The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
PRODUCTIVITY: A SELECTED, ANNOTATED BIBLIOGRAPHY 1965-71 Bulletin 1776 U.S. Department of Labor Bureau of Labor Statistics PRODUCTIVITY: A SELECTED, ANNOTATED BIBLIOGRAPHY 1965-71 Bulletin 1776 U.S. DEPARTMENT OF LABOR Peter J. Brennan, Secretary BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS Ben Burdetsky, Deputy Commissioner 1973 For sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C. 20402, GPO Bookstores, or BLS Regional Offices listed on inside back cover. Price $1.25 domestic postpaid or $1 over-the-counter. Make checks payable to Superintendent of Documents. Microfiche edition available from National Technical Information Service, Springfield, Va. 22151, at 95 cents a set. Make checks for microfiche payable to NTIS. Preface Productivity—the relation between physical output and input—has for many years been a subject of study in the Bureau of Labor Statistics of the U.S. Department of Labor. Productivity studies and research are conducted in the Bureau’s Office of Productivity and Technology. The interest in productivity derives from a number of concerns —the pace of technological change and its effects on employment and skills; the trend in prices and costs; and the rate at which additional goods and services become available. Thus, the study of productivity is essential in understanding the factors giving rise to variations in income and wealth and in determining economic policy. This bibliography, the third in a series, is intended to facilitate such study. It covers a large selection of books and articles that were published between 1965 and 1971. It provides annotated references for nearly 800 publications dealing with concepts and methods, measurement of levels and trends, the sources of productivity change (such as technology and economic growth), and the relation of productivity to the economy as a whole and to economic variables such as wages and prices. Most of the work on this bibliography was performed by Andrea Mooney Sweeny, under the supervision of Horst Brand, in the Division of Industry Productivity Studies. Others who contributed include Jack Ferris, Brian Friedman, and Barbara Donoghue. Martha Farnsworth Riche compiled the subject index. in Contents Page Annotated l i s ti n g .......................................... 1 Concepts and methods .......................... M easures............................................................................................................................................................ Factors affecting p ro d u ctiv ity ...................................................................................................................... A. Labor and education................................................................................................................... B. Management and organization................................................................................................... C. Technological change................................................................................................................... D. Research and development......................................................................................................... Productivity, prices, and c o s t s ...................................................................................................................... Productivity and em p lo y m en t....................................................................................................................... Productivity and economic grow th................................................................................................................. Theses and dissertations.................................................................................................................................. Bibliographies, annual reports, etc................................................................................................................... 1 15 27 27 34 38 53 59 68 78 85 89 Author i n d e x ................................................................................................................................................................. 92 Subject i n d e x ................................................................................................................................................................. 99 I. II. III. IV. V. VI. VII. VIII. IV A n n otated Listing I. Concepts and methods 1.001 taking intermediate products into account, result in output series which are highly suspect. Aigner, D. J. and Chu, S. F. “On Estimating the Industry Production Function.” American E conom ic Review, Vol. 58, No. 4, September 1968, p. 826-839. 1.005 Presents an estimation technique which allows the economist to make a traditional interpretation of an empirically estimated microproduction function, where the under lying production process is assumed to be deterministic. 1.002 The authors specify several production functions to allow for types of neutral tech nological change other than the Hicks or Harrod models. 1.006 Alterman, Jack, and Kutscher, Ronald E. Capital Flow Matrix, 1958, BLS Bulletin 1601. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1968. 72 pp. 1.007 American Machinist. The Tenth American M a ch in ist Inventory o f Metalworking Equipment, 1968. New York, McGraw-Hill, 1968.320 pp. 1.008 Anderson, W. H. L. “Production Scheduling, Intermediate Goods, and Labor Produc tivity.” American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 1, March 1970, pp. 153-162. Explores why short-run elasticity of man hours in relation to output is empirically less than 1, and why hours of input seem to respond to changes in output with a distributed lag. Maintains that studies of variation in labor productivity based on final product, rather than Borch, Karl. “Theories and Principles of Productivity Measurement at Different Levels.” Productivity Measurement Review, August 1965, pp. 5-15. Examines conceptual and practical problems in productivity measurement. Presents estimates of the number and age of metalworking machinery in the United States. 1.004 Berglas, Eitan. “Investment and Technological Change.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 73, No. 2, April 1965, pp. 173-180. Argues that studies by Solow, Kendrick, and Fabricant give insufficient weight to the effects of investment on economic growth. Tests empirically three hypotheses that suggest that observed technical change has a larger effect on the rate of investment than those studies imply. Shows in detail the transactions of capital goods among producing and using industries, and thus differs from conventional inputoutput tables, which distribute capital goods output directly to an overall category of “gross private domestic fixed capital formation.” 1.003 Beckmann, Martin J., and Sato, Ryuzo. “Aggre gate Production Functions and Types of Technical Progress: A Statistical Analysis.” American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 1, March 1969, pp. 88-101. Braae, G.P. “Indirect Measurement of Labor Productivity in House-Building in Britain, 1919-38.” Manchester School o f Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 35, No. 3, September 1968,pp. 275-84. Suggests a method for estimating labor productivity where data for inputs are lacking or unreliable. 1.009 1 Briscoe, G.; O’Brien, P.; and Smyth, D. J. “The Measurement of Capacity Utilization in the United Kingdom.” Manchester School o f Economic and Social Studies , Vol. 38, No. 1929-1967.” Review o f Income and Wealth, Vol. 16, No. 1, March 1970, pp. 19-50. 2, June 1970, pp. 91-117. The authors provide a conceptual basis for separating social product and social factor input accounts into estimated price and quantity components. The authors examine five methods of increasing capacity utilization in the United Kingdom for the period 1954-67. 1.010 Brown, Murray, ed. The Theory and Empirical Analysis o f Production. Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 31. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1967. 515 pp. 1.014 Defines differences in efficiency as any variation in output per worker unexplained by weighted differences in the capital-labor ratio. After discussing some data problems, author presents an array of estimates of efficiency for a group of manufacturing industries in a number of developing countries. A collection of papers summing up present knowledge on the structure of the production function, pointing out areas where more research is needed, and suggesting some new approaches. 1.011 Brubaker, E. R. “Embodied Technology, the Asymptotic Behavior of Capital’s Age, and Soviet Growth.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 50, No. 3, August 1968, pp. 304-311. 1.015 Explores the usefulness of the hypothesis of embodied technological change in studying the sources of growth of the Soviet economy. Interpreting the data within the framework of a Cobb-Douglas function, amended to reflect the effects of disembodied technical change and investment in education, fails to explain most of the “residual.” It was assumed that design changes in physical capital, implicit in changes in the age of capital, accounted for the residual. As opportunities for reducing the average age of capital decline, so will the contribution to growth from this source. 1.012 1.016 Christensen, L. R., and Jorgenson, D. W. “The Measurement of U.S. Real Capital Input, 1929-1967,” Review o f Income and Wealth, Vol. 15, No. 4, December 1969, pp. 293-320. Deakin, B.M. and Seward, T. Productivity in Transport: A Study o f Employment, Capital, Output, Productivity and Technical C hange. Occasional Papers, No. 17. Cambridge, England, Cambridge University Press, 1969. 248 pp. The authors measure employment, capital, output, labor productivity, and technical change in major sectors of surface and air transportation, and develop a production function to interpret the data. They probe for more fundamental explanations by testing hypotheses relating to the links between output Christensen, L. R., and Jorgenson, D. W. “U.S. Real Product and Real Factor Input, David, Paul A. “Labour Productivity in English Agriculture, 1850-1914: Some Quantitative Evidence on R egional Differences.” Economic History Review, Vol. 23, No. 3, December 1970, pp. 504-514. Derives estimates of labor productivity in different farming regions of England from data on daily wages paid to laborers and piece-rate quotations for well-defined tasks performed by hand methods. Patterns of labor efficiency closely correlate with geographical patterns of agricultural wage-rate differences. Argues that findings are consistent with the thesis that until recently many areas of England displayed features typical of economically under developed agrarian societies. The authors provide a conceptual basis for real capital input based on perpetual inventory estimates of capital stock and corresponding estimates of capital service prices. 1.013 Daniels, Mark R. “Differences in Efficiency among Industries in Developing Countries.” American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 1, March 1969, pp. 159-171. 2 1.021 and labor productivity; labor productivity and prices; output and technical change; and capital stock input and technical change. 1.017 de Leeuw, Frank. “A Revised Index of Manu fa c tu rin g Capacity.” Federal Reserve Bulletin, Vol. 52, No. 11, November 1966, pp. 1605-1615. Examines a version of the hypothesis that highly capital-intensive pursuits are well suited for underdeveloped countries because they force management to perform much-needed but unfamiliar tasks. Describes the methods used to calculate capacity and capacity utilization in manu facturing. Compares the revised indexes to those previously published. Sees a need for more thorough understanding of basic con cepts, better coverage of key manufacturing industries, and alternative approaches to collecting information on capacity. 1.018 1.022 1.023 Diamond, Peter A. “Disembodied Technical Change in a Two-Sector Model.” Review o f Economic Studies, Vol. 33 , No. 90, April 1965, pp. 161-168. 1.024 Du Boff, Richard B. “Electrification and Capital Productivity: A Suggested Approach.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 48, No. 4, November 1966, pp. 426-431. Presents evidence that there was a strong causal connection between industrial electrifica tion at the time of the first World War and the upward shift in the productivity trend at that time, as observed by Kendrick. Diamond, Peter A. “Technical Change and the Measurement of Capital and Output.” Review o f Economic Studies, Vol. 32(4), No. 92, October 1965, pp. 289-298. Asserts that equations which describe the development over time of an economy with disembodied technical change can also be used to describe differences in production with capital of different vintages in a model 'with embodied technical change. The rate of embodied technical change is estimated from aggregate data for the post-war U.S. economy. Domar, Evsey D. “An Index Number Tourna ment.” Quarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 81, No. 2, May 1967, pp. 262-272. Compares the Soviet-type index Of industrial production using value-of-output or price weights and the Federal Reserve-type index of value-added weights. Finds that both indexes contain biases when compared to certain alter native indexes. Presents and explains the use of a two-sector model for the measurement of technical change in consumption goods and investment goods, taking into account differences in the growth of labor inputs. 1.020 Doll, John P.; Rhodes, James V.; and West, Jerry G. Economies o f Agricultural Produc tion, Markets, and Policy. The Irwin Series in Economics. Homewood, 111., Richard D. Irwin, 1968. 557 pp. The authors discuss the economics of production and the algebra of production functions, as well as multiple factor input and product output models. Denison, E. F. “Some Major Issues in Produc tiv ity Analysis: An Examination of Estimates by Jorgenson and Griliches.” Survey o f Current Business, Part II, Vol. 49, No. 5, May 1969, pp. 1-28. Discusses the methodology and conclusions of the article by Jorgenson and Griliches reprinted in the same issue of the Survey. 1.019 Diaz Alejandro, Carlos F. “Industrialization and Labor Productivity Differentials.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 2, May 1965, pp. 207-214. 1.025 Fabricant, Solomon. A Primer on Productivity. New York, Random House, 1969. 206 pp. Introduces basic ideas about productivity. Discusses the sources of productivity, and relates productivity to business cycles, infla tion, and economic policy. Also discusses productivity abroad. 3 1.026 Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago. "‘Larger Farms—A Continuing Trend.” Business Con ditions, May 1969. pp. 7-13. 1.031 Sees a continued trend towards larger and fewer farms because of the inability of smaller farms to use machinery and labor efficiently or to provide operators with satisfactory incomes. Suggests a need for adjustment in methods of financing larger farms. 1.027 A collection of essays dealing with con ceptual and measurement problems of output and productivity in service industries. Among industries discussed are medical care, com mercial banks, and retail trade. Chapters also deal with service industries in Canada and with the development of service industries in the 19th century. Feinstein, C. H. Domestic Capital Formation in the United Kingdom, 1920-1938. Studies in the National Income and Expenditure of the United Kingdom. Cambridge, England, Cambridge University Press, 1965. 270 pp. 1.032 Derives estimates of gross and net capital formation and the capital stock for the economy as a whole and for the major sectors. Compares his methods and estimates with those of other economists. 1.028 Fenske, Russell W. “An Analysis of the Meaning of Productivity.” Productivity Measurement Review, August 1965, pp. 16-22. 1.033 1.034 Galatin, Malcolm. Economies o f Scale and Technological Change in Thermal Power Generation. ' Amsterdam, North-Holland Publishing Co., 1968. 196 pp. Presents econometric models of the produc tion process in a multiplant unit in order to explore the effects of technological change and economies of scale on steam-electric power generation. Reviews past studies. Fogel, Robert W., and Engerman, Stanley L., eds. The Reinterpretation o f American Economic History. New York, Harper and Row, 1971. 494 pp. 1.035 Presents a number of historical essays on capital formation, growth, innovation, and related subjects. Gaathon, A. L. Economic Productivity in Israel Praeger Special Studies in International Economics and Development. New York, Praeger, in cooperation with the Bank of Israel, 1971.280 pp. Discusses alternative theories and measure ments of productivity in estimating and ex p lain in g Is ra e l’s perform ance from 1950-65 (postscript 1965-69). Develops two models to appraise long-run productivity prospects. Ferguson, C. E. “Time Series Production Functions and Technological Progress in American Manufacturing Industry.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 73, No. 2, April 1965, pp. 135-147. Fits time-series data for 1949-61 covering two-digit American manufacturing industries to the production function suggested by Arrow, Chenery, Minhas, and Solow, to discover whether technological change in these indus tries has been biased. Finds most change has been either neutral or capital-using. 1.030 Fuchs, Victor R. “The First Service Economy.” The Public Interest, Winter 1966, pp. 7-17. Discusses the growth of services and of the labor force producing services rather than tangible goods. Explores reasons for this evolution, its benefits, and the difficulty of measuring productivity in services. States the need for appropriate measures of output. Examines alternate definitions and inter pretations of productivity. 1.029 Fuchs, Victor R., ed. Production and Produc tivity in the Service Industries. Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 34. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1969. 395 pp. 4 Geisel, John M. “A Method for Measurement and Analysis of Supervisory Work.” Journal o f Industrial Engineering, Vol. 19, April 1968, pp. 175-185. Argues that fundamental changes in the functions of the foreman have given rise to problems of determining the effectiveness with which foremen are performing their tasks. Establishes a number of criteria which permit management to deal with these problems. 1.036 been drastically underestimated since 1940, thus seriously skewing most production and productivity studies. This underestimation is due to the omission of government-owned, privately operated plant and equipment from the capital accounts. George, K. D. Productivity and Capital Expend iture in Retailing. Cambridge, England, Cambridge University Press, 1968. 86 pp. 1.040 Assesses the role of capital expenditures in increasing productivity in retailing in the United Kingdom, 1960-66. Also examines possible obstacles to growth and investment, such as shortages in management, high costs, inadequate financing, and difficulties in site acquisition. Disputes the Hirshman argument that process-centered industries and man-paced operations are particularly suited to raise labor productivity in less developed countries. 1.041 1.037. G old, Bela. Explorations in Managerial Economics: Productivity, Costs, Technology and Growth. New York, Basic Books, Inc., 1971. 297 pp. Contains chapters on productivity and on the economic effects of technological innova tions, providing brief, critical surveys of existing approaches to measurement. Suggests analytical and measurement techniques par ticularly suited to the analysis and evaluation of managerial (or operational) problems. 1.038 1.042 Golov, A. “Methodology of the Measurement and Planning of Labor Productivity in the U.S.S.R.” International Labour Review, Vol. 97, No. 5, May 1968, pp. 447-464. Green, H. A. J. “Embodied Progress, Invest ment, and Growth.” American Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 1, March 1966, pp. 138-151. Reinterprets the concept of “embodied technical progress,” as developed by Solow and Phelps. Argues that certain aspects of this concept must be viewed in terms of contrasting rates of change of technical progress in the investment and consumption sectors. 1.043 Gordon, Robert J. “ $45 Billion of U.S. Private Investment Has Been Mislaid.” American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 3, June 1969, pp. 221-237. Griliches, Zvi, and Jorgenson, Dale. “Sources of Measured Productivity Changes: Capital Input.” American Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 2, May 1966, pp. 50-61. The authors investigate the relation of changes in the structure of capital to established estimates of changes in total factor productivity from 1929 to 1964. They con clude that errors in measuring capital inputs have resulted in significant overstatement of productivity gains. Argues that the U.S. figures on the stock of capital available for private production have Gouverneur, J. Productivity and Factor Propor tions in Less Developed Countries: The Case o f Industrial Firms in the Congo. New York, Oxford University Press, 1971. 171 pp. Analyzes the long-run changes in the labor coefficient, the capital coefficient, capital intensity, and the occupational composition of the labor force in relation to output changes. Describes methods of measuring production and labor productivity within the framework of the system of planning and incentives recently introduced in the Soviet Union. Explains the new approach employed in ascertaining for planning purposes the economic basis for gains in labor productivity in enterprises and industry. 1.039 Gouvemeur, J. “Hirshman on Labor Produc tivity Differentials: An Empirical Analysis.” Bulletin, Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 32, No. 3, August 1970, pp. 259-265. 5 1.044 1.048 Grossling, William, and Dovring, Folke. “Labor Productivity Measurement: The Use of SubSystems in the Interindustry Approach, and Some Approximating Alternatives.” Journal o f Farm Economics, Vol. 48, No. 2, May 1966, pp. 369-377. A compendium of papers dealing primarily with the measurement of productivity in the trade sector. The authors seek to measure the benefit to the community of technological change in agriculture by developing a productivity index including both direct and indirect man-hours as input. 1.045 1.049 Gupta, S., and Steedman, I. “An Input-Output Study of Labor Productivity in the British Economy.” Bulletin, Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 33, No. 1, February 1971, pp. 21-34. 1.050 Hall, R. E. “Technical Change and Capital From the Point of View of the Dual.” Review o f Economic Studies, Vol. 35 (1), No. 101, January 1968, pp. 35-46. 1.051 Hunt, E. H. “Quantitative and Other Evidence of Labour Productivity in Agriculture, 1850-1914.” Economic History Review, Vol. 23, No. 3, December 1970, pp. 515-519. Criticizes a paper in the same issue of the Review by Paul A. David (see entry 1.010). Hamada, K. “Optimal Capital Accumulation by an Economy Facing an International Capital Market.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 77, No. 4, July, August 1969, pp. 684-697. 1.052 International Labor Office, Measuring Labor Productivity. Geneva, ILO, 1969. 172 pp. Provides a comprehensive survey of the methods and problems of measuring labor productivity. Reviews national productivity measures, explains difficulties in international comparisons, and suggests ways to improve international comparability of productivity statistics. Argues, on the basis of the neoclassical growth model, that capital borrowing (or lending) occurs when a country increases its capital more (or less) than its domestic savings. Defines optimal path of accumulation and examines its properties. Hogg, H. C.; Rankine, L. B.; and Davidson, J. R. “Estimating the Productivity of Irriga tio n W a te r.” Agricultural Economic Research, Vol. 22, Nc. 1, January 1970, pp. 12-17. The authors use the example of sugar cane irrigation on two Hawaiian sugar plantations to show how to incorporate known economic rela tionships into a production function which can be optimized by economists and managers. Develops certain basic notions of capital theory econometrically. Investigates the problem of the production function in terms of factor price functions, relating the wage to the price of machines’ services over time. 1.047 Hildebrand, George H., and Liu, Ta-Chung. Manufacturing Production Functions in the United States, 1957: A n Interindustry and Interstate Comparison o f Productivity. Ithaca, New York, New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations, Cornell University, 1965. 224 pp. The authors estimate production function coefficients for 15 2-digit manufacturing industries. The authors argue that gains in labor produc tivity in a given industry may be due to the substitution of manufactured products from outside the industry, so that “system” produc tivity may actually change little, if at all. They provide alternative measures of system produc tivity by means of input-output calculations. They find that their derived rates of change in productivity of individual industries differ significantly from those found by the conven tional approach. 1.046 Heskett, J. L., ed. Productivity in Marketing. Papers of the Theodore N. Beckman Symposium on Marketing Productivity, April 1965. Columbus, Ohio, College of Commerce and Administration, The Ohio State University, 1965. 88 pp. 6 1.053 Industrial Relations Research Association (December 29-30, 1968, Chicago, 111.), University ofWisconsin,Madison, pp. 129-135. Intriligator, Michael D. “Embodied Technical Change and Productivity in the United States, 1929-1958.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 1, February 1965, pp. 65-70. Argues for ex p a n d ed analyses of productivity and discusses the conceptual aspects of such expansion. Estimates embodied and disembodied tech nical change using a Cobb-Douglas production function. 1.054 1.058 Jack Faucett Associates, Inc. Development o f a Matrix o f Interindustry Transactions in Capital Goods in 1963. Prepared for the Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor. Silver Spring, Md., Jack Faucett Associates, December 1966. 117 pp. The authors explain the meaning and uses of company productivity measures and describe procedures and problems involved in their construction. Includes case studies of how six companies measured their productivity. Estimates the output and consumption of capital goods by in dusty. Presents matrix tables of capital expenditures for the producing and consuming industries. 1.055 1.059 Jorgenson, Dale W. “The Embodiment Hypo thesis.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 74, No. 1, February 1966, pp. 1-17. Jorgenson, Dale W., and Griliches, Zvi. “The Explanation of Productivity Changes.” Review o f Economic Studies, Vol. 34, No. 99, July 1967, pp. 249-284. 1.060 The authors argue that if real product and real factor input are accurately accounted for, the observed growth in total factor productivity is negligible. They find that the rate of growth of input explains 96.7 percent of the rate of growth of output; change in total factor p ro d u c tiv ity ex p lain s the re st. The accumulation of knowledge is governed by the same economic laws as any other process of capital accumulation—costs must be incurred if benefits are to be achieved. 1.057 Kim, S. “Interregional Differences in Neutral Efficiency for Manufacturing Industries: An Empirical Study.” Journal o f Regional Science, Vol. 8, No. 1, Summer 1968, pp. 19-27. Formulates an index of specialization as part of the Cobb-Douglas function. Finds that in six cases productivity is favorably influenced by diversification, while in three cases it is not. 1.061 Kendrick, John W. “An Evaluation of Produc tivity Statistics.” Proceedings o f the T w enty-F irst Annual Winter Meeting, Kennedy, R. V. “The Meaning and Measure ment of Potential National Production in Australia.” Economic Record, Vol. 32, No. 3, August 1970, pp. 219-229. Derives quarterly nonfarm potential GNP for the period 1950-69. Links peaks in real output and extrapolates the trend rate of real GNP growth from a full employment peak. Also derives potential GNP from relationships between unemployment and changes in real output, and from an aggregate production function technique. C onstructs a mathematical model of embodied technical change free of Solow’s assumptions that technical change takes place at a constant exponential rate and that con sumer and investment goods as conventionally measured are perfect substitutes in production. 1.056 Kendrick, John W., and Creamer, Daniel. Measuring Company Productivity: Hand book with Case Studies. Studies in Business Economics, Number 89. New York, The Conference Board, 1965. 120 pp. Kleiman, E.; Halevi, N.; and Levhari, D. “The Relationship Between Two Measures of T otal Productivity.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 48, No. 3, August 1966, pp. 345-347. The authors show mathematically the biases in the productivity measures of Kendrick and 7 Solow. They show why the two measures may yield very different results in a rapidly developing economy. 1.062 The authors probe the feasibility of measuring productivity in the Federal Aviation Administration and examine measures applying to the agency as a whole, to its organizational components, and to its missions. Test results confirm the feasibility of measuring produc tivity of most of the components and missions as well as of the agency as a whole. Klotz, Benjamin P. Industry Productivity Pro jections: A Methodological Study. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1966. 5 pp. 1.067 Explores whether plants with high produc tivity levels can serve as a guide to projecting future productivity increases in an industry. Finds that data on “second-best” plants may be used to predict industry productivity 7 years later. 1.063 Shows that man-hour productivity data evidence a strong cyclical component in addi tion to the secular trend. Productivity falls when output falls, and then rapidly increases from the trough. This econometric study explains the theory and origins of this phenomenon. Klotz, Benjamin P. Productivity Analysis in Manufacturing Plants. BLS Staff Paper 3. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1970. 97 pp. Uses both the Cobb-Douglas and the con stant elasticity of substitution production functions to estimate the economies of scale and elasticities of substitution in 23 industries. 1.064 1.068 Klotz, Benjamin P. “Projecting Industry Productivity.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 89, No. 5, May 1966, pp. 514-517. 1.069 Kovalick, Peter N., and Moundalexis, John. Feasibility o f Measuring Federal Aviation Administration Productivity. U.S. Depart ment of Transportation, Federal Aviation Administration, June 1967. La Tourette, J. E. “Sources of Variation in the Capital-Output Ratio in the United States Private Business Sector.” Kyklos, Vol. 18, No. 4, 1965, pp. 635-651. Examines the sources of variation in the capital coefficient for the U.S. private sector during the 1909-1959 period. They are the composition of capital, the age of capital, and the nature of technical progress. These sources are measured by the ratio of plant to equipment, the weighted age of the stock of capital, and a proxy time trend. Knudsen, John W. “Productivity Changes.” Monthly Review, *Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, April 1971, pp. 3—9. Discusses measurement problems as well as the sources of gains in productivity. 1.066 La Tourette, J. E. “Aggregate Factors in the Trends of Capital-Output Ratios.” Canadian Journal o f Economics, Vbl. 3, No. 2, May 1970, pp. 255-275. E xam ines fa cto rs associated with the movement of capital coefficients in the United States and Canada. Finds that economic growth in Canada is secured only with a reduction in the rate of return and an accumulation of capital in excess of the increase in output. Describes a method of projecting produc tivity 6 to 8 years ahead by comparing current productivity of second-best-practice establish ments with the average for all establishments. S e co n d -b est-p ra ctic e establishments are generally 6 to 8 years behind best-practice establishments in the level of productivity they have reached. 1.065 Kuh, Edwin. “Cyclical and Secular Labor Productivity in U.S. Manufacturing.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 1, February 1965, pp. 1-12. 1.070 8 Lessowski, Witold. Capital-Output-Employment Ratios in Industrial Programming. Translated from the Polish by J. Syskind. New York, Pergamon Press, 1965. 225 pp. Discusses changes in underemployment, which are defined as changes in output per man that accompany fluctuations in aggregate demand and output. Suggests that when the government adjusts the level of aggregate demand, it should aim to balance the cost of inflation against the cost of underutilization, including the cost of underemployment. Carries out a detailed theoretical and statistical analysis of productivity and capital/ labor ratios, with a view to their use in industrial planning and the evaluation of economic policy in Poland. 1.071 Levhari, D., and Samuelson, P. “The Non switching Theorem is False.” Quarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 80, No. 4, November 1966, pp. 518-519. 1.075 The authors discuss aspects of the “switching theorem,” according to which one set of techniques may be replaced by another when the rate of interest declines, to be reinstituted as the rate declines still further. The authors retract a theory they had advanced earlier, according to which no switching would occur under certain assumptions of the composition of production techniques. Argues that the factors of production are “quantity augmenting” : that is, any improve ment in the quality of a factor of production may be treated as an increase in the quantity of that factor, holding quality constant. 1.076 1.072 Lou, L. J., and Yotopoulos, P. A. “A Test for Relative Efficiency and an Application for Indian Agriculture.” American Economic Review, Vol. 61, No. 1, March 1971, pp. 94-109. 1.077 Lucas, R.E., Jr. “Tests of a Capital-Theoretic Model of Technological Change.” Review o f Economic Studies, Vol. 34, No. 2 (98), April 1967, pp. 175-189. 1.078 new BLS price indexes which trends in 4-digit industries, in wholesale price indexes, which in commodity markets. Moss, M. “Needs for Consistency and Flexi bility in Measures of Real Product by Industry.” Review o f Income and Wealth, Vol. 14, No. 1, March 1968, pp. 1-17. Discusses the impact of disparities between industrial production and gross product in manufacturing on the analysis of relations between prices and output and prices and productivity. Recommends improvements in data and concepts. Masters, Stanley H. “The Behavior of Output Per Man During Recessions: An Empirical Study of Underemployment.” Southern Economic Journal', Vol. 33, No. 3, January 1967, pp. 388-394. Moss, Bennett R. “Industry and Sector Price Indexes.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 8, August 1965, pp. 974-982. Discusses reflect price contrast to reflect trends Treats the problem of “residual growth” — i.e., that part of growth unaccounted for by increases in labor and capital inputs - in terms of technological change resulting from the allocation of inputs away from current production into what may be called “tech nological investment.” 1.074 “Measuring how Office Workers Work.” Business Week, November 14, 1970, pp. 54-60. Discusses the methods and the increasing importance of measuring clerical work. The authors introduce a new method for measurement of relative economic efficiency between two or more firms. They take into account differences in technical and pricing efficiency. They apply the method to Indian agriculture. 1.073 McCarthy, M.D. “Quantity-Augmenting Tech nical Progress and Two-Factor Production Functions: A Skeptical Note.” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 33, No. 1, July 1966, pp. 71-80. 1.079 9 Muller, Charlotte, and Worthington, Paula. “The Time Structure of Capital Formation: Design and Construction of Municipal Hospital Projects.” Inquiry, Vol. 6, No. 2, June 1969, pp. 42-52. Examines the relation between output, employment, and capital stock in 14 industry groups in Great Britain, 1948-64. Finds that production has become more capital intensive in all groups despite their differing characteris tics. In all manufacturing (except textiles) and construction, labor productivity has increased, owing to a balance of factors involving faster growth in capital stock than in output, and substantially faster growth in stock than in the labor force. The authors examine the problem of translating capital funding into plant and equipment within the municipal hospital system of New York City. They deal with the question of why only one-half of funds budgeted for hospital construction are actually spent. 1.080 Nadiri, M. Ishaq. “Some Approaches to the Theory and Measurement of Total Factor Productivity.” Journal o f Economic Litera ture, Vol. 8, No. 4, December 1970, pp. 1137-1177. 1.085 Discusses the major contributions to the literature in recent years, and presents an authoritative list of source materials. 1.081 A detailed introduction to the interpretation of productivity concepts, measurement of productivity in industry and agriculture, and the problems of international productivity comparisons. Nance, Harold W. “Five Techniques for Measuring Clerical Work.” The Office, Vol. 66, No. 5, May 1967, pp. 12-14. Examines the pros and cons of five approaches to the measurement of clerical output. 1.082 1.083 1.086 Nesvera, Vaclav. “Capital Stock Require ments.” Czechoslovak Economic Papers, No. 5. Prague, Czechoslovak Academy of Sciences, 1965, pp. 57-69. North, Douglas C. “Capital Formation in the United States during the Early Period of Industrialization: A Re-examination of the Issues.” The Reinterpretation o f American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley T. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971, pp. 274-281. Analyzes the factors which determine the level and dynamics of capital stock require ments, with special attention to the causes of differences in capital requirements between different industries. Argues for a broadening of the definition of capital formation beyond the savingsinvestment nexus to cover all expenditures .which raise productivity, including those for health and education. Nevile, J.W. “How Productive is Australian Capital?” Economic Record, Vol. 43, No. 103, September 1967, pp. 405-411. 1.087 Calculates the output-capital ratio for five countries and uses the findings as a yardstick to appraise the productivity of Australian capital. Concludes that the -output-capital ratio is lower in Australia than it is in the five countries reviewed. 1.084 Nishikawa, Shunsaku, and Yamada, Saburo. Productivity Measurement Manual Tokyo, Asian Productivity Organization, 1969. 165 pp. Based on work by Joan Robinson, this article corrects some errors in her argument and develops a criterion for the choice of techniques under full employment of labor. Evaluates the nature of obsolescence in a socialist economy. Nicholson, R. J. “ Capital Stock, Employment and Output in British Industry 1948-64.” Yorkshire Bulletin o f Economics and Political Science, Vol. 18, No. 2, November 1966, pp. 1-21. Okishio, N. “Technical Choice Under Full Employment in a Socialistic Economy.” The Economic Journal, Vol. 76, No. 303, September 1966, pp. 585-592. 1.088 10 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, Productivity Measurement, Volume III. Paris, OECD, 1966.434 pp. Asserts that if increases in one factor raise the marginal productivity of other factors, the demand for factors by competitive firms always displays complementarity between the factors. A compendium of monographs from 15 member countries describing methods of measuring industry productivity. 1.089 Paelinck, Jean. “Programming — Projection — Productivity.” Productivity Measurement Review, February 1965, pp. 23-32. 1.094 Discusses the principal factors determining the productivity of different industries. Points out that high productivity-production ratios are associated with high levels of capital investment. 1.090 The authors discuss certain aspects of the “switching theorem” , according to which a set of techniques may be replaced by another set when the rate of interest declines, to be reinstituted when it declines still further. Parker, William N. “Productivity Growth in American Grain Farming: An Analysis of Its 19th Century Sources,” in The Reinterpreta tion o f American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley T. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971, pp. 175-186. Argues that productivity growth is due to the response of entrepreneurs, workers, and investors to certain opportunities, in particular the opportunities to employ growing supplies of productive factors, and to utilize improve ments in knowledge about how to combine these factors. Assesses these opportunities in the light of statistical data. 1.091 1.096 1.097 Rymes, Thomas K. On Concepts o f Capital and Technical Change. Cambridge, England, Cambridge University Press, 1971. 191 pp. Rymes, Thomas K. “Professor Read and the Measurement of Total Factor Productivity.” Canadian Journal o f Economics, May 1968. Argues that by developing measures of technological change, prediction of the course of relative prices, real wage rates, and the price of capital goods is possible. Total factor productivity measures can also be developed. “Productivity: Big Challenge for ' l l ” Modern Manufacturing, January 1971, pp. 48-61. 1.098 Rader, T. “Normally, Factor Inputs Are Never Gross Substitutes.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 76, No. 1, January-February 1968, pp. 38-43. Roman, Zoltan. “Alternative Measures of Productivity: Examples from Hungarian In d u s tr y .” Productivity Measurement Review, No. 43, November 1965. Budapest, Central Bureau of Statistics, pp. 12-16. Examines the problems of defining and measuring capital. Argues in support of the Harrod-Robinson concept of capital, rejecting as invalid the “neo-Walrasian” theories advanced by American economists. Philpot, G. “Labor Quality, Returns to Scale, and the Elasticity of Factor Substitution.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 52, No. 2, May 1970, pp. 194-199. Provides a number of yardsticks for measuring productivity at the company level. 1.093 1.095 Discusses alternative measures of labor productivity in mining and manufacturing industries for the period 1958-1963. Presents a test of the elasticity of substitu tion between capital and labor in 16 industries. Even allowing for differences in the quality of labor, 15 of the 16 industries had the same elasticity of factor substitution, and 12 showed constant returns to scale. 1.092 Robinson, Joan, and Naqui, K.A. “The Badly Behaved Production Function.” Quarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 81, No. 4, pp. 580-591. Sahota, G. S. “Efficiency of Resource Alloca tion in Indian Agriculture.” American Journal o f Agricultural Economics, Vol. 50, No. 3, August 1968, pp. 584-605. Presents an analysis of resource allocation in Indian agriculture. Average and marginal 11 productivity differences are derived for a number of inputs in the production of different crops. Concludes that there are relatively few inefficiencies in resource allocation in Indian agriculture. 1.099 1.103 Sahota, G. S. “The Sources of Measured Productivity Growth: U.S. Fertilizer-Mineral Industries, 1936-1960.