It has frequently been pointed out that the transfer of income is inevitable in any case; that only the level of the economy's output and employment at which the transfer will take place is in question. This view holds that, if the transfer does not take place early, income and activity in the entire economy will decline and that that income to businesses and individuals which originally financed capital expansion will, along with the income of the unemployed, be that which declines most sharply. Indeed, this view argues that the basis for a restoration of this income and of a flow of expenditures on capital goods (inventories) is best laid by an immediate transfer which will remove the disarticulation via absorbing excess capacity and excess inventories by way of expanded consumption. Price changes and income transfers.—Disarticulations lead to decline via reduced real expenditures flows which are diffused through the economy with general declines in income which conventional price movements, by themselves, are powerless to halt. This has given rise to proposals for specific price changes not called forth by orthodox economic forces acting on individual decision makers. Generally, these proposals call for an increase in prices for those items sold by those whose incomes it is desired to increase because they will, therefore, expand their expenditures flows, and a decrease in prices for those items sold by those whose incomes it is desired to decrease because they have already narrowed their expenditures flows. These prices are to be maintained whether or not, atomistically viewed, they maximize the individual positions of the market participants. Specifically, with a decline in expenditures flows for capital goods (or inventories), wage rates should be raised while volume is consciously maintained and retained profits and dividends are pinched. Or, conversely, wage rates might be maintained while output prices are consciously reduced and retained profits and dividends are pinched. The latter alternative, however, does create the added danger of reduced consumption if further price cuts thereby come to be anticipated. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 333 Logically, this income redistribution via conscious changes in prices (of labor and of output) and conscious maintenance of output is a powerful antirecessionary device. It also requires either (1) substantial Government control over prices and outputs or (2) a very high level of industrial statesmanship. Conventional market forces do not call forth the actions required. Furthermore, under reversed conditions wherein the output distortion requires, and stimulates, an expansion of investment expenditures, a redistribution of income toward savers (i. e., businesses and upper-bracket income persons) is logically required. This shift, also not called forth by conventional market forces, would necessitate (1) substantial Government control over wage rates or (2) a very high level of labor statesmanship. INVESTMENT AND THE PRICE SYSTEM G. D. Bodenhorn, University of Chicago In a capitalist, free enterprise economy, most decisions about output, investment, and consumption are made by individuals, families, or corporations who are seeking to further their own self-interest. It has long been the wonder of philosophers, economists, and political scientists that such a system should, in most instances, lead to socially desirable results. This happens, to put it simply, because the way for people to serve their best interest is to make money, and the way to do this is to make something which other people want and are willing to buy. In such an economic system, prices are the measure of the value of a product, and the prospect of selling a product at a profit constitutes the inducement to produce. The function of profit in a free enterprise economy is to draw productive resources into the correct industries, so that these industries can increase their output. The resource should, from the point of view of the society, be used where they will best satisfy consumer wants and needs. Producers must pay for the resources which they use, and then sell the product at a price which consumers are willing to pay, when they compare this price with the prices of other products which could be used to satisfy their wants. If consumers find a product so valuable that they are willing to pay the producer more than enough to pay the productive resources, and leave a large profit besides, then more resources should be devoted to the production of this product. In this way the resources will be used to produce that product which is most valuable to the consumer. Investment is undertaken by individuals, or groups of individuals, who seek thereby to make profits. In general, if there is an industry which presents opportunities for unusual profits, as compared with the necessary investment, entrepreneurs invest and attract resources to the industry. This increases the output of the industry, and profits are reduced to a more normal level. Usually this flow of investment funds and of resources into high profit uses is in the public interest. This is because the industries and firms which make high profits use resources more efficiently and satisfy consumer wants better. This procedure also requires that low profit firms and industries contract, and sometimes are even forced out of business. The system then involves the survival and growth of the fittest, with fitness measured by the ability to serve the consumer and earn profits. As a Nation, however, we are interested in investment not only from the point of view of the expansion of particular industries, but also because investment employs people and creates income when it is undertaken, and permits growth of national product and income at a later date. We are interested, therefore, in appraising the performance of the investment sector of our economy from three points of 335 336 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH view: that of the economy as a whole, that of the firm, and that of the industry. I am going to discuss each of these briefly, with emphasis on investment at the industry level. INVESTMENT BY THE TOTAL ECONOMY It is not easy to appraise the performance of our economy from the standpoint of the total level of investment. The only criteria that we could use are that investment should be high enough to maintain full employment and to produce a satisfactory rate of growth for the economy as a whole. We have, to be sure, ample evidence that investment has been high enough to maintain full employment— or to put this another way, has been high enough to employ the savings from a full employment level of income—since the end of World War II. The question of a satisfactory rate of growth is complicated by the fact that we have no good standard of what is satisfactory or unsatisfactory in this field. Many individuals argue that our postwar rate of growth is not satisfactory because it is substantially lower than the Eussian rate of growth. If, as has been suggested, Russian output were to catch up with ours in the next 15 to 20 years, this might well be a more serious blow in our contest with communism than was the recent Russian success in conquering space. It seems clear that our economy will not grow as fast as the Russian economy has been growing unless we take special measures to stimulate investment. However, it is not my intention to advocate that such measures be taken, particularly since I believe this decision to be a political one rather than an economic one. As an economist, I see no cause for alarm at the rate of growth which our economy is now achieving. Furthermore, I should like to issue a warning to those who think that a race with the Russians in this area is necessary. It will not be easy to devise methods of stimulating investment which will not destroy the freedom which is essential to a capitalist economy, and which will not create a much more serious problem of inflation than we have been facing for the last 10 years. INVESTMENT BY THE INDIVIDUAL FIRM Recent studies 1 of investment decisions of the firm stress the importance of profits as a requirement for investment. These studies do not, to be sure, indicate that the firms with the highest profits are always the ones which invest the most, and we should not expect to find that our general economic principles are followed to the letter in each and every instance. The price system can be said to work satisfactorily if by and large there is a tendency for investment to flow into those firms and industries which are most profitable; and the evidence supports the conclusion that this is the case. Perhaps the most important result of the recent studies has been the shift in emphasis from considerations of the demand for investment funds to considerations of the supply of such funds. Earlier treatments of the investment problem stressed the importance of profits in creating a demand or desire to invest and increase production. The 1 See for example, Meyer and Knh, The Investment Decision, Harvard University Press, 1957. and the National Bureau of Economic Research Conference on Research in Income and Wealth, vol. 19, Problems of Capital Formation, Princeton University Press, 1957. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 337 idea was that entrepreneurs wish to make profits, and therefore seek to invest money in profitable enterprises. The assumption seemed to be that the funds would be available for the entrepreneurs to borrow, and that they would naturally channel the funds into the most profitable places. More recent studies of investment decisions of the firm stress the importance of profit in providing a source of investment funds, rather than as signaling a profitable place to use funds. That is, a firm which wishes to invest must either Dorrow the money, or get more money from stockholders, or use money which it has saved itself. The two sources of internally saved money are depreciation and profits which have not been distributed to stockholders as dividends. Firms which have large profits are in a better position to retain some of these profits and to use them for investment purposes. This emphasis on the supply of investment funds stems in part from the way in which investment decisions are usually made by the firm. There are usually individuals in the lower levels of management in any firm who think of many ways in which to invest the firm's funds. Therefore, the problem of top management usually seems to be one of reducing the requests for funds on the part of lower management to the level of funds which are available to the firm. That is, the firm usually looks as though it wants to invest more money than it actually has available. Therefore, the availability of the funds seems to be of crucial importance. It is clear, of course, that for the economy as a whole it is not always the availability of funds which limits