View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

Search



A

A

A

REAL ESTATE RESEARCH

ABOUT

February 19, 2014

REAL ESTATE RESEARCH
SEARCH

Real Estate Research provided
analysis of topical research and
current issues in the fields of housing
and real estate economics. Authors
for the blog included the Atlanta Fed's

Asymmetric Information and the Financial Crisis

Search
RECENT POSTS

In describing the $13 billion settlement reached between JPMorgan and the

Jessica Dill, Kristopher Gerardi, Carl
Hudson, and analysts, as well as the

Department of Justice last November, Attorney General Eric Holder said,

Boston Fed's Christopher Foote and
Paul Willen.

Without a doubt, the conduct uncovered in this investigation helped
sow the seeds of the mortgage meltdown. JPMorgan was not the

the Southeast
What's Being Done to Help Renters

In December 2020, content from Real
Estate Research became part of

only financial institution during this period to knowingly bundle toxic
loans and sell them to unsuspecting investors, but that is no excuse

during the Pandemic?
An Update on Forbearance Trends

Policy Hub. Future articles will be
released in Policy Hub: Macroblog.

for the firm's behavior.

Examining the Effects of COVID-19
on the Southeast Housing Market

Disclaimer
Email Me
Subscribe by E-mail
Subscribe by RSS
Other Fed Websites
Comment Standards:
Comments are moderated and will
not appear until the moderator has
approved them.
Please submit appropriate
comments. Inappropriate comments
include content that is abusive,
harassing, or threatening; obscene,
vulgar, or profane; an attack of a
personal nature; or overtly political.
In addition, no off-topic remarks or
spam is permitted.

Assessing the Size and Spread of
Vulnerable Renter Households in

What Holder describes sounds like a textbook example of what economists call
asymmetric information: JPMorgan knew something about the loans it was

Southeast Housing Market and
COVID-19

selling (that they were toxic) that they didn't reveal to investors. Specifically, the
government alleged that JPMorgan reported facts to the investors that turned out

Update on Lot Availability and
Construction Lending

to be wrong. For example, JPMorgan may have said that it made only 10 percent
of the loans in a pool to investors (as opposed to owner-occupants) when the

Tax Reform's Effect on Low-Income
Housing

actual percentage was 20 percent. So it would seem as if economic theory,
which has a lot to say about asymmetric information, should help us understand

Housing Headwinds
Where Is the Housing Sector

the crisis. Indeed, to many, asymmetric information and "bad incentives" are the
leading explanations of the financial crisis. For example, a Reuters article that

Headed?
Did Harvey Influence the Housing

described the settlement made the following claim:

Market?
CATEGORIES

The behavior that the largest U.S. bank admitted to, authorities said,
is at the heart of what inflated the housing bubble: lenders making

Affordable housing goals

bad mortgages and selling them to investors who thought they were
relatively safe. When the loans started turning bad, investors lost

Credit conditions
Expansion of mortgage credit

faith in the banking system, and a housing crisis turned into a
financial crisis.

Federal Housing Authority
Financial crisis

In future posts, we will consider this seemingly intuitive idea, and argue that the

Foreclosure contagion
Foreclosure laws

economic theory of asymmetric information, in fact, provides very little aid in
understanding the central questions of the crisis.

Governmentsponsored enterprises
GSE

Let's focus on Holder's quote. The standard theory of asymmetric information

Homebuyer tax credit
Homeownership

implies that JPMorgan's misrepresentations could not cause significant losses to
investors. That may seem surprising. Many may think that either we don't

House price indexes
Household formations

understand the economics of asymmetric information or it's just another example
of the naïveté of economists regarding how the real world actually works. While

Housing boom
Housing crisis

there is certainly no shortage of examples of economists holding naïve opinions
about the real world, in this case, we will argue that we are correctly

Housing demand
Housing prices

characterizing the economist's view and that it is based on a common-sense
argument.

Income segregation
Individual Development Account

Let's start with the economics. Let's assume that JPMorgan is selling a pool of

Loan modifications
Monetary policy

loans, about which it knows the true quality, to a group of buyers who can't
observe the true quality. What does economic theory say will happen?

Mortgage crisis
Mortgage default

A. Investors will overpay for the assets and lose money.

Mortgage interest tax deduction
Mortgage supply

B. Investors will underpay for the assets and make money.
C. Investors will infer the true quality of the loans and pay accordingly.