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 48, No. 2, May 1966, pp. 193-204. Examines productivity and the factors affecting it. Holds that measuring output by constant dollar sales causes overestimation of productivity growth. Constructs an incomeprice model to obtain more accurate results. Shows that in the industries under study a little less than one-third of the change in the overall index of output per unit of input is explained by scale economies and the remainder by intrafirm technical progress. Of the intrafirm technical change, about half is accounted for by improvements in the quality of labor and about a quarter by improvements in the quality of capital. 1.100 1.104 Salkin, Jay S. “Land Size and Patterns of Resource Use and Productivity in South Vietnam ese Rice Production.” Asian Economic Review, Vol. 12, No. 2, August 1970, pp. 196-216. 1.105 Samuelson, Paul A. “A Summing Up.” Quarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 80, No. 4, November 1966, pp. 568-583. 1.106 Sawney, P. K. “Productivity Trends in Indian Cement Industry.” Asian Economic Review, Vol. 9, No. 3, May 1967, pp. 255-271. Solo, Robert A. “The Meaning and Measure of Economic Progress.” Technology and Culture, Vol. 9, No. 3, July 1968. pp. 389-414. Evaluates problems, techniques, and limita tions implicit in the measurement of economic progress as an indicator of human welfare and the quality of culture. Examines total factor productivity, with an explanation of methodology. Emphasizes the sharing of productivity gains by input factors. Also investigates productivity trends at regional levels. Sherrard, William R. “Labor Productivity for the Firm: A Case Study.” Quarterly Review o f Economics and Business, Vol. 7, No. 1, Spring 1967, pp. 49-61. Presents a case history of labor productivity in a lumber firm, with the following objectives: (1) to identify the factors which caused labor productivity to change; (2) to make inferences concerning the development of the lumber industry in the Pacific Northwest; and. (3) to determine the importance of company-level labor productivity studies to management and to economic historians. Summarizes and interprets results of a symposium on “reswitching” , papers from which were reprinted in this issue of the Jounal. “Reswitching” refers to the possibility that declining interest rates may cause consumption to rise relative to saving on a transient basis. 1.102 Shaw, L. H. “Alternative Measures of Aggregate Inputs and Productivity in Agriculture.” Journal o f Farm Economics, Vol. 49, No. 3, August 1967, pp. 670-683. Asserts that certain inconsistencies exist in the current measurement of aggregate inputs and productivity in agriculture. Offers an alternative way of measuring the components of aggregate agricultural production which affords consistent treatment. Investigates production functions and patterns of resource use on rice farms of different sizes in South Vietnam. Argues that there is overutilization of labor on small farms and underutilization on larger farms. 1.101 Schwartzman, David. The Decline o f Service in Retail Trade: An Analysis o f the Growth o f Sales per Man-Hour, 1929-1963. Study No. 48. Pullman, Wash., College of Economics and Business, Washington State University, June 1971.261 pp. 1.107 12 Stephenson, Samuel S. “A Four-Level Quantita tive Measurement of Company Produc- cannot be considered as measures of social productivity. Such measures would include changes in the use of past labor, and would reflect the share of the production sector under study in the total. Uses input-output methods to develop what may be interpreted as a measure of total factor productivity. tivity.” Productivity Measurement Review, No. 42, August 1965, pp. 61-69. Outlines methods for constructing partial and total factor productivity indexes for companies and their departments. 1.108 Temin, Peter. “Steam and Waterpower in the Early 19th Century,” in The Reinterpreta tion o f American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley T. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971. pp. 228-237. 1.112 Examines the use of stationary steam engines in America around 1840. Explores characteristics of their supply and draws comparisons with England. Discusses the • factors underlying the choice between steam and water power in various industries. 1.409 Presents views on the functions of Govern ment in an enterprise system; institutional factors affecting efficient public expenditure policy; problems of analysis in evaluating public expenditure alternatives; the current status of the planning-programming-budgeting system; the performance of program budgeting and analysis in the Federal Government; and a discussion of unresolved issues in major policy areas. Thornton, J. “Value-Added and Factor Produc tivity in Soviet Industry.” American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 5, December 1970, pp. 863-871. Develops new estimates of value added in Soviet industry for the period 1955-67. Estimates shares of labor and capital. Explains growth in output from growth in inputs, and presents estimates of Soviet productivity. h i 10 1.113 Thurow, Lester C. “Disequilibrium and the Marginal Productivities of Capital and Labor.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 50, No. 1, February 1968, pp. 23-31. 1.114 Tlusty, Zdenek. “Measuring the Productivity of Labor from the Standpoint of the Reproduc tion Process.” Czechoslovak Economic Papers, No. 5. Prague, Czechoslovak Academy of Sciences, 1965. pp. 71-89. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. BLS Handbook o f Methods for Surveys and Studies, BLS Bulletin 1711,1971, pp. 213-235. These four chapters give background and explain derivation of data on output per man-hour for the private sector as a whole and for a variety of industries, discuss the Bureau’s program of studies of technological change, and describe the series on labor and material requirements in construction. Argues that indexes of productivity based on the ratio of goods produced to labor inputs U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee. The Pla nning-Programming-Budgeting System: Progress and Potentials. Hearings before the Subcommittee on Economy in Government, September 14, 19-21, 1967. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1967.412 pp. Presents views of government officials and academic experts on efficiency in government, together with budgetary and other pertinent data. Argues that estimates of the marginal productivity of both capital and labor in the United States suggest a disequilibrium. The marginal product of capital is smaller than the actual returns to capital, while the marginal product of labor is larger than the actual returns to labor. 1.111 U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee. The Analysis and Evaluation o f Public Expendi tures: The PPB System. A compendium of papers submitted to the Subcommittee on Economy in Government. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1969. Three volumes, 1,241 pp. 13 1.115 input-output tables, especially at the sector level. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Industrial Productivity Measure ment in the United States. Mimeographed. Office of Productivity, Technology, and Growth, January 1970. 15 pp. 1.120 D escribes the industrial productivity program of the U.S. Government. Outlines the methodology used to develop output per man-hour measures. 1.116 U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Meaning and Measurement o f Productivity, BLS Bulletin 1714, 1971. 15 pp. Contains articles by Jerome A. Mark and Herbert Stein. Prepared for the National Commission on Productivity. The authors demonstrate an optimal solu tion under conditions of imperfect knowledge for problems of technological choice in multi-product capacity situations. 1.121 Explains why productivity increase is important to the economy, how it is measured, and why it is difficult to measure. 1.117 1.122 1.123 Yoshihara, K.; Furuya, K.; and Suzuki, T. “The Problem of Accounting for Productivity Change in the Construction Price Index.” Journal o f the American Statistical Associa tion, Vol. 66, No. 333, March 1971, pp. 33-41. The authors examine the problem of estimating a price index for an industry whose output is not standardized, such as construc tion. They formulate an input cost and input productivity index for the Japanese construc tion industry, and find that the input cost index increases twice as fast as the input productivity index. Also find that the input productivity index approximates a hedonic Watanabe, Tsunehiko. “A Note on Measuring Sectoral Input Productivity.” Review o f Income and Wealth, Vol. 17, No. 4, December 1971, pp. 335-340. Explores the relation between total factor productivity derived from national income accounts and total factor productivity based on Worton, David A. “New Productivity Measures in Canada,” in American Statistical Associa tion, Proceedings o f the Business and Economic Statistics Section, 1965, pp. 158-161. Describes the Canadian government’s program for measuring productivity. Van Dussen, P. E. “Aggregate Production Relationships in Ten Manufacturing Indus tries in South Africa.” Finance and Trade Review, Vol. 9, No. 1, June 1970, pp. 21-42. Fits industry data to a Cobb-Douglas production function. Uses results to estimate returns to scale, elasticity of substitution, and the rate and nature of technological change. 1.119 Wohlmuth, Karl. “The Growth of the Capital Stock in the Soviet Union.” Kyklos, Vol. 23, No. l,p p . 122-132. Presents a review of Soviet Capital Stock, 1928-1962, by Richard Moorsteen and Raymond P. Powell, in which theories of Soviet economic growth in general and the lack of adequate data are critically discussed. Usher, Dan. “Income as a Measure of Productivity: Alternative Comparisons of Agricultural and Nonagricultural Produc tivity in Thailand.” Economica, Vol. 33, No. 132, November 1966, pp. 430-441. Discusses possible biases in agricultural statistics tending to understate productivity in agriculture. Implicitly criticizes policies pro moting the transfer of labor out of agriculture when such policies are based on inadequate or fallacious statistics. 1.118 Wein, Harold H., and Sreedharan, V.P. The Optimal Staging and Phasing o f Multi product Capacity. MSU Studies in Com parative and Technological Planning. East Lansing, Mich., Institute for International Business and Economic Development Studies, Division of Research, Graduate School of Business Administration, Michigan State University, 1968. 131 pp. 14 output index for a specified type of construc tion much more closely than an input cost index. 1.124 2.003 Yotopoulos, P. A.; Lau, J. J.; and Somel, K. “Labor Intensity and Relative Efficiency in In d ian Agriculture.” Food Research Institute Studies in Agricultural Economics, Trade and Development, Vol. 9, No. 1, 1970, pp. 43-55. Discusses the short-run decline in produc tivity in a number of selected industries between 1966 and 1967. Attributes part of the decline to lower utilization of capacity. 2.004 The authors argue that conventional averages of output per unit of input do not reveal the relative degree of economic efficiency of large as against small farms. Production functions may vary between the two categories or they may be nonhomothetic. Technical and price efficiency may differ, and market conditions faced by these farms may also differ. They use Indian data to test these arguments. They propose that efficiency be measured by means of a decision rule, such as profit maximization. 2.005 Adelman, Edwin, and Ardolini, Charles. “Productivity in the Soft Drinks Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 12, December 1970, pp. 28-30. 2.006 Ball, Claiborne M. “Employment Effects of Construction Expenditures.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 2, February 1965, pp. 154-158. Compares the labor requirements, both on-site and off-site, of single-family housing, hospital, highway, and various other types of construction. Alburo, Florian, A. “Philippine-United States Industrial Productivity Differences.” The Philippine Economic Journal, Vol. 9, No. 1, First Semester, 1970, pp. 1-16. 2.007 Finds that differences in productivity between countries arise from differences in the rates at which technological change is absorbed. Presents evidence from the United States and the Philippines. Disputes the conventional theory that the ratio of capital to labor determines productivity. Auer, L. “Labor Productivity in Agriculture, A Canada-U.S. Comparison.” Canadian Journal o f Agricultural Economics, Vol. 18, No. 3, November 1970, pp. 43-55. Contrasts postwar trends in labor produc tivity in Canada and the United States, finding Canadian productivity to be 25-35 percent lower. Urges more concentrated research Li all aspects of Canadian agricultural economics. The authors explain that the rapid rise in productivity in the soft drinks industry between 1958 and 1968 was a result of large output increases, technological improvements, larger establishments, new products, and increases in capital expenditures. 2.002 Auer, L. Canadian Agricultural Productivity. Staff Study No. 24. Ottawa, Economic Council of Canada, December 1969. 101 pp. Compares the productivity performance of Canadian and U.S. agriculture, identifies sources of growth, and explores the potential for future productivity gains. II. Measures 2.001 Ardolini, Charles W. “Output Per Man-Hour in S elected Industries.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 3, March 1970, pp. 54-55. Ball, Claiborne M. Labor and Material Require ments for Construction o f Federally Aided Highways, 1958, 1961, and 1964, BLS Bulletin 299. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1966. 17 pp. Estimates the man-hours required, both on and off the building site, to produce, sell, and deliver materials for each $1,000 of construc tion in 1964. 15 2.008 2.012 Ball, Claiborne M., and Murray, Roland V. Labor and Material Requirements for Sewer Works Construction, BLS Bulletin 1490. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1966. 31 pp. An empirical analysis of the commercial banking industry to determine whether any observed scale economies are related to specialization of labor. The authors present estimates of man-hours required both on and off the building site to produce, sell, and distribute materials for each $1,000 of construction in 1962 and 1963. 2.013 2.009 Ball, Robert; Finn, Joseph T.; and Riche, Martha F. Labor and Material Requirements for Hospital and Nursing Home Construc tion!, BLS Bulletin 1691. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1971. 50 pp. 2.014 Bateman, Fred. “Labor Inputs and Productivity in American Dairy Agriculture, 1850-1910.” The Journal o f Economic History, Vol. 29, No. 1, June 1969, pp. 206-229. 2.015 Behman, Sara. Productivity Change for Carpenters and Other Occupations in the Building o f Single-family Dwellings, and Related Policy Issues. Berkeley, Berkeley Center for Labor Research and Education, Institute of Industrial Relations, University of California, April 1971. 199 pp. Brady, Dorothy, ed. Output, Employment, and Productivity in the United States After 1800. Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 30. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1966. 660 pp. A collection of essays dealing with long-term trends and the data from which they are derived. Also presents essays on regional developments and historical aspects of specific industries, including'the New England textile industry, petroleum, and metal mining, as well as on power and the sources of productivity change. Develops average physical labor productivity estimates for carpenters and a group of related occupations involved in the on-site building of single-family dwellings in 1930 and 1965 in Alameda County, California. Author believes that the findings are applicable in many other areas as well. Finds that average physical labor productivity rose 3.2 percent per year over the period studied. Discusses implications for manpower policy. Bossier, W. “An International Interfirm Com parison: Productivity Methodology for Foundries.” Productivity Measurement Review, No. 41, May 1965. Reports on various types of ratios found to be useful in international comparisons. Examines the place of dairy farming in American agriculture. Determines man-hours used in dairy farming, and derives unit labor requirements and productivity estimates for 1850-1910, by region. 2.011 Bergson, Abram. Planning and Productivity Under Soviet Socialism. New York, Columbia University Press, 1968. 95 pp. Discusses Soviet productivity levels and trends as compared to the United States and other countries, and explains the differences in terms of education, sex, and attitude dif ferentials. The authors estimate the man-hours required both on and off the building site to produce, sell, and deliver materials for each $1,000 of construction in the 1960’s. 2.010 Bell, F.W., and Murphy, N.B. “Economies of Scale and Division of Labor in Commercial Banking.” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 35, No. 2, October 1968, pp. 131-139. 2.016 Burck, Gilbert. “The Still-Bright Promise of Productivity.” Fortune, Vol. 78, October 1968, p. 134+. Discusses productivity in the service indus tries and the associated measurement problems, especially of output per man-hour in govern ment. Also discusses effects of the increasing 16 2.017 service component of GNP on the total economy’s productivity. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, November 1969. 24 pp. Bynum, Alice L. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour - Hosiery Industry, 1947-64, BLS Report 307. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, June 1966. 24 pp. The authors present data relating to output per man-hour, as well as a study of technological developments. 2.023 Presents data on productivity and analyzes the factors affecting it. 2.018 Canada, Dominion Bureau of Statistics. Aggregate Productivity Trends, 1946 to 1966. Ottawa, Canada, 1967. Measures the time required to prepare and inspect poultry using various types of equip ment and production systems, in order to determine the optimal characteristics of a commercial processing plant. This bulletin presents sector measures of productivity for Canada, as well as comparisons with U.S. data. 2.024 2.0L9 Carey, John L. “Output Per Man-Hour in Gray Iron Foundries.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 10, October 1969, pp. 51-52. 2.025 Carey, John L., and Kelly, Terence F. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour, Steel Industry, 1947-65, BLS Report 306. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, June 1966. 25 pp. Carey, John L., and Kelly, Terence F. Labor Productivity o f the Steel Industry in the United States, BLS Report 310. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, July 1966. 36 pp. 2.026 2.027 Carey, John L. and Lyon, Richard W. Gray Iron Foundries Industry, 1954-66: Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour, BLS Bulletin 1636. Cordtz, Dan. “City Hall Discovers Produc tivity.” Fortune, Vol. 84, No. 10, October 1971, p. 93 +. Discusses the rising costs and declining quantity and quality of municipal services, and the managerial and technological methods being adopted to raise productivity of municipal employees. The authors analyze changes in output, employment, and technology to explain labor productivity between 1947 and 1965. 2.022 Cohn, Edward A., and Waldorf, William H. “Output Per Man-Hour in Food Manu facturing.” Marketing and Transportation Situation, MTS-156. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, February 1965, pp. 30-34. The authors present and discuss productivity measures for the food processing industry and several of its component sectors. The authors present data on productivity and analyze the factors affecting it. 2.021 Cleaver, Joe M. “Productivity in an Expanding Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 4, April 1965, pp. 373-377. Analyzes the major factors affecting produc tivity in the primary aluminum industry and presents pertinent indexes. Discusses output, employment, output per man-hour, and general characteristics of the gray iron foundries industry for the period 1954-1966. 2.020 Childs, Rex E. Efficiency in Poultry Eviscera tion and Inspection Operations, Marketing Research Report No. 813. U.S. Department o f Agriculture, Agricultural Research Service, June 1968. 20 pp. 17 Dacy, Douglas C. “Productivity and Price Trends in Construction Since 1947.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 4, November 1965. Discusses the lack of direct data to measure productivity in the construction industry and presents estimates derived indirectly. Direct measures fail because the output of the construction industry is extremely hetero geneous. Changes in wage rates, man-hours, pecuniary value of construction, and in materials, prices serve as the data bases from which estimates of prices and productivity are imputed. 2.028 2.032 Examines growth patterns in Western Europe and the United States between 1958 and 1962. Shows that growth rates were lower in the United States and the United Kingdom because they had already absorbed the produc tivity gains due to employment shifts from small-scale agriculture to manufacturing that most of the other countries were still experiencing during this period. Daly, D.J.; Keys, B.A.; and Spence, E.J. Scale and Specialization in Canadian Manufac turing. Staff Study No. 21. Ottawa, Economic Council of Canada, 1968. 102 pp. 2.033 Examines the disparity in productivity levels between the United States and Canada for nine broad industry groups. 2.029 Daly, D. J., and Walter, D. “Factors in Canada-United States Real Income and Wealth.” Review o f Income and Wealth, Series 13, No. 4, December 1967, pp. 285310. 2.034 Dawson, John. Productivity Change in Canadian Mining Industries. Staff Study No. 30. Ottawa, Economic Council of Canada, 1971.63 pp. 2.035 Dowie, J. A. “Productivity Growth in Goods and Services: Australia, U.S.A., U.K.” Economic Record, Vol. 42, No. 100, December 1966, pp. 536-554. Discusses the relative productivity perform ance of the goods and services sectors in Australia during the 1950’s. Draws comparisons with the United States and the United Kingdom. Denison, Edward F. “As I See It: American W orkers are More Productive than Europeans.” Interview in Forbes, Vol. 104, No. 1, July 1,1969, pp. 48-50. Maintains that since the American worker has more education and has more capital to work with, he is more productive, and therefore is justified in asking for significantly higher wages than his European counterpart. Dovring, Folke. Productivity o f Labor in Agricultural Production. University of Illinois College of Agriculture. Agriculture Experiment Station Bulletin 726. Urbana, 111., 1967.73 pp. Examines the behavior of the ratio of farm output for final use to the sum of direct and indirect labor used in production since 1919. Finds an accelerating rate of productivity change over time. Measures total factor productivity and identifies sources of growth since World War II. 2.031 Denison, E. F. Why Growth Rates Differ: Postwar Experience in Nine Western Countries. Washington, The Brookings Institution, 1967. 494 pp. Estimates the contributions of key growth variables. Examines and compares the sources and rates of growth in Europe and the United States. The authors discuss the differences in real output per employed person between Canada and the United States for 1960. The results indicate that the level of labor productivity in Canada was about 20 percent lower than in the United States. 2.030 Denison, Edward F. “Sources of Postwar Growth in Nine Western Countries.” American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 2, May 1967, pp. 325-332. 2.036 18 Dragonette, Joseph E. Indexes o f Output Per Employee - Air Transportation Industry, 1947-64, BLS Report 308. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, August 1966. 13 pp. 2.042 Presents data on productivity and analyzes factors affecting it. 2.037 Dragonette, Joseph E., and Jaynes, Philip W. “Output Per Man-Hour, Gas and Electric Utilities.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 1, January 1965, pp. 34-39. Briefly discusses productivity, output, product uses, changes in manufacturing, tech nology, capital expenditures, and general characteristics for the period 1958-66. The authors analyze factors affecting productivity and present pertinent indexes. 2.043 2.038 Dragonette, Joseph E., and Myslicki, Chester. “Air Transport: Trends in Output Per Employee.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 91, No. 2, Feb. 1968, pp. 13-16. 2.044 Duncan, James H. “Old and New Productivity Techniques Start Closing Gaps.” Columbia Journal o f World Business, Vol. 4, No. 1, January-February 1969, pp. 69-76. 2.045 Fehd, Carolyn S. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour — Corrugated and Solid Fiber Boxes Industry, 1958-1966, BLS Bulletin 1641. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, December 1969. 19 pp. 2.046 Fehd, Carolyn S. “Output Per Man-Hour in S elected Industries.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 12, December 1970, pp. 39-40. Fleming, M. C. “Cost and Prices in the Northern Ireland Construction Industry 1954-64.” Journal o f Industrial Economics, Vol. 14, No. 1, November 1965, pp. 42-54. Describes the derivation of an index of construction output prices by developing annual estimates of the value of gross output at constant prices, based on labor, material, overhead and profits, and changes in the cost-of these components. Reports a general lag in productivity among 30 industries studied by BLS. Discusses the productivity performance of these industries between 1947 and 1969. Fleming, M. C. “Conventional Housebuilding and the Scale of Operations: A Study of Prices.” Bulletin. Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 29, No. 2, May 1967, pp. 109-137. Presents the results of a study of conven tional housebuilding in Ireland, assessing the influence of scale of operations on prices and labor productivity. Examines the relationship between prices and size of firm, as well as of prices and size of contract. Presents productivity and related indexes. Discusses changes which have affected produc tivity. 2.041 Ferris, John W., and Gale, Hazen. “Trends in Output Per Man-Hour in the Sugar Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 7, July 1970, pp. 32-34. The authors discuss productivity, output, employment, technological change, and capital expenditures. Discusses reasons for Europe’s productivity lag behind the United States. Among the factors responsible are education, social struc ture, and management’s resistance to change. 2.040 Fehd, Carolyn S. “Productivity in the Petro leum Pipelines Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 94, No. 4, April 1971, pp. 46-48. Discusses the major factors affecting produc tivity, including trends in output and demand and capital investment. The authors discuss output and employment in the air transport industry, they analyze output per employee for the period 1947-66, as well as productivity by size of airline and type of service. 2.039 Fehd, Carolyn S. “Productivity in Corrugated and Solid Fiber Boxes.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 2, February 1970, pp. 64-65. 19 2.047 2.051 Fuchs, Victor R. “Statistical Analysis of Productivity in Selected Service Industries in the United States, 1939-1963.” Review o f Income and Wealth, Vol. 12, No. 3, September 1966, pp. 211-344. E xam ines d iffe re n tia ls in output, employment, and productivity across 17 service industries in the United States from 1939 to 1963. Sixteen of these industries show positive rates of change in real output per man. Thus, author finds no basis for assuming that productivity cannot or does not increase in industries providing services. 2.048 The authors present and analyze data on output, output per person, and output per man-hour. 2.052 Fuchs, Victor R., and Wilburn, Jean Alexander. Productivity Differences within the Service Sector. Occasional Paper 102. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1967. 109 pp. 2.053 George, K. D. Productivity in Distribution. Occasional Papers, No. 8. Cambridge, England, Cambridge University Press, 1966. 107 pp. Analyzes the composition of sales, charac teristics of the labor force, and labor productivity in retailing, with emphasis on comparisons between towns of different size and towns having similar market size. Gale, Hazen F. “Industry Output, Labor Input, Value Added, and Productivity Associated with Food Expenditures.” Agricultural Economics Research, Vol. 20, No. 4, October 1968, pp. 113-133. 2.054 R elates the output represented by expenditures for farm food in 1947 and 1958 to the total output, labor, and value-added requirements of all supplier industries (including trade) within an input-output frame work. Determines contributions of the various industries to changes in farm food output and related variables between 1947 and 1958. George, K. D. “Productivity in the Distributive T ra d es.” Bulletin, Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 31, No. 2, May 1969, pp. 61-75. Examines recent trends in productivity in the British distributive trades sector, as well as the relation of output, employment, and productivity; productivity and growth; and productivity trends and unemployment. 2.055 2.050 Gale, Hazen F., and Waldorf, William H. Output Per Man-Hour in Distributing Foods o f Farm Origin, Bulletin No. 1335. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, April 1965. 24 pp. The authors describe factors affecting productivity, and compare food distribution with other sectors of the economy. The authors present and analyze data on a detailed industry basis. They also present a study of contrasting productivity trends in the barber and beauty shop industries. 2.049 Gale, Hazen F., and Van Horn, Thomas R. “ Labor Productivity in Food Distribution.” Marketing and Transportation Situation, MTS-168. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, February 1968, pp. 12-20. Gale, Hazen F. “Output Per Man-Hour in Selected Industries.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 4, April 1969, pp. Haldi, John. “The Value of Output of The Post Office Department,” in The Analysis o f Public Output, by Julius Margolis, ed. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1970, pp. 338-387. 66- 68 . Discusses the valuation and pricing of postal services under existing technology. Outlines rate structure, nature of demand, costs, pricing policies, and externalities. A comment by William M. Capron follows. Discusses output, employment, output per man-hour, and growth in productivity for the years 1957-67. Presents a table of average annual rates of growth for selected industries. 20 2.056 2.061 Hayami, Y., and Ruttan, V.W. “Agricultural Productivity Differences Among Countries.” American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 5, December 1970, pp. 895-911. Discusses the performance of selected industries in 1970. Presents statistics of average annual rates of change in output per man-hour for the 35 industries between 1957 and 1970. The authors discuss the contribution of resource endowments, technical inputs, and human capital to differences in agricultural output per worker in terms of an inter country, cross-section production function analysis. 2.062 2.057 Headley, J. C. “Estimating the Productivity of Agricultural Pesticides.” American Journal o f Agricultural Economics, Vol. 50, No. 5, February 1968, pp. 13-23. 2.063 Henneberger, John E., and Ketterling, Virgil H. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour: Radio and Television Receiving Sets, 1958-66. U.S: Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1966. 27 pp. 2.064 Henneberger, John E., and Gale, Hazen F. “Productivity in the Major Household Appliance Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 9, September 1970, pp. 39-42. 2.065 Henneberger, John E. “Productivity Rises as Radio—T.V. Output Triples in 8 Years.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 3, March 1969, pp. 40-42. Hilgert, Ronald J. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour - Concrete Products Industry, 1947-63, BLS Report 300. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, November 1965. 19 pp. Presents data on productivity, and analyzes the factors affecting it. Discusses production, employment and tech nological changes during the 1958-1966 period, and the rapid gains in output per man-hour over this period. Herman, Shelby W., and Fulco, Lawrence J. “Productivity and Unit Labor Costs in 1968.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 6, June 1969, pp. 11-15. The authors review and analyze trends in productivity and unit labor costs in the private economy, and discuss the relationships between these and other economic factors such as employment, nonlabor payments, and prices. The authors discuss the factors affecting productivity in the major household appliance industry, 1958-69, individual 'output, popula tion growth, replacement demand, responses to the business cycle, capital expenditures, and changes in technology. 2.060 Herman, Shelby W., and Fulco, Lawrence J. “Changes in Productivity and Unit Labor Costs — A Yearly Review.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 94, No. 5, May 1971, pp. 3-8. The authors review and analyze develop ments in 1970, and relate them to changes in employment. The authors present data bearing upon productivity together with a discussion of industry characteristics. 2.059 Herman, Shelby W. “Productivity in the Railroad Industry,” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 10, October 1970, pp.,42-43. Summarizes a BLS study on productivity in the railroad industry (BLS Report 377). Econometric techniques based on the CobbDouglas production function were used to estimate returns to scale and elasticity of substitution. Estimates the productivity of expenditures for agricultural pesticides for 1963. The results indicate that chemical pesticides are highly productive inputs. 2.058 Herman, Arthur S. “Output Per Man-Hour in Selected Industries.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 94, No. 10, October 1971, pp. 59-60. 2.067 21 Huffstutler, Clyde; Hohenstein, Jeffrey; and Adelman, Edwin. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour, Motor Vehicles and Equipment, 2.068 1957-66, BLS Bulletin 1613. U.S. Depart ment of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, December 1968. 31 pp. Commerce, National Bureau of Standards, Clearinghouse for Federal Scientific and Technical Information, 1965. 23 pp. The authors present data bearing upon productivity in the industry, together with a discussion of the factors affecting it. Summarizes and criticizes the Bureau of the Budget report Measuring Productivity o f Federal Government Organizations. Concludes that the report could be extended from five to most other civilian agencies as well as to some functions of the Department of Defense. Jackman, Patrick C. “Unit Labor Costs in Five Iron and Steel Industries.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 8, August 1969, pp. 15-22. 2.073 Compares trends in unit labor costs, output per man-hour, and hourly compensation in the United States and four other major steelproducing countries. 2.069 Presents data on productivity and analyzes the factors affecting it. Jacks, Frederick G. “Productivity, the Name of the Game.” The Journal o f Industrial Engineering, Vol. 19, No. 6, June 1968, pp. 11-13. 2.074 Cites the large gains made in productivity in the steel industry in the previous 30 years, but maintains that further advances are necessary to meet foreign competition. 2.070 Jehring, John J. Increasing Productivity in Hospitals, A Case Study o f the Incentive Program at Memorial Hospital o f Long Beach. Madison School of Business, Center for the Study of Productivity Motivation, The University of Wisconsin, 1966. 74 + pp. 2.075 Kendrick, John W. Postwar Productivity Trends in the United States. Mimeographed. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1971 (to be published in 1973). 2.076 Koo, Anthony Y. C. “British and American Productivity and Regional Patterns of Exports.” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 17, No. 1, March 1965, pp. 158-163. Using regression equations, the author calculates the relative share of British and American exports to various regions of the world as a function of their productivity ratios. Substantial differences in regression coefficients were found between the regional and the aggregate equations employed hitherto in such studies. Kendrick, John W. Summary and Evaluation o f Recent Work in Measuring the Productivity o f Federal Agencies. U.S. Department of Konopa, Leonard J. “An Analysis of Some Changes in Retailing Productivity Between 1948 and 1963.” Journal o f Retailing, Vol. 44, No. 3, Fall 1968, pp. 57-67. Offers some rough productivity estimates for various forms of retailing. Discusses problems in defining and measuring productivity in this sector. Updates the author’s earlier work, published in 1961, which traced trends in U.S. produc tivity from 1889 to 1957. Focuses on developments in aggregate and industry produc tivity during the post-World War II period. 2.072 Klotz, Benjamin P., and Herman, Shelby W. Productivity in the Railroad Industry, BLS Report 377. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, March 1970.32 pp. The authors develop production functions, analyze the production structure of the industry, and discuss key factors which underlie productivity differences. Describes the installation and operation of a savings sharing program, and discusses its impact on hospital performance. 2.071 Ketterling, Virgil H. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour - Aluminum Rolling and Drawing Industry, 1958-65, BLS Report 314. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, December 1966. 20 pp. 22 2.077 The authors examine the interaction of compensation, output, and output per man hour in 1969, when unit labor costs rose by 6.3 percent. Lomax, K. S. “The Measurement and Compari son of Productivity at Industry Level in O.E.C.D. Member Countries.” Productivity Measurement Review, No. 43, November 1965, pp. 7-11. 2.082 Explores international comparisons of productivity at the industry level, using the International Standard Industrial Classification for 14 member countries of the OECD. 2.078 The authors discuss the slowed growth in productivity in 1965 and 1966, viewing it as a result of pressures of sustained demand, contraction in reserve resources, and the need to hire less skilled labor. They examine the movement of productivity and unit labor costs in the major sectors of the economy. Maddala, G. S. “Productivity and Technological Change in the Bituminous Coal Industry, 1919-54.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 73, No. 4, August 1965, pp 352-365. Analyzes productivity and technological change in the bituminous coal industry in the United States by using the technique of aggregate production functions. Capital input is measured in terms of horsepower. The rise in labor productivity is explained almost entirely by the rise in horsepower per worker. 2.079 2.083 Maddison, Angus. “Comparative Productivity Levels in the Developed Countries.” Banca Nazionale Del Lavoro Quarterly Review, Rome, December 1967. 2.084 2.085 Mark, Jerome A. “Productivity Trends and Their Implications.” Speech, presented at the Conference on Productivity and Progress, American Institute of Industrial Engineers, at Florida Technological University, Orlando, Florida, March 13, 1971. 16 pp. Miller, Stanley F., and Rothberg, Herman J. Labor and Material Requirements for College Housing Construction, BLS Bulletin 1441. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, May 1965. 34 pp.t The authors estimate the man-hours required, both on and off the building site, to produce, sell, and distribute materials for each $1,000 of construction in 1961. 2.086 Mark, Jerome A., and Herman, Shelby W. “Recent Changes in Productivity and Unit I^bor Costs.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 5, May 1970, pp. 28-32. Miller, Stanley F. “Labor and Material Required for College Housing.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 9, September 1965,pp. 1100-1104. Presents estimates of on-site and off-site labor requirements, cost of materials and direct wages, and construction time required for college housing projects. Holds that productivity provides a means for all groups to have a larger share of the Nation’s product without taking from one group to give to another. 2.081 McCloskey, S. N. “Productivity Change in British Pig Iron, 1870-1939.” Quarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 82, No. 2, May 1968, pp. 281-296. Assesses the causes of productivity lags in a comparison of British and U.S. productivity. Discusses levels of output, purchasing power, U.S. exchange rates, output per person, GNP, and consumption per person in ten developed nations. 2.080 Mark, Jerome A., and Ziegler, Martin. “Recent Developments in Productivity and Unit Labor Costs.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 90, No. 10, May 1967, pp. 26-29. Moss, Fred T. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour - Footwear Industry, 1947-63. U.S. Depart ment of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, July 1965. 17 pp. Presents data on productivity and analyzes the factors affecting it. 23 2.087 Moss, Fred T. “Output Per Man-Hour in the F ootw ear Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 89, No. 4, April 1966, pp. 401-404. 2.092 Finds that productivity increased relatively slowly between 1947 and 1964. Growth was hampered by competition from increasing imports and the necessity of short production runs. Discusses and takes issue with data showing a declining tendency in the capital-output ratio. Develops data showing that the ratio has continued to rise. 2.093 2.088 Myslicki, Chester. “Report on Productivity Increases in the Auto Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 3, March 1969, pp. 37-39. 2.094 National Commission on Food Marketing. Organization and Competition in the Dairy Industry. Technical Study No. 3. Washing ton, U.S. Government Printing Office, June 1962.409 pp. 2.095 Nelson, Richard R. “A Diffusion Model of International Productivity Differences in M an u factu rin g Industries.” American Economic Review, Vol. 58, No. 5, December 1968, pp. 1219-1248. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. The Comparative Measure ment o f Productivity in the European Paper-Making Industry. Paris, OECD, 1965. 69 pp. 2.096 Presents productivity measures for a sample of European factories. Remery, R. “International Inter-Firm Compari son in the Domestic Heating and Cooking Appliance Industry.” Productivity Measure ment Review, No. 43, November 1965, pp. 17-98. Reports on a survey conducted by the OECD of domestic heating and cooking appliance industries in five countries (Federal Republic of Germany, Austria, Belgium, France, and Italy). Comparability ratios were obtained based on taxes, social charges, labor conditions, depreciation, and overtime charges. The use of these ratios made management more familiar with the industry and with related industries, as well as with new methods of interfirm comparisons. Examines certain difficulties with existing formal theory purporting to explain inter national differences in manufacturing produc tivity. Presents an empirical analysis of Colom bian—U.S. productivity differences, which tends to modify current theories. 2.091 Pratten, C., and Silbertson, A. “International Comparisons of Labour Productivity in the Automobile Industry, 1950-1965.” Bulletin, Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 29, No. 4, November 1967, pp. 373-394. The authors discuss problems of produc tivity measurement in the automobile and component industries. Contains indexes of output, man-hours worked and output per man-hour in the fluid milk industry from 1958 to 1964. 