View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Regional Economist
January 1997

Eighth
Note

Should the Fed
Target the CPI?
As Fed Chairman Alan Greenspan
has been saying for some time, and
the Boskin Commission’s recent report
confirms, the consumer price index
appears to overstate the cost of living
by about 1 percentage point. If this
estimate is accurate, then annual costof-living increases in government benefit programs and upward adjustments
in tax brackets have been too high.
Predictably, the political controversy
surrounding this subject centers on
whether we should correct the bias in
the CPI to help balance the budget.
But lost in the debate is another important question: Should the Federal
Reserve use the CPI—biased or not—
to define its price-stability objective?
The answer, in my opinion, is yes.
As the Boskin Commission reported,
roughly half the bias in the CPI, called
substitution bias, arises because current
data-gathering methods fail to account
for the public’s ability to shift its purchases quickly, in response to changes
in relative prices. This bias can be
eliminated, but only with a shifting
of priorities or an increase in resources
at the Bureau of Labor Statistics. The
other half of the bias arises because it
is difficult to account for new products and improvements to existing
products. These issues are thorny and
unlikely to be resolved anytime soon.

Obviously, we should continue
the debate about how to make the
CPI as accurate as possible. That
said, as a long-run objective for monetary policy, the CPI has several
things already going for it. It is one
of the most carefully constructed
and timely of all economic measures.
Moreover, it is widely recognized and
often used in economic calculations
and indexing arrangements.
If we’re trying to achieve price
stability in terms of cost of living,
by definition we should be looking
for CPI growth that is equal to its
estimated bias. The CPI increased
3.3 percent in 1996. Subtract the 1
percentage-point bias in the measure, and you can see that we’re still
2.3 percentage points away from
having stable prices. Let’s say,
though, that the Fed were to set a
0 percent to 2 percent long-run
objective for the CPI, and it ended
up growing roughly 1 percent a year.
We would then have effectively eliminated inflation.
My point is that uncertainty
about the best way to measure the
cost of living shouldn’t keep us from
the important task of choosing a
price index to measure our progress
toward price stability. As resources
allow, I am certain that the BLS will
continue to fine-tune the CPI. In
the meantime, the Fed can define its
price stability objective in a way that
takes any known bias into account.

3

Thomas C. Melzer
President

Regional Economist
January 1997

The
OVERLOOKED

The Rural Eighth Di s t r i c t
O

ver the past few decades, much
has been made of the blight
and subsequent revitalization of
urban America.1 Many cities have
witnessed population and job
flight to the suburbs. To lure back
many of these lost jobs and residents, local, state and federal governments have devised a wide
range of incentives, usually involving infrastructure improvements or
tax breaks for real estate development or new employment.2 Numerous cities have since rejuvenated
their business districts.
At the same time, however,
scant attention has been paid to
development in rural areas. Historically, farm policy had been
thought of as constituting rural
policy. But farming has changed
over time, becoming much more
sophisticated because of dramatic
advances in technology.3 In 1960,
farm output made up about 4
percent of all U.S. output; today
it comprises only a bit more than
1 percent. Yet despite farming’s
falling share of total output, rural
areas have continued to record
income and employment growth.
Areas that were once thought of
as primarily farmland are today
much more diverse and, in fact,
have been posting some of the

B Y AD AM M. ZARETSKY

nation’s strongest income and
employment growth over the
last 10 to 20 years, even though
only 20 percent of the nation’s
population lives there. Strikingly,
though, 40 percent of the Eighth
Federal Reserve District’s population lives in nonmetropolitan
areas, making rural policy and
development even more important in this area.4

A Snapshot of District
Rural Areas
Eighth District rural areas largely are agricultural. District states
are home to almost one-fourth—
about half a million—of all farms
in the country. Missouri alone
contains about 5 percent of the
nation’s farms. But, because the
farms in our District are generally
about half the size of those in
other parts of the country, they
constitute only a little more than
one-eighth of the nation’s farm
acreage—about the same as in
Texas. District farm output contributes just 2 percent to the
region’s total output, making it
slightly more important here than
it is in the rest of the nation.

5

The somewhat greater presence
agriculture has in the District, however, does not make this region
more rural than others in the
nation. The proportion of the
region’s population that lives in
rural areas is a more meaningful
determinant of rural status. Not
only does two-fifths of the District’s population live in nonmetropolitan areas, but this share also
accounts for a whopping 23 percent of the nation’s nonmetropolitan population. In comparison,
the District is home to only 14 percent of all of the nation’s residents.
District urban and rural areas
also have higher population densities than their national counterparts. District metropolitan areas,
for instance, have about 325 persons per square mile, while the
national average is about 290 persons per square mile. The difference is even more dramatic in
nonmetropolitan areas: 45 persons per square mile in the District versus 18 persons per square
mile in the nation, or about 2 1/2
times the density. This higher
density makes the District’s rural
areas attractive to businesses
because of the larger-than-usual
labor pool from which to draw
workers. This gives these areas a

relatively important role to play in the
region’s overall economy.

Rural Areas: Myths
and Realities
Because rural areas are usually characterized by farming—an industry of

Employment in District Rural Areas
Between 1974 and 1984, nonfarm
payroll employment actually grew
somewhat faster in the District’s rural
counties than in its urban counties.5
For the most part, however, employment growth in urban and rural areas
was slow, averaging about 1 percent a
year during the decade. Individual
states, however, differed in their
growth patterns. For example, all
District states except Illinois and
Indiana had average job growth of
more than 1 percent a year. Illinois
and Indiana, which are in the Rust
Belt, an area that suffered severe setbacks during this time, experienced
employment growth that was about
half a percentage point below the District norm in both urban and rural
areas. Only in Kentucky and Missouri
did rural areas create more jobs than
urban areas.
By the mid-1980s, the resurgence
of job growth in the region was obvious. The District’s average growth
rates were up a full percentage point
from the previous decade. Arkansas,
Mississippi and Tennessee—states in
the southern part of the District
which generally have lower labor
costs due to less unionized labor
forces, right-to-work laws and lower
taxes—rebounded with stronger
growth in both urban and rural areas.
In all District states except Missouri,
however, urban employment growth
rates still outpaced rural ones, with
some approaching 3 percent a year.
Manufacturing as a Driving Force

NOTE: Several
small nonmetro
counties in
Arkansas, Illinois,
Kentucky and
Missouri are not
included for
some years.
SOURCE: U.S.
Department of
Commerce,
Bureau of
Economic
Analysis

dwindling importance in U.S. output—as well as a more tranquil
lifestyle than that found in cities, a
common perception is that they grow
slower than urban areas. An examination of two different growth measures—employment and personal
income—shows that, for the District,
this perception has some validity.
Growth rates in both payroll employment and per capita personal income
have, in general, been slightly faster
in metropolitan than nonmetropolitan areas, though the differences are
often negligible.

