The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
Treas. HJ 10 .A13P4 v. 213 U. S. Dept. of the Treasury, Press releases.! LIBRARY 3IQR? p" r"\!*s *\ P O G M 5v> > TREASURY DEPARTMENT partmentoftheTREASURY ;HINGTON,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR RELEASE - ON•DELIVERY Expected at 11:30 a.m. Monday, April 3, 1978 STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE ROGER C. ALTMAN, ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR DOMESTIC FINANCE BEFORE THE HOUSE BUDGET COMMITTEE Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: I am pleased to appear today to discuss with you certain of the President's urban policy initiatives. The Administration has worked hard this past year to analyze social, economic and fiscal conditions in American cities, the effectiveness of existing Federal policies and programs aimed at cities, and, then, to determine the need for new program initiatives. The culmination of this process was announced by the President last Monday. His urban policy proposals are worthy of your support, and we join with the other Departments in urging you to include the related funding in the First Concurrent Budget Resolution. The President's message presented the conceptual framework of his urban policy. Over this next month we will be drafting legislation on the various program initiatives in consultation with the Congress. So today I will not describe the specific details of initiatives, but I will address the general thrust of three components of the President's urban policy proposal: the National Development Bank, Supplementary Fiscal Assistance and the tax proposals — the industrial revenue bonds, the differential investment tax credit and the employment tax credit. These initiatives address the following principles of the President's urban policy: o Involving all levels of government and the private sector. o Leveraging significant private sector resources. o Increasing access to opportunities for disadvantaged people. o Providing flexibility to respond to diverse needs of all cities and communities while recognizing that certain localities will require strategic targeting of resources. - 2 The National Development Bank It is clear to us that a crucial cause of urban decay has been the decline of the private sector employment base in central cities. This has resulted in a smaller tax base and higher fiscal strain for city governments. While fiscal and monetary policies are effective instruments for improving the overall level of economic activity, we have learned that they are not precise enough tools to address the interrelated problems of slow growth, chronic economic decline, and the resulting high levels of unemployment among certain groups in many of our cities. We believe, therefore, that new Federal incentives for the private sector to expand job opportunities in distressed areas should be undertaken. The National Development Bank represents a long-range economic development strategy to rebuild the private economies of distressed areas. Its key objective is to help create permanent jobs. This strategy includes a set of financing incentives to influence businesses to remain and expand or to locate in distressed areas. The effect of these incentives would be to improve business and job opportunities by lowering one element of the costs of doing business — the cost of capital. The package of incentives includes: 1) A program of "up-front" capital grants involving up to 15% (or a maximum of $3 million) of an eligible firm's capital costs for rehabilitation or fixed asset expansion. EDA and HUD grants would be used. 2) In coordination with the grants, a program of loan guarantees to cover 75% of the remaining capital costs at interest rates representing a slight premium above Treasury rates. In special circumstances the Bank could subsidize the interest rate down to 2.5%. The business or project could only receive this package of a grant and loan guarantee if it obtained the balance of its needed financing from private sources. 3) An increase in the limit from $5 to $20 million of tax-exempt or taxable industrial revenue bonds that can be issued in an economically distressed area. - 3 4) A new secondary market for a) private loans made directly to eligible small- and medium-sized businesses to finance capital expenditures; and (b) the private loans made to businesses receiving federal financing assistance through the Development Bank. A "private market test" will place the initial credit decision not in the Federal bureaucracy, but in the private market. This test will differentiate between economically viable projects which can provide permanent private sector jobs and those which will fail. It will also help ensure that the Bank will be financially self-sustaining. Hence, we think that the Bank can leverage significant private sector investment in distressed areas with relatively small Federal exposure. Successful local economic development requires public and private cooperation and careful planning at the local level. We have designed this Development Bank as a catalyst for promoting public and private sector cooperation in distressed areas and one which will leave maximum flexibility for economic development planning at the local level. This proposed Development Bank, Mr. Chairman, is the result of an intense analysis of current Federal economic development programs and a series of consultations with Mayors, Governors, academicians, economic development practitioners, and representatives of the business, labor and financial communities. It will not duplicate existing federal programs, but, rather, fill a gap among federal tools aimed at local economic development. Specifically, there is no major Federal program involving truly long term financing incentives to affect business locational decisions. Mr. Chairman, our combination of long term financing incentives are strong enough to influence locational decisions. They can reduce long term business borrowing costs significantly and impact job creation. Local practitioners have confirmed that it is a proposal which can be combined with other resources to seriously attack the continuing losses of private investment and jobs. A crucial question in considering this proposal, of • course, is why the Federal Goverment should influence locational decisions at all. We think that the answer is clear. For years, through a variety of programs, the - 4 Federal Government has directly and indirectly encouraged certain developmental patterns. It is only logical that rebuilding distressed areas must be an object of Federal policy. The costs of doing nothing are too high — they include the tremendous human suffering and capital waste of permitting these areas to continue to decline. They include increased costs for welfare, health and unemployment compensation for the unemployed — those who cannot move to find new jobs in growing areas. They include the inefficient use of scarce national economic resources which flow into new areas to build new private facilities and public infrastructure while the old and valuable infrastructures are underutilized. Supplementary Fiscal Assistance Program Let me turn now to discuss the fiscal relief component of President Carter's urban policy — our proposed Supplementary Fiscal Assistance Program. This would replace the expiring Anti-recession Fiscal Assistance Program (frequently called countercyclical revenue sharing), and would use the $1.04 billion already contained in the President's fiscal 1979 budget for the countercyclical program. The new program, Mr. Chairman, would provide relief to local governments experiencing fiscal strain because of underlying and long term economic decline. We are recommending it because there are a series of local governments which cannot withstand the impact of losing their current countercyclical funds. These are not governments, however, which are experiencing temporary recession-induced fiscal strain. Instead, their fiscal difficulties reflect shrinking urban revenue bases caused by the long-terra out-migration of taxpayers, investment and jobs or by underdevelopment. During the past year, the Treasury Department studied carefully the fiscal conditions of our largest municipalities. Indeed, as part of this effort, some of you may be familiar with a report we made available to Congress concerning the fiscal impact on these municipalities of President Carter's 1977 Economic Stimulus Program. In that report, we developed an index of "municipal fiscal strain" and ranked the 48 largest municipal governments according to that index. It became clear to us that certain local governments are experiencing considerable fiscal strain. Their revenues are stagnant, and the combination of inflation, high local unemployment and high concentrations of low income persons are - 5 exerting upward pressure on their expenditures. The loss of countercyclical funds would require these "high strain" localities to implement severe fiscal austerity programs, which would have highly negative effects on the provision of municipal services to their citizens. These high strain localities are precisely those who are least able to afford the loss of monies available under the current countercyclical programs. Many simply would be unable to balance their budgets without it. Their only choices would be to cut expenditures or raise taxes by the amounts of countercyclical funds lost. Yet, in these areas, taxes already are at high levels and raising them further would be counterproductive to economic redevelopment. Concerning service reductions, many of the largest cities would be forced to cut services, such as police and fire, which are vitally needed. In addition, they are already experiencing high unemployment levels, and further layoffs could only worsen their economic plight. Tax Proposals Industrial Development Bonds Let me now address the three tax portions of the President's urban policy. As part of the Development Bank proposal, the President has recommended changes in the small issue exemption governing the use of tax-exempt industrial development bond (IDB) financing. Under current law, small issue IDBs can be issued on a tax-exempt basis for financing investment in depreciable property or land by private business firms. The use of such tax-exempt financing within any county is limited to the first $1 million of any project or, alternatively, to $5 million if total capital expenditures by the firm over a six-year period, beginning three years before the date of bond issue and ending three years after, do not exceed $5 million. In the tax reform program, the Administration proposed that the use of tax-exempt small issue IDBs be repealed except for distressed areas and that for such areas the $5 million limit be increased to $10 million with the capital expenditures limitation applying at this higher level. The original IDB proposal reflected the concern of this Administration that preferential tax-exempt financing be channeled to areas of most urgent need. The current proposal extends the IDB recommendations in the tax reform package. The increase of industrial development bond financing to $10 million in the tax program will - 6 be further increased to $20 million. The urban policy IDB proposals leave intact the recommendations in the tax reform program to remove tax-exempt industrial development bond financing in areas which do not qualify as distressed. Thus, while the dollar limitations are liberalized, there is still a strong commitment to limit the use of tax-exempt IDB financing to those areas of the country which are having difficulty in attracting private capital. Also these IDB's will be eligible for the Administration's taxable bond option proposed as part of the tax reform program. Under the taxable bond option, state and local governments will have the choice of issuing tax exempt or subsidized taxable bonds. The Federal subsidy on taxable bonds will be 35 percent of the taxable rate for bonds issued during the first two years and 40 percent thereafter. The urban policy IDBs may also be issued on either a tax exempt or a subsidized taxable basis. Differential - Investment'Tax-Credit In addition, the Administration is proposing, on a twoyear trial basis, a program of a differential investment tax credit for private investment (including the construction and rehabilitation of industrial buildings) for the improvement of distressed areas. These tax credits would be administered by the Commerce Department except that the income tax system would be employed as a clearing mechanism for final payment to the investor. Authority to grant the additional five percent investment credit would total $200 million for each of the next two years. To become eligible, a company would apply to the Commerce Department for a "certificate of necessity" basing its request on financing need and employment potential for the particular project in the distressed area. The certificate would be attached to a firm's tax return, thus making the firm automatically eligible for the additional five percent investment tax credit for the specified amount of the project. This program would be similar to that which was used and administered by the Defense Production Board during World War II and the Korean War. The Treasury Department would be responsible to audit the firm's net tax liability and not its eligibility for the certificate of necessity. Employment Tax-Credit The Administration proposes a targeted employment tax credit that would substitute for the new jobs tax credit in the present law that is scheduled to expire at the end of this - 7 year. A tax credit for employment is desirable because of persistent problems of structural unemployment, but the existing jobs credit addresses the unemployment problem in a very unfocused and uncertain way. That credit has been available for the employment of workers generally and only for firms whose employment is growing. The credit is uncertain in application because an employer needs to predict the rate of growth of his unemployment tax base to the end of the year in order to judge whether a credit will be allowed. In the case of slow growing industries and regions, the credit is denied to most employers simply because the demand for their products does not justify an increase of the wage base by more than two percent over the previous year. No employment incentive is provided to large employers that expect to grow by more than about 50 employees in a year. Preliminary results from a recent survey of taxpayers conducted by the Census Department for an inter-agency task force show that less than 3 percent of employers report any conscious effort to increase their employment in response to the credit. These preliminary results also suggest that at least 80 percent of the dollar amount of the credit will be received by employers who report no conscious effort to increase employment. The Administration proposal would focus the employment incentives of the tax credit on the most serious structural unemployment problem: the high incidence of unemployment among disadvantaged youth and handicapped workers. The categories of individuals who would be aided under this proposal have a recent rate of unemployment of about 5 times that of the remaining labor force. This proposal would not discriminate against slow growing or declining firms nor against firms with rapidly expanding employment opportunities. It would, however, require that all of the benefits be targeted at a demonstrated special problem area of unemployment. As compared with the present jobs credit, this proposal would provide a larger dollar amount of incentive to employ each worker over a two-year period, but at less than one-half of the total revenue cost of the present program in a typical year. According to the Administration proposal, a tax credit would be allowed to employers of eligible handicapped and disadvantaged individuals for two full years. The major identifiable source of structural unemployment is minority and disadvantaged youth. Most other groups within the labor market do not suffer from pervasive structural - 8 unemployment. There are approximately 2.3 million young Americans between the ages of 18 and 24 who live in low income households. The recent unemployment rate among this group is 26 percent; and this does not count the large number of such persons who wish to work full time but can find only part time work or who have not been seeking work because they believe it is futile. This program will provide strong incentives for employers to offer employment opportunities to those disadvantaged young people who have found it most difficult to gain the important experience of working in the private sector. Because the tax credit is continued for up to two years for each employee, there is an incentive for employers to retain these employees long enough for them to gain sufficient work experience and training to become a part of the regular workforce. Therefore, this program will provide the necessary extra help to bring into our country's workforce many young persons from low income backgrounds, who might otherwise be denied entrance into the regular private job market. I appreciate this opportunity today to present the broad outlines of some of the urban initiatives. We look forward to working with you and the other members of Congress to achieve the President's urban policy goals. oOo FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY April 5, 1978 10:30 a.m. STATEMENT BY THE HONORABLE RICHARD J. DAVIS ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR ENFORCEMENT AND OPERATIONS AT THE THIRD SOUTHWESTERN STATES CONFERENCE ON CRIME AND THE BORDER ALBUQUERQUE, NEW MEXICO It is a pleasure to be here with you along the Southwest border - a part of our country appropriately known for its dynamism and the strength and diversity of its people. Like other regions in our country, however, it is also confronted with a series of complicated, and difficult problems. Some of these problems are properly viewed as being essentially social and economic in nature: the issues raised by the presence of undocumented aliens largely fall in this category. Others, however, are more clearly of an enforcement nature. These include the smuggling of narcotics, firearms and other commodities across the Mexican/United States border. In the several days of this conference it is this latter group of problems—and particularly narcotics smuggling—which are the focus of attention. My purpose here today is to share with you our view that meeting the enormous challenges raised by these problems requires a unity of effort involving all of us--the states, the Federal B-810 - 2 « government, and our neighbor, Mexico. I would like to discuss with you some of the obstacles I have observed to effective cooperation during my experiences as a Federal prosecutor, and now as a Treasury Department official. By identifying these obstacles, hopefully we can avoid them. Finally, I would like briefly to share with you proposals recently made in the firearms area which could assist state and local governments in their struggle against violent crime, and in which you may have an interest. This conference, with its broad base of state and federal agency representation and with representatives from our good neighbor, Mexico, represents an admirable recognition of certain truisms in the world of law enforcement which are often ignored: that crime knows no boundaries—those violating our laws do not respect particular state, city or even international borders, but instead carry out their activities wherever they see financial gain; that criminals do not conform their conduct to how we write our criminal laws and divide up our responsibilities—criminals commit their acts for gain and usually not with specific regard to whether the laws they break are enforced by state authorities, the FBI, DEA, Customs, ATF, or the Albuquerque Police Department; that a single series of acts might involve violations of laws enforced by all of us; and the final truism, that crime— particularly the kind of crime involved here--is too big to be challenged by a single agency or a single level of government standing alone. - 3 These truisms operate everywhere in varying degrees, but no where are they clearer than along the Southwest border. We share 2,000 miles of border with Mexico. And through the twenty-four ports of entry along that border some 5 million vehicles and 170 million persons enter the United States on an annual basis. In addition, millions of people and a huge volume of air cargo arrive annually through our international airports in this area. Given these facts it is not surprising that we are confronted with a major problem of narcotics smuggling across the border into the Southwest, and beyond the border into the rest of the United States; and a problem of smuggling of commodities— both otherwise licit and illicit—in both directions across the border. And to meet this problem the total combined DEA, INS, Customs, and ATF presence along the border, including administrative personnel, is only approximately 5,700 people. Faced with these problems, and the reality of our own limitations, we all, I believe, should accept another basic truism--that we must pool our efforts and work together if we are to have any impact at all on the enforcement problems with which we are all concerned. But while this need is clear, it is not always simple to implement. As a federal prosecutor in New York, as well as in my current position in the Treasury Department, I have had first hand experience in the interaction of - 4 federal agencies with each other, and with state agencies. While cooperation was always the official byword, I am sad to report it was not always a reality. The first pitfall which I have sometimes observed accompanying joint investigative efforts is destructive competition. Now I have used the word "destructive". Competition is not always bad: to some degree it is the engine for greater efforts. And by saying that such competition is a pitfall, I do not mean to suggest that it is maliciously motivated. Competition is largely motivated by a desire to receive credit for success. And being able to point to success will often determine whether we receive the budgetary resources we believe we need. Similarly, the publicizing of one's accomplishments is a valid way to secure necessary public support and attract potentially valuable information. It is precisely because of this fact—that competition has a rational starting point—that it can become so dangerous. It can lead to rival, not joint investigations, duplication of efforts, withholding of witnesses and information and, on some occasions, open confrontation. Such competition is not only destructive of our efforts, but it ultimately causes the loss of public support we so desperately need. By always being conscious of these risks, I hope, and believe, that we can avoid this pitfall. - 5 A second pitfall I have observed is distrust. When I was in the U. S. Attorney's Office in New York, it was not uncommon for me to hear the refrain—you cannot trust the "locals." And at that time there was some support for this concern. In some parts of the Police Department there was a serious corruption problem which was being confronted by the then Commissioner of Police. One area of corruption was narcotics and the reasons are clear. When an officer finds hundreds of thousands of dollars and large amounts of heroin that can be readily sold, he is faced with a real temptation which is not always avoided. The problem—and potential—for corruption is not, however, governed by which side of the federal systems one works on. Rather, it exists for federal as well as state agencies. I know that this topic is not a pleasant one, but if we are to avoid distrusting each other, we must articulate this problem and deal with it by supporting the need for strong anticorruption units in all our agencies. On the other hand, and equally as important, we must not allow paranoic distrust to overwhelm our common sense. Only in this way—particularly where narcotics is involved—can we remove the obstacle of distrust from the desirable goal of cooperation. - 6 Another pitfall I would like to raise derives from the inevitable disagreements which come in any joint investigation. Rarely in the real world is there one tactic or one strategy which is perfect to the exclusion of all others. Nevertheless, I have observed an "only we can be right" attitude in various investigations, particularly on the part of federal agencies. The result is that disagreements over tactics reach such levels that they lead ultimately to the disruption of the entire investigative effort. By realizing that good faith and differences of opinion can exist, however, we will be able to compromise on differences and avoid these consequences. A recognition of a need for mutual interdependence and of the dangers of destructive competition, distrust and failure to compromise are essential elements in the program of statelocal-federal-international cooperation which is so necessary. That is true everywhere; it is particularly important here along the border. The Federal government, however, should be doing more than simply working with your investigations. It should design programs which use its resources to enhance state and local enforcement efforts and to do things you cannot do alone, because activities in other jurisdictions are contributing to the problems you face. - 7 I would like to take a few minutes to describe some proposals which we have made which would do exactly this. Now these proposals, which are in a series of proposed regulations, are in the firearms area. I have been told that this is not the part of the country where one should talk about gun control. But violent crime is not a sectional problem—it exists everywhere, including in New Mexico, Arizona, Texas, and California. According to the FBI Uniform Crime Report for 1976, in these four states alone a total of 204,963 violent crimes were reported to the police. A high percentage of these crimes— particularly homicides, robberies, and aggravated assaults— involved the use of firearms. And the recently released preliminary 1977 figures show that the volume of these crimes has continued to increase in the South and West. In addition, during the period 1972 to 1976, 622 police officers were killed in the United States in the line of duty. Over ninety-five of these were from these four states. And in eighty-five percent of these cases the officers killed were slain with firearms. The problem of firearms abuse thus is, unfortunately, with us all. These proposed regulations seek to help meet that problem. If implemented, they will provide ATF better ability to trace firearms actually used in crime, and to identify possible sources of firearms into the hands of criminals where they can cause so much destruction. - 8 What do these proposals do? The regulations require all firearms to have a unique serial number. While all now have some number, duplication and the presence of more than one number on a firearm have led to confusion for police and frustrated some efforts to trace weapons used in crimes. The regulations require the reporting to ATF of all commercial transactions in firearms. The manufacturers and importers must report what they make and import and to which wholesalers, jobbers or dealers they sell which firearms; wholesalers, jobbers and retailers must similarly report their dispositions of firearms, unless they sell them directly to a private individual. As you know, all this information is now required to be kept on the premises of the individual licensees—these regulations only bring it to one place where it can be effectively used. The regulations require that all licesees report thefts of firearms. Twenty percent of firearms used in crimes are stolen: this proposal gives us a formal program to learn where they were stolen from, so that we can take steps to act on this problem. What do these proposals not do? They do not require private individuals to do anything. They do not require the names of private individual purchasers to be reported-when a sale is made to such a person - 9 the fact that the weapon was sold is reported, the name and address is not. That, as now, would be retained in the files of the dealer. They do not create any form of registration or permit system. How will these proposals help you, at the state and local level, as well as us? First, an important thing they would do is to enhance greatly our ability to trace firearms used in crime and found at crime scenes or elsewhere. This would provide law enforcement officials—state, local, and federal—with important possible leads. Now to conduct a trace ATF must call everyone in the chain of distribution to get the name of the first retail purchaser. That takes time—hours in an emergency, but days, a week or longer in routine cases. Also, recent studies have shown that large numbers of all traces are incomplete because someone in the chain has lost, miskept, or destroyed required records. The consequence of all this is that now ATF must limit the number of traces it can perform to 5,000 a month. If these proposals were fully implemented, ATF could conduct virtually an unlimited number of traces in hours, because only a call to the last retailer would be necessary. - 10 These regulations will also give us a greater ability to target our investigative resources towards those who are abusing the system and providing an outlet of weapons for illegal use. Now, identifying those parts of the country which are sources of firearms being illegally transported to other states, requires numerous agents pursuing large numbers of investigative leads. The problem of identifying specific dealers selling guns into the illegal market is even more difficult. The information derived from these regulations, however, would enable us to identify those localities, and with proper analysis, those dealers receiving unusually large numbers of firearms and who, therefore, might be involved in diverting weapons into the criminal market. We could then target our investigative resources towards these places and dealers. This way we can bother the clearly legitimate dealer less, and accomplish more with our existing resources. In sum, as I said, these proposed regulations are designed not to burden our individual citizens, but to help fight violent crime and those who are supplying guns for use in those crimes. I hope that over the next forty-five days you will all feel free to send your comments to us on these proposals. - 11 The responsibilities we all face are great: the task of enforcing our laws is enormously difficult. Conferences like this can help us all meet this challenge and I appreciate the opportunity you have given me to be here with you today. We at Treasury look forward to working with you in the future. I, or my office can assist you, I hope you will feel free to contact us. 0O0 If DepartmenlofthtTREASURY WASHINGTON, D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 April 3, 1978 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE RESULTS OF TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL AUCTIONS Tenders for $2,301 million of 13-week Treasury bills and for $3,401 million of 26-week Treasury bills, both series to be issued on April 6, 1978, were accepted at the Federal Reserve Banks and Treasury today. The details are as follows: RANGE OF ACCEPTED COMPETITIVE BIDS: High Low Average 13-week bills maturing J u l y 6> 26-week bills maturing October 5, 1978 1978 Price Discount Rate Investment Rate 1/ Price 98.382 98.377 98.378 6.401% 6.421% 6.417% 6.60% 6.62% 6.61% 96.610 96.601 96.604 Discount Rate 6.705% 6.723% 6.717% Investment Rate 1/ 7. 7. 7.05% Tenders at the low price for the 13-week bills were allotted 84%. Tenders at the low price for the 26-week bills were allotted 6%. TOTAL TENDERS RECEIVED AND ACCEPTED BY FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTSAND TREASURY: Location Received Boston $ 24,470,000 New York 3,934,705,000 24,115,000 Philadelphia 34,870,000 Cleveland 42,600,000 Richmond 37,020,000 Atlanta 342,840,000 Chicago 43,450,000 St. Louis 28,870,000 Minneapolis 28,755,000 Kansas City 19,615,000 Dallas 299,795,000 San Francisco Treasury TOTALS 6,325,000 $4,867,430,000 Accepted $ :: Received 39,390,000 19,470,000 J 1. 996,000,000 \\ 5,534,980,000 8,645,000 24,060,000 : 56,725,000 34,495,000 : 52,965,000 20,965,000 : 24,750,000 30,910,000 : 252,690,000 53,860,000 : 42,125,000 15,450,000 : 31,605,000 12,870,000 : 28,415,000 : 18,075,000 10,030,000 16,615,000 : 41,270,000 j 370,495,000 • $ 6,325,000 j $ 8,130,000 3,189,180,000 7,645,000 31,725,000 13,405,000 24,690,000 40,190,000 14,125,000 12,605,000 15,705,000 9,030,000 26,095,000 8,800,000 8,800,000 $2, 300,705,000 aj^$6 ,451,275,000 $3,401,325,000 a/Includes $384,755,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. b/Includes $186,850,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. ^/Equivalent coupon-issue yield. B-811 Accepted FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY STATEMENT OF PAUL H. TAYLOR DEPUTY FISCAL ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON DOMESTIC MONETARY POLICY OF THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS WEDNESDAY, APRIL 5, 1978, 8:15 A.M. Mr. Chairman and Members of the Subcommittee: I am pleased to appear in support of proposed legislation to extend until April 30, 1979 the authority of Federal Reserve Banks to purchase directly from the Treasury up to $5 billion of public debt obligations. Under current legislation, Public Law 95-154, approved November 7, 1977, the authority will expire at the end of this month. The authority has existed since 1942, and has usually been extended for two-year periods, although there have been some lapses in recent years. In January 1977, the Department submitted proposed legislation to the Congress to extend the direct-purchase option to October 31, 1981. I understand, however, that prior to taking up that measure the Subcommittee desires to hold oversight hearings on Treasury debt management B-812 - 2 policies, and that the one-year extension you are now considering would merely provide interim authority. The primary purpose of the authority is as a backstop for Treasury cash and debt operations, permitting more economical management of our cash reserves and allowing us to carry lower than normal balances in our checking accounts at the Federal Reserve Banks when the need arises. The purchase option has been used sparingly. However, it's value does not rest on its frequency or the extensiveness of its use, but its availability as a backstop for Treasury cash operations, permitting more economical management of our cash position and assuring our ability to provide needed funds almost instantaneously in the event of any kind of emergency. During normal conditions, the Treasury has wholly adequate recourse to short-term funds through our weekly Treasury bill auctions or the short-term cash management bills which can provide funds to the Treasury in as few as three days. From the close of calendar year 1975 to the present, we have made only a single use of the option, and that use was - 3 limited to a $2.5 billion draw to maintain a maximum cash balance just prior to expiration of the legislation establishing the temporary ceiling on the public debt in the fall of 1977. In the more distant past, the authority was used during periods when disruptions occurred in the financial markets at the same time the Government needed to raise cash to maintain Government functions. Usually, the authority is not used for long periods, the average length being from 2 to 7 days? only twice in the past 35 years has the Treasury had to draw funds in this manner for 20 days or more at any one time. The accompanying table shows the instances of actual use. The authority is subject to the public debt limit and its use is reported in the Daily Treasury Statement, the weekly Federal Reserve Statement, and in the Federal Reserve Board's annual report to the Congress. Thus, the Department views the authority as a temporary accommodation to be used only under unusual circumstances. In that connection, it is important to emphasize that any direct recourse by the Treasury to Federal Reserve credit - 4 - under this authority is subject to the discretion and control of the Federal Reserve itself. The authority is an invaluable cash-management tool, however, and the Department urges prompt consideration of the proposed legislation to ensure that it does not expire on April 30, 1978. That concludes my prepared statement, Mr. Chairman. I will be glad to respond to any questions. oOo Attachment DIRECT BORROWING FROM FEDERAL RESERVE BANKS 1942 TO DATE Maximum Amount At Any Time (Millions) Calendar Year Days Used 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 1948 1949 19 48 none 9 none none none 2 $ 422 1,302 1950 1951 1952 1953 1954 1955 1956 1957 1958 1959 2 4 30 29 15 none none none 2 none 1960 1961 1962 1963 1964 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 none none none none none none 3 7 8 21 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 none 9 1 10 1 16 none 4 Note: Number of Separate Times Used Maximum Number Of Days Used At Any One Time 4 4 6 28 -- • _ 484 2 7 -- • -- • • -- • • 220 1 2 180 320 811 1,172 424 2 2 4 2 2 1 2 9 20 13 -- • • -- - • -- - • 207 1 2 -- - - __ 99 • -- - - -- - - -- - - -- - - -- - - 1 3 3 2 3 3 6 12 • • 610 38 485 131 1.042 1 1 3 1 4 7 1 6 1 7 — — — 169 153 596 1,102 • • 2,500 1 4 Federal Reserve direct purchase authority expired October 1, 1977, and was reinstated November 7, 1977, until April 30, 1978. Office of the March 9, 1978 Fiscal Assistant Secretary FOR RELEASE AT 4:00 P.M. April 4, 1978 TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL OFFERING The Department of the Treasury, by this public notice, invites tenders for two series of Treasury bills totaling approximately $5,700 million, to be issued April 13, 1978. This offering will not provide new cash for the Treasury as the maturing bills are outstanding in the amount of $5,713 million. The two series offered are as follows: 91-day bills (to maturity date) for approximately $2,300 million, representing an additional amount of bills dated January 12, 1978, and to mature July 13, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 S2 3 ) , originally issued in the amount of $3,404 million, the additional and original bills to be freely interchangeable. 182-day bills for approximately $3,400 million to be dated April 13, 1978, and to mature October 12, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 T7 1 ). Both series of bills will be issued for cash and in exchange for Treasury bills maturing April 13, 1978. Federal Reserve Banks, for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities, presently hold $3,013 million of the maturing bills. These accounts may exchange bills they hold for the bills now being offered at the weighted average prices of accepted competitive tenders. The bills will be issued on a discount basis under competitive and noncompetitive bidding, and at maturity their par amount will be payable without interest. Except for definitive bills in the $100,000 denomination, which will be available only to investors who are able to show that they are required by law or regulation to hold securities in physical form, both series of bills will be issued entirely in book-entry form in a minimum amount of $10,000 and in any higher $5,000 multiple, on the records either of the Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or of the Department of the Treasury. Tenders will be received at Federal Reserve Banks and Branches and at the Bureau of the Public Debt, Washington, D. C. 20226, up to 1:30 p.m., Eastern Standard time, Monday, April 10, 1978. Form PD 4632-2 (for 26-week series) or Form PD 4632-3 (for 13-week series) should be used to submit tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. / B-813 -2Each tender must be for a minimum of $10,000. Tenders over $10,000 must be in multiples of $5,000. in the case of competitive tenders the price offered must be expressed on the basis of 100, with not more than three decimals, e.g., 99.925. Fractions may not be used. Banking institutions and dealers who make primary markets in Government securities and report daily to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York their positions in and borrowings on such securities may submit tenders for account of customers, if the names of the customers and the amount for each customer are furnished. Others are only permitted to submit tenders for their own account. Payment for the full par amount of the bills applied for must accompany all tenders submitted for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. A cash adjustment will be made on all accepted tenders for the difference between the par payment submitted and the actual issue price as determined in the auction. No deposit need accompany tenders from incorporated banks and trust companies and from responsible and recognized dealers in investment securities for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or for bills issued in bearer form, where authorized. A deposit of 2 percent of the par amount of the bills applied for must accompany tenders for such bills from others, unless an express guaranty of payment by an incorporated bank or trust company accompanies the tenders. Public announcement will be made by the Department of the Treasury of the amount and price range of accepted bids. Competitive bidders will be advised of the acceptance or rejection of their tenders. The Secretary of the Treasury expressly reserves the right to accept or reject any or all tenders, in whole or in part, and the Secretary's action shall be final. Subject to these reservations, noncompetitive tenders for each issue for $500,000 or less without stated price from any one bidder will be accepted in full at the weighted average price (in three decimals) of accepted competitive bids for the respective issues. Settlement for accepted tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, and bills issued in bearer form must be made or completed at the Federal Reserve Bank or Branch or at the Bureau of the Public Debt on April 13, 1978, in cash or other immediately available funds or in Treasury bills maturing April 13, 1978. Cash adjustments will be made for differences between the par value of the maturing bills accepted in exchange and the issue price of the new bills. -3Under Sections 454(b) and 1221(5) of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954 the amount of discount at which these bills are sold is considered to accrue when the bills are sold, redeemed or otherwise disposed of, and the bills are excluded from consideration as capital assets. Accordingly, the owner of these bills (other than life insurance companies) must include in his or her Federal income tax return, as ordinary gain or loss, the difference between the price paid for the bills, whether on original issue or on subsequent purchase, and the amount actually received either upon sale or redemption at maturity during the taxable year for which the return is made. Department of the Treasury Circulars, No. 418 (current revision), Public Debt Series - Nos. 26-76 and 27-76, and this notice, prescribe the terms of these Treasury bills and govern the conditions of their issue. Copies of the circulars and tender forms may be obtained from any Federal Reserve Bank or Branch, or from the Bureau of the Public Debt. FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE EXPECTED AT 10:00 A.M. EST WEDNESDAY, APRIL 5, 1978 STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE C. FRED BERGSTEN ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON INTERNATIONAL DEVELOPMENT INSTITUTIONS AND FINANCE OF THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS The Issues Mr. Chairman, I am particularly pleased to appear before this Subcommittee today. The purpose of my testimony is to consult with you regarding the amounts and shares of U.S. participation in upcoming replenishments of the international development banks. Such formal hearings, in advance of U.S. pledges to replenishment negotiations, have never before taken place. They are one more indication of the commitment of this Administration to consult as closely as possible with the Congress before making any new pledges to these institutions. We greatly appreciate the opportunity afforded us by this Subcommittee to do so, and we stand ready to participate in similar sessions with any of B-814 _0 the other interested committees which might wish to hold them. Ultimate U.S. participation in the replenishments will of course require legislative authorization and appropriation by the Congress, but we hope to help smooth the way for that process — which will begin in calendar 1979 for the replenishments under consideration — through these hearings today. We view today's hearing as the first in a series, which will provide an opportunity for both the Congress and the Administration to look carefully at overall U.S. participation in the development banks in the course of working out the U.S. pledges to the next replenishment of each. We will seek to relate the institutions to each other, within the context of overall U.S. policy objectives. The institutions which we propose to discuss this year include the World Bank, the Inter-American Development Bank and its Fund for Special Operations, the Asian Development Fund and the African Development Fund. The time period covered extends from 1979 well into the 1980s. (The next replenishments of the capital of the Asian Development Bank, and of the International Development Association, are still further away and thus would not seem ripe for discussion' in 1978. In this first consultation, I would like to confine my comments to the replenishments of the Asian Development -3Fund (ADF) and the African Development Fund (AFDF). The discussions for replenishments of the capital and of the Fund for Special Operations of the Inter-American Development Bank, and for the general capital increase of the World Bank, are not likely to reach an advanced stage until this summer or fall. Consequently, thinking within the Administration on these increases is only at a preliminary stage and my treatment of them today will necessarily reflect this. By contrast, final pledging sessions are planned for the ADF on April 22-23 and the AFDF on April 30; we therefore need to adopt a final U.S. position on each during the course of the next few weeks. The Policy Framework Before discussing these two replenishments in detail, I would like to provide a brief framework by summarizing the background of our support for the international development banks and outlining our general recommendations on lending levels and U.S. shares. This Administration considers U.S. support of the banks as fundamental to U.S. foreign policy, as indicated by the presence with me today of the Assistant Secretaries of State for both East Asian Affairs, Mr. Richard Holbrooke, and African Affairs, Mr. Richard Moose. Over a period of several years, successive Administrations and Congresses -4have increased our reliance on the development banks. Today, these institutions are the primary source of development lending in the world. They are highly effective promoters of economic growth and social development in the less developed countries. Their staffs are highly trained, competent and experienced. They have established an outstanding record over time, not only in appraising and formulating project proposals but in fostering desirable economic policy changes in recipient countries. The banks have been effective catalysts for increasing the flow of private capital to the LDCs, and for the generation of additional official capital flows from industrial and OPEC countries. They assure good use of our development money. At the same time, the organization and operations of the banks have been highly advantageous to the United States. Through their leverage of private capital, and their system of burden-sharing among all donor countries, they enable U.S. Government budgetary outlays to be held to a minimum. For example, each dollar actually paid in by the United States to the capital of the World Bank has produced $36 in total Bank lending. In fact, about 95 percent of the support of the banks' hard loan windows lies outside the U.S. Treasury. For all windows of all the banks, taken together, the U.S. share of the -5most recent replenishments totaled just under 25 percent — the target called for in the most recent authorizing legislation which originated in this Subcommittee and was passed by the Congress in 1977. The United States also benefits from procurement arising from projects financed by the international development banks. Bank expenditures in the U.S. economy have amounted to more than $2 for every $1 that we have contributed to them in official payments throughout their history. In the 5-year period, 1972 through 1976, average annual U.S. payments were $303 million while receipts averaged $758 million — or $2.50 for every dollar paid in. More broadly, the banks have become a key element in our country's overall relationship with the less developed nations. These relationships encompass political, security, economic and humanitarian concerns. They entail important considerations affecting our trading position, access to critically needed raw material (including petroleum), large amounts of our foreign investments and the income we derive from these holdings. In summary, we have found the international development banks to be extremely effective and useful instruments for helping to meet a broad range of U.S. policy objective We firmly conclude that they merit continued U.S. support. -6- F u Lu r^e _Le nd i^ ng _bv__t h e ^Deve 1 qgmen t _Ban k s Over the past five years, the average annual growth rate in lending by the banks has been between 10 and 15 percent in real terms. This rapid growth was desirable, in bringing the banks to a central position in the global development process. It enabled them to develop the critical mass which is so important to their effective functioning. It placed them in a position where their advice will be, and must be, heeded by recipient countries. It generated economies of scale which are of great benefit to donor countries and recipient countries alike. For the future, however, the growth of development bank lending need not be as rapid. They have already established their central position and effectiveness of operation. At the same time, there is a floor on how far their growth rates should be allowed to fall. Our conclusion within the Administration is that this floor is represented by an annual growth rate in real bank lending of around five percent. Such a rate woulci permit the banks to maintain their share of support for rates of growth which are needed in the developing countries. It would enable them to finance orojects directly meeting basic human needs as well as orojects more oriented towards economic growth oer se. It would provide some degree of insurance, particularly -7for uoper and middle income recipient countries, against the possibility of decreasing private capital flows. In our judgment, a grov/th rate below 3 percent could focus future lending too narrowly on projects which require lower capital inputs. It would force a faster phase-down in lending to upper income countries, such as Mexico and 3razil, and to projects which meet basic human needs and help poor people in these countries. Very importantly, from the viewpoint of U.S. interests, fewer bank resources would then be available for energy and raw materials development. There is of course room for variation, for the individual windows of the different banks, within this overall range which we propose. Such variations would accommodate the different roles of the institutions, as well as the economic conditions and prospects in different geographic areas of the world. In the case of the Inter-American Development Bank's soft loan window, the Fund for Special Operations, lower lending levels may turn out to be appropriate because almost all of its borrowers in Latin America are among the more advanced developing economies. On that same criterion, the Asian Development Fund could justify a somewhat higher rate of growth in view of the fact that it lends to the poorest countries in Asia -- with annual per capita incomes below $300. A rate of increase higher than 5 percent would certainly appear to be necessary for the African -8Development Fund, because it is relatively new and thus operating from a much lower lending base — as well as because the countries being assisted are among the poorest in the world. As I said at the beginning of my statement, discussions on increased resources for the World Bank and the Inter-American Development Bank are now at a preliminary stage. Informal discussions are currently under way in the IBRD's Board of Executive Directors on a General Capital Increase (GCI), which would become effective in about FY 1983 -- requiring U.S. authorizing legislation perhaps in 1980, with appropriations beginning in FY 1982. A long lead time is necessary, because the size of the GCI will in part determine IBRD commitment levels in the immediate future. The major issues are how fast the IBRD should grow, how large the capital increase should be, and whether the increase should take place entirely in the form of callable capital or whether some of it should be paid in. No decision on any of the issues has been made at this time. The United States has taken no firm positions, pending thorough consultations with Congress. We have indicated our view on appropriate growth rates along the lines which I outlined above. We have also taken the position that there should be no change in the current U.S. share of the Bank's capital, 24.1 percent, because -9of the difficulties which would result in adjusting shares for other members, the fact that shares have just been altered via a Selective Capital Increase for this purpose, and the related need to avoid upsetting relative country shares at the International Monetary Fund, which have always been closely linked to shares at the IBRD. For the Inter-American Development Bank, informal discussions will probably begin at the Bank's annual meeting on April 17-19 and negotiations are expected to take place later this year. Our general thinking at this point is to emphasize the Bank's capital lending, in view of the relatively advanced level of development throughout the Hemisphere. Given a reasonable replenishment size, the U.S. shares could remain at the present level of 34.5 percent for Bank capital and 40 percent for the Fund for Special Operations. At this point, Mr. Chairman, let me devote the remainder of my remarks to the immediate issues facing us in the replenishments of the Asian Development Fund and African Development Fund. THE_ASIAN_DEVELqPMENT_FUND The Asian Development Fund was established in 1974 to mobilize concessional resources, on an organized and regular basis, to consolidate and standardize the Asian Development Bank's lending to the smaller an3 -10poorer developing member countries in Asia. The preponderance of the Bank's funds has been lent to countries with incomes per capita of less than $200. Six member countries account for the major share of these concessional loans: Pakistan, Burma, Nepal, Afghanistan, Bangladesh and Sri Lanka. These six are among the poorest countries in the world. In addition, it should be noted that most of them have good human rights records; U.S. support for the ADF thus helps fulfill the Congressional mandate, which also originated in this Subcommittee, to channel an increasing share of our multilateral development assistance to countries which do not engage in "consistent patterns of gross violations of internationally recognizei human r ights . " Beyond these six, several Pacific islands which are of importance to U.S. policy toward the region (particularly the Solomons and Western Samoa) receive ADF funds — our primary channel for providing assistance to them. In addition, we believe that the Fund may soon resume modest amounts of lending for basic human needs projects in Indonesia, the Philippines and Thailand. India has not received funds from the ADF because of its large share of IDA lending. Agriculture has been the primary sector for ADF lendinq. Over the period of the ADF's existence, 52 percent of total concessional lending has gone to this sector. In -111977, 57 percent of the concessional lending went to agriculture The second most important sector has been public utilities, accounting for 28 percent. Lesser amounts have gone to industry, transport and communications, and education. Prior to the establishment of the ADF, the Bank's concessional lending depended on contributions made at random and frequently tied to donor procurement. The lack of uniformity in timing and conditions impeded effective developmental use of such funds, and posed considerable administrative problems for the Bank. An initial amount of $486 million (ADF I) was therefore mobilized among fourteen regional and non-regional developed member countries in 1974. The U.S. share was $150 million, or 28.57 percent, second only to Japanese share of 33.71 percent. On the basis of these resources, the ADB financed a concessional lending program over the period 1973-1975 of $457 million. In 1975, negotiations between the Bank and the donor countries led to an initial replenishment of the ADF (ADF II) of $809 million. The U.S. contribution was $180 million, or 22.24 percent — down from the original U.S. share of 28.57, which the Fund had hoped to maintain via a proposed U.S. contribution of $231 million. In 1977, the Bank proposed a second replenishment of the Asian Development Fund (ADF III) of $2.15 billion -12to finance lending over the four-year period 1979-1982. An initial round of negotiations was held in October 1977 in Kyoto, Japan. The U.S. delegation took no position with respect to the total of the replenishment. It did, however, indicate that our share would not exceed 22.24 percent — the U.S. share of the first replenishment, and the share suggested in a sense of the Senate provision of the FY 1978 Foreign Assistance Appropriations Act. A second meeting was held in mid-February 1978 in Geneva. Most countries supported the Bank's proposed replenishment total of $2.15 billion. A few countries either believed the total to be excessive or were not in a position to make a definitive commitment. The U.S. delegation stated that it was still not in a position to make a commitment, but that it believed the U.S. decision-making process would be completed prior to the final replenishment meeting scheduled for late April. The delegation also doubted that the United States could commit to 22.24 percent of a replenishment as high as $2.15 billion. The Bank's proposal of $2.15 billion aims at a steadily increasing share for concessional lending within the overall program of the Bank over the fouryear period. It would thus raise the ratio of concessional lending to total lending to 40 percent by 1982. A -1322.24 percent U.S. share of that replenishment would be $478 million, calling for annual appropriations of almost $120 million. The Administration does not believe a replenishment of $2.15 billion is justified. It would imply an annual growth rate of 10 percent in ADF lending, which is well above our norm as outlined above. We believe a replenishment in the $1.8-$2.0 billion range to be a more proper figure, which implies growth rates of 6-3 Percent — sliqhtly above the norm, for the reasons already mentioned. Although this is marginally above our overall objectives in terms of growth we consider it justified in this instance because of the Fund's operations in the poorest countries of the region and its orientation toward reaching the poor and helping meet basic human needs, particularly in the agricultural sector. In addition our best judgment is that this figure will promote the broadest possible burden-sharing. It represents a significant decline from our original share of 28.57 percent. Assuming a 22.24 percent U.S. share, a $1.8 billion dollar replenishment would imply a U.S. contribution of about $400 million, or annual appropriations of $100 million. A $2.0 billion replenishment would imply a U.S. contribution of $445 