View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Search



A

A

A

REAL ESTATE RESEARCH

ABOUT

April 5, 2012

REAL ESTATE RESEARCH
SEARCH

Real Estate Research provided
analysis of topical research and
current issues in the fields of housing

Debunking a popular myth about mortgage lending

Search

and real estate economics. Authors
for the blog included the Atlanta Fed's

In their research paper "The New Deal and the Origins of the Modern American

Jessica Dill, Kristopher Gerardi, Carl
Hudson, and analysts, as well as the

Real Estate Loan Contract in the Building and Loan Industry," Jonathan Rose
and Kenneth Snowden discuss financial innovation in the mortgage market in the

Assessing the Size and Spread of
Vulnerable Renter Households in

Boston Fed's Christopher Foote and
Paul Willen.

1930s. The main focus of the paper is the switch among building and loan
societies (B&L) from amortization-by-share-accumulation to amortization-by-

the Southeast
What's Being Done to Help Renters

In December 2020, content from Real
Estate Research became part of

direct-reduction. To the typical reader—even one interested in the mortgage
market—the topic sounds, to put it gently, quite esoteric. But I think this is an

during the Pandemic?
An Update on Forbearance Trends

Policy Hub. Future articles will be
released in Policy Hub: Macroblog.

excellent paper and highly relevant to anyone interested in the financial crisis.

Examining the Effects of COVID-19
on the Southeast Housing Market

Disclaimer

The authors systematically debunk a highly popular story about the history of
mortgage lending in the United States. Rather than explain the story, I will quote

Southeast Housing Market and
COVID-19

Email Me

Robert Kuttner, who exposited it in The American Prospect in July 2008:

Update on Lot Availability and
Construction Lending

RECENT POSTS

Subscribe by E-mail
Subscribe by RSS
Other Fed Websites
Comment Standards:
Comments are moderated and will
not appear until the moderator has
approved them.
Please submit appropriate
comments. Inappropriate comments
include content that is abusive,
harassing, or threatening; obscene,
vulgar, or profane; an attack of a
personal nature; or overtly political.
In addition, no off-topic remarks or
spam is permitted.

Before the Roosevelt era, virtually all mortgages were short term
loans of five years or less, typically interest-only, with the principal

Tax Reform's Effect on Low-Income
Housing

due and payable at the end. If the homeowner could not roll over the
loan, he lost the house. As foreclosures skyrocketed, the New Deal

Housing Headwinds
Where Is the Housing Sector

invented the modern, long-term, self-amortizing mortgage.

Headed?
Did Harvey Influence the Housing
Market?

Kuttner is not an economist, but most economists are equally fond of the story.
As Nobel Prize winner Franco Modigliani wrote, in a book coauthored with

CATEGORIES

industry expert Frank Fabozzi: "Until [the Depression], mortgages were not fully
amortized, as they are now..., but were balloon instruments in which the principal

Affordable housing goals

was not amortized, or only partially amortized at maturity, leaving the debtor with
the problem of refinancing the balance."

Credit conditions
Expansion of mortgage credit

Modigliani is not alone, as many economists who discuss the history of the

Federal Housing Authority
Financial crisis

mortgage market repeat some version of the story.1 In fact, it appears that the
only historical fact that most economists know about the mortgage market is that

Foreclosure contagion
Foreclosure laws

the federal government invented the amortizing mortgage during the Great
Depression.

Governmentsponsored enterprises
GSE

The myth of the balloon mortgage

Homebuyer tax credit
Homeownership

What Rose and Snowden document is that B&Ls, which started lending money
to borrowers in the 1830s, had never offered balloon products and had always

House price indexes
Household formations

demanded full amortization from their borrowers. B&Ls were the main source of
residential finance on the eve of the Depression, so Kuttner and Modigliani's

Housing boom
Housing crisis

reading of history is clearly missing something important. I will discuss the
sources of their misconception below, but first let me discuss what else Rose

Housing demand
Housing prices

and Snowden address in the paper.