6

What sustained job growth during
the leaner mid- to late-1970s and drove
much of the resurgence that followed?
As the charts at left show, between the
mid-1970s and mid-1980s, manufacturing employment levels fell in all
District metropolitan areas, except
those in Arkansas. This isn’t too surprising since manufacturing’s share of
total employment has been declining
nationally for decades, with some of
the biggest hits taken in the 1970s.
What is surprising, though, is that
manufacturing employment levels in
most states’ nonmetropolitan areas
actually increased during this period.
Only in the Rust Belt states did they
decline. Thus, while almost all District urban areas were losing manufacturing jobs, the bulk of District rural
areas were creating them. One explanation for this is better access to
transportation from improved rural
highways. Although growth rates
in rural areas were admittedly low—
less than 1 percent a year—the mild
growth served to set the stage for the
coming resurgence.

Regional Economist
January 1997

From the mid-1980s to the mid1990s, manufacturing employment
took off in all District states’ rural
areas, even those in the Rust Belt.
Kentucky and Missouri, in fact,
experienced an average growth rate
of more than 2 percent a year.
Although most states’ urban areas
also added manufacturing jobs during this time, they came at a slower
pace than in rural areas.
Overall, many more counties
added manufacturing jobs than lost
them. About twice as many District
urban counties had some manufacturing employment growth than had
some decline. But about four times
as many District rural counties experienced manufacturing employment
growth as experienced declines over
the period.
Where did the strongest growth
occur? The maps at right show those
counties where average growth either
increased or declined by more than
5 percent a year during the past 10
years. Only one District metropolitan county falls into the decline category, while about 30 percent of those
that grew, did so at more than 5 percent a year.
The split among nonmetropolitan
counties follows a similar pattern.
Only six rural counties witnessed a
decline in manufacturing employment of more than 5 percent a year
over the period. Here, too, almost
30 percent of those counties that
grew did so by more than 5 percent,
illustrating that they were not only
adding manufacturing jobs during
the decade, but also holding their
own against their urban neighbors.
This is significant since manufacturers had usually favored urban areas
because of their better access to
labor, transportation, financing and
an established corporate community.

MANUFACTURING EMPLOYMENT
SUCCESS STORIES (AND FAILURES)
1984-1994
Me t ro p o l i t a n

No n m e t ro p o l i t a n

The North/South Divide
About 17 percent of all current
District employees work for manufacturing firms—marginally more than
the 16 percent nationwide. Somewhat surprisingly, District nonmetropolitan counties have the higher
concentrations of manufacturing
workers—about 23 percent in nonmetropolitan counties compared
with 15 percent in metropolitan
counties. Both the nonmetropolitan and metropolitan District shares
are lower than they were 10 years
ago—four percentage points in the
metro areas, one percentage point
in nonmetro areas.
As the figure on the next page
shows, the nonmetropolitan counties
in Arkansas, Mississippi and Tennessee are especially manufacturing

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Commerce,
Bureau of Economic Analysis

7

intensive—more than 20 percent of all
employees in these counties work for
manufacturing firms. Nonmetropolitan counties in the northern states
of the District, particularly Missouri,
Illinois and Kentucky, generally have
average or below average shares of
manufacturing employment.
What, then, explains the north/
south discrepancy in the District’s
manufacturing employment concentrations? For the most part, it exists
because southern states generally

District norm. Only in Mississippi
and Tennessee did rural per capita
income grow faster than urban.
By the mid-1980s, growth in per
capita income accelerated in nearly
all District states—in some cases by
almost one percentage point a year.
However, very few District counties
experienced income growth of more
than 3 percent a year during the period—only 6 percent of all rural counties, mostly in the southern states,
and no urban counties. Even fewer

MANUFACTURING EMPLOYMENT’S
SHARE OF TOTAL EMPLOYMENT-1994
Metropolitan

Nonmetropolitan

SOURCE: U.S.
Department of
Commerce, Bureau
of Economic
Analysis

have less restrictive labor laws and
lower labor costs than their northern
neighbors. In fact, average manufacturing wages in southern District
states are about $3 an hour less than
in northern District states. This has
made southern states particularly
attractive to firms looking to cut costs
and improve efficiency, as increasingly fierce competition has evolved
in domestic and foreign markets.
What about Income Growth?
Another measure of a region’s
prosperity is its personal income
growth. Per capita personal income
measures the average level of income
per person. Between 1974 and 1984,
real per capita income (adjusted for
inflation) in the District grew slightly
less than 1 percent a year. The Rust
Belt states exhibited the slowest
growth, while increases in Arkansas,
Missouri and Tennessee exceeded the

8

had declines in income. Thus, just
about all counties experienced average growth, regardless of whether
they were rural or urban.
A clear urban/rural distinction
exists in the level of per capita
income among District counties,
though. Metropolitan counties are,
for the most part, wealthy; nonmetropolitan counties, particularly
those in the southern states, are
mostly poor. As a result, rural areas
still have problems they haven’t yet
overcome, which, if not addressed,
will restrain their prospects for future
growth. The income disparity with
their urban neighbors, and its resultant poverty, is one of their most
prevalent problems.
Prevalent Poverty
District rural counties, especially
in the south, have the region’s highest concentrations of poor people.