million, with annual appropriations of about $111 million. -14THE AFRICAN DEVELOPMENT FUND The African Development Fund (AFDF) was created in 1973 as the concessional lending affiliate of the African Development Bank (AFDB). The Bank itself was established in 1964 to make loans to African nations on near-market terms; it has no non-African members. The African Development Fund makes loans to the poorest countries in Africa. Except under the most unusual circumstances, loans are not granted to countries with per capita GNP above $400. Absolute priority is given to nations with per capita GNP of $200 or less. Since its creation, the African Development Fund has made loans totaling $360 million to 27 nations, of which $141 million was lent to 17 countries in 1977. Agriculture, transportation and public utilities are the largest components of AFDF lending. The Fund's initial resources, consisting of contributions by fourteen non-African donor countries and the African Development Bank itself, amounted to $89 million in 1973. Since that time, four new contributors to the Fund (the United States, Saudi Arabia, Kuwait and France) and further contributions by original donors raised total AFDF resources to $443 million as of December 31, 1977. The current U.S. contribution of $25 million represents 5.6 percent of total Fund resources, tying us with Norway as the sixth largest donor in the Fund. -15For FY 1979, the Administration is requesting an appropriation for an additional $25 million contribution to the AFDF — which would raise the U.S. share of total AFDF resources to about 10 percent, and tie the United States with Japan as the second largest donor in the Fund after Canada. This amount would represent our contribution to the first AFDF replenishment, which covers AFDF lending in the CY 1976-1978 period. The United States was not a member of the African Development Fund when the first replenishment was negotiated, and Congress itself initiated the legislation authorizing this U.S. contribution. The AFDF will have committed all of its loanable resources by the end of 1978. For the Fund to continue its lending beyond this year, management has proposed a second replenishment to cover lending activities in 1979-81. AFDF management initially proposed a replenishment totaling $1,010 million — sufficient to sustain an average annual increase in real AFDF lending of more than 30 percent. Donor countries held their first meeting to discuss the issue in London on December 13-14. At that meeting, no firm consensus was reached on the size of the second replenishment. There was little support for the $1 billion proposed by Fund management however. The United States took no position on the size of the replenishment or the aoprooriate U.S. share, while other donors appeared to -16support a replenishment in the $550-$750 million range. Discussion of the second AFDF replenishment resumed in Geneva on March 6-7, 1978. The U.S. delegate again took no position on the replenishment, citing the need to await the outcome of our internal decision-making process. A consensus of other donors appeared to be forming toward the upper end of the range. The Administration has carefully reviewed the second replenishment of the African Development Fund, and believes that a U.S. contribution to the replenishment of $125 million — which would probably produce a U.S. share of the total replenishment in the 15-18 percent range — appropriate. would be The President personally mentioned his intention to propose $125 million during his visit to Nigeria last week, subject of course to Congressional authorization and appropriates. Africa's great development needs are well-known. It is the world's least developed area, with eighteen of the twenty-nine poorest countries in the world. About 75 percent of the African population is engaged in subsistence agriculture. Africa's average per capita GNP in 1975 was only $390; over a third of the continent's nations have a per capita GNP of $200 or less. In coming to a decision on the second replenishment it is essential to examine the Fund's administrative capacity. Two reviews of Fund administration have recently been -17conducted, by a group of international development experts and by a private consulting firm. While pointing out areas where further improvement may be needed, both indicated that the Fund has made great strides in improving its ability to identify, process and administer sound development projects. We have also discussed the Fund's administrative procedures with its management, which is firmly committed to continuing its efforts to improve Fund administration. In short, we believe that the Fund's capacity to effectively utilize its resources for African development has increased markedly and will continue to increase in the future. A U.S. contribution of $125 million, assuming a U.S. share of 15-18 percent implies a replenishment of about $700 million — sufficient to sustain a minimum real growth rate in Fund lending of 10 percent during the 1979-81 period. This is somewhat higher than our proposed rates of growth for the other development banks. We believe, however, that such growth is justified by Africa's endemic poverty and by the low initial lending levels of the African Development Fund; such growth has generally characterized the early years of the other concessional lending institutions The proposed 15-18 percent U.S. share of the replenishment would represent a significant increase from our current level of under 6 percent, or even our projected 10 percent share if Congress appropriates the additional $25 million proposed for -18FY 1979. This share is also above the 10.6% U.S. share suggested for the African Development Fund in the sense of the Senate provision of the FY 1978 Foreign Assistance Appropriations Act. However, such a share is still below the level of U.S. participation in any of the other soft loan windows of the international development banks, and we believe it is essential to demonstrate clearly to the nations of Africa our interest in assisting their growth and development. A $125 million U.S. contribution should enable the United States to obtain the Executive Directorship in the voting constituency — and Yugoslavia. which we share with the United Kingdom The United States currently holds the Alternate Executive Director position in this three-country grouping. Conclusion In concluding, Mr. Chairman, I want to reemphasize the importance that we place on these consultations. Last year, the Administration committed itself to consult fully with the Congress before making any new pledges to the development banks. We believe that only through this approach can the Administration and the Congress, working together, produce a stable and sustainable U.S. policy toward the banks. -19The United States has several major policy objectives which it seeks to promote in the international development banks, which I believe are shared by the Congress and the Administration: overall economic development, meeting basic human needs, reaching the poorest and least advantaged people in developing countries, and enhancing the observance of human rights. Over the past year, we have made significant progress on these issues, and on others raised by the Congress concerning the administrative practices of the banks (including their accountability, salary levels and other Perquisites) as I reported to this Subcommittee in detail on February 28. In all of these instances, our ability to achieve our objectives of course depends fundamentally on our willingness to contribute our fair financial share to the institutions. In this context, it is imperative that understandings be worked out between the Congress and the Executive in advance of the final negotiations on amounts and shares of U.S. participation in these institutions. In the past, pledges were often made solely by the Executive Branch and presented to the Congress as fait accompli. As a result, Congress has often expressed grave concern over the level and percentage shares of U.S. contributions. Appropriations of funds already authorized have lagged the contributions and subscriptions of other member countries. It is in -20the spirit of full consultation, and an effort to achieve the closest possible understanding with the Congress, that we carry out these consultations with you this morning. FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 9:00 A.M. APRIL 5, 1978 •> TESTIMONY OF THE HONORABLE W. MICHAEL BLUMENTHAL SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON SOCIAL SECURITY OF THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE Mr. Chairman and Members of this distinguished Committee: When this Administration came into office in 1977, it was confronted with a difficult and persistent financial solvency problem in the social security system. Briefly, the problem had two facets: one, short-term and the other, long-term. The short-term financial condition of the trust funds had deteriorated as a result of the worst recession since the Thirties, which reduced receipts below projections, and the worst inflation since World War I, which boosted benefit outlays above projections. The prospect of continuing financial deterioration was present^ even though annual increases in the waye base had already heen r:an^ated in law. Reserves in the Disability Trust Fund were expected to be depleted by 1979, and the Old Age and Survivors Trust Fund was expected to run out of reserves by 1983, according to estimates by the Funds' Trustees. Overall, the combined OASDI Trust Fund. which had a $41.1 billion reserve at the end of 1976, would have been exhausted by 1982. B-815 - 2- The longer-term solvency problem was the result, in part, of an indexing flaw which had been introduced into the benefit formula in 1972 and which overcompensated benefits for inflation. About one-half of the projected long-term deficit of the Trust Funds was the result of this inappropriate indexing calculation. The other half of the long-term deficit reflected changes in the projected composition of our population over the next 75 years. Declines in birth and mortality rates are expected to change the present three-to-one ratio of workers to beneficiaries to a two-to-one ratio in the next century, thus increasing the projected growth in benefits and decreasing the projected growth in receipts. As a consequence, for the 75-year period running to 2051, the trust funds were expected to incur an average deficit of 8.2 percent of future taxable payrolls. The Trustees of the Social Security Trust Funds told the Congress,in their 1977 report,that the system was in critical need of financial support to restore the solvency of the system in both the short- and longer-term. This was essentially the problem worrying the American people, and the issue squarely faced last year by this Administration and the 95th Congress. Both responded to the concerns of the American public, which overwhelmingly supports -3- the social security system and which, clearly/ favors raising additional taxes to save the system from insolvency. Many proposals were made during 1977, both in the Administration and the two branches of Congress. After considerable debate and deliberation, the Congress enacted the Social Security Admendments of 1977 which effectively eliminate the anticipated trust fund deficits, and restore trust fund reserves to healthy levels adequate for meeting contingencies. This was done by increasing both payroll tax rates and the wage base on which the taxes are levied. It is worth noting that all of the payroll tax increases taking place this year—amounting to $5.2 billion—are the result of legislation enacted in 1972, even before the financial situation of the funds reached critical levels. And more than half of the tax increase scheduled for 197 9 ($8.6 billion of the $15 billion projected rise in tax collections) reflects pre-1977 legislation. I emphasize this point to put the near-term problem into perspective. The fact is that^the need for substantial increases in revenues for social security system has been evident for some time. Even without the special drain on the trust funds resulting from the recession and inflation of the mid-70's, the changing age structure of the population and the desire to improve retirement benefits required -4increased tax levies on the working population. While the problem was exacerbated by the economic events of 1973-76, the fundamental need to "pay now to enjoy later" has been recognized for several years and partially accommodated by automatically raising the tax base. The legislation enacted in 1977 wisely did not attempt to cure the entire solvency problem in one huge step. The rise in taxes attributable to the 1977 amendments is relatively small for the bulk of taxpayers. For example, the worker earning $15,000 in 1979 will pay $920 in social security contributions. Of this, $908 reflects the social security amendments of 1972; only $12 is attributable to the additional taxes enacted last year. In fact, the additional tax will not exceed $260 for any one earner in 1979, and that top increase of $260 will only occur if the employee earns $22,900 or more. Of the 113 million projected contributors to social security in 1979, only 10 million will or 9 percent/earn $22,900 or more, whereas 103* million will earn less than $22,900. For those below the $22,900 breakpoint, most will have hardly any social security tax increase next year resulting from the legislation enacted by the 95th Congress. I emphasize this point because the public's attention has been directed to the potential tripling in the dollar amount of social security tax payments over the next 10 years as a result of the recent legislation. This potential has to be put into perspective. First, half of the prospective increase is -5the result of legislation in force since 1972. Second, the emphasis on the rise in potential tax payments overlooks the rise in projected earnings. The burden of social security taxes— that is, the share of income absorbed by these taxes--will rise to be sure, but by far less than the dramatic tripling emphasize in press accounts. 1979 FICA Tax (Employee) Wage or Salary : FICA Tax "~ Income : Prior Law $ 5,000 302 306 + 4 10,000 15,000 20,000 25,000 605 908 1,144 1,144 : 1977 Law : Difference 613 920 1,226 1,404 It is important, therefore, in considering + 8 + 12 + 82 +260 the 1977 legislation, neither to overstate the impact of the additional taxes imposed nor to underestimate the benefits that will accrue to participants in the social security system. The tax increases enacted by this Congress were designed to be least burdensome on the low and moderate income workers covered by social security. And these increases would be more than offset by the proposed reductions in income taxes recommended in the President's tax program. For a four-person, one-earner family, the proposed income tax reduction would offset the rise in social security taxes—both those resulting from the 1977 amendments and those reflecting earlier legislation—up -6- to more tiian $20,000 in annual inaome. For four-person, two-earner families, the offset is complete up to more than $30,000 in annual income. Thus even with the scheduled rise in social security taxes next year, the overall Federal tax burden would be reduced, in 1979, for the vast bulk of American taxpayers. At the same time, the social security tax increases have removed the immediate threat of trust fund deficits, thereby allaying the fears of 33 million social security beneficiaries. We believe that most Americans are willing to pay the additional taxes levied to keep the system solvent, an indication of how highly our electorate values the prospect of dignity in retirement. By virtue of the new tax schedule, the Congress has effectively eliminated the projected short-term deficit. Instead of having completely depleted reserves by 1982, the 1982 reserve ratio in the OASDI fund (that is beginningof-year reserve as a percent of the 1982 outlays) would be 30 percent, a level considered reasonable to meet contingencies. -7- Beginning Reserve Ratio in OASDI Trust Fund Year 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 Prior to 1977 Amendments 47% 36 27 18 9 0 1977 Amendments 47 37 29 26 25 30 In addition, the 1977 Amendment substantially improves the longer range actuarial status of the trust funds, by removing the indexing flaw which overcompensated benefits for inflation. The OASDI trust funds will run a surplus for the next 25 years of 0.97 percent of taxable payroll. Over the next 75 years, it is estimated that instead of an average deficit of 8.2 percent of taxable payroll, the fund will have a mild deficit of 1.46 percent on the average. -8Having developed—after careful study and long deliberation—a system of contributions adequate to meet the needs of this and future generations of retirees, it would in our judgment be unwise to undo this progress by hasty action. Such action is also unnecessary, because the income tax reduction and reform proposals submitted by the President—so sorely needed to meet other important economic and social objectives—would at the same time offset the near-term scheduled rise in social security taxes. What is needed is more careful deliberation and examination of the options available to us. The Congress will, in coming months, have several opportunities for weighing alternatives, since there are four separate commissions or study groups looking at various aspects of the social security problem. The National Commission on Social Security, which was authorized under the 1977 Social Security Amendments and whose members are appointed partly by the Congress and partly by the President, has been given the mandate of studying and reporting within two years on the fiscal status of the Old Age, Disability and Health Insurance Trust Funds and the adequacy of such trust funds to meet the immediate and long-range financing needs of such programs. The -9- Conunission will examine the scope of coverage/ the adequacy of benefits, the impact of social security, disability and health insurance programs on other government income transfer programs, and alternative financing methods. The quadrennial Advijsory CounciJ. on Social Security is also authorized to review the status of the social security trust funds including the scope of coverage, methods of financing social security problems, and the impact of social security on public assistance programs. The Council is required to submit reports of its findings and recoiniTienaat ions to the Secretary of Health, Education and Welfare by October 1, 1979. An additional study is authorized under the 1977 Amendments. It will evaluate the integration of the social security and the Federal Civil Service retirement systems. In addition it will evaluate the impact of full coverage of State and local employees under social security. The report of this study is due by the end of next year. -10- Finally, the President has proposed the establishment of a Commission on Retirement Policy to provide a comprehensive analysis of the retirement and disability structure of the United States, including the Nation's retirement and disability needs for the next 60 years and the financial ability of the existing public and private retirement systems to meet those needs; the financing mechanisms and benefit structures of the present public and private systems; the overlaps and gaps in the present benefit structures; and the role of individual savings in meeting retirement and disability needs. As this list of commissions and studies indicates, the wide range of the complex issues involved in any modification of the social security system will be thoroughly examined in coming months. It is clear that decisions taken with respect to any of these issues have wide ramifications. For example, the issue of expanding the coverage of the social security system through integration of the system with other public and private pension systems is an important element in calculating future costs and, therefore, the necessity for additional revenues. -11 It may be that a reexamination of the benefits schedule will also suggest changes in the system's financing requirements. In this connection, it is worth noting that a recent poll indicated that respondents were about evenly divided when confronted with a choice between future tax increases and limits on such increases even at the cost of lower benefits. To me, the poll suggests that the public accepts and endorses the concept of a strong link between contributions and benefits, at least for the retirement aspects of the system. Any actions to sever or strain this link must keep in mind the strength of this tradition, a factor which underlay the decisions taken by the Congress in enacting the 19 77 amendments to the social security system. In light of the complexity of the issues involved, and also in light of the coming availability of thorough, dispassionate and highly competent examination of the social security system, it is our conclusion that any changes should have the benefit of these forthcoming reviews. oOo FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 10:00 P.S.T. APRIL 6, 1978 REMARKS BY THE HONORABLE DANIEL H. BRILL ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR ECONOMIC POLICY AT THE CONFERENCE ON THE MIDYEAR ECONOMIC OUTLOOK OF THE CONFERENCE BOARD SAN FRANCISCO, CALIFORNIA Economic policy making in a democratic society involves an intricate balancing among contending objectives. Every objective is, in itself, worthy. Economic growth is a legitimate objective for an expanding population with ever-rising aspirations. So are: the achievement of more equitable distribution of the fruits of growth, enlarged employment opportunities to bring the disadvantaged into the main stream of American economic life, repair of our deteriorated urban centers, preservation of our environment, better medical care—the list is endless. All worthy, all achieveable—but not all at once. As wealthy as this nation is in terms of natural resources, advanced technology and a skilled work force, it can make only moderate progress on all these objectives simultaneously. Nevertheless, this should be a period in our economic cycle when the rate of progress on many fronts could be accelerated. There is slack in the system; we are not close to straining our labor or capital resources. Despite the significant achievement last year of creating over 4 million new jobs and reducing the number of unemployed by 1.2 million, we still have 6 percent of B-816 -2- labor force unemployed. And despite a real growth in output of 5-3/4 percent, there is still about one-sixth of industrial plant idle. Why can't we move faster toward satisfying the whole range of legitimate social and economic objectives? In my judgment, the principal barrier is our recent history of inflation and the current widespread expectation of accelerating inflation. The roller-coaster experience of the past decade— soaring inflation followed by deep recession—has apparently made us a nation of risk-averters. Private investment opportunities now require a much higher premium to induce the required capital inflow, the pay-back time horizon for research and for new investment embodying research results has been so shortened as to threaten our technological superiority, and government initiatives are limited and debilitated by inflation. Even when the economy has slowed, we have been locked into an unacceptably high rate of inflation. During the second half of the 60's and into the early 1970's, the inflation rate—as measured by the GNP deflator—averaged over 4-1/2 percent per year, two and a half times as rapid as in the first half of the 60's. Prices soared in 1973 and 74, in response to food shortages, the oil situation and the surge in raw materials demands during the worldwide investment boom. In 1974, added impetus to prices -3came from "catchup" efforts after the removal of wage and price controls. As the worldwide economic contraction set in in 1975, cost and price advances began to subside from the peak rates of 1974. The pattern of unwinding continued into 1976, though the decline reflected principally further easing in farm and food prices and some Federally mandated rollbacks in energy prices early in the year. Throughout 1976, and again during 1977, the underlying rate of inflation—as measured by the rise in consumer prices excluding food and fuel—averaged around 6 percent, up about one-half frcm the pace of the late 1960's and early 1970's. Si wholesale prices—other than for farm products, foods and energy—rose at a 6 percent rate during both 1976 and 1977. Basically, the inflation unwinding process stopped at 6 percent. It is bad enough to be unable to bring down the rate of inflation below 6 percent even with unemployment in the 7 to 8 percent range. It is more disturbing that as significant improvement has taken place in the unemployment picture, signs have emerged that the inflation rate is accelerating. To be sure, recent price figures are distorted by temporary factors such as adverse weather and the coal strike, but it does appear that the underlying rate of price rise has moved up to at least the 6-1/2 percent range as unemployment has dipped to 6 percent. This is not a viable relationship. We cannot tolerate the waste of resources—nor the social and economic tensions—implied by a 6 percent level of unemployment. But neither can we succeed -4with programs to encourage fuller employment of resources if high inflation persists or accelerates. ' This is not a matter of lack of will, or of demons lurking at the central bank. The fact is that inflation and inflationary expectations induce economic behavior in the private sector perverse to the success of stimulatory efforts. With the scars of 1973-4 still fresh in executive suites, the prospect of accelerating inflation no longer brings forth the "build now before costs go up" reaction. More often, the reaction is to delay expansion in fear that inflation will inevitably result in recession; who wants to initiate an investment project today—at today's high costs--that might come on stream just as the economy nosedives? Similarly, consumers appear to respond negatively to their anticipations of inflation; buying now to beat the price rise is not a common reaction, except perhaps in the area of housing. It all adds up, to me, to the simple conclusion that the economy can't get where we want it to go, if the path it takes is inflationary. To find a safer route requires, first, an analysis of the nature of contemporary inflationary forces. What kind of inflation do we have? I find it easier to stress what kind we do not have. We do not have an excess demand inflation with "too much money chasing too few goods." We do not have a wage or profit inflation, with one group or sector carving out exorbitant gains. Instead, we have what for want of a better term I will describe as "tailchasing" inflation. Let me explain the need for this new analytical category. -5Ultimately, the rate of growth of real income is dependent upon the rate of growth of output per unit of input. This sets the limits. Beyond this, one sector can gain at the expense of another only by a shift in relative factor shares, brought about by market forces or by exercise of market or political power. The shares of the "pie" available to labor and capital are also limited by redistribution of shares from the private to the public sector and from the producing to the nonproducing elements of society—retirees, welfare recipients, and others. Such redistribution means a smaller share to those currently engaged in the production process. But the limits for all are set by the rate of growth in productivity. Unfortunately, the rate of growth in U.S. productivity has slowed down perceptibly in the last decade. From 1950 through 1968 private nonfarm productivity expanded by about 2.6 percent annually. From 1968 through 1977 it rose by about 1.4 percent per year—roughly one-half as much. Even after cyclical adjustment, a wide disparity remains. The causes of this slowdown in productivity growth are complex, but seem to center around a slower growth in capital per worker in recent years. Whatever the cause—or causes—the fact is that the "pie" to be shared has grown more slowly over the past decade than the rate of growth earlier in the postwar period. -6Moreover, during recent years, a larger share of the 'k>ie" has been going to those not participating in the production process. Total government transfer payments to individuals have risen from 6-1/2 to 7 percent of national income in the early 1960's to the 13 to 14 percent range in recent years. In the division of the remainder of the "pie", neither labor nor capital has measurably benefited. The share of labor compensation in the gross product of the corporate sector has a slight upward tilt over the postwar period, but if supplements to wages are subtracted to leave only wages and salaries this is converted to a slight declining trend. For the other factor of production, capital, profits adjusted to put the cost of inventories and capital consumed in the production process on a replacement cost basis have represented a much lower share of corporate gross product in the 1970's than in the earlier postwar decades. What is clear then, is that neither labor nor capital has been able to gain, relatively, during this last inflationary decade. This is not only true in relative terms; neither labor nor capital has made much progress in absolute terms. The tail- chasing process has speeded up and has thrown off ever higher money wages and profits, but forward progress in real terms has slowed down to the vanishing point. -7First, take the case of labor. Employee compensation per man-hour rose by 95 percent in the 1968-77 period, exceeding the 51 percent gain in the 1959-1968 period. But that is almost all tail-chasing. Corrected for inflation, real compensation per man-hour rose only 12 percent between 1968 and 1977—just a little more than 1 percent a year—and well below the 27 percent gain of the earlier period. And, because of a decline in hours worked, real compensation per week rose only about 8 percent between 1968 and 1977—less than 1 percent a year. Second, take the case of capital. Corporate profits after tax—as reported under current accounting conventions—rose by 122 percent between 1968 and 1977, exceeding the 65 percent gain between 1959 and 1968. Correction for inflation requires several adjustments to the reported figures. A first step is to adjust inventories and capital consumption allowances to a replacement-cost basis. This cuts the profit increase about in half, and leaves a rise of 52 percent in the 1968 to 1977 period. If these adjusted profits are then expressed in dollars of constant purchasing power, there was actually a decline of 11 percent in real profits during the 1968-1977 period. This contrasts with a rise of 61 percent, on the same inflation adjusted basis in the previous period. Can anyone doubt that both labor and capital would be better off by a return to lower rates of inflation? -8The crucial question is how we phase down to lower rates of inflation. Granted that no one is gaining much from the tail-chasing process, how do we slow down the process without slowing down the economy? If demands were pressing on resource availability, the answer would be relatively simple—turn loose the conventional tools of stabilization policy and let fiscal/ monetary restraint bring demands into better balance with supply. But the situation in which we now find ourselves, with demands inadequate but prices buffeted by everyone's desire to catch up with rising costs and prices, and all highly sensitized by a decade of inflation, is not easily amenable to conventional tools of stabilization. There is a sense in which we are prisoners of the past. Inflation has now continued for a decade in this country at rates that are much higher than most of our previous experience. As a result, markets have adjusted to some considerable degree, building on an expectation, too often validated, that inflation is more likely to continue than to stop, and more likely to accelerate than to decelerate. This leaves markets exceedingly vulnerable to any signs of intensification of inflationary pressures. The tangible signs of a rise in the rate of inflation would lead to higher rates of interest. Given the state of expectations, an effort by the monetary authorities to prevent or reverse such an inflationinduced rise in interest rates could be self-defeating. The -9- markets' interpretation of a significantly faster rate of monetary expansion would only push prices and interest rates up all the more rapidly. This would be tail-chasing with a vengeance. I might note that monetary policy-makers were once accused of "money market myopia", i.e., resting policy too heavily on movements of interest rates. Perhaps today, financial market participants can be charged with "aggregates astigmatism", i.e., too much preoccupation with jiggles in the monetary aggregates. Whether the contemporary preoccupation is sound economics or not—and I'm afraid my biases show--it has to be reckoned with in the formulation of policy. ception becomes reality. In markets, per- As a result, policy approaches which might once have been open to us are no longer available after a decade of inflation. Instead,our economic and financial policies must be shaped so as to reduce inflationary expectations, not to magnify them. Since no major group is currently benefitting from the inflation process and since we all stand to lose in the long run, the sensible course is to chase our tails a little more slowly. In that way--and perhaps only in that way—the current inflationary process can gradually be slowed down and inflationary expectations reversed. This was, and is, the compelling logic underlying the deceleration strategy outlined earlier this year by the President in his Economic Message. -10The strategy rests on the hypothesis that the rate of wage and price escalation can be reduced in every market, that businessmen assured of some moderation in the rate of cost increases can moderate their price increases accordingly, and that labor negotiators assured of moderation in the rise in the cost of living can temper their wage demands. In other words, if we can all "cool it" in concert, everyone will benefit. Because this program is voluntary, rather than mandatory or coercive, and because it does not rely on a single standard of wage and price behavior, it has been dismissed by some as probably ineffective. We disagree. In light of the foregoing analysis of the inflation process—the process in which wages have been vainly chasing prices which have been vainly chasing wages, in an escalating cycle with no one the victor for long— we think the self-interest of all participants in the success of the program will be evident and a powerful force in achieving some abatement of inflationary pressures. 0O0 CONTACT: ROBERT W. CHILDERS (202)634-5248 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 7, 1978 REVENUE SHARING FUNDS DISTRIBUTED The Department of Treasury's Office of Revenue Sharing (ORS) distributed more than $2.0 billion in general revenue sharing and antirecession fiscal assistance payments today to more than 37,000 State and local governments. General revenue sharing funds accounted for most of today's payments, totaling $1.7 billion to 37,203 State and local governments. One thousand thirty-one governments did not receive funds because they did not file necessary forms, in spite of reminders from the Office of Revenue Sharing. Today's Antirecession Fiscal Assistance (ARFA) payments totaled over $305 million to 17,033 State and local governments and were based on a quarterly national unemployment rate of 6.6 percent for the quarter beginning October 1, 1977. Only governments whose individual jurisdictions had unemployment rates in excess of 4.5 percent for the calendar quarter beginning October 1, 1977 were eligible for the ARFA payments. B-817 -2- Current legislation authorizes the Office of Revenue Sharing to provide quarterly Revenue sharing payments to State and local governments through the end of Federal fiscal year 1980. Quarterly payments under the Antirecession Fiscal Assistance Program are authorized through September 30, 1978. - 30 - FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY Expected at 9:30 a.m. STATEMENT OF DONALD C. LUBICK ACTING ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR TAX POLICY ON INTEGRATION OF THE CORPORATE AND INDIVIDUAL INCOME TAX BEFORE THE CO.MMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS OF THE HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES April 7, 1978 INTRODUCTION There is widespread agreement that changes in our tax laws are needed to strengthen and maintain the current economic expansion and to assure the future productivity of the economy. In particular, changes are needed to stimulate business investment. One technique suggested by many for achieving these goals is integration of the corporate and individual tax systems. Under present law, income earned from activity conducted in corporate form is subject to taxation twice if distributed to shareholders. First, the income is taxed at the corporate level at rates up to 48 percent. In addition, if the after-tax income of a corporation is distributed to individual shareholders as dividends, it is subject to a B-818 - 2 second tax at rates of 14 to 70 percent. Integration would eliminate or reduce one of these levels of tax. During his 1976 campaign for the Presidency, President Carter called for an end to the double taxation of corporate dividends. Over the past year, the Treasury has studied integration extensively. We have analyzed the economic effects of the present tax laws and considered a number of possible integration systems in great detail. One approach which we developed and considered carefully was substantially similar to the proposal which Chairman Ullman has introduced. As you know, we ultimately decided not to recommend an integration proposal. Instead, the President proposed other incentives for business, principally in the form of individual and corporate rate cuts and liberalization of the investment credit. The rate cuts will benefit both small and large businesses and will reduce corporate taxes by $6 billion in 1979 and $8.5 billion in 1980.^ The individual rate cuts will benefit unincorporated businesses. Needed business investment also will be encouraged by improvements in the investment tax credit. mhe present 10 percent rate will be made permanent—rather than reverting to the 7 percent level that is now scheduled to apply after 1980. In addition, the ability of taxpayers to utilize the investment credit will - 3be increased, and the credit will be made available for a broader range of investments.—' Jn my testimony today, I would like to explain why the President ultimately decided not to recommend corporate integration and instead proposed these other forms of business tax relief. There are two broad reasons underlying this decision. First, integration is a fundamental structural reform of our tax system and raises a wide range of policy issues. There must be an opportunity for the implications of these issues to be considered by the Administration and Congress, as well as by the various groups in our society which will be affected. Given the pressing need for a tax bill this year, we simply did not feel that there was sufficient time for these issues to be adequately considered. I will devote the major portion of my testimony to describing these issues. Second, due to the fact that the form of integration affects the competitive position of some sectors of the business community vis-a-vis others, we found an absence of broad business support for any single plan. The business community in general favored other forms of business tax reductions such as those which we have included in our program. - 4 I would like to mention, however, two factors which did not underlie the decision. First, the Administration did not conclude that integration should be rejected because of undesirable economic effects. We believe integration has merit and deserves further study. Second, the Administration did not conclude that integration is technically infeasible. In fact, we concluded that a plan of integration could be made to work technically and even could allow various collateral simplifications of the tax system to be adopted. PROPOSALS WHICH SHOULD BE CONSIDERED IN CONJUNCTION WITH INTEGRATION Before describing policy issues raised by integration itself, I would like to discuss certain changes in the tax laws which we believe should be considered at the same time as integration. The Administration considered integration in conjunction with two related proposals: reduction of the top individual marginal rate to a rate which approximates the top corporate rate, and taxation of capital gains as ordinary income.^ These proposals are linked to integration for two reasons. First, they relate to the basic structural elements involved in the taxation of income from corporations. We believe integration should be considered only as part of a - 5 more general reform of the tax treatment of corporate income that would move towards taxing all income once at appropriate individual marginal rates. Integration for dividends does not remove the incentive for high bracket taxpayers to accumulate income within corporations. For these taxpayers corporations provide a form of tax shelter. Even with integration they can save taxes by accumulating money within a corporation rather than paying currently one tax on the earnings at their appropriate marginal rate. This tax shelter effect can be eliminated only by reducing the maximum individual rate to approximately the top corporate rate and taxing capital gains as ordinary income. Second, a very substantial portion of the tax reduction resulting from integration is distributed to wealthy individuals since these are the individuals who own the most stock. In other words, integration as an isolated proposal is regressive. For the same reason elimination of the capital gains preference is progressive and therefore is an appropriate revenue offset to integration. We continue to believe that integration should be considered only in conjunction with these other proposals. - 6 POLICY CONSIDERATIONS RAISED BY INTEGRATION IN GENERAL I would like to turn now to policy considerations raised by integration proposals in general. Many specific advantages have been claimed for corporate integration in comparison to other methods of stimulating capital formation. At the same time, some of these claims have been challenged both by tax professionals and by representatives of private groups. I would like to describe the claimed advantages and the areas of uncertainty which we believe require further study. The following four arguments have been raised in favor of integration proposals to reduce the double tax on dividends, such as the one introduced by Chairman Ullman: (1) integration would reduce the bias against equity financing and in favor of debt that characterizes the present tax system; (2) integration would promote better use of scarce capital resources by reducing a bias against investment in the corporate sector and against industries with high dividend payout ratios; - 7 (3) integration would improve the capital market by reducing the current bias in favor of corporate retentions relative to distributions; and (4) integration would give relatively more benefits to low-income taxpayers and so be less regressive than other forms of stimulus to capital formation. Encouraging Corporate Equity Financing Under present law, corporations, in computing taxable income, are allowed a deduction for interest but not for dividends. This means that a corporation pays interest with pre-tax dollars and pays dividends with after-tax dollars. Thus, corporations are encouraged to finance their operations with debt instead of equity. The proportion of debt in the corporate financial structure has increased over the past 15 years, giving rise to concern about increased corporate vulnerability to business risks such as cyclical downturns. Many economists believe that reducing the double tax on dividends would encourage a greater relative use of equity financing. However, some recent economic research has challenged this traditional view. According to this research, the bias of the current system is only against raising new - 8equity and is not against corporate reinvestment of retained earnings. Since most corporate investment currently is out of retained earnings, the bias of the present system may be narrower than is generally believed. If. this is so it may be more cost effective to provide relief from double taxation solely for dividends on newly invested equity capital. In any case, it should be noted that the corporate tax cuts proposed in the President's tax program will also reduce the relative costs of equity financincr by reducing the "corporate" portion of the double tax. The relative effectiveness of integration and corporate rate cuts in encouraging new investments in corporate equity remains an open question. Reducing the Bias Against Investment in the Corporate Sector Another reason advanced for adopting integration is to correct a bias against investments in the corporate sector. Corporate income distributed to shareholders is taxed twice. Income from investments in unincorporated enterprises is only taxed once. For nontax reasons, the corporate form of organization is more prevalent in some industries than in others. Because of the double taxation of corporate income, owners of industries organized in corporate form (such as - 9basic industries) incur substantially higher tax on capital income than owners of industries conducted in noncorporate form (such as real estate). Such differentials in tax rates result; in inefficiency in the use of capital. Relatively too much investment is channelled to unincorporated enterprises because choices among investments are affected by tax considerations. The Administration agrees that gains in economic efficiency could be realized from reduction of the double tax on dividends. However, moving towards equalization of rates of tax on capital income will cause some industries and firms to receive much bigger tax reductions than others and will change the relative value of investments as between industries. We believe that these consequences should be carefully considered by Congress and affected groups within the society. Reducing the Bias Against Distributions Another reason advanced for adopting integration is to reduce the bias of current law against corporate distributions. Retained corporate earnings are taxed once, whereas distributed corporate earnings are taxed twice. Accordingly, it is argued that corporations are encouraged to retain - 10 earnings. Of course, retained earnings are reflected in higher share prices, and a selling shareholder is taxed on this appreciation. However, tax on this appreciation is deferred until the shareholder sells the stock and appreciation is taxed at capital gain rates. Corporate integration, it is argued, will reduce this bias against retention, thus reducing the advantage of large and established firms which can generate capital internally. These corporations will be forced to compete in the open market for investment funds, and new enterprises will be able to compete for these funds. The stock of capital within the economy thus will be distributed with greatest efficiency. There are two issues relating to this claimed advantage of integration which deserve substantially more consideration and debate. First, the extent to which the current tax system actually discourages distributions has not been resolved. It is open to question on both theoretical and empirical grounds. For example, while some econometric research suggests that dividend payout ratios should increase because of integration, dividend payout ratios appear to have remained roughly constant in European countries that have integrated. Further analysis is required before one - 11 can confidently predict the effect of integration on distributions. Second, even assuming that dividend payout ratios would increase because of integration, there is substantial disagreement as to whether this result is good or bad for the economy. In contrast to the favorable arguments presented above, some experts argue that if shareholders receive more dividends they will increase consumption, thereby reducing funds available for business investment. Also, raising capital in equity markets involves substantial transactional costs. Retention of earnings, of course, does not involve these costs. By this line of argument, tax reductions designed to stimulate capital formation should not encourage shareholder pressure on corporations for increased distributions. Progressivity Relative to Other Forms of Business Tax Reduction The final argument in favor of integration is that it is less regressive than other techniques for reducing the tax burden on capital income. Integration through dividend relief in effect reduces the corporate tax on taxable income distributed to shareholders. Integration results in shareholders receiving relatively more income, which is then taxed at each shareholder's marginal rate. In contrast, at least a portion of the benefits of a corporate tax rate cut - 12 will be retained by corporations and thus will not be subject to current tax at individual marginal rates. Thus, integration is relatively less regressive than a system which reduces the tax on all corporate income, whether or not distributed. In the absence of other tax changes, the relative progressivity of reduction of the double tax on dividends, compared to other forms of business tax relief, would be an important consideration. While the Administration is not proposing integration at this time, the business tax cuts in the tax program are balanced by provisions that limit deductions used mostly by the wealthy and provisions that provide substantial tax cuts for lower and middle-income families. If integration is adopted in addition to the other elements of the Administration's program, it would distort in favor of wealthy taxpayers the distribution of tax reductions which the Administration's program is designed to achieve. POLICY ISSUES RAISED BY INTEGRATION DEVELOPMENT OF A SPECIFIC PROPOSAL— In developing an integration proposal we became aware of the fact that resolution of technical issues often involved significant policy judgments. Various categories of corporations and shareholders could receive significant relative advantages or disadvantages depending on how these issues - 13 were resolved. As the specifics of a proposal developed, we found that various businesses and shareholder groups became concerned with the effects of integration and many advocated instead the business tax cuts which the President ultimately recommended. We became convinced that if integration were to be proposed, these issues should not be left to the draftsmen, but should be fully explored with Congress and affected groups within the society. I would like to describe some of the more significant issues which we identified. Form of Integration Proposal Integration can take one of two basic forms. It can treat the corporation like a partnership and tax all income to the shareholders currently, regardless of whether or not the income is distributed. This is generally referred to as full integration. Alternatively, it can provide relief from double tax only to the extent corporate income is in fact distributed. This is referred to as partial integration or dividend relief. Chairman Ullman's proposal takes the latter form, that is, it provides relief from double tax only to the extent corporate income is in fact distributed as dividends. The Treasury Department concluded that full - 14 - integration was infeasible because of its administrative problems. We agree with Chairman Ullman that partial integration is technically feasible. There are various mechanisms which can be utilized to achieve partial integration. All of them are similar in that economically they provide relief by reducing or eliminating the corporate tax on income which the corporation distributes to its shareholders. It is possible, however, to formulate partial integration either as a reduction of the corporate tax or as shareholder relief. If partial integration takes the form of relief from corporate tax, the corporation receives a deduction for dividends which it pays, a credit against its tax liability on account of dividends which it pays, or a lower rate of tax on distributed earnings. If partial integration takes the form of shareholder relief, shareholders include in income all or a portion of the tax which the corporation paid on income distributed as dividends and take a credit against their individual tax liability for such amount. Significant short-term consequences flow from the form utilized. If integration takes the form of a reduction of the corporate tax, the tax savings resulting from integration will be received in the first instance by the corporation. This means that the corporation will have more cash and may - 15 be able to retain some of the integration tax savings for internal generation of capital. On the other hand, if integration takes the form of shareholder relief, the tax savings of integration initially will be in the hands of the shareholders. The corporation will be able to obtain benefits from integration for the internal generation of capital only if it can convince its shareholders that on account of this change in law it is appropriate for the corporation to reduce the level of its cash distributions. Thus, the form in which integration is proposed may have an important impact on the extent to which corporations in the short run are able to capture at least a portion of the integration benefits for internal capital formation. In the long run, the choice between corporate tax reduction and shareholder relief may not affect the retention rate. A second significant impact of the form involves the calculation of corporate income for financial accounting purposes. If integration takes the form of reduction of corporate tax, corporations probably will be able to report lower tax costs and consequently higher after-tax profits. If integration, on the other hand, takes the form of shareholder relief, corporations will probably have to report the same tax costs as they do today. An integration system which resulted in higher reported profits for financial - 16 accounting purposes could have a wide range of psychological effects from stock pricing to wage increases for employees. Another important impact of the form involves our treaty obligations with foreign countries. Frequently, under these treaties the United States agrees not to withhold more than a specified amount from dividends paid to residents of the treaty country. If integration takes the form of reduction of the corporate tax, it may be argued that we are in violation of treaty obligations if the benefits of integration are denied to foreign shareholders. If, however, integration takes the form of shareholder relief there is a stronger argument that we have not violated treaty obligations if foreign shareholders are denied the benefits of corporate integration. Because of this factor, European countries which have adopted integration have chosen the shareholder relief form. Treatment of Tax Preferences Development of an integration proposal also requires major policy decisions with respect to the treatment of tax preferences. Tax preferences are created by special provisions included in the Internal Revenue Code to encourage taxpayers to undertake activities which are deemed to be - 17 socially desirable. In general, preferences are of four types: (1) credits, such as the investment credit; (2) artificial deductions, such as percentage depletion, (3) accelerated deductions, such as rapid amortization of pollution control facilities; and (4) exclusions from gross income, such as interest on state and local government obligations. Under present law, corporate tax preferences give rise to economic income which is not subject to corporate tax. This income, however, is taxed to shareholders if distributed as dividends. Insofar as preferences already serve to eliminate the corporate tax, integration may provide no benefit unless the favorable treatment of the preferences is preserved when corporate income is distributed to shareholders. An example of this preservation under current law is the treatment of tax-exempt interest earned by mutual funds. Under certain circumstances tax-exempt income retains its tax-exempt character when distributed to shareholders of the mutual fund. If the preference were not "flowed through," the mutual fund shareholders would be taxed on the income when distributed. - 18 If preferences are not flowed through, integration will provide a greater benefit to corporations in those industries which currently have fewer preferences and consequently pay relatively high effective rates of tax relative to economic income. Thus, integration could have an effect on the competitive position of different industries in attracting capital investment. The treatment of preferences thus presents a fundamental question: should integration be limited to relieving double taxation only to the extent that a corporate tax is actually paid, or should it attempt to pierce the corporate veil and pass through the benefit of corporate tax preferences to shareholders. Chairman Ullman's proposal does not pass tax preferences through to shareholders. In the event that the decision is made not to flow through the benefit of preferences it will be necessary to provide some rules to determine the source of any dividend distributions. A corporation with preferences has, in effect, two pools of income; income with respect to which tax has been paid (after-tax taxable income) and preference income with respect to which no tax has been paid. There are three options for determining the source of dividends: all distributions may be treated as first coming out of after-tax taxable income until such income is exhausted; all distributions may be treated as first coming out of preference - 19 income until such income is exhausted; or all distributions may be deemed to be partially out of each pool, presumably on a pro rata basis. Treating after-tax taxable income as distributed first will provide the greatest benefit to industries with relatively high levels of preference income and distributions, while treating preference income as distributed first will provide the least benefit. Chairman Ullman's proposal treats distributions as coming first out of after-tax taxable income. Also, to some extent his proposal allows shareholders the benefits of integration even when their corporation has distributed all of its after-tax taxable income and is making distributions out of preference income. (This results from the fact that under the proposal the amount which a corporation is permitted to add to the shareholder credit account for a taxable year exceeds the maximum amount of shareholder credits the corporation could have declared for such taxable year if it distributed all of its fully taxed income.) In other words, his proposal provides tax relief even when the distributed income has not incurred any corporate tax. This treatment makes preferences more valuable to a corporation than they are under current law. Under current law corporate preference income is not subject to corporate tax. Under Chairman Ullman's proposal, preference income can, in effect, give rise to a refund of corporate tax paid on other - 20 income. This treatment is most serious during the proposal's 10-year phase-in period. To a lesser degree it continues to 4/ be present even after the proposal is fully phased in.