investment. In times of recession, such as these, the funds are available but there is apparently not enough demand. This is simply another illustration of the familiar theme that things do not always look the same from the point of view of the individual firm as they do from the point of view of the economy. Profits are clearly important on the demand side as well. This is because a firm which has been making profits usually feels more optimistic about the future and wants to invest more than a firm which has been having difficulty making profits. This association on the demand side would, of course, increase the apparent correlation between investment and profits as an internal source of funds. In a situation of this kind, it is frequently difficult, if not impossible, to determine how much of the association between profits and investment is due to the increased availability of funds which is associated with the increased profit, and how much is due to the increased demand for funds which is also associated with the increased profit. From the point of view of this analysis, however, it makes no difference why profitable firms invest. The price system is functioning properly if resources are flowing into the profitable firms, since these are the firms which know how to use the resources to best satisfy consumer demands. The evidence of recent studies shows that profitable firms do indeed attract investment and expand. INVESTMENT BY INDUSTRIES Most of the interest in investment in recent years has been either in the investment of the firm or the investment of the economy as a whole, and little has been said about investment at the industry level. 338 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH One reason for this is that investment decisions are made by firms, not industries. Another reason is that better data are available for firms than for industries. I have therefore analyzed two sets of data with a view to seeing how the profit system and the price mechanism are apparently working at the industry level. All of my data are confined to manufacturing, and the number of industries into which the manufacturing sector of the economy is divided is quite small. In no case do I consider more than 21 manufacturing industries, and in much of the data only 11 industries are available. The industries are therefore very broadly defined, which has certain advantages as well as disadvantages. The main advantage is that the broader the industry, the less likely are firms to engage in activities which cut across industry lines. Therefore, the data are somewhat more reliable for broad industries than they would be for more refined industries since the data came from firms and each firm is placed in only one industry. On the other hand, broadly defined industries can cover up many interesting things which are happening within the industry. It may be that some segment of the industries are exceedingly profitable and are expanding rapidly, while other segments of the industry are stationary or even declining. The two sets of data which I have analyzed differ in the length of the period covered, and in the definition of investment, as well as in industrial breakdown. The first set of data, from the National Industrial Conference Board, covers the entire period from 1925 to 1954 for 11 industries, and has a finer industrial classification since 1939. The Census Bureau data covers only selected years from 1947 to 1954. The conference board data uses a very broad definition of investment, including as investment all the assets of a firm except holdings of securities and securities of other firms. The Census Bureau data is concerned with expenditures which are more commonly thought of as investment. Finally, the conference board has information on the total investment tied up in an industry at any time, as well as information on the amount of investment during a particular year. This permits measurement of the rate of return on investment, and the rate of increase of investment. The Census Bureau data give only plant and equipment expenditures during a particular year, and other Department of Commerce sources give profits (not of income tax) for the same years. The Census Bureau data permits only measurement of the relative change in investment from 1 year to another as compared to the relative change in profits between the same years. In spite of these important differences in definitions and in treatment of the data, both sources indicate that, by and large, investment is being channeled into the more profitable industries. Again, as in the case of the investment of the firm, we find that there are individual exceptions from time to time, but still in general the industries which realize the highest profits, or which show the greatest improvement in profit position, are the ones which expand investment the fastest. Thus both sets of data apparently present the results of an economy which is functioning the way a free enterprise society is supposed to operate. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 339 THE CONFERENCE BOARD DATA The first set of data which I have analyzed is put out by the National Industrial Conference Board, and gives investment and rate of return on investment for 11 manufacturing industries from 1925 through 1954, and for about 20 manufacturing industries since 1939. The 11 industry data has the advantage of giving a long historical sweep. The finer industrial classification permits a somewhat more detailed analysis of postwar developments. The definition of investment which the conference board uses is the broadest possible one. They define investment as the total assets of a firm, less only holdings of the securities of other firms and of the Government. This means that the investment figure includes not only plant, equipment, and inventories, which are usually thought of as investment, and are included as investment in our national income accounts, but also such items as cash and accounts receivable, which are not included as investment in the national income accounts. The conference board includes all assets because the firm needs to raise money to obtain these other assets in much the same way that it needs to obtain money to finance plant, equipment, and inventories. Profits for the industries are given after income taxes have been paid, and also after deducting any interest or dividends which the firm collected from its security holdings. The rate of return on investment in any year is then the profit earned during the year divided by the total amount of money which is invested in the firm as of the end of the year. Thus the profit is earned during the year, but the investment may have been made at any time prior to the end of the year. The question which I seek to answer is whether those industries with the highest rate of return on investment are also the industries which increase their investment the most. In order to do this, it is necessary to measure investment during any given year relative to the size of the industry; that is, relative to the amount of investment in the industry at the start of the year. This means really that we are measuring the rate of increase of investment, rather than the absolute amount of investment. I also sought to reduce the influence of irregular factors by averaging both the rate of increase of investment and the rate of return on investment over 2-year periods. This means that if automobiles, for example, had a particularly good year followed by a poor one, these 2 years would be averaged together. The idea in back of this procedure is that investment is usually made for the long term, and on the assumption that some years will be good and others poor. A 2-year average gives a somewhat better indication of the normal rate of return, and also of the normal rate of increase of investment. I also experimented with somewhat longer periods, such as 4 and 8 years, and found that the relationship between profits and investment improved for these longer periods. Table I shows the correlations between rates of increase of investment and rates of return on investment, by industry, for various time 23734—58 23 340 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH periods.2 It should be noted that the correlations are quite good in the postwar years, and in the early thirties, and are somewhat lower during the war and recovery from the depression of the early thirties. The 4- and 8-year correlations are all high, except for those that include the mobilization period of World War II. The data not only confirm the idea that industries which make high profits in any particular period are those which invest during this period, but also confirm the idea that a particular industry invests more when its profits are high than when its profits are low. For our broader industrial classification of 11 manufacturing industries, we have data for investment and profits covering 14 2-year periods. We find that the correlation between the rate of investment and the rate of return through time is uniformly high for all industries. This is a reflection primarily, of course, of the business cycle. During periods of prosperity both profits and investments are high, while those are low during periods of recession and depression. In some industries the war years caused a certain amount of discrepancy in the correlation between rates of return and rates of investment. However, even in these industries, the disturbance was not enough to reduce the correlation significantly. It is also worth noting that the profit position of an industry changes relatively slowly through time. That is, the industry with the highest rate of return on investment in any 2-year period is likely also to have a comparatively high rate of return on investment during the following 2-year period, and probably had a comparatively high rate of return on investment during the preceding 2 years. In spite of the relatively slow change during 2-year periods, very significant changes are possible over longer periods. In fact, industries which showed high rates of return during the war period are unlikely to be showing high rates of return today and probably did not show high rates of return during the late 1920's. Nevertheless, there is apparently a pattern of rates of return which appears during normal peacetime prosperous periods. During the period under study this pattern was broken first by the great depression, and second, by the World War. Nevertheless, this normal pattern has reemerged to a noticeable extent in the 1950's. 2 These correlations are of ranks, rather than of actual rates of return and investment. My hypothesis is that the most profitable industries should invest the most, and I can test this by correlating the ranks of the industries according to profitability and increase in investment. 341 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE I.