Regional Economist
January 1997

In fact, about 40 percent of these
counties had more than 21 percent
of their populations living below
the poverty line in 1989.6 In contrast, most District metropolitan
counties had less than 14 percent
of their populations living below
the poverty line.
Given the amount of poverty that
exists in District rural counties, and
the fast income growth experienced
by some of these counties in the late
1980s and early 1990s, one might
suspect that increases in government
payments to the poor may have driven some of the growth. In fact,
they did. Between 1984 and 1994,
per capita government payments,
adjusted for inflation, grew about
half a percentage point a year faster
in each state’s rural areas than in its
urban areas.
A Bit Older and Wealthier
Certainly, though, these payments
were not all going to those in poverty.
In 1994, only 11 percent of all federal
government transfer payments went
to welfare programs, while 70 percent
went to Social Security and Medicare.
Perhaps, then, most of these transfer
payments were not going to those in
poverty, but rather to those receiving
Social Security and Medicare. The
evidence supports this.
The rural areas of all seven District
states have a larger share (15 percent)
of their population in the 65 and
older age group than their urban
neighbors (12 percent). Although
this pattern holds true for each
District state, it is most pronounced
in Arkansas, Illinois and Missouri.
Rural regions likely benefit from
the larger presence of this age group
because its members not only receive
a steady stream of income and services from the government, but they
also have accumulated wealth, which
they’re willing to spend. As a matter
of fact, a recent economic study
found that the Social Security and
Medicare programs, for example,
have enabled senior citizens to spend
savings that otherwise would have
been kept for medical emergencies or
other necessities.7 This has allowed
them to become some of the biggest
spenders in the economy today,
which probably bodes well for the
future of rural areas.

as, or better than, their urban neighbors. Although some of the growth
could be a spillover from urban revitalization projects, many rural areas
have exhibited income growth that’s
at least comparable to, and employment growth that’s stronger than,
their urban counterparts.
Moreover, rural areas have diversified their economies away from
agriculture, which represents just a
minuscule portion of total output
today. Manufacturing is one sector
that has been instrumental in this
diversification. Nonmetropolitan
counties are now some of the District’s most manufacturing-intensive
areas. Large pools of labor and better
access to transportation have helped
rural regions attract these businesses
away from cities.
The next wave of development
will likely arise from pathbreaking
telecommunications technologies.
A recent General Accounting Office
report argues that while improved
roads were once seen as the key to
“rural areas’ overcoming the barrier
of distance, . . .telecommunications
technologies may [now] be a critical
element in many rural areas’ efforts
to maintain and foster social and
economic development.”8 The belief
is that these technologies will better
link rural areas with other communities and their expertise, thereby
improving medical services, creating
new jobs and increasing access to
educational opportunities.
Because firms that specialize in
information technology and services,
which will probably lead the economy in future growth opportunities,
can essentially locate themselves
anywhere, lower-cost areas will be
the most attractive. If per capita
income continues to grow as it has
for the past 10 years, then rural areas,
especially in the southern parts of
the District where business costs are
lower, can expect to see even more
development than they have already.

Adam M. Zaretsky is an economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Eran Segev
provided research assistance.

ENDNOTES
1

The terms “urban” and “metropolitan,” and “rural” and “nonmetropolitan” are not strictly
synonymous; however, they will
be used interchangeably in this
article. “Metropolitan areas” refer
to metropolitan statistical areas
and consolidated metropolitan statistical areas, as defined by the U.S.
Office of Management and Budget.

2

See Zaretsky (1994) for a more
detailed description of these
incentives.

3

See Cooper and Sigalla (1996) for
a description of how technological
advances have made agriculture
more productive and efficient.

4

The region includes Arkansas,
Illinois, Indiana, Kentucky,
Mississippi, Missouri and Tennessee. Although the Eighth Federal
Reserve District does not cover all
of these states in their entirety, this
article will refer to whole states in
its analysis.

5

Farm employment, which is not
included in payroll employment
data, declined in all areas during
1974-1984 and 1984-1994. It represents a very small fraction of
total employment, however.

6

The cutoff of 21 percent is used
because one-third of District counties had more than this share of
their populations living in poverty
in 1989.

7

See Gokhale and others (1996).

8

See U.S. General Accounting Office
(1996), p. 1.

REFERENCES
Cooper, J.B., and Fiona Sigalla.
Agriculture, Technology and the
Economy, Federal Reserve Bank
of Dallas (Fall 1996).
Drabenstott, Mark, and Tim R.
Smith. “The Changing Economy
of the Rural Heartland.” Economic
Forces Shaping the Rural Heartland,
Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
City (April 1996), pp. 1-11.
Gokhale, Jagadeesh, Laurence J.
Kotlikoff, and John Sabelhaus.
“Understanding the Postwar
Decline in U.S. Saving: A Cohort
Analysis.” Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity, no. 1 (1996),
pp. 315-407.
Morgan, Kathleen O’Leary, Scott
Morgan, and Neal Quinto. State
Rankings 1996: A Statistical View
of the 50 United States, 7th ed.
Morgan Quinto Press (1996).
Smith, Tim R. “Determinants of
Rural Growth: Winners and Losers
in the 1980s,” Research working
paper, RWP 92-11, Federal Reserve
Bank of Kansas City (December
1992).
U.S. General Accounting Office.
Rural Development: Steps Toward
Realizing the Potential of Telecommunications Technologies,
GAO/RCED-96-155 (June 1996).
Zaretsky, Adam M. “Are States
Giving Away the Store?” The
Regional Economist, Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis (January 1994),
pp. 5-9.

What’s in Store for
These Regions?
Despite popular misconceptions,
District rural areas have not been left
behind over the past two decades. In
fact, they have generally fared as well

9

by Miche lle Cla rk Nee ly

T

aking a cue from
Canada, the United
Kingdom and other
countries, the U.S. Treasury
decided last year to begin
offering inflation-indexed
bonds to investors looking
to protect their savings from
unexpected increases in
inflation. With the first
auction scheduled for early
1997, economists, finance
professionals and policymakers are cheering the
change. But will indexed
bonds shake the market, or
merely cause a stir?

What’s An
Indexed Bond?
Unlike a conventional, or
nominal bond, an inflationindexed, or real, bond promises to pay its holder a fixed
real rate of return—a return
that is unaffected by unexpected changes in the inflation
rate. While a conventional
bond repays an investor
principal plus some stated
interest, an indexed bond
repays principal adjusted for
inflation and a fixed interest
rate applied to the adjusted
principal. Investors value
such protection because large
increases in unanticipated
inflation can eat away at an
investment’s real return.