- Foreign Tax Credit An issue similar to that presented by preferences arises with respect to the foreign tax credit. The United States generally taxes the worldwide income of its residents and domestic corporations. The United States, however, allows a credit against U.S. tax liability for taxes paid to foreign countries. The foreign tax credit is intended to insure that the tax law is neutral with respect to foreign and domestic investment. That neutrality has been a cornerstone of United States tax policy. In designing an integration proposal, it is necessary to reexamine this policy of neutrality. Some argue that neutrality should be the basic principle underlying international tax policy. Neutrality is achieved when an enterprise pays the same total rate of tax on foreign profits as on domestic profits. This would require the integration of foreign corporate and domestic individual income taxes. That is, an individual would receive credit for corporate taxes irrespective of whether they were paid to the U.S. or - 21 the foreign country. Others, mindful of revenue considerations point out that allowing a shareholder credit for foreign corporate taxes can be a significant revenue drain on the U.S. Treasury because it may require the. refund to sharehold 5/ of taxes paid by the corporations to foreign treasuries.— In addition, some argue that a flow through of the foreign tax could weaken our treaty bargaining leverage with other countries having integrated tax systems since those countries typically do not flow foreign taxes through to their shareholders. Traditional practice within a classical system has given the source country the major portion of the tax revenue from foreign investment with only residual taxing rights accruing to the residence country. It is not clear how the tax revenue from foreign investment should be divided between the source and residence countries within an integrated system. Whether the revenue split should be "SOSO" or something else is an open question. It is very clear, however, that giving more than 100 percent of the tax revenue to the source country is unacceptable. But this is precisely the effect that full flow through of foreign taxes to individual shareholders would often have. - 22 - There are a variety of possible solutions. Foreign corporate taxes could be allowed as a credit at the individual shareholder level, but limited to the individual shareholder's effective tax on his foreign source income. This would avoid the refund of foreign taxes by the United States, but would be administratively complex since each individual shareholder would be required to compute a foreign tax credit limit. Another possibility would be for the United States to allow a full credit at the shareholder level for foreign corporate taxes, but require the foreign "source" country to finance the credit. This would entail an EEC type "clearing house" payment. A third possibility would be for the United States to deny a part or all of the flow through of foreign taxes, but, like France, Germany, and the United Kingdom, soften the impact through favorable dividend ordering or tracing rules. Special Categories of Shareholders A number of major issues arise in connection with the treatment under integration of special categories of shareholders. The most important of these categories is tax- exempt institutions. Many integration proposals (apparently including that of Chairman Ullman) effectively exclude taxexempt institutions from participating in the benefits of - 23 integration by denying these shareholders a refund of any corporate tax attributable to their dividends. It is frequent! argued that this exclusion will reduce the revenue cost of integration. Theoretically, a strong argument can be made that taxexempt entities should be entitled to the benefits of integration. Such entities arguably are equivalent to taxpayers with a zero marginal tax rate. If tax-exempt entities do not receive the benefits of integration, then taxable shareholdi with very low marginal tax rates will be left with more dividend income after tax than charities. This anomaly led a tax law professor to ask us: "at what rate of tax are tax-exempts tax exempt?" In other words, denying charities the benefits of integration is equivalent to subjecting them to tax. The exact effect of denying the benefits of integration to tax-exempt shareholders is hard to predict. There is considerable concern that over a period of years this treatment might lead to a major shift of tax-exempt investors out of the equities market in favor of debt instruments at least with respect to new investments. Thus, as taxable and taxexempt shareholders readjust their portfolios, the anticipated revenue saving would not be realized and there would be significant transactional costs. In addition, this shift in - 24 - portfolios may undermine the positive impact on equity markets expected in connection with integration. Also, denial of the benefits of integration to charities will cause these institutions, to the extent they continue to own corporate equity, to exert pressure on corporations to continue high levels of cash dividend payouts. (Taxable shareholders might be willing to accept lower cash payouts because they would be receiving tax credits as a result of integration.) This will tend to force corporations to pass the entire benefit of integration through to shareholders. Such a result has been a major concern to corporate managers. In particular, tax-exempt pension trusts present difficult technical problems. It can be argued that it is appropriate to treat these trusts like other exempt organizations to the extent they receive dividends attributable to contributions made with pre-tax dollars. (Taxable income earned with respect to pre-tax dollars is mathematically equivalent to tax-exempt income earned with respect to after-tax dollars.) However, this argument is inapplicable to the extent these trusts receive dividends attributable to contributions made with after-tax dollars such as voluntary employee contributions. Any mechanism for allocating dividends between these sources would be extremely complex. - 25 A second category of shareholders presenting special considerations are financial intermediaries. These include mutual funds and real estate investment trusts for which a dividends paid deduction form of integration is provided under current law. In addition, there are life and casualty insurance companies, both mutual and investor owned, as well as commercial banks and other stock and mutual depository institutions. The tax treatment of these institutions has been developed over a period of many years and has been designed to insure that the tax system does not disrupt the competitive balance which exists among the different classes of institutions. Inclusion of these institutions in an integration program in such a way as to insure maintenance of that balance will require extensive study. Transactions Finally, there are a number of provisions under current law which in effect mitigate the effects of the present system of double taxation. These include the ability to liquidate a corporation, or make certain noncash dividend distributions, without recognizing unappreciated gain at the corporate level. These provisions introduce a substantial amount of complexity into the law and provide the impetus for much tax planning. These provisions should be studied - 26 in the context of an integration proposal, since integration is intended to provide an overall solution to the problems of double taxation. CONCLUSION We believe that integration has considerable merit. As the discussion indicates, however, experts are divided on some of the potential effects of the proposal, and various segments of the business community are divided on the technical aspects of its implementation. We believe further analysis and debate of these issues is essential. - 27 Footnotes 1/ Under the proposal, effective October 1, 1978, the corporate tax rate will be reduced from 20 percent to 18 percent of the first $25,000 of income, from 22 percent to 20 percent on the next $25,000 and from 48 percent to 45 percent on income exceeding $50,000. The maximum rate will be reduced by an additional point, to 44 percent, on January 1, 1980. 2/ The principal changes in the investment credit are (1) extension of its application to industrial structures, (2) extension of its application to pollution control facilities which are subject to rapid 5-year amortization, and (3) increase, generally from 50 to 90 percent, in the amount of tax liability which may be offset by the investment credit. 3/ In connection with its consideration of integration, the Administration also considered repeal of the $100 dividend exclusion allowed to individuals under current law. 4/ For example, assume corporations X and Y each earns $100 of taxable income on which each pays $48 of corporate tax, and in addition corporation Y earns $20 of preference income on which it pays no corporate tax. Assume further that each corporation has a sole shareholder in the 40 percent tax bracket to whom it distributes all of its aftertax income. Current Law X Corp. Y Corp. $100 economic income -48 corporate tax on $100 "52" $120 economic income -48 corporate tax on $100 72 Shareholder of X Corp. Shareholder of Y Corp. $ 72.00 dividend income $ 52.00 dividend income -28.80 tax (c*t 40% rate) -20.80 tax (at 40% rate) 43.20 cash after tax 31.20 cash after tax The value to the shareholder of the $20 preference income is $12 ($43.20 - $31.20). - 28 Ullman Proposal Fully Phased in X Corp. $100 economic income -48 corporate tax on $100 52 Shareholder Credit Account Corp $120 economic income -48 corporate tax on $100 72 Shareholder Credit Account $14.40 ($48 x .30) $14.40 ($48 x .30) Shareholder of X Corp. Shareholder of Y Corp. $ 72.00 dividend income $ 52.00 dividend income +14.40 gross up ($72 x .20) +10.40 gross up ($52 x .20) 86.40 62.40 34.56 tax (at 40% rate) 24.96 tax (at 40% rate) -14.40 credit -10.40 credit 20.16 51.84 net cashtax after tax 14.56 37.44 net cashtax after tax ($72 dividend - $20.16 tax ($52 dividend - $14.56 tax) The value to the shareholder of the $20 of preference income is $14.40 ($51.84 - $37.44). As illustrated above, the value of the preference is $12 under current law. The Ullman proposal makes preferences more valuable. Even though the preference income is not taxed at the corporate level the Ullman proposal provides tax relief when the preference income is distributed. As a result, the income is bearing less than one full level of tax. 5/ For example, assume a domestic corporation's only taxable income was $100 earned in a foreign country which imposed a $48 income tax, and that the corporation paid the remaining $52 to its U.S. shareholder who had a 30 percent marginal tax rate. Under current law the corporation will be allowed a $48 foreign tax credit and will owe no U.S. tax. If the entire $48 were treated as U.S. taxes paid under a system of integration which provided full dividend relief the results would be as follows: The shareholder would gross his dividend up by $4 8 (the taxes deemed paid by the corporation) and report $100 of taxable income. The shareholder would incur a $30 tax, offset by a $48 credit, and so would receive an $18 refund. The U.S. Treasury would be refunding taxes which were, in fact, paid to a foreign government. FOR'RELEASE -ON - DELIVERY Expected at 10:00 a.m. Friday, April 7, 1978 Statement of Roger C. Altman Assistant Secretary for Domestic Finance, before the HUD—Independent Agencies Subcommittee of the Senate Appropriations Committee Mr. Chairman and members of this distinguished Subcommittee: I appear before you today to discuss the plans of the Department of the Treasury as they relate to the administrative expenses of the Office of New York Finance. My testimony this morning will cover three major areas: first, a review of the New York City Seasonal Loan Program and the administration of that program; next a brief discussion regarding the Administration's proposal for federal financing assistance to New York beyond June 30, 1978; and finally, the level of appropriations we believe necessary to enable us to effectively administer and oversee this new proposal. History of-the"Loan-Program Under the New York City Seasonal Financing Act of 1975, the Treasury Department was authorized to extend up to $2.3 billion in short-term loans to the City to meet the cash flow imbalance occurring within the City's fiscal year. During its 1976 fiscal year, New York borrowed $1.26 billion and repaid it with interest, either on time or ahead of schedule. In fiscal 1977, $2.1 billion was borrowed and again repaid punctually. During this current year, the City has borrowed $1,875 billion and we expect payment on time or ahead of schedule. B-819 - 2 As you know, the Act requires Treasury to charge New York City one percent more than the rate on outstanding U. S. Government obligations of comparable maturity. As a result, this year's seasonal loans to New York will yield a net surplus of approximately $13 million which will be returned to Treasury's general fund. The aggregate net surplus received by Treasury during the course of the program should exceed $30 million. The administrative expenses associated with our monitoring of the Seasonal Financing program will aggregate approximately $3.5 million — $1,235 million in FY 1976, $1.09 million in FY 1977 and approximately $1.15 million in FY 1978. One could argue, therefore, that this seasonal program has not cost the U.S. taxpayers anything. Indeed, the U.S. Government has substantially profited from it. Recent ~Developments Under this program, the City has made significant progress toward financial independence, but its ability to borrow on its own has not been restored. Therefore, a primary purpose of the Seasonal Financing Act — to restore New York's access to conventional credit markets — has not been achieved. At Secretary Blumenthal's request, the City submitted a four year budget and financing plan to Treasury on January 20 of this year. The City's plan calls for the attainment of a balanced budget — according to GAAP — over the plan period. From a financing viewpoint, it also calls for an extension, on a declining level, of federal seasonal loans as well as long term federal loan guarantees. Without dwelling on the specifics of the City's financing plan, to which Secretary Blumenthal testified at great length before the House Subcommittee on Economic Stabilization, our judgment is that the budget plan is relatively sound. We do have certain reservations, however, concerning the financing plan. First, our analysis of the Plan leads us to conclude that the City can adequately provide for its capital requirements by selling somewhat less — perhaps $4 1/2 billion — than the $5.1 billion in long term securities provided in their plan between the years 1979-1982. Second, -3we believe that this reduced level of long-term financing can be assured with a more modest amount of federal financing assistance than the City has asked for. However, we have concluded that the City's solvency would not be assured in the absence of any federal lending assistance beyond June 30 of this year. While it is conceivable that if every contingency is favorably resolved, then no additional federal lending assistance to the City would be required. Yet, we do not believe it would be responsible to risk bankruptcy should events prove this judgment wrong. New York City in bankruptcy will prove far more expensive to this Nation than the modest form of federal assistance we have proposed for New York City. The'Administration-Financing-Proposal Therefore, in order to assure the financial solvency of New York City and eventually its financial independence, we have proposed that Congress (i) authorize the Secretary of the Treasury in the four years ending June 30, 1982, to guarantee for no more than fifteen years up to $2 billion in aggregate principal amount of taxable NYC or MAC securities with a minimum annual guarantee fee of 1/2% per annum payable on any outstanding guaranteed securities; and (ii) amend PL 94-236 to permit the City and State employee pension funds to purchase City or MAC securities during the 1979-1982 period. This financing proposal is based on three principles: that major responsibility must be assumed by local parties in the financing needs of New York City; that the City's budget be truly balanced by the end of the plan; and that the New York City financing crisis be resolved once and for all, restoring New York's ability to finance itself. I believe that, with the cooperation of the relevant local parties, this plan will lead New York City to a truly balanced budget by 1982 which should enable them to regain access to the public credit markets and return to financing themselves. Outside Legal-Services I think it might be appropriate for me to mention certain matters that have received this Committee's attention recently. I am referring to Treasury's retention of the law firm of Debevoise, Plimpton, Lyons & Gates and our utilization of staff resources. As you may know, the law firm was retained in order to assist Treasury in analyzing the numerous complex legal issues that arise in connection with any New York City - 4 financing plan. The amount and difficulty of the work required to analyze those issues was, in the judgment of the General Counsel, beyond the capacity of Treasury's existing staff, and it was not possible to expand our inhouse capacity, even on an interim basis, within the appropriate time frame. Therefore, Treasury decided to retain an outside law firm and the Debevoise firm was chosen. The circumstances surrounding those decisions are generally set forth in the letter of February 24, 1978 from Treasury's General Counsel to Mr. Frederick W. Rhodes of the Senate Appropriations Committee Staff, which with your permission I offer for the record. The Treasury continues to be satisfied that no improprieties or conflict-of-interest were involved. But in response to concerns that have been expressed about the importance of appearances in this area, Treasury and the Debevoise firm agreed to limit their contract to coverage of work-to-date and all work was completed last month. With regard to our utilization of staff resources, it is true that a small number of individuals were detailed elsewhere or otherwise not working exclusively on matters relating to New York City. Yet, the amount of man-hours devoted to the New York City financing issue by Treasury personnel has consistently exceeded, and by substantial amounts, the amount paid for from the administrative funds of the Office of New York Finance. Yet, because our use of personnel in this fashion might be considered by some not in conformance with the purpose of the New York City administrative fund, we have chosen to reassign those individuals who, though funded through the Office of New York Finance, worked on unrelated matters. All individuals funded through that account will spend a majority of their time on the New York City financing issue. Administrative-Expenses Our appropriation under the New York City Seasonal Financing Act, in fiscal 1978, is $1.15 million. The Administration is requesting that you appropriate the same amount for fiscal 1979. We would continue to exercise considerable management and oversight responsibilities if our guarantee proposal is enacted into law. In its present form, our proposal authorizes the Secretary of the Treasury to guarantee up to $2 billion of NYC or MAC securities. Yet Federal guarantees - 5 would be issued only to the extent that the public markets and private lenders do not provide the necessary funds on an unguaranteed basis. In other words, we will require the City to use its "best efforts" to borrow from unguaranteed sources, before any guarantees would be issued. A key responsibility of the Office of New York Finance, therefore, will be to administer this "best efforts" test. In general, I believe that the monitoring requirements involved in this type of guarantee agreement, are no less important than those requirements mandated through the seasonal loan program. Specifically, even though a credit agreement has not yet been drafted, we obviously will require the City to continue to submit to Treasury detailed financial reports on a regular basis — perhaps monthly, quarterly and annually. The analysis of this information will be important to assist the Secretary of the Treasury in assessing the extent to which New York City's financial problems are being solved in the post-1978 period. In addition, while we do not expect that the entire $2 billion of proposed guarantees will be used during the 1979-1982 period of authorization; a portion probably will be necessary. It is clear, therefore, that Treasury must maintain an active role in monitoring the finances of New York City at least through 1982. I am developing management plans for the Office of New York Finance, therefore, which are aimed at ensuring a four-year capability. As you recall, during the early stages of the Seasonal Financing Act, Treasury decided not to develop an in-house capacity to perform all of the functions involved in administering the loan program. Given the many imponderables at the time, the decision to rely on the expertise of outside consultants was sound. When I assumed responsibility for the Seasonal loan program in March of 1977, it made little sense to alter the administration of the program inasmuch as the existing authority expired on June 30, 1978. Yet, as the Seasonal Financing Act expires, and a new federal program takes its place, I believe it would make more sense and would be more cost-effective to expand on our in-house capacity and place less dependence on outside consultants. Let me turn now to our specific personnel and expense requirements. Presently, our professional, secretarial and clerical staff totals nineteen. As I previously mentioned, our fiscal '78 appropriation is $1.15 million. - 6 Of this amount, we have allocated approximately $400,000 for personnel compensation and benefits, nearly $675,000 for consultants, $25,000 for travel, $15,000 for rent, communication and utilities, and the remaining $35,000 or so for contingencies and miscellaneous items such as printing, equipment and supplies. For the two largest budget items — personnel and consultants it is my recommendation that, at a minimum, these dollar amounts be reversed — that we increase our staff to approximately 24 persons and reduce our dependency on outside consultants to a lower level, perhaps $400,000. Furthermore, this latter figure should decline in subsequent years. Regarding the location of our staff, I believe we should continue to maintain offices both in New York and Washington. The personnel located in New York City will take primary responsibility for reviewing the City's budget progress and audit its cash flow. This division will audit and verify the reports received from the City and, if necessary, recommend changes and improvements to the reports. It also will inspect accounts, books, records and other financial documents of the City or any financing agency participating in the financing needs of New York City in the post-1978 period. The Washington staff will continue to assess the City's financing progress and will advise the Secretary as to the use of any guarantees. In particular, it must find that there are adequate prospects of repayment on any guaranteed bonds. In order to execute this function, this office must maintain continuing liaison with other Federal agencies, the General Accounting Office, the private sector, representatives of the City and State and other agencies of New York, and, of course, the legislative branch. The Washington Office will be responsible for responding to legislative and constituent inquiries, Congressional testimony, preparing briefing papers and other policy documents to keep the Secretary, as well as other appropriate parties well informed. Let me close by saying that our recommendations on continued federal financing assistance for New York City are modest. Consistent with this approach, we have proposed a modest budget for the Administration of the o 0 o program. kpartmentoftheTREASURY ASHINGTON,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE EXPECTED AT 10:00 A.M., MST APRIL 7, 1978 ' REMARKS BY THE HONORABLE C. FRED BERGSTEN ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS BEFORE THE 1978 FINANCIAL CONFERENCE OF THE AMERICAN MINING CONGRESS ARIZONA BILTMORE HOTEL, PHOENIX, ARIZONA U. S. COMMODITY POLICY: THE INTEGRATION OF DOMESTIC AND INTERNATIONAL REQUIREMENTS It is a great pleasure for me to address the 1978 AMC Financial Conference on the commodity policy of the Carter Administration. Over the past fourteen months, we have sought to develop a comprehensive approach to this issue which can provide substantial benefits to both consumers and producers of primary commodities, in the United States and in other countries That policy seeks to integrate domestic and international elements into a single, coherent approach. In so doing, it has focussed on four interrelated, complementary policy instruments: — international commodity agreements between producers and consumers, to reduce excessive price volatility in world commodity markets; — promotion of increased productive capacity abroad for key raw materials through greater activity by the World Bank, the regional development banks, and our own Overseas Private Investment Corporation (OPIC); B-820 -2a strategic stockpile policy based on revised strategic objectives and implemented in ways which are consistent with our national and international economic goals; •7- support for the stabilization of export earnings of producing countries through the Compensatory Finance Facility of the International Monetary Fund. Acting OPIC President Poats will be discussing the invest- ment issues with you later in the program, and export earnings stabilization relates only indirectly to our own national needs. Hence I will focus today on our approach to international commodity agreements (ICAs), and on the relationship between U.S. domestic and international commodity policies as reflected in our current management of the strategic stockpile. International Commodity Agreements The prices of primary commodities are exceptionally unstable. It is not unusual for commodity prices to double or even triple within a year or two and then plummet back toward previous levels, though such behavior is extremely rare for manufactured or processsed goods. During the 1970's, commodity prices have been even more unstable than usual — particularly with the extraordinary surge which took place in 1973-74 and the subsequent decline during the 1975-76 recession. Recent price instability seems also to have been aggravated by commodity -3speculation and inventory buying, spurred by inflationary expectations and fears of impending shortages. The U.S. economy experiences real costs from such price instability. On the one hand, price surges for key raw materials spread throughout the economy, resulting in upward pressure on the general price level. On the other hand, precipitate and lasting declines in prices can deter investment in new productive capacity, leading to longer run price increases and even eventual shortages. Price fluctuations also increase the costs of producing and processing primary commodities. The greater the unpredictability of price fluctuations, the larger the risks associated with the industry — which are then reflected in the cost of capital, and the more frequent the shifts in rates of production. Even when large fluctuations are expected, manufacturers and processors who use primary commodity inputs experience increased costs by having to employ more working capital and hold larger inventories. Hence, ICAs which effectively reduce price instability can provide significant economic benefits for the United States: dampening of inflationary pressures, smoothing of income flows to U.S. commodity producers, more stable investment patterns over time, stabilizing and reducing operating costs for domestic producers and processors (and thus prices for their consumers). Moreover, such agreements -4spread the burden of responsibility for international commodity problems among producing and consuming countries, and promote cooperative efforts toward their solution. It is often argued that the market provides the optimal degree of price stability for commodity trade. this is not always the case. Unfortunately, The direct benefits of reducing commodity price fluctuations accrue to all buyers and sellers, whether or not they individually contribute to the cost of the stabilization arrangement; hence the incentive to individual market participants to contribute to the cost of stabilization is negligible, and the market alone will not call forth the appropriate institutions. the indirect benefits of price stabilization — reduction of overall inflation rates — In addition, notably the extend well beyond the universe of participants in the commodity markets themselves. Thus, price stability can be considered a public good, and an appropriate target for governmental action. Our task with respect to market stabilization is to devise economically rational, workable ICAs which stabilize prices while still allocating resources efficiently. This is no mean task, and the limited history of efforts to construct effective ICAs is strewn with failure. The theory is reasonably clear, but the practicality is exceedingly difficult. When we are successful in designing agreements which provide net economic benefits to the United States, we will join them. Otherwise, we will not. In fact, only a handful of -5agreements now seem feasible: ICAs already exist for tin, coffee, cocoa and most recently sugar, and advanced discussions are underway on wheat, natural rubber and copper. For other product^', such as tungsten and jute, we are extremely dubious despite proposals for ICAs emanating from some producing countries. In working on ICAs we believe that certain principles are essential to serve the multi-faceted interests of the United States as a major importer/consumer or exporter/ producer of virtually every primary commodity: — they must be designed to stabilize prices around underlying market trends, not to raise prices; — they must balance the interests of producers and consumers, in terms of responsibilities and benefits; — they must provide wide latitude for the operation of market forces. More detailed criteria depend upon whether the individual ICA is an international buffer stock arrangement or an export guota/national stocking scheme. I will discuss each in turn, suggesting the principles which should apply and drawing from concrete examples wherever possible. International Buffer Stocks We believe price stabilization agreements should operate wherever possible through buffer stocks. Bought when prices -6are low and sold when they are high, within an agreed price range, buffer stocks can be more effective than any other approach in stabilizing prices without distorting markets or production patterns. We even expect them to make profits to help cover operating costs. Buffer stocks are far preferable to supply controls regarding market efficiency, effectiveness, operational simplicity and consumer benefits: — Buffer stocks allow price to allocate resources to the most efficient producers, whereas production controls force low cost and high cost producers to cut back output equally, creating inefficient production patterns. Production and export quotas, usually allocated according to some historical average of market shares, tend to freeze the production/marketing status quo and bar entry by newer, possibly more efficient, producers. — Production and export quotas must cover a large percentage of world output, estimated to be up to 90 percent for some commodities, to avoid leakages which would otherwise undermine the arrangement. The wider their membership, the more complex becomes the allocation of quotas and the enforcement of operational provisions. By contrast, buffer stock arrangements can contribute to price stabilization regardless of output coverage -7or breadth of membership i^f the stocking authority and financing are sufficient — though it is desirable for all major producers and consumers to participate, to spread the costs of stock accumulation and ICA operation widely and equitably among those who receive the direct benefits of reducing price fluctuations. — The implementation of supply controls is usually based on previous years' data and other outdated information, and requires long lead times before having full impact on the market. Buffer stocking purchases and sales can be made quickly in response to market developments, can affect the market without delays, and require little data other than prices to guide operations. — Supply controls can benefit producers in the short run, by stemming price declines, but they often work to the disadvantage of consumers by reducing supplies, raising prices, and raising the average cost of production. Buffer stock purchases to halt a price decline also impose a cost on consumers, but subsequent sales from the stock eventually provide consumers with an offsetting benefit while permitting least cost producers to continue operating at optimal production levels throughout the price cycle. Buffer stocks are not suitable for every commodity. There are three basic criteria which must be met for this, our preferred, approach to apply to a given commodity. -8The first is that the international price must be established in an open market. A buffer stock would be ineffective for a commodity for which there is no "market" price. For example, open market sales of bauxite are rare due to the highly integrated nature of the international aluminum industry, and of tungsten because prices are set almost exclusively through individual, non-standardized contracts. Secondly, the commodity should be either non-perishable or easily rotated in storage facilities, so that stock, maintenance is feasible and carrying costs do not become exhorbitant. Storage is no problem for a number of commodities, but for others such as bananas and meat it would either be infeasible or the cost would be prohibitive. Thirdly, the commodity should be relatively homogeneous in the sense that most trading takes place in a limited number of well-defined grades whose prices move in tandem. There are at least fifteen grades of natural rubber, but most trade takes place in three grades for which price movements are highly correlated so that a benchmark is readily available. Lack of homogeneity would probably prohibit the establishment of buffer stocks for tungsten, oilseeds, or spices. Copper satisfies many of the economic conditions for a buffer stock arrangement including open trading, storeability and homogeneity and several studies indicate that -9substantial benefits could be achieved from stabilization of copper markets. However, there are a number of practical difficulties in establishing such an arrangement. The buffer stock required would be large and expensive: cost estimates vary from around $1.5 billion to $6 billion depending upon the width of the price range, the price at which copper is purchased, and the extent of any reliance on "back-up" supply controls. Moreover, any imposition of supply controls would cause legal difficulties for a number of producing countries; in the case of the United States, our laws may well prohibit their use. Nevertheless,we are continuing to examine the copper markets in an effort to see whether any kind of stabilization agreement is feasible. International discussions are now focussed on the establishment of a producer-consumer forum for copper, which is the most important traded commodity without an international locus for producer-consumer discussions. We expect such an international body to be established this year to: a) continue an examination of possible price stabilization arrangements, b) monitor trends in the copper market and conduct consultations and information exchange on market developments, and c) discuss and propose interim actions related to supply/demand, stocks and pricing. This body would eventually report its conclusions to a higher level producer/consumer preparatory group, which would take a decision on whether to convene a negotiating conference for an ICA for copper. -10In designing and evaluating buffer stock arrangements which will fully defend the interests of the United States, we seek: -,- stocks which are large enough to protect against price surges as well as price declines; — price ranges which are (1) compatible with the size of the Duffer stock, (2) easily adjustable to market trends, and (3) sufficiently wide to allow the market to operate effectively in allocating resources; — schemes which rule out the use of production controls and limit any use of export quotas to extreme market conditions, in order to allow the buffer stock to operate unencumbered within the price range set by the agreement; — assurance that the commodity sector in producing countries receives the direct benefits which accrue to those countries from stabilization, in order to benefit from the proper economic incentives for the commodity concerned. The Record to Date Many of the ICAs proposed for international discussion, and actually put into practice, have not met these criteria. As a result, the experience with ICAs has not ~\rsn in t-prms of achieving price stability always been encouraging in terms -11The buffer stock arrangements often advocated by producing countries incorporate "back-up" supply control features to permit a smaller, less costly buffer stock and assure defense of the floor price. But when production and/or export controls are used, the buffer stock is often unable to accumulate sufficient stock at the lower end of the range to defend the ceiling once there is a resurgence of prices. If the imposition of supply controls also forces producers to cut back output significantly, or drives out marginal cost producers, the result may be rapid price rebounds and destabilization of markets. This has been a frequent occurrence over the years with the International Tin Agreement (ITA). Experience with the ITA also vividly illustrates the necessity of achieving adequate buffer stocks through shared financing by producers and consumers. As the United States and other consuming countries joined the ITA over the years, most of them refused to contribute to the financing of the buffer stock. The result has been an undersized stock, incapable of stemming either price surges or declines. In essence, consuming countries failed to protect their own interests by this approach in the past. Since the first ITA in 1956, the tin market has undergone four major price declines. In each case, after purchases of tin and near financial exhaustion of the buffer stock, the Tin Council imposed export controls to protect the floor price. However, production cutbacks by -12private producers, who were unwilling to shoulder the burden of stocking the excess tin they could not export, soon followed. The result was tin shortages and rapid price rises that an inadequate buffer stock was powerless to moderate. Breaches in the price ceiling in 1961, 1963-66 and in the 1970's caused the Council to repeatedly raise the range and, with it, support levels which would later have to be defended again through export controls. Partly due to the most recent use of export controls in 1975, current market prices are above the ceiling and the buffer stock is exhausted. If the ITA had had a larger buffer stock over the past twenty years, it might have been successful in absorbing excess supplies during those major price declines, making export controls unnecessary and enhancing the capability of the buffer stock to defend against price surges. We have also been concerned that the ITA has been operated in a way that tends to accommodate tax and investment policies in producing countries discouraging production and new investment, and resulting in an ever-higher price floor. This situation has also contributed to the tripling of tin prices during the last six years. Last year we began to take action to overcome the three structural deficiencies in the tin market: (1) the Tin Council's wide discretion to resort to export controls, -13(2) its small, ineffective buffer stock and (3) tax and other policies in producing countries which act as disincentives to expanded production. < First, we moved last July to secure passage of a resolution in the Tin Council recommending that export controls be resorted to only when there is a surplus "beyond the capabilities of the buffer stock to absorb." Second, we have announced our intention to contribute up to 5,000 long tons of tin metal to the ITA buffer stock. A bill to authorize this contribution is now before Congress. We hope it will be enacted shortly and we urge you to support it. Enlargement of the buffer stock could be instrumental in creating an effective ITA, with the capability to stem future price surges and declines and thereby significantly reduce its reliance on export controls. This contribution will also demonstrate a new commitment on the part of the United States to share in the financing of commodity agreements which promote our economic interest, and it is symbolic of a new U.S. effort to work cooperatively and pragmatically with other producers and consumers toward effective solutions to commodity problems. Effective ICAs must have price ranges which are sufficiently wide to allow the market price to adequately perform its allocative function, while checking extreme price movements. The width of the range must also be compatible -14with the size of the buffer stock. The narrower the bandwidth, the larger the stock generally required to hold market prices within the band. With the U.S. and other consumer country contributions, we estimate that the ITA would have the capability of acquiring up to 75,000 tons of tin (in part by using tin warrants to borrow on the commercial market). Given the present bandwidth of +11 percent, however, it is questionable whether 75,000 tons would still be enough. Our analysis suggests that a bandwidth of +15 percent or wider may be required for compatibility with a 75,000 ton stock. Consequently^Utmay become necessary to widen the •i tin price range or to consider further increases in the size of the buffer stock. It is also important that ICAs provide sufficient flexibility to adjust the price band as underlying market forces shift, in order to continuously bracket the long term market trend. We will in no case sanction the establish- ment of agreements designed to raise prices above long-term market trends, or permit ICAs to operate in such a manner. It is therefore important that the United States participate actively, where appropriate, in the negotiation of ICAs and in their day-to-day operations once they are established. There is little we can do to prevent market- disruptive, producer country dominated ICAs if we do not take part. Our concern for economic rationality, market -15efficiency and a balance between producer and consumer interests — coupled with our market strength in most commodities — gives us the potential of assuring that ICAs are properly constructed and managed. Furthermore, we will insist that our market strength is translated into enough voting power in any ICA we join to insure us a significant say in its operation. It is quite possible that the ITA would have been a much more effective instrument for price stability had the United States participated in it fully from the outset, rather than standing aside. Our membership in the Tin Agreement has already begun to pay off. We have succeeded in moderating increases in the price range, and have been much more able to bring pressure on exporting countries to adopt market-oriented production policies than we could have from outside the ITA. High production and export taxes in some of the major producing countries have been a contributing cause of declining tin production and investment over the past five years. We took steps toward alleviating this problem by securing passage of a Tin Council resolution last summer which calls on producing countries to take "all reasonable administrative and fiscal steps to promote further expansion in the tin industry." Our efforts have produced some results so far, but we are continuing to press for further action. It is extremely important that the benefits from ICAs, such as improved income stability, flow directly to the sector producing the commodity itself. "Flow through -16assurance" is necessary if price floors are to benefit consumers by spurring continued investment in new productive capacity and avoiding longer term supply shortages. This is a sensitive issue because it touches the internal sovereignty of producing countries, but it is fundamental to the effectiveness of a price stabilization arrangement. No ICA can provide a balance of producer and consumer benefits if the operations of a marketing board or the levying of high producer taxes prevent expansion in producing sectors which the stabilization of prices through the ICA would otherwise call forth. Export Quota/National Stocking Schemes I have already indicated clearly our general opposition to supply controls as a price stabilizing mechanism. At the same time, there may be a case for export quota/national stocking schemes for commodities which are unsuitable for an internationally held buffer stock. This applies particularly to agricultural commodities, where price instability comes mainly from the supply side and which have low price and income elasticities. Periodic surpluses for these commodities may become much more burdensome and costly to absorb through pure buffer stock arrangements than for other commodities. The export quota/national stocking arrangement can promote greater price stability by coordinating the accumulation and release of national stocks through internationally agreed export quotas. Such arrangements should not deviate from the principles which I have laid out for -17buffer stocks except that there is greater reliance upon the export quota mechanism. In addition, these arrangements should provide for flexibility through frequent reallocation of quotas to permit efficient, lower cost producers to increase their market shares. Flexible reallocation provides added reassurance to consumers through the encouragement of investment by efficient producers who wish to increase their market shares in future years. There are two types of export quota/national stocking arrangements now in place, for coffee and sugar. They differ in the degree of reliance upon export quotas, versus stocks, to stabilize prices. Although the provisions of the 1976 Coffee Agreement have never gone into effect due to the 1975 Brazilian frost, the features of that Agreement bear a brief look. Price zones for quota adjustment may be set by the Coffee Council at the beginning of each coffee year in light of recent price trends. If no agreement is possible, price triggers for automatic quota imposition and suspension go into effect. These triggers are subject to biennial price review and can be revised as market conditions change. Unlike previous quota arrangements, the latest Coffee Agreement provides incentives for producing countries to maintain production and increase domestic stocks which can be released once prices begin to rise, by giving producers credit for holdings of national stocks in allocating export -18quotas. Further flexibility is provided by resetting and reallocating country quotas on the basis of actual export performance. For the new International Sugar Agreement (ISA), coordinated national stocks play a more important role in price stabilization. An initial stock buildup of 2.5 million tons of sugar is called for over the next three years—nearly three times the stocking requirements called for in the previous ISA. Once the stocks are accumulated, they must be made available for release to defend the Agreement's ceiling price in the event of a subsequent price runup. In contrast to the Coffee Agreement, where quotas play the primary stabilization role, quotas in the ISA are operated in conjunction with the stocking provisions. When prices decline toward the floor, quotas are triggered and producing countries are required to accumulate stocks with the latter actually taking precedence over export quota fulfillment. This provision helps to insure both market stabilization and that stocks will actually be accumulated for later use in defense of the ceiling price. The Administration has stated that the ISA is a cornerstone of its domestic sugar policy. But U.S. farm legis- lation requires us to support the domestic price of sugar at no less than 13.5 cents per pound, well above the current world price of 7.5 cents. Recently, the President implemented -19import duties and fees as required by Congress to assure that this target is met. Eventually, however, we expect the new ISA to raise the world price to a level which would permit the Secretary of Agriculture to suspend these duties and fees. And we anticipate that any future legislation affecting sugar prices will be designed as a backup to the ISA, in the event it fails to defend its floor price. Consequently, the negotiation and successful operation of the new International Sugar Agreement could prove to be a milestone in the coordination of U.S. domestic and international commodity policies. Strategic Stockpile Policy Coordination of domestic and international commodity policy raises an issue which has been of considerable interest to the American Mining Congress over the past several years: U.S. stockpile arrangements. The minerals industry has often been highly critical of Government management of the strategic stockpile. It has been alleged that certain actions over the last two and a half decades were taken in a seemingly haphazard way, often to achieve short term economic and political objectives. As you know, after the stockpile goals were reduced sharply in 1973, Congress refused to authorize further disposals — disposals which it was claimed had been proposed partly in response to widespread shortages and high prices for many materials, and partly to generate Government -20revenues that would help reduce the budget deficit. Since then, Congress, with industry support, has insisted that the Executive Branch re-examine stockpile guidelines and objectives. We think the Administration has been responsive to these concerns, and hope that we can now begin a new era of cooperation with industry and the Congress on this issue• The Carter Administration has adopted new stockpile goals which resulted from the 1975-76 interagency re-examination chaired by the Federal Preparedness Agency, and has been developing an annual materials plan for achieving them. Since these new goals are consistent with the needs of a wartime economy during a three-year global war, as opposed to the previous assumption of a one-year conflict, they will require large acquisitions and in some cases disposals. It will take several years to fulfill these goals. Thus, the requests for approval of acquisitions and disposals which have been transmitted to Congress for FY 1978-80 are only a beginning. For example, tin disposals are now scheduled for no more than 45,000 tons, though 167,000 tons of tin now in the stockpile are considered surplus. Similarly, legislative authorization is currently pending for the purchase of up to 225,000 tons of copper, far below the goal of 1,299,000 tons. The Administration is also supporting the principle of using proceeds from sales of surplus materials to purchase deficit materials. We are willing to hold those funds in a -21separate account for about two years. However, we oppose holding such proceeds indefinitely in escrow to fund future purchases. Such a procedure would violate accepted budget practice by tying up idle funds for several years. Two other principles are legally binding on the Administration in managing the stockpiles: (1) they should be used for strategic, not economic, purposes, and (2) acquisitions and disposals should not disrupt markets. Consequently, the General Services Administration is careful to avoid dumping commodities in a way that would depress prices below market trends. We recognize that disruptive selling has taken place in the past, but this Administration has no intention of engaging in such selling. We believe that quick Congressional action to provide for the sale of substantial amounts of tin (and the purchase of substantial amounts of copper) will help stabilize the tin market. The tin sales will serve to fill the expected deficit between tin production and consumption of 35,000-40,000 tons over the next three years and allow for minimal re-building of the buffer stock while maintaining tin prices within the ITA mid-range. Once the United States fully establishes its policy with respect to the tin stockpile, our efforts to improve the operation of the ITA buffer stock should be much more effective. Therefore, we feel that Administration support for such stockpile actions are not only consistent with our overall -22commodity policy but, as George Munroe of Phelps Dodge in his statement before the Subcommittee on Military Construction and Stockpiles put it last month, "... the exchange would permit GSA and the taxpayer the rare opportunity to observe and benefit from the maxim, 'buy low, sell'high,'/and/ ... do much to improve the health of the nation's copper-producing industry as can be accomplished by any single government action." Conclusion We have tried to develop a comprehensive policy to reduce the price instability for primary commodities which adversely affects the U.S. economy, its producers and its consumers. That policy is designed to promote the wide range of interests of the United States as a producer/exporter and consumer/importer of key raw materials. An important element is the active participation of the United States in the negotiation and operation of ICAs designed to stabilize commodity prices around their underlying market trends in a way which balances the interests of producers and consumers and leaves wide latitude for the operation of market forces. Where feasible, we prefer international buffer stocks that operate unencumbered by supply controls within wide, flexibly adjustable price ranges which bracket market trends. In order to achieve buffer stocks of sufficient -23size to be effective in protecting against both high and low prices, producing and consuming countries should share in the financing of such arrangements. Where an international buffer stock is not feasible or appropriate, we can accept producer-consumer arrangements which combine export quotas and nationally-held stocks if they include a flexible quota reallocation system and provide for the accumulation of sufficiently large stocks to protect consumers in the event of price surges. We believe ICAs that meet these criteria will promote U.S. economic interests. We will join those which do, and reject those that do not. It is important that the strategic stockpile policy not unduly disrupt markets, is not used for short-term political or economic purposes, and is consistent with our overall commodity policy. I believe this is now being done and I hope that we can look forward to a new era of cooperation between Congress, industry and the Administration in the operation of the annual materials plan to achieve our strategic stockpile goals. If we conduct our strategic stockpile policy in a consistent manner, and are successful in implementing our overall international policy, U.S. producers and consumers will benefit. The U.S. economy should experience more stable growth, with reduced inflationary pressures, in the years to come. Our economic relations with the developing -24countries, and with other industrialized countries, will be improved. We seek your support in carrying out the several key facets of this policy which I have discussed today. oOo THE SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY WASHINGTON 20220 Dear Mr. Mayor: I am writing to express my deep concern over the impasse that has developed in the labor contract negotiations in New York and what may be a trend toward expensive labor settlements. As you know, President Carter shares with you the goal of restoring New York City to economic and fiscal health, and hence the Administration is working actively with you in support of legislation in the Congress that will have that effect. However, without a speedy and responsible settlement between the City and its unions the prospect, in my view, of early and favorable Congressional action—which is essential to the City's future—is in real jeopardy. While we have not completed our analysis, I am concerned over the budget effects of extending the terms of the Transit Workers settlement to new contracts with the City unions. It is unclear to me that New York City could afford such a settlement and still remain within the four-year budget plan already presented to Treasury and the Congress. As I have repeatedly stated, a credible budget plan is crucial to the City's future and to the proposed federal legislation. Among other things, this means that increased labor costs must be financed from recurring revenues and true savings. Furthermore, I am also mindful, as I am sure you are, of the enormous burden placed on New York City's budget by the current levels of debt service. If your budgetary outlook has truly improved, I suggest that you and the unions consider applying additional funds to even modest reductions in the City's debt. This would augur well for New York's fiscal and economic future. 