2.090 Piakash, Piem. “Relationship Between Size and Productivity in Selected Indian Industries.” Asian Economic Journal, Vol. 11, No. 3, May 1969, pp. 237-248. Using output-capital ratios and profitability ratios derived from Indian census data, the author investigates the relation between productivity and firm size. Finds that in the nine industries studied, productivity increases with firm size. Reviews changes in production and employ ment over the 1957-1966 period and their relation to output per man-hour measures for the industry. Also discusses changes in technology. 2.089 Perlo, Victor. “Capital-Output Ratios in Manu facturing.” Quarterly Review o f Economics and Business, Vol. 8, No. 3, Autumn 1968, pp. 29-42. 24 Renten, Henry, and Walker, James F. Labor and Material Requirements for School Construction, BLS Bulletin 1586. U.S. Examines the economic efficiency of the airline transportation industry since World War II. Discusses production functions and produc tivity. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, June 1968. 23 pp, The authors estimate the man-hours required, both on and off the building site, to produce, sell, and deliver materials for each $1,000 of construction in 1964-65. 2.097 2.102 2.103 Southard, Leland. “Labor Productivity in Food Manufacturing.” Marketing and Transporta tion Situation MTS-171. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, November 1968, pp. 16-20. 2.104 Spatz, Laura H. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour - Man-Made Fibers Industry, 1957-63. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, October 1965. 20 pp. Strassman, W. P. “Construction Productivity and Employment in Developing Countries.” International Labour Review, Vol. 101, No. 5, May 1970, pp. 503-518. 2.3 05 United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. Principal Factors Affecting Labor Productivity Trends in the Iron and Steel Industry. New York, United Nations, 1969. 200 pp. Examines reasons for the changing intensity of interest in construction in the 1950’s and 1960’s. Discusses recent behavior of the sector with respect to productivity, innovation, and employment in developing countries. 2.101 Seeks to explain international differences in productivity and related data revealed in a 1967 study by presenting additional statistics and by analyzing productivity in terms of a larger variety of underlying factors. Straszheim,Mahlon R. The International Airline Industry. Brookings Institution Transport Research Program. Washington, The Brookings Institution, 1969. 297 pp. United Nations Statistical Commission and E conom ic Commission for Europe. Methodological Problems o f International Comparison o f Levels o f Labor Productivity in Industry. Conference of European Statis ticians. Statistical Standards and Studies, No. 21. New York, United Nations, 1971. 102 pp. Deals with the general methodological problems arising in comparisons of labor productivity in industry. Details the specific problems encountered in comparisons relating to individual branches of industry. Presents data on productivity and analyzes the factors affecting it. 2.100 United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. International Comparisons o f Labor Productivity in the Iron and Steel Industry. New York, United Nations, 1967. 29 pp. Briefly analyzes productivity and related data for five European countries and the United States. Discusses measurement problems. Presents and briefly discusses productivity measures for the food processing industry and several of its sectors. 2.099 Week, Discusses the decline in U.S. productivity in 1969, stressing the uncharacteristic economic growth accompanying it. Blames the situation on hoarding of labor and lack of incentive in a market where jobs are easy to obtain. Predicts rising unemployment for 1970. R ich e, Martha Farnsworth. “Man-Hour Requirements Decline in Hospital Construc tion.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 11, November 1970, p. 48. Discusses direct and indirect labor require ments for hospital construction for 1960 and 1966. Compares labor requirements for hospital construction with other construction industries. 2.098 “The New Inefficiency.” Business September 20, 1969, p. 45. 2.106 25 United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. Productivity o f Underground Coal 2.110 Workings. New York, United Nations, 1965. 189 pp. Presents productivity indexes and related data. Describes the coal mining industries of the countries participating in the study and the technological changes that have taken place in the industry. 2.107 A chartbook covering trends in productivity, and their relation to other economic trends. 2.111 U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service. Changes in Farm Produc tion and Efficiency, A Summary Report. Statistical Bulletin 233. Annual. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office. An annual report presenting major statistical series on farm production, production inputs, and efficiency. Also provides the latest information for appraising changes in farm inputs and practices, improvement in labor p ro d u c tiv ity , and progress of farm mechanization. 2.108 U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. “Comparative International Labor Cost and Productivity,” in United States International Economic Policy in an Inter dependent World. Papers submitted to the Commission on International Trade and Investment Policy, Vol. 1. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, July 1971. pp. 535-546. 2.112 Waldorf, William H. “Labor Productivity in F ood W holesaling and R etailing, 1929-1958.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 48, No. 1, February 1966, pp. 88-110. Presents estimates of the rate of growth of output and labor productivity in food whole saling and retailing based on various measures of output. These include an index of gross output and two indexes of net output, a double-deflated value-added series, and a margin-weighted series. 2.113 U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Indexes o f Output Per Man-Hour, Selected Industries, 1939 and 1947(annually since 1953). “Why It’s So Tough to Boost Productivity.” Business Week, July 25, 1970, p. 64 +. Discusses the decline in U.S. productivity in 1970. Shows that traditional ways of boosting productivity, such as raising capital investment, are not justified when sales are off and the outlook for the economy is bleak. Presents indexes of productivity, output, employment, man-hours, and unit labor requirements in manufacturing and nonmanu facturing industries, together with a description of methods used in arriving at the figures and an analysis of current trends. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. “Productivity and Unit Labor Costs in Export and Import-Competing Industries, 1958-68,” in United States International Economic Policy in an Inter dependent World. Papers submitted to the Commission on International Trade and Investment Policy and published in conjunction with the Commission’s Report to the President. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, July 1971. Vol. l,p p . 507-533. Examines trends in output per man-hour and unit labor costs in two groups of manufacturing industries: those in which exports are an important part of domestic output, and those in which imports are an important part of new supply (domestic output plus imports). Reports that the United States as a whole maintained a favorable unit labor cost position during the 1960’s even though raises in hourly compensation were not offset by productivity gains as much as in other countries. Provides a special comparison of iron and steel industries. 2.109 U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Productivity and the Economy, BLS Bulletin 1710. 1971.35 pp. 2.114 26 Woodhall, Maureen, and Blaug, Mark. “Produc tivity Trends in British Secondary Educa- terms of rates of return on the investment in human capital. Presents theoretical and empirical analyses. tion, 1950-63.” Sociology o f Education, Vol. 41, No. 1, Winter, 1968. pp. 1-35. The authors develop a number of alternative output measures for education and construct productivity indexes. They conclude that regardless of the output measure used,, productivity in British secondary education declined between 1950 and 1963. 2.115 3.003 Ziegler, Martin. “Productivity in Manufac turing.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 90, No. 10, October 1967, pp. 1-5. Discusses productivity for the period 1947-66. Explains the rise in productivity as reflecting the cumulative influence of invest ment in human resources and capital equip ment, advances in technology, managerial skills, and interindustry shifts within the manufac turing sector. Also discusses long-term trends, effects of the business cycle, movement in unit labor costs, and real labor income in the sector. Develops a production function for human capital and examines its relation to the life cycle of earnings. 3.004 III. Factors affecting productivity A. Labor and education Bartsch, W. H. “The Industrial Labor Force of Iran: Problems of Recruit ment, Training and Productivity.” The Middle East Journal, Vol. 25, No. 1, Winter 1971, pp! 15-30. 3.006 Besen, S. M. “Education and Productivity in U.S. Manufacturing: Some CrossSection Evidence.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 76, No. 3, May-June 1968, pp. 494-497. Bjeda, K. “The Pattern of Education and E conom ic G ro w th .” Economic Record, Vol. 46, No. 115, September 1970, pp. 368-383. Discusses limitations of studies of education as an investment in human capital in terms of patterns, content, and quantity of education in various countries in the postwar period. Correlates changes in education with changes in the rate of growth of GNP. Becker, Gary S. Human Capital: A Theo retical and Empirical Analysis, with Special Reference to Education. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1965. 187 pp. 3.007 Examines activities-particularly onthe-job training and schooling—that in crease worker qualifications and the effects these activities have on income in of Reports the results of an attempt to assess the role of labor force quality, as measured by educational attainment, in explaining interstate productivity dif ferentials in manufacturing. Attributes Iran’s productivity growth almost entirely to improvements in capital quality and quantity, holding that there has been negligible growth in labor quality due to a lack of vocational train ing and management’s hiring of cheap rather than capable labor. 3.002 Bertram, Gordon W. The Contribution o f Education to Economic Growth. Staff Study 12. Ottawa, Economic Council of Canada, 1965. E xam ines econom ic aspects expanded and improved education. 3.005 3.001 Ben-Porath, Yoram. “The Production of Human Capital and the Life Cycle of E a rn in g s.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 75, No. 4, Part I, August, 1967. pp. 352-365. 27 Blaug, M., ed. Economics o f Education, Selected Readings, Volumes I and II. Baltimore, Penguin Books, 1968, Vol. 1,441 pp.; Vol. 2, 396 pp. Contains surveys of the pertinent literature and essays on the concept of investment in human capital, cost-benefit analysis of educational expenditures, and manpower forecasting. The authors suggest new census tabula tions to permit more sophisticated appli cation of human capital concepts to migration. 3.011 3.008 Bowles, S. S. “The Aggregation of Labor Inputs in the Study of Growth and Planning: Experiments with a TwoLevel CES Function.” Journal o f Poli tical Economy, Vol. 78, No. 1, January-February 1970, pp. 68-81. A critique in the form of a review article of the contribution of economics to educational planning in developing countries. Upholds the universities as centers of creative thought, and opposes as being futile attempts to quantify the knowledge they generate in terms of rates of return. Develops a labor service index based on the aggregate supply of labor having different levels of schooling. Estimates a two-level constant elasticity of substitu tion function, using international crosssectional data on relative earnings and factor supplies. Finds a consistent but quantitatively small relationship between relative factor earnings and relative factor supplies. 3.009 3.012 Bowman, Mary Jean. “The Human Invest m ent R ev o lu tio n in Economic Thought,” in Economics o f Education, Selected Readings, M. Blaug, ed. Baltimore, Penguin Books, 1968, pp. 101-134. 3.013 Bowman, M. J., and Myers, R. G. “Schooling, Experience, and Gains and Losses in Human Capital Through Migration.” Journal o f the American Statistical Association, Vol. 62, No. 319, September 1967, pp. 875-898. Feldstein, M. S. “Specifications of Labor Input in the Aggregate Production Function.” Review o f Economic Studies, Vol. 34(4), No. 100, October 1967, pp. 375-386. Explores the importance of improving the specification of labor input by allowing the elasticity of output with respect to the humber of employees to differ from the elasticity with respect to the average number of hours per em ployee. Discusses the implications of such inequality for economic analysis and policy, and suggests reasons why output elasticity with respect to hours may substantially exceed that with respect to number of employees. The authors apply concepts of human capital to migration through use of costbenefit models. The models take as their point of departure “individual” view points but are transformed into social decision models by readjusting para meters to allow for cost and income tra n sfe rs, by replacing individually expected earnings by socially expected or realized productive contributions, and by applying probability values to allow for rates of return or nonreturn of migrants. Engerman, Stanley L. “Human Capital, Education, and Economic Growth,” in The Reinterpretation o f American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley T. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971. pp. 241-256. Analyzes problems in the estimation of the costs and benefits of education. Shows how the rate of return on educa tion may be measured. A survey of the recent literature and a critical interpretation of leading ideas. 3.010 Enarson, Harold L. “Education and the Wealth of Nations.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 90, No. 3, March 1967, pp. 21-24. 3.014 28 Gintis, Herbert. “Education, Technology, and the Characteristics of Worker Presents Von Thuenen’s views on human capital. Von Thuenen treated human beings with the definitional schemes of capital, attempted to explain the influence of education on labor productivity, and suggested opportune policy measures, particularly in the area of conscription. Productivity.” American Economic Review, Vol. 61, No. 2, May 1971, pp. 266-279. Argues that schools contribute to worker productivity, not through their academic efforts, but rather by encourag ing personality characteristics conducive to favorable performance in a work role. 3.015 3.019 Hansen, W. Lee, ed. Education, Income, and Human Capital Studies in Income and Wealth, Vol. 35. New York, N a tio n al B ureau o f Economic Research, 1970. 320 pp. Presents the results of a survey in which American firms were requested to compare the labor time required per unit of output in their operations in the United States with their operations abroad under similar organizational con ditions and degrees of mechanization. A compendium of papers examining the interrelationships among education, income distribution, and production. 3.016 Hartley, K. “The Learning Curve and Aircraft Industry.” Journal of Industrial Economics, Vol. 13, No. 2, March 1965, pp. 122-128. 3.020 Argues that economies of learning result from applying direct labor to a complex task, so that the more often the job is repeated the more the worker will learn. Draws on experience in the aircraft industry. Explains the use of learning curves in estimating average direct labor costs for a given output, and examines the implications of learning for the con cept of capacity. 3.017 Kiker, B. F. Human Capital in Retros p ect. Columbia, South Carolina, Bureau of Business and Economic R esearch , U niversity of South Carolina, 1968. 142 pp. 3.021 Levenson, Irving F. “Reductions in Hours of Work as a Source of Productivity Growth.” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 75, No. 2, April 1967, pp. 199 ff. Discusses critically a 1947 study by the Bureau of Labor Statistics on the relation between hours of work and output. Kiker, B. F. “Von Thuenen on Human Capital.” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 21, No. 3, November 1969, pp. 339-343. Kuznets, Simon. “The Contribution of Immigration to the Growth of the Labor Force.” The Reinterpretation o f American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley T. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971, pp. 396-401. Studies immigration to the United States before restriction. Discusses the importance of immigration to the labor force and considers the importance of human capital to economic growth. Schooling and training in skills, received by immigrants in their countries of origin, represented a large capital inflow to the United States. Summarizes and appraises the methods of human capital evaluation which have appeared historically, and the uses to which the human capital concept has been put. 3.018 Kreinin, Mordechai E. “Comparative Labor Effectiveness and the Leontief Scarce-Factor Paradox.” American Economic Review, Vol. 55, No. 1, March 1965, pp. 131-140. 29 3.022 Levhari, D. “Further Implications of Learning by Doing.” Review o f Economic Studies, Vol. 33 (1), No. 93, January 1966, pp. 31-38. ment o f Personnel Quarterly, Vol. 9, No. 2, Summer 1970, pp. 26-32. Arguing that knowledge of work results may enable the worker to attain personal goals and to satisfy higher level needs, the author evaluates the effective ness of using knowledge-of-results tech niques in a unionized industrial setting in terms of their impact upon productivity. Explores certain implications of the “learning by doing” hypothesis advanced by Arrow in the Review o f Economic Studies, June 1962. Discusses the diver gence between social and private returns and the resulting divergence between income distributions implicit in Arrow’s hypothesis. Among the findings is a measure of the magnitude of the subsidy required to bring social and private returns to equality. 3.023 3.026 Mathewson, Stanley B. Restriction o f Ouput Among Unorganized Workers. Carbondale, 111., Southern Illinois University Press, 1969. 212 pp. The authors present and discuss statis tical findings from a sample survey of the productive use of time among American families, in both paid and unpaid pur suits, as well as of their reaction to change. Reissue of a classic first published in 1931, presenting case studies of un organized workers’ resistance to maintain ing given output standards or to increas ing output, and the reasons for it. Finds such resistance as widespread among the unorganized as it was thought to be among organized workers. 3.024 3.027 Merrett, S. “The Rate of Return to E ducation: A Critique.” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 18, No. 3, November 1966, pp. 289-303. 3.028 National Productivity Council of India. Role o f Labor in Productivity. NPC Report No. 46. New Delhi, National Productivity Council, March 1966. 73 pp. The report of an Indian study team sent to the United States to evaluate the contribution made by workers to produc tivity advance. 3.029 Migliore, Henry R. “Improving Worker Productivity through Communicating Knowledge of Work Results.” Manage Musgrave, P.W. Technical Change, the Labor Force, and Education: A Study o f the British and German Iron and Steel Industries, 1860-1964. New York, Pergamon Press, 1967. 286 pp. Explores the types of economic and technical change which most strongly affect education, and how education may best promote change. Asserts that the positive correlation between education and other deter minants of earning power will exaggerate the importance of education in any simple bivariate analysis. The use of the current pattern of earnings as a measure of differential productivities ignores such factors as age differentials, which have been determined in fact by past changes in relative supply conditions, or poor pay in some occupations, which may reflect transient demand conditions. 3.025 Morgan, James N.; Sirageldin, Ismail; and B aerw ald t, N ancy. P ro d u ctive Americans: A Study o f How Individ uals Contribute to Economic Progress. Survey Research Center Monograph No. 43. Ann Arbor, The University of Michigan, 1966. 545 pp. 30 Nelson, Richard R., and Phelps, Edmund S. “Investment in Humans, Techno logical Diffusion, and Economic G ro w th .” A m e ric a n Econom ic Review, Vol. 56, No. 2, May 1966, pp. The authors present some empirical findings about peasant agriculture which cannot be reconciled by traditional price theory. 69-75. The authors hold that the more rapid the rate of technological discovery in an economy, the higher the payoff of in creased education, since more educated managers are more receptive to innovative possibilities—implying that society should develop more human capital relative to tangible capital. 3.030 3.034 Examines reasons for the rise in levels of skills in the labor force. Finds that the rise is closely associated with shifts towards industries requiring higher skills. Novikov, H. “Problems in the Effective Utilization of Labor Resources.” Problems o f Economics, Vol. 12, No. 10, February 1970, pp. 72-88. 3.035 Discusses a broad range of problems bearing upon factors influencing labor productivity in the Soviet Union. 3.031 3.036 Pandit, N. H., ed. Measurement o f Cost Productivity and Efficiency in Educa tion. New Delhi, National Council of Educational Research and Training, 1969. 434 pp. 3.037 Price, J. E., and Etherington, D. M. “The P arad o x of Surplus Agricultural Labour and Positive Marginal Produc tiv ity o f Labour.” The Indian Economic Journal, Vol. 13, No. 5, April-June 1966, pp. 682-687. Rapping, Leonard. “Learning and World War II Production Functions.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 57, No. 1, February 1965, pp. 80-86. Discusses the sharp rise in shipbuilding productivity during World War II, emphasizing the role of organizational and individual learning resulting from accumulated production experience. A collection of 32 papers discussing methods of costing, measurement of efficiency, economic criteria for invest ment, productivity, and problems in measuring cost-benefit relations in educa tion. 3.033 R aim on, Robert L., and Stoikov, Vladimir. “The Quality of the Labor Force.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 20, No. 3, April 1967, pp. 391 ff. Using the average earnings of occupa tional groups as a measure of the economic efficiency of their members, the authors undertake to evaluate the degree of improvement of the quality of the labor force in recent years. They find that from 1956 through 1964, the quality of employed workers increased less than 3 percent, with most of the increase resulting from the decline in the number of farmers and farm laborers. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (Study Group in the E conom ics of Education). The R e sid u a l Factor and Economic Growth. Paris, OECD, 1964. 275 pp. Four papers with comment on the nature and sources of economic growth and te c h n ic a l progress and the importance of educational investment. 3.032 Raimon, Robert L. “Changes in Produc tivity and the Skill-Mix.” International Labour Review, Vol. 92, No. 4, October 1965, pp. 314-324. Rosenberg, Jerry M. Automation, Man power, and Education. New York, Random House, 1966.179 pp. Outlines the responsibilities of educa tors in helping to alleviate economic hardships caused by rapidly changing 31 technology. Discusses government and business responses to educational needs arising from such change. 3.038 period. Finds that pertinent estimates by Denison overstate the improvement for the 1930-60 period. Schroeder, Gertrude. “Labor Planning in the U.S.S.R.” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 32, No. 1, July 1965, pp. 1-14. 3.051 States that planning related +o the management of human resources has increased in scope and complexity in the U .S .S .R . as industrialization has accelerated. There is a wide discrepancy between plans and results because in creases in population and labor force are frequently underestimated while increases in productivity and wages are usually overestimated. 3.039 Introduces a human capital term into the standard Cobb-Douglas function, con taining measurable characteristics such as age and education. 3.052 Schultz, Theodore W. “Capital Formation by Education,” in The Reinterpreta tion o f American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley T. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971. pp. 241-256. 3.053 Schultz, Theodore W. Investment in Poor People. Seminar on Manpower Policy and Program. U.S. Department of L abor, Manpower Administration, 1967. 25 pp. 3.054 “Shortage of Workers Cramps Soviet Muscle.” Business Week, March 21, 1970, p. 50+. Discusses the problem of inefficiency and waste in the Soviet Union. Explains how political considerations have forced plant managers to overstaff in the face of labor shortages for new industry. Points to growing emphasis on productivity and incentives for both management and labor. Schwartzman, David. “The Contribution of Education to the Quality of Labor, 1 9 2 9 -6 3 .” A m e ric a n Economic Review, Vol. 58, No. 3, June 1968, pp. 508-514. Presents estimates of improvements in educational attainment over the 1929-63 Sen, A. K. “Labor Allocation in a Cooperative Enterprise.” Review o f Economic Studies, Vol. 33, No. 96, October 1966, pp. 4-96. F inds th a t income distribution according to “needs” tends to produce an underallocation of labor, and distribution according to “work” or productivity produces an overallocation of labor. Optimum allocation requires a mixture of the two distribution methods. Using rate of return as a criterion for evaluating the efficiency of investment, the author concludes that there has been great underinvestment in human capital, particularly among the poor. Offers an explanation for this misallocation of resources. 3.050 Sellers, Walter E., Jr. Labor Used on U.S. Farms, 1964 and 1966. Rev., October 1970. Statistical Bulletin No. 456. U .S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service, 1970. 23 pp. Examines labor inputs by region, farm size, and farm type. Presents estimates of hours of labor used per $100 of farm products sold, by type of farm. Describes problems in estimating the costs and benefits of education. Shows how the rate of return on education may be measured. 3.040 Scully, Gerald W. “Human Capital and Productivity in U.S. Manufacturing.” Western Economic Journal, Vol. 7, No. 4, December 1969, pp. 334-340. 32 3.055 Examines statements made by British observers in the 1850’s on labor scarcity and industrial efficiency in the United States. Discusses the inadequacy of these observations in light of empirical data, and of relative factor proportions of technologies referred to by those observers. Singer, H.W. “The Notion of Human In v e s tm e n t.” Review o f Social Economy, Vol. 24, No. 1, March 1966, pp. 1-14. Shows that changes in the relative levels of economic and social develop ment result from a number of structural and fu n c tio n a l relations between economic and social factors. Argues that there is a “social profile” made up of social components more strongly linked to one another than to economic levels. Construction of social profiles is inhibited by lack of adequate social indicators. 3.056 3.060 Discusses the “human investment revolution” in economic thought of the past decade. Stoikov, Vladimir. “Productivity and the Quality of the International Labor Force.” British Journal o f Industrial Relations, July 1968, pp. 156-165. 3.061 The author assigns weights to various sectors of the labor force for 37 countries to show how quality measurement of labor improves productivity estimates. 3.057 Sutermeister, Robert A., ed. People and Productivity. New York, McGraw-Hill, 1969. 511 pp. 3.062 Sveikauskas, Leo. “Influences on Produc tivity.” MSU School o f Labor and Industrial Relations, Spring Quarter, 1971, pp. 5-6. Reviews a study of major factors in productivity improvement. Concludes that the proportion of professionals and technicians and levels of skill represent the most important influences on produc tivity, followed by the relation of capital to labor and the age of the capital stock. 3.059 U.S. Congress, House. Committee on Science and Astronautics, Sub committee on Science, Research, and Development. New Technology in Education. Selected References. Com piled by the Education and Public W elfare D ivision, Congressional Research Service, Library of Congress. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1971. 140 pp. Includes citations relating to (1) issues, problems, and future uses of educational technology; (2) the uses of a variety of specific media; and (3) alternative methods of organizing instruction. Temin, Peter. “Labor Scarcity and the P roblem of American Industrial Efficiency in the 1850’s.” The Journal o f Economic History, Vol. 26, No. 3, September 1966, pp. 277-298. Tjioe, B. Khing, and Burns, Leland S. “Housing and Productivity: Causality and Measurement,” in Proceedings o f the Social Statistics Section, American Statistical Association, 1966, pp. 155-160. The authors explore the relation between the productivity of workers and changes in the quality of their housing. Discusses sociological and psycho logical factors that influence produc tivity. 3.058 Terreblanche, S. J. “The Relative Con tribution of Tangible and Human C apital Formation to Economic Growth.” South African Journal o f Economics, Vol. 38, No. 1, March 1970. 3.063 33 Waud, R. N. “Man-Hour Behavior in U.S. Manufacturing: A Neoclassical Inter p r e ta tio n .” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 76, No. 3, May-June 1968, pp. 407-427. Investigates the movement of produc tion worker man-hours at the 2-digit SIC level for manufacturing industries for 1954-64, using labor costs and capital prices as explanatory variables. Estimates elasticity of man-hours with respect to real hourly labor costs and capital costs. 3.064 hours, occur as employers attempt to coordinate their labor inputs and produc tion schedules in response to variations in the demand for their product. Hence, the workweek is a useful indicator of labor shortages or surpluses. Weinberg, Edgar. Improving Productivity: Labor and Management Approaches, BLS Bulletin 1715. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, September 1971.35 pp. B. Management and organization 3.068 Describes efforts by labor and manage ment to provide training opportunities, make greater use of worker know-how, establish more satisfactory work rules, and institute more effective work incentives. Cites experiences of a crosssection of American industries. 3.065 Traces public and private efforts to spur industrial productivity in Japan, and the relationship of these efforts to Japan’s economic growth. Among major topics are international exchange of study team s, management training, small business development, labor-management relations, research, and information activities. Welch, F. “Education in Production.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 78, No. 1, January-February 1970, pp. 35-39. 3.069 Explores the reasons why the demand for and the rate of return on education have been maintained, even though the supply of highly educated workers has increased greatly. 3.066 3.070 , Asian Productivity Organization. Top Management Symposium. Conference Report, Hong Kong, 1969. Tokyo, Asian Productivity Organization, 1969. 218 pp. Presents papers on the role of manage ment in accelerating economic growth, the role of research and development, the effect of traditional management systems on economic developments, and related subjects. Willacy, Hazel M. “Changes in Factory Workweek as an Economic Indicator.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 10, October 1970, pp. 25-31. 3.071 Argues that changes in average weekly hours, and more particularly in overtime Asian Productivity Organization. Review o f Activities o f National Productivity O rganizations in APO Member Countries. Tokyo, Asian Productivity Organization, 1964-. An annual summary of activities, such as organizing missions to study foreign expertise, handling technical inquiries, conducting training courses, etc. Wysong, John W. Labor Productivity and L a b o r F orce Characteristics o f Selected Types o f Commerical Farms. Mimeograph Series No. 28. College Park, Md., Department of Agricultural Economics, University of Maryland, 1968.27 pp. Argues that substantial gains in labor productivity are possible up to the point at which farmers fully utilize their labor force. 3.067 Asian Productivity Organization. Achieve ments in the First Decade o f the Productivity Drive in Japan. Tokyo, Asian Productivity Organization, 1968. 117 pp. 34 Becker, S. W., and Stafford, Frank. “ Some Determinants of Organizational Success.” The Journal o f Business, The authors examine the relationships b etw een average “ p ro d u c tiv ity ” , measured in terms of labor inputs, of the top companies in an industry and other companies in the same industry; the relationships between industry concentra tion and industry “productivity” ; and the relative weight of the component parts of the “productivity” figures. Vol. 40, No. 4, October 1967, pp. 511-518. The authors analyze the relative effect on organizational efficiency of variables frequently utilized by psychologists, economists, and sociologists—such as organization size, adoption of innova tions, psychological distance in the management team, and the environment. They use findings from a statistical study of the firms in the savings and loan industry. 3.072 3.075 Argues that productivity in Great Britain could be increased dramatically through better business organization, more labor-management communication, and more effective management. Presents eight case studies to illustrate his points. B ock, B etty . “The ConcentrationP ro d u c tiv ity Q u a n d a ry .” The Conference Board Record, Vol. 4, No. 6, June 1967, pp. 2-7. Examines the relationship between concentration (on the establishment level) and productivity (as measured by the dollar value of shipments per employee). Finds that industries with the highest productivity tend to be the more concentrated ones. 3.073 3.076 3.077 Dahmen, Erik. Entrepreneurial Activity and the Development o f Swedish Industry, 1919-1939. The American E c o n o m ic T ra n sla tio n S eries. Homewood, 111., Richard D. Irwin, 1970. 440 pp. Discusses problems of industrial trans formation using Schumpeter’s concepts of technological progress and economic development. 3.078 Diebold, John. Business Decisions and Technological Change. New York, Praeger, 1970. 268 pp. A collection of the author’s speeches and articles on how automation changes the decisionmaking environment of the manager, and on the facts he should consider in introducing new technology. Includes case studies in government and private industry. Bock, Betty, and Farkas, Jack. Con centration and Productivity: Some Preliminary Problems and Findings. Studies in Business Economics, No. 103. New York, The Conference Board, 1969. 170 pp. Chao, Kang. Agricultural Production in C o m m u n ist C hina, 1949-1965. Madison, University of Wisconsin Press, 1970. 357 pp. Examines the effects of the socialist transformation on agricultural inputs, outputs, and technology. Bock, Betty, and Farkas, Jack. “The Productivity-Concentration Quandary Re-examined.” The Conference Board Record, Vol. 5, No. 7, July 1968, pp. 13-19. The a u th o rs re fin e measures, developed in an earlier article, designed to show relative productivity of the first four and the first eight companies in given industries. Measures are based on value added per employee and value of shipments per employee in 1963. They find that the first four and the first eight companies in an industry had on the average higher productivity than other companies in the same industry, and that industries with high concentration tended also to rank high in productivity. 3.074 Butterworth, Jack. Productivity Now. New York, Pergamon Press, 1969. 148 pp. 35 3.079 Dovring, Folke. “Land Reform and P ro d u c tiv ity in Mexico.” Land Economics, Vol. 46, No. 3, August 1970, pp. 264-274. 3.083 Discusses how and why Japanese industry develops its own technology in preference to purchasing Western know how. Investigates the effect of the Mexican land reform on productivity in agri culture. Finds that the ejidos (created by land reform) obtain higher crop yields at lower input cost than large, privately owned farms. 3.080 3.084 Dubin, Robert; Homans, George C.; Mann, Floyd C.;and Miller, Delbert C. Leadership and Productivity. San F ran c isc o , C handler Publishing Company, 1965. 138 pp. 3.085 Fleming, M. C. “Inter-Firm Differences in Productivity and their Relation to Occupational Structure and Size of F irm .” M anchester School o f Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 38, No. 3, September 1970, pp. 223-245. 3.086 Hayami, Y. and Ruttan, V. W. “Korean Rice, Taiwan Rice and Japanese Agri cultural Stagnation: An Economic C onsequence o f C olonialism .” Quarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 84, No. 4, November 1970, pp. 562-589. Leibenstein, Harvey. “Organizational or Frictional Equilibrium, X-Efficiency, and th e R ate of Innovation.” Quarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 83, No. 4, November 1969, pp. 600-623. Argues that firms frequently do not produce maximum output with given inputs (“X-inefficiency”), or increase output with the same inputs (“X-efficiency”). Examines the effect this behavior has on technological change and growth. The authors examine the stagnation in agricultural output and productivity in Japan after World War I. Rice imports from Korea and Taiwan were responsible for deterioration of domestic agriculture, and affected indigenous technological potential unfavorably. L e ib e n ste in , Harvey. “Allocational E fficien cy vs. ‘X -E fficiency’.” American Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 3, June 1966, pp. 393-415. Argues that gains from improvements in allocational efficiency are frequently trivial, but in many instances considerable increases in productivity occur with sub stantially no technical change or increases in capital. This increase in efficiency is called “X-efficiency” and is related to motivational changes. Demonstrates that the level of labor productivity attained by different firms is statistically related to the proportion of administrative, technical, and clerical staff rather than size. Shows higher productivity is dependent on resolving problems of industrial organization and management. 3.082 Jehring, J. J. “The Productivity Crisis,” Management o f Personnel Quarterly. Spring 1967, pp. 21-24. Argues that the increasing demand for services and welfare programs can be met only by superior methods of improving productivity. This requires that systems be organized so as to spur motivation of the factors of production, i.e., managers, workers, and suppliers of capital. Contains four essays exploring the impact of supervisory practices on productivity and workers’ behavior. 3.081 “Japan: Now the Imitator Shows the Way.” Business Week, May 16, 1970, pp. 88-89 +. 3.087 36 Melman, Seymour. “Industrial Efficiency Under Managerial vs. Cooperative Journal o f Economic History, Vol. 26, No. 4, December 1966. pp. 556-571. Decision-Making.” Review o f Radical Political Economics, Vol. 2, No. 1, Spring 1970, pp. 9-33. Hypothesizes that the development of modern health and welfare programs is at least in part a response to the rising productivity and increasing relative scarcity of labor accompanying economic development. The hypothesis is explored in the historical context of industrializa tion in England, Germany, the United States, and Russia. Questions whether industrial produc tion requires the managerial hierarchical mode of decisionmaking. Examines 12 Israeli establishments and finds that those that do not have a hierarchical manage ment structure have productivity records equal or superior to those that do. 3.088 Mullen, James H. Personality and Produc tivity in Management. New York, Temple University Publications, dis tributed by Columbia University Press, 1966. 140 pp. 3.092 Examines whether formal work-group leaders affect the productivity of work groups under highly structured techno logical conditions. Explores the impact on productivity o f w idely varying differences in personality and leadership of three division managers in a large insurance company. 3.093 3.089 Noda, Nobuo. How Japan Absorbed A m erica n Management Methods. Translation Series No. 10. Tokyo, Asian Productivity Organization, 1969. 37 pp. 3.094 Patrick, G. F. and Eisgruber, L. M. “The Impact of Managerial Ability and Capital Structure on Growth of the Farm Firm.” American Journal o f Agricultural Economics, Vol. 50, No. 3, August 1968. pp. 491-506. Rimlinger, G. V. “Welfare Policy and Economic Development: A Compara tive Historical Perspective.” The Shultz, George P. and McKersie, Robert B. “Stimulating Productivity: Choices, Problems, and Shares.” British Journal o f Industrial Relations, Vol. 5, No. 5, March 1967, pp. 1-18. The authors discuss three approaches frequently followed by management to raise productivity: (1) buying out of bad practices; (2) sharing of gains from pro ductivity improvements; and (3) man power policy conforming with techno logical changes. They discuss the circum stances under which these approaches promise to be most successful. The authors conclude, on the basis of a simulated case study of farm firm be havior over a 20-year period, that man agerial ability and long-term loan limits are major factors influencing farm firm growth. 3.091 Sales, Stephen M. “Supervisory Style and Productivity: Review and Theory.” Personnel Psychology, Vol. 19, No. 3, Autumn 1966, pp. 275-286. Presents a theoretical framework for expected differential effects of demo cratic versus authoritarian supervision on productivity. Reviews and evaluates relevant literature. Presents a historical survey of the factors leading to the adoption of American methods of management by Japanese industry. 3.090 Rosen, Ned A. Leadership Change and Work-Group Dynamics, An Experi ment. Ithaca, N.Y., Cornell University Press, 1969. 261 pp. 3.095 37 Sirota, David. “Productivity Manage ment,” Harvard Busines Review, Vol. gains in economic organization and reduced hazards, rather than from tech nological changes. 44, No. 5, September-October 1966, pp. 111-116. Argues that work standards present barriers to high productivity. Recom mends that standards of long-term improvement rather than daily output be the gauge of worker efficiency. 3.096 C. Technological change 3.100 “Step Up Your Productivity?” Medical Economics, September 30, 1968, pp. 63-154. A special issue, examining such topics in physicians’ productivity as the forma tion of partnerships in place of single practice, and delegating more clinical tasks to aides. Also explores ways to raise productivity without impairing the quality of medical care. 3.097 A compilation of articles on basic aspects of numerical control, applica tions, tooling-up procedures, and pro graming methods. 3.101 “The Productivity Crisis.” New Society, Vol. 8, No. 208, September 22, 1966, pp. 434-448. 3.102 Vepa, Ram K. Productivity in Small Industries - Some Lessons from Japan. Asian Productivity Organization, Tokyo, 1969. 