Expected inflation, real returns
and nominal returns are linked by a
simple relationship called the Fisher
equation, which states that the real
return on a bond is roughly equivalent to the nominal interest rate
minus the expected inflation rate.1
For example, if an investor purchases
a Treasury security with a 6 percent
nominal interest rate, and inflation is
expected to be zero during the investment period, the real expected return
would be 6 percent. In the real
world, however, inflation is usually
positive, so in most cases the real rate
of return will be less than the nominal return.
Because investors understand this
relationship between inflation and
real returns and want, therefore, to be
compensated for any decline in purchasing power, nominal interest rates
tend to rise when investors expect the
inflation rate to worsen, and vice
versa. But what happens if actual
inflation is higher than expected
inflation? An investor purchasing a
conventional bond at 7 percent
expects a real return of 5 percent if
inflation is expected to be 2 percent
during the investment period. If
actual inflation turns out to be 4 percent, however, the bond’s real return
drops to 3 percent. If the actual inflation rate is high enough, the real
return can even turn negative, causing the investor to pay the borrower
for the privilege of using his money,
rather than the other way around.
An inflation risk premium is built
into nominal bond yields to compensate investors for the risk that inflation will be higher than expected. Of

10

course, inflation risk can work the
other way: If actual inflation is less
than expected inflation, the investor
gains while the issuer loses. Because
investors are thought to be risk
averse—they dislike surprise losses
more than they like surprise gains of
equal magnitude—the inflation risk
premium in nominal interest rates
is positive.
Indexed bonds eliminate inflation uncertainty. A holder of an
indexed bond is assured that the
real cash flow of the bond (principal plus interest) will not be
affected by inflation. On the surface, at least, indexing appears to
be a win-win proposition. Investors gain because their capital is
protected, while issuers gain
because they do not have to pay the
inflation risk premium. Moreover,
this joint gain increases with the
term of the bond, for two reasons.
First, there is a higher risk that
expected inflation will differ from
actual inflation the further out into
the future you go, and second, any
inflation forecast error is magnified
with longer-term bonds because of
interest compounding.

The Treasury Experiment
Although the Treasury’s initial
auction of inflation-indexed bonds
is to be for 10-year notes starting
at $1,000 denominations, by early
1998, the Department plans to
offer indexed securities of other
maturities, as well as indexed savings bonds.2 The 10-year indexed
notes will be auctioned quarterly in
a uniform price auction similar to
that used for other marketable
Treasury securities.
The Treasury’s indexed bond is
structured like the Canadian real
return bond. The Department will
calculate semi-annual interest payments by adjusting the principal for
inflation and applying the auctiondetermined, fixed real interest rate to
the adjusted principal. The inflation
adjustment will be based on the
Consumer Price Index for all Urban
Consumers (CPI-U), a widely used,
though flawed, measure of U.S. inflation.3 To ensure that investors will
not come up short from any deflation occurring during the investment
period, the Treasury has promised
that the final principal payment will
be at least equal to the original par
amount of the security at issuance.4

Indexed Bond Benefits
Investors, issuers and policymakers—
especially monetary policymakers—

Regional Economist
January 1997

all stand to gain from indexed
bonds. For investors, the major benefit is the guarantee of a real yield.5
In the past, government bond
investors have been burned when
inflation exceeded nominal interest
rates, resulting in negative real
returns. Although the inflation rate
has been relatively low for the past
several years—hovering around 3
percent—there is always a chance
that poor economic policy or an
external shock could drive it higher.
Consequently, the Treasury Department is promoting the securities
to conservative investors who can
ill-afford capital losses, like those
saving for impending retirement or
college costs and those living on
fixed incomes.
The potential benefits for the
Treasury are many. Indexed bonds
could substantially reduce inflation
risk and—depending on their share
of total government debt—stabilize
the Treasury’s real funding costs.
While unexpectedly high inflation
benefits the Treasury by lowering the
real return it has to pay investors,
unexpectedly low inflation increases
the government’s funding costs. For
example, the Treasury is currently
paying a 15.75 percent coupon on a
20-year bond it issued in 1981 when
CPI-U inflation was 10.4 percent; the
real cost to the Treasury for that
bond at issuance was 5.35 percent.
Today, however, with inflation averaging about 3 percent, the real cost
of the bond is close to 13 percent.
Many analysts believe the Treasury
will pay real rates of 3 percent to 4
percent on long-term indexed bonds.
The more certain benefit for the
Treasury is the money it will save by
eliminating the inflation risk premium on some portion of its debt.
Although the size of the premium is
debatable, most economists estimate
it to be at least 50 basis points for
short-term bonds and even more for
longer-term bonds.6 Because the
Treasury borrows about $200 billion
a year, the potential savings could be
substantial, even if just a small portion of new debt were indexed.
One of the subtler, yet equally
important, benefits brought about
by indexing government debt is the
information the process would provide policymakers about inflation
expectations and real interest rates.
For their part, monetary policymakers could ascertain a market-based
estimate of inflation expectations by
observing the difference in interest
rates on conventional and indexed
bonds of the same maturities. They
could then use these estimates to
assess how well the central bank is
doing its job.

Demand Downside
Despite these wide-reaching benefits, the success of indexed bonds is
by no means certain. Demand for
them will be dampened by several
factors, not the least of which is the
tax treatment they are subject to. The
tax consequences are twofold. First,
because the current U.S. tax code does
not distinguish between increases in
real income and increases in nominal
income due to inflation, the indexed
bond holder’s tax liabilities will
increase, lowering the after-tax real
yields on these securities. Second, the
Treasury has determined that
investors will pay taxes on the inflation-adjusted increase in principal
accrued each year (as well as the interest received), even though it is not
paid out to maturity. A surge in inflation, therefore, could result in a tax
liability that would swamp the current cash income from the bond.

Because of this unfavorable tax treatment, many analysts think the
demand for these securities will be
limited to tax-deferred financial
assets, like IRAs and 401(k) plans.
Another factor working against the
success of indexed bonds is that,
even after adjusting for inflation and
risk, they still will be outperformed by
stocks and many corporate bonds,
especially over the long term. That’s
why they’re likely to make up only a
small portion of most investors’ portfolios. But even if inflation-indexed
bonds fail to dazzle the securities
world, they’re still likely to quench
the thirst of conservative investors—
without leaving them on the rocks.

Michelle Clark Neely is an economist at the
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Thomas A.
Pollmann provided research assistance.

11

ENDNOTES
1

This relationship assumes there
is no default or interest rate
risk premiums.