2 But equally important to obtaining Congressional action, is the necessity for speed in resolving the present impasse between the City and its unions. I realize the difficulties of this overall situation for you, the union leaders and members and for the people who live and work in New York. But I urge you and the unions to recognize that only a labor settlement reached quickly and reflecting extreme restraint will permit favorable Congressional action on the Administration's proposed New York City financing legislation. I would appreciate your continuing to keep us advised concerning the negotiations and potential budget effects. Sincerely, W. Michael Blumenthal The Honorable Edward I. Koch Mayor of New York City City Hall New York, New York 10007 Contact: FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 7, 1978 George G. Ross (202) 566-2356 REVISED INTERNATIONAL BOYCOTT REPORT AVAILABLE JUNE 1 AT IRS DISTRICT OFFICES The Treasury Department today announced that Form 5713, International Boycott Report, is being revised and is expected to be available through the local district offices of the Internal Revenue Service about June 1, 1978. The Treasury Department also announced interim procedures under which the time for filing Form 5713 has been extended to July 15, 1978. Filing of Form 5713 As detailed in Answer A-7 of the International Boycott Guidelines issued January 20, 1978 (published January 25, 1978 in 43 FR 3454), one copy of Form 5713 should be sent to the Internal Revenue Service Center, 11601 Roosevelt Boulevard, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania, 192 55, and another copy should be attached to the taxpayer's income tax return that is filed with the taxpayer's customary Internal Revenue Service Center. Both copies normally must be filed when the income tax return is due, including extensions. Interim Procedures Taxpayers whose income tax returns are due in 1978 before June 15, 1978 may satisfy their reporting obligations by complying with the following procedures: — Taxpayers who have no boycott participation or cooperation to report on Form 5713 may: (1) file the unrevised Form 5713 with their income tax return, or (2) use the normal procedures for obtaining an extension of time for filing the income tax return and file the revised Form 5713 when the income tax return is filed, or (3) file the income tax return without a Form 5713 attached and file the revised Form 5713 no later than July 15, 1978. If this last option is chosen, an amended tax return need not be filed with the Form 5713. Taxpayers who have boycott participation or cooperation to report on Form 5713 must file the revised Form 5713 and may not file the unrevised Form 5713. B-821 - 2 - These taxpayers may either: (1) use the normal procedures for obtaining extensions of time for filing the income tax return and file the revised Form 5713 when the tax return is filed, or (2) file the income tax return without a Form 5713 attached and file the revised Form 5713 no later than July 15, 1978. If the latter option is chosen, an amended income tax return must be filed with the revised Form 5713 unless there are no tax benefits to be lost as a result of the participation in or cooperation with the international boycott. * * * * * partmentoftheJREASURY TELEPHONE 566-2041 5HINGT0N,D.C. 20220 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 10, 1978 RESULTS OF TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL AUCTIONS Tenders for $2,304 million of 13-week Treasury bills and for $ ^»^01 million of ?6-week Treasury bills, both series to be issued on April 13, 1978, wer^accepted at the Federal Reserve Banks and Treasury today. The details are as follows: RANGE OF ACCEPTED COMPETITIVE BIDS: 13-week bills maturing July 13, 1978 Price High Low Average Discount Rate 98.392 a/ 98.388 98.389 Investment Rate 1/ 6.361% 6.56% 6.377% 6.57% 6.373% 6.57% 26-week bills maturing October 12T 1 978 Discount Investment Price Rate Rate 1/ 96.599 b/ 96.589 96.591 6.727% 6.747% 6.743% 7.06% 7.08% 7.08% a/ Excepting 1 tender of $600,000 b/ Excepting 1 tender of $10,000 Tenders at the low price for the 13-week bills were allotted 79%. Tenders at the low price for the 26-week bills were allotted 88%. TOTAL TENDERS RECEIVED AND ACCEPTED BY FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTS AND TREASURY: Location Received Boston $ 26,595,000 New York 4,053,435,000 Philadelphia 22,695,000 Cleveland 36,320,000 Richmond 56,500,000 Atlanta 31,385,000 Chicago 403,035,000 St. Louis 51,865,000 Minneapolis 25,725,000 Kansas City 44,040,000 Dallas 30,250,000 San Francisco 360,015,000 11,155,000 Treasury TOTALS $5,153,015,000 Accepted $ 20,760,000 1,910,385,000 18,160,000 31,665,000 18,900,000 31,385,000 55,725,000 21,700,000 7,725,000 40,575,000 24,095,000 111,415,000 11,155,000 Received $ 27,035,000 5,000,590,000 23,640,000 65,410,000 40,070,000 20,335,000 275,730,000 46,785,000 38,240,000 30,950,000 15,840,000 368,170,000 8,860,000 $2,303,645,000 £/ $5,961,655,000 Sj Includes $ 442,235, 000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. d/Includes $223,215,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. _1/Equivalent coupon-issue yield. B-82 Accepted $ 21,435,000 2,891,170,000 17,440,000 40,310,000 22,210,000 20,335,000 95,190,000 18,785,000 21,760,000 30,950,000 13,720,000 198,370,000 8,860,000 $3,400,535,000 jd/ FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE CONTACT: ROBERT W. CHILDERS (202) 634-5248 April 7, 1978 REVENUE SHARING DATA RELEASED TODAY The Office of Revenue Sharing today released the data to be used to allocate funds for Entitlement Period Ten of the General Revenue Sharing Program. The U.S. Department of the Treasury's Office of Revenue Sharing is sending the latest available figures on population, per capita income, local adjusted tax collections and intergovernmental transfers to each eligible unit of local government. State governments are being provided their most recent data for population, urbanized population, per capita income, state and local taxes, general tax effort, state individual income tax collections and Federal individual income tax liabilities. All recipient governments may review the figures and notify the Office of Revenue Sharing if they believe the figures are inaccurate. Data correction proposals should be received by the Office of Revenue Sharing by May 16, 1978. B-823 General revenue sharing funds are allocated according to formulas set by the revenue sharing law. The formulas use data provided primarily by the Bureau of Census, the Bureau of Economic Analysis, the Interna] Revenue Service and the Bureau of Indian Affairs. Quarterly payments for Entitlement Period Ten will be made in January, April, July and October 1979, to approximately 39,000 units of State and local government. A maximum of $6.85 billion will be distributed during the tenth entitlement period. Since the General Revenue Sharing Program was authorized in 1972, more than $38.6 billion has been distributed. -30- EMBARGOED FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY EMBARGOED FOR WIRE TRANSMISSION AT 1:30 P.M. APRIL 11, 1978 Office of the White House Press Secretary \ THE WHITE HOUSE TEXT OF THE ADDRESS BY THE PRESIDENT TO THE AMERICAN SOCIETY OF NEWSPAPER EDITORS APRIL 11, 1978 During the last 15 months we in the United States have made good progress in sustaining growth and creating jobs. Four-and-a-half million more people are at work today than fifteen months ago. The unemployment rate has fallen from nearly 8 percent to a little more than 6 percent. Average household income, after adjustment for both taxes and inflation, is 5 percent higher now than a year ago. Business profits in the second half of 1977 were 15 percent higher than one year before, and during that time the inflation rate was held to a reasonable and predictable level. But too many Americans -- particularly young people and members of minority groups -- are still without jobs. I am determined to sustain our economy's progress toward high employment and rising real income, with both existing programs and with new, carefully targeted incentives to encourage private business to hire the hard-core unemployed. We have other economic problems which cause us continuing deep concern. Our nation's economic health can be protected only if we can cope with the two developments that now threaten it most seriously — the high level of oil imports and the increasing rate of inflation. These two problems both imperil our economic recovery and threaten the strength of the dollar, and they must be controlled. The steps that we will take are part of a wider international effort by the major industrial nations to promote world recovery in 1978. In this effort, each country has a role to play — with the U.S. maintaining its growth while attacking inflation and limiting oil imports, other countries achieving their growth targets,and all countries avoiding protectionism and providing greater aid to developing countries. In the hope that this concerted approach will make a large contribution to world recovery, I joined the leaders of six other nations yesterday in announcing that we will meet on July 16 and 17 in Bonn to press ahead with our common efforts. But the first requirement is effective action within each nation. The primary reason for our problems with the balance of trade and the decreasing value of the dollar is no mystery. Ten years ago we were paying rouyhly $2 billion for imported oil. This year oil imports will cost us more than $45 billion. Our energy problems are no longer theoretical or potential They are an active threat to the economic well-being of our people. Of all the major countries in the world the United States is the only one without a national energy policy, and because the Congre has not acted, other nations have begun to doubt our will. Holders of dollars throughout the world have interpreted our failure to ?c as a sign of economic weakness, and these views have been direct! translated into a decreasing value of our currency. -2The falling dollar in international monetary markets makes inflation worse here at home. It raises the price of goods we import, and this makes it easier for domestic producers to raise their own prices as well. That is why we must have meaningful energy legislation without further delay. Our security depends on it, and our economy demands it. If Congress does not act, then oil imports will have to be limited by administrative action under present law, which is not the most desirable solution. One way or the other, oil imports must be reduced. Recently our healthy and sustained economic growth has exceeded that of most other nations who are our major trading partners, so we have been better able to buy their goods than they have to buy ours. Our standard of living and our ability to grow depend on the raw materials and goods we import from other countries. Therefore, to prevent further serious trade imbalances, we need to export more agricultural products and other goods and services to pay for our purchases abroad. A Cabinet-level task force, chaired by the Secretary of Commerce, will develop additional measures to promote exports, and will report back to me within 60 days. Now I will discuss the steps we must take to protect our national economic growth and the jobs and prosperity of our people from the threat of growing inflation. Conserving energy, increasing efficiency and productivity, eliminating waste, reducing oil imports and expanding our exports will help to fight inflation; but making that fight a success will require firm government policies and full private cooperation. The inflation we are suffering today began many years ago and was aggravated in 1973 and 1974 by a quadrupling of OPEC oil prices, widespread crop shortages, Soviet grain purchases, substantial devaluation of the dollar, and a worldwide industrial boom that led to double digit inflation in the United States and around the world. It now has become embedded in the very tissue of our economy. It has resisted the most severe recession in a generation. It persists because all of us — business and labor, farmers and consumers -are caught on a treadmill that none can stop alone. Each group tries to raise its income to keep up with present and anticipated rising costs; eventually we all lose the inflation battle together. There are no easy answers. We will not solve inflation by increasing unemployment. We will not impose wage and price controls. We will work with measures that avoid both extremes. Our tirst and most direct efforts are within government itself. Where government contributes to inflation, that contribution must be lessened; where government expenditures are too high, that spending must be reduced; where government imposes an inflationary burden on business, labor, and consumers, those burdens must be lightened; wherever government can set an example of restraint and efficiency, it must do so. -3- The budget I have proposed for the next fiscal year is both tight and capable of meeting the nation's most pressing needs. The prospective deficit in that budget is as large as we can afford without compromising our hopes for balanced economic growth and a declining inflation rate. As always, pressures are developing on all sides to increase spending and enlarge that deficit. Potential outlay increases in the 1979 budget which are now being considered by Congressional committees would add between $9 billion and $13 billion to spending levels next year. The price of some of these politically attractive programs would escalate rapidly in future years. I am especially concerned about tuition tax credits, highway and urban transit programs, postal service financing, farm legislation, and defense spending. By every means at my disposal, I will resist those pressures and protect the integrity of the budget. Indeed, as opportunities arise, we must work to reduce the budget deficit, and to ensure that beyond 1979 the deficit declines steadily and moves us toward a balanced budget. I will work closely with the Congress and, if necessary, will exercise my veto authority to keep the 1979 budget deficit at or below the limits I have proposed. The Federal government must also act directly to moderate inflation. Two months ago I proposed that in each industry and sector of the economy wage and price increases this year be voluntarily held significantly below the average increase for the two preceding years -an important principle of deceleration. I am determined to take the lead in breaking the wage and price spiral by holding Federal pay increases down. Last year, Federal white collar salaries rose by more than seven percent. I intend to propose a limit of about 5.5 percent this year, thereby setting an example for labor and industry to moderate price and wage increases. This year I will also freeze the pay of all Executive appointees and members of my senior staff. I believe that those who are most privileged in our nation -- including other executives in government and in private companies -- should set a similar example of restraint. State and local governments employ every seventh worker in our nation and I have sent letters to every Governor and to the Mayors of our larger cities asking that they follow the Federal example and hold down their pay increaes. I have also asked that if those governments plan to reduce taxes they first consider lowering sales taxes, which add directly to the consumer's burden. The Federal government will take several other steps to reduce inflation: All Executive Branch agencies will avoid or reduce the purchase of goods or services whose prices are rising rapidly, unless by so doing we would seriously jeopardize our national security or create serious unemployment. I am also asking that all new or renegotiated Federal contracts which contain price escalation clauses should reflect the principle of deceleration. MORE -4- — We must cut the inflationary costs which private industry bears as a result of government regulations. Last month I directed Executive regulatory agencies under my control to minimize the adverse economic consequences of their actions. I am determined to eliminate unnecessary regulations and to ensure that future regulations do not impose unnecessary costs on the American economy. Our efforts to reorganize the Federal bureaucracy and to streamline the Civil Service will help us put the government's house in order. I support "sunset" legislation to ensure that we review these regulatory programs every few years, and eliminate or change those that have become outdated. I also urge Congressional budget committees to report regularly to the Congress on the inflationary effect of pending legislation, much as the Council of Economic Advisors and the Council on Wage and Price Stability now report to me. — The combined actions of my Administration and the Civil Aeronautics Board have already led to substantial cuts in some airline passenger fares. Despite the opposition of private interests, the airline regulatory reform legislation must be enacted this year. We are also re-examining excessive Federal regulation of the trucking industry, an effort which may result in increased efficiency while reducing freight transportation costs and retail prices. In addition, I am asking the independent regulatory agencies to try to reduce inflation when they review rate changes, and to explore regulatory changes that can make the regulated industries more efficient. -- Last fall, major new legislation was passed which will improve economic conditions for farm families, and we have announced additional administrative action to raise farm income this year. Unfortunately, the Senate has just passed a bill that would raise food prices by 3 percent and the overall cost-of-living by .4 percent, shatter confidence in the crucial export markets for America's farm products, and cripple American farm families through increased costs. It is bad for farmers, bad for consumers, and bad for our nation. I will veto any farm legislation, beyond what I have already recommended, that would lead to higher food prices or budget expenditures. — Housing construction rates have been at a high level and costs have risen rapidly, partly because of sharp increases in the price of raw materials such as lumber. Since lumber accounts for one-fourth of the total cost of a new house, we can obtain some relief by increasing production and using our existing lumber -5- output more efficiently. Therefore, I have instructed the Departments of Agriculture and Interior, the Council on Environmental Quality, and my economic advisors, to report to me within 30 days on the best ways to sustain expanded timber harvests from Federal, State and private lands, and other means of increasing lumber yields in ways that would be environmentally acceptable, economically efficient and consistent with sound budget policy. — Daily hospital costs have jumped from $15 in 1950 to over $200 today, and physicians1 fees have risen 75 percent faster than other consumer prices. It is very important that Congress act now on the proposed Hospital Cost Containment Bill as the most effective step we can take toward reasonable hospital prices. Failure of Congress to act on the Hospital Cost Containment legislation will cost the taxpayer more than $18 billion in needless government spending over the next five years. Together with the airline deregulation bill, this is one of the two most important measures the Congress can pass to prevent inflation. These measures have so far been delayed by the opposition of powerful lobbying groups. I will continue to give this legislation my full support, and I call on the leaders of Congress to do the same. Such government actions as I have discussed today can be important steps toward controlling inflation. But it is a myth that the government itself can stop inflation. Success or failure in this overall effort will largely be determined by the actions of the private sector of the economy. I expect industry and labor to keep price, wage and salary increases significantly below the average rate for the last two years. Those who set medical, legal and other professional fees, college tuition rates, insurance premiums and other service charges must also join in. This will not be easy. But the example of Federal action must be matched. Inflation cannot be solved by placing the burden of fighting it only on a few. The Council on Wage and Price Stability recently began a series of meetings with representatives of business and of labor in major industries such as steel, automobiles, aluminum, paper, railroads, food processing, communications, lumber and the postal services. In consultation with the private parties the Council will identify the rate at which prices, wages and other costs have been rising in recent years, the outlook for the year ahead and the steps that can be taken to reduce inflation. Let me be blunt about this point. I am asking American workers to follow the example of Federal workers and accept a lower rate of wage increase. In return, they have a right to expect a comparable restraint in price increases for the goods and services they buy. Our national interest simply cannot withstand unreas•*.. ~ble increases in prices and wages. It is my responsibility to -;- .^ i; out firmly and clearly when the welfare of our people is at oers of my Administration have already discussed this deceleration program with a number of leaders of labor, business and industry. They have promised their cooperation. Later I expect to meet with -6- business and labor leaders to discuss contributions that they can make to help slow the rate of inflation. One of the most important contributions they can make is to show that restraint applies to everyone — not just the men and women on the assembly line, but also the managers in the executive suites. Just as I will freeze the pay of the top executives in the Federal government, the American people will expect similar restraint from the leaders of American business and labor. I am determined to devote the power of my office toward the objective of reduced inflation. Our approach must be flexible enough to account for the variations in our complex economy — but it must be comprehensive enough to cover most of the activities of our economy. In the long run, we should develop special programs to deal with sectors of the economy where government actions have the greatest potential for reducing inflation. These include housing, medical care, food, transportation, energ\ and the primary metals industries. The members of my Cabinet will woik individually and with the Council on Wage and Price Stability tc develop and to announce early action to reduce inflation within pheir own areas of responsibility. To accomplish our deceleration goa^s in the private sector, I am asking my Special Trade Representative, fypbert Strauss, to take on additional duties as a Special Counselor on Inflation. He will work with me, with Treasury Secretary Blumenthal, my phief financial spokesman, with Charlie Schultze, the Chairman of -he Council on Wage and Price Stability and its Executive Director, Barry Bosworth. He will have specific authority to speak for me in the public interest, and will be a member of the Steering Committee of the Economic Policy Group under the chairmanship of Secretary Blumenthal. Reducing the inflation rate will not be easy and it will not come overnight. We must admit to ourselves that we will never cope successfully with challenge until we face some unpleasant facts about our problems, about the solutions, and about ourselves. The problems of this generation are, in a way, more difficult than those of a generation before. We face no sharply focused crisis or threat which might make us forget our differences and rally to the defense of the common good. We all want something to be done about our problems -- except when the solutions affect us. We want to conserve energy, but not to change our wasteful habits. We favor sacrifice, as long as others go first. We want to abolish tux loopholes — unless it's our loophole. We denounce special interests, except for our own. No Act of Congress, no program Qf our government, no order of my own can bring out the quality that we need: to change from the preoccupation with self that can cripple our national will, to a willingness to acknowledge and to sacrifice for the common good. As the nation prepared for the challenge of war, Walter Lippmann addressed these words to our nation forty years ago: "You took the good things for granted," he said. "Now you must earn them again. It is written: for every right that you cherish, you have a duty which you must fulfill. For every hope that you entertain, you have a task you must perform. For every good that you wish could happen . . . you will have to sacrifice your comfort and ease. There is nothing for nothing any longer." These words of admonition apply to us now. (tpanmentoftheTR[/[$URY ^SHINGTON, D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 April 11, 1978 MEMORANDUM FOR THE PRESS: Secretary Blumenthal will hold a news conference 11 A.M., Wednesday, April 12, in the Cash Room # FOR RELEASE AT 4:00 P.M. April 11, 1978 TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL OFFERING The Department of the Treasury, by this public notice, invites tenders for two series of Treasury bills totaling approximately $5,700 million, to be issued April 20, 1978. This offering will result in a pay-down for the Treasury of about $6,015 million as the maturing bills are outstanding in the amount of $11,715 million ($3,004 million of which represents 139-day bills issued December 2, 1977, and $3,004 million of which represents 43-day bills issued March 8, 1978). The two series offered are as follows: 91-day bills (to maturity date) for approximately $2,300 million, representing an additional amount of bills dated January 19, 1978, and to mature July 20, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 S3 1), originally issued in the amount of $ 3,409 million, the additional and original bills to be freely interchangeable. 182-day bills for approximately $ 3,400 million to be dated April 20, 1978, and to mature October 19, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 T8 9) . Both series of bills will be issued for cash and in exchange for Treasury bills maturing April 20, 1978. Federal Reserve Banks, for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities, presently hold $3,332 million of the maturing bills. These accounts may exchange bills they hold for the bills now being offered at the weighted average prices of accepted competitive tenders. The bills will be issued on a discount basis under competitive and noncompetitive bidding, and at maturity their par amount will be payable without interest. Except for definitive bills in the $100,000 denomination, which will be available only to investors who are able to show that they are required by law or regulation to hold securities in physical form, both series of bills will be issued entirely in book-entry form in a minimum amount of $10,000 and in any higher $5,000 multiple, on the records either of the Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or of the Department of the Treasury. Tenders will be received at Federal Reserve Banks and Branches and at the Bureau of the Public Debt, Washington, D. C. 20226, up to 1:30 p.m., Eastern Standard time, Monday, April 17, 1978. Form PD 4632-2 (for 26-week series) or Form PD 4632-3 (for 13-week series) should be used to submit tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. B-824 -2Each tender must be for a minimum of $10,000. Tenders over $10,000 must be in multiples of $5,000* In the case of competitive tenders the price offered must be expressed on the basis of 100, with not more than three decimals, e.g., 99.925. Fractions may not be used. banking institutions and dealers who make primary markets in Government securities and report daily to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York their positions in and porrowings on such securities may submit tenders for account of customers, if the names of the customers and the amount for each customer are furnished. Others are only permitted to submit tenders for their own account. Payment for the full par amount of the bills applied £or must accompany all tenders submitted for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. A cash adjustment will be made on all accepted tenders for the difference between the par payment submitted and the actual issue price as determined in the auction. No deposit need accompany tenders from incorporated banks and trust companies and from responsible and recognized dealers in investment securities for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or for bills issued in bearer form, where authorized. A deposit of 2 percent of the par amount of the bills applied for must accompany tenders for such bills from others, unless an express guaranty of payment by an incorporated bank or trust company accompanies the tenders. Public announcement will be made by the Department of the Treasury of the amount and price range of accepted bids. Competitive bidders will be advised of the acceptance or rejection of their tenders. The Secretary of the Treasury expressly reserves the right to accept or reject any or all tenders, in whole or in part, and the Secretary's action shall be final. Subject to these reservations, noncompetitive tenders for each issue for $500,000 or less without stated price from any one bidder will be accepted in full at the weighted average price (in three decimals) of accepted competitive bids for the respective issues. Settlement for accepted tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, and bills issued in bearer form must be made or completed at the Federal Reserve Bank or Branch or at the Bureau of the Public Debt on April 20, 1978, in cash or other immediately available funds or in Treasury bills maturing April differences accepted 20,in 1978. exchange between the Cash andpar the adjustments value issueof price the will of maturing be the made new bills for bills. -3Under Sections 454(b) and 1221(5) of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954 the amount of discount at which these bills are sold is considered to accrue when the bills are sold, redeemed or otherwise disposed of, and the bills are excluded from consideration as capital assets. Accordingly, the owner of these bills (other than life insurance companies) must include in his or her Federal income tax return, as ordinary gain or loss, the difference between the price paid for the bills, whether on original issue or on subsequent purchase, and the amount actually received either upon sale or redemption at maturity during the taxable year for which the return is made. Department of the Treasury Circulars, No. 418 (current revision), Public Debt Series - Nos. 26-76 and 27-76, and this notice, prescribe the terms of these Treasury bills and govern the conditions of their issue. Copies of the circulars and tender forms may be obtained from any Federal Reserve Bank or Branch, or from the Bureau of the Public Debt. FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 11, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY DEPARTMENT ANNOUNCES START OF ANTIDUMPING INVESTIGATIONS OF PHOTOGRAPHIC COLOR PAPER FROM JAPAN AND WEST GERMANY The Treasury Department said today that it will begin antidumping investigations of photographic color paper imported from Japan and West Germany. The Treasury's announcement followed a summary investigation conducted by the U. S. Customs Service after receipt of a petition filed by the Minnesota Mining & Manufacturing Company alleging that this product is being dumped in the United States. The petition alleges that photographic color paper is being exported from Japan and West Germany at prices below those in the home markets. The petition is directed against photographic color negative paper, which is used to make color prints from color negative film. These cases are being referred to the U. S. International Trade Commission (ITC). Should the ITC find (within 30 days) that there is no reasonable indication of injury or likelihood of injury to a domestic industry, the investigations will be terminated. Otherwise, the Treasury will continue its investigations into the question of sales at less than fair value. (Dumping occurs when there are both sales at less than fair value and injury to a U. S. industry.) Notice of these actions will be published in the Federal Register of April 12, 1978. Imports of photoaraphic color paper from Japan and West Germany were valued at approximately $33 million and $29.5 million, respectively, during calendar year 1977. o B-825 0 co For Release 9:30 A.M. EST April 13, 1978 STATEMENT BY DONALD C. LUBICK ACTING ASSISTANT SECRETARY FOR TAX POLICY DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES Ocean Mining Legislation I am pleased to appear before you today to discuss the Treasury Department's view of financial aspects of deep seabed mining. H.R. 3350 is before you today because of its revenue sharing provisions. The Administration is developing specific proposals pertaining to the taxation of seabed mining income and the customs duties applicable to deep seabed nodules. But in view of the complexity of the tax issues and the other, complex issues before this Committee, the Congress, the Administration and the industry all agreed to consider non-tax provisions now. The Administration believes, however, that tax and tariff provisions should move in tandem with the ocean mining bills before the Congress and that the issuance of permits for commercial recovery should be deferred until tariff and tax provisions are enacted. The tax and tariff proposals will be submitted shortly. Accordingly, my testimony this morning will be addressed to why we endorse the provisions for revenue sharing and how those payments will be treated for tax purposes under existing law. Sharing of Revenues With the International Community All nations are agreed that the resources of the ocean should be managed for the benefit of the entire world community. The Administration embraces that concept and it believes that any domestic regulatory regime should provide for a sharing of the revenues from ocean mining at the B-826 -2outset. Consequently, if revenue sharing provisions are included in current legislation, U.S. companies will understand, and plan accordingly, that their operations will have to include payments to the international community from the beginning of commercial operations. The proposed regulation stipulates that a permittee will pay 3.75 percent of the imputed value of the minerals recovered from the seabed into a special Treasury account. The burden of such payments on seabed mining companies should be extremely modest. First of all, the rate is relatively low. Second, the rate applies to the minerals as they are removed from the seabed, which we have estimated to be 20 percent of the value of metals sold. We think it inappropriate to apply international revenue sharing to the transportation, processing, and distribution activities which are clearly outside the seabed resource area. The United States will continue to pursue this position at the current LOS negotiations. Finally, the payments provided under the proposed legislation are to be made in proportion to the value of minerals actually removed, rather than as a fixed license or production fee to be paid in advance. The Secretary of the Treasury would supervise the receipts, disbursements and management of the fund. There already are a number of similar special accounts which the Secretary of the Treasury supervises and standard procedures have been set up to insure safe and efficient management. He would invest the funds in appropriate U.S. Government securities which pay prevailing interest rates and the income from the investment would be added to the account. In addition, the Secretary of the administering agency will issue, before any permit to recover minerals is granted, necessary regulations to carry out the intent of the law with respect to the fund. In the event that the U.S. does not become a party to an international agreement within 10 years, payments will be terminated and the funds will be used as decided by the Executive Branch and the Congress. Tax Treatment of Revenue Payments of how payments I would like to turn Sharing to the questions made to the revenue sharing account will be treated for tax -3purposes under existing law. The primary rationale for a revenue sharing account is that seabed nodules are the "common heritage of all mankind". The revenue sharing requirements in the proposed legislation are in lieu of payments to a true owner of the seabed nodules for the right to take that resource. Accordingly, such payments would appropriately be deducted from the gross income of a seabed miner, much as a royalty payment to a true owner would be. As I stated at the outset, the Administration is not proposing specific tax amendments at this time. Nor are we addressing the issue of U.S. tax treatment of revenuesharing payments to an international seabed authority under a convention. We would like to reserve for the future an opportunity to share with you our analysis of existing law and our proposals for change. In this context, we would call your attention to the Administration's proposal that Section 107 of the bill before you today be deleted and replaced with the following: "Section 107. Act not to affect tax or customs treatment of Seabed Mining Nothing in this Act shall affect the application of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954, as amended or the Tariff Act of 1930, as amended." Without this specific wording, we believe that H.R. 3350 might convey tax benefits that the Ways and Means Committee would wish to consider more fully in the context of a broad package of tax amendments. Accordingly, we would urge you to accept the Administration's proposal for changing Section 107 as indicated above. In conclusion, I would urge your acceptance of the revenue sharing provisions and the postponement of the * consideration of any tax provisions, explicit or implicit. To assure this second objective, we believe that Section 107 should be amended as indicated above and that tax provisions be enacted before any permits for commercial recovery are issued. I appreciate this opportunity to discuss our views with you. I will be glad to answer your questions. oOo FOR RELEASE AT 4:00 P.M. April 12, 1978 TREASURY TO AUCTION $2,171 MILLION OF 2-YEAR NOTES The Department of the Treasury will auction $2,171 million of 2-year notes to refund $2,171 million of notes held by the public maturing April 30, 1978. Additional amounts of these notes may be issued at the average price of accepted tenders to Government accounts and to Federal Reserve Banks for their own account in exchange for $403 million maturing notes held by them, and to Federal Reserve Banks as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities for new cash only. Details about the new security are given in the attached highlights of the offering and in the official offering circular. oOo Attachment B-827 HIGHLIGHTS OF TREASURY OFFERING TO THE PUBLIC OF 2-YEAR NOTES TO BE ISSUED MAY 1, 1978 April 12, 1978 Amount Offered: To the public $2,171 million Description of Security: H I , ' Term and type of security Series and CUSIP designation •. ..«,<;. 2-year notes Series N-1980 (CUSIP No.< 912827 HR 6) Maturity daite ." .".*. April 30, 1980 Call date. :vr. .......... *.*. . No .provision Interest coupon rate ...;.. . , To be determined based on '£*. ->-'- n the. average of accepted bids Investment yield....."...;. To be determined at auction Premium or discount .. . . . To be determined after auction Interest payment dates.-... October 31 and April 30 Minimum denomination available $5,000 Terms of Sale: Method of sale Yield auction Accrued interest payable by investor None Preferred allotment Noncompetitive bid for $1,000,000 or less Deposit requirement 5% of face amount Deposit guarantee by designated institutions Acceptable Key Dates: Deadline for receipt of tenders Settlement date (final payment due) a) cash or Federal funds b) check drawn on bank within FRB district where submitted c) check drawn on bank outside FRB district where submitted Delivery date for coupon securities. Wednesday, April 19, 1978, by 1:30 p.m., EST Monday, May 1, 1978 Wednesday, April 26, 1978 Tuesday, April 25, 1978 Monday, May 1, 1978 partmentoftheJREASURY SHINGTQN,D.C. 20220 ELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 14, 1978 TREASURY REQUESTS AUTHORITY CONCERNING FUTURES TRADING BASED ON GOVERNMENT SECURITIES The Treasury Department yesterday recommended that "the Commodity Exchange Act be amended to grant the Secretary of the Treasury a limited authority with respect to future contract markets based on Government securities consistent with the protection of vital national interests." The Treasury proposal was made in letters from Deputy Secretary Robert Car swell to Senator Patrick J. Leahy, Chairman of the Senate Subcommittee on Agricultural Research and General Legislation and Representative Ed Jones, Chairman of the House Subcommittee on Conservation and Credit. The letter asked that the Secretary: * be granted the final right to approve or disapprove the designation of contract markets in futures contract based on securities issued or guaranteed by the United States or Federal agencies; * be authorized to suspend trading in futures contracts, to disapprove any existing or proposed delivery dates for transactions in designated contract markets and to revoke the designation of contract markets; * be granted discretionary authority to take these actions to avoid potential adverse impact of such trading upon the issuance of, or trading in, the underlying Government securities, and * be granted access to information from the Commodity Futures Trading Commission which he deems necessary in the exercise of "his authority. The text of the letter is attached. B - 828 THE DEPUTY SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY WASHINGTON. D.C. 20220 APR 1 3 1978 Dear Mr. Chairman: I would like to take this opportunity to comment on the legislation before you, K.R. 10285, which would extend the life of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC). The Treasury is primarily interested in the potential impact of this legislation on the market for securities issued or guaranteed by the United States or Federal agencies. I will confine my comments here, which are on behalf of the Administration, to that issue. The Government securities market is the core of the money and capital markets in the United States. It is by far the largest, most resilient and efficient market in the world. Price movements in Government securities can and do affect all of our financial markets and the strength of our economy. The continued stability and efficiency of the Government securities market are vital to the Nation's economic health and to the ability of the Treasury to finance the national debt. In 1977, the Treasury through market refinancings and new issues sold $198 billion of Government securities principally through auctions to participants in the overthe-counter market for Government securities. The low cost and efficiency with which this volume of securities was sold are the result of the steady and responsible development of this market over many years. The Market for Government Securities The over-the-counter market for Government securities is principally a cash market involving sophisticated dealers in Government securities and institutional investors, such as banks, pension funds, savings and loan associations, state and local governments, insurance companies and corporations. In addition to buying and selling for next day delivery, trading activity in the over-the-counter market includes entering into repurchase agreements, reverse repurchase agreements, when-issued trading, short selling and entering into contracts for forward delivery, some of which have elements lin common with trading in futures contracts on organized exchanges. 2 The breadth and liquidity of the Government securities market are not only important to the Treasury's capacity to finance the national debt but are also vital to the implementation of monetary policy. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York, operating on behalf of the Federal Open Market Committee, conducts operations in the market to affect the level of member bank reserves and thus the availability of credit in the economy. A highly liquid Government securities market is essential to the ability of the Federal Reserve to inject into or absorb from the commercial banking system a large volume of reserves temporarily — often overnight — o r on a more permanent basis. Prices of Government securities serve as a benchmark in pricing securities of other public and private issuers and as such are important to markets for other debt securities. The unique credit standing of the U.S. Government, the large amount of outstanding Government securities and the high volume of trading across the maturity spectrum make the prices of Government securities the most reliable index of the financial markets. The importance of this market to the Nation and its financial system cannot be overstated. It is a national asset that must be carefully protected. The Commodity Exchange Act The 1974 amendment to the Commodity Exchange Act, which created the CFTC, charged that agency with designating contract markets for futures transactions in commodities; that is, determining which futures contracts may be traded on organized exchanges. The CFTC was also charged with the regulation of trading activity in futures markets. Under the 1974 amendment, the scope of the CFTC extends not only to agricultural and other tangible commodities, but also to securities, since the amendment broadened the definition of "commodity" to include all financial instruments. Thus, the CFTC has jurisdiction over futures trading based on Government securities. 3 When the 1974 amendment was being considered by Congress, the Treasury recommended that the role of the CFTC with respect to Government securities be limited to futures contracts sold on organized exchanges. Congress adopted this recommendation, providing that: Nothing in this Act shall be deemed to govern or in any way be applicable to transactions in... government securities, unless such transactions involve the sale thereof for future delivery conducted on a board of trade. Growth in Futures Trading Based on Government Securities In 1974 there was no organized trading in futures contracts based on Government securities although for many years — as I have discussed above — there has been trading activity of a similar nature to futures contract trading on an exchange. The growth of futures trading on exchanges since then has been explosive. CFTC first authorized the commencement of trading in futures contracts based on Government securities in October 1974 when the Chicago Board of Trade introduced trading on futures contracts based on mortgage pass-through securities guaranteed by the Government National Mortgage Association (GNMA). Because of the hedging opportunities afforded mortgage origination and the willingness of speculators to assume market risks, the growth in trading activity in these contracts soared. In 1976, trading in GNMA futures contracts amounted to a total of $12.9 billion. In 1977, total trading jumped to $42.4 billion. On January 6, 1976, trading in futures contracts based on 13-week Treasury bills commenced on the International Monetary Market (IMM) of the Chicago Mercantile Exchange. The growth of trading activity in this contract rose from a total of $110 billion in 1976 to $322 billion in 1977. The average daily trading volume during 1977 totaled almost $1.3 billion, and reached a high in December 1977 of $2.3 billion. The December total equaled about 30% of trading activity in the market for the underlying Treasury bills as reported by the primary dealers. At the end of 1977, open interest (long or short positions which have not been closed out by offsetting transactions) amounted to $17.2 billion. 4 In August 1977, the Chicago Board of Trade initiated trading in futures contracts based on Government bonds. It is too early to determine the receptivity of the market to this new instrument. I have appended to this letter a table illustrating the dramatic growth of trading in each of these three contracts. New Proposals * The CFTC is currently considering two additional contract market designations based on Government securities. These proposals, both of which were submitted by the IMM, involve futures contracts based on 52-week Treasury bills and Treasury coupon issues that at the time of delivery, have four years remaining until maturity (4-year notes). The 52-week bill proposal is similar to the existing futures contracts based on 13-week bills, but the 4-year note proposal is different from currently traded futures contracts based on Government securities. The proposal provides that the deliverable security will be a specific issue which is currently outstanding and which, at the time of delivery, will mature in four years. In other words, all outstanding Government securities with more than four years to maturity would eventually become eligible for futures trading. Most of these securities will have been outstanding for some time when futures contracts based on them become eligible for trading. Studies conducted by the Treasury and by the Federal Reserve indicate that trading activity in Treasury notes and bonds declines substantially with the length of time a security has been outstanding. Consequently, trading in the over-the-counter market in securities covered by the 4-year note proposal is likely to be quite small compared to trading activity in newly offered securities. A thinly traded security more easily facilitates the manipulation of the price of that security, and therefore futures contracts based on that security. The Treasury has serious reservations concerning the 4-year note proposal. 5 CFTC - Treasury Consultations Prior to designating contract markets for futures contracts based on each of the three Government securities now subject to futures trading, and in connection with its review of the two proposals now pending, CFTC staff has informally requested the Treasury's views on the proposed contract designation. The weight given to Treasury views is, under the statute, entirely within the discretion of the CFTC. Thus, under the present arrangement the Treasury has no statutory basis for exercising its responsibility to insure the continued proper and efficient functioning of the Government securities market with respect to this large and growing market. Oversight of the Government Securities Market The over-the-counter market for Government securities is overseen jointly by the Treasury and the Federal Reserve acting as Treasury's agent. Government securities are exempt from registration requirements under the Securities Act of 1933. The role of the Treasury and Federal Reserve is one of careful and continuous market surveillance rather than structured and formal regulation. We believe that this approach has contributed greatly to the development of the extraordinary efficiency and resiliency of this market. The Treasury Department and the Federal Reserve System engage in daily oversight of the trading activities of the primary dealers, i.e. those dealers reporting their operating statistics each day to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. Some of the primary dealers, because of their other activities, are also subject to the registration requirements of^ the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and CFTC or, in the case of commercial bank dealers, to supervision by the banking authorities. Nonetheless, the primary oversight of their activities in the Government securities market has been exercised by the Treasury and the Federal Reserve. 6 In addition to the collection of financial statistics which commenced in 1958 and has beer, expanded subsequently, the Treasury and the Federal Reserve in 1966 established a Joint Treasury-Federal Reserve System Committee charged with the continuing review of the performance of the Government securities market and the investigation of situations which might involve trading abuses. Two recent examples of the exercise of this latter function involved close cooperation with, and the provision of expert technical assistance to, regulatory agencies. Treasury and Federal Reserve experts assisted Internal Revenue Service (IRS) inspectors investigating alleged leaks of Treasury financial announcements prior to release, and subsequently provided expert assistance to the SEC in investigating alleged fraudulent behavior uncovered by the IRS investigators. Within the past few months, the Treasury advised the SEC of the possibility of fraudulent trading activity in GNMA securities, and the Treasury and Federal Reserve provided expert assistance to the SEC in the initial phases of its investigation of such activity. Information gathering by the Treasury and the Federal Reserve is facilitated by continuous market contact. The Federal Reserve Bank of New York conducts daily interviews with senior members of the primary cealer firms to discuss developments in trading activity. In addition, the New York Fed's trading desk communicates daily with the primary dealers. The Treasury Department also is in continuous contact with the market, although on a less extensive scale. Senior staff members discuss market developments by telephone and through personal contacts with senior representatives of primary dealer firms and other financial institutions. The extensive contact between Treasury and Federal Reserve personel and participants in the Government securities market has aided the recognition of developments which have required supervisory or regulatory attention. 7 The* Need _for_a TreasuryPolo in the Futures Market In 1974 it was not clear what future contractu based on Government secur i t. i es would be de.s Lgna t eel for trading on exchanges or what the consequence:; of such designations liiiqhl be*. II i <; now clear that the volume? and variety of these futures; contracts have become significant. Yet the Treasury Department, which lias the general responsibility for the sale of Government securities and the integrity of the market for these securities, presently has no authority with respect to one portion of the market based on such securities, namely, the futures contract market. It is important to recognize that there is a direct link between Government securities price movements in the over-the-counter market and price movements of futures contracts based on those securities. In the Treasury bill futures market, for example, speculation and arbitrage quickly limit any growing divergence between over-thecounter and futures prices. A security dealer who wished to establish a speculative position in Treasury bills probably would buy either the outstanding bills or, if they were less expensive after accounting for financing costs, futures contracts based on the bills. Also, arbitragers would quickly move to minimize distortions in the price relationship between the over-the-counter and futures markets. Consequently, abuses in the futures market could lead to price distortions in the over-the-counter market. It is not apparent, however, that futures contracts based on Government securities serve the price discovery function which is generally cited by the CFTC as a major element in their economic purpose tests for determining appropriate contract market designations. The Government securities market is unique in that frequent new issues by the Treasury, combined with active secondary market trading in a large volume of outstanding securities of various maturities, result in a market "yield curve" at any point in time which serves as an indication of interest rate expectations and of the price the Treasury would be required to pay in auctioning a new issue. It is also important to recognize that the futures market has the potential of interfering with the debt management responsibilities of the Treasury. To the extent that market participants substitute futures contracts for their holdings of underlying securities, funds could be diverted from new issues or refinancings of Government securities or from the market for outstanding issues, a result that could produce a higher borrowing cost for the Federal Government. 8 We must also be concerned about potential futures market abuses. The low margin required for purchasing a futures contract based on Government securities enhances the potential for abuses. Individuals and institutions can speculate with a small amount of money — a $1,200 initial margin permits an investor to purchase a $1,000,000 Treasury bill futures contract — in return for the opportunity of reaping a proportionately large profit or suffering a proportionately large loss. The low margin requirement, in conjunction with the risk-free nature of Government securities, could result in, or indeed encourage, excessive speculation. Any speculative abuse could have an adverse effect psychologically on investor's perceptions of the underlying Government securities. That could only result in higher cost financing and potential impairment of the efficiency and resiliency of the Government securities market. As the number of futures contracts based on Government securities rises, the potential for markets in those contracts to affect over-the-counter market prices of the underlying securities will, in all likelihood, also rise. The development of the market for futures contracts based on Government securities is in an embryonic stage. The expansion of these new markets must be diligently monitored and action taken as necessary to insure the continued proper and efficient functioning of the over-the-counter market and the ability of the Federal Government to finance the national debt. The Treasury is not in a position today to take whatever actions might be required to insure such continued proper and efficient functioning. Recommendations The Treasury is vitally concerned with the continued integrity and efficiency of the over-the-counter market for Government securities. Moreover, the Treasury must be and is concerned with the impact of our financing operations on the broader money and capital markets. Yet, under existing law Treasury has no authority to approve or disapprove the designation of futures contract markets based on Government securities, nor does it have authority to revoke contract market designations or to suspend futures trading based on Government securities where such trading does or may adversely impact the primary market. Exclusive regulatory authority now rests with the CFTC. 9 The Treasury Department recommends that the Commodity Exchange Act be amended to grant the Secretary of the Treasury a limited authority with respect to futures contract markets based on Government securities consistent with the protection of vital national interests. We are proposing that the Secretary be granted the final right to approve or disapprove the designation of contract markets in futures contracts based on securities issued or guaranteed by the United States or Federal agencies. The Secretary should also be authorized to suspend trading in futures contracts, to disapprove any existing or proposed delivery date for transactions in designated contract markets and to revoke the designation of contract n.arkets. The Secretary should be granted discretionary authority to take these actions to avoid potential adverse impact of such trading upon the issuance of, or trading in, the underlying Government securities. To perform this function, the Secretary must also be granted access to information from the CFTC which he deems necessary in the exercise of his authority. I have appended the Administration's proposed bill to amend the Commodity Exchange Act for the purposes discussed in this letter. The Administration is not taking a position at this time on any aspects of S.2391 other than as expressed in this letter. The Administration does not recommend that the regulatory responsibilities of the CFTC be vested in the Treasury; nor do we recommend that the Treasury assume the sole responsibility to approve the designation of contract markets in futures contracts based on Government securities. We believe that our proposed amendment would assure the continued efficiency and integrity of the Government securities market without unduly encumbering the existing regulatory structure. 10 The Department has been advised by the Office of Management and Budget that the submission of the proposed amendment is in accord with the program of the President. Sincerely, f&TQy- <-GLS> Robert Carswell The Honorable Ed Jones Chairman, Subcommittee on Conservation and Credit Committee on Agriculture House of Representatives Washington, D.C. 20515 Enclosures epartmentoftheTREASURY £H!NGT0N,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 Statement of Stephen J. Friedman Deputy Assistant Secretary for Capital Markets Policy Department of the Treasury Before the Securities and Exchange Commission * Hearings on the Impact of Securities Regulation on Small Business Capital Formation April 13, 1978 3:00 p.m. The Treasury Department is pleased to have,the opportunity to participate in the Commission's examination of the impact of Federal securities regulation on the ability of small businesses to raise capital. It is essential that smaller businesses have access to adequate capital flows, and the Commission's decision to examine its role in this area is an important step. My testimony this afternoon is addressed principally to one development: the increasing trend toward formalization of the disclosure rules for private placements, a trend reflected in the provisions of Rule 146 and in the case law under^Section 4(2). Our views may be briefly summarized: — small businesses play a central role in our economy. — like all American business, they have experienced great difficulty in raising eguity capital. — the eguity problem is exacerbated for new or growing small businesses because they have little or no access to the public markets. — the trend toward imposing disclosure patterns developed for the public markets on private placements should be reversed, since it places added costs on the raising of capital by small businesses that are not required for the protection of investors or the policies underlying Section 4(2) of the Securities Act. B-829 - 2 The Role of Small Business Small businesses comprise a large sector of the economy. They represent 97 percent of the total number of the nation's business concerns; and they account for 43 percent of our gross national product and 58 percent of our non-agricultural work force. 1/ Even more important, small businesses represent a significant source of competition, innovation and growth. Studies indicate that small firms contribute at least their share of technological innovations and may well provide a proportionately greater share of the more important ones. 2/ Economists have highlighted the relationship of technological innovation to economic growth: new technology creates increased productivity, lower inflation and lower unemployment; it promotes the competitiveness of U.S. products in both domestic and world markets. 