—Correlation of rate of return on investment with rate of increase of investment for manufacturing industries [Selected time periods, 1927-54] Correlation Time period 2-year periods: 1927 and 1928 1929 and 1930 1931 and 1932 1933 and 1934 1935 and 1936 1937 and 1938 1939 and 1940 1941 and 1942 1943 and 1944 1945 and 1946 1947 and 1948 1949 and 1950 1951 and 1952 1953 and 1954 4-year periods: 1927 through 1930 1931 through 1934 1935 through 1938 1939 through 1942 1943 through 1946 1947 through 1950 1951 through 1954 8-year periods: 1931 through 1938 1939 through 1946 1947 through 1954 11-industry classification 0.15 .69 .75 .75 .27 .30 .33 .35 .37 .75 .37 .54 .51 .58 Finer industry classification i 6.257 1.065 2.426 3.574 3.455 3.187 .61 .86 .57 .28 .56 .77 .54 .83 .27 .62 * There are 19 industries in these years. 2 There are 18 industries in these years. 3 There are 21 industries in these years. Source: National Industrial Conference Board. It should also be noted that the price system has apparently performed its function quite well during the post war period. At the end of the war there was a substantial shortage of productive capacity and likewise, a shortage of many consumer goods. At this time the rate of return on investment was exceedingly high, and so was the rate of increase of investment. In fact, the rate of return was so high that it induced so much investment that the rate of return finally fell back to a more normal level during the early 1950's. Thus, it appears that the high rates of return during the reconversion period served a useful function.3 3 This particular conclusion is confirmed by the data from the First National City Bank of New York, which shows a very high rate of return on investment in the reconversion period which gradually becomes smaller and reaches what could be considered a rather normal level in the 1950's. This is all the more interesting because the National City Bank does not measure the rate of return in the same way t h a t the conference board measured rate of return. Instead of taking the total asset of the firm as a measure of investment, the National City Bank uses the net worth. 'Therefore, the rate of return is profit as a percent of net worth. 342 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH THE CENSUS BUREAU DATA The Census Bureau has published data on plant and equipment expenditures by industry for several years since 1947. The 1947 data came from the census of manufacturers, while data for 1949, 1951, 1953, and 1954 were obtained from the annual surveys of manufacturers. This data gives plant and equipment expenditures by industry during the particular year, and gives us no information as to the total level of investment of the firm either during the year or at the beginning of the year. Accordingly, I have not sought to associate investment in plant and equipment in any particular year with the profits in that year, but rather to associate changes in plant and equipment expenditures with changes in the level of profits in the various industries. Data on profits for the same industry classification that are used by the Census Bureau in these reports are available from the Department of Commerce in their national income statistics. The hypothesis which I wish to test is whether the industries which have shown the greatest growth in profits are also the industries which have shown the greatest growth in plant and equipment expenditures. In order to reduce the effect of fluctuations in profit from year to year, profits were not calculated for a single year but rather for a 2-year period, in much the same way that the conference board data were handled. Thus, for example, in seeking to explain the change in the rate of plant and equipment expenditures between 1947 and 1954, I did not calculate the increase in profit between 1947 and 1954. I chose rather to take the average profit in the 2 years, 1946 and 1947, and compare these with the average profits for the 2 years, 1953 and 1954. The purpose of averaging profits over a 2-year period is, as before, to make irregular or unexpected changes in profit less important. Unfortunately, a similar averaging of plant and equipment expenditures was not possible because data was generally available only for alternate years. Two difficulties which arise in making this comparison should be noted. First, it seems clear that the industries which are large and have large profits will probably also be the ones which have large increases in profit and large increases in plant and equipment expenditures. In order to avoid this difficulty, therefore, I considered the relative change in profit and in plant and equipment expenditures. That is, I found out, for example, what the percentage increase in profits was between 1947 and 1954, and I also found the percentage increase in plant and equipment expenditures between 1947 and 1954. I then sought to determine if these industries had the highest percentage increase in investment. The second difficulty arises because I am taking a ratio of investment (and profits) in 1 year to the investment (and profit) in another year. If the investment in either one of these years did not bear its normal relationship to profit in that particular year, then the ratios which I get will be misleading. Let us suppose that we have an industry in which investment is usually closely tied to profit. Even so, there will be some years in which the investment is higher than what one would expect on the basis of profits and some years in which the investment is lower than what one would expect on the basis of profits. If we now calculate the rates of growth of investment and profit between any 2 years, we will ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 343 find that the ratios are misleading if either 1 of the 2 years did not bear its normal relationship of profit to investment. TABLE II.—Correlation of percentage changes of plant and equipment expenditures and profits, for manufacturing industries—Selected time periods, 1947-54 Percentage changes between 1947 and*— 1949 1951 1953 1954 Percentage changes between 1949 and 1 — 1951 1953 1954 , Percentage changes between 1951 and *— 1953 1954 Percentage changes between 1953 and 1954 Correlation -0.04 .59 .86 .69 .59 .55 .45 .25 .36 . 48 1 Percentage changes in profits are calculated using a 2-year base period, including the year preceding the base year used for plant and equipment expenditures, and a 2-year final period, again including the year preceding the final year for plant and equipment expenditures. Source : Census Bureau and Department of Commerce. Nevertheless, the relationship between changes in profits and changes in investment is quite good. Table I I shows the correlation coefficients of the rank of the percent increase in investment and the rank of the percent increase in profit. These coefficients are quite high except for the changes which took place between 1947 and 1949; 1947 was a period of rapidly rising prices and an extreme shortage of capital goods. There were many firms which would have liked to invest a good deal more than they were able to invest, because they wished to be able to increase their output. We have reason to suspect, therefore, that 1947 was not a year of normal relationship between profit and investment. Therefore, it should not surprise us too much to find that the changes in investment between 1947 and 1949 were not correlated with the change in profit in these years. In fact, I find it somewhat surprising that the correlations between 1947 and some of the later years are as high as they are. I would rather have expected to find that any changes which use 1947 as a base were rather abnormal and misleading. This is not the case, however, and the correlations between 1947 and 1953 and 1954 are among the highest. This may arise because one would rather expect these correlations to improve with age. This is because changes from year to year tend to be rather smaller than changes between 5-year periods. Thus, any observation which tends to be higher or lower than "normal" will cause a larger change in year to year rates of increase than it will cause in rates of increase for years which are 5 or 10 years apart. Indeed, this improvement of correlation as the time period grows longer is apparent in the data. CONCLUSIONS Investment by private enterprise in our economy has been large enough in the postwar period to keep the working force fully employed, and to achieve a satisfactory rate of growth for the economy. It is true that we have not had continuously full employment, and that we fall short of this goal at the present moment, but these lapses from 344 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH full employment have been neither serious nor prolonged. It is not reasonable to expect a free economy to be devoid of fluctuations in output and employment. A more legitimate concern is that the Russian economy has apparently been growing faster than ours, and will eventually surpass us if this continues. It would indeed be unfortunate if we were no longer able to combat communism with the argument that we have both more freedom and a more abundant economy. However, it is certainly not worth giving up our freedom to seek economic abundance, even in the unlikely event that we could achieve faster growth by doing So. Our fundamental argument must be for the freedom and dignity of the individual, and our cause will surely be lost if we abandon these. Eecent analyses of investment by firms and industries indicate that our economy has been performing satisfactorily in these areas as well. Investment and resources are generally flowing into the more profitable uses, even though there are individual exceptions to this general tendency. RESOURCE ALLOCATION, ECONOMIC STABILIZATION, AND PUBLIC POLICY TOWARD PRICES Carl F. Christ, The University of Chicago I. INTRODUCTION AND SUMMARY In this paper I shall argue that public policy in the United States should try to maintain a stable price level and a high stable level of employment, and that employment is the more important of the two, but that apart from certain important qualifications public policy should pay no attention to the prices of particular goods and services, or to tne quantities consumed by particular individuals. Thus the monetary and fiscal stabilization policies that I shall endorse are explicitly designed to minimize Government action directed at particular goods and services. Other contributors to this compendium will surely pay competent attention to many technical aspects of prices. I have chosen to deal with the relationships between public policy toward prices and some relevant economic principles, in the belief that this will be helpful in arriving at useful public policies. My argument has six main points, some of which are controversial. They may be summarized at the outset, in a somewhat oversimplified fashion, as follows: (1) With certain important qualifications that I shall