View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

ST. LOUIS

2018:Q1 | VOL. 26 | NO. 1

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK

Insights on economic issues in today’s headlines

Why Is Inflation So Low?
The “sharing” economy and
aging population are among
the possible reasons.
President Bullard

Golden Years?

Industry Profile

Comparing Living
Standards across
U.S. MSAs

Many U.S. Households
Report No Retirement
Savings

Health Care Still
Expanding Jobs
in U.S., District

PAGE 3

PAGE 12

PAGE 16

IN THIS ISSUE

2018:Q1 | VOL. 26, NO. 1
The Regional Economist is published
quarterly by the Research and
Public Affairs divisions of the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis. It addresses
the national, international and
regional economic issues of the day,
particularly as they apply to states in
the Eighth Federal Reserve District.
Views expressed are not necessarily
those of the St. Louis Fed or of the
Federal Reserve System.
Director of Research
Christopher J. Waller
Senior Policy Adviser
Cletus C. Coughlin
Deputy Director of Research
David C. Wheelock
Director of Public Affairs
Karen Branding
Editor
Subhayu Bandyopadhyay
Managing Editor
Gregory Cancelada
Art Director
Joni Williams
Please direct your comments
to Subhayu Bandyopadhyay
at 314-444-7425 or by email at
subhayu.bandyopadhyay@stls.
frb.org. You can also write to him
at the address below. Submission
of a letter to the editor gives us
the right to post it to our website
and/or publish it in the Regional
Economist unless the writer states
otherwise. We reserve the right to
edit letters for clarity and length.
To subscribe to the RE, go to
www.stlouisfed.org/subscribe/
regional-economist.
Regional Economist
Public Affairs Office
P.O. Box 442
St. Louis, MO 63166-0442

4

ST. LOUIS

2018:Q1 | VOL. 26 | NO. 1

REGIONAL
ECONOMIST

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK

Insights on economic issues in today’s headlines

Why Is Inflation So Low?

The “sharing” economy, aging population
and monetary policy are among the possible reasons that low inflation persists in
the U.S. and other developed countries.

Why Is Inflation So Low?
The “sharing” economy and
aging population are among
the possible reasons.
President Bullard

Golden Years?

Industry Profile

Comparing Living
Standards across
U.S. MSAs

Many U.S. Households
Report No Retirement
Savings

Health Care Still
Expanding Jobs
in U.S., District

PAGE 3

PAGE 12

PAGE 16

PRESIDENT’S MESSAGE ............................................................................................................. 3

Measuring Labor Share in Developing Countries
Determining the share of GDP going to workers can be tricky. ...............................10
Many Americans Still Lack Retirement Savings
Recent data show that 35 percent of households don’t
participate in a retirement plan. ...........................................................................................12
The Relationship between Oil and Equities at the Zero Lower Bound
The correlation between oil and equities increased sharply after the
Fed’s policy rate hit zero................................................................................................. 14
INDUSTRY PROFILE

Health Care Remains Important Job Engine in Eighth District
Since 2007, the sector has generated about half of the District’s new jobs. .............. 16
DISTRICT OVERVIEW

Income and Living Standards within the Eighth District
Adjusting income to account for local cost of living gives a
better picture of living standards. ................................................................................. 19
NATIONAL OVERVIEW

U.S. Economy Continues to Strengthen
Tax cuts and higher government spending are expected to help
the economy in 2018. ..................................................................................................... 22
ECONOMY AT A GLANCE................................................................................................ 23

COVER IMAGES:
LEFT: ©THINKSTOCK/ISTOCK/ ISFENDIYARA
RIGHT: ©THINKSTOCK/ISTOCK/ KOJI_ISHII

ONLINE EXTRA

Read more at www.stlouisfed.org/publications/re.

Market Concentration and Its Impact on Community Banks

Increased concentration can make it harder for community banks to acquire
within their market.

PRESIDENT’S MESSAGE

Comparing Living Standards
across U.S. Metro Areas:
Which Ones Fared Well?
bout 90 percent of U.S. gross domestic product (GDP) is produced in
metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs).
Furthermore, about 86 percent of the U.S.
population lived in the 381 MSAs in 2015,1
and about 56 percent of the population
lived in the 53 largest MSAs (those with
at least 1 million people).
I am keenly interested in how incomes
and prices differ throughout the U.S. To
gain a better understanding of how the
individual MSAs are performing, I recently
examined which ones have relatively high
and low standards of living, based on a
measure of per capita income.2 From a
macroeconomic point of view, we would
want all MSAs to be performing at a high
level so that overall GDP and standard of
living can be as high as possible.
The approach I used to compare MSAs
is similar to the methodology used to compare standards of living across countries.
I focused on 2015, the most recent year for
which we have complete data.
Comparisons across MSAs are usually
based on real per capita variables that
are adjusted by a nationwide price index.
However, the usual comparisons can be
misleading because they do not factor in
the large differences in cost of living across
the country. Differences in housing costs,
in particular, can be substantial.
Therefore, adjusting for price differences
across MSAs is essential for generating
meaningful comparisons of living standards. My colleagues at the St. Louis Fed
have done just that.3 My analysis draws on
their research.
The Bureau of Economic Analysis
recently released data that measure the
differences in price levels across MSAs for
a given year. These Regional Price Parities (RPPs) are expressed as a percentage
of the national price level. For 2015, these
ranged from 79.7 percent for Beckley,
W.Va., to 124.5 percent for Honolulu (with
the national level being 100 percent). The
most expensive MSAs tend to be relatively

larger and located on either coast, and the
least expensive MSAs tend to be relatively
smaller and located in the interior.
To compare MSAs, the measure of
income that I used is real (i.e., inflationadjusted) per capita personal income,
which I adjusted by the appropriate RPP.
The results suggest that some MSAs have
a much higher standard of living while
others have a much lower standard of
living than the nation as a whole. St. Louis,
for instance, did extremely well. Its RPPadjusted real per capita personal income
was about 13 percent higher than the
national average.
Among all MSAs, St. Louis ranked
No. 20, putting it in the top 6 percent. Said
another way, St. Louis’ standard of living
was higher than about 94 percent of MSAs
in the country.
It is also helpful to look at living standards across the 53 largest MSAs. The top
10 large MSAs with the highest standard
of living include three on the West Coast
(San Jose, San Francisco and Seattle), three
on the East Coast (Boston, Hartford and
Washington) and four in the middle of the
country (St. Louis, Nashville, Minneapolis
and Houston). St. Louis ranked No. 7 in
this group.
Some MSAs among the top 10 had a high
cost of living and others had a low cost of
living. Only St. Louis and Nashville had
a lower cost of living than the national
average. This suggests that these two MSAs
have a cost advantage over their other competitors in the top 10. In some cases, the
cost differential was 30 percentage points
or more.
While this analysis gives an idea of how
MSAs are performing on average, the per
capita concept does not account for the
income distribution within an MSA. For
this, I used data from other research.4 The
main finding is that income inequality
tended to be higher in larger MSAs. In
addition, among the top 10 large MSAs in
terms of living standards, some had very

high income inequality (such as San Jose,
San Francisco and Boston). Others had
income inequality that was closer to the
average (such as St. Louis, Nashville and
Minneapolis).
The bottom line is that, among the top
10 large MSAs, St. Louis and Nashville
were the only ones that could simultaneously claim a higher-than-average standard
of living, a lower-than-average cost of living and moderate income inequality.
The results of this analysis demonstrate
the importance of adjusting for price differences across regions when comparing
living standards. The facts uncovered here
may provide the basis for future research
on why some MSAs are more successful
than others.

James Bullard, President and CEO
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

ENDNOTES
1

2

3

4

Because of data availability in earlier years, I did
not include Enid, Okla., which was classified as
an MSA in 2015.
Bullard, James. “Living Standards across U.S.
Metropolitan Statistical Areas,” presentation
delivered Oct. 6, 2017.
Coughlin, Cletus C.; Gascon, Charles S.; and
Kliesen, Kevin L. “Living Standards in St. Louis
and the Eighth Federal Reserve District: Let’s
Get Real,” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis
Review, Fourth Quarter 2017, Vol. 99, No. 4,
pp. 377-94.
Sommeiller, Estelle; Price, Mark; and Wazeter,
Ellis. “Income Inequality in the U.S. by State,
Metropolitan Area, and County,” Economic
Policy Institute Report, June 16, 2016.

REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 3

Why Is Inflation So Low?
The sharing economy, aging population and
monetary policy are among the possible reasons
By Hee Sung Kim and Juan M. Sánchez

KEY TAKEAWAYS
• If low inflation persists, this would raise
questions about the central bank’s
commitment to its inflation target and
increase the risk of deflation.
• The U.S. isn’t the only country facing this
issue. Other developed countries are
dealing with low inflation.
• Technological and demographic changes
may be likely reasons, although some
hypotheses link low inflation to monetary
policy.

T

TOP IMAGE: ©THINKSTOCK/ISTOCK/ ISFENDIYARA

4 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

BOTTOM IMAGE: ©THINKSTOCK/ISTOCK/ KOJI_ISHII

he U.S. inflation rate has been below
the Fed’s 2 percent inflation target
since 2012. In this article, we revisit the
merits of some of the most common
explanations for the current low inflation rate.
While a moderate inflation rate can
be beneficial for the economy, there are
several reasons to be concerned about
very low inflation. First, an inflation rate
lower than the 2 percent target for a long
period of time may signal that the monetary authority does not have inflation
under control or that its commitment
to the target is not that strong. Second,
very low inflation is typically associated
with an increased probability of falling
into deflation, in which prices and wages
are declining on average. Deflation, in
turn, is a phenomenon associated with
weak economic conditions.
The prime example of the aforementioned concerns is Japan. Since the late
1990s, Japan has experienced a long
period of low inflation that is associated

Figure 1

Recent Evolution of Various Inflation Rates
Percent Change from a Year Ago

with a secular stagnation. In past years,
low inflation in the U.S. triggered concern that the country may be heading to
a Japanese-style low inflation trap.1
Because inflation cannot be measured
by an increase in the price of one product
or service, or even several products or
services, there are many different indexes
to measure inflation, each index signaling different information about inflation.
The Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC), the Fed’s main monetary
policymaking body, prefers to look at
personal consumption expenditures
(PCE) because, among other reasons, the
PCE price index covers a wide range of
household spending.
Figure 1 displays the recent evolution
of the core PCE and core consumer price
indexes (CPI) for the U.S. since the 1960s.
Both indexes are seasonally adjusted and
are computed as a year-over-year percentage change. It is also important to note that
these indexes are “core” indexes, which
exclude food and energy items that fluctuate dramatically. Looking at core indexes,
rather than focusing on a short episode
of spikes in inflation, helps to observe
the inflation trend.2 The PCE inflation in
November 2017 was 1.5 percent, well below
the inflation target of 2 percent.
Low inflation not only is a phenomenon
observed in the United States, but also has
been a concern around the world. Figure 1
includes the average core CPI for countries in the Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD).
While the average inflation rate in OECD
countries has historically been higher
than the inflation rate in the U.S., inflation
in these two areas has been sluggish in
recent years, with CPI in OECD countries hitting 1.9 percent in October 2017
and CPI in the U.S. hitting 1.7 percent in
November 2017.
Finally, Figure 1 also includes inflation expectations from the University
of Michigan’s Surveys of Consumers.
It shows that expectations have also
been on a declining trend since 2011 but
remain above the target, at 2.5 percent in
November 2017.

15

10

5

0
1960

1970

1980

1990
Year

2000

2010

2020

Core personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index—U.S.
Core consumer price index (CPI)—U.S.
Core CPI—OECD
U.S. inflation expectations from the University of Michigan

SOURCES: U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD), and University of Michigan’s Surveys of Consumers.
NOTES: Core indexes exclude energy and food prices. The red line represents a 2 percent inflation rate, a
target that the Federal Reserve formally set in 2012.