3/ The Importance of Capital An adequate supply of capital is important to all businesses, and particularly high technology companies. They are capital-intensive and often require substantial development periods during which there is little or no cash flow. For them, the availability of eguity capital is critical. A study performed for the Department of Commerce found that during the period 1970-1971, small technology-based firms obtained almost 50 percent of their external financing in the form of equity, and only 13 percent in the form of long-term debt. In contrast, 1/ U.S. Small Business Administration, The Study of Small Business (June 3, 1977) at 3. 2/ See Daniel Hamburg, R&D: Essays on the Economics of Research and Development (New York: Random House, 1966); Edwin Mansfield et al., Research and Innovation in the Modern Corporation (New York: Norton, 1971). K. Pavitt and S. Wald, The Conditions for Success in Technological Innovation (Paris, OECD, 1971). 3/ See, G. Tassey, The Effectiveness of Venture Capital Markets in the U.S. Economy, 25 Public Policy 483-4 (1977); Speech of Frank Press, Science Adviser to President Carter, titled: Science and Technology: The Road Ahead (February 13, 1978). - 3 small manufacturing firms obtained only eight percent of their external capital from eguity investment during that period. 4/ The concern about undercapitalization runs strongly through out the whole small business community. In our conversations with small businessmen and our review of government financing programs for minority businesses, the theme of a need for more eguity, and a fear of expanding debt-equity ratios, has been present. Access to Public Markets In considering the role of disclosure policy in the capital raising process for small companies, it is useful to think separately about the markets for publicly-traded and privately-placed securities. For the consequences of taking one route rather than another are great, even leaving wholly aside the regulatory costs of the offering itself. For example, the public markets provide liquidity, which not only enhances the value of the securities sold, but those retained by the management. The impersonality of the investor relationship may make it easier for the management to retain control. Having public stockholders brings with it a series of costly and time-consuming disclosure burdens and other legal obligations. Indeed, it is those very disclosure rules and legal obligations that have done much to make the public markets so efficient. In contrast, a private placement can usually be done faster; but the illiquidity of the investment means that shares will be less valuable and the issue more costly for the issuer. Investors traditionally have less formal disclosure, but are in a position to undertake a personal investigation of the issuer. Moreover, investors often ask for and receive a larger voice in the business, through contractual provisions or otherwise, than is true in public offerings. In theory, an issuer will take all of these factors, plus the costs of complying with disclosure requirements, into account in determining where it will seek its capital. But, at least since 1972, a large number of smaller companies do not appear to haveAssociates, had a realistic choice.of Venture Capital 4/ Charles River An Analysis Market Imperfections prepared for Experimental Technology Incentives Program, National Bureau of Standards at 12 (February 1976) . - 4In recent years, smaller companies have had a difficult time in securing equity capital. While there is little data on the amount of private equity financing by small companies, we do know from available data that public eauity offerings by small companies have fallen dramatically. Registered securities offerings by smaller companies — those with a net worth of less than $5 million — have dropped from a high of 698 in a single year, 1969, to only 42 in the three years of 1974 through 1976. 5/ There has been a similar precipitous fall in the number of offerings by companies seeking public equity for the first time. In 1977, such offerings totaled only $264 million compared to $3.3 billion for the year of 1972. 6/ For the first two months of 1978, such offerings totaled only $3.25 million. 7/ There is much debate over the causes of reduced flows of equity to issuers, particularly to small companies. In general, it is our judgment that inflation has been the most significant cause. It has eroded corporate profits, increasing greatly the cost of equity to issuers. And it has raised the yield on debt securities, further decreasing the attractiveness of riskier equity securities. Other observers emphasize changes since 1969 in the effective tax rates on capital gains in decreasing the returns on equity. In addition, there are a number of factors that have special impact on the public securities markets. Recent stock market losses incurred by investors appear to have caused more conservative investor behavior — that is, a general reduction in the level of risk taking and a shortening of acceptable investment time horizons. The trend toward increased institutionalization of the securities markets and the decline of individual participation in the markets has reduced the pool of money available to small, growing companies. Finally, structural changes in the securities industry also play some role. We have received some evidence that 5/ Venture Capital New Issueinterest Barometer, 1974-1976, suggests that there Journal, is sharply lower in market(Capital Publishing Corporation). making activities for smaller companies. It may be that 6/ Investment Dealers Diqest, Corporate Financing Directory (March 7, 1978 and March 1972)". 2/ Investment Dealers Diqest, Corporate Financing Directory (unpublished data) . - 5 the 300,000 or 400,000 share first offering that was typical of the late 1960's no longer presents a profitable market-making opportunity. Any such trend would be exaggerated by the recent reductions in the number of brokerage firms. And the greater concentration may also mean that there are fewer firms making it their business to underwrite the securities of small issuers. For all these reasons, many small businessmen simply do not have a meaningful choice between private and public markets. Moreover, in addition to the difficulties in bringing small businesses to market, the threshold amounts for a public offering appear to have escalated substantially. Recent reports of public offerings by venture capitalist-backed companies with a net worth under $5 million showed that of 29 such issues in 1977, 21 were in excess of $2 million; for 1976, 27 of the 32 such issues were over $2 million. 8»/ It may be that the drop in the number of Regulation A offerings, from almost 400 in 1974 to about 125 in 1975 and 1976, also,-, reflects the fact that the Regulation A ceilings are too ,,-' low. 9/ For the smaller amounts, either because of relative costs 10/ or market acceptance, the issuer must stay in the private placement market. We do not suggest that all small companies, particularly unseasoned ones, should have access to the public markets. But in the current market and regulatory environment even small companies which are sufficiently seasoned to tap the public equity market are unable to do so. The need for equity financing in the early stages of a company's life can only be satisfied by a venture capitalist. Used in this sense, the term focuses not on the character of the investor, but on the character of the investment:, it is a private placement exhibiting high risk, a lack of liquidity,. a substantial intended holding period and, if successful,,high returns. the difficulty of Barometer, raising equity publicly, 8/ VentureBecause CapitalofJournal, New Issue 1976-1977 (Capital Publishing Corporation). V Securities and Exchange Commission, 37 Statistical Bulletin No. 1 at 31 (January 1978). 10/ The costs of registered public offerings are proportionately larger for smaller issues. See, Securities and Exchange Commission, Cost of Flotation of Registered Issues 1971-1972 at 9 (December 1974) . - 6 the venture capitalist must also furnish the second, third and perhaps fourth rounds of financing as well. It is important to keep in mind that what I have called the "venture capitalist" is a term that covers a wide variety of investors: friends and relatives, middle class and wealthy individuals, professional venture capital investors and, in the later stages, institutions. The Role of Regulatory Costs What role do regulatory costs play in this process? Some studies have sought to quantify those costs, particularly in the case of public offerings. 11/ I must confess to some level of skepticism about the work done thus far. If one thing is clear, it is that we have all too few facts about what is going on in the real world in this area. For that reason, we are encouraged by the Commission's current effort, under agreement with the Department of Commerce's National Bureau of Standards Experimental Technology Program, to establish a permanent system for monitoring the impact of securities regulation on capital raising by small, technology-based businesses. This monitoring system should serve as a valuable tool in analyzing the costs and benefits of many of the Commission's rules and regulations which are the subject of these hearings. Nevertheless, we must deal with the information that is now available. In doing so, I believe that some preliminary judgments can be formed without the help of empirical data. It is clear that the costs of disclosure — under both the 1933 Act and the 1934 Act — are rising. Nevertheless, we believe that in the case of the public markets, the Commission's disclosure policies have done much to generate public confidence in the integrity of our markets. While the process of considering the value of these policies is and should be a continuing 11/ Securities and Exchange Commission, Costa of Flotation of one, 12/ rigorous disclosure is, in effect, ticket of admisIssues 1971-1972, (December 1974). Charles River sion Registered to the public markets. Associates, An Analysis of Venture Capital Market Imperfections, prepared for Experimental Technology Incentives Program, National Bureau of Standards at 402-410. 12/ The work of the Commission's Advisory Committee on Corporate Disclosure represents the latest attempt to review our corporate disclosure policies. -7For the reasons discussed below, we do not think the price of admission to the private placement market should be as high. Even though it is more difficult to quantify the impact of regulatory costs on private placements, it is clear from the chorus of complaints that the participants believe it is too high. And, in our view, many of the considerations that prompt rigorous disclosure policies in the public markets are not applicable to private placements. Moreover, the special importance of giving attention to the impact of regulatory costs on those seeking capital in the private placement market is evident if the public eguity market is closed to smaller issuers seeking relatively small — but still substantial in absolute terms — amounts of equity. Those issuers do not have the choice of going to the public or private markets for equity, weighing the costs of each course, including the costs of complying with disclosure requirements. Their only choice is the private placement market. As the regulatory costs rise, the "margin" of companies that find the total cost of raising capital too high will broaden; for them, the flow of external equity funds Placement is choked Disclosure off. Developments in Private Policies Let us examine Rule 146. Paragraph (e) specifies the kind of information an offeree is required to have, or have access to, in the course of a private placement. The note to this paragraph makes it clear that "access" can only be conferred by a special relationship to the issuer or by economic power. For individual investors, often the source of capital for smaller companies, neither position nor economic power confers the necessary access. Accordingly, an issuer seeking the certainty that the Rule was designed to afford has no choice but to supply substantially the same information that would be required in a registration statement. At that point, the rules of the public marketplace have been imported into the private financing area. And this aspect of the Rule may well have a highly selective impact. In the case of stronger companies, that can attract institutional investors, the burden of preparing an elaborate disclosure document is not imposed. The smaller, undercapitalized company that must depend upon individual investors has the greater disclosure burden in private placements. This emphasis in Rule 146 on disclosure standards is, of course, also found in some of the cases under Section 4(2). In - 8 cases like Woolf v. S. D. Conn & Co. 13/ and Doran v. PetroleumManagement Corporation 14/, the courts have emphasized that issuers relying on the Common law" of Section 4(2) must make available substantially the same information as if registration were undertaken. Public vs. Private Disclosure Policies We applaud the proposal in Securities Act Release 5913 to lower the disclosure requirements for Rule 146 sales under $500,000 from the Form S-l standard to the Regulation A standard. Nevertheless, in our view the Commission should go further and consider reversing the trend toward requiring formal disclosure in private placements. In many respects, the disclosure rules adopted for public markets do not serve the same policy objectives in the context of private placements. First, disclosure rules have been developed with a view toward serving the needs of the public markets for reliable and timely information that will enable the markets to make the most efficient allocation of resources in the economy. The public securities markets, most economists agree, have an impressive capacity to digest and disseminate complex and even fragmentary information in a short period of time so that securities prices at any time reflect all information available to the market. 15/ The present SEC-administered system of mandated corporate disclosure is premised on the belief that market forces and selfinterest alone cannot be relied upon to assure a sufficient flow of timely and reliable information to the market place. 16/ Thus, many disclosure questions have been resolved in favor of greater disclosure in order to improve the efficiency of the public market. This consideration 13/ 515 F.2d 591 (5th Cir. 1975). is not present in the private 14/ 545 F.2d 893 (5th Cir. 1977). IV This is the efficient markets hypothesis. See generally, Fama and Miller, Theory of Finance (New York 1972) ; West and Tinic, The Economics of the Stock Market, 2-4 (1971); Baumal, The Stock Market and Economic Efficiency (1965). 16/ See, Report of the Advisory Committee on Corporate Disclosure to the Securities and Exchange Commission, Volume 1 at II (November 3, 1977). - 9 markets. A private placement is essentially a face-to-face transaction in which either the investor or his representative can ask questions and probe the facts. There is no "market" to process the information. The basic question concerns the information in which the investor is interested and his ability to evaluate it. In a public offering, the issuer's relationship to investors is impersonal and indirect. The Commission must develop formal disclosure rules to protect investors. Investors cannot ask questions or talk to management; they can only choose not to buy. In addition, the potential for abuse is greater in the case of public offerings, which are distributed through organized sales efforts and general advertising and solicitation. For these reasons, we do not think the Commission should require formal disclosure as a condition to obtaining the benefit of an exemption under Section 4(2) of the Securities Act. Reliance should be placed on the anti-fraud rules to protect purchasers, and such factors as the manner of offering and the number and character of the investors would demarcate the line between private and public transactions. We do not believe that an elimination of the formal disclosure requirements would result in damage to investors. Certainly, in the case of private placements by reporting companies, investors will ask for, and receive, the available documents. Institutional investors and others that are experienced enough to know what to ask for are in a position to make their own investigation. Is there really any substantial group left? If the suitability rules of Rule 146 and the analogous requirements of sophistication imposed by some cases are effective, the remaining group also should be in a position to protect itself, either individually or through represe tatives. We believe that this suggestion is consistent with the structure of the Securities Act and with its evolution. I doubt that Congress ever intended that the level of formal disclosure be the same for private placements as it is for public offerings. 17/ The policy question raised by the private placement exemption is this: under what circumstance is it permissible for a company to issue securities without registration? It seems to me strange 17/ See Coles, Has Securities Law Regulation in the Private Capital Markets Become a Deterrent to Capital Growth: A Critical Review, 58 Marquette Law Review 395 (1975). - 10 to answer that question by saying "when the issuer has done about the same thing as if it had registered, absent only Securities Act liability and SEC staff review." Of course, there are those who believe that the exemption afforded by Section 4(2) was developed only for isolated transactions and that formal disclosure was to be the rule for sales of securities. In response, I would point out that the disclosure system has evolved to a point where that is no longer practical. The extent and cost of disclosure are such that to impose the existing system on the private capital-raising process for smaller businesses would be unreasonable. The course suggested leaves open at least two possible undesirable developments. On the one hand, a desire to conform to the anti-fraud rules may, in time, generate similar formal disclosure practices. At the other extreme, practices could develop that would seriously diminish the protection afforded investors. We cannot predict with certainty the likely outcome. We believe, however, that a combination of the impact of the anti-fraud rules and the demands of the marketplace for information are more likely to produce useful information practices than an attempt to establish the correct level of disclosure by rule. Prior to Rule 146, the anti-fraud rules do not seem to have compelled the development of an elaborate disclosure document for private placements in all cases. It has been the adoption of that Rule and, even more important, increasing sensitivity to the liability of professionals, that has powered this development. It is not yet clear how the Hochfelder 18/ case will impact the professional liability question. But if the Commission is to be successful in reducing the burdens of disclosure where it makes sense to do so, this is an area which requires increasing attention. Before turning to the public securities markets, I would like to say a brief word about Rule 144, which regulates the resale of securities purchased by investors in private placements, called "restricted securities". The operation of this rule, in our view, appears to have a very important impact on the ability of small companies to raise capital under the private offering exemption. Rule 144 is designed to insure that purchasers of restricted securities do not act as conduits for the sale to the public of unregistered securities of issuers concerning which adeauate 18/ Ernst & Ernst v. Hochfelder, 96 S.Ct. 1375 (1976). - 11 current information is not available to the public. Thus, the Rule prohibits resale of restricted securities unless the issuer has been subject to the reporting reguirements of the Securities Exchange Act for at least 90 days prior to the sale of the securities, and the purchaser has held the securities for at least a minimum period of two years. Moreover, the securities must be offered in such a manner and in such quantities as not to disrupt the trading markets. They can be sold only in normal trading transactions with no unusual brokerage commissions and the amounts that can be offered in a specified time period are limited. s To the extent that Rule 144 restricts the ability of investor to sell their investments in small businesses, it tends to reduce the liquidity of such investments, and thereby discourages the flow of capital into small businesses. Moreover, investors holding restricted securities in small companies may be encouraged to sell their ownership interests to larger companies in order to liquidate their investments, thereby contributing to the undesirable trend toward increased concentration within the economy. We recognize that the Commission has been, and is, addressing these concerns. Through recent action, the Commission has increased the availability of the streamlined Form S-16 so that more holders of restricted securities may be able to sell their holdings in secondary distributions under the less costly Form S-16 registration statement. However, Form S-16 provides no relief for investors in newly-reporting companies since Form S-16 is available only to issuers which have reported under the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 for a period of three years prior to the registration. Thus, Rule 144 may still be having a large impact on investment in small newly-reporting companies. For this reason we are pleased that the Commission's Directorate of Economic and Policy Research has underway a study designed to assess the market impact of sales under Rule 144. We hope that, if the results of this study show that sales under the present volume and rate of sale limitations of Rule 144 are not having a significant market impact, the Commission will consider loosening these limitations, perhaps on an experimental Public basis. Offerings Before closing, I would like to say a word about public offerings of securities. As I explained earlier, we support the basic notion that rigorous disclosure is an appropriate - 12 condition of entry to the public markets. Nevertheless, while the disclosure system has enhanced the efficiency and fairness of the U. S. securities markets, there is evidence that the costs of disclosure bear more heavily on small companies. The Commission's most recent study of the cost of flotation of registered issues covering the period 1970 through 1972 found that the costs of flotation are proportionately larger for smaller issues. To illustrate, the study found that for registered stock offerings under $1 million, the average underwriter's compensation, or spread, amounted to about 12.5 percent and other expenses to about 8.25 percent of the gross proceeds of the offering. In other words, net proceeds to the issuer- were slightly less than 80 percent of the aggregate offering price. Contrast this with offerings in the range of $20 to $50 million. For these, underwriters' compensation averaged 4.4 percent and other costs .6 percent, for total costs of 5 percent, enabling the issuer to net about 95 percent of the aggregate offering price. 19/ More recently, the findings of the Commission's Advisory Committee on Corporate Disclosure also tend to substantiate this inverse relationship between the relative costs of flotation and the size of the issuer. 20/ Congress recognized the especially burdensome impact of the disclosure requirements on small companies by authorizing the Commission to exempt securities from registration where it finds that registration is not necessary to the public interest because of the small amount involved or the limited character of the offering. 21/ The major small issue exemption promulgated by the Commission under this authority is Regulation A, which permits small firms to raise up to $500,000 in any one year without registration. The Regulation reauires the issuer to file with the regional office of the Commission a notification and offering circular which contain less extensive 19/ Securities and Exchange Commission, Cost than of Flotation of narrative and financial statement disclosure that required Registered Issues 1971-1972, at 9, (December 1974). 20/ Report of the Advisory Committee on Corporate Disclosure to the Securities and Exchange Commission, Volume 1 at pp. 22-28. 21/ This is the "small issue" exemption of section 3(b) of the Securities Act of 1933. - 13 on a Form S-l. Because Regulation A offerings are reviewed at the regional offices rather than at the Commission's headquarters, Regulation A offerings were intended to provide a more expeditious review process than registered offerings. As the Commission has noted, 2_2/ the number of Regulation A offerings has decreased dramatically in recent years. This decline in the use of Regulation A is a matter of concern. We believe that the exemption provides the basis for a reasonable balancing of the needs for investor protection against the costs of public offerings to small issuers. Thus, we believe it is important that the exemption works effectively for smaller companies. While many explanations for the decline of Regulation A offerings have been advanced, it does seem that one important barrier to the use of Regulation A is the $500,000 ceiling on Regulation A offerings. The available evidence suggests that offerings of this size cannot be economically underwritten by investment banking firms. 23/ Thus, in order to encourage reputable investment bankers to underwrite Regulation A offerings, the ceiling on Regulation A offerings should be raised at least to $2.5 million, and possibly $3 million. A common complaint often voiced with regard to Regulation A is that the exemption is too costly and time consuming. Delay in obtaining financing can be especially critical to new small 22/ Securities and Exchange Commission, Release No. 33-5914, 34-14529 at 40. 23/ The average costs of registered public offerings under $2 million totaled over 16 percent of the gross proceeds during the period 1971-1972. Securities and Exchange Commission, Cost of Flotation of Registered Issuer 19711972 at 9 (December 1974). Few registered securities offerings of under $2 million in amount appear to have been made in recent years. The SBA Task Force on Venture and Equity Capital found that few securities firms will underwrite an issue of less than $3 million. Report of the SBA Task Force, on Venture and Equity Capital, at 16 (January 1977). Investment bankers specializing in underwriting small companies have stated that the costs of a Form S-l registration make it virtually uneconomical to underwrite an offering below $2 million. See address of William Hambrecht, general partner of the firm of Hambrecht and Quist, before the Securities Regulation Institute of the University of California Conference (January 20, 1978). - 14 companies, which may require an immediate infusion of equity to maintain their creditworthiness. We believe it is important that the Commission consider carefully ways in which it might provide for more expedited review of Regulation A offerings and reduce their costs, to the extent consistent with the protection of investors. While we appreciate the substantial efforts of the Commission's staff in attempting to devise a simplified registration statement for public offerings not exceeding $3 million, we doubt that the proposed Form S-18 would result in significant cost savings over a Form S-l registration statement. We believe more meaningful relief for the small company can be achieved through lifting the ceiling on Regulation A offerings. Once a company, and its lawyers, accountants and underwriters, incur the fixed costs of a due diligence investigation and preparation of the necessary audited financial statements, minor reductions in the amount of narrative disclosure in the registration statement do not achieve significant incremental costs savings. Professionals involved in preparing a Form S-18 will be subject to liability under section 11 of the Securities Act to the same extent that they are in a Form S-l registration. Moreover, permitting the preparation of audited financial statements in accordance with GAAP rather than Regulation S-X would not significantly reduce the costs of financial statement disclosure. The differences between financial statement disclosure under Regulation S-X and GAAP are narrowing as accountants increasingly equate the requirements of Regulation S-X with GAAP. Contact: FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE Carolyn M. Johnston (202) 634-5377 APRIL 14, 1978 TREASURY SECRETARY BLUMENTHAL NAMES EDWARD JOSEPH GIBLIN SAVINGS BONDS CHAIRMAN FOR MICHIGAN Edward Joseph Giblin, Chairman of the Board and Chief Executive Officer, Ex-Cell-0 Corporation, Troy, has been appointed Volunteer State Chairman for the Savings Bonds Program by Secretary of the Treasury W. Michael Blumenthal, effective immediately. He succeeds Robert E. Dewar, Chairman of the Board, and Chief Executive Officer, K-Mart Corporation, Troy. Mr. Giblin will head a committee of business, labor, financial, media, and government leaders, who -- in cooperation with the Savings Bonds Division -- assist in promoting the sale of Savings Bonds. Mr. Giblin was graduated from Fordham University with a BS degree, and has a Masters in Business Administration from New York University. Mr. Giblin's business associations are as follows: Peat, Marwick, Mitchell & Company, 1951-53; Ex-Cell-0 Corporation, 1953 to date. He became President and Chief Executive Officer of Ex-Cell-0 In 1971; and in 1978 he assumed the duties of Chairman of the Board. Mr. Giblin has corporate directorships on the Detroit Bank & Trust Company; Detroit Edison Company; Ex-Cell-0 Corporation; and Tecumseh Products Company of Michigan. Other directorships include Beta Gamma Sigma Directors' Table; Machinery and Allied Products Institute; and United Foundation of Detroit. Mr. Giblin is married to the former Josephine Fischer, and has one son. B-830 Contact: Carolyn M. Johnston (202) 634-5377 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE APRIL 13, 1978 TREASURY SECRETARY BLUMENTHAL NAMES JOHN D. BUCHANAN, JR. SAVINGS BONDS CHAIRMAN FOR FLORIDA Jphn D. Buchanan, Jr., Senior Vice President, Prudential Insurance Company of America in Jacksonville, has been appointed Volunteer State Chairman for the Savings Bonds Program by Secretary of the Treasury W. Michael Blumenthal, effective immediately. He succeeds George H. Gage, Jr., President, General Telephone Company of Florida, Tampa. Mr. Buchanan will head a committee of labor, business, financial, media, and governmental leaders, who — in cooperation with the Savings Bonds Division — assist in promoting the sale of Savings Bonds. Mr. Buchanan joined Prudential in 1947 as a Special Agent, and was named Assistant Director of Agencies in 1952. In 1954 he became manager of the newly-formed Cleveland Agency in the South Central Region, earning five President's Citations for outstanding sales and service achievement. Mr. Buchanan has been active in professional, business, and civic activities for a number of years. He is a Directorat-Large of the Florida State Chamber of Commerce, and a member of the Governor's Florida Council of 100; a member of the Jacksonville Board of the National Conference of Christians and Jews; and Secretary of the Board and a Century Club member of the YMCA of Jacksonville. He was also 1976 Duval County "TaHe Stock in America" Chairman, and Co-Chairman of the Corporate Committee for the 1976 United Negro College Fund. Mr, Buchanan is married to the former Jo Janet Dodds of Omaha and they have three daughters. i B-831 Contact: Carolyn M. Johnston (202) 634-5377 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE APRIL 14, 1978 TREASURY SECRETARY BLUMENTHAL NAMES JOHN PATRICK MAGUIRE SAVINGS BONDS CHAIRMAN FOR CALIFORNIA John Patrick Maguire, President Emeritus, Continental Telephone Corporation, Bakersfield, has been appointed Volunteer State Chairman for the Savings Bonds Program by Secretary of the Treasury W. Michael Blumenthal, effective immediately. He succeeds Ernest J. Loebbecke, Director, The TI Corporation, Los Angeles. Mr. Maguire will head a committee of state business, financial, labor, media, and governmental leaders, who — in cooperation with the Savings Bonds Division — assist in promoting the sale of Savings Bonds. Mr. Maguire started his career with Kern Mutual Telephone Company of Taft, California, which is now a part of Continental Telephone Company of California. From 1954 to 1961 he was president of Central Western Company, which merged with Continental in 1961. Mr. Maguire retired from Continental Telephone Corporation on January 9, 1976, after five years as president. He is currently president emeritus and a member of the board of directors of that company. Mr. Maguire's outside activities include memberships in the Kiwanis Club of Taft, California; the Advisory Committee to the Rural Electrification Administration Administrator; and the California Independent Telephone Association. He is also General Chairman of Mercy Hospital Building Fund Campaign, and was recently appointed to the Board of Directors of the Hospital. Mr. Maguire is married to the former Lois A. McAlpine, and they have two children. B-832 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 13, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY ANNOUNCES COUNTERVAILING DUTY INVESTIGATION OF IMPORTS OF PAPERMAKING MACHINES FROM FINLAND The Treasury Department today announced an investigation to determine whether the Government of Finland is subsidizing exports of papermaking machines and parts thereof. The investigation results from a petition filed on behalf of domestic interests. The Countervailing Duty Law requires the Secretary of the Treasury to collect an additional duty that equals the size of a "bounty or grant" (subsidy) found to have been paid on the exportation or manufacture of merchandise imported into the United States. A preliminary determination in this case must be made not later than August 9, 1978, and a final determination no later than February 9, 1979. Notice of this action will appear in the Federal Register on April 14, 1978. Imports of papermaking machines and parts thereof from Finland during the first 11 months of 1977 were valued at approximately $21 million. o B 833 0 o tpartmentoftheJREASURY SHINGTON,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 13, 1978 Contact: George G. Ross 202/566-2356 TREASURY ISSUES FIFTH DISC ANNUAL REPORT The Treasury Department today released its fifth Annual Report on the "Operation and Effect of the Domestic International Sales Corporation Legislation" (DISC). This report covers income tax returns for DISC'S whose fiscal period ended between July 1, 1975 and June 30, 1976, referred to as DISC year 1976. Highlights of the report are: — The revenue cost to the U. S. Treasury was $1.2 billion for DISC year 1976. — Total U. S. exports are estimated to have been $2.9 billion higher in DISC year 1976 than they would have been without the DISC program. The $2.9 billion estimate is based on comparisons of the growth rates of DISC vs. non-DISC exports in individual product classes since the DISC program was enacted in 1971. The $2.9 billion estimate has not been adjusted to take account of either flexible exchange rates, or the possible displacement of non-DISC exports by DISC exports, both of which tend to diminish the impact of DISC. — The total pre-tax profit margin on DISC exports of manufactured goods was 14.0 percent of gross sales, more than twice as large as the comparable profit margin on sales to the domestic market. — The ten largest beneficiaries of the DISC program realized 22 percent of the total tax saving. This year's DISC report provides additional evidence that the DISC provision has been cost-ineffective in stimulating exports. The President recommended in January 1978 that this wasteful tax subsidy be repealed over a three-year period, beginning in 1979. Copies of the fifth DISC Annual Report are available for purchase from the Superintendent of Documents, U. S. Government Printing Office, Washington, D. C , 20401. When ordering, use Stock No. 048-000-00311-7. B-834 fartmentoftheJREASURY $HINGT0N,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 u tos ii ^o Contact: " Robert 'EF^ifiipp 202/566-5328 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE, APRIL 13, 19 78 FINDINGS OF THE DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY WITH REGARD TO THE COVERAGE OF WIRE ROD, WIRE AND WIRE PRODUCTS UNDER THE TRIGGER PRICE MECHANISM. The Treasury Department today released its Findings on the coverage of steel wire rod, wire and wire products under its "Trigger Price Mechanism" for imported steel mill products. The Findings, together with the record of a hearing held on March 28 will be filed today with the U.S. District Court for the District of Columbia, in connection with the lawsuit filed by Davis Walker Corp. challenging the trigger price mechanism as applied to wire rod. The Findings address the issues considered in the hearing and respond to the Court order that the Treasury consider the effects on domestic producers of wire and wire products of including wire rod under the trigger price mechanism without simultaneously including wire and wire products. The major findings of the Treasury Department are: — that the characterization of wire rod as a "semifinished" product does not distinguish it from other products covered by the trigger price mechanism. The only relevant consideration is determining whether it is a "steel mill product" and there appears to be no doubt of its status as such. — that a portion of the total domestic demand for wire rod may not now be met by the domestic industry. But that fact does not alleviate the need to deal with unfairly priced imports of that product through the trigger price mechanism. -- that the current trigger price on wire rod is based on the best evidence of the costs of production of the Japnese industry producing that product for export. Until evidence is found to justify a change in that price, it should be continued in effect. B-835 -2— that trigger prices should be — and will be — issued on those wire and wire products considered to be "steel mill products" and imported in significant quantities. Trigger prices will be issued next week on wire, wire nails and barbed wire, thereby covering 75% by value of the imports of wire and wire products within the 32 AISI categories of "steel mill products." — that the temporary absence of trigger prices on these products does not appear to have resulted in an increase in sales of wire products at unfairly low prices. — that the trigger price mechanism has not set a minimum import price for wire rod. Those exporters which can sell below trigger prices but at fair value appear to be doing so. The fact that many exporters have raised their prices to the trigger prices or above is the result of a voluntary decision not to risk the assessment of dumping duties on their products. — that the trigger price mechanism should not be expanded at this time beyond steel mill products because of the need to focus the Department's resources on the critical problems of the basic steel mill industry identified by the Interagency Task Force that recommended the trigger price mechanism. FINDINGS OF THE DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY WITH REGARD TO THE COVERAGE OF WIRE ROD, WIRE AND WIRE PRODUCTS UNDER THE TRIGGER PRICE MECHANISM. Pursuant to the notice published in the Federal Register on March 10, 1978 (43 F.R. 9912), public comment was requested and a hearing was held to consider a series of allegations made by the independent producers of wire rod, and contested by others, in connection with the operation and effect of the Treasury Department's "trigger price mechanism" (TPM). These allegations were set out in the Federal Register Notice and may be summarized as follows: 1. It is inappropriate to include wire rod under the trigger price mechanism because (a) wire rod is a semi-finished product; and (b) there is a domestic shortage of wire rod. 2. The trigger prices for wire rod are too high in relation to the costs of producing that product by the most efficient foreign steel industry. 3. It is inappropriate to apply the trigger price mechanism to rod as long as it is not being applied to wire and wire products. A hearing was conducted on March 28, 1978, before the General Counsel and the Deputy Assistant Secretary of the Treasury, at which oral statements were presented by 21 witnesses. Through March 29, 1978 - the date specified in the Notice - 28 written presentations were submitted and -2more than 200 separate letters were received. These comments were read and, together with other information available to the Treasury, formed the basis for the findings set.forth below. On March 24, 1978, the United States District Court for the District of Columbia, in the case of Davis Walker Corp. v. Blumenthal, ordered the Secretary of the Treasury to "consider the effects on the domestic producers of steel wire and wire products of the decision to include steel wire rod in the 'trigger price system' without simultaneously including steel wire and wire products and make findings with respect thereto...." These findings address the issues raised in the Federal Register Notice of March 10, as well as those addressed to the Treasury Department in the Order of the District Court. I. Background On December 6, 1977, the President approved a Report prepared by an Interagency Task Force under the chairmanship of Under Secretary of the Treasury Anthony M. Solomon, entitled "A Comprehensive Program for the Steel Industry." The Report reflected the Task Force's study of the problems of the Nation's basic steel industry and recommended a series of steps to be taken by the Government. The Task Force had found that the production of steel mill products -3constitutes a "basic industry" of the United States; employment problems in that industry were extensive; the maintenance of a viable steel mill industry was essential to the country's security and economic interests; overexpansion of production facilities and a reduction in demand throughout the world had created a "steel glut"; substantial sections of the basic steel industry had obsolete facilities; uncertainty existed with respect to a number of applicable U.S. government programs, from transportation to environmental protection; and the basic steel industry was responding to the significant increases of low priced imported steel mill products with unprecedented numbers of complaints under the Antidumping Act. With respect to the latter finding, the Task Force recommended that "the Department of the Treasury, in administering the Antidumping Act, set up a system of trigger prices, based on the full costs of production ... of [Japanese] steel mill products ... which would be used as a basis for monitoring imports of steel into the United States and for initiating accelerated antidumping investigations with respect to imports priced below the trigger prices." Report at 13. In essence, this recommendation contemplated a more effective organization of the Treasury's resources to identify imports of steel mill products at prices that appeared.to warrant -4investigation under the Antidumping Act and to expedite action under the Act. However, it was clear from this beginning of the "trigger price mechanism" that the program was solely a method for identifying shipments of steel and invoking the existing procedures of the law, by specially organizing the resources of the Treasury Department to be devoted to this problem. At the outset, the Task Force noted that its proposal "does not detract from any of the legal rights that foreign producers or the domestic industry presently enjoy under the Act." Report at 14. Concurrently, the Task Force stressed its focus of concern was with the basic steel mill industry of the country. Accordingly, it suggested that "only steel mill products as conventionally defined in the United States be included in the system." Report at 15. Following the President's approval of the Report's recommendation, the Treasury moved to implement the "trigger price mechanism." At its request, the Council on Wage and Price Stability collected information concerning Japanese costs of producing the principal classes of "steel mill products" as defined by the American Iron and Steel Institute. On January 3, 1978, the first group of base prices of products, stated to represent about 75% by value of the steel mill products imported during the preceding year were announced. 43 F.R. 1464 (1978). On February 3, -51978 the "extras" for such products were announced. 4703 (1978). 43 F.R. Thereafter additional trigger prices were cal- culated and published. Prices for pipe and tube products were published on March 27, 1978, 43 F.R. 12783 (1978). Treasury has been working on the preparation of trigger prices for those remaining classes of "steel mill products", as defined by the AISI, which are imported in significant quantities. Before trigger prices for wire and wire products could be computed, independent producers of such merchandise (i.e., companies that purchase rather than manufacture steel wire rod to make wire and wire products) objected, among other things, to the existence of trigger prices for rod while no such prices existed for wire and wire products. Based on those objections, the Treasury announced its hearing and specific invitation for comments. The lawsuit seeking an injunction against the implementation of the trigger price mechanism with respect to rod was then initiated, based on essentially similar arguments. II. The Issues Pursuant to the Notice of March 10 and the Order of the District Court, the following issues have been considered and the following findings reached: 1(a) Is it inappropriate to include wire rod under the trigger price mechanism because wire rod is a "semi-finished" product? -6The contention that wire rod is a semi-finished product is based generally upon the claims that: - there is no practical use for wire rod other than as*the "raw" material used in the production of wire and wire products, and - wire rod is referred to as "semi-finished" by a number of groups which classify steel mill products for various purposes (e.g. the American Iron and Steel Institute (AISI), and the Interstate Commerce Commission). Characterization of wire rod as a semi-finished steel mill product is intended to convey the fact that wire rod emerges at a relatively early stage in the steel mill production process and generally requires further processing in a steel mill before it is used as a component of, or as, a complete consumer item. Other products which are included in the TPM and are characterized by the groups listed above as "semi-finished" include ingots, blooms, billets, and skelp. For the purpose of the TPM, there is no reason to attach particular significance to the description of wire rod as "semi-finished." In fact, wire rod is produced by processing steel billets, themselves considered a "semifinished" product. Moreover, wire rod is not distinguishable from other steel mill products by the fact that additional processing in a steel mill is usually necessary before it can be "consumed." Other products requiring substantial -7processing include hot rolled bars (also produced from billets) which are used as the "raw material" for coldfinished bars, and hot rolled sheets which are used as the "raw material" for pipe and tubing. Trigger prices on hot rolled bars and hot rolled sheets have been issued. The important feature of wire rod for purposes of the trigger price mechanism is that it is a "steel mill product." It has been so characterized by the industry for a variety of reasons for at least thirty years because it is a product, independently traded in commerce, and made and sold by the "steel mills" that constitute the Nation's basic steel mill industry. The basic steel mill industry was identified by the Interagency Task Force as requiring relief and for which the trigger price mechanism was recommended. The products made by that industry are, therefore, the ones for which the Treasury has adopted "trigger prices." The fact that a particular "steel mill product" emerges at one stage or another in the steel mill production process is not relevant in view of the fact that the product is nevertheless sold in that form in the world market as a separate item of commerce. As such, it is susceptible to possible dumping. In fact, wire rod is the subject of two antidumping complaints now pending before the Treasury. That further processing of such a product is possible, either in a steel mill before it is sold for consumption outside the steel industry or by a separate wire drawer, has no relevance to the purposes of the TPM. Virtually all the steel mill -8- products covered by the trigger price mechanism require further fabrication before they can serve their ultimate purpose. For many of these products this processing occurs in steel mills, as "steel mill products" include such finished items as railroad wheels and barbed wire. The question of the coverage of semi-finished products under the trigger price mechanism affects many of the 32 categories of "steel mill products" so characterized by the AISI. For example, cold rolled sheets are sometimes imported in a semi-finished form as cold rolled bands for galvanizing. Such products lack the side trimming, end trimming, and annealing processes that are normally applied to finished cold rolled sheets. Such products are not excluded from the trigger price mechanism due to their "semi-finished" character. Many such imports are covered by trigger prices through the use of negative extras, that is, deductions from the base price to account for the reduced cost of the steel without all of the normal processing. Trigger Price Handbook" at p. 26-8.) (See e.g., "Steel However, it would not be feasible to publish an extra for every conceivable product that might emerge at one stage or another in the steel making process. Provision is made to cover such products by permitting Customs agents to make allowance in the form -9of a deduction from the trigger price but not present in the particular imported product.* The point was properly made by the wire drawers that trigger prices have not been issued for the other products called "semi-finished" by the AISI, such as ingots, blooms, castings, billets, slabs, and skelp. But that, too, is not a basis for eliminating trigger prices on rod. First, although trigger prices have not yet been issued on these other semi-finished products, they are covered by the "trigger price mechanism." As steel mill products, a Special Summary Steel Invoice (SSSI) must be presented with every import entry of such products. Trigger prices have not yet been issued for these products because to date they have represented a low volume of steel imports. No significant evidence has been presented that steel in this form is being imported at unfairly low prices *See Question A. 7. in the Questions and Answers released on February 10, 1978. A. 7. Q. Under the trigger price mechanism, what treatment will be given to "seconds", i.e., overrolled, secondary or under processed material? A. "Seconds", when priced below applicable trigger prices, will be reviewed as will all other shipments. If it is established that merchandise invoiced as "seconds" is actually an incomplete or off-spec product, allowance will be made. The fact that merchandise is a "second" does NOT except it from the trigger price mechanism. The SSSI invoice should reflect the quality in Item 15 "Description of Goods (Include Specifications)" . (Emphasis added . ) -10so as to affect domestic producers adversely. This situation is being kept under review and trigger prices for these products will be issued when information developed through the review of SSSI's indicates it is appropriate to.do so. In view of these facts, it is determined that the characterization of wire rod as a semi-finished product does not distinguish it from other products covered by the trigger price mechanism. The only relevant consideration is determining whether it is a steel mill product and there appears to be no doubt of its status as such. l«b. Is it inappropriate to include wire rod under the trigger price mechanism because there is a domestic shortage of that product? Independent producers of wire and wire products contend that there is insufficient domestic capacity in the production of wire rod to meet domestic demand. From that fact, they argue that the inclusion of wire rod under the trigger price mechanism is inconsistent with the objectives intended to be served by the Antidumping Act. The domestic capacity to produce wire rod was the subject of widely divergent testimony at the hearing conducted on March 28. Some evidence was produced to support the claim that there exists a current shortfall of 1.2 million tons per year. This claim was contested by domestic producers of wire rod who produced evidence that the entire domestic demand could be met if domestic mills were able to price -11their products so as to recover an acceptable profit. A representative of the AISI was clear there is "no lack of capacity." One producer indicated its ability and willingness to take orders for April delivery. There does not appear to be any reliable estimate of current domestic capacity to produce wire rod. Domestic capacity is largely a function of the allocation of productive resources. Decisions on such allocations turn on relative cost and profit projections for particular product lines and the rapidity with which integrated producers, which produce the greatest portion of domestic wire rod, shift production to this product. There appear to be a number of options available for steel mill facilities and a shift to wire is not necessarily economically sensible nor practical. Among problems identified by such a shift are those of marketing and distributing wire rods compared to wire and wire products. Different customers buy rods, different methods of shipment are used. It is not the type of shift that is guickly ac- commplished. It is a fact that imports have supplied a significant share of U.S. consumption in recent years. But that fact may be the result of low priced imports that have deterred the establishment of adequate domestic supply facilities. The Antidumping Act is intended not only to protect against injury to an existing industry but also to counteract unfairly priced imports that may prevent -12the establishment of an industry in this country. From the evidence presented it appears that the primary determinant of domestic productive capacity is the price at which the end product can be sold. Domestic producers s of wire rod allege that the presence of unfairly priced imported wire rod has seriously undermined the profitability of producing that product, thereby discouraging any expansion of productive capacity. Others have provided evidence that the same unfairly priced foreign rod has caused the actual shut-down of domestic wire rod production facilities. The Antidumping Act is properly aimed at unfairly priced imports that actually injure, threaten to injure or prevent the establishment of a domestic industry. If a shortfall in capacity now exists, it may be the result of substantial sales of imports at "less than fair value." Low present capacity cannot be regarded as a basis for encouraging further imports at such price levels. From the evidence that has been introduced it is fair to conclude that total demand for wire rod is not now met by domestic supply. However, the causes of that situation are less clear. The Interagency Task Force recommended measures to stimulate the demand for products of the U.S. basic steel mill industry. One important stimulus was to be the expedited application of the Antidumping Act to steel mill products imported at less than fair value. Under these circumstances, possible present shortfalls in U.S. supply -13cannot be considered a proper basis for failing to apply the TPM to imports of wire rod. 2. Is the trigger price for wire rod too high in relation to the cost of producing that product by the most efficient foreign steel industry? The trigger price mechanism is based on the concept that the "fair value" of imported products is unlikely to be lower than their costs of production by the world's most efficient industry. This concept reflects, in part, the position of the Antidumping Act that sales over an extended period of time below the cost of production are below "fair value." The Japanese steel industry, taken as a whole, has been regarded by a variety of sources as the most efficient at this time, and its costs of producing steel mill products the lowest, although a particular producer in any country may, of course, have lower costs with respect to a particular product. The trigger prices published with respect to wire rod have been calculated by the Treasury and its advisers at the Council on Wage and Price Stability from data furnished by the Japanese Ministry of International Trade and Industry as obtained by that agency from the six largest steel companies in Japan operating integrated steel mills. Integrated mills are those producing a broad spectrum of steel products, from the starting materials for making raw steel through -14a variety of semi-finished to finished products. These companies account for most Japanese exports of "steel mill products," including wire rod. Indeed, no information has been received that any smaller, more specialized Japanese companies, in particular so-called "mini-mills," using different production techniques and relying heavily on scrap as a raw material, account for any appreciable exports to this country or elsewhere. Wire producers who have contended that they have been unable to purchase wire rod from Japanese sources at prices that prevailed prior to the implementation of the TPM have cited as an example of price revisions only those adopted by one of the integrated companies, Nippon Steel Co., whose costs are presumably most like those on which the trigger prices were calculated. The wire producer's principal arguments concerning the level of the trigger price for rods were based on contentions that: - the world market price for rod is below the level of the trigger prices; - the production costs of domestic producers in the U.S. are even lower than the trigger prices; and - the production costs of foreign mini-mills are below the trigger price. The first two contentions are not relevant to the Antidumping Act's price comparisons and, therefore, not to the TPM. -15The last contention is unproven. The prices of wire rod in the world market cannot serve as an appropriate guide to identify sales at "less than fair value" under the U.S. Antidumping Act. The depressed worldwide demand for steel has driven down prices for all steel mill products. The domestic steel industry has compiled a substantial amount of evidence, included in 23 separate anti-dumping complaints (two of them with respect to wire rod) to demonstrate that these conditions have had the effect of causing many steel producers to sell their products in the world market at prices below cost. The Antidumping Act is designed to protect U.S. industry from such below cost sales. To use the world market price as the trigger price would, therefore, defeat, rather than aid, the application of the Antidumping Act. Prices and costs of domestic producers or sellers are also not relevant in establishing the "fair value" of merchandise. The Antidumping Act is not designed to keep out foreign products that may be sold at prices below those offered by domestic producers. It is aimed only at products sold at "less than fair value." That "fair value" is based on the foreign market value or the costs of production of exporters to this country. Therefore, U.S. prices or costs cannot be used to establish standards for invoking the Act. -16On the other hand, the allegation that the trigger price may be above the costs of production of certain more efficient foreign producers may be a relevant consideration. However, it is important to recognize, first, that the production costs of different foreign steel producers are likely to vary over a wide range, not only depending upon such national factors as domestic wage rates, raw material, transportation and energy costs, but also upon individual company efficiencies due to product mix, historic age of facilities, differing management techniques and the like. By choosing the average costs of production of the integrated mills of Japan, considered to be the world's most efficient steel mills, the Treasury Department could be reasonably assured that for most producers their costs of production, and thereby "fair value," would be at or above the level established by the trigger price. Thus, the Treasury Department believes it was justified in devoting its resources to scrutinizing sales of imports below trigger prices so established to determine whether to self-initiate antidumping investigations. This is the background against which to view the claim that the trigger prices for wire rod are too high. In fact, other than the data submitted to Treasury through MITI and analyzed for Treasury by COWPS, very little evidence of the actual costs of production of any foreign steel mills in Japan or elsewhere, has been presented. The principal claim of domestic buyers of imported rod that the Department erred is based on the fact its trigger prices were computed from the production -17costs of the six large Japanese integrated mills. It is argued that a more appropriate measure would be the so-called mini-mills, which are said to have certain efficiencies due primarily to their relatively greater reliance on the use of scrap as a raw material. However, even if this were proven, it does not appear to be a justification for changing, much less suspending, the trigger prices on wire rod. First, the Japanese mini-mills referred to are not currently producing for export. Therefore, their sales have not been a factor affecting the U.S. industry. Trigger prices should be fixed to relate to the import trade. Second, the key variable in the alleged cost efficiency of minimills is the price of scrap. But the price of scrap appears to fluctuate dramatically over short periods of time. To gear the trigger price of wire rod to such a variable factor would make it extremely difficult to administer the TPM in a sensible manner. Finally, if any foreign producer feels it can sell wire rod below trigger prices but at or above "fair value," it can do so — and some appear to be doing so. Deficiencies in the computation of the trigger price from the sources that were selected are, in any event, susceptible of correction. Evidence was also presented.by an American wire producer that the costs of,producing wire rod by a certain domestic U.S. "mini-mill" were, in 1977, substantially below the trigger base price of $240 per net ton; accordingly, it argued that the costs must be less for the Japanese industry. Reference was made to the 1977 Annual Report of Ameron, Inc., a producer -18of steel billets in California, to show that the reported costs for producing 133,000 tons of billets (from which wire rod is made) were $18,100,000, resulting in a per ton cost of $136.09. Further, based on some figures asserted to be derived from the experience of U.S. Steel, the cost of converting billets to rods was estimated to be $53.02, which with capital charges resulted in a cost of rod of $i94.44. In subsequent communications with the Treasury, initiated entirely by Ameron, Mr. G.A. Hanke, Jr., the President of the company stated that the cost information supplied at the hearing was "erroneous." Specifically, he asserted that (1) the cost figures failed to reflect start-up costs, which had been capitalized, but which, if properly accounted for, would have added additional costs of $33.33 per ton; (2) the cost figures for 1977 reflected an unusually low scrap price of $44.00 per ton, which has increased to $63 per net ton as of March 1978 and will increase in April to $68; and (3) the reported costs reflect per ton cost savings of $4' to $5 of producing billets for both reinforcing bars and wire rod, the former being a lower quality and of lower cost. Taking these considerations into account, Ameron believes its cost of producing low carbon billets for rod alone was actually about $175 per ton. On this basis, Mr. Hanke reported that Ameron's price for wire rod of $230 per ton in June 1977 was approximately equal to its costs at the division level, but below total costs when corporate level charges (e.g., general overhead, debt) are added. He had no doubt that the $240 per -19net ton in 1977, used as the base trigger price for commercial quality wire rod, was a low figure. Accordingly, it is determined that the current trigger price on wire rod is based on the best available evidence of the costs of production for the Japanese industry producing wire rod for export. Until evidence is found to justify a change in that price, it should be continued in effect. 