discuss, in a private-property free-contract economy public policy is not properly concerned with the relative prices at which particular goods and services are exchanged in the market, such as 1,000 haircuts for one stripped 1958 Plymouth; nor, therefore, is public policy properly concerned with the absolute prices of particular goods and services, such as $1.75 for a haircut, or $1,750 for a stripped 1958 Plymouth. This is because relative prices have a job to do m allocating resources, and, with the qualifications alluded to, this job is done in what economists call an optimal way if the relative prices are determined by free contract. (2) Again with certain important qualifications that I shall discuss, in a private-property free-contract economy public policy is not properly concerned with the quantities of particular goods and services produced by the economy as a whole, or consumed by particular individuals. This is because, with the qualifications alluded to, freedom of contract leads to what economists call an optimal allocation of resources. (3) There is an important area within which public policy is properly concerned with particular relative or absolute prices, and/or with the quantities of particular goods and services consumed by particular individuals. This area provides the qualifications referred to under points (1) and (2). These qualifications arise in part from the question of wealth distribution, a question not answered by the economists' definition of "optimal allocation of resources." In addi- 345 346 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH tion, most of these qualifications involve one or more of the following situations: An individual is not well informed about the alternatives facing him, or about the consequences of his actions; an individual is not the best judge of his own interests; an individual cannot sell or mortgage himself as he can other wealth; an individual's deed brings about gains or losses to himself that are greater or less than the gains or losses to society, so that an individual who pursues his own private gain is not advancing the interests of society as much as he might. Familiar examples of the last are theft, fraud, extortion, tax evasion, monopolization, etc.; others will be discussed below. (4) Public policy in a private-property, free-contract economy is properly concerned with stabilizing the absolute price level, or simply the price level for short, that is, with stabilizing an appropriate average of the absolute prices of all goods and services. (We now have three price indexes for measuring the price level: the gross national product deflator published annually—not quarterly, alas—by the Commerce Department, and the Wholesale and Consumer Price Indexes published monthly by the Bureau of Labor Statistics.) The reason we ought to strive for a stable price level is not that a rising price level or a falling level is bad in itself—indeed, I shall argue that almost any kind of changes in the price level would be fine as long as everybody foresaw them accurately in advance; the reason is rather that the price level has a job to do that it can only do well if its future movements are accurately foreseen by everyone, and that stabilizing the absolute price level is the best way to permit everyone to foresee its future movements accurately. (5) Public policy in a private-property free-contract economy is properly concerned with maintaining a high stable level of employment of resources, especially human resources. The reason for this is that full employment is better than unemployment, and that in the absence of public policy to the contrary we have experienced occasional periods of substantial unemployment. (6) Although there appears to be some conflict between the objectives of a stable price level and a high stable level of employment, particularly in recent years, appropriate monetary and fiscal policy can come tolerably close to achieving both of these objectives at the same time. If it is necessary to choose, I would be inclined to accept some price level instability rather than very much unemployment, because while both bring about a redistribution of income and wealth among people, unemployment brings about a loss of income and wealth to the economy as a whole, in addition to a redistribution. Sections I I to VI below discuss some economic principles fundamental to these 6 points, and the remaining sections (VII to X I I ) discuss the 6 points in more detail. II. THE PROBLEM OF THE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH Any economic society must decide, explicitly or implicitly (the latter is the more typical), what kind of distribution of income and wealth among its people there shall be. This is a highly controversial issue. Most people prefer receiving a larger to a smaller share of the total social income and wealth. In addition, many if not most people have ideas about what constitute fair principles for distributing income and wealth, and these ideas are not all consistent, to say the least. ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 347 Fundamental conflicts of interest arise here. Social and economic institutions and laws are involved in the resolution of this issue, not once for all, but again and again, year after year. I I I . PRIVATE PROPERTY AND FREE CONTRACT A society based on private property and freedom of contract settles this issue by taking the initial distribution of property as given, and letting the subsequent distribution arise from free contracting, in a manner familiar to all. There are rules for deciding who owns each piece of property. Typically, each person initially owns himself (and within limits his immature children), and whatever property he has been given by his parents or others, by inheritance or otherwise. Each person has control over the use of his own property, except that we do not permit a person to sell or mortgage himself or his children. Property can change hands only by free contract agreed to by all parties to the contract (this usually involves exchange), or by free gift. A person's wealth increases rapidly if he receives large gifts, if he produces much, if others become willing to offer high prices for what he owns, and if he saves much. Because of freedom of contract, no person is forced to accept a material position that he thinks is inferior to the one that his original property will provide for him. If anyone can produce property that he regards as more valuable than the resources he consumes in the process, then he can gain from production. And if he can find other people who will give him in trade things that he regards as more valuable than the things he gives up in return, then he can gain from exchange. Under certain conditions, this kind of an arrangement would lead to what economists call an optimal allocation of resources. The conditions, of course, are the source of the qualifications mentioned in connection with points (1) to (3) at the beginning of the paper. Let me now turn to the economists' definition of "optimal allocation of resources," then state the conditions, and then argue that if they are met, private property and freedom of contract do lead to the economists' optimal allocation of resources. This will occupy sections IV-VI: IV. DEFINITION OF AN OPTIMAL ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES An optimal allocation of resources, in the technical language of the economist, means a situation in which no individual can be made better off without making some other or others worse off. It may help to give examples of situations that are not optimal allocations. For example, if I own a house and I want to sell it provided I can get at least $25,000 for it, and if you want to buy it provided that you can get it for $30,000 or less, then (if we are both well informed about the matter, and if the interests of third parties are not affected) the existing allocation of resources is not optimal, and it can be improved by a contract for the sale of the house from me to you at some price in the range of $25,000 to $30,000. Our respective gains from the improvement in allocation will depend on the price we agree upon: the higher the price, the larger will be my gain and the smaller will ]be yours. Take another example that is more typical in that it involves production as well as exchange: Suppose that you are willing to buy a widget for $120 or less, and that I can cause a widget to be produced 348 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH with resources that I can buy for $90 or more from their owners (including myself). Then, again if all parties are well informed and the interests of persons not party to the action are not affected, the existing allocation of resources is not optimal; it can be improved by a contract for the sale of a widget from me to you for a price somewhere in the range from $90 to $120, and another contract for the sale of the required resources from their owners to me at a combined price somewhere in the same range, but at or below the price of the widget. Gains from the improvement in allocation will accrue to you, me, and the owners of the resources that are used to produce the widget, in a manner depending upon the prices agreed on for the widget and the resources. An optimal allocation is a situation in which no more contracts agreeable to all parties remain to be made. Notice that I said "an optimal allocation," not "the optimal allocation." This is not an accident; it is important. There is an infinite number of optimal allocations, according to this definition. For example, suppose that the existing allocation is optimal; i. e., it is impossible to make anyone better off without making someone worse off. Then suppose that you give a thousand dollars to me. The new allocation is still optimal provided that my wants lead my to buy with my new wealth the same things that you decide to forego because of being poorer: the people whose wares you no longer buy now sell them to me instead, so that no one is affected but you and me, and it is again the case in the new situation as in the old that no one can be made better off without making someone else worse off. If wealth is transferred from you to me, it is more typical if I do not choose to buy with my new wealth just the same things that you decide to give up, but I choose to buy at least some other things instead. This means that if the resource allocation existing just before the transfer was optimal, then the one existing just afterward is not, because resource owners and I can now make mutually agreeable contracts providing for the production of more of the things that I want and can now pay for, and less of the things that you want and can no longer pay for. But, if free contract is permitted, a new allocation of recourses will arise that is optimal in the same sense as was the old: nobody can be made better off without making someone worse off. The