Technological Progress
Alan Greenspan, then chairman of
the Federal Reserve, stated in testimony
before the U.S. Congress in 2005: “The
past decade of low inflation and solid
economic growth in the United States
and in many other countries around the
world … is attributable to the remarkable
confluence of innovations that spawned
new computer, telecommunication, and
networking technologies, which, especially in the United States, have elevated
the growth of productivity, suppressed
unit labor costs, and helped to contain
inflationary pressures.”
His idea, echoing the voices of many
other economists, is that technological advancement has brought down the
price of goods that use new technologies
intensively. Indeed, innovation of smart
electronic gadgets like smartphones has
reduced the demand for various other
gadgets, exemplified by the fact that the
smartphones today can provide better
cameras than professional equipment a

ABOUT THE AUTHORS
Juan M. Sánchez is a research officer and economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis. He has conducted research on several topics in macroeconomics involving financial
decisions by firms, households and countries. He has been at the St. Louis Fed since 2010.
Read more about the author and his research at https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/sanchez.
Hee Sung Kim is a senior research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 5

Figure 2

Core CPI (Percent Change from a Year Ago)

Relationship between Nonfarm Labor Productivity and Inflation
15
1980

10

1981

1979
1974

1975

1982
1969

5

1978
19701977

1989
1987
1993
1995
1994
2006
2000
2016
2012
2015
20141960
20142013

0
–2

1990
1991 1984
1988
1967
1996
2007 1997
1958
2005

1976
1968 1971
1986
1973
1972
2001 2000
1966
1998
2009 19591999
19642004
1965
1963 2003
1960
2010

0
2
Labor Productivity (Percent Change from a Year Ago)

1983
1992
2002
1962

4

SOURCE: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics.
NOTES: Data points are represented by their year, and the core consumer price index (CPI) excludes
energy and food prices. The orange line is the regression line, which suggests periods of higher labor
productivity are associated with lower inflation.

Figure 3
Averaged Inflation, Percent (2010-2016)

Relationship between Old Age Dependency Ratio and Inflation
30
Sudan
Syria
Malawi

20

Iran
Suriname
Ukraine

10
United States
0

Japan
0

10

20

30

40

Average Old Age Dependency Ratio (Percent)

SOURCE: World Bank.
NOTE: The orange line is the regression line, which suggests that aging may be deflationary.

decade ago. According to the U.S. Bureau
of Labor Statistics, prices of general
tuition and medical care have risen
29 percent and 25 percent, respectively,
while prices of television and photographic equipment have decreased
73 percent and 24 percent, respectively,
since 2010.
Arguably, technological advancement
has also increased labor productivity,
therefore reducing unit labor cost. With
the help of easily accessible information,
improved communication, and useful
software/applications, it is not too hard
to imagine that the recent advances in
6 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

technology have contributed to improved
productivity.
Figure 2 reports the correlation
between labor productivity in nonfarm
business and core CPI in the United
States. The downward trend illustrates
that periods with higher labor productivity are associated with lower inflation.
According to the estimated relationship,
an increase in labor productivity of
3 percentage points is associated with a
reduction in inflation by approximately
2 percentage points.
Economists Ian Dew-Becker and Robert J. Gordon have argued that indeed the
slowdown in productivity growth had
major effects in boosting inflation during
1965-1979, while a hike in productivity growth between 1995 and 2005 had
played a role in low inflation.
But why would inflation be low now if
productivity has not grown faster than
before? The most recent wave of technological progress that has drawn attention among economists is the “sharing
economy.”
While there is no consensus on the
exact definition of the term, the sharing economy usually refers to the idea
of a crowd-based market that allows
the exchange of privately owned goods
and services. Airbnb and Uber are
prime examples of the sharing economy.
Although it is not easy to see this in the
official productivity statistics, it is clear
that the rise of the sharing economy has
improved productivity by allowing for
the utilization of otherwise idle goods
and services, which then has led to the
reduction in prices.
For example, economists Georgios
Zervas, Davide Proserpio and John Byers
studied the impact of the introduction
of Airbnb into the Texas market. They
reported that Airbnb’s entry into the
hospitality market has had a quantifiable negative impact on local hotel room
prices, with lower-end hotels and hotels
not catering to business travelers being
most vulnerable to the increased competition from Airbnb. They have estimated
that a 10 percent increase of Airbnb
rooms is associated with a 0.39 percent
decrease in hotel room revenue, whereas
a 10 percent increase in the supply of
hotel rooms has resulted in a 1.6 percent
reduction in hotel room revenue; this
implies that the effects of introducing

Airbnb are about one-fourth that of creating new hotel rooms. With a massive
surge of Airbnb rooms opening recently,
this impact is non-negligible.
It is incontrovertible that the population of the world’s developed economies
is living a longer life, and the age demographic is shifting upward. How does
this shift in population demographic
affect inflation? Figure 3 reports crosscountry correlation between average
inflation and the average old age dependency ratio between 2010 and 2016.3 Old
age dependency ratio is calculated as the
ratio of population aged 65 and above to
the population aged 15 to 64.
The negative correlation suggests that
aging may be deflationary. Notice that in
Figure 3, Japan has the highest old age
dependency ratio and one of the lowest
inflation rates. Indeed, there is a string
of literature that studies how the aging
Japanese labor force is associated with
low inflation.
A study by economists Shigeru Fujita
and Ippei Fujiwara explores a causal link
between aging of the labor force and
deflationary pressure in Japan. Their
argument is that in an economy where
skills are very specific to each individual
firm, a growing share of old workers who
lose their jobs also lose their firm-specific skills and flow into entry-level jobs.
This inflow of old workers to entry-level
jobs negatively impacts young workers’
wages, creating deflationary pressure in
the long run.
While the effect of longevity is clear,
there is certain disagreement about
the effect of changes in the birth rate.
On the one hand, economists Mitsuru
Katagiri, Hideki Konishi and Kozo Ueda
argue that the effect of aging depends on
its causes. Their model concludes that
aging is deflationary when caused by an
increase in longevity but inflationary
when caused by a decline in the birth
rate. On the other hand, economist
Pawel Gajewski extends the analysis
to OECD countries and argues that a
decline in the birth rate is also deflationary in the data.4
How does this Japanese experience
translate to the U.S.? We have measured
the effects of the young age dependency
ratio (the ratio of the population aged 0-14

©THINKSTOCK/ISTOCK/WISSANU01

Demographic Transitions

Some economists argue that globalization of trade and services has kept prices under control.
However, others say globalization has a limited influence on a country’s inflation rate.

to the population aged 15-64) and the old
age dependency ratio on U.S. inflation
using the coefficients obtained by Gajewski. Between 1960 and 2016, the old age
dependency ratio increased by about 50 percent, and the young age dependency ratio
decreased by about 43 percent in the U.S.
Focusing on the post-crisis period from
2010 to 2016 that experienced persistent
low inflation, both decreasing young age
dependency and increasing old age dependency are associated with a 0.1 percentage
point decrease in inflation annually. Since
inflation was lower than the target by 0.4
percentage points on average during that
period, about 25 percent of the difference
could be accounted for by the changes in
demographics since 2010.

Indeed, there is a string
of literature that studies
how the aging Japanese
labor force is associated
with low inflation.

Globalization
As noted above, low inflation is not
uniquely observed in the United States.
While some countries, notably Argentina
and Venezuela, have suffered from very
high inflation in recent years, many of
the developed countries are experiencing
persistent low inflation. Some economists
have argued that widespread low inflation
may be due to globalization. Particularly,
economists Claudio Borio and Andrew
Filardo argue that current inflation
models are too “country-centric,” failing
REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 7

Figure 4

Average Inflation (1955-1988)

Central Bank Independence and Inflation
Spain

8

New Zealand

Italy
Australia

6

UK

Denmark

France/Norway/Sweden
Japan
Belgium

4

2

1
Less Independent

Canada

US

Netherlands

Switzerland
Germany

2
3
Index of Central Bank Independence

4
More Independent

SOURCE: Alesina and Summers (1993).
NOTE: The orange line is the regression line, which suggests that countries with more independent central
banks are associated with low average inflation.

Figure 5

Meetings between the Federal Reserve Chair and the U.S. President

Number of Meetings

40
30
20
10
0
1953

1960

1967

1974

1981

1988

1995

2002

2009

2016

Year

SOURCES: Digital Presidential Library and Federal Reserve Archival System for Economic
Research (FRASER).
NOTE: The number of meetings at the White House includes official phone conversations. A decline in the
meetings suggests less political interference.

to acknowledge the growing role of global
factors on the inflation process. They
point out that the sensitivity of inflation
to domestic output gaps (the difference
between current output and potential
output) has been falling, while the importance of global output gaps has been
increasing.
The significance of globalization’s
impact on inflation is at least debatable,
however. The World Economic Outlook
report in 2006 from the International
Monetary Fund (IMF) describes that the
direct effect of globalization on inflation
through import prices has, in general,
been small in the industrial economies. In
addition, speeches by then-Federal Reserve
Chair Janet Yellen and former Federal
Reserve Vice Chairman Donald Kohn also
stressed that the impact of foreign factors
on U.S. prices is rather limited.
One of the factors that may explain this
is that the exchange rate in cheap-labor
countries would eventually appreciate
as real wages catch up to past gains in
productivity. Along the same lines, more
recent empirical papers that analyze
cross-country data seem to conclude that
globalization has a limited influence on a
country’s inflation. A study of 11 developed countries by economists Jane Ihrig,
Steven Kamin, Deborah Lindner and
Jaime Marquez produced no meaningful
evidence for the globalization hypothesis,
which asserts that the internationalization
of goods and financial markets has been
changing the determinants of national
macroeconomic outcomes such
as inflation.
Another study that observed 50 countries around the world also concluded
that while global economic fluctuations
affect the dynamic of domestic inflation, foreign output gaps are still not as
important as domestic output gaps, and
trade openness is still too small to justify
significant brakes in inflation dynamics.5
Inflation Targeting and
Central Bank Independence
What if inflation is simply very low
because monetary policy is too tight?
There are at least two reasons to believe
that this hypothesis may be relevant.
First, inflation targeting has become
widespread since its introduction in 1989
by New Zealand. Nine advanced economies and 21 emerging market economies

8 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

are now “inflation targeters.”6 This means
that a growing number of countries
are making inflation the primary goal
of monetary policy. Not surprisingly,
this results in lower rates of inflation.
Although inflation targeting does not
necessarily imply inflation that is too low,
the fact that inflation lower than the target is often considered better than inflation higher than the target may contribute
to an inflation rate that, on average, is
lower than the target.
The second reason is central bank
independence, which is closely related to
inflation targeting. The fact that central
banks can focus solely on reducing inflation depends crucially on their ability to
act independently. Indeed, economists
Alberto Alesina and Lawrence Summers have empirically shown a negative
relationship between inflation and central
bank independence by devising indexes
to measure the autonomy of the central
bank.7 This clear negative relationship
is shown in Figure 4. It suggests that
countries with more-independent central
banks are associated with low inflation.
Why is this relevant today? Because
the number of countries that are inflation
targeters has been increasing, and central
banks have become more independent.
In particular, the index of central bank
independence proposed by economist
Fernando Martin, which counts the number of meetings between the chair of the
Federal Reserve and the U.S. president,
shows a clear downward trend in the U.S.,
as shown in Figure 5.
Neo-Fisherism
Finally, some economists have argued
that the relationship between interest rates
and expected inflation proposed by Irving
Fisher implies that low policy rates for a
long period of time must imply low inflation.8 The Fisher relationship indicates that
the nominal interest rate can be approximated by the sum of the real interest rate
and the expected inflation rate. In the
past, this relationship has been interpreted
to mean that the real interest rate is the
independent variable. Thus, the expected
inflation rate has a unidirectional causal
relationship with the nominal interest rate,
that is, a higher expected inflation rate will
result in a rising nominal interest rate.
However, in an environment in which
the monetary authority keeps the relevant

nominal interest rate very close to zero
for a long period of time, this relationship
would simply imply that the expected
inflation rate is equal to the negative of
the real rate. Recall that under the Fisher
hypothesis, the real rate is independent
of monetary policy (it depends on factors
like long-term economic growth). Thus,
if the real rate is close to zero, it must
be that, under this hypothesis, expected
inflation is close to zero as well. The solution to low inflation in this context is to
increase the nominal interest rate.
Some evidence for this argument is
derived from Japan, where the nominal
interest rate has been close to zero since
the late 1990s, and the inflation rate shows
no sign of increasing.9
Conclusion
Overall, we find that there are several
reasons pushing inflation down, not just
in the U.S. but also in other developed
countries. The new sharing economy and
the demographic transition come up as
the most likely explanations. However,
it is hard to rule out that long periods of
near zero policy rates have implied that
only low expected inflation is compatible
with the current fundamentals of the
economy.
(This article was first published online Feb. 2.)