2

Treasury securities with original
maturities ranging from one to 10
years are notes; securities with
original maturities of greater than
10 years are bonds. The term
“bond” will be used hereafter to
refer to either or both.

3

See Berry and Pianin (1996)
for information about biases
in the CPI.

4

See the Federal Register (1996) for
more detail on the structure of
these bonds.

5

Indexed bond holders are not,
however, immune from market
risk (the risk that the price of an
already-issued security will decline
in response to increases in market
interest rates) if they sell before
maturity. That said, most analysts
believe that inflation protection
will reduce market risk.

6

See Campbell and Shiller (1996)
for a discussion of estimates of the
size of the inflation risk premium.

FOR FURTHER READING
Berry, John M., and Eric Pianin.
“Hill Panel Says Inflation
Overstated,” Washington Post
(December 5, 1996).
Campbell, John Y., and Robert J.
Shiller. “A Scorecard for Indexed
Government Debt,” National
Bureau of Economic Research
Working Paper No. 5587 (April
1996).
Federal Register, U.S. Department of
the Treasury. 31 CFR Part 356.
“Sale and Issue of Marketable
Book-Entry Treasury Bills, Notes,
and Bonds (Department of the
Treasury Circular, Public Debt
Series No. 1-93); Proposed Rule
(September 27, 1996).
Hetzel, Robert L. “Indexed Bonds as
an Aid to Monetary Policy,”
Economic Review, Federal Reserve
Bank of Richmond (January/
February 1992), pp. 13-23.
Shen, Pu. “Benefits and Limitations
of Inflation Indexed Treasury
Bonds,” Economic Review, Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City (Third
Quarter 1995), pp. 41-56.

weather-related development, national trends in farm income typically
hold at the state level as well.

District Farmers Cash In
In the upper reaches of the Eighth
Federal Reserve District, corn and soybeans reign as the dominant crops,
while in the southern parts, cotton
and rice are king.2 The District is also
home to a significant portion of the
nation’s production of broilers (in
Arkansas) and catfish (in Mississippi).
To understand why crop receipts and
the value of farm inventories contributed so heavily to the rise of real
NFI in 1996, it’s helpful to look at
how the corn, cotton, rice and soybean harvests fared in the District
and the United States last year.
As the accompanying figure indicates, with the exception of rice,
production of the four crops in
the seven District states in 1996
surpassed that in 1995. In the
case of corn and soybeans, substantially more output was produced last
year, while in the case of cotton,
only a modest increase in production
was seen.3

What’
s
Up
Down on the Farm?
by Kevin L. Kliesen

N

ineteen ninety-six was
a pretty good year for
farmers in the Eighth
Federal Reserve District.
Above-average prices and
higher-than-normal crop
yields in the past year are
expected to produce a substantial rebound in aggregate
farm income. These increases
also bode well for rural businesses—like automobile and
farm machinery dealers—
which expect farmers to spend
a good part of their increased
fortunes on Main Street.

1996 Farm Income:
Lots of “Spendin’
Cabbage”
The most commonly cited
measure of farm income is
the United States Department
of Agriculture’s (USDA) net
farm income series. Net farm
income (NFI) is the sum of
crop and livestock receipts,
government farm program
payments, noncash income
(such as the value of food
grown on the farm for home
consumption) and other
miscellaneous farm-related
income, less production
expenses (including labor
and property taxes), a capital
consumption allowance

(depreciation) and taxes and interest on real estate. Net farm income
also includes the value of the
change in farm inventories, which
is the difference between the value
of farm inventories at the beginning
and end of the year. By this measure, the USDA projects real farm
income to be $46.2 billion in 1996,
more than 43 percent above that
registered in 1995, and more than 8
percent above its 1990-95 average.1
The USDA expects most of the
rise in real 1996 NFI to come from
a $6.3 billion increase in the value
of farm inventories and a $6.0 billion increase in crop receipts. A
further boost to farm income is
expected from the sales of livestock
and related products, which are predicted to increase $3.4 billion in
1996. Overall, this jump in farm
incomes reflects the effects of both
higher prices and increased production. On the price side, through
the first three quarters of 1996, the
USDA’s index of aggregate crop
prices was at its highest level since
the series began in 1975. Similarly,
the index of livestock prices in the
third quarter of 1996 was at its
highest in six years. On the output
side, total meat production through
the first 10 months of 1996 was up
a little more than 2.5 percent from
the same period in 1995, while the
fall harvest was generally bountiful,
produced bin-busting crops.
Although corresponding state
level data will not be available until
late 1997 at the earliest, unless a
state suffers from an unusual

12

Corn
As the figure shows, corn production in the District last year was a little more than a third larger than the
crop harvested in 1995. The two largest corn-producing states—Illinois
and Indiana—saw increases of 31 and
13 percent, respectively, while Missouri’s production more than doubled, and Arkansas’ harvest nearly
doubled. The uptick in production
occurred because harvested acreage
increased in all seven states and—
except for Arkansas and Tennessee—
yields were also higher in 1996 than
in 1995.
At 9.3 billion bushels, the national
1996 corn crop was the third largest
on record. This surpassed the 1995
crop by more than 25 percent, but
fell about 8 percent short of the 1994
record. Normally, a surge in production of this magnitude would push
corn prices down significantly. However, because the supply of U.S. corn
ended the 1995/96 marketing year at
its lowest level in more than two
decades, the increased production is
expected to keep 1996/97 ending
stocks (inventories) about 23 percent
below their 1990-95 average. As a
result, the average price of corn for
the 1996/97 marketing year is expected to be about $2.70 a bushel, which
is much higher than the $2.30 average that prevailed from 1990 to 1995,
but still well below the $3.24 average
for 1995/96.