foregoing should make it clear that when an economist says that an allocation of resources is an optimal one, he is taking the currently existing distribution of wealth as given, and is saying that the economy is satisfying efficiently the wants that are regarded as most important by those people who happen to have the wealth. No judgment is made at all on the question of whether the currently existing distribution of wealth is too unequal, too equal, fair, proper, justified, or anything of the sort. Thus in saying that a particular allocation of resources is an optimal one, the economist completely sidesteps an important public policy question, namely, what should the current distribution of wealth be ? It is important to notice that if the current distribution of wealth is accepted, and if individuals are allowed to contract freely thereafter, then the distribution of wealth may and almost certainly will change, in favor of those who receive gifts, who produce much, whose property becomes highly valued by others, and who save much. It may seem strange to use the term "optimal" in a way that does not raise the important policy question of wealth distribution. But ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 349 on reflection, I think it is not so strange after all. If economics is to be a science, then it must contain propositions that will be recognized as valid by scientifically trained people, regardless of the value judgments that they hold or the vested interests that they have. The statement that it is better for people to get more rather than less satisfaction from their wealth must be acceptable to nearly everybody, Socialist or private enterpriser, rich or poor, and hence it is useful to have a term that describes a situation where the best has been achieved in this respect. Optimal allocation of resources is that term, and its meaning is therefore perfectly clear. The policy question of what kind of wealth distribution is proper is one concerning which economics as a science has no well-established answer. Indeed, in most respects it is not a scientific question at all, but a question of value judgments. V. CONDITIONS FOR AN OPTIMAL ALLOCATION OF RESOURCES UNDER PRIVATE PROPERTY AND FREE CONTRACT Now it is time to state the conditions under which private property and free contract will lead to an optimal allocation of resources, thus defined. The following discussion draws heavily on Prof. Frank H. Knight's account of the assumptions necessary of the existence of perfect competition, set forth on pages 76-80 of his book, Risk, Uncertainty, and Profit, first published in 1921 as one of the Hart, Schaffner & Marx prize essays in economics. For completeness, I shall first repeat that an optimal allocation of resources is a situation in which nobody can be made better off without making someone else worse off. The required conditions are as follows (all are clearly unrealistic in some way) : (a) Motivation.—Each individual seeks intelligently to satisfy his wants as completely as he can with the means he has. In particular, he will always buy from the lowest priced seller he knows of, and will always sell to the highest priced buyer he knows of. (b) Information.—Each individual knows what his present and future wants are and how important they are to him; he also knows what present and future actions are open to him, and what the consequences of his actions will be. In particular, he knows everyone else's present and future bid and asked prices for all wealth, he knows what and how much he can produce now and in the future with any given combination of resources, and he knows to what extent his present and future wants will be satisfied by each kind of wealth. (c) Mobility.—Resources are perfectly mobile, that is, it takes no time and. costs nothing to convert from one kind of productive activity to another, or to exchange goods in the market. (d) Competition.—Every individual is such a small buyer and seller of the things he deals in, relative to the total transactions of the market, that his decisions to bid or ask or buy or sell have no perceptible effect on the prices bid or asked by others. (e) Third parties.—Every individual deed affects only the doer, and every contract affects only the parties to the contract. In particular, this excludes contracts by which third parties are injured, and also contracts by which third parties are benefited. 350 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH (/) The institution of private property and free contract as we know it is modified to permit individuals to sell or mortgage their persons in return for present and/or future benefits. These conditions have been deliberately designed so that if they were fulfilled, then each individual would seek and find others with whom he can make mutually advantageous contracts, and such contracts, and such contracts would be made, until no more remain to be made. When that state of affairs occurs, an optimal allocation of resources has been achieved. VI. THE ROLE OF RELATIVE PRICES I N RESOURCE ALLOCATION It is now easy to explain the role of relative prices in the process of resource allocation. First, note that if everyone seeks the best price he can get, and no one can control prices, and everyone knows what prices are being quoted, then it will turn out that for each good or service there is a single market price: No one will pay more and no one will accept less. Market prices may change in response to changes in resource availability, technology, tastes, or wealth distribution, but they are not perceptibly influenced by any individual's action. Market prices, and in particular relative prices, have several jobs to do in allocating resources; these jobs can conveniently be grouped into three related but more or less distinct main groups. The first is to decide how much of each product is to be made, and for whom. The second is to decide what combination of resources is to be used in making each product. And the third is to decide how much of current output shall be consumed and how much shall be saved and invested for increasing future output. Kelative prices perform these jobs in several ways. They carry information throughout the economy concerning products that are being made in larger or smaller than optimal amounts, and concerning products that are not being produced with the optimal combination of resources. They provide the incentive for people to shift toward an optimum. And they distribute the product among resource owners, since each resource owner is paid the market price for his resources, thus receiving an income that he can use in the way most satisfying to him. The price of a product, relative to the combined price of the resources used to produce it, tells whether the right amount of that product is being produced or not. If the relative price of a product is high, so that the rate of return to capital in that industry is higher than elsewhere in the economy, then too little of this product is being produced, because buyers can induce resource owners to shift resources from elsewhere to make more of it, at prices that will satisfy both the buyers of the extra product and the owners of the transferred resources. (Recall the example of the widgets in sec. IV.) And the fact that the rate of return in that industry is higher than elsewhere in the economy provides the incentive for more resources to come into it. Similarly, if the price of a product is low relative to its cost, that is a sign that too much of it is bein^ produced, and provides the incentive for resources to leave that industry. If the price of a resource is low, relative to the value of the output it can produce in a certain firm, that is a sign that too little of the resource is being used in that firm, and the firm will induce owners of ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 351 the resource to shift some of it from elsewhere in the economy to that firm, at a price that will satisfy both the firm and the owners of the resource. Similarly, if the price of a resource is high relative to the value of the output it can produce in a firm, then the firm is using too much of the resource, and the firm is led to cut down on the use of it. Thus, in the end, producers are induced to make for each buyer the things he values most highly. Resource owners are induced to apply their resources where they can produce things that are most highly valued by buyers. And each producer is induced to make his product with the combination of resources that costs least; i. e., that is the least useful to other producers. Interest rates form the relative prices of future versus present goods and services (if the absolute price level is stable—of that more later). Through interest rates, consumers decide how much to consume and how much to save, and entrepreneurs are induced to invest in activities whose products will be most highly valued relative to their cost; i. e., relative to the things that must be foregone to obtain them. It is important to remember that relative prices established under free contract will not lead to these optimal results unless resource owners are permitted to receive the market price for each unit of resources they own, for otherwise the incentive to allocate optimally is affected. This means that large incomes will be received by those who own large amounts of valuable resources. Policy directed toward the distribution of the ownership of resources will be considered in section VIII. One of the most important advantages of free contract, barely mentioned so far in this paper, is that it provides automatic adjustments to changes in tastes and technology. Resources shift out of industries whose products have become less desirable or more expensive to produce, and into industries whose products have become more desirable or cheaper to produce. Equally important, producers who feel that they have ideas for useful new products or better techniques are free to try them out, and if buyers find they are worthwhile, they will be adopted. VII. PREVIEW OF THE REST OF THE PAPER If the foregoing two sections were a perfectly accurate picture of the real world, there would be no need for public policy at all, except to maintain the institution of private property and free contract, and possibly to modify the initial distribution of wealth (of which more in the next section). Though the real world is not just like the picture drawn, there is a significant resemblance. In the remainder of this paper, I shall argue first that there are important areas within which givernment is justified in modifying the results that would follow from free contract alone (this is the third of the six points that I stated at the beginning). Then I shall argue that after that is taken account of, there remains a significant field within which public policy should not be concerned with prices of particular goods and services, or the quantities consumed by particular individuals (these are the first 2 of the 6 points). Then I shall argue that public policy should be concerned with stabilizing the price level and with maintaining a high stable level of employment, that both objectives can be tolerably well attained, and that if it is necessary to yield a little on one of them, it is better to yield on the stable price level (these are the last 3 of the 6 points). 