3. It is inappropriate to include wire rod under the trigger price mechanism as long as trigger prices have not been issued on wire and wire products. This issue was the basis of the greatest comment at the hearing. Those who presented views were almost unanimous in urging the retention of trigger prices on rod if the Treasury Department also published such prices with respect to wire and wire products. It was the absence of trigger prices on the latter class of products about which the most complaints were received. The Treasury had not been unaware of the grounds for these complaints nor insensitive to taking steps to overcome the problems that may have been created by the adoption of trigger prices for rod without a simultaneous publication of such prices for wire products. However, the preparation of trigger prices for literally hundreds of products in thousands of differing specifications has been a time consuming and laborious task. Initial efforts were directed at adopting base prices for the products imported in the largest quantities. Seventeen base trigger prices (including the four grades of wire rod), covering 75% by value of all imported steel, were -20announced first. The prices for so-called extras for these products were prepared and published within a month, and constitute a 68 page book. Prices for pipe and tube products were next; prices for wire and wire products are to follow and certain classes of such products will be included in trigger prices to be published within the next week [see attached chart]. While it would have been desirable to publish all trigger prices for all products at the same time, it was decided to publish the prices that were calculated when those computations were completed. This procedure was intended to provide the promptest guidance and the promptest possible relief to the basic steel industry. Even before the adoption of the TPM, the Treasury had received and was processing two complaints under the Antidumping Act with respect to wire rod from France and the United Kingdom. In light of this fact, Treasury concluded it should not defer the publication of trigger prices with respect to a product as to which the U.S. industry had shown at least a prima facie case of some injury caused by substantial s.ales below "fair value". To the extent that the independent wire producers contend that they are now unable to purchase this product at the prices that prevailed prior to the adoption of the TPM, their complaint cannot properly be directed at the Treasury Department: it is a complaint that must be addressed to their foreign suppliers. These companies may, however, properly decide not to continue -21to offer their product at prices that may be below "fair value" — even though such offers and sales may have been made in the past. Unable to continue purchasing'rod at previously low prices, the independent wire drawers have contended they are caught in a "squeeze." They say they are required to purchase higher-cost starting material, but face competition in the sale of wire products, the prices of which are uninhibited by "triggers." Further, to the extent foreign makers of wire products can purchase lower-priced rod abroad, they can produce and sell wire products in their home markets and sell in this country at a "fair value" that may be lower than profitable sales prices the domestic wire producers could offer. Finally, they observed that the domestic integrated mills had increased their wire rod prices to a greater extent than their wire prices, thereby exacerbating the "squeeze." To the extent that the mere absence of trigger prices on wire products to be included in the TPM has contributed to the "squeeze" of which the wire drawers complain, Treasury expects that the early publication of such prices will help to alleviate the problem.* *As is discussed in greater detail below, however, the Treasury does not presently intend to develop trigger prices for all products made from wire rod. At least for the moment, it will adhere to the mandate established by the Interagency Task force that recommended the TPM: to develop trigger prices for "steel mill products." Those items that are made from wire rod but have not been classified as "steel mill products" by the industry will not now be placed under the TPM -22With respect to those wire and wire products which are considered "steel mill products" trigger prices will be announced next week covering a majority of the imports of the wire and wire products included within the 32 categories of "steel mill products." A complete breakdown of these items and their import volumes is provided in the attached chart. Once these trigger prices are issued, the major concerns of domestic integrated and independent steel wire producers should be met as far as the coverage of steel mill products under the trigger price mechanism is concerned. To the extent that foreign competitors of domestic independent wire drawers are able to make or obtain in bonafide arm's length transactions wire rod at prices below those at which rod is now available for purchase in the U.S. market, the present Antidumping Act does not provide relief. It does not prevent a foreign producer of merchandise such as barbed wire from acquiring rod at low prices and fabricating that rod into wire that is sold at correspondingly low prices in both its home and export markets. In that situation, the producer is using savings in one factor of production no less proper than savings it may achieve in labor costs or energy expenses. The Antidumping Act is not aimed at preventing foreign producers from relying on savings in their production costs; it only seeks to prevent price discrimination in the sale of merchandise. If the law is to "reach back" to determinations of whether those factors of production are, in turn, "fairly" -23priced, Congress must amend the statute. The TPM cannot be use to do so. To the extent that foreign producers of rod may now turn to the production of wire and wire products, only speculation about future possibilities was adduced. At the hearing, evidence was presented which indicates that a shift of production into wire and wire products would take time, particularly in view of the different marketing and distribution networks needed to sell wire and wire products. Thus, it is highly unlikely that foreign sellers will undertake to shift productive resources into the production of wire and wire products to take advantage of the temporary absence of trigger prices on such products, particularly when they know that trigger prices will shortly be adopted with respect to those products. To the extent that the independent producers of wire products face competition from foreign and domestic rod suppliers who also use some of their rod to make wire products — and, thus, compete with their own customers — that problem is also beyond the reach of the Antidumping Act. No provision of that law prevents a supplier of a product, such as rod, from setting high sales prices for that product, even though it also sells articles it makes therefrom, such as wire products, at relatively low prices to the disadvantage of its rod customers. To the extent such competition comes from domestic firms, the Antidumping -24Act cannot be applied at all; to the extent it comes from foreign companies, only to the extent that the wire product prices are below their own "fair value" can the Act apply. But in that setting, the foreign wire maker's sales prices for rods are not relevant. In sum, none of the arguments of the independent wire drawers appears to amount to more than a claim that if they are forced to compete in sales with low priced products, they should be able to obtain raw materials at low prices — even if below "fair value." The Antidumping Act provides for no such exception and, correspondingly, neither could — nor should — the TPM. The TPM identifies steel mill products imported at prices that may well be below "fair value." It does no more. Its effect may have been to reduce the availability of less than "fair value" rod — as it, and the law on which it is based, intended. The fact that the trigger price mechanism is not designed to cover all the wire and wire products which the independent wire producers make raises a different problem. This objection calls into question the decision of the Interagency Task Force to focus the attention of the Department on the problems of the basic steel mill industry. Treasury believes the problem identified by the Task Force was the most serious, requiring immediate and extraordinary attention and that it was, therefore, reasonable for the TPM to cover only the 32 types of products classified as "steel mill products" by the American Iron and Stee Institute. -25The classification of certain steel products as "steel mill products" as employed by the American Iron and Steel Institute, constitutes a complete and well-recognized set of product definitions which are understood by foreign and domestic steel producers. The actual product categories and the delimitation of "steel mill products" were initially established by the Steel Division of the Business Defense Services Administration (BDSA) of the U.S. Department of Commerce in 1948. Since 1948, that basic format has continued with some product categories added as more information became available. In some cases, product categories were dropped following their discontinuance as a useful classification, such as when the Tariff Schedules of the United States became effective in 1963 and telephone and telegraph wire was deleted as a separate item. There does not appear to be any issue with respect to the use of the American Iron and Steel Institute categories of "steel mill products." What is at issue is whether it is appropriate to expand the list of steel products covered by the trigger price mechanism beyond those recognized as "steel mill products." Views as to how many different product categories should be covered vary. The Independent Wire Producers Association identified an additional six categories of products. However, this modest figure belies the complexity of any undertaking to cover all the products included in these categories. The Specialty Wire Association in its request that all wire -26products be covered by trigger prices identified over 100 individual wire products for which trigger prices would have to be issued.* To attempt to determine appropriate trigger prices and to monitor all of the imports of these wire products would add to the already burdensome task of Treasury in administering the TPM in the areas which the Interagency Task Force identified as most urgently needing relief. If the point made by the independent wire producers were to be accepted, a further problem is posed: Any fabricator of products produced from steel would be in a position to argue that trigger prices must be issued on the product he makes before trigger prices can be applied to his "raw material/' Thus, producers of everything from paper clips to automobiles could insist that their product lines be covered before trigger prices are applied to the steel mill products they buy. Treasury could not administer such an expanded trigger price mechanism with its present resources. Indeed, as the representatives of the AISI suggested, the system would then collapse of its own weight. *If the Bureau of the Census list of wire and wire products is used, trigger prices would have to be developed on everything from paper clips to coat hangers. See attached Table 6A-1. The Bureau of the Census data also supports the conclusion that the choice of the 32 categories of steel mill products as defined by the AISI was a reasonable delimitation of the products produced by basic steel mills since generally the largest portion (by value) of such products are produced by establishments defined as basic steel mills, while the largest portions of wire and wire products not considered steel mill products by AISI are produced by establishments that are not considered basic steel mills. -27But there are also added reasons for declining to expand the list of covered products beyond the AISI categories now included: It is not at all clear that foreign fabricators of steel products are actually selling their products in their home markets or in the United States at prices below the costs of production for the most efficient foreign producers of those products. It is important to recognize that the conditions which have led to the depressed market prices for basic steel mill products are not necessarily present in the fabricated steel industry. It remains to be established that any such products are actually entering, or have entered, the United States at prices below theii costs of the production by the most efficient foreign fabricating industry to the injury of the domestic competitors of the fabricators. In 1977, only four antidumping complaints (affecting only three separate products) were initiated with respect to wire products outside of the 32 categories of steel mill products, but none has reached the stage at which findings have been made that the foreign sellers were selling at less than "fair value" or below their costs. Thus, the substantial effort of developing trigger prices for these products might be unneeded. Of course such goods may be found to have been dumped. That raises a second consideration: Producers of fabricated products as those who make wire rope or strand, may file cases under the Antidumping Act against imports of such products. When sufficient evidence is presented, the Secretary -28of the Treasury is required to initiate an antidumping proceeding. Thus, domestic steel fabricators are in a position to achieve virtually the same results that would follow from the trigger price mechanism. In' sum, the question fairly put is: "If the Treasury devotes substantial resources to intensified monitoring of certain imports, must it extend that monitoring effort to all related products?" The answer seems clearly to be, "no." The AISI categories chosen reasonably deal with the basic steel industry problem on which the Interagency Task Force and the President focused. Special, expedited action involves the considerable expenditure of resources. At the moment, the coverage of the TPM provides intensive monitoring and rapid self-initiations into possible violations of the Antidumping Act with respect to the identified need. To add additional hundreds of products would impose a massive strain that has not been justified to date. Thus, it has been determined that at this time trigger prices for products outside the 32 AISI categories need not be established. 4. What are the effects on the domestic producers of steel wire and wire products of the decision to include s.teel wire rod in the "trigger price system" without simultaneously including wire and wire products? -29The independent producers of wire and wire products have made a number of allegations as to the effect of the trigger price mechanism, some of them directed to the fact that wire rod is covered by a trigger price and some of them to the fact that there are no trigger prices on wire and wire products. The Treasury Department has attempted to identify each of the major effects claimed and has reached the following findings. CLAIMED EFFECT: The trigger price mechanism has had the effect of increasing the price of imported wire rod to the level of the trigger price. FINDING: Some foreign producers of wire rod appear to have increased the price of the wire rod they export to the United States to the level of the trigger prices and others have not. No evidence has been presented to substantiate the claim that any foreign producers in a position to sell below the trigger price but at fair value under the Antidumping Act have been precluded from doing so by the trigger price mechanism. In fact, the President of one of the largest importers of steel products, Kurt Orban, testified that those foreign companies which can sell at fair value' below the trigger price are doing so. (See Transcript at p. 164). This fact is further substantiated by the reports from the Customs Service to the effect that a substantial volume of wire rod is entering into the United States at prices below the trigger prices. -30The Treasury Department's trigger price mechanism has not established a minimum import price for wire rod. However, since trigger prices have been set at the level of the cost of production for the most efficient foreign steell industry, it is understandable that most foreign producers have raised their prices to the trigger price level to avoid an antidumping investigation which could result in antidumping duties equal to or greater than the difference between their export prices and the trigger prices. This voluntary decision on the part of foreign producers to comply with the Antidumping Act is reasonable and entirely in line with the objectives of that Act. CLAIMED EFFECT: The trigger price mechanism has had the effect of raising the domestic price of wire rod to the level of the trigger price. FINDING: The price of domestic wire rod appears to have increased since the trigger price mechanism went into effect on February 21, 1978. However, it does not appear that such price increases have been caused primarily by the trigger price mechanism. The price increases by the major U.S. steel producers which went into effect in March were planned before the trigger prices for wire rod were issued. These price increases have been claimed to be rela to increases in costs, such as those the steel industry contends will also follow the settlement of the recent coal miners1 strike. -31To some extent the trigger price mechanism may have helped the domestic steel mills to raise their prices by deterring foreign producers from selling their products at unfairly low prices. Again this effect is clearly mandated by the Antidumping Act and is the result of the voluntary decisions of foreign producers to comply with the provisions of that Act. CLAIMED EFFECT: The coverage of wire rod by the trigger price mechanism has resulted in or contributed to a domestic shortage of wire rod. FINDING: No absolute shortage of wire rod appears to exist. What may exist is a shortage of rod at prices below "trigger prices." The extent of domestic capacity to produce wire rod and offer it for sale to independent wire drawers is a function of the allocation of productive resources which, in turn, is determined by projected returns on investment. In view of the domestic industry's decisions there may be a present — and even a continuing — need to import a certain percentage of the domestic supply of wire rod. But that fact does not alleviate the need to deal with unfairly priced imports. To permit unfairly low priced imports to be sold in the United States would only further weaken the existing domestic capacity to produce that product to the long term detriment of producers and consumers alike. -32In sum, wire rod is not unavailable. At least one domestic producer who testified at the hearing offered wire rod for delivery in April. Other producers indicated that they had excess capacity available to produce wire rod. CLAIMED EFFECT: The trigger price mechanism has placed independent wire and wire products producers in a "squeeze" by raising the price of their raw material without raising the prices of their finished products. FINDING: The delay in announcing trigger prices for wire and wire products included in the AISI categories of "steel mill products" may have encouraged some foreign sellers of wire and wire products to continue sales at less than fair value and deterred integrated, domestic producers of such products from increasing their prices. However, as the Treasury has consistently indicated it would adopt trigger prices for such products, and, in fact, will announce some as early as next week, no evidence has been adduced that sales of such products at low prices have accelerated. There was no evidence foreign rod makers could or would shift to wire production and sale in the interim since different equipment is used to make wire and different marketing practices are used to sell wire. -33To the extent the sgueeze is caused by the ability of foreign makers of wire to obtain inexpensive rod from unrelated sources and to sell wire products in the U.S. at low prices that are nevertheless not below the "fair value" of the wire products, the present Antidumping Act provides no remedy. Accordingly, the TPM cannot be applied to overcome this problem for domestic wire makers. To the extent the squeeze is caused by the dual distribution practices of both foreign and domestic makers and sellers of both rod and wire (who sell rod at comparatively high prices and wire at low prices), again the Antidumping Act provides no remedy. To the extent the "squeeze" is caused by the limited coverage of the TPM to the AISI group of "steel mill products" and, thus, does not include all wire and wire products made or sold in the United States, the scope of coverage has been limited to that proposed by the Interagency Task Force as approved by the President. The TPM is a device to allocate Treasury's resources to monitor imports and expedite antidumping actions in an area identified as critical: the basic steel mill industry. The classification of products produced by that industry has been simply followed. Expanding the TPM to cover added products might, through the dissipation of Treasury resources, prevent its effective application -34in the area where the need was identified. But such a selflimitation in no way inhibits wire and wire producers from pursuing the established, existing remedies of the Antidumping Act to imports of wire and wire products that are priced below "fair value." LLJL&A Peter D. Ehreahaft Deputy Assistant Secretary and Special Counsel (Tariff Affairs) April 13, 1978 Attachment A Specialty U/ita -QiioclcLtlon 1625 Eye Street, Northwest Washington, D. C. 20006 Telephone: 202-331-1611 February 9, 1978 Listing of Steel Wires ir Filter Wire ircraft Cord Wire ntenna Wire nnor Wire mature Binding ale Ties & Baler Wire all Bearing Wire elt Lacer or Belt Hook Wire lack Annealed Wire Wire Lobby Pin ookbinder Wire ox Binding Wire DX Stitching or Stapling Wire raiding Wire rake Cable Wire ridge Wire room Wire able Television Lead Wire ar Seal Wire arbon Valve Spring Wire arbon Welding Wire ard Clothing Wire lain Link Wire lain Wire Lay Cutting Wire .ip Wire >ld Heading Wire >mmon Pin Wire mcrete Form Twist or Snap Tie Wire mcrete Reinforcement Wire, Plain or Deformed mduit Wire mnector Wire •ntrol Wire •Rural Telephone Wire •tterpin Wire rtain Spring Wire nt Spacer Wire op Line Wire ectronic Lead Wire Farm Fence & Barb Wire Fire Screen Wire Fish Hook Wire Fish Leader Wire Flat High and Low Carbon Wire Flexible Shaft Wire, High & Low Carl Florist Wire Fuse Wire Galvanized Armor Wire Galvanized Core Wire Galvanized Flooded Strand Galvanized High & Low Carbon Wire Galvanized Redraw Wire for Staples Galvanized Steel Cores for ACSR Galvanized Strand Wire Galvanized Support Wire Glass Netting Glazier Wire Guitar Wire Hairpin Wire Hard Drawn Spring Wire Hard Drawn Wire for Prestressed Cone Heddle Wire High Carbon Wool Wire High Nickel Alloy Wire Hose Clamp Wire Hose Reinforcement Wire - High Press Hose Wire - Low Pressure Industrial Quality Wire Jewelry Chain Wire Lamp Lead Wire Line Wire Link Wire Lock Stock Wire Lock Washer Wire Mandrel Wire Manufacturers Coarse Wire Match Wire Mattress Wire discing of Steel Wires Merchant Wire Metal Spray Wire Metal Stitching Wire Music Wire Nail Wire Needle Wire Oil Tempered Carbon Valve Spring Wire Oil Tempered Chrome Silicon Commercial & Valve Wire Oil Tempered Chrome Vanadium Commercial & Valve Wire Oil Tempered Modified Chrome Vanadium Valve Wire Oil Tempered Spring Wire (Two Classes) Oil Well Measuring Wire Overhead Door Spring Wire Paper Clip Wire, Tinned, Liquor Finished or Galvanized Pen Spring Wire Piano Wire Pile Wire Pin Ticket Wire ^Pinion & Pivot Wire Pipe Cleaner Wire Pre-formed Staple Wire Prestressed Concrete Stress Relieved Wire Reed High Carbon & Low Carbon Wire Regulator Spring Wire Ring-Traveler Wire Rivet Wire Rolling Quality Wire Rope Wire, Bright & Galvanized Scrapeless Nut Wire Screw Wire Shade Roller Wire Shaped High and Low Carbon Wire Shoe Wire Sinuous Arc Spring Wire Sinuous Upholstrey Spring Wire Special Alloy Wire Spiral Bindling Wire Spoke Wire Stainless Brush Wire Stainless Cold Heading Wire Stainless Cotterpin Wire Stainless Flat Wire Stainless Heddle Wire Stainless Jewelry Chain Wire Stainless Lashing Wire Stainless Reed Wire Stainless Rope Wire Stainless Rub Nail Wire - 2 - „ _, , „, Attachment A Stainless Shaped Wire Stainless Spring Wire Stainless Weaving Wire Stainless Welding Wire Stainless Wool Wire Staple Wire Steel Flat & Shaped Wire Stitching Wire Straight Pin Wire Strand Wire Stone Sawing Strand Wire Surgical Wire T Pin Wire Tag Wire Tempered Carbon Brush Wire Tempered High Carbon Flat Wire Tempered High Carbon Shaped Wire Terminal Pin Wire Thermocouple Wire Tinned High and Low Carbon Wire Tire Bead Wire Untempered Carbon Brush Wire Untempered Chrome Silicon & Chrome Vanad Upholstery Border Wire Upholstery Lacing Wire Upholstery Spring Wire Vacuum Hose Wire Weaving Wire Welded Fabric Wire Wire Tire Cord - Strand and Cable Woven Mesh Wire • Attachment B •1A-36 B U S T FURNACES; STEEL W O R K S ; ROLLING A N O FINISHING MILLS 1172 CCJISUS Of •AfWCTBfft: TA8LE 6A-1. Products and Product Classes—Quantity and Valua of Shipmtnts by AH Producers: 1972 and 1967—Cont»u*j 0ncfcdei %m*nut* tat watua el lim products resorted net antyfryeatatrefrnefm CM*** iad in this M e a t y ,frtrtteafrysatatfiatvnsnn i • "aKonds/y" predeca. Sss aopsndu. L p a n s u o A of Ttrm "Vita of liua-awr) UiUtsJ TstsJ product tfyQfMrB inctudiof m ussiest. •n product Vat* OsattJtV B T R L V T U AKD U L A T B ) PWO0CCT3« 815- — BIST 14964 13157 K964 — — — — } ferrous wire Cloth and Other Wowoo ferrous wire Product*. 13157 11 M964 11 13157 31 14964 31 13157 91 14944 61 13157 II 14964 81 1313: 7i 14964 71 13157 II M964 II 13137 II I4064 II lade la Industries 3312 and 331S Made In fabricated wire products, a.e.c. (Industry 3496) other Industries UM.9 (X) 19.4 (X) Ti.J Millie* a*, ft. 43.9 1.8 lardvare olota 1,000 a. tarns.. 10.0 11.4 Industrial elre cloth, ateel Millie* *q. ft. .do. .do. <JU) flu) flu) t 31 39.4* (X) -} Stainless steel paper aachine vlra oloth (fourdrlaler cylinder) • .. Made in lnduatrles 3312 and 331S Made la Industry 3496 and other Industries .do. .do. .do. (M) f.4 (nO 5.4 Other elre cloth and voven el re products Including dl oloth .do. (HA) 37.6 Made la lnduatrles 3312 and 3313 Made in fabricated wire products, a.e.e. (industry 3496) and other lnduatrles. ... •9.3 93.9 14S.7 9.9 19.1 13.4 <VA) 33.4 14.3 13.7 .do. Other Fabricated Tire Products. (X) I*) 41 Voven wire netting (poultry, fur far*, stucco, etc.)*. Tire cloth sad t o w n wire products, a.a.k. } (X) Insect el re screening, eteol, Including atalaless steel, Made la Industries 3313 and 3313 Made In Industry 3496 and other Industries 13157 M 14964 98 13157 00 14964 00 13131 — 14969 — 13139 — I4M9 — itli fltt) 19.4 (x) 3.9 (X) 4.0 (x) 847.5 (X) •49.3 (X) 38O.0 (X) 393.7 374.5 (X) 437. 5 33.1 35.8 44.9 39.9 71.2 69.0 71.9 51.9 Tire chain: 13159 41 14969 41 13139 49 14969 49 13139 49 14969 49 13139 61 14969 51 13139 31 14969 51 13159 S3 14969 53 13139 S3 14969 S3 Tire Other Made In lnduatrles 3312 and 331S Made la Industry 3496 and other Industries. } Barbed and twisted steel wire' Made In Industries 3312 and 3313 Made In Industry 3496 and other Industries,.. Wire bale tlea" Made la Industries 3312 and 331S Made In industry 3496 and other Industries. 1,000 a. tons. •do. 37.3 34.4 35.4 36.2 .do. .do. •1.3 17.0 47.8 31.3 .do. 141.2 37.8 195.7 34.9 .do. .do. 118.6 23.6 31.0 6.9 (HA) (HA) (KA) .do. 143.7 36.4 129.3 35.9 .do. .do. 130.3 13.5 30.6 5.9 109.1 31.3 30.4 5.5 .do. 633.9 130.4 679.9 116.9 .do. .do. 539.4 94.5 109.3 21.1 599.7 90.1 99.8 18.1 .do. 185.3 53.1 200.9 51.7 .do. .do. 176.7 8.6 47.0 6.1 183.5 17.4 39.3 13.4 254.1 39.3 (HA) (KA) (KA) (HA) (iu) Voided steel wire fabric: 13159 II 14969 61 13159 61 14969 61 13159 65 4969 65 3159 IS 4969 63 3139 71 4969 71, 3159 71 4969 71 3159 73 4969 73 3139 75 4969 73 3159 77 4969 77 Concrete reinforcing* mesh.. Mads In Industries 3312 and 3313 Made in Industry 3496 and other Industries. Other welded steel wire fabric Mad* in industries 3312 and 3315 Made In Industry 3496 and other industries. Wire garment hangers Made In Industries 3312 and 3313 Made in industry 3496 and other Industries. Million lb. 233.7 ...do .do. 176.5 57.2 3130 00 3150 02 32.4 15.9 19.0 wire carts, including- household, grocery-type, and Industrial. (X) 36.3 (X) Steel wire cages (X) 9.3 (X) 16.2 (X) 3.2 (X) 242.4 Paper clips (X) 3159 98 4969 98 31S9 00 4969 00 49.3 339.9 Other wire products Including baskets, guards, florists' designs, kltchenware, etc • Other fabricated wire products, n.».k Steel wiredrawing, n.s.k., for establishments with 10 employees or more. (See note.) Steel wiredrawing, n.s.k., for establishments with less than 10 employees. (See note.) S«« footnotes at end of table. { 28.9 (X) 31.5 (X) 32.0 (X) 32.1 (X) 4.4 (X) 1.1 (X) _ 1172 CENSUS CV MaJUfACTUIES i \) . / Attachment •LAST F U R N A C E S ; S T E k W O f M S ; BOILING A N D FlNrSHING 9JIL1& ^ 9 . TABLE 6A-UProducts and Product Classes—Quantity %nd Value of Shipments by All Producers: 1 9 7 2 and 196/—Continrjjd »atx«4ai•ISM*1| andwas*of Q»arodeitiraaartadnot enh; by apactsNnsntickesrf e*J *flatealuatry.fretafcofry ej "•Kondary'' product!. Sea appendix, cxfavuxjaa mi Tanrn "Value of Mauaesaj*) skmfi Tetel product shipments indudloi snarplant ttaoafan itn un ran (aeattlV Oiaatftt VSJM (swUavt douen) 1315- — S T D L Will AMD RZLAT3S PRODUCTS, TOTAL. 93131 — 34961 — 33131 — 34961 — 33151 34961 33151 34961 11 11 11 11 33151 34961 33151 34961 33151 34961 31 21 35 35 35 33 93131 34961 33131 34961 33131 34961 33151 34961 33 33 41 41 41 41 00 00 33152 — 33152 33132 33152 33132 Mottlasulated Ferrous tire Rope, Cable, sad Strand, } <x) ) 370.3 •XX) 399.2 343.2 174.2 .do. .do. 333.0 93.2 199.3 55.0 172.4 101.7 .do. 4.0 7.1 34.0 .do. .do. .do. 175.0 143.1 32.9 55.4 49.3 7.1 49.1 (HA) (HA) fire strand for pre stressed concrete*. .do. 70.6 17.2 59.9 fire forms. .do. (HA) 39.1 Iron aad ateel wire rope and cable*. Made la loduatrtea 3312 aad 3315 Made la Industry 3496 aad other industries. Made la Industries 3313 and 3313 Made la Induetry 3496 and other lnduatrloe, 1,000 s. toae. .do. .do. Woalneulated ferrous wire, rope, eable, and strand, a.s.k. Steel wire nails, spikes, aad brade:* Bright .' Cal vanl xed ., Ceavent-<oa ted Other nails, spikes, ete Steel wire staples* ' Steel tacka (wire and box) Steel cut nails, spikes, and brads, including track aplkes and horseshoe nails , Steel nalla and aplkea, a.s.k Steel wire:* As reported la Current } 364.6 ix) Steel Malls aad Spikes. 33132 00 (X) 94.4 } } 2,199.8 (X) Ccaposlte strand, rope, and eable, lacludlng wire a trend a of different aetala (except ACSR ) Steel wire strand, except wire strand for preetreeeed concrete, including guard rail eable*..... Made la Industries 3312 and 3315 Made la industry 3496 sad other lndustrlee 33152 23 33152 25 33132 33 33136 00 34966 — 33136 — 34966 — (X) Hade la industries 3312 aad 3315 , Made la fabricated wire producta, a.e.e. (industry 3494) aad other Indus trlee.. • 11 13 17 19 33123 — 33133 — 33125 00 33133 00 (X) (•Win 1,000 a. toaa. ...do .do. .do. 3.7 34.4 (HA) (X) 5.4 (X) (X) 344.5 (X) (HA) (HA) 226.9 91.5 73.3 77.4 99.4 29.0 20.0 40.9 240.9 40.4 41.1 14.0 .do. .do. 37.9 9.4 73.0 9.4 44.4 4.3 .do. 19.9 (X) 7.0 1.9 31.7 Industrial Reports, aerlea MA-339, (X) (X) 719.0 (X) 734.3 (X) (X) 397.9 (X) (X) 323.7 (X) . (x) 245.4 (X) (X) 172.1 (X) (X) 73.3 (X> 173.3 95.1 (HA) .do. .do. 141.4 31.9 37.4 27.7 (HA) (XA) Aa reported in the census of manufactures Made in steel Bills (industry 3312) Made in steel wiredrawing (lnduetry 3315) and other lnduatrles Fencing and Fence Catea. Made In Industries 3312 and 3313 Made in fabrlcatea wire producta, n.e.e. (lnduetry 3496) and other industries , (X) 33136 34966 33136 34966 13 13 13 13 33156 34966 33136 34966 33136 34966 35 33 21 21 21 21 Fence gates, posts, snd fittings..'. .do. 235.5 74.4 (HA) • Ire fence, woven and welded* .do. 368.9 100.0 134.2 Made in Industries 3312 and 3313 Made In Industry 3496 and other Industries. .do. .do. 327.3 41.6 49.2 11.9 120.0 16.2 33156 34966 33156 349G6 33156 34966 71 71 71 71 00 00 Ornamental lswn fence .do, 4.0 2.3 7.7 Made In industries 3312 and 3313 Made In Industry 34966 and other Industries. .do. .do. (HA) (HA) } Chain link* fencing, excluding post, gstes, and flttlnga. Msde In industries 3312 snd 3315 Made ia Industry 3496 and other industries Fencing and fence gates, n.s.k See footnotes at end of table. 1,000 s. tons. (X) (XA) (KA) 7.2 .3 1.8 (X) 1,494.3 Attachment C Projected Coverage of U.S. Wire Product Imports By Trigger Price Mechanism AISI Cat. No. ' (TSUSA No.) 609.^0.10 .40 .41.05 .20 .25 .65 .43.05 .15 .45.10 .40 (Subtotal 646.25.00 .26.20 .40 (Subtotal 1977 U.S.. IMPORTS % or Dotal, mports or Ai (Category (By Value) ($1000) 16 16 16 16 16 16 16 16 16 16 5349 9149 14,381 1638 52,639 31,205 1319 19,499 23,508 34,397 2 3 5 1 18 11 0 7 8 12 16 193,084 67) 20 20 20 4,029 100,825 58,981 2 62 36 20 163,835 100) 20 21 366,261 NA • 42.02.00 21 9,342 100 16 TOTAL Coverage of total wire and wire product imports considered steel mill products (by value) 15% FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY Expected at 1:00 p.m. Thursday, April 13, 1978 Contact: Robert E. Nipp (202) 566-5328 Remarks by Arnold Nachmanoff Deputy Assistant Secretary for Developing Nations Treasury Department The Southern Center for International Affairs, Meeting in Miami, Florida The International Development Banks And the Development Process I spend much of my time in Washington in the winter and spring immersed in carrying out a program that must be justified in often excruciating detail before the Congress. We speak in a special jargon when appearing in the Capital that is often a puzzle to outsiders. One of the attractions of your invitation is the chance to speak to an audience and equally concerned with the objectives, and even more involved with what the international development banks accomplish. These organizations of which the United States has usually been a founder and leading member are: The World Bank Group, which includes the International Development Association (IDA) and "he International Finance Corporation (IFC), the Inter-Ameri n Bank (IDB), the Asian Development Bank and the African ^lopment Fund which is attached to the African Develops 3ank. B-836 - 2My theme is to explore why the developing countries are important to the United States and how the development banks further our interests by providing a framework within which the developed countries can join with developing nations to support and manage the transfer of resources for their growth. As the flow of private capital of all kinds from the developed economies becomes larger and more complex in form and purpose, one of the IFIfs more important functions is to influence national policies in directions that enhance and improve the workings of the international capital market. I. The Importance of the Developing Nations The phrase "developing countries*' is in danger of becoming a cliche of public discourse. Whatever they are called, they represent a reality of two billion people on three continents, who in spite of extraordinary cultural, political and economic diversity tend to see themselves as a group, set apart by their history and interests, from the industrial nations, led by the United States. To a greater extent than ever before these nations are paying more attention to the objectives of development so that they may improve the living standards of their people, especially of those large groups, mired in poverty. We have always ic^Ti-.if ied ourselves with the aspirations of the developing -ations for a number of reasons. - 3 First of all, the developing nations collectively are already a force to be reckoned with in world affairs. Their attitudes and actions could have decisive effects on world peace. Their foreign policies modify the atmosphere and style of international relations; their development policies can change our physical environment and effect our economy. We need simply to recall what happened to the prices of oil and wheat in the past four years and their impact on our domestic rate of inflation. One of the purposes of our membership in and support of the international banks is to establish a type of relationship in which our interest in the development of these countries is accepted without question so that we can tackle problems of mutual interest without suspicion of our motives. Second, many of these countries are desperately poor. More than one billion people do not have access to potable water; 700 million do not have enough to eat; 500 million cannot read or write; and 250 million do not have adequate shelter. For these reasons alone, they have a claim on our humanitarian tradition which sent men, food and medical supplies abroad long before public aid was established. Third, helping these countries has proved to be in our long range economic interest. The LDCs collectively have had a remarkable record of growth in the first post-war generation of development. From 1 50 to 1975, per capita - 4 " growth was about 31 per year, or the same as the developed nations. In other words, despite a population growth at least twice as rapid as the United States, Western Europe and Japan, product per head has risen as quickly as in the more advanced economies. In extreme cases like South Korea, GNP has been growing since 1960 at a rate which doubles national product per head every decade. Brazil's growth is only slightly slower. The point is that whatever the vicissitudes of the business cycle or of balance-of-payments crises, taking into account faster population growth, the developing economies, have been growing faster than our own and other industrial countries. We cannot assume that even those areas that have made the least progress in the past will not move ahead once again. South Korea was regarded in 1960 by the experts as a country that would never be able to support itself by competing in international trade. How odd that opinion seems today! Faster development leads to more rapidly growing markets. In 1970 the developing country share of world imports was 18% of which OPEC accounted for 3%. Six years later, it had risen to 231 including 71 for the OPEC, most of wl *ch are still considered developing and are, or are likely for some time to come. be,capital importers - 5- This growth has had very beneficial effects on our exports. The non-OPEC LDCs have been taking a fairly constant share of just under one quarter of exports or a somewhat larger share than the European Community. Adding the OPEC countries, raises that share to 361 in 1977, having shot up from 27% in 1972 just before the oil price hike. The variations in the next few years are not likely to change the reality that the developing nations are and will continue to be our most important foreign market. Sales totaled $43 billion last year, of which roughly 70% were manufactures. In that category, machinery and transport equipment accounted for more than half. Roughly half of our exports of wheat, rice and cotton have gone to developing countries in recent years. that Some estimates indicate about one million jobs depend on these exports. As public and private creditors and as investors, the United States has an important stake in healthy LDC economies as the following indicators illustrate: 37% of our income derived from direct investments abroad,or $7 billion in 1976,came from there -roughly two-thirds of our government loans have been made to developing country borrowers, -- the rest being t-;.Jort and other credits to developed coun- > .< ;. - 6 - repayment of about 30% or $70 billion, of commercial bank lending to foreign countries, outstanding at the end of 1977 depends on their continuing creditworthiness-rough estimates indicate that 15-20% of bank profits arise from loans to these countries. II. The Role of the Development Banks Some developing countries have been more successful than others. Within that broad category we have an emerging middle class--economies with incomes of roughly $500-$2000 per capita. They have constructed the basic infrastructure of power and transport. Their agriculture is being modern- ized and illiteracy is beginning to vanish. The worst health problems have been conquered and family planning is beginning to spread. Industry is well established and is on its way to become the major economic activity. Most important, they have learned how to compete in world trade with both industrial and primary products. Their rapidly rising exports of goods and services have been a key element in the speed of their development by giving them the means to buy essential goods and to supplement public aid with private credits. They are the customers of the "hard" windows of the development banks. the institution. These are the ordinary operations of Typically the banks can lend no more - 7than their capital and reserves. That capital consists of a paid-in portion, now usually 10%, with the rest, callable, acting as a guaranty of the bank's own bonds. By this device the development banks can tap the international capital market. Bond buyers have the double pro- tection of the guaranties, the bulk of which come from developed countries, as well as the diversification of risk implied in the bank's wide-ranging portfolio of loans. While the maturities of the banks' loans are 15-30 years the interest rates necessarily are marketrelated. Although these countries are poor by comparison to the United States and other developed economies, they are far better off than their poorer brethern in South Asia, much of Africa or Haiti, to cite an example nearer home. Their economies are still mired in traditional agriculture, infrastructure generally is feeble compared to needs, and malnutrition and illiteracy are grave problems. Ex- ternally, creditworthiness is poor so that foreign capital transfers must be in the form of grants or loans with high concessional interest rates and very long maturities. - 8 These countries are the typical customers of the soft windows. They are funds, fed mainly by budgetary transfers, largely but not exclusively from the banks' developed country members. The interest rates are now 3/4 of 1%, except for certain loans from the soft loan window of the IDB, and the maturities range up to fifty years. I would like to concentrate today on the role the multilateral banks play in the investment policy and in programs designed to reach the poorer groups of the middle income developing nations. These countries have a population of more than 600 million people. Their economies rely today mainly on direct and portfolio investment and on credit carrying largely commercial interest rates. New government-to-government grants or aid-type loans are becoming rarer. The hard windows of the development banks are, as a result, becoming the more important source of public develo ment capital. /They alone, therefore, can take the long view and are in a position to take more risks to back their judgements. At the same time, they are free by the terms of their charters and, largely in practice, of the political considerations. The dimensions of this market are not completely known but we do have good enough estimates to establish the orders of magnitude. The total flow of medium and long-term capital is$25-30 billion a year to all countries of this group of - 9developing nations including the oil exporters. About $2.5 billion or 10% comes from the multilateral lenders and roughly the same amount from government aid agencies. Between 15-20% is direct investment. Thus, about 80% of the credit and investment is private and 20% official. Private credit, mainly from commercial banks (plus some bond sales) is 60% of the total. For some countries such as Brazil and Mexico that are heavier borrowers from the banks, the multilateral share is less than 10%. The existence of a private international capital market serving the developing countries on such a scale is quite new, in the post-war period. middle sixties. It dates from perhaps the Once again, as it did in the past, private lending became the predominant source of capital. The borrowers are largely new, the product of the successes of the first generation of development. Therefore, the rules of operation are still changing and certain amount of management is desirable from both the lender and borrower's point of view. The special function the development banks (and the IMF) perform is to make the market work better by a combination the of/quality of their policy advice to the borrowers and by supplying long-term credits to complement the shorter maturities of the private lender. The banks' presence acts as an endorse- ment for private lenders and investors in a particular country that the development strategy of their customers is proper and reasonable, so that they will have the resources with which to repay ivy the future - 10 - In other words by influencing the volume and direction of investment, and related spending for education and health, the probability of producing a more rapidly developing economy, which diffuses its benefits widely is greater. The banks make their greatest contribution by minimizing "white elephant" projects which tie-up large quantities of capital with little return in output and encouraging efficient allocation of resources. The advisory role is strengthened by the relatively small number of influential policy makers, executives and experts in many developing nations, that need to be reached and, by its link to credits. Local leaders and experts will see many bank missions in the course of their working careers. The contact will require them to think through more carefully their assumptions and articulate them more precisely. In the informal and confidential give and take between experts, improvements can be made without loss of face and policy directions subtly altered. The banks are not shy about attaching economic and technical conditions to their loans to improve their efficiency. On the other hand, they have good motives to refrain from academic or trival advice because the loan engages the prestige and financial standing of the lending institutions as well as the borrowers. If a country is badly managed, so that its creditworthiness is endangered, then so are the bank's - 11 loans. With current annual lending level of eleven billion dollars, their collective clout is considerable. Ill. Development Banks and Commercial Banks Probably no private institution is more directly concerned that development banks carry out their functions successfully than the American commercial banks. I noted earlier the importance of foreign commercial banks in the total flow of capital to the better-off developing nations-between 50-60% of the total. A great deal of this expansion has taken place since the double shock of the oil price increase in 1973 and the world recession that followed in 1974-75. For these two years the combined current account deficit of the better-off developing countries, not including oil exporters, was estimated to be $47 billion. Private medium and long-term credit expansion to the same group covered $17 billion of the gap, and, undoubtedly, the expansion of short-term credits also played a significant but probably considerably smaller role. Even though, current accounts deficits have fallen in 1976 and 1977, bank lending has continued on a high level enabling its recipients to also build up their exchange reserves. During this latter period, for example U.S. bank lending to non-oil LDCs has risen $15 billion. The remarkable flexibility of the commercial banks operating in the international market, with the American banks playing the leading role, has helped the developing to external recession. natio i borrowers to stretch out their internal adjustment/ Even ifi 1975 wheri: the full force of the recession had stru K - 12 the growth rate of the developing countries other than oil exporters was almost 4% compared to the long-term post-war trend of 3%. By 1976, it rose once more to 5%. We see the relationship between the development banks and the commercial banking system as complementary. The development banks (and the IMFj establish and maintain a policy framework within which private lenders operate. They also contribute appreciable capital resources on long repayment terms which reduces the burden of amortization for the developing country borrower. For both reasons, the risk to the private intermediate lender is lessened. But growth and its benefits could not take place to the same degree unless the commercial banks were prepared to transfer through their credits some of the enormous resources at their disposal. Both types of lending contribute to develop- ment, the reduction of lending risk and the preservation and expansion of the international credit market. IV. The Development Banks and the United States The remarkable thing has been how inexpensive the hard windows have been to the American taxpayer. The World Bank which has three quarters of these loans, has received only $650 million fr * this purpose from the U.S. budget since its foundation ••:.:>• gh FY 1977. Yet it has committed $38.6 billion of loans. ank regularly makes profits on these opera- tions and ?• Kern to reserves as well as making contri- Klitinn*? n A V <t-,~ -i •#- e? «?