98 pp. 3.103 Walton, Gary M. “Sources of Produc tivity Change in American Colonial Shipping, 1675-1775.” The Economic History Review, Vol. 20, No. 1, April 1967, pp. 67-78. Atkinson, Anthony B., and Stiglitz, Joseph E. “A New View of Techno logical Change.” Economic Journal, Vol. 79, No. 315, September 1969, pp. 573-578. The authors argue that mathematical theories implying generalized shifts in the production function due to technological change fail to take account of the “locali zation” of technological progress in par ticular fields. Improvement of technique in one field may have no effect on other techniques in the same or related fields. Some implications for research conducted in developing countries are discussed. Cites evidence on sources of changing productivity in colonial shipping for the 100-year period preceding the American Revolution. Argues that most of the improvement in productivity arose from Arnfield, R. V., ed. Technological Fore casting. Edinburgh, Edinburgh Univer sity Press, 1969. 417 pp. A collection of papers reviewing the history of technological forecasting, especially in Europe, and discussing tech niques of forecasting. Discusses the measures taken by the Japanese government to help small businesses cope with the cost squeeze arising from the fact that, while the wage rates they pay are rapidly nearing those paid by bigger firms, their productivity lags behind. 3.099 American Machinist. AM on Computers Their Role in Manufacturing. New York, McGraw-Hill, 1971. 140 pp. A compilation of articles on the management, cost, and factory applica tions of com puter. A collection of articles investigating the obstacles to higher productivity in Great Britain. 3.098 American Machinist. A M on NC - How to Use N um erically Controlled Machine Tools with Maximum Effici ency. New York, McGraw-Hill, 1967. 176 pp. 38 3.104 observed on a 6-week tour of 12 American cities and draws lessons for Australia. Ayres, Robert V. Technological Fore casting and Long-Range Planning. New York, McGraw-Hill, 1969. 237 pp. Discusses various types and methods of forecasting and how these may be in c o rp o ra te d in overall economic planning. 3.105 3.109 A collection of papers summarizing the state of technological forecasting. Bagrit, Sir Leon. The Age o f Automation. New York, New American Library of World Literature, 1965. 128 pp. 3.110 Discusses the social and political implications of automation. Predicts a fuller, more creative life for mankind. 3.106 Ball, Robert; Herman, Arthur; and Lyon, Richard. Outlook for Computer Pro cess Control, BLS Bulletin 1658. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1970. 70 pp. 3.111 Baranson, Jack. Role o f Science and Technology in Advancing Develop ment o f Newly Industrializing States. Mimeographed. U.S. Department of State, Office of External Research, January 1969. 73 pp. technological reasons for them. 3.112 Brown, Lester R. The Social Impact o f the Green Revolution. International Conciliation Publication No. 581. New York, Carnegie Endowment for Inter national Peace, 1971.61 pp. Discusses the implications of success ful new agricultural technology for the relief of hunger, and for employment, population, and the distribution of benefits. Bennett, E. C. Mechanization o f the U n ited States Printing Industry. S y d n ey , Australia, Printing and Kindred Industries Union, New South Wales Branch, September 1966.48 pp. 3.113 Reports on new printing technology, p a rtic u la rly typesetting technology, Brown, Lester R. “The Agricultural Revolution in Asia.” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 46, No. 4, July 1968, pp. 688-698. Discusses the striking increases in food grain crops in major Asian countries in the late sixties, and the political and Considers how developing countries may increase their ability to absorb and adapt—and how developed economies may more effectively transmit—advanced technologies. 3.108 Brooks, George W. “Unions and Techno logical Change.” The Conference Board Record, Vol. 5, No. 6, June 1968. pp. 23-25. Contrasts the attitude of the United Auto Workers, oriented toward efficiency and rapid technological change, with that of trade unions more resistant to change. Concludes that the issue in labor manage ment relations is the extent to which employers should be restricted in intro ducing new technologies. The authors examine the extent to which computers have been installed in six industries; how many will be installed in the future; what factors govern their adoption; what type of manpower is required for computer process control; and what kinds of industrial relations problems have arisen as a consequence of computer installation. 3.107 Bright, James R., ed. Technological Fore casting for Industry and Government. Englewood Cliffs, N.J., Prentice-Hall, Inc., 1968. 484 pp. 39 Brown, Murray. On the Theory and M ea su rem en t o f Technological C hange. C am bridge, E ngland, Cambridge University Press, 1966. 214 pp. Uses input-output tables to evaluate technological change from 1947 to 1958. Discusses the properties of the CobbDouglas and constant elasticity of subs titution production functions. Presents various methods of measuring both neutral and non-neutral technological change and tests several of these methods, using U.S. historical data. 3.114 3.118 Bush, George P., and Hattery, Lowell H., eds. Automation and Electronics in Publishing. The American University Technology of Management Series, V olum e 3. Washington, Spartan Books, 1965. 206 pp. D evelops a set o f parameters associated with Harrod’s and Solow’s classifications in a neoclassical two-sector model. Provides a unified treatment of Hick’s, Harrod’s, and Solow’s classifica tions of bias in technological change. Examines the conditions for “aggregate neutrality.” A collection of papers examining tech nological changes and their effects on production, management, organization, and labor relations in several types of publishing. Considerable attention is paid to computerized typesetting. 3.115 3.119 Capron, William M., ed. Technological Change in Regulated Industry. Studies in the Regulation of Economic Activity. Washington, The Brookings Institution, 1970. 211 pp. 3.120 Carter, Anne P. “Changes in the Structure of the American Economy, 1947 to 1958 and 1962.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 49, No. 2, May 1967, pp. 209-224. 3.121 Carter, Anne P. “The Economics of Techn o lo g ic a l C h an g e.” S c ie n tific American, Vol. 214, No. 4, April 1966, pp. 25-31. Critchlow, Robert V. “Technological Changes in the Printing and Publishing Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 8, August 1970, pp. 3-9. Reports that technology has been advancing strongly to meet a rapidly increasing demand for printed material. Finds that the occupational requirements of the industry have been changing significantly. Presents an overall picture of techno logical change in the United States by systematically comparing the 1947 and 1958 input-output tables. 3.117 Conference on the Communication of Scientific and Technical Knowledge to Industry (Stockholm, October 7-9, 1963). Proceedings. Paris, Organiza tion for Economic Cooperation and Development, April 1965. 188 pp. Reviews conditions necessary for the most efficient international transfer of scientific knowledge among small- and medium-sized firms as well as among large ones. Contains studies of the interaction between technological change and the regulatory process in the electric power g e n e r a t i n g i n d u s t r y , a n d in communications, commercial aviation, and surface transportation. Also presents a theoretical analysis of the impact of innovation on a number of regulatory practices, as well as an interpretive con cluding essay. 3.116 Chang, W. W. “The Neoclassical Theory of Technical Progress.” American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 5, December 1970, pp. 912-923. 40 Crossman, E. R. F.W.; Laner, Stephen; Davis, Louis E.; and Caplan, Stanley H. Evaluation o f Changes in Skill Profile and Job Content Due to Technological Change: Methodology and Pilot Results from the Banking, Steel and Aerospace Industries. Report submitted to the Director, Office of Manpower Policy, Evaluation and Research, U.S. Department of Labor. Berkeley, Department of Industrial Engineering and Operations Research, University of California. October 1966. 100 pp. plus appendix. Identifies and discusses sectors of the economy where automation has caused important changes in production pro cesses and employment. The authors address the question of the skill levels required by advancing technologies and test the hypothesis that higher levels of mechanization and auto mation require lower levels of skill. They develop specific methods to measure the effect of new technologies on skills, controlling for such “extraneous” factors as differences in product quality or design or staffing patterns as compared with the old technology. They establish tentative criteria for the prediction of needed skills. 3.122 3.125 Examines factors underlying the tech nological superiority of American firms over their foreign counterparts, and finds that the difference results mainly from managerial and financial inadequacies of European firms. 3.126 D airy m ple, Dana G. Technological Change in Agriculture: Effects and Implications for Developing Nations. U.S. Department of Agriculture, Foreign Agricultural Service, April 1969.82 pp. 3.127 David, Paul A., and Van de Klundert, Th. “ Biased Efficiency, Growth and Capital-Labor Substitution in the U.S., 1899-1960.” American Economic Review, Vol. 55, No. 3, June 1965, pp. 357-394. 3.128 Earl, Victor. Technological Forecasting. The Economist, Brief 11. London, The Economist Newspaper Ltd., 1968. 24 pp. Discusses the kinds of problems tech nological forecasting tries to solve and how forecasters go about the task. Diebold Group, Inc .Automation: Impact and Implications: Focus on Develop ments in the Communications Indus try. Washington, Communications Workers of America, 1965. 182 pp. Doctors, Samuel I. The Role o f Federal Agencies in Technology Transfer. Cambridge, Mass., The MIT Press, 1969. 230 pp. Considers problems of technology transfer from government-sponsored research and development to the economy as a whole. Discusses NASA’s Technology Utilization Plan. The authors measure the distribution of technological change between laborassociated and capital-associated improve ments in factor efficiency. Their estimate of the elasticity of substitution casts doubt on the appropriateness o f . the C obb-D ouglas form of production function. 3.124 Diwan, R. K. “About the Growth Path of Firms.” American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 1, March 1970, pp. 30-43. Deals with technological factors influencing the behavior of firms. Dis cusses elasticity of factor substitution, technological impact on labor efficiency, and bias of technological change. Finds that these factors at first grow with the firm, reach a maximum, and then start falling off as the size of firm keeps growing. Examines the adoption process for agricultural technology. Surveys the economic, social, and political effects of the development of high-yield grains and of increased farm mechanization. 3.123 Diebold, John. “Is the Gap Techno logical?” Foreign Affairs, Vol. 46, No. 2, January 1968, pp. 276-291. 3.129 41 Evan, E. W. “Some Problems of Growth in the Machine Tool Industry.” Yorkshire Bulletin o f Economic and Social Research, Vol. 75, May 1966, management relations, and the social structure. pp. 22-32. 3.134 Discusses obstacles to higher capacity and output in the Eritish tool industry, especially the difficulty of expanding research activity; the scarcity of scientific, technical, and skilled labor; the problems created by cyclical variations in demand; and the barriers which exist to the substitution of labor. 3.130 Puts forth proposals for the collection of statistics on science and technology on an i n t e r n a t i o n a l l y uniform basis. Discusses the need for such a collection and the difficulties of undertaking it. Fabricant, Solomon. Measurement o f Technological Change. Fourth Seminar on Manpower Policy and Program. U.S. Department of Labor, Manpower Administration, 1965. 32 pp. 3.135 Considers alternate concepts of tech nological change and discusses difficulties of measurement. 3.131 Ferguson, Walter. Farm Labor Used for Fruits and Tree Nuts, 1964. Statistical Bulletin No. 436. U.S. Department of Ag ri cu lt ur e, Economic Research Service, 1969. 43 pp. 3.136 Ferkiss, Victor C. Technological Man, the Myth and the Reality. New York, George Braziller, Inc. and New American Library, 1969. 276 pp. 3.137 Ford, Gordon W., ed. Automation: Threat or Promise? Sydney, Australia, The Australian and New Zealand Association for the Advancement of Science, 1969. 214 pp. Gold, B.; Pierce, W. S.; and Rosegger, G. “Diffusion of Major Technological Innovations in U.S. Iron and Steel Manufacturing.” Journal o f Industrial Economics, Vol. 18, No. 3, July 1970, pp. 218-242. The authors analyze the diffusion of fourteen major technological innovations in the U.S. iron and steel industries. They present a conceptual model of the decision process to explain varying dif fusion rates and differing elaborations of innovation by different firms. A series of papers discussing the impact of automation on production, m a n p o w e r r e q u i r e m e n t s , labor- Gamble, William K.; Adams, Dale W.; and Dorner, Peter. “Institutional Reform: The Conflict Between Equity and Productivity: Discussion.” American Journal o f Agricultural Economics, Vol. 52, No. 5, December 1970, pp. 716-718. The authors each comment on the uneven incidence of the benefits of new agricultural technology both between large and small farmers and between developed and less developed countries. Expl ores the relations between evolving technology and the web of society, economy, and culture. 3.133 Fulco, Lawrence J. “How Mechanization of Harvesting Is Affecting Jobs.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 3, March 1969, pp. 26-32. Analyzes technological developments in harvesting of fruits and vegetables, and their implications for productivity, e m p l o ym en t , training, and labormanagement relations. Presents data on man-hours required per acre at various stages of production in 1964, the first year in which much fruit and nut tree acreage was harvested mechanically. 3.132 Freeman, Christopher. The Measurement o f S c ie n tific and Technological A ctivities. Paris, United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization, 1969. 63 pp. 42 3.138 Goodwin, L. B,; Blase, M. G.; and Colyer, D. “A Development Planning Model for Technological Change in Agri culture.” American Journal o f Agri cultural Economics, Vol. 52, No. 1, February 1970, pp. 81-90. discussing organized labor’s reaction to change. 3.143 The authors examine a model for coordinating activities and allocating resources in the development process. They provide insights into the sporadic nature of economic development. 3.139 Holds that technological change has come in disruptive surges rather than in an even flow because of subconscious “suppression techniques” employed by managers and designers of new programs. Urges more flexible corporate planning. Great Britain. Automation and Its Impli cations. Papers given at the Industry ’65 Exhibition Conference on Produc tivity, Technology, and Change. London, British Productivity Council. 51 pp. 3.144 Presents five papers on automation and its social and monetary costs, followed by a panel discussion. 3.140 Heilbroner, Robert L. Automation in the Perspective o f Long-Term Technical Change. Seminar on Manpower Policy and Program. U.S. Department of Labor, Manpower Administration, 1966. 38 pp. 3.145 Hirsch, Werner Z. “Technological Progress and Microeconomic Theory.” American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 2, May 1969, pp. 36-43. 3.146 Hugh-Jones, E. M., ed. Economics and Technical Change. Oxford, Basil Blackwell, 1969. 178 pp. Irgens, 0 . M. “Increased Productivity Through Exchange of Experience.” Productivity Measurement Review, No. 42, August 1965, pp. 70-81. Reports on the success of two inter national technical cooperation groups in increasing productivity in th e ' textile industry. A compendium of papers describing the impact and benefits of technical change, exploring economies of scale, and International Congress of Human Rela tions. The Social and Economic Impact o f Automation and Technical Change. Proceedings of Congress at Melbourne, Australia, May 1965. Melbourne, Federation Promotions, 1965. 138 pp. A compendium of papers discussing the effect of automation on education, production, economic growth, and employment. Discusses some economic problems posed by technologically progressive firms and proposes a theoretical model to solve these problems. 3.142 International Conference on Techno logical Change and Human Develop ment (Jerusalem, April 1969). Techno logical Change and Human Develop ment. Ithaca, N.Y., New York State School of Industrial and Labor Relations, Cornell University, 1970. 388 pp. Considers the effects of technological change on the quality of life. Explores methods of maximizing the economic gains while minimizing the social costs of technical progress. Briefly reviews the history of tech nological change in the United States in terms of the problem of technological displacement. 3.141 Hunter, Maxwell W. “Are Technological Upheavals Inevitable?” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 47, No. 5, September-October 1969, pp. 73-83. 43 3.147 Isenson, Raymond S. “Technological Forecasting, A Management Tool.” Business Horizons, Vol. 10, No. 2, Summer 1967, pp. 37-46. of absorbing. Urges that techniques be adopted which yield the highest profit, but warns against the introduction of the most advanced kinds of capital goods and methods. Differentiates between two bases of the technological forecast. The first is application- or need-oriented. The second is potential-oriented. Concludes that “it is not necessary to forecast on the naive assumption that historical growth assures future growth.” 3.148 3.152 Examines and updates earlier empirical studies measuring the regional patterns of technical change in U.S. agriculture. Presents a regression model which recognizes explicitly the relation between labor input and labor cost and is based on regression of labor productivity on the wage rate. Jantsch, Erich. Technological Forecasting in Perspective. Paris, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Develop ment, 1967. 401 pp. Surveys techniques and trends in tech nological forecasting. 3.149 Jehring, J. J., ed. Productivity and A uto mation. Madison, Center for Produc tivity Motivation, School of Com merce, University of Wisconsin, 1965. 110 pp. 3.153 Jehring, J. J., ed. Productivity and A uto mation. Bulletin 39. Washington, National Council for Social Studies, 1966. 180 pp. Essays primarily addressed to social studies teachers and students, dealing with the study and measurement of productivity, the nature of work, worker-management relations, social aspects of technological change, and approaches to increasing productivity. 3.151 3.154 Kaldor, Nicholas. “The Choice of Tech nology in Less Developed Countries.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 8, August 1969, pp. 50-53. Knauerhase, R. “The Compound Steam Engine and Productivity: Changes in the German Merchant Marine Fleet — 1871-1887.” The Journal o f Economic History, Vol. 28, No. 3, September 1968, pp. 390-403. Investigates the changes in total industry productivity which resulted from the adoption of the compound steam engine. Compares productivity im provem ents resulting from that adoption with improvements in sailing ship technology. Discusses resulting declines in ocean freight rates after 1870. Takes issue with certain common assumptions about the kinds of tech nology developing countries are capable Kaneda, Hiromita. “Substitution of Labor and Nonlabor Inputs in Japanese Agriculture.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 2 , May 1965,pp. 163-171. Measures the elasticity of substitution between labor and nonlabor inputs by the use of data including and excluding inter mediate product inputs. The elasticities of substitution are estimated from a combination of cross-section and timeseries data from Japanese agriculture. Develops indexes reflecting changes in production efficiency for farms with different scales of operation. Presents three essays discussing the concept of productivity, workers’-relation to automation, and the past and possible future paths of technological change. 3.150 Kaneda, Hiromita. “Regional Patterns of Technical Change in U.S. Agriculture, 1 9 5 0 - 1 9 6 3 . ” Journal o f Farm Economics, Vol. 49, No. 1, February 1967, Part I, pp. 199-212. 44 3.155 Develops a method involving the use of index numbers of prices and wages to circumvent the difficulties in measuring technological progress and estimating capital stock. Kumar, Dharma. “Technical Change and Dualism Within Agriculture in India.” The Journal o f Development Studies, Vol. 7, No. 1, October 1970, pp. 50-59. Examines the changes in income distribution when technical progress does not include subsistence farms but is con fined to the commercial sector of agri culture . 3.156 3.160 Lancaster, Kelvin. “Change and Innova tion in the Technology' of Consump tion.” American Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 2, May 1966, pp. 14-23. Discusses new techniques of automatic machining in the metalworking industries and their implications for productivity, occupational requirements, and employ ment. Argues a theory of consumption along the lines of production theory, with consumer goods as the inputs and a set of satisfying “characteristics” as the output. Draws a parallel between the role of technology in increasing production and its role in increasing consumer satisfaction. 3.157 3.161 Lave, Lester B. Technological Change: Its Conception and Measurement. Engle wood Cliffs, N.J., Prentice-Hall, 1966. 228 pp. 3.162 3.163 Marsden, Keith. “Progressive Techno logies for Developing Countries.” International Labour Review, Vol. 101, No. 5, May 1970, pp. 475-502. Argues that technology transferred from highly industrialized states is not always appropriate for developing states. Suggests criteria for choosing techno logies which will make optimal use of given resources. Lydall, H. “On Measuring Technical P rog re ss . ” Australian Economic Papers, Vol. 8, No. 12, June 1969, pp. 1- 12 . Mansfield, Edwin. The Economics o f Technological Change. New York, W. W. Norton, 1968.257 pp. Investigates basic problems relating to technological change, such as what motivates it, how it is measured, where inventions originate, and what the lag is between technological invention and its introduction. Lovell, C. A. Knox. “Biased Technical Change and Factor Shares in United States Manufacturing.” Quarterly Review o f Economics and Business, Vol. 9, No. 3, Autumn 1969, pp. 17-33. Examines the nature of technical change in 19 American industries during the postwar period, and the effects of technical change upon estimates of the elasticity of substitution and upon trends in relative factor shares. 3.159 Macut, John J. “Prospects for Numerical Control of Machine Tools.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 4, April 1965, pp. 403-406. Reports on the present and potential use of automated machining of metal parts and implications for productivity, employment, and occ u pa ti o na l requirements. Reviews and explains alternate methods of measuring technological change. 3.158 Macut, John J. Outlook for Numerical Control o f Machine Tools, BLS Bulletin 1437. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, March 1965. 63 pp. 45 3.164 Markuson, Barbara Evans. Libraries and Automation. Proceedings of the Con ference on Libraries and Automation held at Airlie Foundation, Warrenton, Virginia, May 26-30, under sponsor ship of the Library of Congress, National Science Foundation, and Council on Library Resources. Washington, Library of Congress, 1964. 268 pp. intermediate and final goods. Thus, con centration on how technological change affects only primary factors may give misleading results if the new processes use more intermediate inputs. 3.168 Argues that the importation of advanced technologies into a developing economy which does not have the markets for the volume of goods these techniques produce will lead to mono polistic business structures, which will in turn lead to a premature halt in the nation’s economic growth. Presents essays intended to acquaint librarians with the technology of library mechanization and its problems. The essays cover the design requirements for a future library; file organization and con version; file storage and access; graphic st orage; l ibrary communications networks; the automation of library systems; and related subjects. 3.165 Merhaw, Meir. Technological Depend ence, Monopoly, and Growth. New York, Pergamon Press, 1969. 204 pp. 3.169 McCloskey, S. N. “The British Iron and Steel Industry, 1870-1914: A Study of the Climacteric in Productivity.” The Journal o f Economic History, Vol. 29, No. 1, March 1969, pp. 173-175. Mishan, E. J. Technology and Growth: The Price We Pay. New York, Praeger, 1970. 193 pp. Discusses the social and environmental costs of the increasing rate of techno logical change. Finds these costs excessive. Argues that the exhaustion of techno logical possibilities explains most of the retardation in British iron and steel productivity growth before 1914. 3.170 Morse, Dean, and Warner, Aaron W.,eds. Technological Innovation and Society. New York, Columbia University Press, 1966. 214 pp. 3.166 Melman, Seymour. Our Depleted Society. New York, Holt, Rinehart and Winston, 1965. 366 pp. The authors present a series of discus sions on the transformation of scientific knowledge into technological innovation, and on the social and political implica tions of technological change. A critical view of the impact of the cold war on the U.S. economy, particu larly in science and technology and the productivity of industry. 3.167 Melvin, J. R. “Intermediate Goods and Technological Change.” Economica N.S.y Vol. 36, No. 144, November 1969, pp. 400-408. Nelson, Richard R. The “Technology Gap” and National Science Policy. C enter D iscussion Paper. Mimeographed. New Haven, Economic Growth Center, Yale University, May 1970. 25 pp. Presents a diagrammatic analysis of the effects of technological change in an intermediate-input model. Shows that a technological change which substitutes the intermediate good for labor need not change prices or output. Such change could in fact result in less output for both Argues that there has been a “techno logical gap” between the United States and Europe for more than 100 years, and that gearing science and technology policy toward either maintaining or eliminating the gap yields sub optimal results. 3.171 46 3.172 3.176 Nelson, Richard R.; Peck, Merton J.;and Kalachek, Edward D. Technology, Economic Growth and Public Policy. Washington, The Brookings Institu tion, 1967. 238 pp. The authors interpret recent findings on the relationship between research and development and productivity; the alloca tion of resources to advances in tech nology ; and the rate of absorption of new technologies in the economy. They develop an “operational” concept of technological knowledge. They also deal with the ways the economy adjusts to technological change and with pertinent publi' policies. 3.173 The reports examine in detail the production process and market situation of the given industry in OECD member countries. They discuss international differences in growth and technological development, and explore reasons for these differences. Nordhaus, William D. “An Economic Theory of Technological Change.” American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 2, May 1969, pp. 18-28. 3.177 Constructs an econometric model of the process of invention to sort out sources of productivity change, in an effort to explain why growth in input does not explain most of the growth in output. 3.174 O’Carroll, Lloyd T. “Technology and M anpower in Nonelectrical Machinery.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 94, No. 6, June 1971, pp. 56-62. 3.178 Olken, Hyman. “Technological Growth and the Evolution of New Industry.” Economic and Business Bulletin, Vol. 22, No. 1, Fall 1969, pp. 15-24. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Gaps in Tech nology: General Report. Paris, OECD, 1968.42 pp. Summarizes the results of OECD studies on differences in innovation and technological potential among OECD member countries. Offers several inter pretations of these results and outlines national and international policies to improve performance. Criticizes present methods of predicting technological changes. Dis cusses laws of the “biology” of industries making intensive use of new technology. Knowledge of these “laws” makes pre diction of upcoming technological break throughs possible. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Gaps in Tech nology: Analytical Report. Compari sons Between Member Countries in Education, Research and Develop ment, Technological Innovation, Inter national Economic Exchanges. Paris, OECD, 1970.300 pp. Examines the nature and extent of differences in scientific and technological p o t e n t i a l among OECD member countries, and their effect on the attain ment of economic and other objectives. Recommends policies insuring that the potentials of all member countries will be increased and be most effectively utilized. Describes innovations being intro duced in the industry and their impact on productivity, employment, and skill requirements. 3.175 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Gaps in Tech nology. Set of six studies. Paris, OECD. Electronic Components, 1968. 190 pp. Scientific Instruments, 1968. 178 pp. Electronic Computers, 1969. 209 pp. Pharmaceuticals, 1969. 149 pp. Plastics, 1969. 162 pp. Non-Ferrous Metals, 1969. 202 pp. 3.179 47 Pack, Howard, and Todaro, Michael. Technological Transfer, Labor Absorp tion, and Economic Development. Center Discussion Paper No. 65. Mimeographed. New Haven, Economic Growth Center, Yale University, May 1969. 14 pp. Discusses methods of technological forecasting, its purposes, limitations, and data requirements. Suggests ways to integrate this type of forecasting into the business decision-making process. The authors urge that developing countries maintain their own capital goods industries so that they will not be forced to employ increasingly laborsaving technology in a labor-abundant economy because of new or used capital goods available from developed economies. 3.180 3.184 A collection of essays on the process, determinants, long-term consequences, and international aspects of technological change, and the diffusion of new tech nology. Among authors included are Schumpeter, Usher, Blaug, Nelson, Griliches, Fellner, Mansfield, Abramovitz, Solow, Denison, and Vernon. Phillips, Almarin. Technology and Market Structure: A Study o f the Aircraft Industry. Lexington, Mass., Heath Lexington Books, 1971. 233 pp. Examines the impact of changes in industrial technology on market structure for the period 1932-1965. 3.181 3.185 Porter, R. C. “Technological Change with U nlim ited Supplies of Labor.” Manchester School o f Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 36, No. 1, March 1968, pp. 69-74. 3.186 Quinn, James B. “Technological Competi tion: Europe vs. U.S.” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 44, No. 4, JulyAugust 1966, pp. 113-130. 3.187 Quinn, James B. “Technological Fore casting.” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 45, No. 2, March-April 1967, pp. 89-106. Salter, W. E. G. Productivity and Tech nical Change. With an addendum by W. B. Reddaway. Second edition. University of Cambridge Department of Applied Economics Monograph. Cambridge, England, and New York. Cambridge University Press, 1969. (Paper edition of 1966 edition.) A theoretical and empirical analysis of technical change in the United States and Britain before and after World War II. Finds that the United States has a large technological advantage over Western Europe. Believes that this lead could be dissipated by a concerted tech nological effort in Europe and by U.S. failure to direct more resources into meaningful research. 3.183 Rosenbloom, Richard S., and Wolek, Francis W. Technology and Informa tion Transfer. Boston, Graduate School of Business Administration, Harvard University, 1970. 174 pp. The authors discuss the flow of tech nical information across organizational lines in large firms. Examines some implications of the Lewis model of technological change. Shows that under certain conditions, technological progress may depress rather than raise the relative share of profits in an economy with “unlimited supplies” of labor. 3.182 Rosenberg, Nathan, ed. The Economics o f Technological Change. Selected Readings. Baltimore, Penguin Books Inc., 1971. 509 pp. Scott, J.T ., Jr., and Reiss, F. J. “Changing Technology and Lease Adjustment: Theory and Practice.” Land Economics, Vol. 45, No. 4, November 1969, pp. 400405. The authors show how technological changes in agriculture frequently change relative returns to landowners and farm tenants. They suggest new allocation of 48 supply and quality of management, labor, and capital, and the receptiveness of society. Examines the experiences of Mexico and Puerto Rico in particular. inputs and profits after the new tech nologies have been introduced. 3.188 Scrupski, Stephen E. “Special Report: Automation for Survival and Profit.” Electronics, Vol. 44, No. 22, October 25, 1971, pp. 62-73. 3.192 Argues that the electronics industry, although essential to the computerized and automated technologies of other industries, has itself lagged in adopting automation, partly owing to lack of standardization. Suggests ways by which the industry can overcome this problem. 3.189 Reporting on a study sponsored by the Department of Labor, the author describes the rapid technological changes that are affecting health services and attendant manpower needs. Also dis cusses trends in productivity and presents estimates of employment by occupation to 1975. Spencer, Daniel L., and Woroniak, Alexander, eds. The Transfer o f Technology to Developing Countries. Papers and Proceedings of a Con ference Held at Airlie House, Warrenton, Virginia, April 1966. U.S. Department of Commerce, National Bureau of Standards, December 1966. 260 pp. 3.193 Participants discuss how technological know-how can effectively be imparted to developing countries, with particular attention to the role of the military. 3.190 Steiner, George A. “Improving the Trans fer of Government-Sponsored Tech nology.” Business Horizons, Vol. 9, No. 3, Fall 1966, pp. 55-62. 3.194 Sultan, Paul, and Prasow, Paul. “Tech nology and T a le n t.” Western Economic Journal, Vol. 3, No. 3, Summer 1965, pp. 247-273. The authors use the marginal produc tivity framework to explore the probable changes in the types and amount of labor demanded because of technical change. They foresee a quickening rate of auto mation, accentuated by management mistrust of labor and foreign competi tion. They consider the barriers to suc cessful manpower programs to be substantial. Strassman, W. Paul. Technological Change and Economic Development. Ithaca, N.Y., Cornell University Press, 1968. 353 pp. Considers the determinants of tech nological change in manufacturing during early industrialization. Deals with access to foreign technical knowledge, the Sturm, Herman M. Technology and Man power in the Health Service Industry, 1965-75. Manpower Research Bulletin No. 14. U.S. Department of Labor, Manpower Administration, May 1967. 109 pp. Presents and analyzes trends in the structure and characteristics of health service em ploym ent; technological developments likely to have an impact on manpower over the period under study; and effects of the expected trends on the demand for health services. Discusses some of the problems involved in the adoption of scientific knowledge by businessmen for new processes and products. Suggests the establishment of a government com mission to aid in the transfer and use of this knowledge. 3.191 Sturm, Herman M. “Technological Developments and Their Effects Upon Health Manpower.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 90, No. 1, January 1967, pp. 1-8. 3.195 49 Fellner, W. “Trends in the Activities Generating Technological Progress.” ment and the economic effects that may result from it. American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 1, March 1970, pp. 1-29. 3.200 Discusses average and marginal social rates of return of progress-generating inputs. 3.196 The Atlantic Institute. Technology Gap: U.S. and Europe. New York, Praeger, 1970. 158 pp. Surveys methods of processing coal in Europe and the United States. Briefly discusses the cost of mechanization and its effect on workers’ safety. Contains two papers and discussions concerning the extent of any “tech nological gap” that might exist, the causes of such a gap, and the methods by which it might best be closed. 3.197 3.201 “The Diffusion of New Technology: A Study of Ten Processes in Nine Indus tries.” National Institute Economic Review, No. 48, May 1969, pp. 40-83. 3.202 Thompson, F. M. L. “The Second Agri cultural Revolution, 1815-1880.” Economic History Review, Second Series, Vol. 21, No. 1, April 1968, pp. 62- 11 . 3.203 United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization. Conference on the Application o f Science and Technology to the Development o f Asia. Final Reports (two volumes). Paris, UNESCO, June 1969. Volume I contains the conclusions and recommendations arising from the conference. Volume II contains five messages directed to the conference. United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. Economic Aspects o f Automation. New York, United Nations, 1971.60 pp. 3.204 Reviews the scope of automation and discusses the economic conditions which permit or are required for its develop United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. Symposium on the A uto m a tio n o f Mining Operations. (Hombourg, France, April 1970.) New York, United Nations, 1970. 285 pp. A collection of papers detailing the innovations which have been introduced at various locations and stages of develop ment of mining. Suggests that technical and economic trends in agriculture between 1815 and 1880 differed fundamentally from trends in previous periods. Argues that the period under review is characterized by the growth of purchased inputs, rather than inputs produced on the farm. Examines implications for commercial and financial operations. 3.199 United Nations Economic Commission For Europe. Policies and Means o f Promoting Technical Progress. Papers presented to the Fifth Meeting of Senior Economic Advisors to ECE Governments. New York, United Nations, 1968. 159 pp. Reviews the difficulties in formulating policies on technological change, and reports on some of the programs which have been pursued. Presents case studies of the policies of several countries. Examines the introduction of several new technologies in an attempt to discover the factors governing the time required for a new invention to be applied internationally. 3.198 United Nations Economic Commission for Europe. Mechanization and A uto mation in Coking Plants. New York, United Nations, 1967. 41 pp. 50 United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization. Science and Technology in Asian Development. 3.208 Conference on the Application of Science and Technology to the Development of Asia (New Delhi, August 1968). Paris, UNESCO, 1970. 216 pp. Presents reports on technology in individual Asian countries. Investigates the conditions necessary for a more inten sive application of science and tech n o lo g y , finding adequate science education to be the most crucial require ment. Presents a mathematical model for planning the supply of professional and technical manpower and for research and development spending. 3.205 Discusses factors which promote or impede the application of scientific and technological findings resulting from the defense and space programs. 3.209 United Nations Educational, Scientific and Cultural Organization. World Summary o f Statistics on Science and Technology. Paris, UNESCO, 1970. 66 pp. United Nations Industrial Development Organization. Technological Develop ments in Lead and Zinc Production and Their Significance to Developing Countries. Report of the Expert Group Meeting on Lead and Zinc Industries. New York, United Nations, 1970. 85 pp. 3.210 Reviews recent technological develop ments in light of their possible applica tion in developing nations. Provides recommendations for both developing and developed countries. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Technological Trends in Major American Industries, BLS Bulletin 1474, 1966. 269 pp. Vilenskii, M. “On the Economic Manage ment of Scientific and Technological Progress.” Problems o f Economics, Vol. 13, No. 12, April 1971, pp. 3-24. Argues that the planning of techno logical progress must be dovetailed with the national economic plan of the Soviet Union. Indicates how this could be done. Appraises major technological changes and their effects on manpower require ments in individual American industries. Vernon, Raymond, ed. The Technology Factor in International Trade. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1970. 493 pp. A collection of papers on theoretical problems of incorporating the effect of technology in international trade theory. 3.211 3.207 Vatter, H. G., and Win, R. E. “Tech nology and the New Philosophy of Poverty.” Southern Economic Journal, Vol. 33, No. 4, April 1966, pp. 559-571. The authors argue that technological advance has made private investment and saving less important and consumption more important, providing the founda tion for a new philosophy of poverty. The traditional philosophy was appro priate to a capital-hungry society, whose goal was to minimize consumption and maximize investment, saving, and growth. But technological advance causes ever more capacity to be created, permitting community preferences to shift towards higher ratios of consumption to total output. In a capital-rich economy with high per capita income, poverty becomes dysfunctional. Summary of statistics on scientific manpower, research and development expenditures, graduates in science and technology, etc. 3.206 U.S. National Science Foundation. Tech nology Transfer and Innovation. Pro ceedings of a Conference held in Washington, D.C., May 1966, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1966. 126 pp. 51 3.212 Walton, Gary M. “Productivity Change in Ocean Shipping After 1870: A Comment.” The Journal o f Economic History, Vol. 30, No. 2, June 1970, pp. 435-442. ment of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1970. 8 pp. Discusses the economic setting of major trends in, and measures to facilitate, mechanization in the construc tion industry. Presents a methodological critique of an article by Knauerhase concerning the changes in productivity related to the adoption of steam ships and the decline of sailing vessels. (See entry 3.154.) 3.213 3.216 Warner, Aaron W. “Technology and the Labor Force in the Offshore Maritime Industry,” in Industrial Relations Research Association, Proceedings o f the Eighteenth Annual Winter Meeting (December 28-29, 1965), 1966, pp. 139-150. Discusses current directions of techno logical change, its likely future pace, and the factors which may speed or impede this pace. Argues that since government subsidies are given only to ships on regularly scheduled routes, the “tramp” sector of the industry has declined sharply. Its equipment is outdated and out of repair. States that by 1985 automation will have reduced manpower requirements per ship to one half of 1945 requirements, but that this reduction is not actually likely to take place because of a lack of ad eq u ately trained personnel and resistance by unions. 3.214 3.217 Westfield, F.M. “Technical Progress and Returns to Scale.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 48, No. 4, November 1966, pp. 432-448. 