352 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH VIII. PUBLIC POLICY TOWARD THE DISTRIBUTION OF WEALTH Let me distinguish two kinds of justifications for public policy to affect the prices of particular goods and services, and/or the quantities consumed by particular individuals. One kind deals with policy to affect the distribution of wealth, which, as pointed out earlier, is a subject not dealt with in the analysis of an optimal allocation of resources. The second kind deals with policies designed to correct misallocations of resources that arise, under free contract, from the fact that not all of the conditions (a\ to (/) in section V above are satisfied in the real world. This section is devoted to the first kind, regarding the distribution of wealth, on the assumption that conditions (a) to (/) are met. The next section is devoted to the second kind. The definition of an optimal allocation of resources that I adopt provides no ground at all for deciding that one initial distribution of wealth is better than another. If a choice among wealth distributions is to be made, it must be made in some other way. Most people, including me, feel that the wealth distribution is a matter of public concern, at least within limits, and that it is proper for government to move toward a greater degree of equality than would result from the institutions of private property, free contract, and unrestricted inheritance (though there is wide disagreement about how far to move). This feeling is based partly on a belief in equality of opportunity (this applies particularly to restrictions on inheritance), and partly on the belief that it is fair and right to compel the fortunate to help the unfortunate. There are many different policies that can redistribute wealth. I t is clear that the best ones are those that do not misallocate resources at the same time. After all, the object of wealth redistribution is to make someone poor better off than before at the expense of someone rich; not to make everyone worse off. This is one of the most important things economists have to say to policymakers. Consider taxes on income, wealth, gifts including inheritance, and consumption—either total consumption, or the consumption of specific luxury commodities. It is clear that a tax on income can be avoided to some extent by not earning as much income as without the tax; taxes on wealth and inheritance can be avoided in part by accumulating less wealth; and taxes on consumption can be avoided to some extent by saving or by shifting to the consumption of untaxed commodities. Any of these taxes has some misallocative effects, as economic analysis can show; the only tax that does not is one that cannot be avoided in any way. The only one I can think of is a sudden expropriation and redistribution of wealth that people were completely unprepared for, and that they firmly believe will never happen again. Of course, once a government levies any tax, it creates expectations that it may do so again, so even this will not work perfectly except the first time. The taxes that have the least misallocative effects are those that have the least effect on relative prices, namely taxes on inheritance, total consumption, or income. (The bad effects of income taxes can be reduced by allowing taxpayers to average their incomes for tax purposes over their lifetimes, as suggested by Prof. William Vickrey in his book, Agenda for Progressive Taxation, published in ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 353 1947.) Worst are taxes on the consumption of particular goods and services only. Subsidies are just like taxes, except that they encourage rather than discourage the activity singled out. Direct cash payments to people with low incomes or wealth are accordingly better than subsidies for the consumption of particular goods and services. (I am still assuming that people are well informed about how to serve their own interests.) A particularly good way to transfer wealth to a person may be to subsidize his education, on the grounds that wealth redistributed in this way is likely to stay redistributed. (Here I am assuming that, at least before he was educated, he was poorly informed about how to serve his own true interests—but this anticipates the next section.) IX. PUBLIC POLICY TO CORRECT RESOURCE MISALLOCATTON UNDER FREE CONTRACT I now turn to policies designed to correct resource misallocations that arise, under free contract, from the fact that in the real world the conditions under which free contract leads to optimum resource allocation do not always hold. A familiar case is that of monopoly, which is distinguished by the seller's ability to affect the price of his product significantly by selling more or less of it. A monopolist, if he exploits his position, turns out less product than would a competitive industry in his place, and charges a higher price, in order to make more profit than would a competitive industry. In effect, he prevents some resources from being used to make his product, even though there are would-be buyers who are willing to pay more for the product than the resource owners could get for the necessary resources if they sold them elsewhere. Economic analysis can demonstrate that the gains that the resource owners and would-be buyers would get, if they were allowed to exchange, are great enough to pay the monopolist's profit and still leave something over. Hence the monopolist creates a misallocation of resources, because he creates a situation in which someone could be made better off without making anyone worse off. Public policy to prevent monopoly is accordingly proper. A second example is that of protection against common disasters, e. g., activities such as national defense, fire and police protection, and sanitation. Here the distinguishing characteristic is that if one individual contracts for protection for himself, he thereby protects his neighbors at least to some extent, whether they agree to help pay for the protection or not: He cannot have the fire in his own house put out without reducing the risk that his neighbor's will catch fire, he cannot protect himself from attack without reducing the likelihood that his neighbor will be attacked, and he cannot practice sanitation without reducing the chance that his neighbors will become infected. If everyone else is going to pay for protection, it may be in the private interest of a single individual not to do so, because he gets substantial protection anyway from the fact that others are providing it for themselves. This is not fair. More important, since many people pursue their interests in this way, the cost of protection for the remaining ones may be so great that they do not think it is worth 354 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH while. For this reason, some private multiparty contracts that would benefit all parties never get made. Therefore, provided it can be shown that a community enterprise financed by appropriately apportioned taxes or assessments could convey to each person benefits that he values more highly than he values his share of the cost, public policy for this purpose improves the allocation of resources and is proper. Indeed, in such a case, the public policy is merely an effective substitute for the private contract that does not get made. However, the proviso is crucial: If it is not possible to apportion the costs of the enterprise in such a way that everyone will value his benefits more highly than his share of the costs, then the enterprise represents a misallocation of resources, and public policy to create it must be justified, if at all, on some other ground. Suppose it has been decided that the costs of a proposed public enterprise can be apportioned in such a way that every individual will experience a net gain. This of course may include situations where some people lose by the enterprise itself, but can be compensated by the gainers so that everyone can still be better off on balance. Then the question arises: Should the costs be so apportioned? Or should they instead be apportioned equally or in some other simple way, with a resulting transfer of wealth to the large gainers from the small gainers and/or losers ? I would argue that if a large extra cost were required in order to make each individual's net gain positive, and if the net losses of the losers under a simpler cost allocation scheme were small, then the simpler allocation method ought to be used, and the small wealth transfer ought to be tolerated. On the other hand, if the wealth transfers would look large to the losers 5 1 would argue that compensation ought to be paid. Any substantial wealth transfers that are made as a result of public policy ought to be a part of the explicit wealth-redistribution policy, and be debated and judged as such. When a government decides to collect taxes or assessments for some activity, the question still remains as to whether the activity should be carried out by the government directly, or whether it should be performed by some private agency or agencies under contract with the government. This is not as important a question of principle as the question of whether to plan and finance the activity publicly; it should be decided essentially on grounds of efficiency. A third case is that of resources whose competitive exploitation would result in a waste of the resources. For example, when many people own land lying above an oil deposit, it is in the private interest of each person to drill and pump oil as fast as possible, before his neighbors have time to get a very big share. But when everyone does this, total costs will be greater and less of the oil in the deposit will be recovered than if just a few wells were drilled in the right places. Everyone could be better off under a unified drilling and pumping operation, and there is a clear case for community action requiring this. Fishing is another industry where this problem can arise. There are many public policies whose justification rests on the premise that people are not well informed, either about their own true interests, or about the alternatives open to them, or about the consequences of their actions, or about all of these. Eules requiring the disclosure of information about the contents of food and drugs, and ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 355 about the nature of corporations whose stock is offered for sale, are of this kind. So also are certain health, safety, and building regulations. ^ A more basic policy