Regional Economist
January 1997

Cotton
Four states in the Eighth District—
Arkansas, Mississippi, Missouri and
Tennessee—accounted for onequarter of the U.S. cotton crop last
year, which, at an estimated 18.6
million bales, was the third largest
on record. Despite the fact that nearly 11 percent fewer acres were harvested in Arkansas last year and 27.5
percent fewer were harvested in
Mississippi, the four-state production
total was still 2.3 percent larger than
in 1995. A large jump in cotton
yields is credited for the increase,
with the average four-state yield
more than 25 percent above the
1995 average. In fact, the 1996 U.S.
cotton crop was the fourth highestyielding on record. Strong domestic
demand by textile producers is
expected to keep cotton prices in
the 1996/97 marketing year about
7.5 cents a pound higher than the
64.5-cent average from 1990-96.
Rice
U.S. rice production is heavily
influenced by Arkansas, which regularly ranks as the nation’s largest
producer, and, to a lesser extent,
Mississippi. Combined, the states
account for almost half of U.S. production; adding in Missouri’s crop
pushes the District share to 52.5 percent. Last year’s production in the
Eighth District was down 3.4 percent
from 1995. Accordingly, the U.S.
rice crop increased just 0.1 percent
from 1995.
Although Arkansas farmers harvested 7.5 percent fewer acres, their
rice crop last year was up 0.2 percent
from 1995, as yields surpassed the
all-time record set in 1994. In Mississippi, the number of harvested
acres dropped by almost a quarter,
and, although yields rose by more
than 9 percent, total production fell
by slightly more than 17 percent.
Missouri’s rice crop dropped by a
little more than 11.5 percent, with
both yields and harvested acres
below those seen in 1995. The drop
in District rice production stemmed
from fewer acres being planted in the
spring, as many farmers—particularly
in Mississippi—planted corn instead
to take advantage of the high prices
that prevailed at the time.
With 1996 U.S. rice production
little changed from 1995, and domestic use in the current (1996/97) marketing year expected to be only
modestly above the five-year average,
ending rice stocks in 1996/97 are projected to fall to a near all-time low of
25.6 million hundredweight.4 As a
result, the USDA projects rice prices
to average 92.5 cents a pound in the
current marketing year, up a little

more than a penny a pound from the
year before, and the highest average
price received by farmers since
1980/81.
ENDNOTES

Soybeans
The 1996 District soybean crop
was a little more than 12 percent
larger than the 1995 one. In Illinois
and Indiana, the two largest-producing states of the seven, last year’s crop
was up more than 6 percent. By contrast, in Missouri and Arkansas, the
1996 soybean crop increased by 19
percent and 30.3 percent, respectively.
Except for Missouri and Tennessee,
1996 harvested acres in the District
exceeded those from 1995, while
yields were generally little changed
from the previous year.
Estimated at 2.4 billion bushels,
the 1996 U.S. soybean crop was the
second largest on record, surpassed
only by the 2.5-billion bushel 1994
crop. Nevertheless, in the current

marketing year ending stocks—which
fell to a seven-year low in 1995/96—
are still expected to end up well below
the 1990/95 average. Thus, the USDA
projects that soybean prices in 1996/
97 will average about $6.50 a bushel,
down only modestly from the sevenyear high posted in the previous year,
but still well above the $5.92 average
from the 1990-96 period.
Overall, 1996 was a memorable
one for Eighth District farmers. With
crop inventories generally well below
their five-year average, it appears that
farm prices will stay at relatively high
levels this marketing year. Coupled
with the bumper harvests yielded by
many crops, real farm incomes in
1996 should greatly exceed those
logged during the previous year.
Kevin L. Kliesen is an economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Daniel R. Steiner
provided research assistance.

13

1

Forecasts of farm income for 1996
are preliminary estimates only.
USDA farm income forecasts are
originally expressed in currentdollar (nominal) terms. In this
article, they have been inflationadjusted using the gross domestic
product (GDP) price index. See
USDA (1996).

2

The seven-state area comprises
all of Arkansas and parts of
Illinois, Indiana, Kentucky,
Mississippi, Missouri and
Tennessee. See back cover.

3

Estimates of 1996 production,
yields, acres harvested, ending
stocks and average prices received
by farmers come from the USDA’s
Crop Production Report and the
World Agriculture Supply and
Demand Estimates, both of which
were released in November of
1996. Analysis of corn, cotton,
rice and soybeans typically refers
to marketing years rather than calendar years. Marketing years for

corn and soybeans begin on Sept.
1 and end on Aug. 31 of the subsequent year. The marketing year
for cotton and rice runs from Aug.
1 to July 31. Forecasted prices for
1996/97 refer to the USDA’s midpoint estimate of marketing year
average price.
4

A hundredweight is a unit of
measurement for rice consisting
of 100 pounds.

REFERENCES
United States Department of
Agriculture. Crop Production,
National Agricultural Statistics
Service, November 12, 1996.
United States Department of
Agriculture. World Agriculture
Supply and Demand Estimates,
World Agricultural Outlook Board,
November 12, 1996.

Pieces
Eight

News bulletins from
the Eighth Federal
Reserve District

Open-Door Policy

sibilities in formulating
monetary policy, providing
financial services, and
supervising and regulating
financial institutions. Visitors are also privy to upclose views of the Bank’s
Protection and Cash departments, including the vault.
The Bank’s core tour
program will continue to
operate as usual, offering
tours to groups of 10 to 42
persons, high school age
and older, at 9:30 a.m. and
1:30 p.m., Monday through
Friday. For more information on either type of tour,
contact Tammy Stutes at
(314) 444-8560.

For years, the St. Louis
Fed has given tours of
its facility to educational
and employee groups
interested in obtaining a
first-hand view of one of
the country’s 12 Reserve
Banks. Starting in 1997,
the tour program has
expanded to accommodate families, vacationers
and other “non-group”
visitors, too.
“Walk-in” tours are
now available at 11 a.m.
on Fridays, starting in the
Bank’s main lobby, which
is at 411 Locust St. The
45-minute presentation
outlines the Fed’s respon-

NET Sports New Look in ’97

G

ood news for data junkies: National
Economic Trends, the St. Louis Fed

publication that provides a comprehensive

wide data, it now concentrates on graphical
presentation of the data.

and can be ordered by calling (314) 444-

The changes, says Fed economist and pub-

8808. NET and the underlying data are also

lication editor Joe Ritter, should make the data

available electronically through the St. Louis
Fed’s home page at www.stls.frb.org.

monthly briefing on the state of the U. S.

more digestible and ease comparisons across

economy, has been redesigned to include

time and between series. The publication also

even more data and better comparisons.

now includes greater cover-

While the publication still reports, rather
than analyzes, monthly and quarterly nation-

Single-copy subscriptions to NET are free

age of asset markets and

Economical Education

international trade.