3.218 Yudelman, Montague; Banerji, Ranadev; and Butler, Gavan. “The Use of an Identity to Examine the Association Between Technological Changes and Aggregate Labour Utilization in Agri culture.” The Journal o f Development Studies, Vol. 7, No. 1, October 1970, pp. 37-49. The authors examine the relationship between output per person in agricultural land under cultivation and average yield per acre in terms of Japanese, Taiwanese, and Mexican agricultural experience. They argue that governments should be more aware of how their policies influence the direction of technological change and of the possible implications of these changes on labor utilization. Weinberg, Edgar. Mechanization and Automation o f Building Site Work. National Response Paper for the Economic Commission for Europe, Committee on Housing, Building and Planning. Third Seminar on the Building Industry, Moscow, October 1970. Mimeographed. U.S. Depart Yeh, M. H., and Lin, Leon. “Technologi cal Change in the Canadian Livestock In d u s try : An In p u t-O u tp u t Approach.” Canadian Journal o f Agri cultural Economics, Vol. 17, No. 2, July 1969, pp. 63-84. The authors analyze the rate of tech nological change in the beef industry and conclude that there was little improve ment in efficiency between 1951 and 1961. Examines the relation between tech nical progress and returns to scale, using Kendrick-Kuznets data for the United States for 1917-1960 and 1890-1960, and applying special methods of nonlinear estimation to the data. 3.215 Wolfbein, Seymour L. “The Pace of Technological Change and the Factors Affecting It.” in Manpower Implica tions o f Automation. U.S. Department of Labor, Manpower Administration. 1965. pp. 15-28. 52 3.219 Technological Knowledge.” American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 2, Zeisel, Rose N. Technology and Man power in the Textile Industry o f the 1970% BLS Bulletin 1578. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, August 1968. 79 pp. May 1969, pp. 29-34. Discusses invention and innovation within the framework of uncertainty and communication theories. Argues that this approach yields more meaningful results than traditional economic approaches. Examines changes in technology; their impact on productivity, employment, and occupational requirements; and methods of adjustment. 3.224 3.220 Zeisel, Rose N. “Technology and Labor in the Textile Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 91, No. 2, February 1968, pp. 49-55. Discusses mechanisms for optimal research and development and the possible lack of optimality in a private enterprise economy. Examines the case of optimality in a small country like Sweden with a considerable foreign trade in pharmaceuticals. Analyzes; the general economic setting of, and major technological developments in, the textile industry as well as their impact on productivity, employment, and skill requirements. Also discusses industry provisions for adjustments to these changes. 3.225 D. Research and development 3.221 Adams, W. J. “Firm Size and Research Activity: France and the United S ta te s .” Q uarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 84, No. 3, August 1970, pp. 386-409. 3.226 Ahmad, Syed. “On the Theory of In d u ced In v e n tio n .” Economic Journal, Vol. 76, No. 302, June 1966, pp. 344-357. Arrow, Kenneth J. “Classificatory Notes on the Production and Transmission of Brown, R. H. “The Achievement Norm and Economic Growth: The Case of Elizabethan England.” Review o f Social Economics, Vol. 27, No. 2, September 1969, pp. 181-201. Bases his argument on the need for a stratum of innovative businessmen to propel economic growth. Explores the values of Elizabethan England in terms of sociology, literature, education, child socialization, etc. Argues that an “achievement norm” developed about a generation before economic growth accelerated, and was causally related to it. Discusses past contributions to the theory of induced invention, relating innovation to changes in relative factor prices. Provides an analytic basis for the concept. 3.223 Becker, S. W., and Whistler, T. L. “The Innovative Organization: A Selective View o f C u rre n t Theory and Research.” Journal o f Business o f the University o f Chicago, Vol. 40, No. 4, October 1967, pp. 462-469. The authors review the status of theory on the subject of innovation. They distinguish between organizations which innovate and are the first to use new methods and organizations which are more cautious and tend to adapt to the innovations of others. Compares the effect of firm size on innovation in the United States and France. Concludes that the large firm is not an essential ingredient of tech nological change. 3.222 Arvidsson, G. “A Note on Optimal Allo cation of Resources for R and D.” Swedish Journal o f Economics, Vol. 72, No. 3, September 1970, pp. 171-195. 53 3.227 A collection of essays on the sources of innovation in the drug industry, modern drug research, costs and returns of innovation, patents, constraints, and related subjects. Discussion by seminar participants is included. Carroll, Jean. “A Note on Departmental Autonomy and Innovation in Medical Schools.” Journal o f Business, Vol. 40, No. 4, October 1967, pp. 531-534. Compares the process of innovation in medical schools with that described by March and Simon for Federal Govern ment departments, where innovations are passed on from the top. 3.228 3.231 Coleman, D. C. “An Innovation and its Diffusion: The ‘New Draperies’.” Economic History Review, Vol. 22, No. 3, December 1969, pp. 417-429. Examines the process of weapons system innovation in the Navy in terms of the behavioral sciences. Focusses on weapons systems adaptation to nuclear deterrence strategies and competition with the Air Force. Illustrates the difficulties of incorpo rating the emergence of new products in econometric models by tracing the inno vation, diffusion, and growth in use of new draperies, a product of the West European textile industry in the 16th and 17th centuries. Finds that a search for cost reduction or factor substitution in the in d u s try was o f secondary importance, that diffusion of new tech niques was dependent on such non economic factors as overseas migration induced by religious persecution, and that national market economies are inappro priate entities within which to investigate innovations and their diffusion. 3.229 3.232 Comanor, William S. “Research and Tech nical Change in the Pharmaceutical Industry.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 2, May 1965, pp. 182-190. 3.233 Feller, Irwin. “The Urban Location of United States Invention; 1860-1910.” Exploration o f Economic History, Vol. 8, No. 3, Spring 1971, pp. 285-303. Presents data for 35 of the largest and most industrialized U.S. cities from 1860 to 1910 in an effort to relate their growth and population and employment char acteristics to inventive activity. Cooper, Joseph D., ed. The Economics o f Drug Innovation. Proceedings of the first seminar on economics of pharma ceutical innovations, April 27-29, 1969. Washington, The American University, Center for the Study of Private Enterprise, School of Business Administration, 1970. 285 pp. Evan, William M., and Black, Guy. “Inno vation in Business Organizations: Some Factors Associated with Success or Failure of Staff Proposals.” Journal o f Business, Vol. 40, No. 4, October 1967, pp. 519-530. The authors analyze factors affecting the success of proposals for innovation submitted to line management by staff specialists. Investigates the relationship between research and development and the rate of new product introduction in the pharma ceutical industry. 3.230 Davis, Vincent. The Politics o f Innova tion: Patterns in Navy Cases. The Social Science Foundation and Graduate School of International Studies Monograph Series in World Affairs, Vol. 4, Monograph No. 3. Denver, University of Denver, 1967. 69 pp. 3.234 54 Goldsmith, Maurice, ed. Technological Innovation and the Economy. A Science o f Science Foundation Symposium on Technological Innova tion and Growth of the Economy 3.235 (C h u rch ill C ollege, Cambridge, England, April 1969). New York, Wiley-Interscience, 1970. 292 pp. to Inventive Activity.” American Economic Review, Vol. 61, No. 4, Discusses the roles of government and of the educational system, and the attitudes of management and labor. Maintains that individuals believe that any information they can discover may be useful for speculative or resale purposes, and therefore they tend to overinvest in inventive activity, rather than underinvest, as most commentators have assumed. September 1971, pp. 561-574. Griliches, Zvi. “Hybrid Corn and the Economics of Innovation,” in The R e in te r p r e ta tio n o f A m erica n Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley T. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971. pp. 207-213. 3.239 Examines differences by area in the acceptance of hybrid corn. Notes the S-shaped pattern of diffusion, corre sponding to that of technical change in general. Finds that adoption of hybrid corn depends mainly upon market factors. 3.236 Examines the factors which affect innovation and its diffusion. These factors include research and development a c tiv ity , purchase o f knowledge, economic and market structures, and availability of financing. Discusses the methods used in assessing the relative importance of innovations in terms of productivity, cost reductions, profits and sales, and patents. Havelock, Ronald G., and associates. Planning for Innovation Through Dissemination and Utilization o f Knowledge. Ann Arbor, Center for Research on Utilization of Scientific Knowledge, University of Michigan, July 1969. About 300 pp. 3.240 Provides a framework for evaluating th e fa c to rs a ffe c tin g innovation, dissemination, and utilization of knowl edge. Reviews the literature on the subject. 3.237 Higgs, R. “American Inventiveness, 1870-1920.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 79, No. 2, March-April 1971, pp. 661-667. 3.241 Kleiman, Herbert S. “A Case Study of Innovation.” Business Horizons, Vol. 9, No. 4, Winter 1966, pp. 63-70. Discusses the development of the integrated circuit, illustrating government and industry roles in innovation. 3.242 Knight, Kenneth E. “A Descriptive Model of the Intra-Firm Innovation Process.” Journal o f Business, Vol. 40, No. 4, October 1967, pp. 478-496. Hirshleifer, Jack. “The Private and Social Value of Information and the Reward Kamien, M. I., and Schwartz, N. “Market Structure, Elasticity of Demand and Incentive to Invent.” Journal o f Law and Economics, Vol. 13, No. 1, April 1970, pp. 241-252. Argues that between industries of like structure, the industry with the greater demand elasticity has the greater inven tion incentive, and that monopoly pro vides a greater incentive to invent than a competitive industrial structure. Extends the wealth maximization model of invention by taking account of costs of information and relating these costs to the urban-rural distribution of population. Concludes that the proportion of the population in urban areas and the number of inventions per capita were closely associated. 3.238 Johnston, R. E. “Technical Progress and In n o v a tio n .” O xford Economic Papers N.S., Vol. 18, No. 2, July 1966, pp. 158-176. 55 Discusses the process of innovation in terms of psychological, sociological, economic, and historical perspectives. Shows that innovation tends to be the product of small contributions by many individuals. 3.243 develop in the future and their effects on employment. 3.246 Leonard, William N. “Research and Development in Industrial Growth.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 79, No. 2, March-April 1971, pp. 232-256. Argues that, contrary to assertions by some researchers, the U.S. steel industry did not lag behind industry of other countries in installing the oxygen con verter process. Shows that all of the innovators —in Japan and Austria, as well as in the United States — met Schumpeter’s criteria that large firms with substantial market power have com paratively great incentives, in addition to ample resources, for research and innova tion. Details a number of economic and technological factors which complicate the decision to introduce new technology at one stage in an integrated plant. Finds that research intensity, measured by company R and D spend ing, relates significantly to growth rates in sales, assets, and net income in 16 industries. Results begin to appear two years after initial spending. Research intensity as measured by manpower ratios is less related to growth. Also finds that excessive allocation to defense and space R and D slows industrial growth. 3.244 Mansfield, Edwin. Industrial Research and Technological Innovation: A n Econometric Analysis. New York, W. W. Norton, 1968.235 pp. 3.247 Presents brief conclusions on such topics as the determination of the rate of technological change, the amount of research and development going on in the United States, the determinants of industrial research and development ex p e n d itu res, and the relationship between such expenditures and innova tion. Mansfield, Edwin. “Innovation and Tech nical Change in the Railroad I n d u s t r y , ” in T ra n sp o rta tio n Economics, John R. Meyer, ed. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1965. pp. 169-198. Minasian, Jora R. “Research and Develop ment, Production Functions, and Rates of Return.” American Economic Review, Vol. 59, No. 2, May 1969, pp. 80-85. Estimates a Cobb-Douglas production function for 17 chemical firms with technology dependent on R & D expenditures. Estimates separate rates of return on R & D expenditures and capital. Discusses trends in labor and total factor productivity, shifts in the produc tion function, distribution of inventions over time, the role of the largest railroads in introducing new techniques and their adoption by other companies, and the most promising technologies likely to Metcalfe, J. S. “Diffusion of Innovation in the Lancashire Textile Industry.” Manchester School o f Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 38, No. 2, June 1970, pp. 145-159. Investigates the diffusion of three cost-saving innovations in the weaving sector of the Lancashire textile industry. Finds that innovations which are similar in their economic and technical aspects are diffused in a similar manner. 3.248 3.245 McAdams, A. K. “Big Steel, Invention, and Innovation Reconsidered.” Quarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 81, No. 3, August 1967. pp. 457-474. 3.249 56 Mueller, Dennis C. Patents, Research and Development, and the Measurement o f Inventive Activity. Reprint No. 129. 3.254 Washington, The Brookings Institution, 1967. 11 pp. Presents estimates of correlation b etw een research and development expenditures, R&D employment, etc., as inputs, and the number of patents as outputs, in an attempt to measure inven tive activity. Finds the correlation to be high. 3.250 Reviews the strengths and weaknesses of national science policies in the 1960’s, and explores the relationships between eco n o m ic growth, technology, and society. Argues that society will demand more of technology in improving the quality of life as well as products and production processes in the 1970’s. Myers, Sumner, and Marquis, Donald B. Successfu l Industrial Innovations. Washington, National Science Founda tion, 1969. 117 pp. 3.255 The authors examine innovations in five industries, as well as the processes which led to commercial success. 3.251 3.256 Nordhaus, William D.Invention, Growth and Welfare: A Theoretical Treatment o f Technological Change. Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press, 1969. 168 pp. 3.257 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Government and Technical Innovation. Paris, OECD, 1966. 60 pp. Ruff, L. E. “Research and Technological Progress in a Cournot Economy.” Journal o f Economic Theory, Vol. 1, No. 4, December 1969, pp. 397-415. Applies techniques of optimal control theory to investigate the relations between the number of firms, the degree to which technological knowledge is a “public good,” and the institutional structure of the economy. The effect of F o resees governments becoming increasingly involved in the innovative process as the pace of technological change quickens. Discusses how a govern ment should stimulate innovation. Rudelius, W., and Wood, G. L. “Life Insurance and Product Innovations.” Journal o f Risk and Insurance, Vol. 37, No. 2, June 1970, pp. 185-190. The authors analyze six important life insurance innovations. Larger rather than smaller, and mutual rather than stock firms accepted innovation first. A firm that was an early adopter of one innova tion was found to be an early adopter of another. There was no apparent relation between growth of sales and rapid adop tion of innovation. Discusses the problem of the inventive process at the firm level. Considers the problems of invention in an economy wide, general equilibrium framework. 3.253 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. The Conditions for Success in Technological Innovation. Paris, OECD, 1971.169 pp. Examines the roles of government, private industry, and the university in technological change. Concludes that the most important factors encouraging successful change are assurance of reward, competition among industries, labor mobility, and manpower planning. Nelkin, Dorothy. The Politics o f Housing Innovation. Ithaca, N.Y., Cornell University Press, 1971,124 pp. Examines critically the “important but finally abortive” Civilian Industrial Technology Program, instituted in the early sixties to foster innovation in “lag ging” industries such as housing and textiles. Highlights the problems involved in attempts to restructure Federal research and development policy to respond to social needs. 3.252 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Science, Growth and Society: A New Perspective. Paris, OECD, 1971.113 pp. 57 at a moment in time between industries. Analyzes the effects of economic growth on technology by focusing on inventions. these relations on the rate of aggregate technological progress in an economy of independent producing-researching firms is examined. 3.262 3.258 Rumiantsev, A. “Problems of Scientific and Technological Progress.” Problems o f Economics, Vol. 13, No. 12, April 1971, pp. 25-45. Discusses technological change in terms of the process of invention, the patterns and effects of innovation in industry, and the consequences of tech nological change for social objectives. Explores the problems of measuring the contribution of research and develop ment to an economy in the Russian context. 3.263 3.259 Samuelson, Paul A. “A Theory of Induced Innovation Along Kennedy Weizsaecker Lines.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 4, November 1965, pp. 343-356. 3.264 Sapolsky, Harvey M. “Organizational S tru ctu re and Innovation” The Journal o f Business o f The University o f Chicago, Vol. 40, No. 4, October 1967, pp. 497-510. 3.265 S h ep ard , Herbert A. “InnovationResisting and Innovation-Producing Organizations.” Journal o f Business, Vol. 40, No. 4, October 1967, pp. 470-477. Discusses organizations in terms of ability to innovate and resistance to innovation. Stresses need for restructur ing organizations to accept or generate innovations. 3.266 S chm ookler, Jacob. Invention and Economic Growth. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press, 1966. 328 pp. Examines the causes of fluctuations in the number of inventions over time and Shell, Karl. “Towards a Theory of Inven tive Activity and Capital Accumula tion.” American Economic Review, Vol. 56, No. 2, May 1966, pp. 62-68. Argues that the rate of technical change may be estimated on the basis of the amount of economic resources devoted to inventive activity. By means of an illustrative study of department stores the author discusses problems of structuring an organization which will maximize utilization of inno vations. Decentralized organization facili tates innovation, yet putting innovations into effect requires more centralization. There is conflict between the search for and the adoption of innovation. 3.261 Shanks, Michael. The Innovators: The Economics o f Technology. Baltimore, Penguin Books, 1967. 294 pp. Explores social and economic factors which determine the pace of the applica tion of scientific knowledge in industry. Explores the notion, common among economists, that innovation has a laborsaving bias. Argues that, if it can be assumed that there is a tradeoff between innovational reductions in labor versus capital input requirements, long-run equilibrium in constant relative shares will exist. 3.260 Schon, Donald A. Technology and Change: The New Heraclitus. New York, Pergamon Press, 1967. 248 pp. 58 U.S. Congress, House, Committee on Science and Astronautics, Subcom mittee on Science, Research, and Development. Selected Readings on Science, Technology, and the Economy. Compiled by the Economics Division and the Science Policy Research Division, Congres sional Research Service, Library of Research and Development in Main land China. New York, Praeger, 1970. 592 pp. Congress. Washington, U.S. Govern ment Printing Office, 1971.95 pp. A compilation of comments on the relation between science, technology, and the economy. 3.267 The authors assemble the available facts on organization and support of science and make some observations on the methods by which the Chinese have acquired and used new knowledge. U.S. National Science Foundation, Divi sion of Science Resources and Policy Studies. A Review o f the Relationship between Research and Development and Economic Growth/Productivity. Washington, D.C., February 1971. 76 pp. IV. Productivity, prices, and costs 4.001 A collection of papers focussing on the effects of R&D on economic growth and productivity. 3.268 Explains the theories of wage determination in layman’s terms. Discusses the implications of, and alternatives to, an incomes policy for Canada. Verma, P. “Patents in British Industry.” Yorkshire Bulletin o f Economic and Social Research, Vol. 21, No. 2, November 1969, pp. 114-118. 4.002 Explains the relationship between productivity and technological change in British manufacturing industries over the period 1954-61. Uses the trend in patents as an indicator of technological change. 3.269 Argy, V. “International Comparisons of Rates of Change in Earnings.” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 20, No. 3, July 1968, pp. 221-232. Explains intercountry differences in rates of change in earnings in terms of two variables: differential unemployment rates and produc tivity growth rates. Williams, Bruce R. Technology, Invest ment and Growth. London, Chapman and Hah, Ltd., 1967.206 pp. 4.003 A collection of the author’s essays dealing with the “technology gap,” the process of innovation, the relation between research and development and economic growth, and related topics. 3.270 Anton, Frank R. Wages and Productivity: The New Equation. Toronto, The Capp Clark Publishing Company, 1969. 152 pp. Barnes, Irston R. “Do Productivity Gains Warrant Wage Increases?” The Conference Board Record, Vol. 8, No. 11, November 1971, pp. 3942. Holds that productivity gains should be distributed through lower prices rather than higher wages, and that higher wages necessarily lead to inflation. Wilson, Andrew H. Science, Technology and Innovation. Special Study No. 8. Ottawa, Economic Council of Canada, 1968. 139 pp. 4.004 Beller, Irving. “Unit Labor Costs and the Worker’s Share.” The American Federatiohist, Vol.72, No. 12, December 1965, pp. 8- 12. Presents a short history of the growth of science and technology. Discusses the process of innovation. Seeks to identify pertinent factors related to Canada’s future development. 3.271 Argues that unit labor costs in manufactur ing have declined significantly in recent years because increases in wages, salaries, and fringe benefits have been lagging behind productivity. Sees a trend toward economic stagnation if a disproportionate share of income continues to go to those who save and invest. Wu, Yuan-li, and Sheeks, Robert B. The Organization and Support o f Scientific 59 4.005 Beller, Irving. “A Social Role for Productivity.” The American Federationist, Vol. 74, No. 5, May 1967, pp. 6-13. “unlimited” number of persons would still be willing to work at the subsistence wage, because of differences in labor productivity. Explains the meaning and importance of productivity and reviews the productivity record of American workers. Argues that man agement is unjustly reaping the benefits of labor’s improved productivity. 4.006 4.011 Analyzes the relationship between labor costs and output per man-hour during the sixties. Blakeman, L. T. “Incomes, Productivity, and Planning.” Long Range Planning, Vol. 1, No. 4, June 1969, pp. 10-13. 4.012 Describes industrial relations planning at Ford of England and explains how the com pany attempts to formulate a wage program which is equitable and which encourages productivity gains. 4.007 Bliss, Charles A. “Flaw in the Wage-Price Guideposts.” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 44, No. 3, May/June 1966, pp. 73-78. 4.013 Bloom, Gordon F. “Productivity: Weak Link in Our Economy.” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 49, No. 1, January-February 1971, pp. 4-14. 4.014 Bodkin, Ronald G. The Wage-Price-Productivity Nexus. Philadelphia, University of Penn sylvania Press, 1966. 302 pp. 4.015 Bottomley, A., and Nudds, D. “Factor Pricing with ‘Unlimited’ Supplies of Labor.” Man chester School o f Economic and Social Studies, Vol. 35, No. 3, September 1967, pp. 277-284. Finds that the price of labor will rise with increasing demand for it, even though an Chandler, John H., and Jackman, Patrick C. Unit Labor Costs in Manufacturing: Trends in Nine Countries, 1950-65, BLS Bulletin 1518. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1966. 34 pp. The authors present and discuss indexes of unit labor costs, hourly compensation, output per man-hour, and related statistics for the United States, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, Sweden, and the United Kingdom. Analyzes econometrically the relationship between wages and prices in the American economy, 1900-1957, in an attempt to deter mine the compatibility of full employment and price stability as national economic goals. 4.010 Canadian Labor Congress. Labor Costs in Canada. Ottawa, Canadian Labor Congress, February 1966. 40pp. This pamphlet presentsorganized labor’s point of view, reviews recent trends in labor costs, and discusses the relationships between wages, productivity, profits, and prices. Maintains that productivity must rise as fast as capital and labor costs to prevent inflation. 4.009 B ro n fe n b re n n e r, Martin. “A Guidepost M o rte m .” Industrial Labor Relations Review, Vol. 20, No. 4, July 1967. pp. 637-649. Refutes the position of the Chicago School that macroeconomic policy, if administered sensibly, can eliminate any need for wage-price guideposts. Suggests changes in guideposts. Argues that using a measure of “physical” productivity in a “financial” context results in confusing gross and net productivity. 4.008 Brand, Horst. “Labor Costs: Major Sources of Recent Pressures.” The Conference Board Statistical Bulletin, Vol. 2, No. 1, January 1969, pp. 2-5. Chandler, John H., and Jackman, Patrick C. “Unit Labor Cost in Nine Countries: Cost Trends in Nine Industrial Nations.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 9, September 1965, pp. 1064-1068. The authors discuss long-term trends in comparative labor costs and in the components of cost ratios. 60 4.016 Argues that a wide range of structural adaptations in government policies, in collective bargaining, and in other private decisions is needed to stabilize wages and prices at sustained high levels of employment. Close, Guy C., Jr. Work Improvement. New York, John Wiley & Sons, Inc., 1960. 388 pp. Discusses methodology and techniques used by business, industry, and service organizations to reduce costs and increase productivity. 4.022 4.017 Confederation of British Industry.Productivity Bargaining. London, Confederation of British Industry, May 1968. 17 pp. Discusses the similarities and differences between Bureau of Labor Statistics and Chamber of Commerce definitions of fringe benefits. Sets forth the CBI’s view of productivity bargaining. Suggests guidelines for the optimal implementation of productivity bargaining. 4.018 Delagrave, Pierre M. “Wage Parity in Canada Not Possible Without Equal Increase in Productivity.” Canadian Vocational Journal, Summer, 1967, Vol. 3, No. 1, pp. 4-14. 4.023 Holds that the Canadian wage structure cannot be raised to the level prevailing in the United States until parity in productivity has. been achieved. 4.019 4.024 Douty, H. M. “Productivity Bargaining in Britain.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 91, No. 5, May 1968, pp. 1-6. 4.025 Great Britain, Department of Employment and Productivity. Productivity, Prices, and Incomes Policy A fter 1969. London, Her Majesty’s Stationery Office, December 1969. 43 pp. A White Paper reviewing past governmental efforts to stabilize and strengthen the economy. Discusses long-term growth and stabilization policies. Dunlop, John T. “Guideposts, Wages, and Collective Bargaining.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 89, No. 6, June 1966, pp. 630-633. Glejser, Herbert. “Inflation, Productivity and Relative Prices: A Statistical Study.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 1, February 1965, pp. 76-80. Investigates the influence on the magnitude of long-run relative price changes of inflation and increases in labor productivity. Formulates statistical models for intercountry comparisons of rates of increase in the consumption price level and in industrial productivity for each of 15 countries. Discusses economic conditions in Britain leading to productivity agreements between labor and management. Explains these agree ments as an exchange of higher wages for greater management control and new standards of work to insure more efficiency in produc tion. Discusses relation to costs, prices, and devaluation. 4.021 Freeman, R. E. “Roles of Farm Productivity and Marketing Margins in Postwar Decline in Farm Prices.” Journal o f Farm Economics, Vol. 48, No. 1, February 1966, pp. 31-41. Finds that changes in the farm prices of several food groups were associated negatively with changes in output per man-hour, and changes in marketing margins were not related to farm price changes. Douty, H. M. “Living Costs, Wages, and Wage Policy.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 90, No. 6, June 1967, pp. 1-7. Holds that wage policy in the United States represents an element in a strategy for price stability under conditions of high employment. The basic guidepost for wage adjustment is the trend of output per man-hour in the private sector. 4.020 Fox, Harland. “Comparing the Cost of Fringe Benefits.” The Conference Board Record, Vol. 4, No. 5, May 1967, pp. 29-35. 61 4.026 to their higher concentration in the low-income South. Great Britain, National Board for Prices and Incomes. Productivity Agreements. Report No. 36. London, Her Majesty’s Stationery Office, 1967. 77 pp. 4.031 Discusses characteristics and effects of productivity bargaining in light of seven specific agreements. 4.027 The authors develop a theoretical model for the size distribution of income with labor’s relative share as a function of technological change. They analyze the impact of techno logical change, education, transfer payments, and inflation on the inequality of income distribution. Great Britain, National Board for Prices and Incomes. Productivity and Pay During the Period o f Severe Restraint. Report No. 23. London, Her Majesty’s Stationery Office, 1966. 22 pp. Discusses the purposes and characteristics of productivity agreements and weighs the result ing gains and costs. 4.028 4.032 Great Britain, National Economic Development Council. Productivity, Prices, and Incomes: A General Review. London, National Economic Development Office, 1967. 41 pp. 4.033 Great Britain, Royal Commission on Trade U nions and Employers’ Associations. “ Productivity Bargaining,” in Research Papers, 4. London, Her Majesty’s Stationery Office, 1967. pp. 1-46. Gwartney, J.D . “Employment Discrimination, P ro d u c tiv ity F a c to rs, and Income Differentials Between White and Non-White Males in 1959.” American Economic Review, Vol. 60, No. 3, June 1970, pp. 396408. 4.034 Horvitz, Wayne L. “The ILWU-PMA Mechaniza tion and Modernization Agreement,” in Industrial Relations Research Association, Proceedings o f the Twenty-First Annual Winter Meeting (December 29-30, 1968), 1969, pp. 144-151. Reviews and evaluates results of the 1963 agreement between the Longshoremen’s Union and shippers to avoid expected upheavals caused by rapid technological change in cargo loading procedures. Using data from the census and the U.S. Department of Health, Education, and Welfare, the author discusses the “productivity factors” affecting the income of nonwhites as compared with whites. He finds that between two-fifths to two-thirds of the income differential is due to lower educational attainment and lower scholastic achievement of non whites, as well as Hartman, Paul T. Collective Bargaining and Productivity: The Longshore Mechanization Agreement. Berkeley, Calif., University of California Press, 1969. 307 pp. Discusses origins of restrictive labor practices and their eventual elimination through collec tive bargaining and other union actions. Pro vides quantitative estimates of productivity change after restrictive rules were abandoned. Reviews the operation of productivity bar gaining and the gains and losses to be realized from it. 4.030 Harris, E. Marjorie, ed. The Realities o f Produc tiv ity Bargaining. Industrial Relations Committee Report. London, Institute of Personnel Management, May 1968. 46 pp. Discusses aspects of productivity bargaining, p artic u la rly in labor-intensive situations. Examines three existing productivity agree ments in detail. Presents and discusses statistics on prices, productivity, and income from employment and other sources in the United Kingdom. 4.029 Harmston, Floyd K., and Hino, Hiroyuki. Tech nological Change and the Inequality o f Income Distribution. Discussion Paper 71-1. Columbia, Mo., University of Missouri, May 1971.22 pp. 4.035 62 Hultgren, Thor. Costs, Prices, and Profits: Their Cyclical Relations. New York, National Tests, by means of multiple regression analysis, the influence of productivity, size, and c o n c e n tra tio n upon inter-industry wage differentials. Bureau of Economic Research, 1965. 229 pp. Examines the behavior of profits and the factors determining profits during the business cycle. 4.036 4.041 Hunt, E. H. “Labour Productivity in English Agriculture: 1850-1914.” Economic History Review, Vol. 20, No. 2, August 1967, pp. 280-292. Presents an econometric model incorporat ing wage determination equations. Scrutinizes the role of profits in the wage equation, which are considered to be a proxy for productivity. Form ulates a productivity determination theory. Finds that the unemployment level does not provide a strong explanation of wage changes and that quarterly statistical explana tions of wage changes are of poor quality. Productivity explained more variance in wage change than profits or the Phillips curve. Explains why agricultural wages in northern England from 1850-1914 were substantially above those in southern England. Regional variations in wages were associated with differences in labor productivity. Farmers in high-*vage areas found themselves at no com petitive disadvantage. 4.037 International Labor Office. Statistics o f Labour Cost. Report prepared for the Eleventh International Conference of Labor Sta tisticians (Geneva, October 1966). Geneva, ILO, 1966. 53 pp. 4.042 Discusses the need to develop reliable measures of the level, composition, and trend of labor costs. 4.038 4.043 Jones, Ken, and Golding, John. Productivity Bargaining. Fabian Research Series 257. London, Fabian Society, November 1966. 38 pp. Kamerschen, David R. “Inter-Industry Earnings Differentials, Productivity, Size, and Con centration.” Journal o f Industrial Relations, Vol. 9, No. 1, March 1967, pp. 52-64. Li-Tien, F., and Chien, W. “A Quantitative Analysis of the Relationship Between the Rate of Growth of Productivity and the Average Wage.” Chinese Economic Studies, Vol. 3, No. 1, Fall 1969, pp. 70-91. The authors hold that labor should receive in the form of wages the benefits from increases in productivity due to increased quality of labor, but that savings due to technological advance should for the most part be retained to further the capital accumulation of the State and the capacity to produce. Strongly advocating productivity bargaining, the authors discuss some features of, and experience with, actual agreements. 4.040 Lamson, Robert D. “Measured Productivity and Price Change: Some Empirical Evidence on Service Industry Bias; Motion Picture Theaters.” Journal o f Political Economy, Vol. 78, No. 2, March-April 1970, pp. 291-305. Discusses the problem of measuring quality change in the motion picture theater industry. Finds that greater attention to the specification of the output of service industries may alter relative appraisals of price and productivity performance. Isaac, Julius E. Wages and Productivity. M elbourne, Canberra, Australia, F. W. Chesire, 1967. 157 pp. Discusses the principles by which the Com monwealth Conciliation and Arbitration Com mission (Australia) determines its wage awards. Also discusses the structure and level of actual earnings. 4.039 Kuh, Edwin. “A Productivity Theory of Wage Levels—An Alternative to the Phillips Curve.” Review o f Economic Studies, Vol. 34(4), No. 100, October 1967, pp. 333-360. 4.044 63 Mark, Jerome A. Wage-Price Guidepost Sta tistics: Problems o f Measurement. Paper | presented before the American Statistical Association, Pittsburgh, August 20-22, 1968. 4.049 Reviews problems associated with the devel opment of output per man-hour measures used for implementing the guide post policy. 4.045 The authors argue that with an increase in wages over a certain range, the increase in resulting productivity is proportionately higher than the wage increase itself. Mark, Jerome A., and Kahn, Elizabeth. “Unit Labor Cost in Nine Countries: Recent Unit Cost Trends in U.S. Manufacturing.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 9, September 1965, pp. 1056-1060. 4.050 The authors discuss trends in post-war labor costs, productivity, and real labor payments. 4.046 4.051 4.052 Mazel, Joseph L. “The Productivity Gap Gets Wider.” Modern Manufacturing, August 1968, pp. 56-61. North, Dick T. B., and Buckingham, G. L. Productivity Agreements in Wage Systems. London, Gower Press, 1969. 262 pp. The authors discuss the main problems in productivity bargaining at the plant level and suggest some ways of solving them. They provide a conceptual framework in which productivity agreements can be understood, and summarize the salient features of experience gained. Mitchell, Edward J. “Explaining the Inter national Pattern of Labor Productivity and Wages: A Production Model with Two Labor Inputs.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 50, No. 4, November 1968, pp. 461-469. 4.053 Seeks an explanation of wage and labor productivity differentials among eleven coun tries by introducing a rough measure of labor quality in estimating each country’s production function. Concludes that a substantial portion of the cross-national differences can be explained by differences in the skill composi tion of the labor force. Neef, Arthur. “Unit Labor Costs in Eleven Countries.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 94, No. 8, August 1971, pp. 3-12. Discusses comparative trends in unit labor costs, labor compensation, and productivity during the 1960’s. Discusses disparity between productivity trends and compensation trends in the postwar period, and what management can do to narrow this gap in terms of increased efficiency. 4.048 Myers, John G. “Productivity Is Up.” The Conference Board Record, Vol. 7, No. 10, October 1970, pp. 10-14. Discusses the relationship between output, productivity, employment, and unit labor costs in Spring 1970, as well as over the longer term. Mauer, J. J., and Hemley, D. D. “Racial Discrimination, Productivity, and NegroWhite Income.” Review o f Social Economy, Vol. 28, No. 2, September 1970, pp. 164-172. Examines reasons for wage differentials between whites and Negroes. Finds that labor productivity mostly explains white-non white income differentials in States outside the South and discrimination mostly explains them in the South. 4.047 Moes, J. E., and Bottomley, A. “Wage Rate Determination with Limited Supplies of Labour in Developing Countries.” Journal o f Development Studies, April 1968, Vol. 4, No. 3, pp. 380-386. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Forms o f Wage and Salary Payment for High Productivity. Inter national Management Seminar (Versailles, September 26-29, 1967). Paris, OECD, 1970.411 pp. Reviews and assesses the effectiveness of forms of wage and salary compensation in 11 member countries. Reports on several new approaches to improving productivity through pecuniary incentives. 64 4.054 Also discusses output per unit of labor, product substitution, and labor mobility as deter minants of sectoral wage movements. Organization for Economic Cooperation and D ev elo p m ent. Producti vity Bargaining. Report by the British Joint Team which visited the United States from 15th-25th May, 1966, to study productivity bargaining. Paris, OECD, 1966. 25 pp. 4.059 Compares the institutional and policy back grounds of American and British industrial relations bearing on the concept of productivity bargaining and its implementation. Presents case studies. 4.055 Examines the relationship between price trends and productivity trends in manu facturing in terms of (1) wage-price guideposts and (2) expected price movements where an industry seeks to maintain a target rate of return on capital. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Wages and Labor Mobility. Paris, OECD, 1965. 258 pp. 4.060 Examines the relationship between changes in wage structures and changes in employment patterns. Points out several wage situations which can, with economic justification, be given as exceptions to productivity guidelines. 4.056 Phelps-Brown, E. H. A Century o f Pay: The Course o f Pay and Production in France, Germany, Sweden, the United Kingdom, and the United States o f America, 1860-1960. New York, St. Martin’s Press, 1969. 476 pp. 4.061 Phipps, Anthony J. “The Roles of Labor Productivity and Demand in the Pricing Process: An Inter-Industry Study Using Time-Series Data.” Bulletin. Oxford Uni versity Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 31, No. 4, November 1969, pp. 285-297. 4.062 Reynolds, Lloyd G., and Gregory, Peter. Wages, Productivity, and Industrialization in Puerto Rico. Homewood, 111., Richard D. Irwin, 1965.357 pp. The authors report on industrial develop ment, management policies, and labor price characteristics between 1945 and 1955. They find management skill the most important factor affecting productivity. Pitchford, J. D. “Wage Policy and Distribution Theory.” Economica, Vol. 34, No. 134, May 1967, pp. 167-180. 4.063 Investigates the determination of wage policy in the context of factor substitution. Rees, Albert, and Hamilton, Mary T. “The Wage-Price-Productivity Perplex.” Journal o f Political Economy, February 1967, pp. 63-70. Discusses the limitations of Phillips curves in explaining the relationship between changes in price and wage levels and unemployment. The context of the discussion is a critical review of The Wage-Price-Productivity Nexus, by Ronald G. Bodkin. (See entry 4.009.) Finds that in labor-intensive industries, prices are cyclically sensitive to changes in productivity and demand, while in capitalintensive industries, prices are cyclically rela tively insensitive. 