that is justified this way in part is the prohibition against a person's selling or mortgaging himself: Freedom is a paramount value, and whenever a person feels that he wants to sell himself for something else offered in return, he should be protected against his own poor judgment. I feel that there is another quite different justification for this policy, namely that human beings are simply not like other property, that they have a dignity that demands they not be treated so, even though it is true that human beings are an important form of wealth, constituting a large share of total wealth. The policy of compulsory education and tax-supported schools rests on several of the justifications suggested above. The compulsory aspect is based in part on the presumption that parents who would not provide for the education of their children are not sufficiently aware that education is a powerful force for the welfare of those who have it, both increasing their knowledge of what opportunities exist, and widening the range of opportunities open to them in particular. Both compulsory education and tax-supported schools are based in part on the disparity between private and total net benefits. If I provide for the education of my children, you are made better off than if I do not, whether you have children or not. The benefit to my family alone, from the education of my children, may not be great enough in my estimation to cover the cost, but the combined benefit to my family and others is great enough so that if a suitable apportionment of cost is made among us all, we can all get a net gain from the education of my children. And similarly with other children. The tax support of schools makes sense for another reason. It is clear that investment in education has a high payoff from a social point of view, especially if particularly promising students are permitted to continue beyond the minimum prescribed level of education. Some of these promising students come from families that do not have the resources to send them to school. The capital market is not organized in such a way that loans for the purpose of education are easy to get, partly because people are not permitted to mortgage themselves: a promising but impecunious student has nothing besides himself that he could mortgage. Hence tax support for schools is a way of making investments in education that, productive as they are, might not be made otherwise. X. THE PROPER PROVINCE OF FREE CONTRACT After taking notice, in the preceding section, of the area within which government can properly modify the results that would come from free contract alone, I now turn to argue that there remains a significant field within which the allocation of resources under free contract is better than if public policy concerns itself with the prices of particular commodities or the quantities consumed by particular persons (these are the first 2 of the 6 points stated at the beginning). Clearly there is a significant field where individuals do know what they want better than the government does, and seek it fairly intelligently; where they are reasonably well informed about their oppor23734—58 24 356 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH tunities; where resources are reasonably mobile between different uses; where substantial competition prevails; and where effects of private contracts on third parties are unimportant by comparison with what it would cost to administer compensating payments. This field includes a large part of the consumer goods area of the economy, and of the area where techniques and capital goods and other resources are marshaled for the production of desired goods and services. The mechanism by which relative prices established under free contract allocate resources is described briefly in section VI above; that section is an important part of the argument here. The economic history of the last hundred or 200 years supports this argument in two ways. For one thing, it is possible to point to many public policies that have sought, with public-spirited motives but with unfortunate results, to do a better job of allocating resources than free contract would do. When the FCC allocates valuable property in the form of television channels to private citizens, it would be better to auction them off, and thus allocate them to people who have the highest opinion of their value, and at the same time to collect some revenue so that taxes could be lower, rather than giving them away free on the say-so of officials—a procedure that provides strong temptation to dishonesty. If regulation is needed to prevent railroads from exercising monopoly power, it should be administered in such a way that a railroad can abandon a service that uses resources more valuable than the service itself. Since the community wants to assist low-income families who are in agriculture, it should do so in a way that does not promote the production of additional farm products at costs greater than consumers are willing to pay. There are many other examples. The second way in which economic history supports free contract in a wide field is in terms of the results of relying on it. I know of no social and economic arrangement in the history of the world that has succeeded in increasing the standard of living of the average man as rapidly as has the system of private property and free contract that has prevailed in the Western World. Other systems have demonstrated the capacity to challenge it in the rate of growth of total output, but not in the rate of growth of the output and distribution of the things that consumers want. XI. GOALS OF STABILIZATION POLICY I now turn to my last three points, concerning stabilization policy. I take it for granted that the maintenance of a high stable level of employment is highly desirable, and that if we can attain it without giving up other valuable things, we certainly should do so. I shall argue that a stable price level is also desirable, not for itself, but because it is desirable that changes in the price level be accurately foreseen. Consider first the relationship between flexible prices and unemployment. Suppose that the price level were perfectly flexible both upward and downward, so that whenever more goods and services were demanded with money than supplied in the economy as a whole, the price level would rise immediately to remove the discrepancy, and so that whenever less goods and services were demanded with money than supplied in the economy as a whole, the price level would fall ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 357 immediately to remove the discrepancy; then there would be no unemployment problem. (There would of course be some normal minimum amount of unemployment, perhaps 3 or 4 percent of the labor force, associated with the transfer of workers from one job to another, but this is no cause for concern.) Therefore from the point of view of minimizing unemployment alone, perfect downward flexibility of the absolute price level appears desirable. We do not have it, we never have had it, and as far as I can see we never will have it, although we seem to have a fair degree of upward price flexibility, as evidenced by the fact that general shortages of goods and services are rare and brief except when they are created by the imposition of price ceilings or quotas. If the price level is to be quite flexible upward but not very flexible downward, as appears to be the case, then, in the absence of public policy to the contrary, it is likely that in periods of strong demand the price level will rise, and in periods of weak demand there will be more than normal unemployment while the price level falls only slowly, as has occurred more or less regularly in the past. Even if we could have a perfectly flexible price level, I believe we would not want to rely on it, because in practice rapid changes in the price level are bad. Why are they bad ? Only because they cannot be accurately foreseen by everyone. When people make contracts whose performance will stretch out over time, such as loans, rentals, insurance, annuities, pensions, etc., or even when they simply hold cash, they cannot do so wisely unless they know what the price level will be at relevant points of time in the future as compared with its present level. For example, suppose I lend you $100 today, to be repaid after a year, and suppose we want to agree on terms that will make it possible to buy 1.05 times as much a year from now, with the principal and interest that you are going to pay me then, as can be bought now with the $100 I am about to lend you. If we know that the price level will not change during the year, we will agree that you are to repay me $105, which is $100 with 5 percent interest. If we know that the price level is going to double during the year, we will agree that you are to repay me $210, which is $100 with 110 percent interest. If we know that the price level will fall to half its current value during the year, we will agree that you are to repay me $52.50, which is $100 with minus 4 7 ^ percent interest. As long as the future behavior of the price level is known, it does not matter much what it is going to be; we can adjust our loan contract to allow for it. But if we don't know what will happen to the price level, then a contract for the repayment of $100 at an interest rate of, say, 5 percent is of unknown worth in terms of real purchasing power * * * it will be worth more if the price level falls than if it rises. An escalator clause could be written into the contract, as is done with some wage contracts, but this device is cumbersome, and it could not very well be used to protect the holder of cash from fluctuations in its real value. The same principle applies to any other contract stretching over time: if the future course of the price level is known, then the contract can be written to take account of these changes, and thus to provide for the payment of the amount of real purchasing power that the parties to the contract want to agree upon. 358 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH If the real value of future payments to be made under such contracts is uncertain, because future price levels are uncertain, then the use of such contracts will be discouraged, with a consequent misallocation of resources. Also, if the price level rises unexpectedly, there will be an unexpected transfer of wealth from lenders to borrowers,, which is unfair, and vice versa if the price level falls unexpectedlyy which is also unfair. The argument for a stable price level, then, is essentially an argument against imperfectly foreseen changes in the price level. It is much easier to persuade people that the price level will be stable in the future than to persuade them that it will rise or fall at some definite rate, or that it will follow some prescribed path. An additional advantage of a stable price level over a varying one, assuming that