District State Colleges Cost Less

Banking Data at Your Fingertips

District State

Just about anything you’d ever want to know about
a U.S. bank or thrift is now available online through
the FDIC’s new “Institution Directory System.”
The system contains financial and demographic
information on more than 12,000 banks and thrifts.
Quarterly financial statistics available on the site
include: earnings, deposit and loan data, and loan
quality measures like charge-offs. The financial data
are available for the last three years, enabling a user
to look at a bank’s financial performance relative to
previous years.
The system can be found by clicking on “Data
Bank” and then “Institution Directory” on the FDIC’s
home page (www.fdic.gov).

Illinois
Indiana
Missouri
Kentucky
Mississippi
Tennessee
Arkansas

14

Rank Among
50 States

1996 State
College Costs1

16
18
24
40
42
44
48

$7,829
7,392
6,750
5,455
5,425
5,372
5,064

National Average
1

$7,013

Average undergraduate tuition and fees and room
and board at public colleges and universities

SOURCE: U.S. Department of Education

Regional Economist
January 1997

District
Data

Selected economic indicators of banking,
agricultural and business conditions in
the Eighth Federal Reserve District

Commercial Bank Performance Ratios
U.S., District and State
All
U.S.

U.S.
District
<$15B 1

AR

IL

IN

KY

MS

MO

TN

Return on Average
Assets (Annualized)
3rd quarter 1996

1.24%

1.33%

1.31%

1.35%

1.03%

1.29%

1.26%

1.50%

1.32%

1.45%

2nd quarter 1996

1.21

1.33

1.29

1.31

1.02

1.30

1.19

1.50

1.34

1.40

3rd quarter 1995

1.21

1.34

1.30

1.28

1.17

1.28

1.22

1.46

1.31

1.45

Return on Average
Equity (Annualized)
3rd quarter 1996

15.25% 14.68% 14.81% 14.11% 10.22% 14.23% 14.37% 15.64% 15.90%

17.34%

2nd quarter 1996

14.99

14.76

14.58

13.78

10.05

14.25

13.58

15.72

16.09

16.89

3rd quarter 1995

15.22

15.28

14.87

13.75

11.85

13.90

14.05

15.98

16.03

17.83

Net Interest Margin
(Annualized)
3rd quarter 1996

4.38%

4.81%

4.39%

4.51%

4.23%

4.41%

4.53%

4.97%

4.15%

4.41%

2nd quarter 1996

4.27

4.77

4.33

4.43

4.22

4.37

4.35

4.93

4.15

4.36

4.23

4.81

4.33

4.30

4.46

4.58

4.25

5.09

4.18

4.23

3rd quarter 1996

1.10%

1.11%

0.78%

0.81%

1.15%

0.71%

0.74%

0.73%

0.72%

0.77%

2nd quarter 1996

1.12

1.10

0.81

0.80

1.09

0.69

0.87

0.74

0.78

0.72

3rd quarter 1995

1.23

1.10

0.71

0.68

1.01

0.56

0.82

0.64

0.61

0.66

3rd quarter 1996

0.57%

0.71%

0.31%

0.20%

0.39%

0.23%

0.39%

0.29%

0.27%

0.40%

2nd quarter 1996

0.57

0.70

0.31

0.19

0.34

0.20

0.41

0.28

0.29

0.36

3rd quarter 1995

0.45

0.53

0.21

0.13

0.39

0.15

0.29

0.23

0.12

0.25

3rd quarter 1996

1.96%

1.84%

1.51%

1.34%

1.56%

1.35%

1.51%

1.54%

1.62%

1.50%

2nd quarter 1996

1.99

1.89

1.53

1.34

1.62

1.36

1.53

1.58

1.63

1.49

3rd quarter 1995

2.07

1.91

1.56

1.34

1.54

1.39

1.57

1.62

1.70

1.55

3rd quarter 1995
Nonperforming Loans

2

÷ Total Loans

Net Loan Losses ÷
Average Total Loans
(Annualized)

Loan Loss Reserve ÷
Total Loans

NOTE: Data include only that por tion of the state within Eighth District boundaries.
1

U.S. banks with average assets of less than $15 billion are shown separately to make comparisons with District banks more
meaningful, as there are no District banks with average assets greater than $15 billion.

2

Includes loans 90 days or more past due and nonaccrual loans

SOURCE: FFIEC Reports of Condition and Income for Insured Commercial Banks

15

Commercial Bank Performance Ratios
by Asset Size

3rd Quarter 1996
Earnings

Asset Quality

Return on Average Assets

Net Loan Loss Ratio

Percent

Percent

Annualized

Nonperforming Loan Ratio

Percent

Percent

Percent

Annualized

3

2

Loan Loss Reserve Ratio

3

Annualized

Percent

D = District

< $100 Million

$300 Million – $1 Billion

US = United States

$100 Million – $300 Million

$1 Billion – $15 Billion

NOTE: Asset quality ratios are calculated as a percent of total loans.
1

Annualized

Return on Average Equity

Net Interest Margin

2

1

Loan losses are adjusted for recoveries
Includes loans 90 days or more past due and nonaccrual loans
Interest income less interest expense as a percent of average earning assets

SOURCE: FFIEC Reports of Condition and Income for Insured Commercial Banks

16

Regional Economist
January 1997

Agricultural Bank Performance Ratios
U.S.
Return on average assets (annualized)
3rd quarter 1996
2nd quarter 1996
3rd quarter 1995
Return on average equity (annualized)
3rd quarter 1996
2nd quarter 1996
3rd quarter 1995
Net interest margin (annualized)
3rd quarter 1996
2nd quarter 1996
3rd quarter 1995
Ag loan losses ÷ average ag loans (annualized)
3rd quarter 1996
2nd quarter 1996
3rd quarter 1995
Ag nonperforming loans 1 ÷ total ag loans
3rd quarter 1996
2nd quarter 1996
3rd quarter 1995