4.058 Read, L. M. “The Measure of Total Factor Productivity Appropriate to Wage-Price G u id e lin e s.” Canadian Jo u rn a l o f Economics, May 1968. Suggests a solution of the simultaneous type in calculating capital carried and capital con sumed when computing total factor produc tivity. Also discusses wage-price relations in terms of productivity change. Shows that the rise in real wages owed much to productivity increases, and that both of these variables are dependent on technical change and the expectations of businessmen. 4.057 Raines, Frederick Q. “Price and Productivity Trends in Manufacturing Industries.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 49, No. 3, August 1967, pp. 393-403. 65 Robertson, D. J. “Guideposts and Norms: Con trasts in U.S. and U.K. Wage Policy.” Reprinted from The Three Banks Review, 4.068 December 1966, No. 72. Reprint no. 294. California, Institute of Industrial Relations, 1967. 29 pp. Examines similarities and differences in U.S. and U.K. wage policies. 4.064 Defines and assesses productivity bargaining in terms of what is expected from it for economic growth, efficiency in the use of labor, the distribution of income, and the labormanagement bargaining process. Robertson, D. J. Productivity Bargaining and the Engineering Industry. London, Kogan Page Associates, for the Engineering Employers’ Federation, 1968. 60 pp. 4.069 Presents guidelines for planning, negotiating, and implementing productivity agreements, and discusses pertinent problems. Also presents a case study, and shows how factors involved in productivity bargaining may be quantified. 4.065 Robinson, Derek. “Implementing an Incomes Policy.” Industrial Relations, Vol. 8, No. 1, October 1968. pp. 73-90. 4.070 4.071 Shrivastav, Omkar S. Economics o f Wages, Productivity and Employment. Gwalior, India, Kailash Pustak Sadan, 1968. 257 pp. Towers, B., and Whittingham, T. G., eds. The New Bargainers: A Symposium on Produc tivity Bargaining. Nottingham, England, Department of Adult Education, University of Nottingham, 1970. 179 pp. A compendium of papers analyzing the nature of productivity bargaining, tracing its development, assaying its effects, and assessing its future. 4.072 Shultz, George P., and Aliber, Robert Z., eds. Guidelines, Informal Controls and the Market Place: Policy Choices in a Full Employment Economy. Chicago, 111., The University of Chicago Press, 1966. 357 pp. Trades Union Congress. Productivity, Prices and Incomes. London, Trades Union Congress, 1965.71 pp. Discusses economic policy in light of the economic situation of Great Britain. Gives an account of discussions between the TUC, the Government, and employer organizations. Contains the proceedings of a conference held at the University of Chicago in April 1966 on policies to influence the market behavior of individual businesses, banks, and labor unions. Productivity change is among the criteria for guidelines and controls. Topham, Tony. Productivity Bargaining and Workers’ Control. Nottingham, England, The Institute for Workers’ Control, 1968. 11 pp. Reviews recent trends in productivity bar gaining, arguing that it aims at wage control and higher profitability, and that it undermines workers’ control at the plant level. Analyzes the relation between wages, productivity, and employment, with special application to developing economies. Reviews and criticizes present theories. 4.067 “Symposium on Productivity Bargaining.” British Journal o f Industrial Relations, Vol. 5, No. 1, March 1967, pp. 1-62. Includes five papers assessing the advantages and disadvantages of various productivity bar gaining approaches. Outlines four stages in adopting a voluntary price and incomes policy, using Britain as a model: (1) obtaining general acceptance of its need, (2) determining policy content, (3) establishing means for implementation, and (4) implementing the policy. Predicts new attitudes towards collective bargaining as government becomes more involved in labor management relations. Sees a need for patience if policies are to be accepted over the long term. 4.066 Stettner, Nora. Productivity Bargaining and Industrial Change. London and New York, Pergamon Press, 1969. 185 pp. 4.073 66 Turner, Marjorie S. “A Comparison of Some Aspects of the Cambridge Theory of Wages and Marginal Productivity Theory.” Journal o f Economic Issues, Vol. 1, No. 3, September 1967, pp. 189-198. Compares the two theories in terms of realism of assumptions in model construction; success of approximation schemes; possibility of distinguishing the model from the theory; and predictive capability. Also discusses possibilities of integrating the two theories. 4.074 Ulman, Lloyd. “Collective Bargaining and Industrial Efficiency.” Reprinted from Richard E. Caves and Associates, ed., Britian’s Economic Prospects. London, George Allen and Unwin Ltd., 1968. Reprint No. 326. Berkeley, University of California, 1968. pp. 323-380. 4.080 U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee. Productivity, Prices, and Incomes. Materials prepared by the Committee Staff, 89th Congress, 2nd session. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 1967. 213 pp. U.S. Secretary of Labor James D. Hodgson. “The Role of Productivity in the Attainment of National Goals.” Speech before the National Machine Tool Builders Association, Washington, D.C., November 11, 1971. 10 pp. Reviews the recent productivity perfor mance of the economy. Discusses the impact of rising productivity on inflation, the inter national competitiveness of U.S. goods, and the quality of life. 4.081 U.S. Congress, Joint Economic Committee. The Wage Price Issue: The Need for Guideposts. Hearing 90th Congress, 2nd session. Wash ington, U.S. Government Printing Office, January 31,1968. 82 pp. Wiles, R. C. “The Theory of Wages in Later English Mercantilism.” Economic History Review, Vol. 21, No. 1, April 1968, pp. 113-126. Suggests that one of the views most com monly attributed to mercantilist economic thought is the desirability of low wages as a guarantee of a favorable balance of trade. However, the “later English mercantilists” recognized that high wages did not conflict with low or competitive prices because of the relationship between productivity and prices. Examines the evidence on the stabilizing effects of guideposts, and the need for their revival. Commenting on the suggestions set U.S. Department of Labor, Manpower Adminis tration. Management Decisions to Automate. Manpower/Automation Research Mono graph No. 3,1965. 37 pp. Reports on the factors that influenced man agerial decisions to automate in eight firms. Compares automation results with expecta tions. Finds expectations of cost reductions through increased labor productivity to be the determining factor. Presents data dealing with productivity, prices, wages, and profits for the economy as a whole and for two selected industrial areasfood products and metals. Characteristics and limitations of the data are summarized. Significant changes in the economy, as revealed by the data, are indicated. 4.077 U.S. Council of Economic Advisers. “Guideposts for Noninflationary Wage and Price Behavior,” in Labor and the National Economy. New York, W.W. Norton, 1965, pp. 88-94. Explains how long-run, economy-wide changes in productivity can be used as a guide for appraising the behavior of wages and prices. 4.079 Identifies and evaluates restrictions on industrial efficiency resulting from the British system of collective bargaining, and discusses policies designed to increase labor productivity. 4.076 4.078 Towers, B., and Whittingham, T.G . “Produc tivity Bargaining in the United Kingdom: An Overview.” Journal o f Industrial Relations, Vol. 13, September 1971, pp. 251-273. The authors define the concept and trace the development of productivity bargaining, as well as its repercussions for industrial relations and for the British economy. 4.075 forth in the committee are Gary Fromm, John W. Kendrick, George L. Perry, and John Sheahan. 67 4.082 Williams, Roger. “Profits: A Fruit of Produc tivity.” Nation’s Business, Vol. 58, No. 10, October 1970, p. 101. input-output relationships and converted into employment requirements through productivity and price adjustments. Argues that productivity data are the best guide for management to improve profits. Shows that profits have increased since World War II only when gains in GNP were larger than cost increases. Productivity decreases when there has been a period of growth with extended low unemployment. Suggests execu tives examine cost records regularly, not just when profits are pinched. 4.083 5.002 Surveys the impact of computer technology on the lower level executive ranks, finding that automation has eliminated or radically changed many of these positions. Wise, David. A n International Comparison o f Unit Labor Cost in the Iron and Steel Industry, 1964: United States, France, Germany, United Kingdom, BLS Bulletin 1580. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1968. 64 pp. 5.003 Wood, Ian, and Lawler, Edward E. “Effects of Piece-Rate Overpayment on Productivity.” Journal o f Applied Psychology, Vol. 54, No. 3, June 1970, pp. 234-238. 5.004 The authors maintain that “excessive” wage rates lead to lower productivity and a higher quality of workmanship. 4.085 Zudak, L. S. “Productivity, Labor Demand, and Cost in a Continuous Production Facility.” Journal o f Industrial Economics. Vol. 18, No. 3, July 1970, pp. 256-275. 5.005 Automobile Manufacturers Association. Tech nological Change and Employment in the Automotive Industry. Detroit, Automobile Manufacturers Association, Inc., 1965. 8 pp. Discusses the manpower and collective bargaining policies of tU.S. automakers. 5.006 V. Productivity and employment Alterman, Jack. “Interindustry Employment Requirements.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 7, July 1965, pp. 841-850. Bardwell, George E., and Mahar, James F. A Method o f Measuring Short-Term Impacts o f Technological Change on Employment and O c cu p a tio n s. Denver, Colo., Denver Research Institute, University of Denver, September 1965. 92 pp. The authors study the innovation process in a sample of power laundries. They formulate a model to predict the impact of innovative capital equipment on employment and skill requirements. Explains the interindustry employment tables showing U.S. direct and indirect employ ment per billion dollars of delivery to final demand and how they were derived from 1958 Aionson, Robert L. Jobs, Wages and Changing Technology: Recent Experience. Bulletin 55. Ithaca, N.Y., Cornell University, July 1965.74 pp. Discusses ways to ease the adjustments necessitated by technological change. Analyzes output, capital, and labor require ments in continuous process facilities, holding that marginal product analysis is inapplicable. 5.001 Ammer, Dean S. Mechanization and Manpower in Gray Iron Foundries. Boston, Bureau of Business and Economic Research, North eastern University, September 1965. 234 pp. Examines technological changes and their effects on production and employment. Com pares management and automation decisions in foundries of widely varying levels of tech nology. Provides a detailed comparison of, and dis cusses factors affecting, unit labor costs. 4.084 American Foundation on Automation and Employment. Automation and the Middle Manager. New York, American Foundation on Automation and Employment, 1966. 49 pp. 68 5.007 Details the technological changes that have occurred and can be expected to occur in the future on several classes of ships. Discusses the effect of the changes on employment, working conditions, and worker attitudes. Barkin, Solomon, ed. Technical Change and Manpower Planning. Paris, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1967.287 pp. Presents 29 case studies prepared in eight countries on the methods of programing tech nological change and manpower adjustments. 5.008 5.013 Bauer, L. L. “The Effect of Technology on the Farm Labor Market.” American Journal o f Agricultural Economics, Vol. 51, No. 3, August 1969, pp. 605-618. Surveys the methods that unions and man agement have adopted to soften the adverse effects of technological change on workers. Estimates the time path of the effect of technology, as measured by expenditures for research and extension services, on the farm labor market. 5.009 5.014 Bauer, Raymond A., ed. Second-Order Con sequences: A Methodological Essay on the Impact o f Technology. Cambridge, Mass., The M.I.T. Press, 1969. 240 pp. 5.015 Bonwick, George J., and Cox, R. W., eds. Automation on Shipboard. Proceedings of a seminar held at Elsinore, Denmark, by the International Institute for Labor Studies, September 1965. London, Macmillan Co. Ltd., 1967. 127 pp. 5.016 Bowen, Howard R., and Mangum, Garth L., eds. Automation and Economic Progress. Englewood Cliffs, N.J., Prentice-Hall, 1966. 170 pp. 5.017 Crossman, E. R. F. W. Automation, Skill, and Manpower Predictions. Seminar on Man power Policy and Program. U.S. Department of Labor, Manpower Administration, 1966. 53 pp. Develops a general model for employment in an automated economy and discusses the man power changes associated with progress towards a thoroughly automated society. Theorizes that labor will come to depend more on capital in place than on demand. Buck, P. B. “Technological Change and the Merchant Seaman.” International Labour Review, Vol. 92, No. 4, October 1965, pp. 298-313. Cottrell, Fred. Technological Change and Labor in the Railroad Industry. Lexington, Mass., Heath Lexington Books, 1970. 159 pp. Compares the effects of changing technology on workers in the United States, the United Kingdom, and New Zealand. A summary of the Report of the National Commission on Technology, Automation, and Economic Progress. 5.012 Christensen, Eric. Automation and the Workers. London, LRD Publications, 1968. 100 pp. Explores questions relating to the effects of automation and its ramifications in several British industries. A collection of papers detailing recent tech nological changes and their effects on employ ment, skill requirements, and labor relations. 5.011 Canada Department of Labor. Technological Changes in the Railway Industry: Employ ment Effects and Adjustment Process. Ottawa, Canada Department of Labor, Economics and Research Branch, 1967. 161 pp. Examines the interaction between tech nological changes and employment on the basis of observations in a major railroad repair shop. Discusses the indirect effects of techno logical change on society, industry, and the environment. Focuses on the secondary effects of the space program. 5.010 Canada Department of Labor. Response to Technological Change. Ottawa, Canada Department of Labor, 1967. 17 pp. 69 5.018 Day, R. H. “The Economics of Technological Change and the Demise of the Share cropper.” American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 3, June 1967, pp. 427449. 5.023 S um m arizes findings on production, technological change, resource utilization, and labor demand from a recursive programing model of the Mississippi Delta farm economy. Shows that a “two-stage” push forced workers out of year-round employment in agriculture, and then forced them out of agriculture altogether. 5.019 The authors examine the extent and pace of the introduction of electronic data processing, and its implications for employment and occu pational requirements. 5.024 Delehanty, George E. Nonproduction Workers in U.S. Manufacturing. Amsterdam, NorthHolland Publishing Company, 1968. 256 pp. 5.025 Domangue, Dennis A. “Technology Changes the Sugarcane Labor Force.” Employment Service Review, Vol. 2, Nos. 1 and 2, January-February 1965, pp. 5-8. 5.026 Dorner, Peter. “Needed Redirections in Eco nomic Analysis for Agricultural Develop ment Policy.” American Journal o f Agricul tural Economics, Vol. 53, No. 1, February 1971, pp. 8-16. 5.027 Foster, Howard G. “Unemployment and Shorter Hours.” Labor Lccw Journal, Vol. 17, No. 4, April 1966, pp. 211-225. Evaluates shorter working hours as a device to combat unemployment. Includes a discus sion of productivity and unit labor costs. Freedman, Audrey, and Weinberg, Edgar. “Changing Manpower Needs in Telephone Offices.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 91, No. 2, February 1968, pp. 56-58. The authors describe how manpower adjustments were made in four cases of shifts from manual to automatic dialing and highlight the importance of a variety of measures to minimize dislocation of workers arising from technological change. Urges close examination of the secondary effects of increases in agricultural productivity, such as changing employment and income distribution patterns. 5.022 Freedman, Audrey; Hammerman, Herbert; and Riche, Richard. Manpower Planning for Technological Change: Case Studies o f Telephone Operators, BLS Bulletin 1574. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1968. 34 pp. The authors describe the manpower policies and experiences of several companies within the Bell Telephone System in converting from manual to long-distance dial telephone systems. Describes how increased mechanization over the last 25 years has nearly eliminated the unskilled, seasonal worker. 5.021 Freedman, Audrey. “Office Automation in the In su ran ce Industry.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 11, November 1965, pp. 1313-1319. Discusses a 1963 BLS study of the extent of electronic data processing and its effects on employment patterns. Analyzes the nature, causes, and implica tions of the increase in the number of nonpro duction workers relative to production workers in manufacturing during the postwar period. Finds a positive correlation between increases in productivity and increases in the number of nonproduction workers. 5.020 Freedman, Audrey; Elliott, Mable; and Keyes, J. Stephen. Impact o f Office Automation in the Insurance Industry, BLS Bulletin 1468. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1966. 71 pp. Friedrichs, Gunter. “Planning Social Adjust ment to Technological Change at the Level of the Undertaking.” International Labour Review, Vol. 92, No. 2, August 1965, pp. 91-105. Outlines minimum trade union demands for the right to plan with management for adjust 70 Policy, sponsored by the National Council on the Aging, Washington, D.C., October 26, 1965. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1965. 8 pp. ment to technological cnange. Suggests that indemnities be paid to workers who are laid off. 5.028 Fryer, John L. “The Implications of Technological Change for Collective Bar gaining.” Industrial Relations, Vol. 22, No. 3, July 1969, pp. 411-421. Discusses past productivity trends, the rela tionship between productivity and employment change, and the future of productivity change and its impact on employment. Stresses the importance of collective bar gaining in solving problems created by techno logical change. Sees a need for new approaches and an enquiry to investigate aspects of tech nological change in Canada. 5.029 5.033 Fuchs, Victor R. “The Growing Importance of the Service Industries.” Journal o f Business o f the University o f Chicago. Vol. 38, No. 4, October 1965, pp. 344-373. Reviews the 20th century productivity pat tern in the United States, with particular reference to the effects of productivity increase on employment, and discusses possible future trends in productivity and employment. Examines the shift in employment and in the gross national product from the goods to the service sector. Discusses some of the impli cations for employment opportunities and sta bility, labor, demand for capital goods, and industrial organization as well as the complica ting effects the shift will have on the economic analysis of productivity. 5.030 5.034 Gaevskaia, V. “Certain Findings of a Study on the Utilization of Labor Resources.” Prob lems o f Economics, Vol. 12, No. 12, April 1970, pp. 45-60. 5.035 5.036 Herman, Arthur S. “Manpower Implications of Com puter Control in Manufacturing.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 10, October 1970, pp. 3-8. Finds from a survey of six industries that expanded use of computers created new jobs and that it did not displace many- workers, although it required retraining. Greenberg, Leon. Productivity Trends and Unemployment. Address to Seminar on Automation, Manpower, and Retirement Helfgott, Roy B. “Easing the Impact of Tech nological Change on Employees: A Conspec tus of United States Experience.” Inter national Labour Review, Vol. 91, No. 6, June 1965, pp. 503-519. Reviews measures taken by companies and unions to minimize the social and economic disruption due to technological change. Goldberg, Joseph P. “Containerization as a Force for Change on the Waterfront.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 91, No. 1, January 1968, pp. 8-13. Discusses the effect of containerization on shipping, longshore labor requirements, and operations. Reviews the union-management agreements made to ease the changes. 5.032 Haase, Peter E. “Technological Change and Manpower Forecasts.” Industrial Relations, Vol. 5, No. 3, May 1966, pp. 59-71. Examines the information available on how technology affects employment, occupational requirements, and job content. Outlines methods of forecasting the manpower impact of technological change. Summarizes a survey of collective farms in Russia, finding large-scale underutilization and uneven utilization of farm labor, especially of women. Argues for the establishment of secondary industries to employ laborers during the long non-growing season. 5.031 Greenberg, Leon. “Technological Change, Pro ductivity, and Employment in the United States,” in Manpower Implications o f A uto mation. U.S. Department of Labor, Man power Administration, 1965, pp. 1-14. 71 5.037 tions, with special reference to the metalwork ing industry. Hubbard, Norman S. “Short-Run Changes in Labor Productivity in United States Manu facturing, 1954-59.” Yale Economic Essays, Vol. 8, No. 2, Fall 1968. 74 pp. 5.043 Estimates short-run employment elasticity for individual manufacturing establishments. 5.038 Illinois. Report o f the State o f Illinois Com mission on Automation and Technological Progress, 1967. Prepared under the direction of William Karp. Springfield, 1967. 108 pp. Reviews recent changes in technology and their effects on the labor force. 5.044 Presents several case studies of key Illinois industries where the problem of technological disemployment was encountered. Makes a series of recommendations. 5.039 5.045 Outlines present and expected future changes in technology, production, and employment with a view towards facilitating required adjustments. International Labor Office. Labor and Automa tion: A Tabulation o f Case Studies on Technological Change. Geneva, ILO, 1965. 87 pp. 5.046 International Labor Office. Labor and Automa tion: Automation and Nonmanual Workers. Geneva, ILO, 1967. 113 pp. Investigates the effects of automation on the nature of work, manpower requirements, eco nomic organization, and labor union attitudes, particularly in Europe. Klotz, Benjamin P. Disemployment o f Labor at the Establishment Level. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, 1966. 17 pp. Assesses the relative impact of productivity and output changes on employment in 17 selected 4-digit industries. Finds that, in gene ral, output did not increase sufficiently to avoid disemployment. International Labor Office. Labor and Automa tion: Technological Change and Manpower in a Centrally Planned Economy. Geneva, ILO, 1966. 92 pp. 5.048 Analyzes material from 163 Soviet publica tions on the effects of automation on occupa Ketterling, Virgil H. “Productivity, Output, and Employment.” American Statistical Associa tion, Proceedings o f the Business and Eco nomic Statistics Section, 1965, pp. 175-183. Examines the statistical relations between output, productivity, and man-hours in the U.S. economy. 5.047 5.042 Jaffe, A. J., and Froomkin, Joseph. Technology and Jobs. New York, Praeger, 1968. 284 pp. The authors examine the relationship between technological change and the labor force, with emphasis on the post-World War II period, and compare trends in the United States with those abroad. Summarizes information on 160 case studies in 14 countries. 5.041 International Labor Office. The Effects o f Advanced Technology on Employment and Conditions o f Work in the Chemical Indus tries. Geneva, ILO, 1969. 77 pp. Reviews the characteristics of the industry and discusses the effect of accelerating techno logical change on production and employment. International Labor Office. Effects o f Techno logical Developments on the Occupational Structure and Level o f Employment in the Leather and Footwear Industry. Geneva, ILO, 1969.73 pp. 5.040 International Labor Office. “Technical Progress and Its Social Consequences in the French Textile Industry.” International Labour Review, Vol. 92, No. 1, July 1965, pp. 51-62. 12 Lawrence, Paul R. “How to Deal with Resis tance to Change.” Harvard Business Review, 5 .053 Vol. 47, No. 1, January-February 1969, pp. 4-5+. Urges managers to seek out meaningful worker participation when introducing change. Finds most resistance the result of thoughtless management practices. 5.049 Summarizes and interprets findings of a year-long investigation, commissioned by the Congress, into the impact of technological and economic change on production and employ ment. Assesses past effects of such change as well as job requirements and major types of manpower displacement likely to occur during the decade ahead. Defines areas of unmet community and human needs toward which application of new technologies might be effec tively directed. Assesses the means by which new technologies might be channeled into other promising directions. Recommends pertinent manpower and other policies. (See also follow ing entries for the appendix volumes to the Commission Report.) Levine, Morton. “Adjusting to Changing Tech nology on the Railroads.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 11, November 1969, pp. 36-42. Reports on measures taken to retrain or otherwise help railroad workers displaced by technological and other changes in the railroad industry. 5.050 Lovejoy, Robert J. “Labor Productivity in Italian Agriculture.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 21, No. 4, July 1968, pp. 570-580. Discusses the dynamics of employment and output and their relationship to productivity in Italian agriculture. Forecasts future trends in productivity. 5.051 5 .054 Mandelstamm, Allan B. “The Effects of Unions on Efficiency in the Residential Construc tion Industry: A Case Study.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 18, No. 4, July 1965, pp. 503-521. 5 .055 Mueller, Eva, and associates. Technological Advance in an Expanding Economy. Ann Arbor, Institute for Social Research, The University of Michigan, 1969. 254 pp. National Commission on Technology, Automa tion, and Economic Progress. The Employ ment Impact o f Technological Change. Appendix Volume II to Technology and The American Economy, The Report o f the Commission. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, February 1966. 399 pp. Contains studies of disemployment; of tech nological change and its impact on jobs by industry; of skill requirements arising from the installation and use of automated equipment; and of hours of work and leisure. Reports on a nationwide cross-sectional sur vey of the effect of technological advance on employment, income, job satisfaction, and job content, and of the effect of education and training on worker adjustment to change. National Commission on Technology, Automa tion and Economic Progress. The Outlook for Technological Change and Employment. Appendix Volume I to Technology and The American Economy, The Report o f the Commission. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, February 1966. 373 pp. Contains projections of employment, man power requirements, and industry productivity to 1975 and discussions of technological devel opments, particularly in the computer field. Compares efficiency and costs in residential construction in Ann Arbor and Bay City, Michigan, and explains the approximately equal costs of building a house as resulting from effective apprenticeship programs (sponsored by unions), entrepreneurial efficiency, and wage and other competitive pressures. 5.052 National Commission on Technology, Automa tion, and Economic Progress. Technology and the American Economy, The Report o f the Commission. Washington, U.S. Govern ment Printing Office, February 1966. 115 pp. 5..056 73 National Commission on Technology, Automa tion, and Economic Progress. Adjusting to niques in the solution of social and economic problems; and evaluates techniques designed to assure civilian and commerical uses of tech nologies developed in defense and space efforts. Change. Appendix Volume III to Technol ogy and the American Economy, The Report o f the Commission. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, February 1966. 275 pp. 5.059 Assesses income maintenance programs and other programs aiding the poor; compares U.S. and Western European programs aiding dis placed workers in adjusting to technological and other changes; examines problems posed for Negroes by recent technological changes; surveys needs of users of manpower projec tions; examines the effect of a minimum wage on the employment of unskilled workers; and reports on a computer experiment in analyzing labor market data bearing upon the impact of technological change. 5.057 Statements by interested organizations and individuals in response to a request by the Commission for their views on the impact of technological change. National Commission on Technology, Automa tion, and Economic Progress. Educational Implications o f Technological Change. Appendix Volume IV to Technology and the American Economy, The Report o f the Commission. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, February 1966. 151 pp. 5.060 5.061 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Manpower Aspects o f A uto m ation National Commission on Technology, Automa tion, and Economic Progress. Applying Technology to Unmet Needs. Appendix Volume V to Technology and the American Economy, The Report o f the Commission. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, February 1966. 291 pp. an d Technical Change. (European Conference, Zurich, February 1-4, 1966.) Paris, OECD, 1966. 138 pp. Discusses the rate of penetration of automa tion in Europe and the impact of technical change on jobs and the location of industry. Explores the requirements for effective man power policy. Examines the possibilities of the computer and other modern planning tools for solving problems of urban planning and metropolitan development; summarizes results of feasibility studies of applying the systems skills of the aerospace industry to the solution of social problems; describes problems of air and water pollution and of waste disposal and suggests methods for their control; examines attempts underway to deal with transportation problems and to use computerized diagnostic screening systems in health care; presents an inventory of computer-aided modeling and simulation tech Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Acceptance and Resistance, A resume of Touraine, Alain, and Associates, Workers’ Attitudes to Technical Change. Paris, OECD, 1965, 116 pp. Summarizes the major findings concerning worker reactions to technological change. Explores experimental developments in the use of computers and other new technologies in the education process and analyzes the implications. 5.058 National Commission on Technology, Automa tion, and Economic Progress. Statements Relating to the Impact o f Technological Change. Appendix Volume VI to Technol ogy and the American Economy, The Report o f the Commission. Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, February 1966. 309 pp. 5.062 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. The Requirements o f A uto mated Jobs. (North American Joint Confer ence, December 1964.) Paris, OECD, 1965. 453 pp. The report of a conference on the impact of automation upon broad occupational trends. Discusses the contributions which both private and public measures can make to facilitate manpower adjustments. 74 5.063 Pejovich, S. “Technological Progress and Tech nical Schools.” Review o f Social Economy, Vol. 26, No. 1, March 1968, pp. 40-49. Seeks to provide a basis for evaluating two alternative manpower programs—training in technical schools and training on the job. Suggests that the average expected rate of return from technical school training is higher than the corresponding rate for on-the-job training. Simple cost-benefit analysis, however, may be misleading. While on-the-job training yields lower returns, it tends to provide greater protection against cyclical unemployment than does technical school training. 5.064 5.069 Piore, M. “On-the-Job Training and Adjustment to Technological Change.” Journal o f Human Resources, Vol. 3, No. 4, Fall 1968, pp. 435-449. 5.070 Richard W. M a n p o w er Planning 5.071 to Adapt to New Technology at an Electric and Gas Utility: A Case Study. BLS Bulletin 293. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics, April 1965. 25 pp. 5.072 Riche, Richard W. “Manpower Planning at an Electric and Gas Utility.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 8, August 1965, pp. 965-967. Discusses a study by the BLS concerning technological changes in both plant and auxil iary operations and how they were dealt with by management and labor. Shirai, Takamasa. “Improvements in Labor Productivity and Employment in Keynes’ So-called Classical System.” Osaka Eco nomic Paper, Vol. 14(2), No. 27, December 1965. Examines the effect of an increase in the marginal disutility of labor, an increase in labor productivity, or an increase in the price of non-wage goods on employment in a two-sector Keynesian system. Describes the methods used in introducing laborsaving technology with a minimum of hardship to employees. 5.067 Shepard, Jon M. Automation and Alienation: A Study o f Office and Factory Workers. Cam bridge, Mass., MIT Press, 1971. 163 pp. Discusses the influence of technology and the degree of job specialization on the worker’s integration into or alienation from work. Finds that alienation levels seem to be reduced by automated technology in both factory and office. Rezler, Julius. Automation and Industrial Labor. New York, Random House, 1969. 224 pp. Riche, Scott, W. H., ed. Office Automation: Adminis trative and Human Problems. Paris, Organi zation for Economic Cooperation and Devel opment, 1965. 103 pp. Discusses some of the manpower problems which industries in four European countries encountered when they introduced computers in their offices in the early 1960’s. Suggests how manpower changes might be made more smoothly. Analyzes changes in workers’ jobs, unions, and relations with employers brought about by technological change. 5.066 Rothberg, Herman J. “A Study of Office Automation in the IRS.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 92, No. 10, October 1969, pp. 26-31. Reports how conversion to automatic data processing in the Atlanta Internal Revenue Service was accomplished without involuntary transfers or separations. Discusses the role of on-the-job training in preventing structural imbalances in labor mar kets. Holds that its role in adjustments to technological change suggests new interpreta tions of labor productivity. 5.065 5.068 Shirom, Arie. Industrial Cooperation and Adjustment to Technological Change: A S tu d y o f J o in t Management-Union Committees.U.S. Department of Commerce, National Bureau of Standards, 1968. 340 pp. Evaluates the potential of joint managementunion committees for effective planning of adjustment to technological change. 75 5.073 Siegel, B. N. “Technical Change and Employ ment in the United States, 1890-1965.” Western Economic Journal, Vol. 6, No. 2, March 1968, pp. 121-133. Society for Personnel Administration, 1965. 68 pp. Outlines the benefits and problems brought about by automatic data processing. Pays par ticular attention to the effect of automation on education. Deals with changes in the historical relation ship between private-sector output growth and employment growth in the United States. The employment elesticity of the rate of output growth has tended to decline over the period of 1890-1965, the decline evidently being associated with acceleration in the rate of technical change. 5.074 5.078 The authors discuss the system of “planned management” introduced in 1964, which increases the role of incentives to make the economy more responsive to change. Postwar trends in employment and manpower planning preceding the introduction of the new system are reviewed. Siegel, Irving H. “Productivity Measures and Forecasts for Employment and Stabilization Policy,” in Dimensions o f Manpower Policy: Programs and Research, Levitan, Sar A., and Siegel, Irving H., eds. Baltimore, Johns Hopkins Press, 1966. 299 pp. 5.079 Explores certain aspects of the meaning, measurement, and use of productivity statistics in the light of policy requirements concerning employment and wage-price stabilization. 5.075 Smith, A. D. Redundancy Practices in Four Industries. Paris, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1966. 129 pp. 5.080 Examines the practices of the steel, railroad, textile, and telecommunications industries in the United States and the United Kingdom in assisting workers whose jobs have been perma nently eliminated by technical change. Explores the reasons for differing practices among these industries. 5.077 “The Key to Full Employment.” American Machinist, June 28,1971. Discusses capital *investment in manufac turing, the impact of imports on employment and investment, and suggests a program to ensure full employment. 5.081 Society for Personnel Administration. Automation Around the Nation. Fourth Annual Conference on Automation and Personnel Administration, May 13, 1965. Washington, Striner, Herbert E. “Technological Displace ment as a Micro Phenomenon.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 90, No. 3, March 1967, pp. 30-31. Argues that the report of the National Commission on Technology, Automation, and Economic Progress obscures the problem of labor displacement due to technology by treat ing unemployment on a macroeconomic basis, while the problem in fact occurs on the microeconomic level. Significant numbers of workers may be affected by displacement, but a macroeconomic treatment will tend statistically to offset their loss of employment by gains elsewhere. Silberman, Charles E. “The Real News About Automation.” Fortune, Vol. 71, No. 1, January 1965, p. 124+. Discusses long-term productivity growth in the private economy. Argues that the effect of automation on employment in the United States has been irresponsibly exaggerated. 5.076 Stieber, Jack and Paukert, Liba. “Manpower and Technological Change in Czechoslovakia.” Industrial Relations, Vol. 8, No. 1, October 1968, pp. 91-107. Touraine, Alain, and associates. Workers ’ Attitudes to Technical Change. Paris, Organi zation for Economic Cooperation and Devel opment, 1965.177 pp. Considers the determinants of workers’ atti tudes toward change. Indicates how managers 76 might gain the cooperation of their workers when instituting change. 5.082 that substantial increases in manufacturing employment are a suitable and effective means of achieving rapid growth in total output, although he finds it desirable that the rate of increase in manufacturing output substantially exceeds that in employment. Ulman, Lloyd. Automation in Perspective. Reprint No. 305. Berkeley, California, Institute of Industrial Relations, University of California, 1967. 18 pp. 5.087 Suggests that the impact of automated con trol technologies on the economy does not essentially differ from that of conventional technologies, and that postwar productivity gains are related to high employment levels rather than to changes in the pattern of technological innovations and their diffusion. 5.083 Summarizes 40 case studies in eight coun tries on experience with coordinating techno logical change and manpower planning at the enterprise level. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Technician Manpower 1966-80, BLS Bulletin 1639. Washington, U.S. Gov ernment Printing Office, March 1970. 28 pp. 5.088 Discusses the employment outlook of tech nicians in various technician occupations and industries in terms of projected requirements. Also discusses criteria for qualifying as a techni cian. Stresses the need for further research. 5.084 U.S. Department of Labor, Manpower Adminis tration. Manpower Implications o f Automa tion. 1965.86 pp. 5.089 U.S. Department of Labor, Women’s Bureau. Automation and Women Workers. 1970. 11 pp. 5.090 Weiss, Jeffrey. “The Changing Job Structure of Health Manpower,” in Proceedings o f the Twenty-Third Annual Winter Meeting, Industrial Relations Research Association. (D ecem ber 28-29, 1970), 1971. pp. 162-172. Criticizes the assumption of fixed manpower coefficients in past studies of the health indus tries. Using dentistry as an example, the author argues that the increasing employment of tech nical personnel to perform the more routine tasks once done by highly trained professionals has been the primary force in raising the productivity of these professionals and in allow ing the health industries to meet rising demand. Walton, F. T. “Manufacturing Employment, Growth and Labor Supply.” Scottish Jour nal o f Political Economy, Vol. 14, No. 1, February 1967, pp. 30-47. Based on the experience of 12 OECD coun tries between 1955 and 1964, the author finds Weinberg, Edgar, and Ball, Robert A. “The Many Faces of Technology.” Occupational Outlook Quarterly, Vol. 11, No. 2, May 1967, pp. 7-10. The authors summarize major developments in technology and industry growth patterns and their impact on job skills. Argues that predictions of persistent techno logical unemployment made in the fifties and early sixties have proved false. Rather, automa tion has caused a significant expansion in job opportunities for women. 5.086 Weinberg, Edgar. “Some Manpower Implica tions,” in Automation Management: A Social Perspective. Athens, Georgia, Second Annual Georgia-Reliance Symposium, 1970. pp. 78-91. Discusses the nature and rate of technologi cal change and its implications for employment, education, and occupational training in the 1970’s. Presents a compendium of papers on techno logical change and manpower presented by the U.S. Department of Labor at the OECD North American Regional Conference. 5.085 Wedderburn, Dorothy. Enterprise Planning for Change. Paris, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, 1968. 140 pp. 77 5.091 at the Seminar on Input-Output Analysis, Bucharest, Romania, September 8-18, 1969. 15 pp. Wolfe, J.N . “Productivity and Growth in Manufacturing Industry: Some Reflections on Professor Kaldor’s Inaugural Lecture.” Economica, Vol. 35, No. 138, May 1968, pp. 117-126. Describes how input-output tables are used as a framework for projections in terms of final demand, interindustry relationships, output, and employment under conditions of stable economic growth and high employment. Shows that assertions that a shortage of productive labor exists in manufacturing are not supported by the statistics of either unem ployment or wage rates. Various branches of manufacturing have been able to expand their work force rapidly. 6.005 An introductory text surveying growth pat terns in developed and less developed econo mies, major theories of growth, and alternative policies for encouraging economic growth. VI. Productivity and economic growth 6.001 Almon, Clopper, Jr. The American Economy to 1975. New York, Harper and Row, 1966. 169 pp. 6.006 Presents internally consistent projections, based on interindustry matrices, of consumer spending, capital expenditures, government pur chases, exports and imports, and technological changes. 6.002 Alterman, Jack. “Input-Output Projections of the U.S. Economy to 1980 and Some Implications,” in American Statistical Asso ciation, Proceedings o f the Business and Economic Statistics Section, 1970, pp. 73-83. 6.007 Alterman, Jack. “Studies of Long-Term Eco nomic Growth.