Multifamily housing
Negative equity

The answer is C. To many, that may sound shocking, but the basic logic is

Positive demand shock
Positive externalities

simple: investors know that they cannot observe the true quality of the loans and
they know that JPMorgan has an incentive to dump bad loans in the pool. Thus,

Rental homes
Securitization

they correctly infer that JPMorgan will dump bad loans in the pool. In other
words, investors form correct beliefs about the quality of a loan,1 despite not

Subprime MBS
Subprime mortgages

being able to observe quality directly.2

Supply elasticity
Uncategorized

"Knowingly bundl[ing] toxic loans" may be unethical or even illegal, but according
to the economic theory of asymmetric information, it shouldn't cause unexpected

Upward mobility
Urban growth

financial losses to investors. The key to understanding the gap between Holder
and economics is the word "unsuspecting." Economists assume that all market
participants are inherently suspicious. Market participants understand that the
people with whom they are doing business have an incentive to cheat them if
those people know more about the products that they are selling.

Are economists naïve to think that market participants can figure out the
incentives of their adversaries? We would argue that common sense says
people are pretty suspicious. Take, for example, real estate agents. A cursory
search on the internet yields the following table of "translations" of real estate
listings:
Loaded with Potential: means loaded with problems the seller didn't
want to tackle.
Cute: means they couldn't think of any other possible way to describe
it.
Great Bones: means you're going to have to gut it and rebuild.
Wooded/Shaded Lot: means surrounded by trees and leaves on the
ground.
Charming: means they couldn't think of a more appropriate word.
Needs a Little TLC: means it needs about $45,000 dollars or more in
renovations and repairs.
Won't Last Long at This Price: means the price is so low it will
compel you to see it but it will take a miracle for you to want to buy it.
No Disclosures: means you're going to have to find out all the
problems with the home on your own.
Most people read this and chuckle, but no one is surprised that real estate
agents stretch the truth. After all, it's their job to convince you to buy. And, in
general, people view salespeople as among the least ethical of all occupations,
only slightly above members of Congress. Perhaps the most egregious example
of this, and in fact the example that motivated the seminal paper on the
economics of asymmetric information, is used-car salespeople. Do used-car
salespeople try to misrepresent the quality of the cars that they are trying to sell?
Most people would likely answer this question with a resounding "Yes, of
course." Does this cause injury to most used-car buyers? Not so much. Since
the general public recognizes that "used-car salesman" is basically American
slang for a fraudster, nobody really believes what they say.
In subsequent posts, we will answer questions about the crisis that turn on
asymmetric information problems:
1. Theory says investors should have guessed the quality of the loans. Did
they?
2. If investors knew the quality of the loans they were buying, why did
JPMorgan pay $13 billion to settle accusations that it misrepresented the
quality of the loans it was selling?
3. Can't policymakers fix some of these incentive problems? Doesn't forcing
issuers such as JPMorgan to retain a portion of the securities they issue
align incentives and mitigate the asymmetric information problem?
4. If asymmetric information didn't cause investor losses, does that mean it
doesn't affect economic outcomes? (Spoiler: The answer is an emphatic
no.)
5. What about rating agencies? Didn't they know that deals were bad but lie
to investors and say they were good?
By Paul Willen, senior economist and policy adviser at the Federal Reserve Bank
of Boston, and

Kris Gerardi, associate economist and policy adviser at the Federal Reserve
Bank of Atlanta.

1

In some situations, investors will hold beliefs that may be wrong on an
individual asset-by-asset basis, but that are right on average. For example, they
might not know which loans are the most likely to default, but their beliefs about
the performance of the pool of loans will be, on average, right.
2

More generally, the revelation principle says that in any equilibrium of an

asymmetric information game, we can confine our attention to equilibria in which
all private information is fully revealed. For example, in Akerlof's (1970) example
of equilibrium in the used car market, the seller knows whether the car is a
peach or a lemon but only the lemons trade. Everyone knows which car is good
(the one that the dealer doesn't sell), but the buyer doesn't buy it because he
knows that the dealer would have an incentive to substitute a bad car.
February 19, 2014 in Financial crisis, Mortgage crisis, Subprime MBS,
Subprime mortgages | Permalink