ENDNOTES
1
2

3

4
5
6
7
8
9

See Bullard, 2010.
However, some economists proposed that the FOMC
should focus more on headline inflation. See Bullard,
2011.
South Sudan and Venezuela are excluded from the
sample because both countries experienced a hyperinflation, in which averaged inflation was greater than
80 percent between 2010 and 2016.
See Canon, Kudlyak and Reed for more details.
See Bianchi and Civelli.
See presentation by Murray.
See Cukierman et al., among many others,
for more details.
See Williamson, 2016.
See Cochrane, and Williamson (forthcoming).

REFERENCES
Alesina, Alberto; and Summers, Lawrence H. Central
Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative Evidence. Journal of
Money, Credit and Banking, 1993, Vol. 25, No. 2,
pp. 151-62.
Bianchi, Francesco; and Civelli, Andrea. Globalization
and Inflation: Evidence from a Time-Varying VAR.
Review of Economic Dynamics, 2015, Vol. 18, No. 2,
pp. 406-33.
Borio, Claudio; and Filardo, Andrew. Globalization and
Inflation: New Cross-Country Evidence on the Global

Determinants of Domestic Inflation. BIS Working
Papers No. 227.
Bullard, James. Seven Faces of “The Peril.” Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 2010, Vol. 92,
No. 5, pp. 339-52.
Bullard, James. Measuring Inflation: The Core Is Rotten.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review, 2011,
Vol. 93, No. 4, pp. 223-33.
Canon, Marie E.; Kudlyak, Marianna; and Reed, Marisa.
Aging and the Economy: The Japanese Experience.
The Regional Economist, Vol. 23, No. 4, pp. 12-13.
Cochrane, John H. Do Higher Interest Rates Raise or
Lower Inflation? Unpublished manuscript, February
2016. See https://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/john.
cochrane/research/papers/fisher.pdf.
Cukierman, Alex; Webb, Steven B.; and Neyapti, Bilin.
Measuring the Independence of Central Banks and
Its Effect on Policy Outcomes. The World Bank Economic Review, 1992, Vol. 6, No. 3, pp. 353-98.
Dew-Becker, Ian; and Gordon, Robert J. Where Did the
Productivity Growth Go? Inflation Dynamics and the
Distribution of Income. NBER Working Paper 11842.
Fujita, Shigeru; and Fujiwara, Ippei. Aging and Declining Trends in the Real Interest Rate and Inflation:
Japanese Experience. Unpublished manuscript,
August 2015. See http://cepr.org/sites/default/files/
Fujiwara%20-%20FF-August2015.pdf.
Gajewski, Pawel. Is Ageing Deflationary? Some Evidence
from OECD Countries. Applied Economics Letters,
2015, Vol. 22, No. 11, pp. 916-19.
Greenspan, Alan. Economic Outlook. Nov. 3, 2005.
See www.federalreserve.gov/boarddocs/
testimony/2005/20051103/default.htm.
Helbling, Thomas; Jaumotte, Florence; and Sommer,
Martin. How Has Globalization Affected Inflation?
World Economic Outlook, April 2006, pp. 97–134.
Ihrig, Jane; Kamin, Steven B.; Lindner, Deborah; and Marquez, Jaime. Some Simple Tests of the Globalization
and Inflation Hypothesis. International Finance, 2010,
Vol. 13, No. 3, pp. 343-75.
Katagiri, Mitsuru; Konishi, Hideki; and Ueda, Kozo.
Aging and Deflation from a Fiscal Perspective. Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Working Paper No. 218.
November 2014.
Kohn, Donald L. The Effects of Globalization on Inflation
and Their Implications for Monetary Policy. June 16,
2006. See www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/
speech/kohn20060616a.htm.
Martin, Fernando M. Debt, Inflation and Central Bank
Independence. European Economic Review, 2015,
Vol. 79, pp. 129-50.
Murray, John. Inflation Targeting After 28 Years: What
Have We Learned? Jan. 16, 2017. See www.regjeringen.no/contentassets/adcde72c116c4804b50e8e44b851569e/1_murray.pdf
Williamson, Stephen. Neo-Fisherism: A Radical Idea,
or the Most Obvious Solution to the Low-Inflation
Problem? The Regional Economist, 2016, Vol. 24,
No. 3, pp. 5-9.
Williamson, Stephen. Inflation Control: Do Central Bankers Have It Right? Forthcoming in Federal Reserve
Bank of St. Louis Review.
Yellen, Janet. Monetary Policy in a Global Environment.
May 27, 2006. See www.frbsf.org/our-district/press/
presidents-speeches/yellen-speeches/2006/may/
monetary-policy-in-a-global-environment.
Zervas, Georgios; Proserpio, Davide; and Byers, John
W. The Rise of the Sharing Economy: Estimating the
Impact of Airbnb on the Hotel Industry. Journal of
Marketing Research, 2017, Vol. 54, No. 5, pp. 687-705.

REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 9

Measuring Labor Share
in Developing Countries
By Brian Reinbold and Paulina Restrepo-Echavarria
©THINKSTOCK/ISTOCK/DARIO GAONA

10 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

Argentina
Chile

Mexico
Brazil

Peru
Colombia

Hong Kong
South Korea

Taiwan
Japan

2010

0.2
2005

0.2

2000

0.3

1995

0.3

1990

0.4

1985

0.4

1980

0.5

1970

0.5

2010

0.6

2005

0.6

2000

0.7

1995

0.7

1985

0.8

1975

FRACTION OF LABOR INCOME OVER GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT

0.8

1990

ftentimes economists think of income
in terms of its factor components:
labor and capital. The labor share is the
fraction of labor income over gross domestic product (GDP), while the capital share
is similarly the fraction of capital income
over GDP. The labor share used to not draw
much attention from researchers because
it was long considered to be constant over
time. However, it is now well-documented
that the labor share in developed countries has, in fact, declined over the last few
decades, but evidence remains mixed for
developing countries.
A more complete understanding of the
labor share can allow economists to better
link the income at the macro-level (i.e.,
GDP) with the experience of individuals at
the household level.1 For example, does an
increase in GDP (national income) necessarily translate to higher income for all
households or only a few?
A declining labor share can lead to stagnant incomes and lackluster wage growth.
Because nominal wage growth signals future
inflation, declining wages can lead to low
inflation.2 Therefore, factoring in the labor
share can help guide monetary policy. Also,
a declining labor share is associated with
increased inequality3 because capital owners
are then receiving a greater share of income,
but the number of capital owners is typically
small relative to the general population.4

FRACTION OF LABOR INCOME OVER GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT

1980

O

Labor Share in East Asia

1975

• Once considered a stable factor, labor’s
share of GDP has fallen in developed
countries. For developing nations, the
evidence is mixed.
• The declining labor share can lead to
stagnant incomes and lackluster wage
growth.
• Alternative ways to measure labor
share can help economists better
understand a country’s growth.

Figure 2

Labor Share in Latin America

1970

KEY TAKEAWAYS

Figure 1

Singapore

SOURCE: Penn World Table.
NOTE: Data end in 2014. For certain countries, data for the most recent years were extrapolated or assumed constant.

Gauging the Self-Employed
In this article, we look at the labor share
and how it can be estimated in developing
countries. If the labor share is declining in
developing economies, this could hinder
their future economic growth. However,
it is more difficult to draw conclusions
for developing and emerging economies
because of data unavailability. One of the
challenges of measuring a country’s labor
share involves factoring in self-employed
people, who can make up a larger share
of the workforce in a developing country
relative to the share in developed nations.
Figure 1 shows the labor share for Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico and
Peru. Together these countries make up

around 80 percent of GDP in Latin America.5
Figure 2 shows the labor share in Hong
Kong, Japan, South Korea, Singapore and
Taiwan.6 These economies experienced
similar growth paths in the 20th century.
These two groups were at similar stages in
their economic development in the mid20th century, but the East Asian economies
grew more rapidly.
As Figures 1 and 2 show, the labor share
varies widely among these economies,
and for some, it also shows considerable
differences over time. In Latin America,
we see that the labor share has declined
since 1995 for all countries except Brazil.
The labor share has shockingly declined
nearly 50 percent in Peru since 1980. In

ABOUT THE AUTHORS
Paulina Restrepo-Echavarria is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis. Her research focuses on international macroeconomics and on search
and matching models of the labor and marriage market. She joined the
St. Louis Fed in 2014. Read more about the author and her work at
https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/restrepo-echavarria.
Brian Reinbold is a research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Figure 3

Labor Share Adjustments to Account for the Self-Employed
Peru

1995

2000

2005

2010

1995

2000

2005

2010

0.2

Adjustment 1

2010

1970

0.2
2005

0.4

2000

0.4

1995

0.6

1990

0.6

1985

0.8

1980

0.8

1975

1.0

1970

1990

Japan

1.0

Baseline

1990

1970

2005

1985

Mexico

1985

0.2

1985

0.2

1980

0.4

1980

0.4

2010

To have a good estimate of the labor
share, it is crucial to have good data on
labor compensation. Labor income is
widely observable for employed individuals that work in formal firms. The challenge lies in estimating the labor income
of self-employed individuals because their
income contains contributions from both
labor and capital.
The Penn World Table (PWT) has data
for several estimates of the labor share.7
Figures 1 and 2 report what PWT considers
the best measure based on several criteria.
However, the labor share varies significantly for each country based on what
assumptions are made and the quality of
data. We graph these different measurements for a subset of countries in Figure 3.
The baseline calculation is the share of
labor compensation of employees. Since it
does not include self-employed income, it
serves as a lower bound for the estimate of
the labor share.
The first adjustment that can be done
to the baseline calculation involves using
mixed-income data. Some countries report
mixed-income data, which is total selfemployed income. For the countries that
report mixed-income data, this adjustment adds all mixed income to total labor
compensation, and this adjustment then
serves as a reasonable upper bound to the
labor share for countries that report mixed
income. (See Adjustment 1 in Figure 3.)
However, since self-employed income
contains both labor and capital income, it
overestimates the labor share.
A second common assumption for adjusting the labor share of self-employed income
is that self-employed individuals use labor
and capital in the same proportion as the
rest of the economy. (See Adjustment 2 in
Figure 3.) This adjustment is considered the
most reasonable estimate. However, Peru,
Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea and
Taiwan do not report mixed income, so
additional information is required.

2000

0.6

1995

0.6

1990

Assumptions for Estimating
Labor Share

1980

0.8

1975

0.8

1970

1.0

1975

South Korea

1.0

1975

East Asia, the labor share has declined
overall for Japan, South Korea and Taiwan
but has actually increased in Hong Kong.
The labor share remains fairly constant in
Singapore. However, estimating the labor
share accurately can be challenging, and
the results will vary depending on what
assumptions are made.

Adjustment 2

Adjustment 3

Adjustment 4

SOURCE: Penn World Table.
NOTES: The labor share is the fraction of labor income over gross domestic product. The baseline calculation is the
share of labor compensation of employees, which does not include self-employed income (mixed income). Adjustment 1 adds all mixed income to total labor compensation. Adjustment 2 modifies the labor share of mixed income by
assuming self-employed individuals use labor and capital in the same proportion as the rest of the economy. Adjustment 3 uses data on the total number of self-employed people and assumes that they earn the same average wage as
employees. Adjustment 4 assumes that all the self-employed work in the agricultural sector, so the entire value added
in agriculture is added to labor compensation. Data end in 2014. For certain countries, data for the most recent years
were extrapolated or assumed constant.

A third adjustment uses information on
the total number of self-employed people
and assumes that they earn the same average wage as employees.8 (See Adjustment 3
in Figure 3.) This assumption is only reasonable if the earning ability of employees
and the self-employed is similar. However,
the self-employed are likely to make less
than those employed in formal firms. Since
the self-employed make up a large share
of the workforce in developing countries,
this discrepancy can overestimate the labor
share for developing nations.