foresight is equally good in both cases, is that with a stable level it is not necessary to do quite so much computing in order to write out a contract that does what one wants in real purchasing power terms. Further, there is a large volume of outstanding contracts for insurance, loans, etc., that were presumably made on the expectation that the price level would stay approximately constant, and there is no equitable reason to transfer wealth from the lenders to the borrowers under these contracts, or vice versa, by changing the price level now. In view of the foregoing argument, I believe it is preferable to maintain an approximately stable price level rather than having a flexible one, and to rely on monetary and fiscal policy to prevent rises in the price level during periods when demand is strong and to prevent unemployment and declines in the price level in periods when demand is weak. XII. STABILIZATION POLICY I N PRACTICE A rising price level together with full employment is due to the fact that more goods and services are demanded with money than are supplied by resource owners at the existing price level. Unemployment is due to the fact that fewer goods and services are demanded for money than are supplied by resource owners at the existing price level. The cure for the former is to diminish the demand for goods and services, and the cure for the latter is to increase it. The Federal Government has several tools in its policy arsenal that can do this without price controls or other serious interferences with resource allocation as established by free contract. These include the following (I describe them in terms of what one wants to do in a case of unemployment; in a case of inflation the reverse of each would apply) : (i) Increase the quantity of money (deposits and currency) in the hands of the public without doing anything else—this is perhaps done most simply by a Government deficit produced by either a cut in taxes or an increase in transfer payments to the public (particularly the unemployed). (11) Reduce interest rates and increase the quantity of money in the hands of the public through open market purchases of outstanding Government securities by the central bank. (A reduction in reserve requirements for commercial banks makes possible an essentially similar operation in which banks buy the public's promissory notes.) ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH 359 (iii) Increase Government purchases of goods and services by means of deficit financing, thus creating a direct demand for production and increasing the quantity of money in the hands of the public. Of these three, the first already occurs to a considerable extent automatically, due to the operation of various built-in stabilizers such as progressive income taxes and unemployment benefits. All three can be applied in a deliberate discretionary fashion, however. I believe that if they are pursued vigorously, as soon as substantial unemployment becomes evident, they can cure any depression promptly; and of course if they are pursued too vigorously and too long, they can turn any depression into an inflation. Similarly, I believe that, if they are pursued vigorously in reverse, they can stop inflation promptly; and if overdone can turn any inflation into a depression. I do not believe that the great depression of the 1930's affords a fair test of the effectiveness of countercyclical monetary and fiscal policy, because either wrong or too weak policies were followed in the first 4 years of the decline. For one thing, the quantity of money in the hands of the public was permitted to undergo an almost steady decline of about 25 percent from the fall of 1929 to the middle of 1933; it should have been kept fairly stable instead. Also, shortly after industrial production had begun to rise in the early spring of 1931, and then had turned down again the summer, the Federal Reserve raised its discount rate from iy2 to Sy2 percent, and then maintained it at or above 2% percent for the next 2 years, when it should have been kept low. Thus it was only after the depression had become very deep, and private spending had fallen drastically, that public policy began to come strongly to the rescue. This may explain why it was not very effective when it did come. The declines in 1948-49 and 1953-54 were much milder, especially the second one. I believe that this was partly because in both of them public countercyclical policy was more appropriate. In the 1948-49 decline, taxes were cut in the latter half of 1948, and the Federal Reserve at least did not raise the discount rate after the decline began (though it did not lower it). In the 1953-54 decline, taxes were cut early in 1954, and the Federal Reserve lowered the discount rate quite promptly and kept it low until the spring of 1955. If I may be permitted to express the opinion, it seems to me that early in February of 1958, when the January unemployment figure of 4.5 million came out and showed an increase of 1.1 million from December, about twice as large as the expected seasonal increase at that time of year, it was then time for a tax cut. There is one cloud on the horizon of the picture I have painted of the effectiveness of stabilization policy, and that is this question: If unemployment is to be kept fairly stable at a level as low as 4 percent of the labor force (which is approximately the postwar average), can the price level be kept from rising? Or put another way, if the price level is to be kept stable, can unemployment be kept as low as about 4 percent of the labor force ? If one compares the histories of recent depressions, one finds it hard to give a clear "ves" answer to this question. In depressions between the two World Wars, prices apparently fell more readily than since the second war. And if one compares the three postwar recessions, which (at this writing) are about equally severe, the current one being a 360 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH bit deeper than the others, one finds the following declines of the Wholesale Price Index, the Consumer Price Index, and average hourly earnings in manufacturing, each measured from its own peak month to its own trough month: Wholesale Price Index Consumer Price Index Average hourly earnings in manufacturing 1948-49 1953-54 1957 (latest) Percent -11 -4 -1 Percent -1 -1 -1 Still rising (February). Do. —ft percent (February). This suggests that prices are becoming less and less flexible downward. If so, and if prices rise at all in the prosperous periods that intervene between recessions, then we are in for a gradually rising price level on a sort of ratchet principle: little or no change during recessions? and increases in between. If this is really the case, I believe it is tolerable if the price level does not rise more than, say, 20 percent in a generation. I would prefer to accept an average price increase of 1 percent a year, rather than having to accept an average level of unemployment of 5 percent instead of 4 percent, if the choice came down to that, because the price rise is largely redistributive, whereas the extra unemployment represents foregone production of goods and services. INFLATION, THE WAGE-PRICE SPIRAL AND ECONOMIC GROWTH Otto Eckstein, Harvard University The relation between economic growth and inflation is not a simple one. Investment adds to effective demand, helping to drive up prices; it also adds to the capacity of the economy, making possible an increased supply of goods in the future. Inflation increases the opportunities for profit, but may discourage saving and distort the directions of investment. This paper examines this relationship, primarily emphasizing postwar experience in the United States. Most of our attention will be devoted to the effect of investments and growth on inflation, a relationship which has been discussed less fully than the reverse.1 Much of our analysis will run in terms of the movements of the wage-price spiral. I. LONG-RUN TRENDS OF OUTPUT AND PRICES I N ADVANCED ECONOMIES The ambiguity of the relationship is brought out most clearly by the long-run experience of many countries. Table I, which draws on the long-run growth data assembled by S. Kuznets, gives the rates of growth of output per decade for 8 countries, and the rates of price change that accompanied the growth. It can be seen that periods of rapid growth occurred with and without inflation, and that periods of stagnation also saw a very wide range of price changes. Thus, as a long-run phenomenon, there is no historical association between growth and inflation.2 !But see A. Smithies, The Control of Inflation, Review of Economics and Statistics, August 1957, pp. 272-281, and S. Slichter, Thinking Ahead: On the Side of Inflation, Harvard Business Review, September-October 1957, p. 15. 2 For the United States, the correlation coefficients for the two series of decade-by-decade changes of prices and output are 0.08 and —0.05. For most of the other countries, the correlations are dominated by extreme values of inflation associated with little growth. 361 362 ECONOMIC STABILITY AND GROWTH TABLE 1.—Rates of growth of output per decade and rates of change of prices per decade in some advanced countries From preceding decade Decades Output growth Percent price change UNITED STATES Output growth Percent price change UNITED STATES 1869-78 _ _ _ _ _ _ 1879-88 1889-98 1899-1908 1909-18 1919-28 .__ 1929-38 1939-48 1950-541 88.0 38.2 56.4 35.5 39.2 6.2 71.7 29.0 -19.5 -12.9 +9.3 +34.6 +46.3 -18.0 +34.2 +34.5 UNITED KINGDOM 1874-83 _ _ . 1884-93 1894-1903 1904-13 1914-23 1924-33 1934-43 1944-53 54.8 45.2 50.6 29.0 29.1 26.0 52.0 -16.0 -7.1 +20.7 +64.0 0 -7.1 +84.8 4.2 19.4 11.8 30.7 9.3 40.6 8.8 23.9 +13.1 -8.7 -2.6 +11.4 +260.0 +35.0 +18.5 +4442.4 ITALY 1865-74 1875-84 1885-94 1895-1904 1905-14 1915-24 1925-34 1935-44 1949-53 21.1 37.6 29.2 16.5 -0.8 21.1 30.2 22.7 -15.0 -0.9 +9.6 +106.0 -16.6 +17.1 +51.3 1864-73 1874-83 1884-93 1894-1903 1904-13 1914-23 1924-33 1934-43 1950-54 SWEDEN JAPAN 1883-92 1892-1902 1903-12 1913-22 1923-32 1933-42 1950-541 64.8 34.7 45.3 67.4 52.1 10.6 +35.4 +38.2 +86. 5 -7.1 +28.6 +18856.3 NORWAY 1864-73 1874-83 1884-93 1894-1903 1904-13 1914-23 1924-33 1934-43 1950-541 +7.5 30.6 21.7 40.5 40.3 25.1 23.2 36.3 60.1 +2.7 +13.9 +99.2 -11.3 +13.0 +62.4 24.3 38.4 41.9 35.8 36.7 16.1 28.5 -6.2 0 +3.5 +126. 5 -26.7 +25.6 +119.3 -12.0 DENMARK 1900-1908 . _ 1909-18 1919-28 1929-39 1950-54 33.0 29.1 38.1 33.5 +71.9 +60.8 -37.5 +174.6 25.1 40.1 .2 33.7 +58.3 -12.7 -7.1 +145.4 NETHERLANDS 1904-13 1914-23 1924-33 1934-43 1950-541 From preceding decade Decades _ 1874-83 1884-93 1894-1903 1904-13 1914-23 1924-33 1934-43 1950-54 __ _ i Last figure for all countries is not a decade-by-decade comparison. Source: S. Kuznets, Quantitative Aspects of the Economic Growth of Nations, Economic Development and Cultural Change, vol. V, No. 1. The explanation of these figures is quite simple. First in the late d