AR

IL

IN

KY

MS

MO

TN

1.30%
1.27
1.28

1.44%
1.40
1.30

1.25%
1.24
1.28

1.31%
1.32
1.26

1.49%
1.47
1.49

1.66%
1.63
1.71

1.33%
1.31
1.28

1.40%
1.40
1.22

12.67%
12.38
12.37

13.34%
12.99
12.38

11.43%
11.34
11.76

14.08%
13.61
12.78

14.37%
14.24
14.72

18.06%
17.79
19.11

12.90%
12.78
12.50

13.27%
13.22
12.79

4.54%
4.48
4.59

4.40%
4.39
4.36

4.14%
4.09
4.26

4.55%
4.55
4.70

4.62%
4.58
4.67

5.32%
5.27
5.50

4.52%
4.47
4.42

4.55%
4.52
4.37

0.29%
0.28
0.17

0.07%
0.06
-0.01

0.14%
0.19
-0.01

0.12%
-0.15
0.07

0.24%
0.18
0.19

0.79%
1.37
0.26

0.32%
0.30
-0.04

0.23%
0.29
0.08

1.63%
1.92
1.29

0.54%
0.74
0.29

1.09%
0.97
1.26

2.22%
1.99
0.29

1.26%
2.01
1.36

1.87%
3.10
0.88

0.85%
1.25
1.00

0.04%
0.44
0.35

NOTE: Agricultural banks are defined as those banks with a greater than average share of agricultural loans to total loans.
Data include only that portion of the state within Eighth District boundaries.
1
Includes loans 90 days or more past due and nonaccrual loans
SOURCE: FFIEC Reports of Condition and Income for Insured Commercial Banks

U.S. Agricultural Exports by Commodity

U.S. Crop and Livestock
Prices

Dollar amounts in billions

Commodity

Jul

Aug

Sep

Livestock & products

.83

.90

.82

Year-to-date
10.95%

Change from year ago
7.0%

Corn

.70

.52

.44

8.37

26.0

Cotton

.73

1.00

.07

3.03

-13.0

Rice

.07

.72

.09

1.00

-4.0

Soybeans

.37

.43

.35

6.31

20.0

Tobacco

.05

.09

.09

1.39

5.0

Wheat

.62

.79

.66

6.88

39.0

TOTAL

4.46

4.63

4.38

59.76

10.0

Indexes of Food and Agricultural Prices
Growth 1

Level
Prices received by U.S. farmers 2
Prices received by District farmers3
Arkansas
Illinois
Indiana
Missouri
Tennessee
Prices paid by U.S. farmers
Production items
Other items
Consumer food prices
Consumer nonfood prices

III/96

II/96

III/95

II/96-III/96 III/95-III/96

117

112

103

16.3%

13.6%

143
144
145
119
143

136
136
146
110
138

126
104
106
102
131

22.2
25.8
-1.8
38.6
13.1

13.8
38.6
36.4
16.7
8.9

116
115
154
158

115
115
152
157

109
110
149
154

4.7
1.2
5.6
1.6

6.4
4.5
3.6
2.8

NOTE: Data not seasonally adjusted except for consumer food prices and nonfood prices.
1 Compounded annual rates of change are computed from unrounded data.
2 Index of prices received for all farm products and prices paid (1990-92=100)
3 Indexes for Kentucky and Mississippi are unavailable.

17

Selected U.S. and State Business Indicators
Compounded Annual Rates of Change in
Nonagricultural Employment

United States
III/1996 II/1996 III/1995

Labor force
134,135 133,647 132,380
(in thousands)
Total nonagricultural
employment
119,947 119,264 117,441
(in thousands)
5.2%
5.4%
5.6%
Unemployment rate
II/1996

I/1996 II/1995

Real personal income*
(in billions)
$4,082.4 $4,054.9 $3,980.4

Arkansas
III/1996 II/1996 III/1995

Labor force
1,245.9
(in thousands)
Total nonagricultural
employment
1,088.8
(in thousands)
5.3%
Unemployment rate

1,082.4 1,072.4
4.8%
5.0%

II/1996

I/1996 II/1995

Real personal income*
(in billions)
$30.2

1,234.0 1,225.7

$29.8

$29.4

Illinois
III/1996 II/1996 III/1995

Labor force
6,155.2
(in thousands)
Total nonagricultural
employment
5,706.1
(in thousands)
5.4%
Unemployment rate
II/1996

Real personal income*
(in billions)
$199.2

6,149.3 6,086.4
5,687.6 5,617.6
5.2%
5.2%
I/1996 II/1995

$198.5

$194.6

Indiana
III/1996 II/1996 III/1995

Labor force
3,093.1
(in thousands)
Total nonagricultural
employment
2,788.9
(in thousands)
4.2%
Unemployment rate
II/1996

Real personal income*
(in billions)
$82.5

3,096.3 3,129.1
2,799.1 2,772.2
4.2%
4.6%
I/1996 II/1995

$82.0

$81.4

18

Regional Economist
January 1997

Kentucky
III/1996 II/1996 III/1995

Labor force
1,861.7
(in thousands)
Total nonagricultural
employment
1,672.6
(in thousands)
4.7%
Unemployment rate
II/1996

Real personal income*
(in billions)
$48.9

1,829.0 1,860.5
1,671.1 1,643.4
5.2%
5.5%
I/1996 II/1995

$48.3

$47.6

Mississippi
III/1996 II/1996 III/1995

Labor force
1,263.5
(in thousands)
Total nonagricultural
employment
1,075.8
(in thousands)
5.8%
Unemployment rate

1,080.9 1,078.5
6.1%
6.4%

II/1996

I/1996 II/1995

Real personal income*
(in billions)
$29.9

1,266.4 1,262.6

$29.8

$29.3

Missouri
III/1996 II/1996 III/1995

Labor force
2,851.5
(in thousands)
Total nonagricultural
employment
2,559.3
(in thousands)
4.1%
Unemployment rate

2,559.2 2,524.6
4.3%
4.9%

II/1996

I/1996 II/1995

Real personal income*
(in billions)
$77.3

2,847.0 2,850.3

$77.1

$75.9

Tennessee
III/1996 II/1996 III/1995

Labor force
2,756.2
(in thousands)
Total nonagricultural
employment
2,564.2
(in thousands)
4.6%
Unemployment rate

2,554.1 2,507.2
4.8%
5.5%

II/1996

I/1996 II/1995

Real personal income*
$73.1
(in billions)
Total
Manufacturing

2,747.8 2,717.6

$72.9

$72.1

Construction

Government
General Services

Finance, Insurance
and Real Estate

Transportation, Communication
and Public Utilities
Wholesale/Retail Trade

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted. The nonagricultural employment data reflect the 1995 benchmark revision.
* Annual rate. Data deflated by CPI, 1982-84=100.

19