There is a fourth adjustment that can be
made. A 2015 paper suggests another way
to estimate labor income of self-employed
individuals in poorer countries that
may be superior to the third adjustment
mentioned above.9 This fourth adjustment
assumes that all the self-employed work in
the agricultural sector, so the entire value
added in agriculture is added to labor
compensation. (See Adjustment 4 in
Figure 3.)
(continued on Page 21)
REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 11

Many Americans Still Lack
Retirement Savings
By YiLi Chien and Paul Morris
©THINKSTOCK/COMSTOCK

A

s baby boomers age, significant debate
has emerged about whether there is a
retirement crisis developing in the United
States. Some argue that the retirement
situation is poor for many Americans,
with many approaching retirement age
with little or no savings. However, others
describe the situation as better than commonly thought, as many retirees report
living comfortably.1
This article aims to offer a glimpse into
the current state of retirement readiness in
the United States. We examine the participation in and usage of the two most common types of financial accounts designed
exclusively for retirement savings.
The first type is the employer-sponsored
pension plan (ESPP); this includes definedbenefit plans, such as traditional pensions,
and defined-contribution plans, such as
401(k) plans. The second is a retirement
plan offered independent of the workplace,
which includes individual retirement
accounts (IRAs) and Keogh accounts.
Overall, our analysis indicates that
many households either do not utilize or
underutilize the retirement savings plans
available to them. We also examine how
retirement savings vary with age and discuss alternative ways that nonparticipants
may be preparing for retirement.
In our analysis, we utilized data on
retirement account participation and
account balances from the Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF). Every three years,
the survey provides cross-sectional data
on U.S. households’ demographic characteristics, incomes, balance sheets and pensions. The Federal Reserve Board, along
with the Department of the Treasury,
released the SCF data for 2016—the most
recent year available—in September 2017.
The primary unit of analysis in the SCF is
the household, and the survey attempts to
capture the distribution of households in
the U.S. Thus, the results reported in this
article should represent the general state
of participation in and usage of retirement
accounts in the U.S.
12 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

KEY TAKEAWAYS
• A growing debate is focused on whether U.S. households have saved enough for retirement.
• The latest Survey of Consumer Finances data show that 35 percent of households don’t
participate in a retirement plan.
• Even for households approaching retirement, the problem of underparticipation in
retirement plans persists.

Little or No Retirement Savings
Previous studies documented low
participation among households and
low account balances for those that do
participate. For example, a 2016 study by
economist Monique Morrissey used SCF
data to show that participation in definedbenefit and defined-contribution plans
is quite low, and that many families have
little or no retirement savings.
Our findings are generally in line with
Morrissey’s. The most recent SCF data
show that not all employers offer pension
plans to their employees and not everyone
who has access chooses to participate.
Only 27 percent and 33 percent of households have defined-benefit and definedcontribution plans, respectively, at their
current jobs; 8 percent of households
have both. In total, about 56 percent of
households have an employer-sponsored
pension plan associated with their current
or previous employment.
One might think that households that
do not have access to an ESPP are more
likely to utilize an IRA or Keogh account
as an alternative option. However, this
is not what we see in the data. Roughly
30 percent of households have an IRA or
Keogh account. Of households that do not
have an ESPP, only 20 percent utilize any
IRAs or Keogh accounts, while 38 percent

of households that have an ESPP also have
at least one IRA or Keogh account. This
implies that participating in one type of
retirement account increases one’s likelihood of participating in additional retirement accounts.
Overall, 35 percent of U.S. households
do not participate in any retirement
savings plan.2
Even among those households that do
hold retirement accounts, many of them
have low account balances. Figure 1
plots the sum of account balances of all
IRAs, Keogh accounts and pension plans
by percentile for various age groups.3 The
median (50th percentile) household of
all ages (the red bar) holds only $1,100
in its retirement account. Even the 70th
and 80th percentiles of households have
only about $40,000 and $106,000 in their
retirement accounts, respectively.
By contrast, the 90th and 95th (not
shown in the figure) percentiles of households hold considerable amounts, at about
$310,000 and $612,000, respectively.
This implies a high degree of inequality
in retirement account balances across
households.
Intuitively, the balance of a retirement
account should increase and peak right
before retirement. Thus, it could be useful
to exclude younger households from our

ABOUT THE AUTHORS
YiLi Chien is a senior economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. His areas
of research include macroeconomics, household finance and asset pricing.
He joined the St. Louis Fed in 2012. Read more about the author and his research
at https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/chien.
Paul Morris is a senior research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Figure 1

Figure 2

Retirement Account Balances
by Age Group

Net Worth of Pre-Retirement
Households

All
50-55

800

2,000

56-61
62-67

Pre-retirement nonparticipant
Dollars (Thousands)

600
400
200
0

All pre-retirement

1,500

1,000

500

Percentile

90th

80th

70th

60th

50th

40th

30th

20th

90th

80th

70th

60th

50th

40th

30th

20th

10th

0
10th

Dollars (Thousands)

1,000

Percentile

SOURCES: Survey of Consumer Finances and
authors’ calculations.

SOURCES: Survey of Consumer Finances and
authors’ calculations.

NOTE: The retirement account balances
reported here do not include pension plans that
do not have a defined account balance.

NOTE: Pre-retirement households are nonretired
households whose heads are ages 50-67; the
nonparticipant category is composed of those
pre-retirement households that do not have
a defined-benefit pension plan, a definedcontribution pension plan, an individual
retirement account or a Keogh account.

analysis to avoid downwardly biasing the
results. Younger households are likely
to be in a stage of saving for expenses,
such as a down payment on a house or
future education costs for their children.
It is reasonable to expect that they might
postpone their retirement savings with the
intention of catching up later.
To account for this, Figure 1 also plots
retirement account balances for nonretired households whose heads are ages
50-55, 56-61, and 62-67. We refer to these
households as pre-retirement households
throughout the rest of the article.
Participation improves very little for
pre-retirement households, indicating that
age plays only a small role in the decision
to participate and that younger households that do not participate may not be
very likely to participate even by the time
retirement approaches.
Conditional on having a positive
retirement account balance, the households with heads ages 56-61 accumulate
more savings, but the underparticipation problem persists. The median of this
group holds only around $25,000. The
balances of the 70th and 80th percentiles
improve to about $148,000 and $320,000,
respectively. The degree of inequality is

more pronounced among this age group:
The 90th percentile of households holds
around $855,000, while the 95th percentile (not shown in the figure) holds almost
$1,470,000.
Fallback Options?
The lack of retirement accounts does
not necessarily imply that nonparticipants
aren’t saving for retirement. Households
could save through other financial assets
or nonfinancial assets, such as home
equity. However, the net worth (the
value of all assets net of total debt) of
pre-retirement nonparticipants is
typically quite limited.
Figure 2 plots the distribution of net
worth among all pre-retirement households and pre-retirement nonparticipant
households. The net worth of pre-retirement nonparticipant households is much
lower relative to that of all pre-retirement
households. Only the pre-retirement nonparticipant households at the upper end
of the distribution have sizable net worth,
but the numbers are still not very sizable,
especially compared to those of all preretirement households. The 80th percentile
has a net worth of approximately $138,000,
and the 90th percentile has a net worth of

$293,000. The net worth of the corresponding percentiles for all pre-retirement households is at least five times larger.
However, these pre-retirement households that don’t participate in retirement
plans may have some fallback options that
fall outside the scope of our analysis. Social
Security benefits are the first and most
obvious option. In addition, postponing
retirement age or taking a part-time job
after retirement could alleviate the problem. In fact, the labor force participation
rate for seniors (age 65 and above with no
disability) has been trending upward
for much of the past decade; it was at
23 percent in January 2018.4
We also do not take into account the
potential inheritance one might get, and
financial support or housing assistance
from children, relatives and friends could
provide some security for those without
significant retirement savings.
Still, this article documents that many
households either do not utilize or underutilize retirement accounts, such as ESPPs
and IRAs. It could be worrisome that,
for many American households, the total
balances of their retirement accounts may
not be sufficient to ensure a solid life in
retirement.

ENDNOTES
1
2

3

4

See Moeller and Henricks for recent reports on the
current retirement crisis.
We define nonparticipants to be households that
do not participate in a defined-benefit pension plan,
a defined-contribution pension plan, an IRA or a
Keogh account.
The retirement account balance reported here does
not include defined-benefit pension plans that do
not have a defined account balance. Therefore, one
should interpret this measure as a lower bound.
For the specific data, see https://fred.stlouisfed.org/
series/LNU01375379.

REFERENCES
Henricks, Mark. Reports of a Retirement Crisis Are Off
the Mark: Think Tank. CNBC, July 5, 2017. See www.
cnbc.com/2017/07/05/reports-of-a-us-retirementcrisis-are-off-the-mark-think-tank-study.html.
Moeller, Philip. 5 Reasons the Retirement Crisis Is
Getting Worse for Average Americans. Money,
March 22, 2016. See http://time.com/money/4266111/
retirement-crisis-worse-average-americans/.
Morrissey, Monique. The State of American Retirement:
How 401(k)s Have Failed Most American Workers.
Economic Policy Institute, March 3, 2016. See www.
epi.org/publication/retirement-in-america/.

REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 13

The Relationship between Oil and
Equities at the Zero Lower Bound
By Brian Reinbold and Paulina Restrepo-Echavarria
©THINKSTOCK/ISTOCK/BASHTA

Figure 1

12

0.6

Correlation

0.4

10

Fed Funds Rate

8

0.2

6

0.0

4

–0.2

2016

2014

2012

2010

2008

2006

2004

2002

2000

1998

1996

1994

0

1992

–0.6
1990

2
1988

–0.4

Fed Funds Rate (Percent)

0.8

1986

• The correlation between changes in
oil prices and equity returns increased
sharply when the Fed’s policy rate
became zero in 2008.
• Some economists believe that this
phenomenon was the result of a
change in how monetary policy
worked at the zero lower bound.
• A study of other countries, however,
indicates that this increased correlation
didn’t occur when their policy rates
became zero.

The Oil-Equity Correlation in the U.S.

Correlation

KEY TAKEAWAYS

SOURCES: The New York Times, U.S. Energy Information Administration, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, FRED (Federal Reserve Economic Data), Haver Analytics and authors’ calculations.

E

conomists have observed that the correlation between oil price changes and
equity returns changed dramatically after
2008. Before 2008, oil and equity prices
were generally uncorrelated, while after
2008 they became highly correlated.
Interestingly, this change in the correlation coincides with the Federal
Reserve’s monetary policy transition to
the zero lower bound (ZLB), in which
the Fed’s policy rate—the federal funds
rate—became zero. In other words, before
2008, the fed funds rate was positive, and
oil price changes were uncorrelated with
equity returns. Then on Dec. 16, 2008, the
fed funds rate became zero, and changes
in oil prices became highly correlated with
changes in the return on equity.
Figure 1 plots this rolling correlation
alongside the fed funds rate.1 The left axis
shows the correlation coefficient between
the change in oil prices and the change in
the Standard and Poor’s 500 Index return,
and the right axis corresponds to the fed
funds rate.
More specifically, the correlation
between changes in oil prices and changes
in the return on equities was essentially
zero before the ZLB. However, the correlation spiked significantly just before
14 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

NOTES: The area between the red dashed lines corresponds to the fed funds rate at the zero lower bound. The correlation is the one-year rolling correlation between the daily change in the crude oil price of West Texas Intermediate–
Cushing, Okla., and the daily S&P 500 equity return. A one-year rolling correlation calculates the correlation between
two time series using the last year of data.

the zero lower bound was reached, and
the increased correlation persisted during
the ZLB. (See the period between the red
dashed lines on Figure 1.) Indeed, the
average rolling correlation was only –0.04
before the ZLB, but averaged 0.40 during the ZLB.2 Also, we see that as the fed
funds rate increased from zero starting in
late 2015, the correlation between oil and
equities eventually declined, although it
is still too soon to make any predictions
that price changes in oil and equity will
become uncorrelated again.
Given this coincidence between the ZLB
and the increased correlation, it is worth
asking whether being at the ZLB may be

the cause for the increased correlation.
Datta, Johannsen, Kwon and Vigfusson
tackled exactly this question. Using a newKeynesian model augmented to include
oil, they concluded that, yes, being at the
ZLB can be the cause for the increased
correlation.3
The intuition behind their result is the
following: When the monetary authority
is constrained by the ZLB (i.e., the policy
rate is set at zero, effectively setting the
short-term nominal interest rate at zero),
it cannot use the fed funds rate to respond
to changes in inflation. The opposite is
true away from the ZLB: The nominal rate
changes in response to changes in inflation.