Income segregation
Individual Development Account

Rose and Snowden show that a major and economically interesting change did
occur during the 1930s, but it wasn't the switch from balloon mortgages to fully

Loan modifications
Monetary policy

amortizing loans. Rather, it was a change in the way that amortization was done.
In the 19th century, the typical B&L mortgage, known as a "share-accumulation"

Mortgage crisis
Mortgage default

contract, was a combination of a perpetual interest-only loan and a forced-saving
scheme. When the accumulated forced saving equaled the balance of the loan,

Mortgage interest tax deduction
Mortgage supply

the savings were used to pay off the loan. To the borrower, the shareaccumulation contract appeared much like a fully amortized mortgage today, with

Multifamily housing
Negative equity

the borrower making a constant monthly payment until the loan was paid off.
There was a difference, however, because the forced saving was not explicitly

Positive demand shock
Positive externalities

used to pay down the loan, but rather was invested in shares in the B&L.

Rental homes
Securitization

In general, these shares were valued at par and paid dividends, which were
invested in additional shares in the B&L. The loan was considered to be paid off

Subprime MBS
Subprime mortgages

when the borrower's accumulated investment (deposits plus accumulated
dividends) reached the original mortgage balance.

Supply elasticity
Uncategorized

Because of the role that dividends played in the amortization schedule, share

Upward mobility
Urban growth

accumulation did expose the borrower to some risk. If interest rates fell or credit
losses were large, dividends might fall and, if credit losses were severe enough,
shares might trade below par. The result was that the timing of the payoff of the

loan was random, although until the Depression, it was almost always around 11
or 12 years. Starting in the 1870s, some lenders started allowing borrowers to
apply the forced saving directly to the balance of the loan to reduce it. B&Ls
slowly adopted the new design, called "direct reduction." Rose and Snowden
document that right before the Depression, most B&Ls still used the shareaccumulation system, but by the end, virtually all used the direct-reduction
system.
Switch to direct-reduction contract not the result of government policy
Rose and Snowden argue that the failure of the share-accumulation model
during the Depression, and not government policy, led to its demise. As
mentioned above, borrowers were exposed to credit risk through their
investment in B&L shares. During the Depression many B&Ls failed, undoing a
lot of the amortization that borrowers had done. Rose and Snowden show that
the rejection of the share-accumulation system across states was highly
correlated with the number of local B&L failures during the Depression.
It is important to stress here that the switch from share accumulation to direct
reduction is not what either Kuttner or the dozens of economists have in mind
when they discuss financial innovation during the Depression. The shareaccumulation mortgage was the antithesis of a balloon mortgage. The loan never
came due, and even when the borrower lost money on the forced-saving
scheme, as they did during the Depression, the borrower could keep the loan
current by making the interest and forced-saving payment. The failure of large
numbers of B&Ls during the Depression shows that short-term balloon payments
weren't the main reason for foreclosures.
Commercial banks were small players in Depression-era loans
The historical basis for the story about the role of the government in the
expansion of the fully amortized mortgage has to do with commercial banks,
comparatively small players in the mortgage market. Commercial banks limited
their offering to short-term, nonamortizing balloon instruments, but the banks
accounted for only about 10 percent of mortgage lending in the United States in
1929. Their unwillingness to make long-term, fully amortized loans did not result
from a failure of imagination or a lack of understanding of household finances but
rather from legislation and regulation that forbade them from making long-term
loans secured by real estate.2
The Homeowners Loan Corporation, set up by Congress in 1933 and the
Federal Housing Administration, which opened its doors shortly thereafter, did
insist on the direct-reduction design for all loans originated under their auspices,
but Rose and Snowden argue that this had little effect on the B&Ls, which were
rapidly moving in that direction anyway. Ironically, to allow commercial banks to
do FHA loans, Congress had to amend the National Banking Act. In other words,
the adoption of direct-reduction mortgages by commercial banks did not result
from the encouragement of policymakers but rather from the cessation of
discouragement.3
"Financial innovation" is incremental, not spontaneous
I am particularly pleased to see this paper, as I have been making this point in
speeches,4 blog posts and congressional testimony for many years, albeit with
much more limited evidence. In the interest of full disclosure, I must confess that
I myself had been seduced by the legend of the invention of the amortized
mortgage during the Depression, and for many years used it as an example in
macroeconomics lectures. It was only when I started researching the history of
the mortgage market in 2005 that I looked at the data and found that it wasn't
true. Let me say that virtually no economist who repeats the story cites any data
or even cites a study that uses data.
Debunking a popular story will get the most attention, but I believe Rose and
Snowden have a deeper, more important point to make. That point is that
financial innovation does not emerge as a bolt from the blue but typically reflects
the accretion of small changes over long periods of time. Rose and Snowden
describe that the emergence of the direct reduction mortgage as the dominant
contract in the United States in the 1930s was the result of 100 years of
incremental innovation. B&Ls, first created in England in the 18th century, came
to the United States in the 1830s and were temporary associations in which a
group of households would agree to contribute to a pool to provide loans to one
another until all the members of the association had homes. Over the next 40
years, B&Ls morphed into permanent institutions but still retained many
cooperative features. The direct reduction contract, imported from England like
the original B&L idea, appeared in the 1870s in Ohio, which had a particularly
innovative B&L industry.
Rose and Snowden argue that the incremental character of financial innovation
is similar to that of nonfinancial innovation. They write that:

Rosenberg (1982) provides a useful conceptual framework for
explaining the trajectory of innovations in the B&L industry. He
emphasizes that the unit of innovation is rarely a single invention;
instead, major productivity improvements are driven by the
accumulation of incremental changes that follow a path shaped by
compatibility with existing practices.
For researchers working on financial innovation, Rose and Snowden's paper
illustrates the importance of careful and thorough historical analysis of
institutions. Many researchers writing about the crisis that started five years ago
make little effort to document institutional facts and instead base theories on
speculation and hearsay. In recent years, researchers have argued that until the
boom of the 2000s, adjustable rate mortgages, negative amortization, and down
payments of less than 20 percent were rare or limited to sophisticated borrowers.
Careful analysis of the historical records shows that these loan features were no
rarer before the boom than fully amortized loans were before the Depression.
Another problematic claim is the popular idea that, during the 2000s, the
mortgage market transitioned from the originate-to-hold model, whereby lenders
hold mortgages on their books, to the originate-to-distribute model, whereby they
sell the loans to investors. Again, the data shows that the originate-to-distribute
model was widely used throughout the postwar era and emerged as the
dominant model of lending in the U.S. in the 1980s.
In conclusion, it is remarkable that despite the paucity of data and the fact that
anyone alive with direct knowledge of pre-Depression era lending is a
centenarian, Rose and Snowden know far more about mortgage markets in 1925
than many economists doing research on the mortgage market today do about
mortgage markets in 2005.
By Paul Willen, senior economist and policy adviser at the Boston Fed (with
Boston Fed economist Christopher Foote and Atlanta Fed economist Kristopher
Gerardi)
1

Rose and Snowden list five examples in addition to the two I cite, but there are
literally dozens more.
Back
2

Adam Gordon, "The Creation of Homeownership: How New Deal Changes in

Banking Regulation Simultaneously Made Homeownership Accessible to Whites
and Out of Reach for Blacks," 115 The Yale Law Journal 186 (2005): 194–96.
Back
3

Ironically, history would vindicate pre-Depression-era regulators' concerns
about long-term fixed rate mortgages. Excessive reliance on long-term fixed rate
mortgages bankrupted the savings and loan industry when interest rates rose in
the late 1970s.
Back
4

See slides 4–5 of this presentation at Harvard Business School in 2009.

Back
April 5, 2012 in Mortgage crisis, Mortgage supply | Permalink

Frequently Asked Questions

Careers

GDPNow
Inflation Project
Jobs Calculator
Market Probability Tracker
Speakers Bureau
Teacher Workshops

Contact Us
A to Z index
Follow the Fed
Publications
Disclaimer & Terms of Use
Online Privacy Policy

Wage Growth Tracker

Data Privacy Policy
Home

1000 Peachtree Street N.E.
Atlanta, Georgia 30309
404-498-8500

Careers