^-f*- •Tii-n^ o-P^il i 9 t o § J;f the Br*nk - 13 were to be liquidated tomorrow our share of the reserves would be about equal to what we have paid in. Continuing lending requires the regular expansion of the Bank's capital. The current replenishment is $8.4 billion of which our share is $1,570 million. portion is $157 million or 10%. The paid-in We are currently in dis- cussions that will eventually lead to a general capital increase. Supporting hard window loans is a major part of our appropriation request. asked for $3.5 billion. For FY 1979, the President has Of this amount $1.5 billion will enable the Banks to continue to make loans at marketrelated interest rates. Only about $100 million should result in actual expenditure. The remaining $1.4 billion is for callable capital of the banks which would only be needed if they suffered defaults or rescheduling so massive that their existing reserves were overwhelmed. The "developing nations" problem has been transformed in the past generation. The issue is no longer when and how they will grow but how we integrate those that have already made striking and help the remaining members of the group h r ogress into the world economy untries to take the path other already followed. The motives - 14 of securing a more peaceful world, of helping those whose state of poverty is repugnant to our ideals, and promoting our own economic interests as exporter, lender remain valid. and investor The emergence of a "middle class" among the developing economies indicates very clearly that we are dealing with countries whose political and economic power is growing. In this same period the international development banks have come fully of age in their ability to raise capital and influence, to the extent it can be done externally, the developing nations. policies and priorities of the more successful/ We see this role as particularly crucial in the new international capital market where private credit has once again assumed the primary function of transferring resources from the capital rich to the capital poor economies. A frame- work is evolving consisting of policies and attitudes of borrowing countries and of the commercial banks particularly in the United States, which has proven its effectiveness in softening the effect of world recession on the developing nations and on their suppliers. It is in mutual our/interest that the better-off developing countries obtain more resources for growth in the private international market so that their growth can be maintained and its benefits spread throughout their populations. This is a situation that will require continuing - 15 and careful management. The development banks(and the IMF)will have to be given regular increases in their resources for some time, in line with the growth of the world economy, if they are to play their part. That is the basis of our policy of supporting the international development banks. tfHINGTON, D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 April 14, 1978 STATEMENT BY SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY W. MICHAEL BLUMENTHAL Reports that the Carter Administration is considering a reduction in the tax cut proposals are entirely erroneous. While there were discussions at the EPG Steering Committee Thursday about Chairman Miller's suggestions, following which economic projections were requested, this does not indicate a change of course for the Administration. The Administration will continue to monitor the economy and will analyze alternative tax proposals. But this in no way indicates a change in policy. The Administration continues to believe its proposals are needed at the level the President prescribed in order to continue the growth of the economy, to encourage business investment, to reduce taxes for middle and lower income Americans, and to some extent, offset the continuing inroads of inflation. The Administration will continue to actively press for passage of a tax law this year which combines tax cuts totalling approximately $35 billion for both individuals and business, and tax reforms which will recover approximately $10 billion in revenue. This represents a balanced set of proposals. The net tax cut of $25 billion will benefit individual Americans by $17 billion with an additional $2 billion by eliminating the telephone excise tax and reducing the payroll tax for unemployment insurance. It will also benefit small and large business by $6 billion. B-837 wtmentoftheTREASURY IINGTQN, D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 it FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY (APPROXIMATELY 10:00. A.M.) APRIL 19, 1978 STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE ANTHONY M. SOLOMON UNDER SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR MONETARY AFFAIRS BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON INTERNATIONAL TRADE INVESTMENT AND MONETARY POLICY COMMITTEE ON BANKING, CURRENCY AND HOUSING HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES Mr 0 Chairman: I appreciate this opportunity t;o testify on H0R0 9066, which would place the administrative expenses of the Treasury in the international affairs area on an appropriated basis and discontinue the funding of those expenses from the Exchange Stabilization Fundo Following my testimony on this bill, I would like to take a few minutes of the Committee's time to discuss a related point on the effect of recent exchange rate changes and revisions of certain accounting standards on the financial statements of the ESFC H0Ro 9066 When this Administration assumed office, one of the first decisions to be .addressed by the head of each Department was that of internal organization and management0 As part of that process, we at the Treasury were faced with a more specific question, which had been one of some Congressional concern: whether to continue payment of administrative expenses connected with Treasury's international responsibilities from the Exchange Stabilization Fund (ESF)« Our decision is reflected in the bill you are considering today — H 0 R 0 9066 -- which was propose by the Treasury„ B-838 - 2 The main purposes of the bill are: (1) to discontinue the use of the ESF as a source of payment of administrative expenses; and (2) to authorize appropriations to meet all administrative expenses associated with the Treasury Department1 s international affairs functions0 The bill also includes the various technical provisions necessary to accomplish this change with minimum disruption to the ongoing work of the Departmento The Exchange Stabilization Fund was created by the Gold Reserve Act of 1934 to provide financial resources for the Secretary of the Treasury to "stabilize the exchange value of the dollar." Those resources are authorized to be used for financial and monetary transactions (ESF "operations11) and for the payment of administrative expenses associated with carrying out the ESF's purpose0 The responsibilities of the Treasury Department in international affairs have increased substantially since 19340 In addition to managing the Exchange Stabilization Fund, the Secretary of the Treasury serves as U.S. Governor of the International Monetary Fund, International Bank for Reconstruction and Development, International Development Association, International Finance Corporation, Inter-American Development Bank, Asian Development Bank, and African Development Fundo The Secretary of the Treasury, as chief financial officer of the United States, serves as Chairman of the Economic Policy Group, the National Advisory Council on International Monetary and Financial Policies, and the East-West Foreign Trade Board; and participates in a variety of inter-agency committees on international economic issues such as the Trade Policy Committee, the Export Expansion Advisory Committee, and the Advisory Committee on P.L. 480. These responsibilities and the related efforts to coordinate international economic policy with domestic economic policy require a staff of experts and adequate administrative support. In today's interdependent world, effective operations in the broad area of international monetary policy require an organization equipped to develop information on, and analyze foreign activities in, the monetary, exchange, trade, investment and development fields, and other matters bearing on the U.S. external payments position; to assist in formulating U.S. policy positions on international economic and financial issues; and to implement those policies. - 3 Given the expanded responsibilities of the Treasury Department in international affairs, and the growing administrative costs resulting from those responsibilities, we examined the question whether it was appropriate to continue the off-budget status of these expenses through their funding from the ESF. We looked closely at the reasons why these sums had been plaid from ESF resources in the past. . Historically, there have been two main reasons for funding the administrative costs of Treasury's international function from the ESF rather than from appropriations: r 1) placing the administrative expenses on-budget might jeopardize the needed confidentiality r^ of specific ESF operations which the administrative expenses support; and 0j- 2) the administrative expenses could not be included V in budget projections because they could be highly unpredictable — with extraordinary developments in the international monetary and financial TC system at times requiring extraordinary expenditures. In our review, we found that administrative expenses directly tied to ESF operations comprise only a very small part of the total ESF administrative budget, and that large, unpredictable administrative expenditures have been increasingly rare. The major portion of the ESF administrative budget supports the broader range of Treasury international activities not directly associated with specific ESF operations. Accordingly, we concluded that ESF administrative expenses could be placed on-budget without jeopardizing the needed confidentiality of ESF operations, and that the Treasury's administrative expenses in the area of international affairs are amenable to the same kind of annual budgetary control and projection applied to other federal expenditures. The bill before you today would accomplish that budgetary control, and place ESF administrative expenses on a fully appropriated basis. Senate action has been completed, with passage of the bill on March 8. .1 urge this Committee to act promptly as well, in order to assure that we can accomplish the objective of this bill for the 1979 fiscal year. - 4I would also mention another question involving the ESF, which was raised soon after I came to Treasury -- access by the GAO to information and documents related to certain international economic activities of the Treasury Department. Mr. Staats and members of his staff met with me early last summer to discuss this matter. The GAO serves a very important function in reviewing and auditing government activities in various international areas. In conducting such authorized audits and reviews, the GAO may seek information on such international monetary matters as U.S. participation in the IMF, debt policies toward developing countries and the interrelationships of monetary and trade policies. In an exchange of letters with Mr. Staats, which is contained in the ESF Annual Report for Fiscal Year 1977, I provided assurance to the Comptroller General that Treasury will continue to cooperate fully in providing the GAO, on request, with such information, appropriate to its authorized audits and reports. In this regard, Treasury also will provide all information pertaining to the ESF relating to such GAO reports and studies, except where the information involves confidential ESF transactions with foreign governments^and monetary authorities or information related to the ESF's market transactions0 Such transactions continue, of course, to be the subject of confidential consultations with members of Congress, and ESF agreements with foreign governments and monetary authorities are transmitted formally to the Congress under the Case Act. I am pleased we have been able to work out cooperative arrangements in this regard which are satisfactory to the Comptroller General, and I am confident that we will have a continuing productive working relationship between the Treasury and the GAO. ESF Annual Report for Fiscal Year 1977 Mr. Chairman, I have provided the Subcommittee with copies of the ESF Annual Report for last fiscal year. This report reflects some fairly important developments and changes in the ESF's financial position and I felt it would be desirable to discuss it with you briefly today, given the opportunity of this hearing. - 5 - As indicated in the report, the very sharp appreciation of the Swiss franc in the exchange market is now creating large actual and accrued exchange losses for the ESF. The losses arise in connection with redemption by the Treasury of Swiss franc-denominated securities issued during the 1960's and early 1970's, under the Bretton Woods par value monetary system, prior to the collapse of that system in August 1971* These Swiss franc-denominated securities -- the so-called ! ^Roosa Bonds11 — were issued to help protect the U.S. gold stock and maintain the par value system. Although these securities were issued by the Treasury's General Account, the ESF has borne the U.S. exchange risk on such securities since their introduction in 1961. The contractual exchange risk provisions on these securities covered discrete par value changes. After the widespread move to floating exchange rates in 1973, the exchange risk provisions became indeterminate and subject to discussion between the U.S. and the Swiss authorities. Negotiations continued over a period of several years, during which no repayments were made by the Treasury and no losses were recorded. During fiscal year 1977, three things occurred. First, in October 1976, understandings were reached on the terms of redemption for these securities, and repayments began in November 1976. Second, exchange rates -- and particularly the exchange rate between the dollar and the Swiss franc -- began to move substantially, and potential exchange losses in connection with these securities began to rise. Finally, a new accounting standard was applied to the ESF for the first time, calling for accrued exchange losses to be recorded currently on the ESF balance sheet as a liability, rather than to be recorded only when realized. These developments have created substantial differences between the ESF's financial statements in this year's report and the reports of previous years. The points I would like to stress are the following. First, the cash exchange losses the ESF has realized to date have not substantially affected the ESF's assets, and the ESF's resources are adequate to meet the further prospective losses now foreseen. These cash and accrued exchange losses will not impair the U.S. ability to conduct necessary monetary operations. The ESF's cash position remains strong and its available SDR holdings are large. Although we presently record SDR allocations as an ESF liability, it is most improbable that this liability - 6- would ever become payable. The SDR allocations would have to be repaid only if the IMF or the SDR Department of the IMF were liquidated, if the U.S. withdrew from the IMF or the SDR Department, or if SDR allocations were cancelled. These are all highly unlikely contingencies, and the latter two are fully under the control of the United States. Second, the ESF's resources are important, but they are only a segment of the overall international monetary resources available to the United States. The ESF's accounts do nojb include, for example, Treasury holdings of gold; U.S. rights to use our reserve position in the IMF and to draw on the credit facilities of the IMF; or the reciprocal currency arrangements maintained by the Federal Reserve System. Third, neither the ESF accounts nor other Treasury accounts presently reflect the gains that could at some pflint accrue to the U.S. Government as a consequence of issuing the Swiss franc securities. As the Subcommittee knows, the essential purpose of issuing these securities was to forestall foreign purchases of U.S. gold as part of an effort to maihtain the old Bretton Woods par value system. We estimate that issuance of the Swiss franc securities resulted in the retention of about 36 million ounces of gold by the United States. Valued at the current market price for gold, this gold represents a potential gain of about $4-1/2 billion for the U.S. Government, or nearly four times the currently estimated losses on the Swiss franc securities. While the ESF thus remains sound and capable of fulfilling its functions, we are nonetheless considering whether the present ESF financial statements convey a fully accurate and meaningful picture of the ESF's financial condition. Accordingly, I have asked the Comptroller General to work with the Treasury to determine whether the accounting treatment presently applied to the items I mentioned earlier is fully appropriate and, if not, to recommend alternative approaches for the Secretary's consideration. I would expect to consult with the Committee again when this work has been completed. Thank you, Mrp Chairman. I would be happy to answer any questions you may have. oo 00 oo WtmentoftheTREASURY TELEPHONE 566-2041 SHINGTON, D.C. 20220 April 17, 1978 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE RESULTS OF TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL AUCTIONS Tenders for $2,300 million of 13-week Treasury bills and for $3,400 million of 26-week Treasury bills, both series to be issued on April 20, 1978, were accepted at the Federal Reserve Banks and Treasury today. The details are as follows: RANGE OF ACCEPTED COMPETITIVE BIDS: 13-week bills maturing July 20, 1978 Price High Low Average Discount Rate 98.453 a/6.120% 6.152% 98.445 6.140% 98.448 26-week bills maturing October 19, 1978 Investment Rate 1/ Discount Investment Price Rate Rate 1/ 6.30% 6.34% 6.32% 96.695b/ 6.537% 6.85% 96.678 6.571% 6.89% 96.682 6.563% 6.88% a/ Excepting 1 tender of $1,745,000 b/ Excepting 1 tender of $200,000 Tenders at the low price for the 13-week bills were allotted Tenders at the low price for the 26-week bills were allotted TOTAL TENDERS RECEIVED AND ACCEPTED BY FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTS AND TREASURY: Location Received Accepted Received Accepted $ 15,440,000 4,901,045,000 9,800,000 32,900,000 24,165,000 16,605,000 199,925,000 45,500,000 31,005,000 39,285,000 9,015,000 355,965,000 $ 8,540,000 3,160,845,000 9,800,000 12,900,000 18,405,000 14,760,000 28,925,000 17,500,000 21,005,000 38,985,000 9,015,000 49,965,000 Boston $ 20,410,000 New York 4,013,495,000 Philadelphia 18,460,000 Cleveland 44,405,000 Richmond 38,280,000 Atlanta 38,120,000 Chicago 203,985,000 St. Louis 53,260,000 Minneapolis 23,270,000 Kansas City 31,935,000 Dallas 18,775,000 San Francisco 317,910,000 $ 20,410,000 1,914,340,000 18,460,000 42,580,000 30,005,000 35,670,000 57,105,000 25,260,000 21,270,000 31,935,000 18,475,000 72,900,000 Treasury 11,735,000 11,735,000 9,605,000 9,605,000 - $4,834,040,000 $2,300,145,000 c/ $5,690,255,000 $3,400,250,000d/ TOTALS ^Includes $447,490,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. Includes $204,945,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. Equivalent coupon-issue yield. 839 TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL OFFERING The Department of the Treasury, by this public notice, invites tenders for two series of Treasury bills totaling approximately $5,700 million, to be issued April 27, 1978. This offering will result in a pay-down for the Treasury of about $6,016 million as the maturing bills are outstanding in the amount of $11,716 million ($6,006 million of which represents 24-day bills issued April 3, 1978). The two series offered are as follows: 91-day bills (to maturity date) for approximately $2,300 million, representing an additional amount of bills dated January 26, 1978, and to mature July 27, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 S4 9), originally issued in the amount of $3,503 million, the additional and original bills to be freely interchangeable. 182-day bills for approximately $3,400 million to be dated April 27, 1978, and to mature October 26, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 T9 7). Both series of bills will be issued for cash and in exchange for Treasury bills maturing April 27, 1978. Federal Reserve Banks, for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities, presently hold $3,387 million of the maturing bills. These accounts may exchange bills they hold for the bills now being offered at the weighted average prices of accepted competitive tenders. The bills will be issued on a discount basis under competitive and noncompetitive bidding, and at maturity their par amount will be payable without interest. Except for definitive bills in the $100,000 denomination, which will be available only to investors who are able to show that they are required by law or regulation to hold securities in physical form, both series of bills will be issued entirely in book-entry form in a minimum amount of $10,000 and in any higher $5,000 multiple, on the records either of the Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or of the Department of the Treasury. Tenders will be received at Federal Reserve Banks and Branches and at the Bureau of the Public Debt, Washington, D. C. 20226, up to 1:30 p.m., Eastern Standard time, Monday, April 24, 1978. Form PD 4632-2 (for 26-week series) or Form PD 4632-3 (for 13-week series) should be used to submit tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. B-840 -2Each tender must be for a minimum of $10,000. Tenders over $10,000 must be in multiples of $5,000. In the case of competitive tenders the price offered must be expressed on the basis of 100, with not more than three decimals, e.g., 99.925. Fractions may not be used. Banking institutions and dealers who make primary markets in Government securities and report daily to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York their positions in and Dorrowings on such securities may submit tenders for account of customers, if the names of the customers and the amount for each customer are furnished. Others are only permitted to submit tenders for their own account. Payment for the full par amount of the bills applied for must accompany all tenders submitted for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. A cash adjustment will be made on all accepted tenders for the difference between the par payment submitted and the actual issue price as determined in the auction. No deposit need accompany tenders from incorporated banks and trust companies and from responsible and recognized dealers in investment securities for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or for bills issued in bearer form, where authorized. A deposit of 2 percent of the par amount of the bills applied for must accompany tenders for such bills from others, unless an express guaranty of payment by an incorporated bank or trust company accompanies the tenders. Public announcement will be made by the Department of the Treasury of the amount and price range of accepted bids. Competitive bidders will be advised of the acceptance or rejection of their tenders. The Secretary of the Treasury expressly reserves the right to accept or reject any or all tenders, in whole or in part, and the Secretary's action shall be final. Subject to these reservations, noncompetitive tenders for each issue for $500,000 or less without stated price from any one bidder will be accepted in full at the weighted average price (in three decimals) of accepted competitive bids for the respective issues. Settlement for accepted tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, and bills issued in bearer form must be made or completed at the Federal Reserve Bank or Branch or at the Bureau of the Public Debt on April 27, 1978, in cash or other immediately available funds or in Treasury bills maturing April 17, 1978. cash adjustments will be made for differences between the the maturing bills accepted m exchange andpar thevalue issueof price of the new bills. -3Under Sections 454(b) and 1221(5) of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954 the amount of discount at which these bills are sold is considered to accrue when the bills are sold, redeemed or otherwise disposed of, and the bills are excluded from consideration as capital assets. Accordingly, the owner of these bills (other than life insurance companies) must include in his or her Federal income tax return, as ordinary gain or loss, the difference between the price paid for the bills, whether on original issue or on subsequent purchase, and the amount actually received either upon sale or redemption at maturity during the taxable year for which the return is made. Department of the Treasury Circulars, No. 418 (current revision), Public Debt Series - Nos. 26-76 and 27-76, and this notice, prescribe the terms of these Treasury bills and govern the conditions of their issue. Copies of the circulars and tender forms may be obtained from any Federal Reserve Bank or Branch, or from the Bureau of the Public Debt. CO i—1 )L- VO Zi Csi VO ?aeraiWASHINGTON, iinancmg DanK D.C 20220 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE CO CO m CVi a > <\j i_ o Q_ April 18, 1978 SUMMARY OF FEDERAL FINANCING BANK ACTIVITY March 1-March 31, 1978 Federal Financing Bank activity for the month of March, 1978, was announced as follows by Roland H. Cook, Secretary: On March 1, the Export-Import Bank of the United States sold Note #14 to the Federal Financing Bank in the amount of $260 million, maturing December 1, 1987, and bearing interest at a rate of 8.024% on a quarterly basis. The United States Railway Association made the following drawdowns guaranteed by the Department of Transportation: Date Note # Amount Maturity Interest Rate 13 $1,500,000 8.125% 12/26/90 4/30/79 7.513% 8 1,218,250 4/30/79 7.491% 8 307,000 12/26/90 8.125% 13 500,000 4/30/79 7.533% 8 1,670,000 The FFB purchased participation certificates from the General Services Administration in the following amounts: 3/1 3/7 3/9 3/15 3/30 Date Series 3/2 3/9 3/14 3/31 K-005 M-031 L-038 K-006 Amount $2,172,307. 14 3,196,308.,53 1,568,977. 20 1,975,972. 56 Maturity Interest Rate 7/15/04 7/31/03 11/15/04 7/15/04 8.39% 8.367% 8.329% 8.439% On March 3, the Bank advanced $901,741.00 at an interest rate of 8.241% on a quarterly basis to the Missouri-Kansas-Texas Railroad. The advance was made under a $12 million note which is guaranteed by the Department of Transportation and matures on November 15, 1997. B-841 - 2The FFB purchased from the Student Loan Marketing Association the following notes guaranteed by the Department of Health, Education and Welfare: Interest Date Note # Amount Maturity Rate 6/6/78 $45,000,000 6.668% 134 3/7 6/13/78 45,000,000 6.618% 3/14 135 3/21 136 6/20/78 45,000,000 6.519% 3/28 137 6/27/78 70,000,000 6.626% The National Rail Passenger Corporation drew the following amounts under Note #13 which matures on April 30, 1978, and is guaranteed by the Department of Transportation: Interest Date Amount Rate $1,184,000 3/10 6.573% 1,500,000 3/20 6.486% 1,000,000 3/28 6.574% 4,000,000 3/31 6.793% The Tennessee Valley Authority sold notes to the FFB in the following amounts: Interest Date Note # Amount Maturity Rate 3/14 6.719% 72 6/30/78 $100,000,000 3/31 6.607% 73 6/30/78 225,000,000 On March 20, the Bank advanced $9.7 million to the Western Union Space Communications at a rate of 8.261% on an annual basis. The advance to Western Union was made against a $687 million master note maturing on October 1, 1989, the repayment of which is secured by the National Aeronautics and Space Administration's obligations to Western Union under a tracking system procurement contract. On March 16, the FFB purchased a Certificate of Beneficial Ownership from the Farmers Home Administration in the amount of $505 million. The maturity is March 16, 1983 and the interest rate is 8.14% on an annual basis. On March 22, the Bank purchased debentures from Small Business Investment Companies in the aggregate amount of $8,440,000 bearing an interest rate of 8.135% and maturing on March 1, 1988. The debentures are guaranteed by the Small Business Administration. On March 31, the Bank purchased a Certificate of Beneficial Ownership from the Rural Electrification Administration in the amount of $97,023,000. The maturity is March 31, 2008, and the interest rate is 8.465%. - 3 The Federal Financing Bank advanced the following amounts to utility companies under notes guaranteed by the Rural Electrification Administration: Interest Rate Date Borrower Amount Maturity 12/31/12 12/31/12 3/6/80 12/31/12 12/31/12 8.315% 8.315% 7.671% 8.315% 8.315% 7,000,000 400,000 12/31/12 12/31/12 8.327% 8.327% 3/8 East Ascension Telephone Co.450,000 157,000 "3/8 Big River Elect. Corp. 5,800,000 3/8 Tri-State Gen. § Trans. 3/8/80 12/31/12 6/30/80 7.662% 8.30% 7.701% 12/31/12 8.292% 12/31/12 8.268%. 3/1 3/1 3/1 3/1 3/1 u 3/2 3/2 Oglethorpe Elect. Membership$ Arkansas Elec. Coop. Corp. Golden Valley Elect. Assn. United Power Assn. East Kentucky Power Coop. Cooperative Power Assn. Allied Tele. Co. of Arkansas 3/10 Allegheny Electric Corp. 4,392,000 • 20,145,000 728,000 12,000,000 2,649,000 2,056,000 3/14 Northwest Iowa Power Coop. 28,108,000 3/15 Colorado-Ute Elect. Assn. 4,467,000 12/31/12 8.268% 3/16 Cajun Elect. Power Coop. 3/16 Cooperative Power Assn. 3/16 Allied Tele. Co. of Arkansas 56,000,000 10,000,000 343,000 3/16/80 12/31/12 12/31/12 7.642% 8.27% 8.27% 3/17 Empire Telephone Co. 66,000 12/31/12 8.269% 3/20 Big River Power Corp. 3/20 Corn Belt Power Corp. 4,292,000 1,333,000 12/31/12 12/31/12 8.268% 8.268% 3/27 Basin Elect. Power Corp. 1,723,000 3/27/80 7.662% 3/29 Big River Elect. Corp. 340,000 12/31/12 8.356% 2,610,000 3/30 Southern Illinois Power Corp. 1,165,000 3/30 Big River Elect. Corp. 3/30/80 12/31/12 7.74% 8.353% 9,212,000 3/31 Oglethorpe Elect. Membership 1,621,000 3/31 Allegheny Elect.' Coop. 12/31/12 12/31/12 8.36% 8.36% Interest payments on the a quarterly basis. above REA advances are made on On March 8, the FFB entered into a guaranty agreement with the Department of Transportation (DOT) to purchase up to $17.6 million of Chicago § Northwestern Transportation Company obligations. The obligations are guaranteed by DOT under §511 of the Railroad Revitalization and Regulatory Reform Act of 1976, and are repayable in ten equal annual installments beginning March 1, 1980. - 4 The FFB made the following advances to foreign governments under loans guaranteed by the Department of Defense: Date of Date of Promissory Interest Borrower Amount Advance Note Maturity Rate 3/9 Argentina 6/30/76 $ 327,844.77 6/30/83 7.879% 6/30/76 3/13 93,588.40 6/30/83 7.8551 6/30/76 3/27 877,926.26 6/30/83 7.8741 China 6/29/76 3/2 1,520,000.00 7/1/84 7.9661 6/30/77 3/24 3,400,000.00 7/1/85 7.966% Colombia 6/10/76 3/30 939,594.61 6/30/83 7.9491 Costa Rica 9/30/77 3/6 1,000,404.00 4/10/83 7.91% Honduras 9/30/77 9/30/77 9/30/77 3/2 3/3 3/23 11,264.00 23,250.00 231,250.00 10/7/82 10/7/82 10/7/82 7.8811 7.869% 7.803% Indonesia 7/1/76 7/1/76 7/1/76 7/1/76 7/1/76 9/30/77 2/15/78 6/24/77 2/15/78 2/15/78 2/14/78 9/6/77 9/6/77 9/6/77 9/30/77 3/3 3/8 3/9 3/20 3/27 3/31 3/10 3/14 3/14 3/21 3/23 3/3 3/14 3/30 3/22 267,446.67 802,576.00 253,650.94 802,576.00 164,142.16 3,133,856.00 100,000,000.00 14,514.25 22,526,894.97 1,150,000.00 23,890,338.53 103,778.57 79,487,147.25 227,605.82 12,902.40 6/30/83 6/30/83 6/30/83 6/30/83 6/30/83 9/20/86 1/12/08 5/12/07 1/12/08 1/12/08 1/12/08 12/31/84 12/31/84 12/31/84 6/30/83 7.908% 7.882% 7.879% 7.844% 7.874% 8.117% 8.353% 8.316% 8.325* 8.304% 8.315% 9/30/77 9/30/77 7/28/75 9/30/77 9/30/77 3/13 3/24 3/24 3/2 3/20 1,683,500.00 3/20/84 5,050,500.00 3/20/84 1,385,129.58 6/30/83 1,969,018.50 4/10/84 38,025.76 4/10/84 7.96% 7.889% Senegal 9/29/77 3/6 1,482,395.18 9/10/89 8.157% Spain 9/28/77 9/28/77 3/21 3/23 7,860,732.00 3,447,394.00 6/10/87 6/10/87 7.987% 8.012% Thailand 9/29/76 9/29/76 3/1 3/2 772,671.09 60,317.88 6/30/83 6/30/83 7.889% 7.916% Tunisia 9/29/76 9/29/77 3/6 3/14 3,521,371.46 44,106.00 10/1/84 10/1/85 7.982% 7.952% 9/30/76 9/22/77 3/3 3/3 7,091,218.75 2,498,043.79 10/1/86 10/1/87 8.041% 8.082% Israel Korea Liberia Malaysia Peru Turkey totaned^Jz.^binlSJ.8^ h °ldinSs on March 31, 1978, 7.987% 7.927% 8.038% 7.835% 7.894% 7.919% 7.873% FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE Contact: John P. Plum — 202-566-2615 Wednesday, April 19f 1978 NEW FISCAL ASSISTANCE LEGISLATION GOES TO CONGRESS The Department of the Treasury today submitted legislation to Congress embodying the Administration's Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program, an important element in President Carter's urban policy. The new measure would replace the expiring Anti-recession Fiscal Assistance Program (also called countercyclical revenue sharing) and would use funds already included in the fiscal 19 79 budget for the countercyclical program. Although the general economy has improved and overall unemployment rates are declining, certain fiscally strained local governments need supplemental fiscal assistance because their underlying economies continue to be weak. The recommended legislation authorizes an appropriation of $1.04 billion for FY 1979 and $1.0 billion for FY 1980. Funds will be allocated annually, although actual disbursements will occur quarterly. General purpose local governments are eligible for the program if they are experiencing either unemployment in excess of 4.5 percent or disptoportionately slow growth in any two of the following three economic indicators — employment, per capita income or population. The new eligibility criteria will target aid to those local governments whose fiscal strain primarily reflects long term economic weakness. The new program provides general purpose fiscal assistance because this type of aid gives more flexibility to recipient governments. Generally, such governments have shrinking revenue bases caused by a long-term out-migration of taxpayers, investment and jobs. Additional tax rate increases o¥ service reductions would only cause further economic decline. The new formula establishes broader measures of need for all governments, especially smaller jurisdictions, by including the three additional economic indicators and by separating small from large governments. Indian tribes, Alaskan native villages, certain territories and the Commonwealth of Puerto Rico would be eligible for assistance under the legislation. oOo B-842 SECTIONAL ANALYSIS of a bill "To authorize a supplementary fiscal assistance program of payments to local governments, and for other purposes." Section 101, Short Title. This section provides that the Act may be cited as the "Supplementary Fiscal Assistance Act of 1978." Section 102, Findings of Fact and Declarations of Policy. This section sets forth a policy statement on the importance of the economic veil-being of local governments to the national economy. Many local governments have experienced secular decline, and are also suffering from the effects of national economic problems. Due to these economic factors, there is a need for a program to continue general purpose fiscal assistance to local governments experiencing budgetary hardship due to secular economic decline. In addition, assistance to local governments is an essential element of a comprehensive urban policy. Section 103, Authorization of Payments. This section authorizes the Secretary of the Treasury (hereinafter referred to as "the Secretary") to make payments each calendar quarter to local governments experiencing substantial unemployment (above 4.52) or secular economic decline, as reflected in slow growth or decline in two of the three following factors: employment, per capita income and population. (I 103(a) and (b)) This section also authorizes an appropriation of $1,040,000,000 for each of fiscal year 1979 and $1,000,000,000 for fiscal year 1980 for payments to eligible local and territorial governments, Indian tribes and Alaskan -2- native villages, in addition to funds necessary for the administration of the program. This level of funding for the program it consistent with the President's budget. Payments are authorized only to local and territorial governments, Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages, and the level of funding represents an amount that approximates such governments' aggregate share under title II of the Public Works Employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 U.S.C. I 6721 jet seq; hereinafter referred to as "title II"). State governments are excluded for several reasons. As independent political entities, State governments have a variety of revenue sources that are not available to local governments. Further, many State governments have current revenue surpluses and, as a whole, are less in need of supplemental fiscal assistance than local governments experiencing substantial unemployment or secular economic decline. Also, State governments are generally not experiencing a secular economic decline. Direct payments to local governments will be more effective in alleviating budgetary hardships resulting from high levels of unemployment and secular economic decline within a local jurisdiction. The existing program under title II contains several variable factors which control the level of funding nationally, and to individual governments each quarter. These fluctuations in funding cause a considerable decree of uncertainty on the part of recipient governments and hinder their efforts to plan, budget and efficiently use the funds. A great deal of the uncertainty as to funding levels and eligibility in the existing program is eliminated in the program under this Act. The latter provides for the -3aaount appropiated to be allocated and paid nationally during a fiscal year. Also, the possibly that funding would cease when the national rate of unemployment fell to six percent has been deleted from this Act. Payments would continue to be made on a quarterly basis but allocations to the individual governments would be made annually; quarterly allocation and reallocation, as required by the existing program, are no longer deemed necessary since the mitigation of cyclical fluctuations is no longer a purpose of the legislation. Local governments would thus have adequate notice of whether they are eligible for the program, and of the amount of their payment for the upcoming fiscal year. Payments would be made within the first five days of each calendar quarter in fiscal years 1979 and 1980. The program of payments under this Act, like those under the State and Local Fiscal Assistance Act of 1972, as amended (31 U.S.C. I 1221 et aeq.) and title II of the Public Works Employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 D.S.C. § 6721 et seq.) , is not a grafot or financial assistance program. It is an entitlement program and, as such, is not governed by the requirements and conditions normally applicable to grant or financial assistance programs. Section 104, Local Government Allocation. This section contains the formula, definitions and eligibility criteria used to allocate funds to local governments under this Act. The formula criteria are necessarily Complex to accommodate the various measures of fiscal strain and financial need. Section 104(a) provides that each eligible local government's annual allocation under the Act will equal its "local government percentage" -4- •ultiplied by the appropriation for the fiscal year leas the amounts allocable to the territories under f 113 and to Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages under | 114. Section 104(b) provides the method for determining a "local government percentage . That percentage represents each government's share of the annual appropriation. A local government percentage is computed by multiplying a government's "local distribution index" (a term defined in S 104(c)(5)) by its local revenue sharing amount for the most recently completed general revenue sharing entitlement period, and then dividing the product of that multiplication by the sum of such products for all eligible local governments nationally. This allocation formula differs from the formula under title II which is geared exclusively to unemployment, and multiplies a government's unemployment rate in excess of 4.52 by its local revenue sharing amount. The local government index used for the program in this Act utilizes several additional data factors in measuring fiscal need. The local revenue sharing amount data factor under the current legislation is retained because of its factors of tax effort, population and per capita income. Also, it is incorporated so as to produce a result consistent with the distribution pattern of the current program. Section 104(c) set6 forth the eligibility criteria and the method of calculating a local government index for each eligible local government. The definition for a local government ($ 104(c)(1)) is substantially the same as the definitions used in the State and Local Fiscal Assistance Act of 1972, as amended (31 U.S.C. 1221 et seq.) and title II. -5- Eligibility (| 104(c)(2)) is limited to fiscally distressed local governments because State governments generally have a greater revenue raising capacity and would be better able to replace title II funds. For the purpose of determining eligibility, local governments are divided into two categories - those wholly or pa/tly within a standard metropolitan statistical area (SMSA) (S 104(c)(2)(A)) and those entirely outside an SMSA (non-SMSA) (S 104(c)(2)(B)). Because of techniques used to generate unemployment and employment data, separation into SMSA and non-SMSA groups will compensate for and minimize measurement discrepancies between the sizes of potential recipient governments. Fiscal stress between urban and rural governments may not be comparable by the same measures, and the SMSA/non-SMSA distinction is intended to equalize the relative posture of each group. A government will be eligible if it has an unemployment rate in excess of 4.5 Z, or if it satisfies two of the following three conditions: (1) its local rate of growth in employment is less than such rate for all SMSAs (or non-SMSAs); (2) its local rate of growth in per capita income is less than such rate for all SMSAs (or non-SMSAs) or; (3) its local rate of growth in population is less than such rate for all SMSAs (or non-SMSAs). Therefore, a government can qualify on the basis of its unemployment rate, or its slow growth as compared to its group (SMSA or non-SMSA) in two of the three data factors specified above (employment, population or per capita income). Generally, these growth rates are determined by subtracting from the most recently available data for each data category, the data for a preceding comparable period of time for all eligible local governments, or for a specific government, as appropriate, and dividing that difference by the data for such prior period. -6- The eligibility criteria measure the government's secular economic condition and serve as indicators of a government's fiscal atrain, if any. The use of a local unemployment rate (I 104(c)(3)(A)) in excess of 4.52 results in targeting to areas with higher fiscal strain, since unemployment rates above this level generally reflect the magnitude of secular decline, such as decline in employment, low assessable base growth, and high tax burdens. Unemployment rate is a conceptually straightforward measure of economic distress that is widely accepted by the public, Congress, and various interest groups, and is used in the current program. Therefore, the use of unemployment also provides a link with the existing distribution pattern. A virtue of unemployment rates is their availability on a current basis. The use of an unemployment rate above 4.5 2 also serves as a measure of a local government's social welfare burden in terms of welfare payments, and health and criminal justice services. The local rate of growth in employment (S 104(c)(3)(B)) is a good indicator of the long term trend of the local economy. When used in conjunction with the local rate of growth in per capita income and population, it may give a better indication of secular economic decline in rural government areas than unemployment alone. Also, it represents the employment aspects of the unemployment, and is more indicative of government revenues, since employment generates tax receipts. As a determinant of taxable wealth and level of economic activity, measurement of local rate of growth in per capita income ($ 104(c)(3)(C)) gauges each government's economic position relative to its group (SMSA or -7- non-SiSA). For governments in rural areas, this is a particularly good indication of relative secular economic decline. Per capita income is also an important measure of living standards and purchasing power, and therefore relates directly to economic conditions and government financial condition. This indicator can also provide a measure of underemployment, which is particularly common in rural areas because many agricultural jobs pay low wages in relation to manufacturing or service jobs, and there are often too few full-time jobs relative to population. Recent evidence indicates that there is a direct relationship between local rate of growth in population (I 104(c)(3)(D)) and fiscal condition. Generally, cities with declining or slowing population growth have greater fiscal strain. The local rate of growth in population is also considered to be a good indicator of a community's attractiveness in terms of its ability to draw future residents and a labor aupply and, thus, of its future economic health. The local rate of growth in population may reflect past shifts in economic activity as well as how to predict future changes. Individuals make residential choices for a number of reasons. To the extent that people move m search of better employment opportunities, the rate of growth in population is a second-order indicator of past economic performance. Population changes affect governmental revenues and expenditures, either directly or indirectly, since they impact the economic base of a government. For example, the residential property tax is the foundation of most local government revenues. Changes in population influence the amount of property -8tax revenues by causing changes in the market value of residential property. As the population of a city increases, demand for available housing is likely to rise and ao will its market value and, thus, property tax revenues. Although the supply of housing will in time expand in response to this rise in demand, this does not happen immediately. A fall in a city's population produces the opposite effect: demand drops, as do market values and property tax receipts. The supply of housing in this instance is usually even more unresponsive and will remain constant for some time. Once the SMSA and non-SMSA eligible governments are identified, the next step is to determine each eligible government's "local distribution index" (S 104(c)(5)). Several calculations are used so that each government gets the benefit of whichever one produces the highest result. These four separate calculations are based on the following data: (I) the local rate of unemployment in excess of 4.5 2; and the local rates of growth in (2) employment, (3) per capita income, and (4) population. For each of these data categories, the difference between a local government's rate and its group's (SMSA or non-SMSA) rate is divided by the standard deviation (weighted by population to account for differences in size between governments) of the rates of the governments in its group. Once this index is developed for each government, it is used to compute that government'8 local government percentage. That percentage represents a local government'6 share of the total funds to be made available for payments to local governments each fiscal year of the program. -9- Section 104(d) provides that if the annual allocation to a local or territorial government, Indian tribe or Alaskan native village for a fiscal year is less than $200, such government ahall not receive any payment for that fiscal year. Allocations below $200 per year are too small to be meaningful to the those governments and the processing of the payments creates a substantial administrative burden (| 104(d)(1)). The other limitation on allocations (§ 104(d)(2)) is that a government may not receive more funds under the Act than it received under title II during the period beginning July 1, 1977 and ending June 30, 1978, except for those governments which received no allocation under such Act during that time period. Funds made available due to this allocation constraint will be redistributed to the remaining governments (§ 104(d)(3)). Governments that received no allocations under title II during the aforementioned time period will not benefit from this redistribution of funds. Section 104(e) provides authority regarding treatment, for allocation purposes, of a local government located only in part within a larger political entity, and authority to take into account boundary changes and governmental reorganizations. Section 105, Use of Payments. This section provides that payments under the Act shall be used for basic services customarily provided to persons under the jurisdiction of the recipient local or territorial government, Indian tribe or Alaskan native village. The governments may use payments for the same governmental purposes for which as they use their own revenues, -10- including capital expenditures for equipment and construction projects. This provision eliminates the restriction on capital expenditures currently applicable to payments under title II. As with funds under title II, these payments may be used as the local contribution for a Federal matching grant 49 to be utilized in a manner not inconsistent with the Act. Section 106, Statement of Assurances. This section provides that in order for a local or territorial government, Indian tribe or Alaskan native village to receive a payment, a statement of assurances shall be filed annually with the Secretary. The signatory government shall assure the Secretary that it will comply with the following conditions in the expenditure of payments under the draft bill: the government will use the funds for basic expenditures as set forth in Section 105 (S 106(a)); it will use fiscal, accounting and audit procedures that conform to guidelines established by the Secretary (after consultation with the Comptroller General) (§ 106(b)(1)); it will provide access to the Secretary (and the Comptroller General) of any books, documents, papers or records as the Secretary may require to review compliance within the provisions of the Act (§ 106(b) (2)); it will make such reports as are requested by the Secretary to carry out the purposes ofthe Act (§ 106(c)); it will comply with the nondiscrimination requirements of section 107 (§ 106(d)) and the labor standards requirements of section 108 (I 106(e)); and it will use payments only in accordance with the substantive laws and budgetary procedures that are applicable to the use of its own source revenues (I 106(f)). The latter 11- assurance is currently in the State and Local Fiscal Assistance Act of 1972, as amended, and title II and would be the principal restriction on the use of the payments under this Act. Section 107, Nondiscrimination. This section prohibits discrimination on the basis of race, color, national origin or sex under any program or activity funded by payments under either this Act or title II (S 107(a)(1)). Any prohibition against discrimination on the basis of age under the Age Discrimination Act of 1975 (42 U.S.C. I 6101 et seq.) or with respect to an otherwise qualified handicapped individual as provided in section 504 of the Rehabilitation Act of 1973 (29 U.S.C. I 794 et seq.) also applies to any such program or activity; the handicap discrimination provisions would not be applicable to construction projects begun before January 1, 1977 (S 107(a)(2)(B)). The ban on discrimination on the basis of religion in the Civil Rights Act of 1964 (42 U.S.C. S 2000e(2)) and in title VIII of the Civil Rights Act of 1968 (42 U.S.C. IS 3601-19) also applies to such program or activity. In addition, the provisions of the State and Local Fiscal Assistance Act of 1972, as amended and title II with respect to fund tracing (S 107(a)(2)(A)), administrative enforcement, the authority of the Attorney General to intervene or initiate suit, and private remedies (31 U.S.C. S 1242, 1244-45), are incorporated in this section (I 107(b)) of the Act. Thus, the section is substantially similar to the pertinent provision in title II. fowever, it is intended that any act of discrimination alleged to have occurred prior to the effective data of this Act, despite the repeal of title II, will continue to be subject to the jurisdiction of the Secretary. -12- Section 108, Labor Standards. This section provides that all laborers and mechanics employed by contractors on construction projects funded in whole or in part by payments under this Act or title II shall be paid wages at rates not lets than those prevailing on similar projects in the locality ss determined by the Secretary of Labor under the Davis-Bacon Act (40 U.S.C. If 276a-5). This section is substantially identical to the pertinent provision in title II. However, it is again intended that the Secretary retain jurisdiction, notwithstanding the repeal of title II. Section 109, Withholding. This section provides that after affording reasonable notice and an opportunity for a hearing, payments shall be withheld by the Secretary from a government that has failed to perform any action covered by any assurance required by section 106 of this Act or by title II, except for the nondiscrimination provisions, until the Secretary is satisfied that compliance with that section has been achieved. For discrimination cases, the remedies and procedures of section 107 apply. Section 110, Data Provision Responsibilities. This section requires the Secretary of Labor and the Secretary of Commerce to collect and make available to the Secretary the data needed to administer the Act. The Secretaries of Labor and Commerce are also required to advise the Secretary as to the availability and reliability of data relevant to the program. Section 111, Rulemaking Authority. This section authorizes the Secretary, after consultation with the Secretaries of Labor and Commerce, to prescribe -13- rules necessary to carry out his functions under this Act, not later than 90 days after the effective date of this Act. Section 112, Reports. This section provides that the Secretary shall report to Congress as soon as practical after the end of each calendar year during which payments are made, on the amounts paid to local governments, Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages, as well as withholding actions taken pursuant to section 107 (Nondiscrimination) and section 109 (Withholding). Section 113, Allocations to Puerto Rico, Guam, American Samoa, and the United States Virgin Islands ("territories"). This section allocates to these territories, in the aggregate, an amount equal to 12 of the amount appropriated for each fiscal year ($ 113(a)). Each of the territories shall receive an allocation based on its population compared to the total population of all the territories (S H3fb)(1)). Each territory may allocate such sums to the local governments within its jurisdiction as it deems appropriate (S 113(c)). This is similar to the pertinent provision in the title II, except that the funds paid to the territories under this Act are not in addition to the funds paid to the eligible local governments. Section 114, Allocations to Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages. This section allocates to Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages, in the aggregate, an amount equal to 0.32 of the amount appropriated for each fiscal year (I 114(a)). Each tribe or village shall receive an allocation -14- based on its population compared to the total population of all Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages (§ 114(b)(1)). This differs from title II, under which the tribes and villages Are generally treated in the same manner as local governments. Section 115, Applicability to Antirecession Fiscal Assistance. This section repeals title II with certain exceptions and provides that the expenditure of any funds made available in fiscal years 1977 and 1978 provided under title II, which remain unexpended, ahall be governed by the provisions of this Act. Thus, restrictions under title II relating to use and other matters will no longer be applicable to the expenditure of those funds, after this Act becomes effective. Since the countercyclical aspects of the existing program are no longer relevant under this Act, funds remaining available for expenditure will not be subject to the requirements that have been imposed for countercyclical purposes. The exceptions to repeal are for the purpose of ensuring that the assurance, nondiscrimination, labor standards and withholding provisions of title II remain in force with respect to title II funds. It is intended by this means to preserve the Secretary's jurisdiction over noncompliance which has, or is alleged to have, occurred prior to the effective date of this Act. A Bill To authorize a supplementary fiscal assistance program of payments to local governments, and for other purposes. Be it enacted by the Senate and the House of Representatives of the United States of America in Congress assembled, that this Act may be cited as the "Supplementary Fiscal Assistance Act of 1978." FINDINGS OF FACT AND DECLARATION OF POLICY SEC. 102. FINDINGS.— The Congress finds and declares — (a) that local governments represent a significant segment of the national economy whose sound fiscal and economic condition is essential to national economic prosperity; (b) that secular economic decline and national economic problems have imposed considerable hardships on many local government budgets; (c) that general purpose assistance has been especially helpful to those governments experiencing secular economic problems which are aggravated by severe cyclical fluctuations; and (d) that a general assistance program which aids local communities requiring fiscal relief is an essential component of a comprehensive urban policy. AUTHORIZATION OF PAYMENTS SEC. 103. (a) IN GENERAL. ~ The Secretary of the Treasury (hereinafter referred to as the "Secretary") shall in accordance with the provisions of this Act make payments to local governments, territories, Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages to provide fiscal assistance to areas experiencing substantial unemployment or a high degree of fiscal strain or secular -2- economic decline as reflected in disproportionately alow growth in employment, per capita income and population. (b) PAYMENTS TO RECIPIENT GOVERNMENTS. — The Secretary ahall pay, not later than five days after the beginning of each calendar quarter, to each eligible local government, territory, Indian tribe and Alaskan native village, which has filed a statement of assurances under section 106, an amount equal to one fourth of the annual amount allocated to such government under section 104. The first quarterly payment shall be made within the first five days of October, 1978. Payments under this Act may be made with necessary adjustments on account of overpayments or underpayments. (c) AUTHORIZATION FOR APPROPRIATIONS. — There is hereby authorized to be appropriated for payments to eligible local governments, territories, Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages for the fiscal year 1979 the sum of $1,040,000,000, and for the fiscal year 1980 the sum of $1,000,000,000, and such additional sums in each fiscal year as may be necessary for the administration of this Act. LOCAL GOVERNMENT ALLOCATION SEC. 104 (a) IN GENERAL. — The Secretary shall allocate to each eligible local government from the amount appropriated for payments for each fiscal year pursuant to section 103, an amount for each such fiscal year equal to such government's local government percentage multiplied by an amount equal to the difference between the amount appropriated pursuant to section 103 and the amounts allocable pursuant to sections 113 and 114. Such allocation shall -3be made by the Secretary during the September preceding the appropriate fiscal year for which such allocation is made, based on the most current available data, pursuant to rules issued under section 111 of this Act. (b) LOCAL GOVERNMENT PERCENTAGE. — For purposes of this Act the local government percentage for an eligible local government is equal to the quotient resulting from (1) the product of the local distribution index for such eligible local government multiplied by the local revenue sharing amount for such eligible local government, divided by (2) the sum of such products for all eligible local governments. (c) DEFINITIONS. — For purposes of this Act (1) "local government" means a county, municipality, township, or other political subdivision of a State which is a unit of general government (determined on the same principles as are used by the Bureau of the Census for general statistical purposes), and performs substantial governmental functions. Such term includes the District of Columbia. (2) "eligible local government" means a local government which satisfies the following conditions: (A) For a local government with boundaries in whole or in part within a Standard Metropolitan Statistical Area (SMSA), as defined by the Department of Commerce and reported to the Secretary (hereinafter "SMSA governments"), an "eligible local government" is a local government which, in the area under its jurisdiction, either — -4- (i) has a local unemployment rate as determined pursuant to subparagraph (3)(A) in excess of 4.5 percentage points; or (ii) satisfies at least two of the following: (js) the local rate of growth in employment, as determined pursuant to subparagraph (3)(B), is less than the rate of growth in employment in all SMSAs; (b) the local rate of growth in per capita income, as determined pursuant to subparagraph (3)(C), is less than the rate of growth in per capita income for all SMSAs; (c) the local rate of growth in population, as determined pursuant to subparagraph (3)(D), is less than the rate of growth in population for all SMSAs. (B) For a local government with boundaries entirely outside an SMSA (hereinafter "non-SMSA governments"), an "eligible local government" is a local government which meets the unemployment or growth criteria set forth in subparagraphs (2)(A)(i) or (ii), above, except that the term "non-SMSA" is inserted in lieu of "SMSA." (3) Local rate of unemployment, and local rate of growth in employment, per capita income and population are determined as follows: (A) "Local unemployment rate" is the rate of unemployment in the area under the jurisdiction of the local government during the most recent four calendar quarters for which data are available, as determined or assigned by the Secretary of Labor and reported -5to the Secretary. In the case of a local government for which the Secretary of Labor cannot determine a local government unemployment rate, the Secretary of Labor shall assign such local government the local unemployment rate of the smallest unit of. local government or appropriate geographic area for which a local unemployment rate has been determined and within the jurisdiction or area in which such local government is located, unless an unemployment rate has been provided for the local government to the Secretary of Labor by the Governor of the State in which the local government is located and such rate has been determined by the Secretary of Labor to have been developed in a manner consistent with procedures used by the Secretary of Labor and then assigned to the local government. (B) "Local rate of growth in employment" is the rate of employment growth determined by subtracting from the employment in the area under the jurisdiction of a local government for the most recent four calendar quarters for which data are available, the employment within such area for a four calendar quarter period which preceded such recent four calendar quarters by either five or six years (depending on which prior year data are most useful), as determined by the Bureau of Labor Statistics for the Secretary of Labor, and dividing this difference by the employment within such area for the earlier four calendar quarter period. In the event that data are not available for such earlier period for -6- determining an allocation under this section, the Secretary of Labor shall determine the rate of growth in employment on the basis of data for the most appropriate period of time less than five years preceding the most recent year for which data are available. In the case of a local government for which the Secretary of Labor cannot determine employment for a local government, the Secretary of Labor shall assign to such local government the local rate of growth in employment of the smallest unit of local government or appropriate geographic area for which such rate has been determined and within the jurisdiction or area in which such local government is located, unless a local rate of growth in employment has been provided for the local government to the Secretary of Labor by the Governor of the State in which the local government is located and such rate has been determined by the Secretary of Labor to have been determined in a manner consistent with procedures used by the Secretary of Labor and then assigned to the local government. The local rate of growth in employment shall be determined or assigned by the Secretary of Labor and reported to the Secretary. (C) "Local rate of growth in per capita income" is determined by subtracting from the per capita income in the area under the jurisdiction of a local government for the most recent year for which data are available, the per capita income within such area for a year which preceded such recent year by either five or six years (depending on which prior year data are most useful), as -7- determined by the Bureau of the Census for the Secretary of Commerce for general statistical purposes, and dividing this difference by the per capita income within such area for the earlier year. In the event that data are not available for such earlier period for determining an allocation under this section, the Secretary of Commerce shall determine the local rate of growth in per capita income on the basis of data for the most appropriate period of time less than five years preceding the most recent year for which data are available. The local rate of growth in per capita income shall be determined by the Secretary of Commerce, and reported to the Secretary(D) "Local rate of growth in population" is determined by subtracting from the population in the area under the jurisdiction of the local government for the most recent year for which population data are available,'the population in such area as of a date which preceded the date of the most recently available population data by either five or six years (depending on which prior year data are most useful), as determined by the Bureau of the Census for the Secretary of Commerce for general statistical purposes, and dividing this difference by the population within such area for the earlier year. In the event that data are not available for such earlier period for determining an allocation under this section, the Secretary of Commerce shall determine the local rate of growth in population on the basis of data for the most appropriate 8- year less than five years preceding the most recent year for which data are available. The local rate of growth in population shall be determined by the Secretary of Commerce and reported to the Secretary. (4) "Local revenue sharing amount" for a local government is the amount determined under section 108 of the State and Local Fiscal Assistance Act of 1972, as amended (31 U.S.C. S 1221 et seq.) , for such local government for the most recently completed entitlement period, as defined under section 141(b) of such Act. (5) "Local distribution index" means: (A) For each SMSA government, the largest of the quotients resulting from (i) subtracting 4.5 percentage points from the local unemployment rate for such government and dividing the difference by the standard deviation weighted by population of all SMSA governments' unemployment rate, using 4.5 percentage points as the mid-point in calculating the weighted standard deviation; (ii) subtracting the local rate of growth in employment for such government from the rate of growth in employment for all SMSAs (as calculated from data collected by the Bureau of Labor Statistics for the Secretary of Labor and reported to the Secretary for the same time period) and dividing the difference by the standard deviation weighted by population of all SMSA governments' rates of growth in employment for the same time period; -9(iii) subtracting the local rate of growth in per capita income for such government from the rate of growth in per capita income for all SMSAs (as calculated from data collected by the Bureau of the Census for the Secretary of Labor and reported to the Secretary for the same time period) and dividing the difference by the standard deviation weighted by population of all SMSA governments' rates of growth in per capita income; (iv) subtracting the local rate of growth in population for such government from the rate of growth in population for all SMSAs (as calculated from data collected by the Bureau of the Census for the Secretary of Labor and reported to the Secretary for the same time period) and dividing the difference by the standard deviation weighted by population of all SMSA governments' rates of growth in population. (B) For each non-SMSA government, the same as it does for a SMSA government under subparagraph (5)(A) above, except that the term "non-SMSA" is to be inserted in lieu of "SMSA." (d) ALLOCATION LIMITATIONS.