ABOUT THE AUTHORS
Paulina Restrepo-Echavarria is an economist at the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis. Her research focuses on international macroeconomics and on search
and matching models of the labor and marriage market. She joined the
St. Louis Fed in 2014. Read more about the author and her work at
https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/restrepo-echavarria.
Brian Reinbold is a research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Figure 2

The Oil-Equity Correlation in Other Countries

0.2

5

0.0

3

–0.2
1

–0.4
2016

2011

2006

2001

1996

–1
1991

1986

–0.6

Policy Rate (Percent)

2016

0.6

Correlation

0.4

0.4
0.2

0.2

0.0

–0.2

0.0

–0.4

Policy Rate (Percent)

0.4

0.6

–0.2

–0.6
2016

7

2011

Japan
0.8

2006

9

–0.5

2011

0.6

–0.6

2006

Sweden
0.8

0

1986

2016

2011

2006

2001

1996

1991

1986

–0.6

0.5

–0.4

1986

–0.4

–0.2

2001

3

2001

–0.2

1.5

0.0

1996

6

1996

0.0

2.5

0.2

1991

9

1991

0.2

0.4
Correlation

Correlation

0.4

3.5

0.6
Policy Rate (Percent)

12

Policy Rate (Percent)

0.6

Correlation

France
0.8

15

Correlation

United Kingdom
0.8

Policy Rate

SOURCES: U.S. Energy Information Administration, Financial Times, Nasdaq OMX Nordic Exchange, Sveriges Riksbank,
Bank of England, Bank of Japan, European Central Bank, FRED (Federal Reserve Economic Data), Haver Analytics and
authors’ calculations.
NOTES: The area between the red dashed lines corresponds to the fed funds rate at the zero lower bound. The correlation is a one-year rolling correlation between the daily change in the crude oil price of West Texas Intermediate–
Cushing, Okla., and the daily equity returns of the respective countries’ stock exchange indexes. The policy rate is the
relevant nominal interest rate set or targeted by the country’s central bank.

This intuition follows from the Fisher
equation, in which the nominal interest
rate approximately equals the real interest
rate plus the inflation rate. Away from the
ZLB, the monetary authority can respond
to inflation by adjusting the policy rate.
However, at the ZLB, the monetary authority cannot respond to decreases in inflation
by lowering the policy rate; therefore, the
nominal rate is essentially fixed, and the
real interest rate has to adjust for the Fisher
equation to hold.
This model-implied mechanism means
that changes in inflation affect the real
interest rate differently at the ZLB and

away from it, and hence, it makes sense
that the transmission to output, consumption, oil prices and equity prices is different
at the ZLB and away from it.

a country’s policy rate being at zero, as we
observe for the U.S.
Figure 2 shows data similar to those
plotted in Figure 1 for the United States,
but for the U.K., France, Sweden and
Japan. For these plots, we used each country’s own stock exchange index for equity
returns4 and the relevant policy nominal
interest rate.5,6
We can see that for all countries except
Japan, the correlation between the growth
rate of oil and equity prices oscillates
around zero up to 2008 and then becomes
positive up to around 2012, just as in the
U.S. However, their policy rates were not
at the zero lower bound. For those that
did reach the ZLB, they reached it around
2012, with the exception of Japan, which
went to the ZLB in the early 2000s. Interestingly, we do not see a global spike in oilequity correlations coinciding with Japan
entering the ZLB.
This cross-country evidence hints to
the fact that the inability of the monetary
authority to react to deflationary shocks
does not explain the change in the correlation between oil and equity prices. If
this were the right argument, we would
observe a coincidence between the correlation becoming positive and the policy
rate becoming zero for all these countries,
which is not the case. (See Figure 2.)
However, the increase in the correlation for all countries coincides with the
one in the U.S. This is because the stock
exchanges in these countries are highly
correlated with the S&P 500 and the price
of oil is the same. This means that this is a
more general phenomenon that seems to be
related more to the policy rate of the U.S.
than to the policy rate of each individual
country.7

ENDNOTES
1

An Alternative View
However, if the argument in Datta et al.
is right, and the mechanism that changes
the correlation between the change in oil
prices and the change in equity prices is
through a country’s inability to respond
to inflation using the nominal interest
rate, we should expect a consistent pattern
at a cross-country level. That means the
increased correlation should coincide with

2

We use the West Texas Intermediate–Cushing, Okla.,
for the crude oil index, and we use the S&P 500 for
the equity index. We then calculate the daily price
change in oil and the S&P 500 return using 100 times
the log-difference of consecutive prices. Finally, we
calculate the one-year rolling correlation between
the daily change in oil prices and the daily S&P 500
return. A one-year rolling correlation calculates the
correlation between two time series using the last
year of data. This allows us to see whether there is
any time variation in the correlation between oil
and equities.
A correlation coefficient of 1.0 means the two

(continued on Page 21)
REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 15

INDUSTRY PROFILE

Health Care Remains Important
Job Engine in Eighth District
By Charles Gascon
©THINKSTOCK/MONKEY BUSINESS IMAGES, LTD.

A

s the U.S. population has aged, the
health care sector has become one of
the fastest-growing parts of the economy,
causing a surge in new job openings. Even
technology companies are finding ways
to expand into the health care space, with
products such as wearable medical devices
and the use of 3-D printing to manufacture health care products. With all the
challenges and opportunities that exist,
it is worth taking a closer look into the
health care sector.
Size of the Health Care Sector
The economic size of the sector can be
measured in various ways. Depending on
the measure, the sector could be as small
as one-tenth of the economy or as large as
one-quarter of the economy.
The first stage in measuring the size
is determining which industries should
be included in the sector. A narrow
definition focuses on health care serviceproviding firms, such as doctors’ offices,
hospitals and nursing homes.1 Nationally, about 12 percent of the workforce is
employed in these industries.
However, there are other industries often
included in the definition, such as drug
manufacturers, pharmacies and insurance
companies.2 Including these increases the
share of employment to about 14 percent.
Table 1 highlights the largest firms in each
of these industries. Due to data availability, this article will primarily rely on the
narrower definition of the sector to provide
consistency across various metrics.
Providing health care services is generally more labor-intensive than other
sectors of the economy, such as manufacturing. As a result, the share of national
output (or value added) derived from
the health care sector is about 7 percent,
which is considerably smaller than the
share of employment. However, household
consumption of health goods and services
is notably higher, at around 22 percent
of all household spending, of which
16 percent is health care services and
16 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

KEY TAKEAWAYS
• While the output share is relatively small, health care comprises about 22 percent of
household spending, up from 10 percent in the 1970s.
• The health care sector has generated about 30 percent of new jobs nationally since 2007,
and 50 percent of new jobs in the Eighth District.
• Not all jobs in health care are high-pay. One-third of workers are in health care support
occupations that pay below the average private sector wage.

the rest going to goods such as drugs or
medical devices.
With relatively fast growth in health
care prices during the past few decades,
the share of households’ expenditures on
health care has increased from 10 percent
in the early 1970s. The share of spending
on pharmaceutical products has more
than doubled, from 1.1 percent in 1970 to
3.8 percent in 2016, but remains a relatively small component of overall household spending. While an aging population
will demand more health care services,
technological improvements and better
overall health outcomes could offset some
increased spending.
Strong Growth in Employment
Growth in the health care sector has
been a key driver of employment growth
in the past decade. Since 2007, the U.S.
economy has added about 9.7 million
jobs. During this same period, the health
care sector added just over 3 million jobs,
which breaks down to about 1 million
during the recession and another 2 million after the recession. (See Figure 1.)
In total, gains in the health care sector
over this period account for about 32 percent of new employment, which is impressive considering the sector employed only
9 percent of the workforce in 2007. Among
the three major industries in health care
(according to our narrow definition, as

seen in Endnote 1), the ambulatory care
service industry (e.g., doctor offices, dentist
offices, outpatient centers) added over
2 million of the new jobs.
Job growth in the health care sector
has created a wide variety of jobs beyond
the typical occupations of doctors or
nurses. In fact, only about 60 percent of
people employed in the health care sector
work in health care occupations. The
other 40 percent are in areas such as office
or administrative work, personal care,
food preparation, and community and
social services.
Jobs Openings to Remain High
Building off the distinction between the
health care sector and health care occupations can provide some useful insights
about the sector and the outlook.
The two major health care occupational
groups are: (1) health care practitioners
and technical occupations, and (2) health
care support occupations. The former
group predominantly includes physicians,
specialists, pharmacists and registered
nurses. Of the 8 million people in this
group, the biggest subset is registered
nurses, at over 2.8 million. Health care
support occupations are predominantly
nursing assistants, home health aides and
medical assistants.
Table 2 summarizes the employment
and wage profiles of these two subsets of

ABOUT THE AUTHOR
Charles Gascon is a regional economist and a senior coordinator in the Research Division at
the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. His focus is studying economic conditions in the Eighth
District. He joined the St. Louis Fed in 2006. Read more about the author and his research at
https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/gascon.

The Sector in the Eighth District
Like in most parts of the nation, health
care plays an integral role in the economy
of the Eighth District, which is the area covered by the St. Louis Fed. Louisville, Ky., is
home to two of the nation’s largest health care
firms: Humana Inc. and Kindred Healthcare.
St. Louis is home to two of the District’s
other national health care firms: Express
Scripts Holding Co. and Centene Corp.
Although the District is the headquarters
for many large firms, the overall share of
employment in the health care sector is only

Table 1

Largest Health Care Firms by Industry
NAICS Code

Industry Name

National

Eighth District

3254

Pharmaceutical and
Medicine Manufacturing

Johnson & Johnson

Reliv International Inc.

44611

Drug Stores and Pharmacies

CVS Health Corp.

Express Scripts Holding Co.

52411

Life and Health Insurance
Carriers

UnitedHealth Group Inc.

Centene Corp.

621

Ambulatory Health Care
Services

Humana Inc.

Humana Inc.

622

Hospitals

HCA Healthcare Inc.

BJC HealthCare

623

Nursing and Residential Care
Facilities

Kindred Healthcare Inc.

Kindred Healthcare Inc.

SOURCES: Compustat, Dow Jones.
NOTES: The Eighth Federal Reserve District is headquartered in St. Louis. The District includes all of
Arkansas and parts of Illinois, Indiana, Kentucky, Mississippi, Missouri and Tennessee.

Figure 1

U.S. Health Care Shows Steady Job Growth since 2007
15
Health Care

Nonfarm (Less Health Care)

Total Nonfarm

10
5
0
–5

Jan. ’17

Jan. ’16

Jan. ’15

Jan. ’14

Jan. ’13

Jan. ’12

Jan. ’11

Jan. ’10

Jan. ’09

Jan. ’08

–10
Jan. ’07

Cumulative Job Gains (millions)

workers. Notice that 8.8 percent of the
U.S. workforce is employed in health care
occupations, of which two-thirds are
practitioners and the rest are in support
occupations. Health care practitioners
earn an average wage of $38 an hour,
which is about 60 percent higher than the
average private sector wage. On the other
hand, support occupations earn an average of $15 an hour, or 40 percent below
the average private sector wage.
For the latest 10 years for which data
are available (2006-2016), employment
in both occupation groups was strong,
with employment of practitioners growing
21 percent and employment in support
occupations growing 15 percent. Wage
growth over the period was more modest,
with practitioners’ wages growing
slightly faster than the national rate, and
support occupations experiencing slightly
slower growth.
The U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics
lists three health care support occupations among the top five fastest-growing
occupations over the next 10 years: home
health aides, personal care aides and physician assistants.3 Projected employment
growth in these occupations is between
37 and 47 percent. “Nurse practitioners” is
the only practitioner group in the top 10,
with a projected growth rate of 36 percent.
While the projected growth rate of registered nurses is slower, the base number
is so large that this occupation is projected
to have the third most new jobs over the
next decade (437,000). Again, personal
care aides and home health aides are also
in the top five, with 754,000 and 425,000
new jobs, respectively.
What begins to appear, based on past
trends and BLS projections, is a gradual
shift in the health care sector toward more
low-pay support positions.

SOURCES: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics and author’s calculations.
NOTES: The line represents cumulative gains or losses for all nonfarm payrolls, while each bar shows
cumulative monthly employment gains or losses for the health care sector and nonfarm payroll less health
care since January 2007. For example, the U.S. economy added 9.7 million nonfarm jobs from January
2007 to November 2017, of which 3.1 million were in health care and the rest were outside health care.

about 0.5 percentage points higher than
the national rate. The sector’s output share,
however, is 7.9 percent in the District, compared with 6.6 percent nationally. Among
the four largest metro areas in the District,
St. Louis has the greatest share of output
derived from health care, at 8.2 percent.
The District’s growth in the health care
sector over the last decade has broadly
followed the national trends. The District
health care sector steadily added jobs
throughout the recession. (See Figure 2.)
Overall, the District health care sector
grew only slightly slower than the national
REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 17

Table 2

Health Care Jobs and Pay: 2016
U.S.