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 88, No. 8, August 1965, pp. 983-987. 6.008 Blackett, P. M. S. Technology, Industry, and Economic Growth. The 13th Fawley Foun dation Lecture. Southampton, England, Uni versity of Southampton, 1966. 19 pp. Reviews some of the reasons for the British economic crisis. Discusses Britain’s position in the world, and the changes in the educational and industrial structure necessary to realize its potential. 6.009 Alterman, Jack. The Use o f Input-Output Anal ysis by the Federal Interagency Growth Project in the United States. Paper presented Bhattacharyya, M. A. Capital Longevity and Economic Growth: An Analytical Study. Calcutta, India, Bookland Private Ltd., July 1965. 143 pp. Discusses and analyzes the major theoretical investigations of the relation between the eco nomic life of capital and economic growth. Offers his own growth model. Explains the activities and goals of the Federal Interagency Growth Study Project. States that the main objective of the project is to establish a framework for analyzing the long-term implications for economic growth of shifts in the economy, particularly with respect to manpower utilization. 6.004 Berri, L. “Methodological Problems in Forecast ing Economic Development and Technical Progress.” Problems o f Economics, Vol. 12, No. 10, February 1970, pp. 51-71. Urges Soviet planners to take account of possible technological improvements and the social and economic changes these may initiate when considering future economic programs. Explains the construction and uses of BLS projections of labor force growth, final demand, potential output, industry output, productivity, and employment. 6.003 Baldwin, Robert E. Economic Development and Growth. New York, John Wiley & Sons, 1966. 133 pp. 78 Blitzer, C. R. “Elasticity of Substitution and the Retardation of Soviet Growth Rates.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 52, No. 1, February 1970, pp. 104-108. the rents paid to specialized natural resources critical in the production of those exports. They calculate that Canadian prairie agriculture in the first decade of this century contributed a much smaller share to increases in income than past judgments indicated. They suggest that for most underdeveloped countries even large-scale expansion of primary-product exports cannot be expected to contribute substantially to increases in per-capita income. Discusses an article by Norman M. Kaplan on the subject in terms of two “extreme” assumptions—i.e., that the decline in the Soviet growth rate is due entirely to a decline in technological progress, or that it is due to a decline in the growth rate of combined factor inputs. 6.010 Blyth, C. A., and Hamer, P. “Output, Employ ment, and Productivity Growth in New Zealand Manufacturing Industries.” Produc tivity Measurement Review, No. 41, May 1965. 6.014 Investigates some of the sources of growth in New Zealand’s economy. 6.011 Constructs indexes of industrial output for the period 1949-1959. Seeks to eliminate upward biases in indexes published by the Chinese government. Bruton, Henry J. “Import Substitution and Productivity.” Journal o f Development Studies, Vol. 4, No. 3, April 1968, pp. 306-326. 6.015 After broadly defining the term “import substitution” , the author examines possible approaches to a “successful” import substitu tion policy—one which contributes to raising the rate of growth of output without sowing at the same time the seeds of its own failure. The approach is based on divergent rates of growth of productivity among several sectors. 6.012 Bruton, Henry J. “Productivity Growth in L atin A m erica.” American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 5, December 1967, pp. 1099-1116. 6.016 Clark, Colin. “The Fundamental Problem of Economic Growth.” Welt Wirtschaftliches Archiv, Vol. 94, No. 1, March 1965, pp. 1-9. Concludes that the most important factors in economic growth are not of a physical nature — natural resources or capital — but reside in human nature. Economists should abandon their preoccupation with capital investment as a source of growth and emphasize productivity resting on a variety of human and material factors — such as improvement in education, the development of the institutional frame work, a dependable currency, a smoothly work ing banking and currency system, etc. Chambers, E. J., and Gordon, D. F. “Primary Products and Economic Growth: An Empiri cal Measurement.” Journal o f Political Econ omy, Vol. 74, No. 4, August 1966, pp. 315-332. The authors show that the increase in income to an economy from expansion in primary-product exports can be measured by Christian, James W. “The Dynamics of Eco nomic Growth, Technological Progress, and Institutional Change.” Journal o f Economic Issues, Vol. 2, No. 3, September 1968, pp. 298-311. Argues that, with cyclical stabilization of the economy having been nearly attained, inquiry into structural stabilization should now be emphasized. Development of theory pertaining to institutional change is as necessary as theory pertaining to technological progress. Constructs a dynamic general equilibrium model of condi tions for the full employment of capital and labor resources. The model is designed to highlight the interaction of technological prog ress and institutional change. Presents estimates of the rates of growth of capital, labor, and output for various time periods since 1940 for five Latin American countries. The contribution to growth of out put by capital and labor is identified and subtracted from total output growth to give the productivity growth rate as a residual. 6.013 Chao, Kang. Rate and Pattern o f Industrial Growth in Communist China. Ann Arbor, University of Michigan Press, 1965. 188 pp. 79 6.017 Colm, Gerhard, and Geiger, Theodore. The Economy o f the American People. Third ed. Washington, National Planning Association, 1967. 220 pp. tion in GNP had railroad service been with drawn in 1890. Finds that Fogel’s method involves drastic simplification and empirically unsubstantiated specifications of demand and supply elasticities in markets for transportable goods, that the benefit-cost analyses he offers are problematical, and that social benefits are underestimated. Concludes that, on the basis of Fogel’s own estimates, the railroad gave rise to spectacular investment opportunities. The authors present an account of how the American economy operates and achieves high productivity and living standards, and what future problems it faces. 6.018 Cornwall, John. “Postwar Growth in Western Europe: A Re-evaluation.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 50, No. 3, August 1968, pp. 361-368. 6.022 Reviews several studies of postwar economic growth in Europe, with particular attention to the importance given to the role of capital formation. 6.019 Discusses the institutions and institutional innovations which arose to overcome inter regional and interindustry barriers to capital mobility. Cukor, Gy. “Long-Term Planning and Technical Progress.” Acta Oeconomica, Vol. 4, No. 3, 1969, pp. 239-258. 6.023 Investigates the conceptual and methodo logical problems in forecasting technical prog ress and analyzes the importance for prognosis of changes in patterns of production, consump tion, and technology. 6.020 David, Paul A. “The Mechanization of Reaping in the Ante-Bellum Midwest,” in The Rein terpretation o f American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971, pp. 214-227. 6.024 Eltis, W. A. “Capital Accumulation and the Rate of Industrialization of Developing Countries.” Economic Record, Vol. 46, No. 114, June 1970, pp! 153-168. Discusses conditions under which a develop ing country with an elastic labor supply can achieve rapid industrial growth at moderate capital costs. David, Paul A. “Transport Innovation and Economic Growth: Professor Fogel on and off the Rails.” Economic History Review, 2nd Session, Vol. 22, No. 3, December 1969, pp. 506-525. 6.025 Discusses critically the approach of Professor Fogel to the study of the impact of railroads upon economic growth in the United States, which was to investigate the extent of reduc Divatia, V. V., and Bhatt, V. V. “On Measuring the Pace of Development.” Banca Nazionale Del Lavor Quarterly Review, Vol. 22, No. 89, June 1969, pp. 190-206. The authors present a new method of measuring the pace of economic development in India, which is not adequately reflected by the growth rate in national income. They formulate an index of development potential, which shows a much more rapid rate of increase than national income, and reflects the rapid rate at which the process of structural transfor mation has taken place. Uses the example of the reaping machine to show how demand by the agricultural sector stimulated industrial growth and how industrial growth in turn stimulated the growth of agriculture. 6.021 Davis, Lance E. “Capital Mobility and Ameri can Growth,” in The Reinterpretation o f American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971. pp. 285-300. Eltis, W. A. “Technical Progress, Profits, and Growth.” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 20, No. 2, July 1968, pp. 162-194. Examines the assumption that the rate of technical progress depends entirely on invest- 80 growth, using an activity analysis approach with real outputs and commodity price variables. Discusses neoclassical, Solow-Swan, Kaldor, and Pasinetti saving assumptions and examines the effects of technological progress on stability and growth rates. ment and not at all on the passage of time. Argues that the annual rate of technical prog ress varies proportionately with the share of gross investment in GNP, and that any steady growth rate is a possible one, even with a constant labor force. 6.026 6.030 Enke, Stephen. “The Economic Aspects of Slowing Population Growth.” Economic Journal, Vol. 76, No. 301, March 1966, pp. 45-56. Argues that per capita incomes have not been increasing in many countries because productivity per worker has not increased and capital per worker has not expanded. Argues that greater effort should be made to retard population growth and less to accelerate output. 6.027 Argues that even with zero marginal labor product in agriculture, labor can be drawn into industry only by a fixed wage just sufficient to offset the cost of moving. If incomes grow with rising industrial output but agricultural output remains constant, food prices will rise and workers will seek to protect their real wages. With static technology, rising wages spell declining rates of profits and decelerating growth. Erlich, Alexander. “Development Strategy and Planning: The Soviet Experience,” in National Economic Planning, Max F. Millikan, ed. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1967. pp. 233-278. 6.031 Examines the impact of centralized planning upon economic growth in the Soviet Union. A comment by Abram Bergson follows. 6.028 Fellner, William. “Measures of Technological Progress in the Light of Recent Growth Theories.” American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 5, December 1967, pp. 1073-1098. 6.032 Harbison, Frederick R.; Maruhnic, Joan; and Resnick, Jane R. Quantitative Analysis o f Modernization and Development. Princeton, N.J., Industrial Relations Section, Princeton University, 1970. 224 pp. The authors argue that development cannot be measured by economic growth indicators alone. Cultural, educational, health, and politi cal factors should be considered and quantita tive indicators developed for these variables. 6.033 Goddard, Frederick Owen. A Two-Sector Model o f Economic Growth with Techno logical Progress. University of Florida Mono graphs, Social Sciences, No. 36. Gainsville, Fla., University of Florida Press, 1969. 62 pp. Hicks, John. Capital and Growth. Oxford, England, Clarendon Press, 1965. 343 pp. Reviews the methods of dynamic economics. Presents theoretical discussions of growth equi librium and optimum growth. 6.034 Examines the long-run equilibrium growth path of a two-sector model of economic Hamberg, Daniel. Models o f Economic Growth. New York and London, Harper and Row, 1971.246 pp. An advanced text discussing Harrod-Domar and other growth models. Shows that growth of capital and output at the same rate, with a constant rate of interest, is possible in two ways: (a) If there is a Cobb-Douglas function; (b) if there is a more general constant elasticity of substitution (CES) function but innovations are slanted to make use of the more scarce factor. Argues that the second form is a more accurate representation of the reality of U.S. growth. 6.029 Guha, A. “Accumulation, Innovation, and Growth under Conditions of Disguised Unemployment.” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 21, No. 3, November 1969, pp. 360-372. 81 Hill, T. P. The Measurement o f Real Product, A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis o f Growth Rates for Different Industries and Sectional Comparison of Manufacturing Industry.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 51, No. 4, November 1969, pp. 453-458. Countries. Paris, Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development, February 1971. 119pp. Discusses the theoretical and practical prob lems involved in measuring the growth of real product. Compares industry growth with national growth, finding little relationship between the two in many instances. Analyzes the effects of alternative methods of measure ment of growth rates. 6.035 Using data in 2-digit and 3-digit manufac turing industries in a number of developed and undeveloped countries, the author shows empir ically that output-capital ratios are not inversely related to the level of economic development. 6.039 Holmes, R. A. “Factor Inputs, Technological Progress and Economic Growth in Canada.” The Western Economic Journal, Vol. 4, No. 3, Summer 1966, pp. 247-260. Refines Abramowitz’s total factor produc tivity model, and uses it to estimate produc tivity in some of the major sectors of the Canadian economy between 1941 and 1961. Concludes that technical change (as opposed to simple increase in factor inputs) was responsible for at least one-third of the increase in output in all sectors examined. 6.036 Examines the role of planning in terms of postwar economic growth in France, and how it differs from other aspects of economic policy. A comment by Stanislaw Wellisz follows. 6.040 Kaplan, Norman M. “ Retardation in Soviet Growth.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 50, No. 3, August 1968, pp. 295-303. 6.041 Kennedy, Kieran A. Productivity and Industrial Growth: The Irish Experience. Oxford, England, Clarendon Press, 1971. 276 pp. 6.042 Kuznets, Simon. Economic Growth o f Nations: Total Output and Production Structure. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press, 1971.363 pp. Reviews historical growth trends in major developed countries and several developing economies. 6.043 Kim, Y. C. “Sectoral Output-Capital Ratios and Levels of Economic Development: A Cross- Kurihara, Kenneth K. The Growth Potential o f the Japanese Economy. Baltimore, Johns Hopkins Press, 1971. 148 pp. Analyzes the fundamental forces underlying present and future Japanese economic growth. Deals with consumption, savings, private invest ment, and labor shortages. Analyzes the causes of differences among manufacturing industries in the growth of labor productivity, and the association between longer term changes in productivity and output, with special reference to the Irish manufac turing industry. 6.038 Kindleberger, Charles P. Europe’s Postwar Growth: The Role o f Labor Supply. Cambridge, Mass., Harvard University Press, 1967.270 pp. Argues that high European growth rates since World War II have been chiefly due to large supplies of labor Believes that this supply is now being exhausted, and growth will soon slow to more normal rates. Presents data on the decline in the economic growth rate of the Soviet Union. Explains the decline tentatively in terms of a decline in the rate of increase in factor productivity. Suggests that the decline may reflect changes in the efficiency of economic organization after 1958, resulting in less emphasis on the quantitative aspects of resource allocation. 6.037 Kindleberger, Charles P. “French Planning,” in National Economic Planning, Max F. Millikan, ed. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1967, pp. 278-303. 82 Kuznets, Simon. “Notes on the Pattern of U.S. Economic Growth,” in The Reinterpretation o f American Economic History, Robert W. Fogel and Stanley L. Engerman, eds. New York, Harper and Row, 1971, pp. 17-24. 6.049 Compares growth in population, labor force, product per capita, and product per worker in the United States with other developed coun-. tries. Discusses characteristics of long-term U.S. growth and the variability of U.S. growth rate. 6.044 Lai, Brij Bhushan. Industrial Productivity and Economic Growth. Allahabad, India, Chaitanya Publishing House, 1965. 390 pp. Analyzes the rates of growth per acre for different crops in different regions. Argues that economic forces rather than social and institu tional factors are significantly correlated with growth. 6.050 Reviews India’s productivity performance, noting why and how this performance must be improved. 6.045 6.051 Minami, R. “The Turning Point in the Japanese Economy.” Quarterly Journal o f Economics, Vol. 82, No. 3, August 1968, pp. 380-402. Seeks to discover at what point in its development Japan had “unlimited supplies of labor” available. 6.047 Neher, Philip A. Economic Growth and Development: A Mathematical Introduction. New York, John Wiley and Sons, 1971.32 pp. 6.052 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Food Marketing and Eco nomic Growth. Paris, OECD, 1970. 130 pp. Analyzes developments in food distribution since World War II. Explores the interdepen dence of those developments with agricultural and national economic growth. Nelson, Richard R. “The CES Production Func tion and Economic Growth Projections.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 47, No. 3, August 1965, pp. 326-328. 6.053 Finds that the constant elasticity of substitu tion production function is more useful than the Cobb-Doublas production function only where the capital-output ratio is changing rapidly. Organization for Economic Cooperation and D e v e lo p m e n t. E co n o m ic G row th, 1960-1970: A Mid-Decade Review o f Prospects. Paris, OECD, 1966. 113 pp. Reviews economic growth between 1960 and 1965, and discusses growth problems anticipated for the latter part of the decade. A college text, presenting analyses of macroeconomic theory, mathematical economics, and economic growth and development on an inter mediate level. 6.048 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Agriculture and Economic Growth. A Report by a Group of Experts. Paris, OECD, 1965. 121 pp. Deals with the prospects for agricultural development, emphasizing its role in economic growth. Suggests policies for increasing agricul tural productivity and improving both the national and international allocation of agricul tural resources. Makdisi, S. A. “Syria: Rate of Economic Growth and Fixed Capital Formation 1936-1968.” The Middle East Journal, Vol. 25, No. 2, Spring 1971, pp. 157-179. Reviews and comments on Syrian economic developments. 6.046 Nowshirrani, V.F. The Regional and Cropwise Patterns of the Growth of Per-Acre Output in India.” Bulletin. Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics, Vol. 32, No. 1, February 1970, pp. 59-79. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. Productivity and Economic Planning. Paris, OECD, 1970. 323 pp. A compendium of papers on the numerous national productivity bodies established after World War II and their contributions to eco nomic planning. 83 6.054 Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. The Growth o f Output, 19601980. Paris, OECD, December 1970. 280 pp. A collection of papers dealing with basic growth models, production functions, and insti tutional theory. Reviews growth and factors affecting it in member countries during the 1960’s. Evaluates their growth potential and the difficulties likely to be encountered in managing growth through the 1970’s. 6.055 6.060 Suggests that productivity change is not as large an element in economic change as it is usually taken to be. Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. The Outlook for Economic Growth. Paris, OECD, May 1970. 40 pp. 6.061 Summarizes a longer report on the economic growth of member countries during the 1960’s, their prospects for growth in the 1970’s, and the difficulties in economic management they are likely to encounter. 6.056 Ramachandra, N.; Lee, Tieh-Sheng; Mehta, P. C.; and Hou, Chia-Chu. Role o f Produc tivity in Asian Economic Growth. Tokyo, Asian Productivity Organization, 1970. 186 pp. 6.062 Schuh, G. Edward; Nair, Kusum; and Owen, Wyn F. “Implications of the Green Revolu tion for Economic Growth T A merican Jour nal o f Agricultural Economics, Vol. 52, No. 5, December 1970, pp. 719-722. 6.063 Schultz, Robert S. “Understanding Economic Growth.” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 44, No. 6, November-December 1966, pp. 32-34+. Stiglitz, Joseph and Uzawa, Hirofumi. Readings in Modern Theory o f Economic Growth. Cambridge, Mass., MIT Press, 1969. 497 pp. U.S. Department of Commerce, Bureau of the Census. Long Term Economic Growth, 1860-1965. 1966.256 pp. Includes appro x im ately 400 annual economic time series and nearly 800 com ponent series that are useful for studying economic growth. Presents basic measures of economic growth, and deals with factors vitally related to economic growth. Also shows longrange regional and industry growth trends, and compares U.S. economic growth with that of 6 major foreign countries. Defines the major factors determining growth and outlines the businessman’s role in promoting growth. 6.059 Thurow, Lester C., and Taylor, Lester D. “The Interaction Between the Actual and the Potential Rate of Growth.” The Review o f Economics and Statistics, Vol. 48, No. 4, November 1966, pp. 351-360. The authors present a method for analyzing the interaction between the actual and the potential rate of growth of the American economy from 1949 to 1970. The method makes use of production function analysis to estimate the potential growth of productivity. The authors discuss the impact of techno logical developments in agriculture on the economies of less developed nations. 6.058 Thorbecke, Erik, ed. The Role o f Agriculture in E co n o m ic D evelopment. New York, National Bureau of Economic Research, 1969.480 pp. A collection of papers discussing the relation of agriculture to other sectors of national economies and the transformation of tradi tional agriculture in Russia, China, Japan, Brazil, and Peru. A series of essays dealing with the signifi cance of productivity as well as of nonproduc tivity factors (including attitudes towards work and change) to economic growth. 6.057 Thompson, E. J. “Productivity: Major Element in Economic Change?” Productivity Mea surement Review, August 1965, pp. 23-30. 6.064 84 U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Projections 1970: Interindustry VII. Theses and dissertations Relationships , Potential Demand, Employ m ent , BLS Bulletin 1536, 1966. 155 pp. Asher, Ephraim. Relative Productivity, Factor Intensity and Technology in the Manufacturing Sectors o f the U.S. and U.K. During the Nineteenth Century. Thesis presented to the University of Rochester, 1970. 174 pp. Discusses assumptions and methodology of projections based on input-output matrices. Representing an effort to develop a framework for analyzing long-term growth trends and their implications for policy, the work is a phase of the Interagency Growth Study Project. 6.065 Compares productivity and technology, particularly in the textile industry. Finds capital and labor in the United States to be more productive than in the United Kingdom, and U.S. technology to be biased toward labor saving. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. “The U.S. Economy in 1980: A Preview of BLS Projections.” Monthly Labor Review, Vol. 93, No. 4, April 1970, pp. 3-34. Attiyeh, Richard E. Estimation o f a Fixed Coefficient Vintage Model o f Production. Doctoral thesis pre sented to Yale University, 1966. 63 pp. Presents estimates of the labor force, growth in the economy,, and employment by industry and occupation. Discusses prospective gains in productivity by major sectors. 6.066 6.067 6.068 Interprets the growth in output and changes in factor productivity in U.S. manufacturing by means of a model which disaggregates capital into vintages, each with its own fixed production coefficients. U.S. Secretary of Labor James D. Hodgson. Speech before the National Association of Manufacturers, New York, December 3, 1970. 25 pp. Ban, Sung Hwan. The Long-Run Productivity Growth in K orean Agricultural Development, 1910-1968. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Minnesota, 1971.243 pp. Argues that resource savings from increased productivity will allow the United States to combat poverty, clean up pollution, and enhance leisure without reducing present con sumption. Finds increasing productivity gains in the post World War II period after a poor prewar productivity perfor mance. Vanek, Jarasslow. “A Theory of Growth with Technological Change.” American Economic Review, Vol. 57, No. 1, March 1967, pp. 73-89. Behr, Michael R. Technical Progressiveness in the Agricultural Processing Sector: A Structural Analysis. Thesis presented to the University of Wisconsin, 1969.218 pp. Explores a growth theory incorporating technical progress saving labor and capital in equal proportions, as well as groyvth in produc tive resources. Includes growth theories formu lated by Harrod, Domar, and Solow as special cases. Presents a cross-sectional study of the effects of industry structure and firm characteristics on tech nological change. Finds some support for Schumpeter’s theory of innovation. Belinfante, Alexander E. Technical Change in the Steam Electric Power Generating Industry. Thesis presented to the University of California at Berkeley, 1969. 190 pp. Vanek, Jarasslow. “Towards a More General Theory of Growth with Technological Change.” The Economic Journal, Vol. 76, No. 304, December 1966, pp. 841-854. Examines the effects of embodied and disembodied technological change, returns to scale, and capital depreciation on overall technological progress. E x p lo res th e o rie s o f growth with autonomous capital-augmenting and laboraugmenting (i.e., non-neutral) innovation, while retaining the conventional assumption of con stant returns to scale. Chandrasekar, Krishnamurti. U.S. and French Manufac turing Productivity and Competition in the World 85 Market: A Study in the Theory o f Comparative Cost. Doctoral thesis presented to the New School for Social Research, 1969. 182 pp. Eldor, Dan. An Empirical Investigation o f Hospital Output, Input, and Productivity. Doctoral thesis presented to New York University, 1969. 226 pp. Reexamines the theory that, as between two coun tries, each will export those goods for which the ratio of its output per worker to that of the other’s exceeds the ratio of its money wage rate to that of the other’s. Finds a sig n ifican t relationship between productivity differentials and exports, but not between wage differentials and exports. Presents a case study of a large New York City hospital and a cross-sectional study of short-term, general U.S. hospitals. Finds a negative trend in produc tivity in both cases. Engberg, Vernon, L. Agricultural Productivity and Economic Development in Mexico. Thesis presented to the University of Texas at Austin, 1970, 284 pp. Chung, William K. A Study o f Economic Growth in Postwar Japan fo r the Period o f 1952-1967: An Application o f Total Productivity Analysis. Doctoral thesis presented to the New School of Social Research, 1971.290 pp. Explores the factors determining agricultural output in Mexico. Erlichman, Shmuel. The Attitude o f Trade Unions Toward Productivity: The Cases o f Norway, Israel, and Ghana. Doctoral thesis presented to the New School for Social Research, 1966. 363 pp. Quantifies the sources of Japanese economic growth. Attributes its record of rapid growth to an abundance of well-educated labor, to generous capital and research investment, and to manpower shifts from the agri cultural sector. Argues that although unions speak in favor of increased productivity, in practice they often impede productivity improvements. Cox, William A. Manpower and Productivity in Austrian Industry. Doctoral thesis presented to Princeton University, 1968. 148 pp. Farmer, Berkwood M. Man-Hour Productivity and Future U.S. Agricultural Adjustment. Doctoral thesis presented to North Carolina State University at Raleigh, 1970. 132 pp. Examines sources of output growth in Austria from 1956 to 1964, concluding that nearly one-half of the increased output was due to substitution of capital for labor. One-third was due to technical progress and one-sixth to increases in the quality and quantity of labor inputs. Analyzes the long-run effects of technological change on output and labor inputs and predicts the resulting price and income changes within agriculture. Fernandez, Anibal. Productivity and Technological Progress o f the Venezuelan Petroleum Industry. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Pitts burgh, 1971.205 pp. Daniels, Mark R. International Differences in Productive Efficiency. Doctoral thesis presented to Johns Hopkins University, 1966. 159 pp. Estimates industry productivity in eight developing nations. Offers estimates of average annual increases in productivity. Finds that gains are distributed to workers in the form of higher wages, or appropriated by the government. Day, Ernest H. A n Empirical Study o f the Influence o f Inventive Activities on Value Added per Man-Hour, Sales and Investments in the Chemical and Allied Products Industry. Doctoral thesis presented to the American University, 1969. 220 pp. Fishelson, Gideon. Returns to Human and Research Capital, United States Agriculture 1949-1964. Doctoral thesis presented to the North Carolina State University at Raleigh, 1968. 121 pp. Finds inventive activities, as measured by number of patents and by investment in all phases of research and development, to be highly significant explanatory vari ables of value added per man-hour when time lags are allowed for. Estimates the lags to run from 2 to 5 years. Estimates the rates of return on investments in education, training, and research in U.S. agriculture. Finds them to run above those prevailing in the economy in general. 86 Flueckiger, Gerald E. The Structure and Behavior o f Technological Change in the Iron and Steel Industry: 1700-1899. Doctoral thesis presented to Purdue University, 1970. 206 pp. Examines the sources of Japan’s rapid economic growth and compares Japanese with American and Canadian growth patterns. Finds interindustry shifts an important factor in productivity gains in Japan. Describes organizational and production processes, and how they changed. Foster, Bennett B. Dynamic Production Paths and Labor Productivity Trends: A Comparative Study o f the Major Timber-Based Industries o f the South and the West Coast. Doctoral thesis presented to Duke University, 1966. 183 pp. Hyde, Charles K. Technological Change and the Develop ment o f the British Iron Industry, 1700-1870. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Wisconsin, 1971.355 pp. Finds that productivity in the lumber, plywood, and lumber-based industries runs at or above the total manufacturing rate. Disputes the contention that woodbased industry is suffering from increased relative output costs. Reviews technological changes in the industry. Shows that changes in the relative costs of different iron making processes explain both the timing and the speed of their adoption. Kleiman, Herbert S. The Integrated Circuit: A Case Study o f Product Innovation in the Electronics Industry. Doctoral thesis presented to George Wash ington University, 1966. 260 pp. Gemery, Henry A. Productivity Growth, Process Change and Technical Change in the U.S. Glass Industry. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Penn sylvania, 1967. 206 pp. Reviews the introduction of the integrated circuit, with special emphasis on the role of government in the innovation process. Identifies the conditions under which changes in industry production techniques may be related to labor productivity growth. Undertakes to measure the impact of technical change on the U.S. glass industry. Larvas, Jose M. Output Growth, Technological Change and Employment o f Resources in Philippine Agri culture: 1948-1975. Doctoral thesis presented to Purdue University, 1968. 288 pp. Grossman, Philip. Hours and Output: The Reduction in the Soviet Workweek, 1956-1960. Thesis presented to the American University, 1970. 182 pp. Identifies the sources of farm growth from 1948-1960, and estimates the agricultural output that will be required by the economy in 1975, as well as alternate combinations of resources needed to meet these requirements. Assesses the consequences for productivity of the workweek reduction in Soviet industry from 48 to 41 hours in 1960. Finds that productivity did not increase sufficiently to offset lost work hours, especially in heavy industry. Lee, Joe Won. The Impact o f Technological Change on the Functional Distribution o f Income. Doctoral thesis presented to the City University of New York, 1969. 195 pp. Hanieski, John F. A n Explanatory Model o f Techno logically New Products. Thesis presented to Purdue University, 1970. 206 pp. Explores technological change at the level of the firm. Assesses the impact of continuous factor-augmenting technological change on the relative factor shares at the level of two-digit manufacturing industries. Hansen, John R. The Acquisition o f Technology for Development. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Colorado, 1970. 385 pp. Lorant, John H. The Role o f Capital-Improving Innova tions in American Manufacturing During the 1920’s. Doctoral thesis presented to Columbia University, 1966.311 pp. Identifies and evaluates factors critical to successful acquisition of technology at lowest cost. Hayashi, Kichiro. Technical Change in Japan—Its Measurement. Thesis presented to Indiana University, 1970. 189 pp. 87 Attributes a sharp increase in capital productivity between 1919 and 1929 to a great wave of relatively minor technological advances and to the introduction of mass-production techniques. Obermiller, Frederick W. Factors Associated with Agricultural Development and Growth in Latin America. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Missouri, Columbia, 1969. 373 pp. Mayer, Peter C. Technical Change in the Typesetting o f Daily Newspapers. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of California at Berkeley, 1969. 175 pp. Offers empirical evidence showing that increases in productivity depend primarily on increased quality (as measured by literacy) and quantity of labor, and on increased credit extended to agriculture. Argues that mechanization has had a negative influence on produc tivity. Investigates the effect of wage rates, unionization, and conditions in the equipment market on innovation. Examines the impact of innovative equipment on wages and the frequency of newspaper publication. Oh, Moonsong. The Role o f International Corporations in the Transfer o f Technology to Developing Coun tries. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Pennsylvania, 1970. 291 pp. Meyer, Robert A., Jr. Optimal Policies for Equipment Replacement with Stochastic Technological Change. Doctoral thesis presented to Stanford University, 1969.135 pp. Analyzes and evaluates the process by which techno logy is transferred to developing countries. Cites expatriate personnel and training programs for indigenous workers as the primary transfer vehicles. Discusses factors affecting the decision to innovate, and presents a rule for deciding when to introduce more advanced equipment. Petersen, Dietrick L. The Economic Effects o f Techno logical Innovations on Class I Line-Haul Railroads 1947-1963. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Pittsburgh, 1968. 322 pp. M intcheff, Alexander. Technological Change: A Demand-Pull Model. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Cincinnati, 1968. 127 pp. Argues that innovations are guided primarily by the profit motive, and that there is a tendency toward inventing devices that would substitute for the factor that is relatively more scarce at a given time. Finds that rapid technological change increased labor productivity and reduced material requirements, but failed to increase the rate of return on investment. Argues that modernization efforts were concentrated on cost reduction rather than on expansion of capacity. Mitchell, Edward J. An Econometric Study o f Inter national and Interindustrial Differences in Labor Productivity. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Pennsylvania, 1966. 121 pp. Reinfeld, William. A n Economic Analysis o f Recent Technological Trends in the United States Steel In d u stry. Doctoral thesis presented to Yale University, 1968. 184 pp. Argues that a particular production function exists for each industry. Develops a model which describes the general pattern of labor productivity and wages, as well as of international trade. Examines the relation of firm size to willingness to explore new technologies. Finds that the largest steel makers have been more interested in market-oriented changes designed to increase gross revenues, while the smaller firms have been more concerned with costreducing innovation. Nowill, Paul H. Productivity and Technological Change in Electric Power Generating Plants. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Massachusetts, 1971. 224 pp. Rettig, Raymond B. Productivity Change in the Trans mission o f Electricity. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Washington, 1969. 71 pp. Develops a composite production function, eliminat ing the assumption of constant elasticity of substitution, thus seeking to explain the existence of several produc tion technologies in an industry at one time. Analyzes the importance of economies of scale, factor substitution, and technological change in the transmission of electricity. 88 should be conceived as an endogenous rather than as an exogenous variable in production functions. Reynolds, William A. Innovation in the United States C arpet Industry, 1947-1963. Doctoral thesis presented to Columbia University, 1967. 283 pp. Stephens, John K. Differentiation o f Labor in Macroeconomic Growth Models. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Illinois, 1967. 233 pp. Presents an empirical analysis of the origin, diffusion, and economic results of technological innovation. Finds that the introduction of new tufting processes and of man-made fibers caused significant changes in industry structure and product price. Estimates the parameters of several growth models, postulating a non-homogeneous labor force. Labor is differentiated by skill level, by education, or by time in the labor force. Scheppach, Raymond C., Jr. A Canadian-United States Productivity Comparison. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Connecticut, 1970. 153 pp. Stephenson, Matthew A. The Role o f Technological Change in the English Classical School o f Economics. Doctoral thesis presented to Tulane University, 1965. 293 pp. Compares total postwar factor productivity in the United States and Canada. Examines the effects of reduced trade barriers between the two countries on productivity. Examines the works of economists from Adam Smith to John Stuart Mill. Disputes the modern view that classical economists ignored the effects of technological change. Schlenher, Robert E. Health Improvements and Economic Growth: Neoclassical Theory and the Puerto Rican Experience. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Michigan, 1968. 128 pp. Sveikauskas, Leopold A. Capital-Labor Substitution and Efficiency in United States Manufacturing. Thesis presented to Yale University, 1969. 341 pp. Views public health programs as investments 'in human capital and examines their effect on per-capita output. Examines the conditions associated with high efficiency in each 2-digit U.S. manufacturing industry. Finds that science, technology, and education are the key sources of efficiency. Shen, Tsung-yuen. A Quantitative Study o f Production in the American Textile Industry. Doctoral thesis presented to Yale University, 1966. 289 pp. Yan, Chiou-Shuang J. Technical Change and Investment. Doctoral thesis presented to Purdue University, 1966. 191 pp. Finds a long lag between the introduction of new technology in the'industry and widespread indifference toward innovation. Investigates the relationship between investment and the rate of embodied technological change. Estimates the relative importance of embodied and disembodied technological change, Sonny, Jacob. Technological Change in the U.S. Machine Tool Industry. Doctoral thesis presented to the New School of Social Research, 1971.238 pp. Zarka, Muhammed.Product, Capital, and Productivity in Syrian Agriculture. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Pennsylvania, 1969. 209 pp. Attributes lagging technological change in the industry to slow replacement of aged machine tools due to product durability and to widely fluctuating demand for the industry’s output. Develops a continuous time series for product and capital. Uses a Cobb-Douglas production function to measure total factor productivity. Sosin, Helen K. M. Technological Aspects o f Economic G row th: Demand-Induced Technical Progress. Doctoral thesis presented to the University of Nebraska, 1970. 144 pp. VIIL Bibliographies, annual reports, etc. Argues that technological improvements in capital goods are induced by their producers’ expectations of rising demand, and that therefore technological change Asian Productivity Organization. Dissemination o f Knowledge Series. Tokyo, Asian Productivity Organi zation, 1964-; irregular. 89 Presents summaries of articles on productivity and related subjects which have appeared in publications of member and nonmember countries. Also devotes entire issue to subjects pertinent to productivity improvement. on age-related differences in the capacities of workers; policy implications of automation as related to employ ment; and background material pertaining to automation and to older workers. Canada, Economic Council of Canada. Annual Review. Ottawa, Queen’s Printer, 1964-. Kussow, Omar, and Dunwiddie, William. Instructional Materials on Productivity and Automation: An Annotated Bibliography, A Descriptive List o f Films. M adison, Center for Productivity Motivation, University of Wisconsin, 1965. 14 pp. Published annually, the Review presents discussions of, and data on, economic trends and policy. Each report deals extensively with a particular theme, e.g., prices, productivity, and employment; Canada’s position in the world economy; economic goals; performance of major sectors, etc. Presents an annotated list of titles designed chiefly for classroom use. Also contains a list of relevant films. Manpower Report o f the President (including a Report on Manpower Requirements, Resources, Utilization, and Training by the U.S. Department of Labor). Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office. 19 . Economic Report o f the President (together with the Annual Report of the Council of Economic Advisers). Washington, U.S. Government Printing Office, 19 . Issued annually since 1963, the Manpower Report deals primarily with manpower requirements, resources, utilization, and training. Developments in productivity and related subjects are usually also discussed. Issued annually, the Economic Report regularly discusses developments in productivity, labor costs, and related topics. Educational Technology. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Educa tional Technology Publications, Inc. Monthly. 1961 to date. New Literature on Automation. Amsterdam, Stitching The Netherlands Studiecentrum voor Informatica. Monthly. 