Eighth District

Little Rock

Louisville

Memphis

St. Louis

8.8%

9.6%

11.3%

9.2%

9.2%

9.5%

Health Care Practitioners and Technical Occupations

5.9%

6.8%

8.2%

6.7%

6.8%

6.6%

Health Care Support Occupations

2.9%

2.8%

3.1%

2.5%

2.4%

3.0%

Average Hourly Wage for all Private Sector Workers

$23.86

$21.24

$20.70

$21.28

$20.64

Average Hourly Wage for all Health Care Occupations

30.40

27.98

27.49

29.40

29.91

27.40

Health Care Practitioners and Technical Occupations

38.06

33.87

32.71

34.82

35.66

33.60

Health Care Support Occupations

14.65

13.64

13.40

14.86

13.59

13.68

Share of Workforce in Health Care Occupations

$23.19

SOURCE: Occupational Employment Statistics, Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Outlook
These trends present a unique set of
challenges and opportunities. The key
reason that health care has dominated
regional employment growth over the last
decade is not because job growth in the
sector has been considerably faster than
the nation; rather, it is because growth
outside the sector has been much weaker.
Overall demographic trends continue to
indicate that the health care sector will continue to show strong growth, and the sector
is less sensitive to business cycle fluctuations. These are positives for the region.
However, growth in health care does
18 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

Figure 2

Health Care Accounts for Half of Job Growth in the Eighth District since 2007
600
400

Health Care

Nonfarm (Less Health Care)

Total Nonfarm

200
0
–200
–400
–600
–800
Jan. ’17

Jan. ’16

Jan. ’15

Jan. ’14

Jan. ’13

Jan. ’12

Jan. ’11

Jan. ’10

Jan. ’09

Jan. ’08

–1,000
Jan. ’07

Cumulative Job Gains (thousands)

benchmark; however, job growth outside
the health care sector has been about half
the national rate. As a result, the District
economy added about 500,000 jobs almost
equally split between the health care sector
and other sectors. The health care sector
employs about 10 percent of the regional
workforce and generated almost 50 percent
of the new jobs in the last 10 years.
Employment of health care practitioners
grew 17 percent in the District, slightly
slower than the national rate of 21 percent.
However, employment in support occupations in the District grew only 5.5 percent,
notably slower than the national rate of
15 percent. The wage premium for practitioners in the District is broadly consistent
with the national average of 60 percent
more than what private sector workers
in general earn; however, practitioners
in Memphis have the highest hourly rate
among the District’s major MSAs, and
earn 73 percent more than other private
sector workers in the Memphis metro
area. In St. Louis, practitioners earn a
wage premium of 45 percent.4

SOURCES: Bureau of Labor Statistics, Haver Analytics and author’s calculations.
NOTES: The line represents cumulative gains or losses for all nonfarm payrolls, while each bar shows
cumulative monthly employment gains or losses for the health care sector and nonfarm payroll less health
care since January 2007. For example, the Eighth District added about 500,000 nonfarm jobs from
January 2007 to June 2017, of which 229,000 were in health care and the rest were outside health care.

not guarantee broad-based prosperity.
Beyond the high pay of health care practitioners, the health care jobs in highest
demand pay lower-than-average wages.
More importantly, 40 percent of jobs in
the health care sector are not jobs like
doctors, nurses or health aides, but jobs
in management, technology and other
professional occupations. As a result, continued growth in the health care sector
will require a pool of workers with diverse
skill sets and backgrounds that may come
from other industries.
Research assistance was provided by Heting
Zhu, a senior research associate at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

ENDNOTES
1

2

3
4

The specific industries are: Ambulatory Health Care
Services (NAICS 621); Hospitals (NAICS 622); and
Nursing and Residential Care Facilities (NAICS 623).
NAICS is the North American Industry Classification
System.
Pharmaceutical and Medicine Manufacturing (NAICS
3254); Drug Stores and Pharmacies (NAICS 44611);
and Direct Life and Health Insurance Carriers (NAICS
52411).
See www.bls.gov/emp.
Much of the differences in these wage premiums can
be attributed to differences in the types of practitioners on a more detailed level. For example, Memphis
has a larger share of general internists compared to
St. Louis, and these workers earn a very high wage
premium of 550 percent in both areas.

DISTRICT OVERVIEW

Income and Living Standards
within the Eighth District

ILLINOIS

INDIANA

MISSOURI
KENTUCKY

By Brian Reinbold and Yi Wen

TENNESSEE
ARKANSAS

MISSISSIPPI

KEY TAKEAWAYS
• The paycheck itself doesn’t provide a complete picture of one’s lifestyle since cost of
living can vary geographically.
• Regional price parity indexes can measure differences in the cost of living across regions.
• The District’s cost of living is about 15 percent below the national average, though this
level varies among its counties.

I

ncome inequality has long been an
important issue in welfare economics.
However, solely looking at income tells
only part of the story about the differences in people’s living standards because
income does not reveal information about
the cost of living, i.e., the actual purchasing
power of a person’s income.
For example, housing prices vary
immensely across the country as well as
across urban, suburban and rural areas. Since
housing typically consumes a large share of
an individual’s income, a high income does
not necessarily translate to a high standard
of living if housing is very expensive.
In other words, the purchasing power of
a dollar is not the same across regions due
to variations in the cost of living. Therefore, factoring in cost of living can yield
fruitful insights about true inequality. In
this article, we look at income adjusted
for cost of living in the Eighth District1 to
evaluate income inequality, or more accurately, living-standard inequality.
Real Per Capita Income in the District
Many are familiar with the consumer
price index (CPI) and the personal
consumption expenditures price index
(PCEPI). These temporal indexes are useful for gauging the nationwide consumption price level and its changes over time,
but they do not tell us much about the cost

of living among different regions.
For example, without taking into
account the heterogeneity of the cost
of living, we find that the average 2015
PCEPI-adjusted per capita personal
income by county for the District is about
$31,000, which is well below the U.S. average of $43,996; the gap is about $13,000,
or 30 percent.2 However, as the analysis
below shows, the living standard in the
District is much closer to the national
average than suggested by per capita
income per se.
Regional Price Parity Indexes and
Cost of Living in the District
Recently, the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) developed regional price parity
indexes (RPPs) to facilitate the measurement of living standards across regions.
The RPP is a spatial index that allows us
to compare prices of consumption goods
and housing across regions. The BEA has
RPPs by state, metropolitan statistical
area (MSA) and nonmetropolitan area.
RPPs are constructed to compare prices
relative to the national average. Therefore,
the RPP for the nation is 100.
The 2015 RPP for every MSA and nonmetropolitan area in the District is less
than 100, so cost of living is lower in the
District relative to the nation. The average
RPP is 86.6 and the median RPP is 85.6,

ABOUT THE AUTHORS
Yi Wen is an economist and assistant vice president at the Federal Reserve Bank of
St. Louis. His research interests include macroeconomics and the Chinese economy.
He joined the St. Louis Fed in 2005. Read more about the author and his research
at https://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/wen.
Brian Reinbold is a research associate at the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

The Eighth Federal Reserve District is composed of four
zones, each of which is centered around one of the four
main cities: Little Rock, Louisville, Memphis and St. Louis.

suggesting that the cost of living in the District is about 15 percent below the national
average.
But the cost of living is not even across
the region. For example, the MSA with
the lowest RPP is Jonesboro, Ark., at 81.9,
and Columbia, Mo., has the highest RPP
at 92.2. Also, nonmetropolitan, or more
rural, areas tend to have lower RPPs and
thus a lower cost of living.
Living Standard or Income-Adjusted
for Cost of Living
Now we take county-level real per
capita income and adjust it for cost of living. However, the BEA does not provide
RPPs by county, so we adjust counties that
belong to an MSA by their MSA’s RPP,
and we adjust counties outside an MSA by
their states’ respective nonmetropolitan
RPPs. Table 1 reports income adjusted for
cost of living in the District for the top
five and bottom five counties.
As expected, standard of living is not
the same across the District. The average 2015 RPP-adjusted real per capita
personal income by county is $36,482,
compared with the national average
of $43,996.3 Now the gap between the
District and the national average shrunk
dramatically from about $13,000 in
PCEPI-adjusted terms to about $7,500.
Namely, due to the District’s low cost of
living, we see the gap narrow between
the District’s “income” and the nation’s.
This result is similar to what St. Louis Fed
President James Bullard has demonstrated
about the importance of adjusting income
for cost of living across MSAs in the U.S.4,5
REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 19

Table 1

Adjusted Real Per Capita Income by County: Top Five and Bottom Five
Rank

County

Regional Price
Parity Index,
2015

RPP-Adjusted Per
Capita Personal
Income*
$79,678

State

MSA Name

Arkansas

Fayetteville-Springdale-Rogers,
AR-MO

89.8

1

Benton

2

St. Louis

Missouri

St. Louis, MO-IL

90.6

$62,314

3

Oldham

Kentucky

Louisville, KY-IN

91.2

$55,023

4

Dubois

Indiana

Nonmetropolitan Portion

85.3

$53,895

5

Monroe

Illinois

St. Louis, MO-IL

90.6

$52,090

334

Benton

Mississippi

Memphis, TN-MS-AR

91.5

$27,641

335

Lincoln

Arkansas

Pine Bluff, AR

83.5

$26,483

336

Shannon

Missouri

Nonmetropolitan Portion

84.4

$26,089

337

Lake

Tennessee

Nonmetropolitan Portion

84.4

$26,068

338

Douglas

Missouri

Nonmetropolitan Portion

84.4

$25,771

*Chained 2009 dollars
SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Haver Analytics and authors’ calculations.

Figure 1

Adjusted Real Per Capita Income: Eighth District Counties

ILLINOIS

2015 Regional Price Parity
Index-Adjusted Real
Per Capita Personal Income

INDIANA

$40,001 to $79,700

MISSOURI

$36,901 to $40,000
$35,001 to $36,900

KENTUCKY

$32,501 to $35,000
$25,700 to $32,500

TENNESSEE

SOURCES: Bureau of Economic Analysis, Haver Analytics and
authors’ calculations.

ARKANSAS

MISSISSIPPI

NOTES: The different shades of color correspond to quintiles of
RPP-adjusted real per capita income; in other words, approximately one-fifth of counties correspond to a specific shade.
Dollars are chained 2009 dollars. A bold line represents the
outline of a metropolitan statistical area (MSA); parts of some
MSAs may lie outside the District’s boundaries.

However, inequality remains: The “richest” county commands a living standard
more than 300 percent of that in the
“poorest” county. For example, the living
standard in St. Louis County, Missouri, is
$62,314, and the living standard in Benton
County, Arkansas, is $79,678. Still, despite
these outliers, the living standard is
20 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

relatively consistent across most counties
in the District.
Figure 1 displays 2015 RPP-adjusted
real income per capita on a map of the
District so that we can better visualize
the distribution of the standard of living
geographically. The darker a county is,
the higher its standard of living is. For

example, southern Indiana has a relatively
high standard of living, with median RPPadjusted real income at around $41,000,
while northern Mississippi has a relatively
low standard of living at $33,000.
We also see that counties within MSAs
tend to have higher adjusted incomes
despite the fact that nonmetropolitan areas
tend to have a lower cost of living. This
suggests that income levels tend to rise
more than proportionately with the cost of
living, so that high-income regions tend to
also have a high standard of living despite
the higher cost of living.6
For Further Research
Our analysis allows us to see heterogeneity in living standards—the purchasing
power of incomes—across the District and
its relative position in the nation, but we
would have greater insight into cost of living if we had RPPs by county. Also, within
each county, both income and cost of
living can vary substantially. For example,
income and cost of living vary significantly between urban and rural areas.
Therefore, finer micro-data would allow
for a greater understanding of income
inequality within a county.
Conclusion
In this article, we have looked at the
distribution of living standards in terms
of the purchasing power of real per capita
personal income by county using RPPs.
Adjusting income for cost of living allows
us to evaluate inequality in income’s local
purchasing power instead of income per
se. We see that overall inequality is not so
severe in the District once adjusted for the
cost of living, both across counties and in
comparison to the nation. We also see that
living standards tend to be higher within
MSAs than outside them. In general,
inequality is less severe when measured
by living standards than by income per se.
Still, finer micro-data is necessary to better understand heterogeneity within each
county.