1960 to date. A periodical regularly presenting articles on the relation between technology and education, and the use of technology in education. A periodical presenting listings of current publica tions on computer technology, information theory, the consequences of automation, and related subjects. List ings are annotated. Harrison, Annette. Bibliography on Automation and Technological Change and Studies o f the Future. Rand Corporation Paper, P-3365. Santa Monica, California, Rand Corporation, 1966. 24 pp. United Nations. Industrialization and Productivity. Bulletin. New York, United Nations, 1958 to date. Kennedy, Charles, and Thirlwall, A. P. “Surveys in Applied Economics: Technical Progress.” The Economic Journal, March 1972. Published at irregular intervals, this series presents articles on problems of industrial development in tech nologically less advanced countries. Presents as an appendix of this survey article an authoritative bibliography of works bearing on the tUle theme. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. BLS Publications on Productivity and Technology. 1972. 16 pp. Kreps, Juanita, and Laws, Ralph. Automation and the Older Worker. An annotated bibliography prepared for the Committee on Employment and Retirement of the National Council on the Aging. New York, N.Y., The National Council on the Aging, 1963. 49 pp. Contains citations of articles and reports from 1960 to 1971. The authors present titles on the effect of techno logical advance on job opportunities for all workers; data Regularly publishes original articles on concepts, trends, and the sources of productivity, as well as on U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Monthly Labor Review. Washington, U.S. Govern ment Printing Office. 90 other subjects relating to productivity and technological change. Lists new publications on productivity each month under “ Book Reviews and Notes—Other Publica tions—Productivity and Technological Change.” Period covered generally extends from 1953 to mid-1957, but some references dating from prior to 1953 are included. U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Productivity: A Bibliography, BLS Bulletin 1226, 1958. 182 pp. (Out of print but available at many libraries that are depositories for Government pub lications.) U.S. Department of Labor, Bureau of Labor Statistics. Productivity: A Bibliography, BLS Bulletin 1514, 1966. 129 pp. Presents annotated citations of books, reports, and articles on productivity concepts and measurements; factors affecting productivity; productivity levels and trends in various economic sectors; international productivity comparisons; the relation of productivity to the economy; and a list of bibliographies. Period covered extends from mid-1957 to 1964. An annotated bibliography of books and references on productivity published through June 1957. Presents annotated citations of measures of produc tivity by industry and economic sector; studies of productivity at the plant level; international comparisons of productivity, factors affecting productivity; the rela tion of productivity to the economy as a whole, and to wages and prices; and productivity and labor-manage ment relations. Also contains a list of bibliographies and of doctoral dissertations and theses on the subject. U.S. Department of Labor, Library. The Shorter Work week; Selected References, N.S. No. 5, 1965. 15 pp. Lists titles on real wages, hours, leisure preference, and pertinent legislation. 91 Author Index (Authors of theses and dissertations are not included.) Adams, Dale W. 3.136 Adams, W. J. 3.221 Adelman, Edwin 2.001,2.067 Ahmad, Syed 3.222 Aigner, D. J. 1.001 Alburo, Florian A. 2.002 Aliber, Robert Z. 4.067 Aim on, Clopper, Jr. 6.001 Alterman, Jack 1.002, 5.001, 6.002, 6.003, 6.004 Ammer, Dean S. 5.003 Anderson, W.H.L. 1.004 Anton, Frank R. 4.001 Ardolini, Charles W. 2.001,2.003, 2.067 Argy, V. 4.002 Arnfield, R. V. 3.102 Aronson, Robert L. 5.004 Arrow, Kenneth J. 3.223 Arvidsson,G. 3.224 Atkinson, Anthony B. 3.103 Auer, L. 2.004,2.005 Ayres, Robert V. 3.104 Bennett, E. C. 3.108 Berglas, Eitan 1.006 Bergson, Abram 2.013 Berri, L. 6.006 Bertram, Gordon W. 3.004 Besen, S. M. 3.005 Bhatt, V. V. 6.023 Bhattacharyya, M. A. 6.007 Bjeda, K. 3.006 Black, Guy 3.232 Blackett, P. M. S. 6.008 Blakeman, L. T. 4.006 Blase, M. G. 3.138 Blaug, Mark 2.114, 3.007 Bliss, Charles A. 4.007 Blitzer,C.R. 6.009 Bloom, Gordon F. 4.008 Blyth,C.A. 6.010 Bock, Betty 3.072,3.073,3.074 Bodkin, Ronald G. 4.009 Bonwick, George J. 5.010 Borch, Karl 1.007 Bossier, W. 2.014 Bottomley, A. 4.010,4.049 Bowen, Howard R. 5.011 Bowles, S. S. 3.008 Bowman, Mary Jean 3.009, 3.010 Braae,G. P. 1.008 Brady, Dorothy 2.015 Brand, Horst 4.011 Bright, James R. 3.109 Briscoe, G. 1.009 Bronfenbrenner, Martin 4.012 Brooks, George W. 3.110 Brown, Lester R. 3.111,3.112 Brown, Murray 1.010,3.113 Brown, R. H. 3.226 Brubaker, E. R. 1.011 Bruton, Henry J. 6.011,6.012 Buck, P. B. 5.012 Buckingham, G. L. 4.052 Burck, Gilbert 2.016 Burns, Leland S. 3.061 Baerwaldt, Nancy 3.026 Bagrit, Sir Leon 3.105 Baldwin, Robert E. 6.005 Ball, Claiborne M. 2.006, 2.007,2.008 Ball, Robert 2.009,3.106,5.089 Banerji, Ranadev 3.218 Baranson, Jack 3.107 Bardwell, George E. 5.006 Barkin, Solomon 5.007 Barnes, Irston R. 4.003 Bartsch, W. H. 3.001 Bateman, Fred 2.010 Bauer, L.L. 5.008 Bauer, Raymond A. 5.009 Becker, Gary S. 3.002 Becker, S. W. 3.071,3.225 Beckmann, Martin J. 1.005 Behman, Sara 2.011 Bell, F.W. 2.012 Beller, Irving 4.004,4.005 Ben-Porath, Yoram 3.003 92 Bush, George P. 3.114 Butler, Gavan 3.218 Butter worth, Jack 3.075 Bynum, Alice L. 2.017 Delehanty, George E. 5.019 Denison, Edward F. 1.018, 2.031,2.032, 2.033 Diamond, Peter A. 1.019, 1.020 Diaz, Alejandro, Carlos F. 1.021 Diebold, John 3.078,3.125 Divatia, V. V. 6.023 Diwan,R. K. 3.126 Doctors, Samuel 1. 3.127 Doll, John P. 1.022 Domangue, Dennis A. 5.020 Domar, Evsey D. 1.023 Dorner, Peter 3.136, 5.021 Douty, H. M. 4.019,4.020 Dovring, Folke 1.044, 2.034, 3.079 Dowie,J. A. 2.035 Dragonnette, Joseph E. 2.036, 2.037, 2.038 Dubin, Robert 3.080 Du Boff, Richard B. 1.024 Duncan, James H. 2.039 Dunlop, John T. 4.021 Caplan, Stanley H. 3.121 Capron, William M. 3.115 Carey, John L. 2.019, 2.020, 2.021,2.022 Carroll, Jean 3.227 Carter, Anne P. 3.116,3.117 Chambers, E.J. 6.013 Chandler, John H. 4.014,4.015 Chang, W.W. 3.118 Chao, Kang 3.067, 6.014 Chien, W. 4.043 Childs, Rex E. 2.023 Christensen, Eric 5.015 Christensen, L. R. 1.012, 1.013 Christian, James W. 6.015 Chu, S. F. 1.001 Clark, Colin 6.016 Cleaver, Joe M. 2.024 Close, Guy C., Jr. 4.016 Cohn, Edward A. 2.025 Colm, Gerhard 6.017 Colyer, D. 3.138 Comanor, William S. 3.229 Cooper, Joseph D. 3.230 Cordtz,Dan 2.026 Cornwall, John 6.018 Cottrell, Fred 5.016 Cox, R. W. 5.010 Creamer, Daniel 1.058 Critchlow, Robert V. 3.120 Crossman, E. R. F. W. 3.121,5.017 Cukor, Gy 6.019 Earl, Victor 3.128 Eisgruber, L. M. 3.090 Elliott, Mable 5.023 Eltis, W. A. 6.024,6.025 Enarson, Harold L. 3.011 Engerman, Stanley L. 1.030, 3.012 Enke, Stephen 6.026 Erlich, Alexander 6.027 Etherington, D. M. 3.033 Evan, E. W. 3.129 Evan, William M. 3.232 Fabricant, Solomon 1.025, 3.130 Farkas,Jack 3.073,3.074 Fehd, Carolyn S. 2.040, 2.041,2.042, 2.043 Feinstein, C. H. 1.027 Feldstein, M. S. 3.013 Feller, Irwin 3.233 Fellner, William 3.195,6.028 Fenske, Russell W. 1.028 Ferguson, C. E. 1.029 Ferguson, Walter 3.131 Ferkiss, Victor C. 3.132 Ferris, John W., Jr. 2.044 Finn, Joseph T. 2.009 Fleishman, Edwin A. 6.016 Fleming, M. C. 2.045,2.046,3.081 Fogel, Robert W. 1.030 Ford, Gordon W. 3.133 Foster, Howard G. 5.022 Fox, Harland 4.022 Freedman, Audrey 5.023, 5.024, 5.025, 5.026 Dacy, Douglas C. 2.027 Dahmen, Erik 3.077 Dairymple, Dana G. 3.122 Daly, D. J. 2.028,2.029 Daniels, Mark R. 1.014 David, Paul A. 1.015,3.123, 6.020, 6.021 Davidson, J. R. 1.050 Davis, Lance E. 6.022 Davis, Louis E. 3.121 Davis, Vincent 3.231 Dawson, John 2.030 Day, R. H. 5.018 Deakin, B. M. 1.016 Delagrave, Pierre M. 4.018 de Leeuw, Frank 1.017 93 Hartman, Paul T. 4.033 Hattery, Lowell H. 3.114 Havelock, Ronald G. 3.236 Hay ami, Y. 2.056,3.082 Headley, J. C. 2.057 Heilbroner, Robert L. 3.140 Helfgott, Roy B. 5.035 Hemley, D. D. 4.046 Henneberger, John E. 2.058,2.059, 2.060 Herman, Arthur S. 2.061,3.106,5.036 Herman, Shelby W. 2.062, 2.063, 2.064,2.074, 2.081 Heskett,J. L. 1.048 Hicks, John 6.033 Higgs, R. 3.237 Hildebrand, George H. 1.049 Hilgert, Ronald J. 2.065 Hill, T. P. 6.034 Hino, Hiroyuki 4.031 Hirsh, Werner Z. 3.141 Hirshleifer, Jack 3.238 Hodgson, James D. 4.080, 6.066 Hogg, H.C. 1.050 Hohenstein, Jeffrey 2.067 Holmes, R. A. 6.035 Homans, George C. 3.080 Horvitz, Wayne L. 4.034 Hou, Chia-Chu 6.056 Hubbard, Norman S. 5.037 Huffstutler, Clyde 2.067 Hugh-Jones, E. M. 3.142 Hultgren, Thor 4.035 Hunt, E. H. 1.051,4.036 Hunter, Maxwell W. 3.143 Freeman, Christopher 3.134 Freeman, R. E. 4.023 Friedrichs, Gunter 5.027 Froomkin, Joseph 5.045 Fryer, John L. 5.028 Fuchs, Victor R. 1.031, 1.032, 2.047, 2.048, 5.029 Fulco, Lawrence J. 2.063, 2.064, 3.135 Furuya,K. 1.123 Gaathon, A. L. 1.033 Gaevskaia,V. 5.030 Galatin, Malcolm 1.034 Gale, Hazen F. 2.044,2.049, 2.050, 2.051,2.052, 2.059 Gamble, William K. 3.136 Geiger, Theodore 6.017 Geisel, John M. 1.035 George, K. D. 1.036,2.053,2.054 Gintis, Herbert 3.014 Glejser, Herbert 4.024 Goddard, Frederick O. 6.029 Gold, Bela 1.037,3.137 Goldberg, Joseph P. 5.031 Golding, John 4.039 Goldsmith, Maurice 3.234 Golov, A. 1.038 Goodwin, L.B. 3.138 Gordon, D. F. 6.013 Gordon, Robert J. 1.039 Gouvemeur, J. 1.040,1.041 Green, H. A. J. 1.042 Greenberg, Leon 5.032,5.033 Gregory, Peter 4.062 Griliches, Zvi 1.043, 1.056, 3.235 Grossling, William 1.044 Guha, A. 6.030 Gupta, S. 1.045 Gwartney, J. D. 4.030 Intriligator, Michael D. 1.053 lrgens,0. M. 3.146 Isaac, Julius E. 4.038 Isenson, Raymond S. 3.147 Haase, Peter E. 5.034 Haldi, John 2.055 Halevi, N. 1.061 Hall, R. E. 1.046 Hamada,K. 1.047 Hamberg, Daniel 6.031 Hamer, P. 6.010 Hamilton, Mary T. 4.061 Hammerman, Herbert 5.025 Hansen, W. Lee 3.015 Harbison, Frederick R. 6.032 Harmston, Floyd K. 4.031 Harris, E. Marjorie 4.032 Hartley, K. 3.016 Jackman, Patrick C. 2.068,4.014,4.015 Jacks, Frederick G. 2.069 Jaffe, A. J. 5.045 Jantsch, Erich 3.148 Jaynes, Philip W. 2.037 Jehring, J.J. 2.070, 3.084, 3.149, 3.150 Johnston, R. E. 3.239 Jones, Ken 4.039 Jorgenson, Dale W. 1.012,1.013, 1.043,1.055, 1.056 Kahn, Elizabeth 4.045 Kalachek, Edward D. 3.172 Kaldor, Nicholas 3.151 Kamerschen, David R. 4.040 94 Lovell, C. A. Knox 3.158 Lucas, R. E., Jr. 1.073 Lydall, H. 3.159 Lyon, Richard W. 2.022,3.106 Kamien,M. I. 3.240 KanedajHiromita 3.152,3.153 Kaplan, Norman M. 6.036 Kelly, Terence F. 2.020, 2.021 Kendrick, John W. 1.057, 1.058, 2.071,2.072 Kennedy, Kieran A. 6.037 Kennedy, R. V. 1.059 Ketterling, Virgil H. 2.058, 2.073, 5.046 Keyes, J. Stephen 5.023 Keys, B. A. 2.028 Kiker, B. F. 3.017,3.018 Kim, S. 1.060 Kim, Y. C. 6.038 Kindleberger, Charles P. 6.039,6.040 Kleiman,E. 1.061 Kleiman, Herbert S. 3.241 Klotz, Benjamin P. 1.062,1.063,1.064,2.074, 5.047 Knauerhase, K. 3.154 Knight, Kenneth E. 3.242 Knudsen, John W. 1.065 Konopa, Leonard J. 2.075 Koo, Anthony Y. C. 2.076 Kovalick, Peter N. 1.066 Kreinin, Mordechai E. 3.019 Kuh, Edwin 1.067,4.041 Kumar, Dharma 3.155 Kurihara, Kenneth K. 6.041 Kutscher, Ronald E. 1.002 Kuznets, Simon 3.020, 6.042, 6.043 Macut, John J. 3.160,3.161 Maddala, G. S. 2.078 Maddison, Angus 2.079 Mahar, James F. 5.006 Makdisi, S. A. 6.045 Mandelstamm, Allan B. 5.051 Mangum, Garth L. 5.011 Mann, Floyd C. 3.080 Mansfield, Edwin 3.162, 3.244, 3.245 Mark, Jerome A. 2.080, 2.081,2.082,4.044, 4.045 Markuson, Barbara Evans 3.164 Marquis, Donald B. 3.250 Marsden, Keith 3.163 Maruhnic, Joan 6.032 Masters, Stanley H. 1.074 Mathewson, Stanley B. 3.023 Mauer, J.J. 4.046 Mazel, Joseph L. 4.047 McAdams, A.K. 3.246 McCarthy, M. D. 1.075 McCloskey, S. N. 2.083,3.165 McKersie, Robert B. 3.094 Mehta, P.C. 6.056 Melman, Seymour 3.087,3.166 Melvin, J. R. 3.167 Merhaw, Meir 3.168 Merrett, S. 3.024 Metcalfe, J. S. 3.247 Migliore, Henry R. 3.025 Miller, Delbert C. 3.080 Miller, Stanley F. 2.084, 2.085 Minami, R. 6.046 Minasian, Jora R. 3.248 Mishan, E.J. 3.169 Mitchell, Edward J. 4.048 Moes, J.E., 4.049 Morgan, James N. 3.026 Morse, Dean 3.170 Moss, Bennett R. 1.077 Moss, Fred T. 2.086, 2.087 Moss,M. 1.078 Moun dale xis, John 1.066 Mueller, Dennis C. 3.249 Mueller, Eva 5.052 Mullen, James H. 3.088 Muller, Charlotte 1.079 Murphy, N. B. 2.012 Lai, Brij Bhushan 6.044 Lamson, Robert D. 4.042 Lancaster, Kelvin 3.156 Laner, Stephen 3.121 La Tourette, J.E.l .068, 1.069 Lau, J.J. 1.124 Lave, Lester B. 3.157 Lawler, Edward E. 4.084 Lawrence, Paul R. 5.048 Lee, Tieh-sheng 6.056 Leibenstein, Harvey 3.085,3.086 Leonard, William N. 3.243 Lessowski, Witold 1.070 Levenson, Irving F . 3.021 Levhari, D. 1.061,1.071,3.022 Levine,Morton 5.049 Lin, Leon 3.217 li-Tien, F. 4.043 Liu, Ta-Chung 1.049 Lomax, K. S. 2.077 Lou, L. J. 1.072 Lovejoy, Robert J. 5.050 95 Murray, Roland V. 2.008 Musgrave, P. W. 3.027 Myers, John G. 4.050 Myers, R. G. 3.010 Myers, Sumner 3.250 Myslicki, Chester 2.038,2.088 Pratten, C. 2.094 Price, J. E. 3.033 Quinn, James B. 3.182, 3.183 Rader, T. 1.093 Raimon, Robert L. 3.034,3.035 Raines, Frederick Q. 4.059 Ramachandra, N. 6.056 Rankine, L. B. 1.050 Rapping, Leonard 3.036 Read, L. M. 4.060 Rees, Albert 4.061 Reiss, F. J. 3.187 Remery, R. 2.095 Renten, Henry 2.096 Resnick, Jane R. 6.032 Reynolds, Lloyd G. 4.062 Rezler, Julius 5.065 Rhodes, James V. 1.022 Riche, Martha Farnsworth 2.009, 2.097 Riche, Richard W. 5.025,5.066,5.067 Rimlinger, G. V. 3.091 Robertson, D.J. 4.063, 4.064 Robinson, Derek 4.065 Robinson, Joan 1.094 Roman, Zoltan 1.095 Rosegger, G. 3.137 Rosen, Ned A. 3.092 Rosenberg, Jerry M. 3.037 Rosenberg, Nathan 3.184 Rosenbloom, Richard S. 3.185 Rothberg, Herman J. 2.085, 5.068 Rudelius, W. 3.256 Ruff, L. E. 3.257 Rumiantsev, A. 3.258 Ruttan, V. W. 2.056,3.082 Rymes, Thomas K. 1.096,1.097 Nadiri, M. Ishaq 1.080 Nair, Kusum 6.057 Nance, Harold W. 1.081 Naqui, K. A. 1.094 Neef, Arthur 4.051 Neher, Phillip A. 6.047 Nelkin, Dorothy 3.251 Nelson, Richard R. 2.090, 3.029, 3.171,3.172, 6.048 Nesvera, Vaclav 1.082 Nevile, J.W. 1.083 Nicholson, R.J. 1.084 Nishikawa, Shunsaku 1.085 Noda, Nobuo 3.089 Nordhaus, William D. 3.173, 3.252 North, Dick T.B. 4.052 Nofth, Douglas C. 1.086 Novikov, H. 3.030 Nowshirrani, V. F. 6.049 Nudds, D. 4.010 O’Brien, P. 1.009 O’Carroll, Lloyd T. 3.174 Okishio, N. 1.087 Olken, Hyman 3.175 Owen, Wyn F. 6.057 Pack, Howard 3.179 Paelinck, Jean 1.089 Pandit, N. H. 3.032 Parker, William N. 1.090 Patrick, G. F. 3.090 Paukert, Liba 5.078 Peck, Merton J. 3.172 Pejovich, S. 5.063 Perlo, Victor 2.092 Phelps, Edmund S. 3.029 Phelps-Brown, E. H. 4.056 Phillips, Almarin 3.180 Philpot, G. 1.091 Phipps, Anthony J. 4.057 Piakash,Piem 2.093 Pierce, W. S. 3.137 Piore,M. 5.064 Pitchford, J. D. 4.058 Porter, R. C. 3.181 Prasow, Paul 3.194 Sahota, G. S. 1.098,1.099 Sales, Stephen M. 3.093 1 Salkin, Jay S. 1.100 Salter, W. E. G. 3.186 Samuelson, Paul A. 1.071, 1.101,3.259 Sapolsky, Harvey M. 3.260 Sato,Ryuzo 1.005 Sawney, P. K. 1.102 Schmookler, Jacob 3.261 Schon, Donald A. 3.262 Schroeder, Gertrude 3.038 Schuh, G. Edward 6.057 Schultz, Robert S. 6.058 Schultz, Theodore W. 3.039,3.040 96 Taylor, Lester D. 6.062 Temin, Peter 1.108,3.059 Terreblanche, S. J. 3.060 Thompson, E. J. 6.060 Thompson, F. M. L. 3.198 Thorbecke, Erik 6.061 Thornton, J. 1.109 Thurow, Lester C. 1.110,6.062 Tjibe, B. Khing 3.061 Tlusty, Zdenek 1.111 Todaro, Michael 3.179 Topham, Tony 4.070 Touraine, Alain 5.081 Towers, B. 4.071,4.074 Turner, Marjorie S. 4.073 Schwartz, N. 3.240 Schwartzman, David 1.103,3.05 0 Scott, J.T ., Jr. 3.187 Scott, W. H. 5.069 Scrupski, Stephen E. 3.188 Scully, Gerald W. 3.051 Sellers, Walter E., Jr. 3.052 Sen, A. K. 3.053 Seward, T. 1.016 Shanks, Michael 3.263 Shaw, L. H. 1.104 Sheeks, Robert B. 3.271 Shell, Karl 3.264 Shepard, Herbert A. 3.265 Shepard, Jon M. 5.070 Sherrard, William R. 1.105 Shirai, Takamasa 5.071 Shirom,Arie 5.072 Shrivastav, Omkar S. 4.066 Shultz, George P. 3.094, 4.067 Siegel, B.N. 5.073 Siegel, Irving H. 5.074 Silberman, Charles E. 5.075 Silbertson, A. 2.094 Singer, H.W. 3.055 Sirageldin, Ismail 3.026 Sirota, David 3.095 Smith, A. D. 5.076 Smyth, D .J. 1.009 Solo, Robert A. 1.106 SomeLK. 1.124 Southard, Leland 2.098 Spatz, Laura H. 2.099 Spence, E .J. 2.028 Spencer, Daniel L. 3.189 Sreedharan, V. P. 1.120 Stafford, Frank 3.071 Steedman,I. 1.045 Steiner, George A. 3.190 Stephenson, Samuel S. 1.107 Stettner, Nora 4.068 Stieber,Jack 5.078 Stiglitz, Joseph 3.103,6.059 Stoikov, Vladimir 3.035, 3.056 Strassman, W. Paul 2.100,3.191 Strazheim,Mahlon R. 2.101 Striner, Herbert E. 5.079 Sturm, Herman M. 3.192, 3.193 Sultan, Paul 3.194 Sutermeister, Robert A. 3.057 Suzuki, T. 1.123 Sveikauskas, Leo 3.058 Om an, Lloyd 4.075,5.082 Usher, Dan 1.117 Uzawa, Hirofumi 6.059 Van de Klundert, Th. 3.123 Van Dussen, P. E. 1.118 Van Horn, Thomas R. 2.051 Vanek, Jarasslow 6.067, 6.068 Vatter, H. G. 3.209 Vepa, RamK. 3.098 Verma,P. 3.268 Vernon, Raymond 3.210 Vilenskii, M. 3.211 Waldorf, William H. 2.025, 2.052, 2.112 Walker, James F. 2.096 Walter, D. 2.029 Walton, F .T . 5.086 Walton, Gary M. 3.099,3.212 Warner, Aaron W. 3.170,3.213 Watanabe, Tsunehiko 1.119 Waud, R. N. 3.063 Wedderbum, Dorothy 5.087 Wein, Harold H. 1.120 Weinberg, Edgar 3.064, 3.215, 5.026, 5.088, 5.089 Weiss, Jeffrey 5.090 Welch, F. 3.065 West, Jerry G. 1.022 Westfield, F.M. 3.214 Whistler, T. L. 3.225 Whittingham,T. G. 4.071,4.074 Wilburn, Jean Alexander 2.048 Wiles, R/C. 4.081 Will, R. E. 3.209 Willacy, Hazel M. 3.067 Williams, Bruce R. 3.269 97 Williams, Roger 4.082 Wilson, Andrew H. 3.270 Wise, David 4.083 Wohlmuth, Karl 1.121 Wolek, Francis W. 3.185 Wolfbein, Seymour L. 3.216 Wolfe, J.N . 5.091 Wood, G. L. 3.256 Wood, Ian 4.084 Woodhall, Maureen 2.114 Woroniak, Alexander 3.189 Worthington, Paula 1.079 Worton, David A. 1.122 Wu, Yuan-li 3.271 Wysong, John W. 3.066 Yamada, Saburo 1.085 Yeh, M. H. 3.217 Yoshihara, K. 1.123 Yotopoulos, P.A. 1.072, 1.124 Yudelman, Montague 3.218 Zeisel, Rose N. 3.219, 3.220 Ziegler, Martin 2.082, 2.115 Zudak, L. S. 4.085 98 Subject Index (Theses and dissertations are not included.) Aluminum, 2.024, 2.073 Capital, 1.030, 1.069,1.082,1.086 economic growth, 6.007, 6.018, 6.022, 6.033 farm, 3.090 invention and innovation, 3.264 measurement, 1.039 metalworking industry, 1.003 United Kingdom, 1.027 Armed Forces, 3.231 Capital formation. See Capital and Capital Productivity Agriculture. See Farm Air transportation, 2.036, 2.038, 2.101 Aircraft, 3.180 Asia, 3.111,3.203, 3.204, 6.056 Capital productivity, 1.047,1.093,1.101 Australia, 1.083 Canada, 1.068 capital, 1.069,1.082,1.086,1.121 construction, hospitals, 1.079 developing countries, 1.021 economic growth, 1.006 energy inputs, 1.024 input-output studies, 1.002,1.054 measurement, 1.012, 1.096 organizational factors, 1.087 Poland, 1.070 production functions, 1.046,1.071, 1.094 retail trade, United Kingdom, 1.036 sources of growth, 1.011,1.043, 1.073 technological change, 1.020, 1.042, 1.053, 1.055, 1.120 United Kingdom, 1.036, 1.084 Australia capital productivity, 1.083 earnings, 4.038 economic growth, 1.059 productivity measures, 2.035 Automation. See Technological change Automobiles. See Motor vehicles and equipment Banking, 2.012, 3.121 Bituminous coal, 2.078. See also Coal; Mining Canada capital productivity, 1.068 costs, 4.013 costs, guideposts, 4.001 economic growth, 6.013, 6.035 invention and innovation, 3.270 labor productivity, 1.122 price stability, 4.013 productivity measures international comparisons, 2.004, 2.005, 2.018,2.028,2.029 mining, 2.030 technological change employment, 5.014 farm, 3.217 manpower adjustment programs, 5.013 Capital stock. See Capital and Capital productivity Cement industry, India, 1.102 Chemical industry, 5.044 China, 3.076, 3.271, 6.014 Coal (see also Bituminous coal;Mining), 2.106,3.200 Colombia, 2.090 Communications industry, 3.115, 3.124 Company productivity, 1.058,1.092,1.105,1.107 employment, 5.047 growth projections, 1.062,1.064 production function, 1.063 Capacity utilization (see also Economies of scale) in manufacturing, 1.017 United Kingdom, 1.009,1.019,1.084 99 Earnings (see also Costs; Costs, foreign countries), 4.043 education, 3.002, 3.003, 3.015,3.024 employment, 4.055 farm, 4.036 international comparisons, 4.002, 4.018, 4.048, 4.056 social variables, 4.030,4.046 technological change, 4.031 Computers, 3.101,3.176, 5.002, 5.036, 5.077 international comparisons, 5.069 Concentration, industrial. See Economics of scale; Organizational factors Concrete products, 2.065 Construction. See also Construction, foreign countries hospitals, capital productivity, 1.079 labor requirements college housing, 2.084, 2.085 highways, 2.007 hospitals and nursing homes, 2.009, 2.097 schools, 2.096 selected types, 2.006 sewer works, 2.008 single-family homes, 2.011 technological change, 3.215 trade unions, 5.051 Economic growth (see also Economic growth, foreign countries) capital, 1.006, 6.007, 6.022, 6.033 education, contribution of, 3.004, 3.006, 3.031, 3.060 farm, 6.049, 6.050, 6.057, 6.061 food distribution, 6.052 improvement programs, 6.053 income shares, 6.026 international comparisons, 6.038, 6.042, 6.043, 6.051,6.054,6.055 invention and innovation, 3.261 measurement, 6.034 organizational factors, 5.015 production function, 6.062 projections, 6.001, 6.002, 6.003, 6.004, 6.006, 6.019,6.048,6.063,6.064 quality of life, 6.017, 6.066 research and development, 3.243, 3.269 social variables, 6.032 sources of, 6.016, 6.058, 6.060 technological change, 6.020, 6.021, 6.025, 6.028, 6.029,6.067,6.068 Construction, foreign countries developing countries, 2.100 Ireland, 2.045 Japan, 1.123 Northern Ireland, 2.046 United Kingdom, 1.008 Corrugated and solid fiber box industry, 2.040, 2.042 Costs (see also Costs, foreign countries), 4.010,4.011, 4.040, 4.058,4.073, 4.081,4.084,4.085 employment, 4.009,4.050,4.061 farm, 4.023 fringe benefits, 4.022 improvement programs, 4.016 income shares, 4.003, 4.004,4.005 iron and steel industries, 4.083 manufacturing industries, 4.014, 4.015, 4.045, 4.051 measurement, 4.037 price stability, 4.008, 4.024 profits, 4.035, 4.041 Economic growth, foreign countries Asia, 6.056 Australia, 1.059 Canada, 6.013, 6.035 China, 6.014 Europe, 6.018, 6.040 developing countries, 6.005, 6.024 France, 6.039 India, 6.023, 6.044, 6.049 Ireland, 6.037 Japan, 6.041,6.046 Syria, 6.045 United Kingdom, 3.129, 6.008 USSR, 6.006, 6.009, 6.027, 6.036 Costs, foreign countries Australia, 4.038 Canada, 4.001,4.013 developing countries, 4.049,4.066 United Kingdom, 4.025, 4.028,4.072 Economies of scale (see also Capacity utilization), 3.072, 3.073,3.074,3.081 banking, 2.012 construction, 2.045 electric power, 1.034 farm, 1.026,1.100,3.079,3.153 India, 2.093 research and development, 3.221 technological change, 3.126,3.142 Czechoslovakia, 5.078 Dairy farming, 2.010, 2.089 Developing countries, 1.021,1.040, 1.041, 2.100, 3.107, 3.122, 3.136, 3.151, 3.163, 3.168, 3.179, 3.189, 3.191,4.049, 4.066, 6.005, 6.024 100 Farm Education, 3.005, 3.007, 3.009, 3.011, 3.014, 3.016, 3.017, 3.018, 3.022, 3.024, 3.040, 3.050, 3.055, 3.062,3.065 cost-benefit analysis, 3.010, 3.012, 3.032, 3.039 earnings, 3.002, 3.003, 3.015, 3.024 economic growth, 3.004, 3.006, 3.031,3.060 international comparisons, 3.006, 3.056 production functions, 3.036, 3.051 productivity measures, 2.114 technological change, 3.027, 3.037, 5.057, 5.063, 5.077,5.088 capital, 3.090 costs, 4.023 economic growth, 6.049, 6.050, 6.057, 6.061 economies of scale, 1.026, 1.100, 3.079, 3.153 employment, 5.008, 5.018, 5.021 income shares, 5.021 input measures, 2.057 invention and innovation, 3.235 labor productivity, 1.015, 1.044, 1.051,4.036, 5.050 labor utilization, 3.033, 3.052, 3.067, 5.030 management, 3.090 organizational factors, 3.082 production function, 1.022, 1.050 productivity measurement, 1.072, 1.104,1.117 productivity measures, 2.004, 2.005, 2.056, 2.057, 2.107 sources of growth, 1.090 technological change, 3.112, 3.131, 3.135, 3.136 3.138,3.152,3.187,3.198 Asia, 3.111 Canada, 3.217 developing countries, 3.122,3.136 economic growth, 6.057 employment, 5.008, 5.018 India, 3.155 international comparisons, 3.218 total factor productivity, India, 1.098, 1.124 Electrical equipment, 3.241 Electric power industry, 1.034, 3.115 Electric utilities. See Electric power industry; Gas and electric utilities Electronic components, 3.176, 3.188 Emigration. See Migration Employment, 5.032, 5.046 company productivity, 5.047 costs, 4.009, 4.041,4.050, 4.061,4.066 earnings, 4.055 farm, 5.008, 5.018, 5.021 guideposts, 5.074 hours of work, 5.022 international comparisons, 5.086 labor productivity, 5.037, 5.071 manpower requirements, 5.001 service industries, 5.029 technological change (see also Technological change, employment) chemicals, 5.044 computers, 5.002, 5.036, 5.069 Czechoslovakia, 5.078 footwear, 5.039 gray iron foundries, 5.003 insurance, 5.023, 5.024 leather, 5.039 manufacturing, 5.091 railroads, 5.014, 5.016 shipping, 5.010, 5.012, 5.031 sugar, 5.020 textiles, 5.043, 5.076 Food, 2.049 distribution, 2.051,2.052, 2.112. 6.052 processing, 2.025, 2.098 Footwear, 2.086, 2.087, 5.039 Forecasting. See Projections; Technological forecasting Foundries (see also Gray iron foundries), 2.014 France, 5.043, 6.039 Fringe benefits, 4.022 Gas and electric utilities (see also Electric power industry) 2.037,5.066,5.067 Energy inputs, 1.024, 1.108 Germany, 3.027, 3.154 Europe economic growth, 6.018, 6*040 productivity measures, 2.031, 2.032, 2.033, 2.039 2.077,2.091,2.103 Government, Federal manpower adjustment policies, 5.068 post office, 2.055 productivity measurement, 1.066,1.112,1.113 productivity measures, 2.072 Exports. See International trade Government, municipal, 2.026 101 Gray iron foundries, 2.019, 2.022, 5.003 Invention and innovation (see also Invention and innova tion, by industry), 1.030, 3.222, 3.223,3.234, 3.236, 3.238, 3.240, 3.251, 3.252, 3.253, 3.255, 3.262, 3.263 Armed Forces, 3.231 Canada, 3.270 capital, 3.264 economic growth, 3.261 manpower, 3.259 organizational factors, 3.225, 3.232, 3.240, 3.256, 3.260,3.265 social variables, 3.226, 3.233, 3.237, 3.242 United Kingdom, 3.247, 3.268 Growth. See Economic growth Guideposts. See Wage-price gui deposts. Health services, 3.192, 3.193, 3.227, 5.090 Hosiery, 2.017 Hospitals, 1.079, 2.009, 2.070, 2.097 Hours of work, 3.021,3.067, 5.022, 5.055 Invention and innovation, by industry electrical equipment, 3.241 farm, 3.235 health services, 3.227 industry studies, 3.250 insurance, 3.256 pharmaceuticals, 3.230 railroads, 3.245 steel, 3.246 textiles, 3.228 Household appliances, 2.059, 2.095 Hungary, 1.095 Immigration, See Migration Imports. See International trade Improvement programs, 3.069, 3.070, 3.078, 3.084, 3.094, 4.016, 4.047, 6.053, 6.058 health services, 3.096 international comparisons, 4.053 Japan, 3.068, 3.098 United Kingdom, 3.075 Iran, 3.001 Ireland, 2.045, 6.037 Iron and steel, 3.137, 3.165 international comparisons, 2.068, 2.083, 2.103 2.105,3.027,4.083 Income shares, 4.003,4.004, 4.005, 4.043,4.047, 4.076 economic growth, 6.026 farm, 5.021 technological change, 4.031 Israel, 1.033,3.087 Italy, 5.050 Incomes policy. See Wage-price guideposts India Japan, 1.123, 3.068, 3.083, 3.089, 3.098, 6.041, 6.046 farm, 3.082, 3.153 cement industry, 1.102 economic growth, 6.023, 6.044, 6.049 farming, 1.072, 1.098,1.124, 3.155 productivity measures, 2.093 Labor productivity, 1.067, 1.111,5.071 farm, 1.015,1.051,4.036, 5.050 input-output studies, 1.045 international comparisons, 4.048 lumber industry, 1.105 manufacturing, 5.037 measurement, 1.065,1.114,1.115,1.116 Canada, 1.122 construction, single-family homes, 1.008 farm, 1.044 Hungary, 1.095 international comparisons, 1.052 office work, 1.076,1.081 supervisory work, 1.035 USSR, 1.038 production scheduling, 1.004 transportation, 1.016 Input-output studies, 1.002, 1.054, 1.111, 1.119,5.001 food, 2.049 projections, 6.002, 6.003, 6.004, 6.064 technological change, 3.116,3.117, 3.217 United Kingdom, 1.045 Insurance industry, 3.256, 5.023, 5.024 International comparisons. See section under specific subject heading International trade, 2.111,3.210,4.080, 6.011 international comparisons, 2.076 102 underdeveloped countries, 1.040 underemployment, 1.074 occupational structure, 5.019 production function, 1.029, 1.049, 1.060, 1.118 productivity measures, 2.028, 2.115 wage-price guideposts, 4.059 Labor quality. See Education; Occupational structure Labor requirements. See Construction, labor require ments Measurement. See under specific subject heading Metal mining, 2.015 Labor utilization, 3.023, 3.025, 3.026, 3.028, 3.053, 3.057,3.059,3.061,3.064 farm, 3.033, 3.052,3.066, 5.030 hours of work, 3.021,3.067 immigration, 3.020 international comparisons, 3.019 Iran, 3.001 occupations, 3.034, 3.035, 3.058 production functions, 3.008, 3.013, 3.063 technological change, 3.218 underemployment, 1.074 USSR, 3.030, 3.038, 3.054 Metalworking, 1.003 Mexico, 3.079 Migration, 3.010, 3.020 Mining (see also Metal mining), 2.030, 3.202 Motor vehicles and equipment, 2.067, 2.088, 2.094, 5.005 Lead and zinc, 3.206 New Zealand, 5.016, 6.010 Leather, 5.039 Nonelectrical machinery, 3.174 Libraries, 3.164 Northern Ireland, 2.046 Longshore, 4.033,4.034 Occupational structure, 3.034, 3.035,3.058, 3.081 health services, 5.090 international comparisons, 4.048 manufacturing, 5.019 technological change, 3.121, 5.006, 5.055, 5.062, 5.088,5.089 underdeveloped countries, 1.041 USSR, 5.042 Lumber, 1.105 Machine tools, 3.100, 3.129, 3.160, 3.161 Management, 3.080, 3.087, 3.088, 3.090, 3.092, 3.093, 3.094,3.095 Office work, 1.076,1.081 Man-hours. See Hours of work Organizational factors, 3.085 capital productivity, 1.087 China, 3.076 costs, 4.040 economic growth, 5.015, 6.008 farm, 3.082 health and welfare programs, 3.091 invention and innovation, 3.225, 3.232, 3.240, 3.256,3.260,3.265 price stability, 4.021 savings and loan associations, 3.071 Sweden, 3.077 technological change, 3.086 United Kingdom, 3.097 Man-made fibers, 2.099 Manpower (see also Employment; Manpower require ments), 3.218, 3.259 Manpower adjustment programs, 5.005, 5.013, 5.015, 5.025, 5.026, 5.049, 5.066, 5.067, 5.068, 5.076 Manpower requirements, 3.194, 5.001,5.083 Manufacturing capacity utilization, 1.017 capital-output ratios, 2.092 costs, 4.014,4.015,4.045,4.051 economic growth, 6.038, 6.039 employment, 5.091 international trade, 2.111 invention and innovation, 3.268 labor productivity, 5.037 Petroleum, 2.015 Petroleum pipelines, 2.043 Pharmaceuticals, 3.176, 3.229, 3.230 103 Philippines, 2.002 labor productivity, 1.008, 1.065, 1.114, 1.115, 1.116 Canada, 1.122 farm, 1.044 Hungary, 1.095 international comparisons, 1.052 supervisory work, 1.035 USSR, 1.038 office work, 1.076,1.081 prices, 4.042 service industries, 1.031,1.032,2.016 total factor productivity, 1.007, 1.037, 1.097 trade, 1.048, 1.103 Plant productivity. See Company productivity Plastics, 3.176 Poland, 1.070 Poultry processing, 2.023 Price indexes, 1.077, 1.123 Prices (see also Costs), 4.057, 4.076 farm, 4.023 international comparisons, 4.024 services, 4.042 wage-price guideposts, 4.059 Productivity measures (see also Productivity measures, foreign countries), 2.015, 2.063, 2.064, 2.071,2.080, 2.081, 2.082, 2.092, 2.102, 2.110, 2.113 air transportation, 2.036, 2.038, 2.101 aluminum, 2.024, 2.073 ' coal, 2.078, 2.106 concrete products, 2.065 construction, 2.006, 2.027 college housing, 2.084,2.085 highways, 2.007 hospitals and nursing homes, 2.009, 2.097 schools, 2.096 sewer works, 2.008 single-family homes, 2.011,2.045 corrugated and solid fiber boxes, 2.040, 2.042 dairy farming, 2.010, 2.089 education, 2.114 farm, 2.004, 2.005, 2.034, 2.056, 2.057, 2.107 food, 2.049 distribution, 2.051,2.052, 2.112 processing, 2.025, 2.098 footwear, 2.086, 2.087 foundries (see also gray iron foundries, this section), 2.014 gas and electric utilities, 2.037 government, 2.026, 2.055, 2.072 gray iron foundries, 2.019, 2.022 hosiery, 2.017 hospitals, 2.070 household appliances* 2.059, 2.095 international comparisons (see also specific industry, this section), 2.079, 2.104, 2.108 iron and steel, 2.068, 2.105 man-made fibers, 2.099 manufacturing, 2.111,2.115 motor vehicles and equipment, 2.067, 2.088, 2.094 petroleum, 2.015 petroleum pipelines, 2.043 poultry processing, 2.023 radio and television sets, 2.058,2.060 railroads, 2.062, 2.074 retail trade, 2.053, 2.054, 2.075 Price stability, 4.008, 4.009, 4.021,4.080 Canada, 4.013 international comparisons, 4.024 Printing and publishing, 3.108, 3.114, 3.120 Production function, 1.001,1.010, 1.075 capital, 1.046,1.071,1.094 company productivity, 1.063 economic growth, 6.028, 6.048, 6.059, 6.062 farm, 1.022, 1.050, 1.100 international comparisons, 4.048 manufacturing, 1.049,1.060, 1.118 research and development, 3.248 technological change, 1.005, 1.011, 1.029, 1.033, 3.103,3.113,3.123,3.158 transportation, 1.016 Production indexes, 1.023, 1.078 Production scheduling, 1.004 Productivity bargaining, 4.068 international comparisons, 4.054 longshore industry, 4,033, 4.034 United Kingdom, 4.006, 4.017, 4.020, 4.026, 4.027, 4.029,4.032, 4.039, 4.052,4.064, 4.069,4.070,4.071,4.074,4.075 Productivity improvement programs. See Improvement programs Productivity measurement capital productivity, 1.012,1.096 construction, 2.027 farm, 1.072,1.104,1.117 government. 1.066,1.112, 1.113 international comparisons, 1.085,1.088,2.104 Israel, 1.033 104 international comparisons, 3.177, 3.205, 3.270 selected industries, 2.003, 2.041, 2.050, 2.061, 2.109 service industries, 2.016, 2.047, 2.048 soft drinks, 2.001 steel (see also iron and steel, this section), 2.020, 2.021,2.069 sugar, 2.044 Service industries, 1.031, 1.032, 2.047, 2.048,4.042, 5.029 Shipbuilding, 3.036 Shipping, 3.099, 3.154, 3.212, 3.213, 5.010, 5.012, 5.031 Productivity measures, foreign countries Australia, 2.035 Canada, 2.004, 2.005, 2.018, 2.028, 2.029, 2 030 Colombia, 2.090 developing countries, 2.100 Europe, 2.031, 2.032, 2.033,2.039,2.077,2.091, 2.103 India, 2.093 Ireland, 2.045 Philippines, 2.002 United Kingdom, 2.076, 2.083,2.114 USSR, 2.013 Skill levels. See Occupational structure Soft drinks, 2.001 Sources of growth (see also Capital productivity; Labor productivity; Technological change; Organizational factors; and Research and development), 1.025, 1.056, 1.065,1.089,2.015,3.173,6.058,6.060 capital, 1.043, 1.073 economic growth, 6.016 Europe, 2.032, 2.033, 2.039 farm, 1.090 international comparisons, 6.054, 6.055 mining, 1.099 New Zealand, 6.010 Puerto Rico, 4.062 shipping, 3.099 USSR, 1.011,1.109 Profits, 4.035,4.076, 4.082 Projections, 1.062, 1.064, 6.001, 6.002, 6.003, 6.004, 6.006, 6.019, 6.048, 6.064, 6.065 Puerto Rico, 4.062 South Africa, 1.118 Quality of life, 1.106, 3.144, 4.080, 5.058, 5.070, 6.017,6.066 Steel (see also Iron and steel), 2.020, 2.021, 2.069, 3.246, 5.076 Radio and television sets, 2.058, 2.060 Sugar, 2.044, 5.020 Railroads economic growth, 6.021 invention and innovation, 3.245 productivity measures, 2.062, 2.074 technological change, 5.014, 5.016, 5.049, 5.076 Sweden, 3.077 Syria, 6.045 Technological change (see also Technological change, by industry), 3.116, 3.117, 3.118, 3.141,3.162, 3.167, 3.172, 3.173, 3.181, 3.184, 3.186, 3.207, 4.079, 5.009,5.059,5.082 capital productivity, 1.006, 1.020, 1.042, 1.053, 1.055, 1.120 consumption, 3.156 diffusion, 2.002, 3.197, 3.225,3.227, 3.228, 3.235,3.239,3.246,3.247 earnings, 4.031 economic growth, 6.020, 6.021, 6.025, 6.028, 6.029,6.067,6.068 economic variables, 3.133, 3.136, 3.142, 3.144, 3.145, 3.149, 3.150, 3.199, 3.209, 3.211, 3.216 economies of scale, 3.126, 3.214 education, 3.027, 3.031, 3.037, 3.062, 5.057, 5.063,5.077,5.088 Research and development (see also Invention and innovation), 3.221,3.224, 3.229, 3.257 China, 3.271 economic growth, 3.243, 3.267, 3.269 government-financed, 3.127, 3.190 measurement, 3.244, 3.248, 3.249, 3.258 technological change, 3.172, 3.195, 3.205 Retail trade, 1.036, 2.053, 2.054, 2.075 Savings and loan associations, 3.071 Scientific instruments, 3.176 Science and technology (see also Technology transfer), 3.119,3.167,3.171,3.254,3.266 105 employment, 5.006, 5.011, 5.017, 5.033, 5.034, 5.038, 5.052, 5.053, 5.054, 5.055, 5.065, 5.073, 5.075, 5.079, 5.080, 5.084, 5.085, 5.088 international comparisons, 5.040, 5.041, 5.045, 5.061,5.078 improvement programs, 3.078 income shares, 4.031 international comparisons, 3.125, 3.171,3.176, 3.178,3.182,3.196 international trade, 3.210 labor utilization, 3.218 manpower adjustment programs, 5.004, 5.027, 5.035, 5.048, 5.052, 5.056, 5.060, 5.062, 5.064,5.072,5.081 international comparisons, 5.007, 5.013, 5.015,5.028,5.056,5.087 manpower requirements, 3.194 measurement, 1.019, 3.130, 3.134, 3.152, 3.157, 3.159 occupational structure, 3.121,5.042, 5.089 organizational factors, 3.086 production function, 3.103,3.113, 3.123 quality of life, 5.058, 5.070 research and development, 3.172, 3.195,3.205 social variables, 3.105, 3.110, 3.111,3.112,3.122, 3.132, 3.133, 3.140, 3.143, 3.144, 3.145, 3.149, 3.150, 3.166, 3.169, 3.170, 3.201, 3.209,3.216 Technological change, by industry aircraft, 3.180 chemicals, 5.044 coal, 3.200 communications, 3.115, 3.124 computers, 3.101,3.106, 5.002, 5.036, 5.069 construction, 3.215 electricity, 3.115 electronic components, 3.188 farm, 3.131, 3.135, 3.138, 3.152, 3.155, 3.187, 3.198, 3.217, 3.218, 5.008, 5.018, 6.057 footwear, 3.039 gas and electric utilities, 5.066, 5.067 gray iron foundries, 5.002 government, 5.068 health services, 3.192, 3.193 insurance, 5.023, 5.024 iron and steel, 3.027, 3.137, 3.165 lead and zinc, 3.206 leather, 5.039 libraries, 3.164 machine tools, 3.100, 3.160, 3.161 manufacturing, 1.029,3.158 mining, 3.202 motor vehicles, 5.005 nonelectrical machinery, 3.174 printing and publishing, 3.108,3.114, 3.120 railroads, 5.014, 5.016, 5.049, 5.076 shipping, 3.154, 3.212, 3.213, 5.010, 5.012, 5.031 steel, 5.076 sugar, 5.020 telephones, 5.025, 5.026, 5.076 textiles, 3.219, 3.220, 5.043, 5.076 transportation, 1.016,3.115 Technological forecasting, 3.102, 3.104, 3.109, 3.128, 3.147,3.148,3.175,3.183 Technological innovation. See Invention and innovation Technological invention. See Invention and innovation Technology transfer (see also Technology transfer, foreign countries), 3.119, 3.127, 3.146, 3.185, 3.190, 3.197,3.208 Technology transfer, foreign countries Asia, 3.203, 3.204 developing countries, 3.107, 3.151, 3.163, 3.168, 3.179,3.189,3.191 Japan, 3.083,3.089 Telephones, 5.025, 5.026, 5.076 Textiles invention and innovation, 3.228, 3.247 productivity measures, 2.015 technological change, 3.219, 3.220, 5.043, 5.076 technology transfer, 3.146 Thailand, 1.117 Total factor productivity (see also Total factor produc tivity, foreign countries), 1.013, 1.025,1.028,1.056, 1.057,1.089,1.106,1.110,1.119 company productivity, 1.058, 1.092,1.107 elasticity of substitution, 1.091 farm, 1.022 input-output studies, 1.111 measurement, 1.007, 1.018, 1.028, 1.037, 1.080, 1.085,1.097,4.060 production function, 1.001,1.010,1.075 technological change, 1.005,1.019 Total factor productivity, foreign countries Canada, 6.035 developing countries, 1.014,1.041 India, 1.098,1.102,1.124 Israel, 1.033 Latin America, 6.012 USSR, 6.036 Trade, 1.048 Trade unions, 3.110, 5.051 106 INTERESTED in keeping current on employment, wages, prices, and productivity? SEE AD ON THE FOLLOWING PAGE! Keeping current on employment, with periodicals from BLS wages, prices, and productivity OQQ EMPLOYMENT a m d EARNINGS Monthly Labor Review — Employment and Earnings Current Wage Developments —a the oldest and most authoritative Government research journal in economics and the social sciences. Regularly features a review of developments in industrial relations, significant court decisions in labor cases, book reviews, and current labor statistics. $9.00 a year; $11.25 foreign; single copy, 75 cents. Occupational Outlook Quarterly —a today —a monthly statistical series of the labor force, employment, unemployment, hours, earnings, labor turnover, and job vacancies. Current data for the United States as a whole, for individual States, and for more than 200 local areas on employment, hours, earnings, and labor turnover. $10.00 a year; $12.50 foreign; single copy, $1.00. ^ monthly report on employee compensation, including: Wage and benefit changes resulting from collective bargaining settlements and unilateral management decisions; statistical summaries; and special reports on wage trends. $4.50 a year; $5.75 foreign; single copy, 45 cents. magazine which gives up-to-the-minute details on tomorrow's jobs. Current information on employment trends and outlook to supplement and bring up to date information in the Occupational O u tlo ok Handbook. $1.50 for four issues during the school year; $2.00 foreign; single copy, 45 cents. SUBSCRIPTION ORDER FORM ENTER MY SUBSCRIPTION TO THE PERIODICALS CHECKED BELOW @ $........................Add $..............................for foreign mailing. No additional postage is required for mailing within the United States, its possessions, Canada, Mexico, and all Central and South American Countries except Argentina, Brazil, British Hon duras, French Guiana, Guyana, and Surinam. For shipment to all other foreign countries include additional postage as quoted for each periodical or subscription service. Send Subscription to: □ 'I Monthly Labor Review' □ 2 Current Wage Developments □ 3 Employment and Earnings COMPANY NAME OR ADDITIONAL ADDRESS LINE STREET ADDRESS i i i i m i i i i i i i i i i CITY I II II II II I M II I PLEASE PRINT OR TYPE | 4 Occupational Outlook Quarterly □ Remittance Enclosed (Make checks payable to Superintendent of Docu ments) □ Charge to my Deposit Account No........................ NAME — FIRST, LAST m □ II II I I I STATE ZIP CODE I INI- MAIL ORDER FORM TO: BLS Regional Offices (Listed on facing page) or Superintendent of Documents Government Printing Office Washington, D.C. 20402 technological change, 3.165, 5.015, 5.016, 5.076 Transportation, 1.016,3.115 USSR Unions, See Trade unions capital, 1.121 economic growth, 6.006, 6.009, 6.027, 6.036 labor productivity, 1.038 labor utilization, 3.030, 3.038, 3.054, 5.030 productivity measures, 2.013 research and development, 3.258 sources of growth, 1.011,1.109 technological change, 3.211,5.042 United Kingdom capacity utilization, 1.009, 1.019,1.084 capital, 1.027 capital productivity, 1.036,1.084 costs, guideposts, 4.025,4.028,4.072 earnings, 4.036 economic growth, 3.129, 6.008 education, 2.114 improvement programs, 3.075 invention and innovation, 3.268 iron and steel, 3.027, 3.165 labor productivity, 1.015,1.045, 1.051 organizational factors, 3.097 productivity bargaining, 4.006, 4.017, 4.020, 4.026, 4.027, 4.029, 4.032, 4.039, 4.052, 4.064, 4.069,4.070,4.071,4.074,4.075 productivity measures, 2.076, 2.083, 2.114 Wages. See Earnings; Costs Wage-price guideposts, 4.007, 4.012, 4.019, 4.021, 4.060,4.067,4.077,4.078 employment, 5.074 international comparisons, 4.063 manufacturing, 4.059 measurement, 4.044 United Kingdom, 4.025,4.028,4.065,4.072 107 B U R E A U O F L A B O R S T A T IS T IC S R E G IO N A L O F F IC E S Region I 1603 JFK Federal Building Government Center Boston, Mass. 02203 Phone: 223-6762 (Area Code 617) Region V 8th Floor, 300 South Wacker Drive Chicago, III. 60606 Phone: 353-1880 (Area Code 312) Region II 1515 Broadway New York, N.Y. 10036 Phone: 971-5405 (Area Code 212) Region VI 1100 Commerce St., Rm. 6B7 Dallas, Tex. 75202 Phone: 749*3516 (Area Code 214) Region III P. O. Box 13309 Philadelphia, Pa. 19101 Phone: 597-1154 (Area Code 215) Regions V II and V III * Federal Office Building 911 Walnut St., 15th Floor Kansas City, Mo. 64106 Phone: 374-2481 (Area Code 816) Region IV Suite 540 1371 Peachtree St., NE. Atlanta, Ga. 30309 Phone: 526-5418 (Area Code 404) Regions IX and X * * 450 Golden Gate Ave. Box 36017 San Francisco, Calif. 94102 Phone: 556-4678 (Area Code 415) Regions V II and V III are serviced by Kansas City. Regions IX and X are serviced by San Francisco. U.S. DEPARTMENT OF LABOR BUREAU OF LABOR STA TISTIC S WASHINGTON, O. C. 20212 T H IR D CLASS M A IL POSTAGE AND FEES PAID U,S. D EP A R TM E N T OF LABOR OFFICIAL BUSINESS PE N A LTY FOR P R IV A TE USE, $300 LAB • 441