ENDNOTES
1

2
3

Headquartered in St. Louis, the Eighth Federal
Reserve District includes all of Arkansas and parts of
Illinois, Indiana, Kentucky, Mississippi, Missouri and
Tennessee.
See Coughlin, Gascon and Kliesen.
The RPP national real per capita personal income is

4
5

6

the same as the non-RPP-adjusted national real
per capita personal income because RPPs are
constructed to be 100 for the nation.
See Bullard, 2017, and Bullard, 2018.
Bullard also shows that MSAs with low incomes
may in fact have higher living standards than
MSAs with higher incomes when adjusting for RPP.
The average 2015 RPP-adjusted real per capita
personal income for District counties within MSAs
is $38,734.92, while the average for District counties outside of MSAs is $35,688.72.

Oil and Equities

(continued from Page 15)

3
4

REFERENCES
Bullard, James. Comparing Living Standards across
U.S. Metro Areas: Which Ones Fared Well?
Regional Economist, March 1, 2018. See www.
stlouisfed.org/publications/regional-economist/
first-quarter-2018/comparing-living-standards.
Bullard, James. Living Standards across U.S. Metropolitan Statistical Areas. Keynote address at the
Bi-State Development 2017 Annual Meeting,
St. Louis, Mo., Oct. 6, 2017.
Coughlin, Cletus; Gascon, Charles; and Kliesen,
Kevin. Living Standards in St. Louis and the
Eighth Federal Reserve District: Let’s Get Real.
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis’ Review, 2017,
Vol. 99, No. 4, pp. 377-394.
U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. Real Personal
Income and Regional Price Parities, July 2016.
See www.bea.gov/regional/pdf/RPP2016_
methodology.pdf.

Labor Share

(continued from Page 11)

This adjustment does not separate capital income from agriculture, which can
inflate the estimate. However, in developing economies, agriculture is less capitalintensive than in developed economies, so
this distortion may be insignificant. Also,
self-employed labor income outside of
agriculture is not counted, which lowers
the estimate. All things considered, this
adjustment is a reasonable approximation of the labor share for developing
economies.
This adjustment is also reasonable
in poorer nations because agriculture
employs about half of the self-employed
and uses little capital.10 This measure,
therefore, gives a rough idea of the labor
share in poorer countries, and this is the
measure reported in Figure 1 and Figure
2 for Peru, Hong Kong, South Korea,
Singapore and Taiwan. Adjustment 4 is
nearly identical to the baseline measure
for Singapore, Hong Kong and Taiwan.
Adjustment 4 also seems reasonable for
Argentina, Chile and Mexico.
However, it might not be very accurate for countries that are already in
their second stage of their structural

case. The periods for QE1, QE2 and QE3 were fairly
close together—constantly increasing the Fed’s balance sheet—and there is no systematic behavior for
the correlation between the price of oil and the price
of equity that can be observed for those periods. QE1
occurred from December 2008 to March 2010, QE2
occurred from November 2010 to June 2011, and QE3
occurred from September 2012 to October 2014. See
Williamson.

5

6

7

variables are perfectly positively correlated, a correlation of –1.0 means the two variables are perfectly
negatively correlated, and a correlation coefficient of
0.0 means no correlation.
See Datta et al.
For the equity indexes, we used the Paris CAC 40
for France, London Financial Times All-Share for the
U.K., the Stockholm Affarsvarlden for Sweden, and
the Nikkei 255 for Japan.
For nominal interest rates, we used the Bank Rate set
by the Bank of England for the U.K., the overnight
deposit rate set by the European Central Bank for
France, the repo rate set by the Sveriges Riksbank
for Sweden and the overnight deposit rate on excess
reserves set by the Bank of Japan for Japan.
We use the West Texas Intermediate–Cushing, Okla.,
for the crude oil index, and we use each country’s
respective equity index. We then calculate the daily
price change in oil and the equity return using 100
times the log-difference of consecutive prices.
Finally we calculate the one-year rolling correlation
between the daily change in oil prices and the daily
equity return.
One might wonder whether quantitative easing (QE)
might have had something to do with this phenomenon. However, we do not believe that this is the

transformation. The number of workers
in the agricultural sector declines as a
country develops. Therefore, Adjustment
4 may simply capture a falling share in
agriculture and not necessarily the entire
labor share. This may be why we see a
significant decline in labor share for Peru
and South Korea.
In summary, estimates of the labor
share can vary depending on data availability and what assumptions are made for
measuring the share of labor income of the
self-employed. This can make a huge difference for developing countries with a large
number of self-employed individuals. Since
Peru, Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea
and Taiwan do not report mixed income,
drawing conclusions on the behavior of
labor share in these economies is challenging. Ultimately, knowing the behavior
of labor share can help economists better
understand a country’s economic growth.

ENDNOTES
1
2
3
4

See Atkinson.
See Barrow and Faberman.
See International Labor Organization and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.
If labor share is declining, then capital share is increasing. This result follows from the accounting identity
that national income is the sum of its factor components: labor and capital.

REFERENCES
Datta, Deepa; Johannsen, Benjamin K.; Kwon, Hannah; and
Vigfusson, Robert J. Oil, Equities, and the Zero Lower
Bound. BIS Working Papers No. 617, Bank for International Settlements, March 2017.
Williamson, Stephen D. Quantitative Easing: How Well
Does This Tool Work? Regional Economist, Third
Quarter 2017, Vol. 25, No. 3, pp. 8-14.

5
6

7
8
9
10

See Ohanian, Restrepo-Echavarria and Wright.
Although Japan is a developed economy, we can
compare the other developing countries with a
developed country.
See Feenstra, Inklaar and Timmer.
See Gollin.
See Feenstra, Inklaar and Timmer.
See Timmer.

REFERENCES
Atkinson, A.B. Factor Shares: The Principal Problem
of Political Economy? Oxford Review of Economic
Policy, Vol. 25, No. 1, 2009, pp. 3-16.
Barrow, Lisa; and Faberman, Jason. Wage Growth,
Inflation and the Labor Share. Chicago Fed Letter,
2015, No. 349.
Feenstra, Robert C.; Inklaar, Robert; and Timmer, Marcel
P. The Next Generation of the Penn World Table.
American Economic Review, 2015, Vol. 105, No. 10,
pp. 3150-82.
Gollin, Douglas. Getting Income Shares Right.
Journal of Political Economy, 2002, Vol. 110,
No. 2, pp. 458-74.
International Labor Organization and the Organization
for Economic Cooperation and Development. The
Labour Share in G20 Economies. Report prepared
for the G-20 Employment Working Group, Antalya,
Turkey, Feb. 26-27, 2015.
Ohanian, Lee E.; Restrepo-Echavarria, Paulina; and
Wright, Mark L.J. Bad Investments and Missed
Opportunities? Postwar Capital Flows to Asia and
Latin America. Working Paper No. 2014-038C,
Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, May 2017.
Timmer, Marcel, ed. The World Input-Output
Database (WIOD): Contents, Sources and Methods.
WIOD Working Paper No. 10, April 2012.

REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 21

NATIONAL OVERVIEW

By Kevin L. Kliesen

F

rom an economic standpoint, 2017
was a good year. Compared with 2016,
the U.S. economy registered stronger real
gross domestic product (GDP) growth,
continued low inflation, a further drop in
the unemployment rate and record-high
equity prices. Indeed, last year’s economic
performance exceeded the expectations
of most professional forecasters. This
performance was all the more impressive
since it occurred against the backdrop of
a modest tightening in monetary policy—
and, moreover, the prospect of further
modest tightening actions in 2018.
Most forecasters are anticipating a continued strengthening in economic activity in 2018 because of this year’s modest
reductions in personal and corporate
income tax rates and increases in federal
defense and nondefense government
expenditures. A key question is whether
inflation will also heat up.

What Are Forecasters Predicting for the Economy?
6.0
5.0
Percent

U.S. Economy
Continues to
Strengthen

Forecast
(2018:Q1 to 2019:Q1)

4.0
3.0
2.0
1.0
0.0

2015:Q4

2016:Q2

2016:Q4

2017:Q2

Unemployment Rate

2017:Q4

Real GDP Growth

2018:Q2

2018:Q4

PCE Inflation

SOURCE: Survey of Professional Forecasters, February 2018.
NOTE: For real gross domestic product (GDP), the percent represents percent change at annual
rate; for personal consumption expenditures (PCE) inflation, it represents percent change,
year over year. The SPF report was released prior to the second estimate for real GDP growth
on Feb. 28.

KEY TAKEAWAYS
• U.S. GDP growth accelerated to 2.5 percent last year from 1.8 percent in 2016,
exceeding forecasters’ expectations.
• Modest reductions in income tax rates and increases in federal government spending
are expected to help strengthen the economy in 2018.
• Long-term inflation expectations have moved steadily higher so far this year.

Building Economic Momentum
Compared with 2016, real GDP growth
accelerated from 1.8 percent to 2.5 percent in 2017.1 Last year’s acceleration in
output growth reflected, to a large extent,
much stronger growth in real business
fixed investment and exports of goods
and services. The acceleration in business
capital spending was especially heartening, since it generally signals increased
confidence in the economic outlook by
businesses. Increased capital spending and exports naturally boosted the
nation’s industrial sector. Following a
0.1 percent decline in 2016, industrial
production rose by 3.5 percent in 2017;
this was the largest increase in seven
years. The demand for goods reflected
solid real consumption spending in 2017
(2.8 percent); however, real residential
fixed investment advanced at a more
modest pace (2.6 percent), while total
government expenditures accelerated
slightly in 2017 (0.7 percent).
22 REGIONAL ECONOMIST | First Quarter 2018

In late December 2017, the Tax Cuts
and Jobs Act was signed into law. Two
key provisions of the act were the reduction of marginal tax rates for most
individuals and the lowering of the
statutory U.S. corporate tax rate from 35
percent to 21 percent. According to the
Joint Committee on Taxation of the U.S.
Congress, the act is expected to lower
U.S. tax revenues by about $1 trillion
over the next 10 years, or about $100 billion a year. While sizable in dollar terms,
the revenue loss is quite modest in terms
of GDP—0.6 percent.
The tax reform package has spurred
many forecasters to raise their mediumterm outlook for the U.S. economy. For
example, the February 2018 Survey of
Professional Forecasters (SPF) projects

that real GDP will increase by 2.8 percent
in 2018; this increase is moderately larger
than the forecast from six months earlier
(2.4 percent). The SPF projects that real
GDP growth will then slow to 2.5 percent
in 2019 and then to 2 percent in 2020. The
pace of economic activity could get a further boost over the next two years because
of the Bipartisan Budget Act that was
signed into law in February. The budget
act, among other things, increases federal
defense and nondefense discretionary
expenditures by nearly $300 billion in fiscal years 2018 and 2019, and an additional
$90 billion in supplementary spending for
natural disaster relief.
Although the unemployment rate is
already quite low at 4.1 percent, the SPF
projects that, with stronger growth, the

ABOUT THE AUTHOR
Kevin L. Kliesen is a business economist and research officer at the Federal Reserve Bank
of St. Louis. His research interests include business economics, and monetary and fiscal
policy analysis. He joined the St. Louis Fed in 1988. Read more about the author and his
research at http://research.stlouisfed.org/econ/kliesen.

ECONOMY AT A GLANCE
All data as of March 19

Research assistance was provided by Brian
Levine, a research associate at the Federal
Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

1

2

Unless noted otherwise, annual percentage increases
in output and prices are changes from the fourth
quarter of one year to the fourth quarter of the
following year.
See this recent presentation by St. Louis Fed President James Bullard at www.stlouisfed.org/~/media/
Files/PDFs/Bullard/remarks/2018/Bullard_KU_
Outlook_Conference_Lexington_KY_6_February_
2018.pdf?la=en.

2

0
Q4

–2
’12

’13

’14

’15

’16

Percent Change from a Year Earlier

Percent

4

CPI–All Items
All Items, Less Food and Energy

2

0

February

–2
’13

’17

’14

’15

’16

’17

’18

NOTE: Each bar is a one-quarter growth rate (annualized);
the red line is the 10-year growth rate.

Rates on Federal Funds Futures on Selected Dates

Inflation-Indexed Treasury Yield Spreads
2.50

2.20
10-Year

5-Year

20-Year

2.00

2.00

1.80
Percent

2.25

1.75
1.50

07/26/17

12/13/17

09/20/17

01/31/18

11/01/17
1.60
1.40

1.25

1.20
March 16

1.00
’14

’15

’16

’17

1.00

’18

1st-Expiring
Contract

NOTE: Weekly data.

3-Month

6-Month

12-Month

Contract Settlement Month

Civilian Unemployment Rate

Interest Rates

8

4
10-Year Treasury

7

3
Percent

6
5

2
Fed Funds Target

1

4
3
’13

February
’14

’15

’16

’17

1-Year Treasury
February

0

’18

’13

’14

’15

’16

’17

’18

NOTE: On Dec. 16, 2015, the FOMC set a target range for the
federal funds rate of 0.25 to 0.5 percent. The observations
plotted since then are the midpoint of the range.

U.S. Agricultural Trade
90

Average Land Values Across the Eighth District
15.0

Exports

75
Billions of Dollars

(This article was first published online March 2.)

ENDNOTES

4

Year-Over-Year Percent Change

In January 2012, the Federal Open
Market Committee (FOMC) established
a 2 percent inflation target for the personal consumption expenditures price
index (PCEPI). Since then, inflation
has regularly been below the FOMC’s
target. In 2017, the PCEPI increased by
1.7 percent, which followed gains of 1.6
percent in 2016 and 0.4 percent in 2015.
But with the pace of economic activity
heating up and the unemployment rate
expected to fall slightly further in 2018,
the SPF projects that inflation will firm
to 1.9 percent in 2018 and to 2 percent
in 2020.
It is important to remember, though,
that the relationship between the unemployment rate and inflation—known as
the Phillips curve—is extremely weak
or nonexistent. As a result, it is generally thought to be highly unreliable as
a predictor of inflation.2 Market-based
measures of inflation expectations seem
to do a better job of predicting inflation.
In this regard, inflation expectations
embedded in Treasury securities have
moved steadily higher in 2018. Expected
inflation over the next five years and
over the next 10 years has averaged 1.95
percent and 2.07 percent, respectively,
since the start of 2018. However, both
year-to-date averages are up only 20
basis points since their averages in the
fourth quarter of 2017.

Consumer Price Index (CPI)

6

Percent

Inflation Developments

Real GDP Growth

Percent

unemployment rate will decline to an
average of 3.8 percent in the fourth
quarter of 2018 and remain at a 3.8 percent average in 2019, but then drift back
up to an average of 3.9 percent in 2020.

60
Imports

45
30
15

Trade Balance
0

’13

’14

’15

’16

January
’17

NOTE: Data are aggregated over the past 12 months.

’18

Quality Farmland

12.5

Ranchland or Pastureland

10.0
7.5
5.0
2.5
0.0
–2.5
–5.0

2016:Q4 2017:Q1

2017:Q2

2017:Q3

2017:Q4

SOURCE: Agricultural Finance Monitor.

On the web version of this issue, 11 more charts are available, with much of those charts’ data specific to the Eighth District. Among the
areas they cover are agriculture, commercial banking, housing permits, income and jobs. To see those charts, go to www.stlouisfed.org/
economyataglance.
REGIONAL ECONOMIST | www.stlouisfed.org 23

P.O. Box 442
St. Louis, MO 63166-0442
Address Service Requested

N E X T

I S S U E

Hispanic Human Capital

I

© THINKSTOCK/ISTOCK/JULIEF514

n 1950, Hispanics accounted for 1.6 percent of the U.S. labor force.
By 2016, they represented 13.4 percent of the country’s workers.
As the Hispanic workforce rapidly grows, its composition also
changes, with increasing diversity in education levels and occupations.
Alexander Monge-Naranjo, a St. Louis Fed economist, examines the
impact of this demographic change on the country’s human capital in
the Second Quarter issue of the Regional Economist.

Welcome to the New Regional Economist

W

e hope you like the changes we’ve made in the
print and online versions of the Regional Economist, starting with this issue. Among other things, we’ve
included key takeaways to highlight the author’s main
points. We also have a bit more info on the authors, as
well as their photos. In addition, we are posting articles
online at www.stlouisfed.org/re as soon as they are complete—about one every 10 days. This allows you to read
the RE’s fresh insights and analysis in a timely manner.
(To receive an email when a new article is posted, sign up
at www.stlouisfed.org/subscribe/regional-economist.)
When all of the articles for an issue are done, we will
continue to compile them into a quarterly magazine and
mail to those who have a print subscription.
If you want to tell us something about the changes,
please email our new managing editor at
Gregory.Cancelada@stls.frb.org.

ECONOMY AT A GLANCE
All data as of March 19
FIRST QUARTER 2018

Real GDP Growth

Percent Change from a Year Earlier

4

Percent

4

2

0
Q4

–2
’13

VOL. 26, NO. 1

Consumer Price Index (CPI)

6

’12

|

’14

’15

’16

CPI–All Items
All Items, Less Food and Energy

2

0

–2
’13

’17

February
’14

’15

’16

’17

’18

NOTE: Each bar is a one-quarter growth rate (annualized);
the red line is the 10-year growth rate.

Inflation-Indexed Treasury Yield Spreads

Rates on Federal Funds Futures on Selected Dates
2.20

2.50
10-Year

20-Year

2.25

2.00

2.00

1.80
Percent

Percent

5-Year

1.75

09/20/17

01/31/18

11/01/17
1.60

1.20

1.25
March 16

1.00
’14

’15

’16

’17

1.00
1st-Expiring
Contract

’18

NOTE: Weekly data.

3-Month

6-Month

12-Month

Contract Settlement Month

Civilian Unemployment Rate

Interest Rates

8

4
10-Year Treasury

7

3

6

Percent

Percent

12/13/17

1.40

1.50

5

2
Fed Funds Target

1

4
3
’13

07/26/17

February
’14

’15

’16

’17

1-Year Treasury
February

0

’18

’13

’14

’15

’16

’17

’18

NOTE: On Dec. 16, 2015, the FOMC set a target range for the
federal funds rate of 0.25 to 0.5 percent. The observations
plotted since then are the midpoint of the range.

U.S. Agricultural Trade
90

Average Land Values across the Eighth District
15.0
Year-Over-Year Percent Change

Exports

Billions of Dollars

75
60
Imports

45
30
15

Trade Balance
0

’13

’14

’15

’16

January
’17

NOTE: Data are aggregated over the past 12 months.

’18

Quality Farmland

12.5

Ranchland or Pastureland

10.0
7.5
5.0
2.5
0.0
–2.5
–5.0

2016:Q4 2017:Q1

2017:Q2

2017:Q3

SOURCE: Agricultural Finance Monitor.

2017:Q4

U.S. Crop and Livestock Prices
140

Index 1990-92=100

120

Crops
Livestock

100
80
60
40
’03

January
’04

’05

’06

’07

’08

’09

’10

’11

’12

’13

’14

’15

’16

’17

’18

COMMERCIAL BANK PERFORMANCE RATIOS

U.S. Banks by Asset Size/Fourth Quarter 2017
$300 millionLess than
$1 billion
$300 million

Less than
$1 billion

$1 billion$15 billion

Less than
$15 billion

More than
$15 billion

1.07

1.04

1.03

1.04

0.93

3.89

3.85

3.87

3.81

3.83

3.03

0.94

0.98

0.82

0.88

0.83

0.85

1.26

1.33

1.34

1.27

1.30

1.10

1.17

1.26

All

$100 million­$300 million

Return on Average Assets*

0.95

1.04

1.00

Net Interest Margin*

3.17

3.90

Nonperforming Loan Ratio

1.17

Loan Loss Reserve Ratio

1.24

Return on Average Assets*

Net Interest Margin*
1.09
1.12
1.36
1.33

0.25

0.50

Fourth Quarter 2017

0.75

Indiana
Kentucky
Mississippi
Missouri
Tennessee

1.03

1.00

1.25

1.50

Percent

Fourth Quarter 2016

Arkansas

0.99
0.88

1.02
0.92

Illinois

Fourth Quarter 2017

0.75

1.16
1.15

Kentucky
0.95
1.03

Mississippi

1.23
1.31

Missouri

1.00

0.78

Tennessee

0.94
1.25

Fourth Quarter 2016

SOURCE: Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council
Reports of Condition and Income for all Insured U.S.
Commercial Banks.
NOTE: Data include only that portion of the state within
Eighth District boundaries.
*Annualized data.

0.63
0.72

Indiana

1.10

0.63

0.74
0.64
0.78
0.64
0.83
0.69

1.03
1.13
1.08
1.11
1.07
1.13

Eighth District

0.90

0.74

0.50

Fourth Quarter 2016

Loan Loss Reserve Ratio

0.71

0.25

0.00 0.50 1.00 1.50 2.00 2.50 3.00 3.50 4.00 4.50
Fourth Quarter 2017

Nonperforming Loan Ratio

0.00

3.63
3.47
3.61
3.69
3.91
3.78
3.86
3.85
3.49
3.47
3.40
3.35

Illinois

1.14
1.12
1.03
0.99
1.04
1.08

0.00

4.14
4.15

Arkansas

0.93
0.99
0.86
1.00

0.82

3.75
3.72

Eighth District

Percent

0.00 0.20

0.40

0.60

Fourth Quarter 2017

0.80 1.00

1.09
1.20

Fourth Quarter 2016

For additional banking and regional data, visit our
website at https://fred.stlouisfed.org.

1.40

REGIONAL ECONOMIC INDICATORS

Nonfarm Employment Growth/Fourth Quarter 2017
Year-Over-Year Percent Change
United
States

Eighth
District †

Arkansas

Total Nonagricultural

1.5%

0.9%

0.7%

Natural Resources/Mining

7.8

–1.1

–3.3

Construction

3.3

1.3

Manufacturing

1.5

Trade/Transportation/Utilities
Information

Illinois

Indiana

Kentucky

0.9%

0.4%

–5.0

1.7

0.0

3.3

1.3

2.1

1.3

1.5

2.3

0.8

0.1

–1.0

0.8%

Mississippi

Missouri

0.9%

Tennessee

1.0%

1.3%

–2.4

4.9

3.4

–0.3

–1.4

1.4

3.1

1.5

0.0

0.8

1.1

1.0

–0.1

0.4

1.3

0.1

–0.2

0.1

–1.3

–2.9

–4.7

–4.0

–6.2

–1.7

–6.3

–0.4

–0.1

Financial Activities

1.8

1.4

1.7

1.3

1.2

–1.4

2.0

1.7

2.6

Professional & Business Services

2.3

1.0

1.5

0.6

0.9

–0.4

3.0

3.1

0.4

Educational & Health Services

2.1

1.7

1.1

1.2

2.8

0.8

3.0

1.7

2.2

Leisure & Hospitality

2.3

1.7

1.2

1.8

–0.7

1.1

2.4

1.9

3.9

Other Services

1.7

0.6

1.5

–0.1

0.1

1.8

–0.3

–0.1

2.2

Government

0.1

0.3

0.5

0.8

0.4

0.0

–0.3

0.3

0.3

† Eighth District growth rates are calculated from the sums of the seven states. Each state’s data are for the entire state even though parts of six of
the states are not within the District’s borders.

Unemployment Rates

District Real Gross State Product by Industry-2016

IV/2017

III/2017

IV/2016

United States

4.1%

4.3%

4.7%

Arkansas

3.7

3.7

3.8

Illinois

4.9

5.0

5.5

Indiana

3.4

3.6

4.1

Kentucky

4.5

4.9

5.2

Mississippi

4.8

5.0

5.6

Missouri

3.6

3.6

4.5

Tennessee

3.3

3.4

4.7

Information 3.4%
Trade/Transportation
Utilities
Manufacturing
18.7%

Financial Activities
Professional and
Business Services

18.4%

Educational and
Health Services

11.7%
16.6%

Construction
3.6%

Natural Resources/
Mining 1.8%

9.0%
10.8%

Leisure and
Hospitality 3.8%
Other Services 2.2%
Government

United States
$16,385 Billion
District Total
$1,932 Billion
Chained 2009 Dollars

Housing Permits/Third Quarter

Real Personal Income/Second Quarter

Year-Over-Year Percent Change in Year-to-Date Levels

Year-Over-Year Percent Change

6.2

1.0

17.8

9.7
12.5

Arkansas
Illinois

15.6

9.8

2.4
2.0

Kentucky

14.2

1.6

2017

0

5

0.3

–0.5

15

20

25

2016

NOTE: All data are seasonally adjusted unless otherwise noted.

30

Percent

2.9

0.8
0.3
0.3

0.8
0.7
0.8

Tennessee
10

1.8

0.7

Missouri

11.0

–5

–0.2

Mississippi

4.4
6.0

1.3

0.6

Indiana
25.1

–6.1

–10

1.1

United States

–1.0 –0.5 0.0
2017

0.5

1.0

2.9
1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

2016

NOTE: Real personal income is personal income divided by the
personal consumption expenditures chained price index.

3.5