-(1) If the amount which would be allocated for any fiscal year to any eligible local government, territory, Indian tribe and Alaskan native village under this Act is less than $200, then no amount shall be paid to such government hereunder. (2) The maximum amount payable annually to a local government under this Act shall be the lesser of the annual allocation determined under -10- this section or the amount allocated during the period beginning July I, 1977 and ending June 30, 1978 under title II of the Public Works Employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 U.S.C. I 6721 et seq.), except for those governments which received no allocation under such Act during the period beginning July 1, 1977 and ending June 30, 1978. (3) Amounts allocated under this section in excess of the maximum allowed under paragraph (d)(2) shall be reallocated to those remaining eligible local governments that have not exceeded the maximum allocation under paragraph (d)(2). Governments with no allocations under title II of the Public Works Employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 U.S.C. § 6721 et seq.), for the period beginning July 1, 1977 and ending June 30, 1978 shall not be eligible for such reallocations under this paragraph. (e) LOCAL GOVERNMENT LOCATED IN A LARGER ENTITY; BOUNDARY CHANGES AND GOVERNMENTAL REORGANIZATION, ETC. (I) ONLY PART OF UNIT LOCATED IN LARGER ENTITY. - If only part of a local government is located in a larger governmental entity, such part shall be treated for allocation purposes as a separate unit of local government, and all computations except as otherwise provided in section 104(c)(2)(A) and appropriate rules, shall be made on the basis of the ratio which the estimated population of such part bears to the population of the larger governmental entity. (2) BOUNDARY CHANGES, GOVERNMENTAL REORGANIZATION. ETC. If by reason of boundary line changes, State statutory or constitutional -11- changes, annexations or other governmental reorganizations, or other circumstances, the application of any provision of this section to a local government does not carry out the purposes of this Act, the application of such provision shall be made, under rules prescribed by the Secretary, in a manner which is consistent with such purposes. USES OF PAYMENTS SEC. 105. Each local government, territory, Indian tribe and Alaskan native village shall use payments made under this Act for basic services customarily provided to persons in the area under the jurisdiction of such government, including expenditures for capital outlay and basic governmental operations. STATEMENT OF ASSURANCES SEC. 106. Each eligible local government, territory, Indian tribe or Alaskan native village may receive payments under this Act only upon filing with the Secretary a statement of assurances, at such time and in such manner as the Secretary prescribes by rule. The Secretary may not require any such government to file more than one such statement during each fiscal year. Each such statement shall contain— (a) an assurance that the requirements of section 105 will be complied with; (b) an assurance that such government will™ (1) use fiscal, accounting, and audit procedures which conform to guidelines established therefor by -12- the Secretary (after consultation with the Comptroller General of the United States), and (2) provide to the Secretary (and to the Comptroller General of the United States), on reasonable notice, access to, and the right to examine, such books, documents, papers, or records as the Secretary may reasonably require for purposes of reviewing compliance with this Act; (c) an assurance that reasonable reports will be furnished to the Secretary in such form and containing such information as the Secretary may reasonably require to carry out the purposes of this Act; (d) an assurance that the requirements of section 107 will be complied with; (e) an assurance that the requirements of section 108 will be complied with; (f) an assurance that such government will spend amounts received under this Act only in accordance with the laws and procedures applicable to the expenditure of its own revenues. NONDISCRIMINATION SEC. 107 (a)(1) IN GENERAL.— No person in the United States shall, on the ground of race, color, national origin, or sex, be excluded from participation in, be denied the benefits of, or be subjected to discrimination under any program or activity of a local government, territory, Indian tribe or Alaskan native village which receives funds made available under this Act, or any program or activity of any State, local or territorial government -13- funded in whole or in part with funds received under title II of the Public Works employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 U.S.C. f 6721 et seq.). Any prohibition against discrimination on the basis of age under the Age Discrimination Act of 1975 (42 U.S.C. f 6101 et seq.) or with respect to an otherwise qualified handicapped individual as provided in section 504 of the Rehabilitation Act of 1973 (29 U.S.C. $ 794 et seq.) shall also apply to such programs or activities. Any prohibition against discrimination on the basis of religion, or any exemption, from such prohibition, as provided in the Civil Rights Act of 1964 (42 U.S.C. S 2000e(2)) or title VIII of the Act of April 11, 1968 (42 U.S.C. § 3601 et seq.), shall also apply to such programs or activities. (2) EXCEPTIONS.~ (A) FUNDING.— The provisions of paragraph (1) of this subsection shall not apply where any State, local or territorial government or Indian tribe or Alaskan aative village demonstrates, by clear and convincing evidence, that the program or activity with respect to which the allegation of discrimination has been made is not funded in whole or in part with funds made available under this Act or title II of the Public Works Employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 U.S.C. i 6721 et seq.). (B) CONSTRUCTION PROJECTS IN PROGRESS.— The provision of paragraph (1), relating to discrimination on the basis of handicapped status, shall not apply with respect to construction projects commenced prior to January 1, 1977. (b) ENFORCEMENT AND REMEDIES.— The provision of subsection (a) of this section shall be enforced by the Secretary in the same manner and in accordance -14- with the same procedures as are required by sections 122, 124, and 125 of the State and Local Fiscal Assistance Act of 1972, as amended (31 U.S.C. f 1221 et seq.), to enforce compliance with section 122(a) of such Act. The Attorney General shall have the same authority, functions, and duties with respect to funds made available under this Act and under title II of the Public Works Employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 U.S.C. S 6721 et seq.) as the Attorney General has under sections 122(g) and (h) and 124(c) of such first cited Act with respect to funds made available under that Act. Any person aggrieved by a violation of subsection (a) of thi6 section shall have the same rights and remedies as a person aggrieved by a violation of subsection (a) of section 122 of such first cited Act, including the rights provided under section 124(c) of such Act. LABOR STANDARDS SEC. 108. All laborers and mechanics employed by contractors on all construction projects funded in whole or in part by payments under this Act or title II of the Pubic Works Employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 U.S.C. S 6721 et seq.) shall be paid wages at rates not less than those prevailing on similar projects in the locality as determined by the Secretary of Labor in accordance with the DavisBacon Act (40 U.S.C. I 276a S 276a-5). The Secretary of Labor shall have, with respect to the labor standards specified in this section, the authority and functions set forth in Reorganization Plan No. 14 of 1950 (15 CFR 3176) and section 2 of the Act of June 13, 1934, as amended (40 U.S.C. i 276c). -15- WITHHOLDING SEC. 109. Except as otherwise provided by section 107(b), whenever the Secretary, after affording reasonable notice and an opportunity for a hearing, finds that a State, local or territorial government or any Indian tribe or Alaskan native village has failed to comply substantially with any assurance filed pursuant to section 106 of this Act or title II of the Public Works Employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 U.S.C. f 6721 et seq.), the Secretary shall notify that government, tribe or village that further payments will not be made under this Act until he is satisfied that there is no longer any such failure to comply. Until he is satisfied, no further payments shall be made to such government, tribe or village under this Act. DATA PROVISION RESPONSIBILITIES SEC. 110. The Secretary of Labor and the Secretary of Commerce shall provide information and data necessary to the administration of this Act. Such information and data shall be provided for each local government, and shall be made available when necessary to the Secretary to assist him in carrying out the provisions of this Act. The Secretaries of Labor and Commerce shall also advise the Secretary as to the availability and reliability of relevant information and data. RULEMAKING SEC. 111. The Secretary is authorized to prescribe, after consultation with the Secretary of Labor and the Secretary of Commerce, such rules as may be necessary for the purpose of carrying out his functions under this Act. Such rules shall be prescribed by the Secretary not later than ninety days after the effective date of this Act. -16- REPORTS SEC. 112. The Secretary shall report to Congress as aoon as is practical after the end of each calendar year during which payments are made under the provisions of this Act. Such reports shall include detailed information on the amounts paid to each local or territorial government, Indian tribe and Alaskan native village under the provisions of this Act and any amounts withheld by the Secretary pursuant to sections 107 and 109. ALLOCATION TO PUERTO RICO, GUAM, AMERICAN SAMOA AND THE UNITED STATES VIRGIN ISLANDS SEC. 113. (a) IN GENERAL. — There shall be allocated for each of the fiscal years 1979 and 1980 for the purpose of making payments under the Act to the Commonwealth of Puerto Rico, Guam, American Samoa and the Virgin Islands, an amount equal to I percent of the amount appropriated pursuant to section 103, multiplied by the applicable territorial percentage. (b) ALLOCATIONS. — ' (I) Territorial percentage. — For purposes of this section, the territorial percentage is equal to the quotient resulting from the division of the territorial population of a territory by the sum of the territorial populations for all territories. (2) For purposes of this section (A) "territory" means the government of the Commonwealth of Puerto Rico, Guam, Anerican Samoa or the Virgin Islands; -17- (B) "territorial population" means the most recent population for each territory as determined by the Bureau of the Census for the Secretary of Commerce and reported to the Secretary; (3) The provisions of sections 103, 104(d)(1), 105, 106, 107, 108, 109, 110, 111, and 112 ahall apply to payments to the territories under thi6 Act. (c) PAYMENTS TO TERRITORIAL LOCAL GOVERNMENTS. -The governments of the territories are authorized to make payments to local governments within their jurisdiction from sums authorized by and received pursuant to this Act as they deem appropriate. ALLOCATIONS TO INDIAN TRIBES AND ALASKAN NATIVE VILLAGES SEC. 114. (a) IN GENERAL. — There shall be allocated for each of the fiscal years 1979 and 1980 for the purpose of making payments under the Act to Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages, an amount equal to 0.3 percent of the amount appropriated pursuant to section 103, multiplied by the applicable Indian tribe or Alaskan native village percentage. (b) ALLOCATIONS. — (I) Indian tribe or Alaskan native village percentage. — For purposes of this section, the Indian tribe or Alaskan native village percentage is equal to the quotient resulting from the division of the Indian tribe or Alaskan native village population by the sum of the populations for all Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages. -18- (2) For purposes of this section - (A) "Indian tribe or Alaskan native village" means an Indian tribe or Alaskan native village which has a recognized governing body and performs substantial governmental functiona. (B) "Population" means the most recent population for each Indian tribe or Alaskan native village as provided by the Bureau of Indian Affairs for the purposes of the State and Local Fiscal Assistance Act of 1972, as amended (31 U.S.C. 1221 et seq.). (3) The provisions of section 103, 104(d)(1), 105, 106, 107, 108, 109, 111, and 112 shall apply to payments to the Indian tribes and Alaskan native villages under this Act. APPLICABILITY TO ANTIRECESSION FISCAL ASSISTANCE SEC. 115. Except for section 213 of title II of the Public Works Employment Act of 1976, as amended (42 U.S.C. S 6721 et seq.) , and except as otherwise provided herein, such title II is repealed and the provisions of this Act shall govern the expenditure by State, local and territorial governments (as defined in title II) of funds made available under title II. FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 10:30 A.M. May 17, 1978 TESTIMONY OF THE HONORABLE ROBERT CARSWELL DEPUTY SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS OF THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, HOUSING AND URBAN AFFAIRS Mr. Chairman and Members of this distinguished Subcommittee: I appreciate this opportunity to testify on behalf of the Treasury on S. 2293, the Electronic Fund Transfers Act of 1977. The EFT Environment The Congress, and this Subcommittee in particular, have played a highly constructive role in the evolving understanding of the impact of EFT on our banking system. The Congress made a major contribution by establishing the National Commission on Electronic Fund Transfers, which delivered its report last fall. The report puts in perspective many questions posed by EFT developments. These hearings are an important link in the chain of understanding. As the pace of change in banking quickens, many old concepts embrace less comfortably the new facts. We must beware of too slavish adherence to our traditional ways of thinking about banking questions. We support the general approach to banking questions represented by S.2293. In our view, its commitment to increased competition in making better banking services available to the consumer is clearly the direction in which we should be moving. EFT is still in an early stage of development. It is basically a phenomenon of the 1970's. Nevertheless, it has the potential to affect profoundly the shape and character of our financial system: the relationships among depository B-843 - 2institutions; the relative roles of depository and nondepository institutions; the effectiveness of traditional regulatory standards (such as the prohibition of interest on demand deposits); the relative strength of large and small institutions; and the products offered by competitors. In light of the newness of EFT and its importance, government regulation of EFT at this time should be as modest as possible, so that it does not unduly retard or distort the free-market development of EFT systems. All regulatory action has an impact on the shape of the industry regulated. Rules such as the prohibition of interest on demand deposits and the branching regulations have had an important effect on the products offered by different institutions and their relative strengths and weaknesses. Once an industry has evolved to accommodate government rules, it is hard to change the rules without disruption. Of course, some competitors will be more aggressive in extending new services than others; some will make more effective use of the new technology. Some will lose market share. But that is not a reason to restrict the growth of EFT systems. The justification for these adjustments will be found in the availability, price and quality of services to consumers. The consideration of the questions raised by S.2293 will, no doubt, continue. We look forward to working with the Subcommittee on these issues, and we hope the bank regulators will monitor developments in this area on a continuous basis. Terminal Deployment Under Section 4 of S. 2293, Federally chartered financial institutions would be permitted to deploy nation-wide point-of-sale ("POS") devices and automated teller machines ("ATMs") which do not perform deposit functions. Deposittaking terminals may be deployed immediately within the sponsoring institution's home state, and interstate within Standard Metropolitan Statistical Areas after January 1, 1980. Before January 1, 1980, deposit-taking terminals may be deployed interstate to the extent that the states permit interstate deployment of terminals by state-chartered insti- J tutions. Federal regulators may not deny permission for terminal deployment on the basis of the suitability of the locations chosen, the area to be served, the number of terminals to be deployed or the bank's capitalization. EFT services may be offered through terminals owned by others to the same extent that terminals may be deployed. We think that this bill has chosen a sensible course in dealing with the deployment of EFT services. It recognizes that the offering of EFT services should not be constricted by rules developed for branches, while seeking to modify the immediate competitive impact of the changes through the use of a phase-in period and restrictions on deposit-taking. We would like, however, to offer a number of suggestions that are designed to smooth the transition: 1. Since January 1, 1980 is coming fast upon us and the legislative process on this bill has only just begun, we suggest that the phase-in period for interstate deployment of deposittaking terminals be changed to a later period — for instance, three years from the date of adoption. 2. The effect of permitting state-wide deployment of EFT deposit-taking services in states with restrictive branching rules will not be unlike the interstate deployment of such services in SMSA's, and we suggest that Congress consider a similar phase-in period for the state-wide deployment of such services. 3. Using deposit-taking as a measure of the circumstances under which nation-wide deployment of EFT services is not permitted will put great strain on the definition of "deposit-taking", and it should be made clear that the bank regulators have adequate powers to deal with the definitional and related problems that will arise. In addition, it should be made clear that the recitation in Section 9(b) of the factors which may not be used as a basis for regulatory disapproval of deposit-taking terminals, is not intended to restrict the traditional responsibility of bank regulators to prohibit unsafe and unsound banking practices. - 4 4. Finally, we suggest that Congress consider requiring periodic reports from the bank regulators and the Treasury. For example, reports at three year intervals for the next nine years might be appropriate. Let me explain our reasons for these conclusions. Phase-In Periods EFT systems are characterized by high costs of "entry" and significant economies of scale. The larger the number of transactions per terminal, the faster its use becomes profitable This is not necessarily a matter of competitive concern, of course, since systems may be shared, or independent operators may offer EFT facilities to small institutions through shared facilities. The same economies of scale would be available to these systems. Thus, in this sense, EFT may substantially expand the reach of smaller institutions that have access to a large, shared terminal network. If all institutions are to have a fair opportunity to adapt to the changes brought by the advent of EFT, there must be adequate time to plan and to secure participation in shared systems. That is particularly the case with interstate deployment, since there is presently little interstate competition in retail banking. Because of economies of scale, only the largest institutions are likely to be able to move quickly. Accordingly, we support the bill's use of a phasein period for interstate deposit-taking activities. In view of the time that will inevitably be consumed by the legislative process, we suggest a period of three years from the date of adoption. In those states, like unit-banking states, that restrict the deployment of brick and mortar branches, the competitive impact of permitting state-wide deployment of deposit-taking terminals will be not unlike permitting interstate deployment of such terminals within SMSA's. In order to try to assure that the resulting changes in competitive patterns are the result of fair competition, all institutions should be given an adequate opportunity to adjust to the prospective changes. Thus, we suggest that Congress adopt a similar phase-in period for state-wide deployment of deposit-taking terminals beyond the areas in which branching is currently permitted. - 5 Branching EFT terminals are one step in a continuum of new ways of extending banking services to customers: for example, telephone transfers, telephone bill paying and electronic check authorization. It is simply not meaningful to ask whether EFT terminals are more like brick and mortar branches than like electronic check authorization, which is viewed as merely an extension of banking services. The regulation of EFT terminals should not be determined by abstract legal niceties. These services may be a powerful competitive tool. All other things being equal, a bank offering EFT services may .,„ increase its market share at the expense of a bank that does not. But this does not mean that EFT terminal deployment is just an indirect form of branching. There is no evidence that suggests that terminal deployment will permit a bank to acquire significant numbers of depositors in distant areas. Accordingly, we agree with S.2293 that EFT terminals should not be treated as branches for purposes of the McFadden Act. This is especially so because terminal systems will be used by savings and loan institutions and credit unions, which are not subject to the McFadden Act, and other credit grantors that are subject to little or no Federal regulation. Definition of Deposit-taking We support the bill's use of deposit-taking as the factor that will confine a depository institution's interstate activities to SMSA's. Deposit-taking has been a traditional touchstone for distinguishing between banking and,other financial activities. But with the evolution of( the banking system, the lines established by this distinction are blurring. If a terminal user orders money transferred from his savings account to his checking account, is that a deposit? How does it differ from a similar direction by letter or telephone? If the customer makes a deposit by leaving a check in an envelope in the electronic terminal, and the envelope is then picked up by a bank employee, how different is that from leaving the envelope in a mail box attached to the terminal? - 6 For these reasons, it is quite important that recognition be given to the regulators' broad authority to define the boundaries of this important concept. In addition, we suggest that the report of this Subcommittee, if not the bill itself, reflect the fact that the provisions of Section 9(b) were not intended to restrict the regulators' traditional responsibility to prohibit unsafe and unsound banking practices. For example, in prohibiting regulatory disapproval of the deployment of deposit-taking terminals on the basis of a "capitalization" requirement, Section 9 should not be read as requiring the regulators to stand idly by as an undercapitalized bank begins a technically ill-conceived EFT program that will bring crushing financial burdens. Sharing At least 14 states have adopted laws which require institutions deploying EFT systems to permit others to offer EFT services through those systems. These laws were prompted by a recognition that industries exhibiting significant economies of scale tend to reduce competition and, in some cases, give rise to natural monopolies. Proponents of mandatory sharing laws are concerned that large financial institutions would overwhelm weaker competitors that could not afford competing systems without sharing facilities. Section 5 of S.2293 embodies the EFT Commission's recommendations on sharing, adopting a so-called "pro-competitive" sharing policy. Financial institutions may agree to share EFT systems or components, but would not be required to do so. State laws requiring sharing would be nullified. If challenged, sharing arrangements would be reviewed by the courts on a caseby-case basis under traditional antitrust standards. Antitrust laws would also govern the objections raised by those who claim to have been improperly denied access to EFT systems. We support Section 5, at least as an interim solution. Mandatory sharing laws tend to produce a smaller number of competitivesystems at the outset. They reduce the incentive to a financial institution to assume risks with EFT, since no competitive gains can be realized. Certainly, EFT ought not be allowed to be disruptive of market structure. Norshould it be allowed to congeal market structure. - 7 Even if it ultimately develops that continuing competition is unrealistic and competing systems cannot survive, and that greater regulation of the terms of access is required, we will be better off for not having imposed that regulation at the outset. For the resulting system will be the product of vigorous competition for dominance in the marketplace. Some,have expressed concern that the antitrust laws do not provide the correct standards for resolving sharing disputes and that the courts are not the most efficient forum to do so quickly. It is feared both that the threat of antitrust action may unduly inhibit desirable sharing arrangements, and that the pace of^antitrust proceedings is too slow for effective relief. We share some of these concerns. We would like to explore further the idea of finding ways to permit the Federal bank regulators to determine disputes under expedited procedures. But it is far too early in the development of EFT systems to know where the real*problems lie and what standards should be applied in resolving disputes. If, as we hope, shared EFT services will be marketed to smaller institutions, this problem may never become serious. And the basic antitrust approach may well prove fully workable, particularly if the Department of Justice develops -appropriate business review procedures.^ We suggest that the experience with sharing questions be closely monitored by the bank regulators and that they report yearly to Congress on this subject. Automated Clearing Houses The role of the Federal Reserve in the operation of the payments system has become the subject of debate in recent ^ years. In the EFT area, the focal-point of this debate is the automated clearing house, or ACH. An ACH provides data processing services for preauthorized transactions, principally deposits. Approximately. B5 pexcent of all ACH transactions are concerned with deposits of U.S.>government payments. At the present time, the Federal Reserve Banks perform the data processing functions for all ACK's in the United States except two. Some observers question whether a public agency ought to be involved in the provision of these services to the private sector. Others focus on the questions of "for whom these services should be provided and how they should be priced. - 8 Under Section 8 of S.2293, ACH participation would be open to all financial institutions; only cost-justified differences in price and other terms would be permitted; Federal Reserve Banks would impose explicit charges according to fully allocated costs; and public sector agencies would be prohibited from offering any other EFT services. The purpose of Section 8 is to create an environment conducive to effective private sector competition in the ACH area. We support the bill's approach on this question. But we believe that this issue cannot be separated from broader questions that remain unresolved. Private competitors will be able to bid effectively only if the government as a source of EFT deposits and Federal Reserve member banks are willing to use private ACH operators when the price of their services is competitive. This cannot be the case if member banks receive ACH services from the Fed in return for reserve balances held — that is, if the reserves are an automatic offset to the prices imposed. In that situation, member banks will have no incentive to pay for ACH services provided by the private sector. True competition would require the Federal Reserve to receive cash payments for ACH services from member banks, thus raising broader questions of "unbundling" of other services and the payment of interest on reserve balances. We understand that the Federal Reserve is in the process of addressing these questions. We will review carefully any legislation that may be required to deal with these issues. Meanwhile, effective legislation in the ACH area should await their resolution. We are also concerned about Section 8's unqualified prohibition of any public agency's involvement in EFT services of any other type. This threatens legislative rigidity at a premature state in EFT development. We cannot be sure how EFT will develop or what impacts it will have on the structure of various financial markets. It may well be that, for whatever circumstance, the presence of some Federal agency in some markets as an EFT service provider in support of POS as well as ACH transactions may be necessary and in the public benefit. Government Access to Records and Customer Rights The Department of Justice will testify on Government access to records and customer rights. FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 18, 1978 ADDRESS BY THE HONORABLE ROBERT CARSWELL DEPUTY SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY ALTERNATE GOVERNOR FOR THE UNITED STATES BEFORE THE PLENARY SESSION OF THE INTER-AMERICAN DEVELOPMENT BANK ANNUAL MEETING VANCOUVER, BRITISH COLUMBIA APRIL 18, 1978 Mr. Chairman, President Ortiz Nena, governors and members, ladies and gentlemen. This afternoon the United States Senate will vote on the second Panama Canal Treaty. That vote will be the culmination of efforts that began over 14 years ago to resolve the divisive issues about control of the canal that have long complicated relations in this hemisphere. Our hope and expectation is that these treaties will finally settle these issues in the hemisphere and establish a more just and equitable relationship between the United States and Panama. President Carter has personally led the effort to conclude a successful negotiation, to win its acceptance by our citizens and to gain Senate ratification. The Senate itself has set aside many other important matters and has devoted more than two months to a careful consideration of the treaties' merits and of their historic implications. I would suggest that this record clearly establishes the important priority that this Administration assigns to its relations in the hemisphere. The treaties are also visible evidence of the substance of U.S. policy toward Latin America and illustrate three major principles that guide us: — First, respect by every nation for the political integrity and economic and social aspirations of every other nation. — Second, recognition of the essential interdependence of developed and developing economies. — Third, impressive progress in many of the world's developing countries — especially in Latin America — which enables them, by ability as well as right, to play an increasingly important role on the international economic scene. B-844 -2This Vancouver meeting is itself a reflection of the inexorable currents at work. The Inter-American Development Bank now embraces not only this most hospitable of host countries, Canada, but many other developed countries around the world. What was originally a regional institution has acquired a global base, and become part of a world-wide system of highly important financial and development institutions. United States support of the bank, like our other Latin American aspirations, is an element in our global approach to the problems of the international economic order -- global growth and prosperity, making optimum use of material and human resources in a livable environment, ensuring the essential justice of international system as a whole. U.S. Policies for Development Last year, Secretary Blumenthal outlined for you the comprehensive nature of U.S. policies and actions benefitting the developing world. He deeply regrets that he is unable to be here today to renew the many warm contacts with other Governors he made in Guatemala. He recently was the host at a luncheon in Washington with President Ortiz Mena and representatives of many of your countries in order to maintain his personal involvement in U.S.-Latin American economic relation. And he has asked me to emphasize that the United States remains absolutely committed both to the implementation of policies beneficial to the developing world, and to the constant search for additional ways in which U.S. interests and the interests of developing nations can be harmonized and better served. This search for a convergence of interests, a sharing of responsibility for solutions to common problems, a commitment to partnership, was a central theme of President Carter's recent journey to Latin America. During his visit to Venezuela, one of the great democracies of the hemisphere, he said: "Our specific obligations will be different, our interests and emphases will vary — but all of us, north and south, east and west, must bear our part of the burden. If the responsibility for global progress is not shared, our efforts will certainly fail, only if the responsibility is shared, can we attain the goals that our people want and that our times demand." We believe the IDB has long symbolized this aspiration. The Bank is a unique cooperative effort between donors and recipients and its policies are shaped by both. For the United States, an important part of the joint responsibility of which President Carter spoke is maintaining the strength of the dollar and the monetary system. The United btates is deeply concerned about the value of the dollar and recognizes that currency stability is in the interest of the U.S. and the world economy. A stable dollar can only be achieved by dealing with the fundamental U.S. economic situation. -3On April 11, the President announced comprehensive new measures to combat inflation. These included a series of measures designed to: (1) limit the size of the 1979 and future Federal budget deficits, (2) restrict the salary increase of Federal Government employees, freeze the salaries of executive appointees for another year, and urge similar wage restraint on state and local governments and private businesses, (3) seek voluntary price restraint in various economic sectors, and (4) reduce the inflationary effect of past and future regulatory actions by the Government, while resisting proposed legislation in several fields which would contribute to inflation. In the energy field, the President once again urged the U.S. Congress to adopt meaningful energy legislation without further delay and indicated that, if Congress did not act, oil imports would have to be limited by administrative action under present law. A third area of priority action is export expansion. We are encouraging American firms to become more export conscious. The Administration is supporting a sharp increase in the lending activities of the Export-Import Bank. Also, in his address on April 11, the President called for a Cabinet-level task force to develop additional measures to promote exports, and to report back to him within 60 days. The recent disorders in the foreign exchange market have reflected doubts about the U.S. ability to reduce its trade deficit. Once markets see that we are proceeding in the right direction on the fundamentals — by curbing inflations, reducing oil imports, and promoting exports -- I would expect markets to calm. The U.S. will, however, continue to intervene to the extent necessary to counter disorderly conditions in the market and to curb destabilizing speculation. The international monetary system is also being strengthened by measures to enhance the sole and resources of the International Monetary Fund. The amended IMF articles have just entered into force. They provide a new legal framework for international financial relations, including expanded IMF authority over exchange rate practices. The resources of the fund have been increased by one-third, to about $48 billion, through implementation of new quotas. The supplementary financing facility will provide an additional $10.5 billion in resources for use in assisting those members with severe balance of payments problems, including, of course, developing countries. Legislation authorizing U.S. participation is now before Congress, and final action should be completed in the near future. World payments are largely a reflection of world trade. In this key area, the Administration has demonstrated concretely its -itdedication to the avoidance of new barriers to imports from developing countries, and to further reduction of existing barriers through the multilateral trade negotiations. We reject protectionism, where problems exist, our reliance is on strengthened domestic adjustment policies or on negotiation of temporary relief measures in specific cases. We do insist on fairness in trading practices, in such problem areas as export subsidies, we must work together to avoid economic conflict. In the main, however, the U.S. offers a solid and growing market for goods at all stages of processing from developing countries. More than 25 percent of our imports of manufactures now come from non-oil developing countries, compared to just 15 percent in 1972. The generalized system of preferences allowed $3-9 billion worth of goods to enter the U.S. duty free in 1977, including $1.1 billion from Latin America. Keeping our markets open has not been an easy task for the Administration in face of the high unemployment situation and a sizeable trade deficit. But the reasons for maintaining a liberal trading stance are sound: minimizing inflation, creating trade-related jobs, avoiding international conflict. These considerations will continue to guide our policy. Trade in commodities has been a special area of concern to developing countries, including many in Latin America. The United States has responded actively and constructively in this area. We understand the concern of developing countries over excessive price fluctuations and resultant disruptions in foreign exchange earnings, domestic investment and employment. We agree that it is desirable to seek international measures to stabilize prices around market trends, and believe that it is in our own national economic interest, as well as that of the world community to do so wherever feasible. Thus we are participating in international stabilization agreements covering coffee, tin, and sugar and are taking part in discussions of possible arrangements for rubber, wheat and copper. The foreign investment policy of the United States has likewise been attuned to the needs and interests of the developing world. Basic decisions remain with private investors, but we will continue to facilitate capital flows through the Overseas Private Investment Corporation which will have a special focus in its operations toward the poorer countries. Through this far-reaching array of policies, the United States is making a major contribution to economic progress and the alleviation of human want in developing countries around the world. We do so for reasons both practical and idealistic, we take great satisfaction in observing the impressive progress of those more advanced of the less developed countries, whose n ™ ; U ? L 0 r S ? inl??bitants are beginning to enjoy more acceptable conditions of daily life and who are assuming a growing importance in the functioning of the world economy. These -5countries are emerging as full participants in the whole fabric of international exchange -- as well as responsible participants in the international political framework necessary for a peaceful planet. At the same time, our humanitarian instincts are disturbed at the'continuing plight of large numbers of people in these countries, as well as those in the least developed countries, who have vastly different endowments, attainments and prospects. The most elemental requirements for sustaining human life itself are often unmet in these countries. Heroic struggles will be necessary to break the grip of stagnation and prevent poverty from feeding on poverty. These are the situations where external help on concessional term must be concentrated, and where our greatest efforts must be directed. To help in this endeavor, the United States increased its foreign assistance by 31 percent in 1977 — 20 percent for bilateral aid, and a massive 69 percent for multilateral aid including for the IDB. President Carter has proposed a further 24 percent rise in 1978, including another 70 percent increase in our contributions to the Development Banks. The Growing Dynamism of Latin America Last year, Latin American regional GDP expanded by more than 5 percent after growing by 4.8 percent in 1976. Back in 1975, when the industrialized world had plunged into deep recession, Latin American economies continued to grow at an impressive rate of almost 3 percent. Latin American growth would have been even higher in 1977 if several major countries including Brazil, Mexico, and Argentina had not been implementing necessary stabilization programs under which all made significant progress. Longer term trends have also been favorable. The average rate of expansion since 1965 has been slightly over 6 percent — considerably better than the world as a whole, which grew at about 4 percent if oil producing countries are excluded. The GDP of the region stood at over $340 billion last year, or a per capital level of about $1,100. This was far above the level of Africa and Asia (excluding Japan). On the external side, Latin American exports grew at a rapid pace in 1977 — rising by about $9 billion to more than $50 billion. The current account in the regional balance of payments improved by about $2.5 billion, aided by a large trade surplus of $3.2 billion with the United States, as compared to a slight deficit the year before. By the end of the year, combined international reserves were $22 billion — nearly quadruple the level of only six years earlier. -6These favorable developments in the aggregate statistics do not mean, of course, the solution of all Latin America's problems. The region is much too diverse for that to be the case. Much poverty remains — an estimated 42 percent of the people'in Latin America live in poverty, irregularly distributed between and within countries. Much still needs to be done to improve domestic resource mobilization and income distribution. We believe this can be done. Latin American nations in general have reached a level of maturity — in their planning capabilities, in the quality of their public administration, in the sophistication and vitality of their private sectors, and in the provision of essential services to their citizens — that places the consolidation of development progress within their grasp. In no other region of the developing world is* this phenomenon so widespread as in Latin America. The Future Role of the IDB This assessment of Latin America's relatively advanced position along the spectrum of development has major implications for the future activity of the Inter-American Development Bank. In particular, it affects the balance between hard loan and soft loan resource requirements, compared to institutions serving other areas of the developing world. It is, inevitably, a central issue for discussion in the context of the next -.•*•• replenishment of the Bank's resources. In terms of country distribution, further progress was made in 1977 in directing resources on the Bank's most favorable terms to the smaller and poorer countries. In the Bank's hard window, however, further efforts are necessary to assure an equitable distribution of resources to countries and to projects requiring development assistance. Some of the other lending during the year may fairly be questioned in terms of priorities. For example, the export credit program is utilized principally by the countries best able to rely on traditional private sources of such financing. We believe that the Bank should devote its resources primarily to those sectors and projects for which private sources of financing on appropriate terms are not available. More resources would thereby be made available for projects of direct benefit to the poorer sectors of society. Several other aspects of the Bank's 1977 activities deserve comment: -7— Complementary financing, drawing directly on private market sources for project loans, took on significant dimensions during the year and opened the way for further development in the future. — The effort to ensure that appropriate technologies are employed in projects financed by the Bank continued to gather momentum during the year. -- The Bank's internal capacity to evaluate the effectiveness of its loans was strengthened in various ways. In addition, the group of controllers, as an independent evaluation mechanism, initiated several subsector reviews that will shed further light on the project lending process. We^ believe that an independent evaluation mechanism is essential to maintain desireable standards of performance. U.S. Policy Toward the IDB I have already noted the sharp increase in U.S. financial contributions to the multilateral financial institutions in 1977. In the IDB, our contribution climbed to a total of $797 million in calendar year 1977, a three-fold increase during the first year of the Carter Administration. In the Inter-American Development Bank during the year, as in other similar institutions, U.S. representatives have used both their voice and their vote on behalf of trie cause of human rights. We believe that the goals and purposes of the Bank encompass a broad range of fundamental concerns. We also believe that scarce development funds generally can be best utilized to promote economic and social objectives by governments which have manifested a commitment to protecting and promoting the rights of their people. As Secretary Blumenthal emphasized last year, we seek to cooperate with all members in finding ways to best advance our common commitment to human rights and the fulfillment of basic human needs while at the Same time insuring the integrity and effectiveness of all the Development Banks. But no nation can continue to have a domestic consensus in favor of providing assistance to other countries if its own sense of decency is offended by the activities of the governments of the countries receiving assistance. Another and quite different matter that affects the ability of the U.S. Government to maintain public support for international development institutions is that of administrative arrangements, especially the salaries and benefits enjoyed by the staffs of these institutions. The banks are widely viewed in the -8United States as public agencies, and are therefore measured against standards appropriate for the use of taxpayers' funds. We believe that the Bank should pursue policies that gradually bring the compensation of its staff more in line with that of representative public and private sectors. T6 the credit of the institution, corrective action has been taken in a number of other administrative areas — such as first class travel, spouse travel and annual meeting arrangements. But the central issue of staff compensation continues to require action urgently. A special committee is at work on the issue in the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund; its conclusions will provide a useful reference for action which we hope all the international financial institutions will promptly follow. Dissatisfaction on matters such as human rights and salaries, along with the sheer increase in the magnitude of money involved, have led to the reluctance in our Congress to fund fully our recent appropriations requests. In addition to the $650 million which we are seeking as new appropriations this year, there remain carryover appropriations requests for $264 million of funds whose original due dates have passed. Of the latter amount, $125 million is for the fund for special operations. We are making an intensive effort with the Congress to obtain the funds to cover all pledges past due, as well as to obtain the full amount of current appropriations. This effort engages the highest levels of our Administration, and there is reason to hope that a large measure of success will be realized. The Future of the IDB There must also be a replenishment of the resources of the Bank. We have already agreed on arrangements for detailed discussion of that replenishment. These discussions will concentrate on the replenishment size, its composition by window, the purposes to which the funds are applied, and where the criteria for determining who within a borrowing country shall benefit from them, as well as certain administrative issues. Needless to say, the U.S. Administration will work in closest contact with our Congress as the replenishment discussions proceed; we have committed ourselves to do so, and no replenishment understanding would be of practical value without it. Although we have no fixed views yet as to the specifics of the replenishment, it may be useful to put forward some issues which we believe should be considered during the coming discussions. 9* -9First, in light of Latin America's advanced stage of economic development compared to other areas of the world, we foresee a replenishment in which FSO resources will decline in relative importance to capital resources. Latin America has progressed to a point where the need for rising levels of concessional financing may no longer be justified. This relative scarcity of FSO funds will force on us hard choices in the allocation process. Second, we must be ever mindful of the needs of the disadvantaged people in the area. We anticipate that an increasing proportion of the Bank's resources will be devoted to benefiting low income beneficiaries in both rural and urban areas, there is a strong need to improve the definitions of who within a society is poor and what types of loans are considered as primarily serving needs. Third, we b elievetheir it would b e appropr iate to make available all replenishmen t resources in co nvertible currencies freely usable by the Ba nk. Although the Bank has made use of FSO national currenc y contributions, and to a limited degree of subscribed OC na tional currencies as well, resources in this form have given rise to numerous admin istrative complications. Rather than add to thes e, it might be pr eferable for the contributions to the FSO reple nishment to consi st exclus ively of convertible currency. To ac hieve this change might re quire a different method of determ ining contributio ns in ord er to ensure equitable burden sharing. Conclusion The original establishment of the Bank 18 years ago was an act or vision, even idealism, by pragmatic financial leaders at that time. Our task now, as financial leaders concerned with the architecture of the international economy in the approaching decade of the 1980's, is to demonstrate again a similar mix of pragmatism and vision. We need to replenish the resources of the Bank but equally important, we must utilize those resources with efficiency, flexibility, and wisdom. It is in this spirit of support and creativity that we approach the future of this Bank. oOOo For Immediate Release April 19, 1978 10:00 a.m. STATEMENT OF GARY C. HUFBAUER DEPUTY ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND INVESTMENT POLICY BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON MERCHANT MARINE U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES Mr. Chairman, I am pleased to be here today to discuss with you the Treasury Department's views on H.R. 9998, a bill to provide for the regulation of rates and charges by certain state-owned carriers in the foreign commerce of the United States. We share the concern reflected in this bill that certain carriers may be competing unfairly in our ocean trades by engaging in "predatory" pricing. By selling shipping services below cost, those carriers may be driving out U.S. vessels and capturing a larger share of the trade. Laws to prevent such unfair practices in our foreign merchandise trade are already on the books. We should deal with unfair competition in international shipping in a similar fashion. Overtonnaging is the dominant feature of our ocean trades today. In its report on H.R. 9518, this Committee identified overtonnaging as the major cause of illegal rebating in ocean shipping. Oversupply of any good or service, including ocean B-845 - 2 shipping, can lead to pricing below cost. Carriers will cut prices during periods of oversupply in an effort to maintain capacity utilization. Below cost pricing by carriers — whether controlled or not — is a reasonable possibility under current market conditions. Goods or services provided by state-controlled economy countries can pose an additional problem since their prices are not necessarily established even in the long run by market considerations. We wish to avoid prejudging whether controlled carriers are actually engaging in pervasive unfair pricing practices. Such practices may not be as widespread as is frequently asserted. Nevertheless, we believe the government should have the tools available to prevent unfair competition. The Administration is prepared to support this legislation, but would recommend certain amendments. In general, we are concerned that the bill's grant of authority to the FMC to determine whether rates are "just and reasonable" is far too broad and vague. In addition, we oppose FMC authority to set minimum rates during any period a rate suspension is in effect. We think the level of rates subject to FMC suspension should be more carefully delineated. While the FMC should have authority to suspend predatory rates, we wish to assure that rate suspensions take place only when unfair - 3 practices are occurring, and not to defeat fair competition. We think the benchmark of rates charged by independent noncontrolled carriers, or 85 percent of the rate charged by the lowest-price conference operating in the same trade, represents a fair standard. Controlled carriers should be allowed to be as competitive as any other carrier in a trade. The 85 percent test is reasonable because independent carriers generally underprice conference carriers by approximately that amount. Independent carriers are able to offer shipping services at rates below those charged by conferences and still earn a profit. My colleagues from the Justice Department are prepared to work with you on the details of the Administration's proposals. These proposals will assure that U.S. carriers are not being victimized by predatory controlled carrier pricing. At the same time, they will allow controlled carriers to continue in the trade as long as they compete fairly. We believe that competition in shipping should be allowed, in fact strengthened. Competition will benefit the shipping public by encouraging the most efficient and cost-effective service possible. It will also help hold down the cost of ocean shipping. This is an important consideration, especially in view of the President's emphasis on curbing inflation. - 4 We believe that this legislation, with the suggested amendments, can be effective in preventing predatory pricing by controlled carriers without discouraging desirable competition in shipping. 0O0 .FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 9:30 A.M. APRIL 19, 1978 STATEMENT OF JOHN R. KARLIK DEPUTY ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR INTERNATIONAL ECONOMIC ANALYSIS BEFORE THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON COMMERCE, SCIENCE AND TRANSPORTATION Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: It is a pleasure for me to testify today regarding the proposed amendment of the International Investment Survey Act of 1976. In order for the Department of the Treasury to carry out the provisions of the Act mandating portfolio investment surveys, we agree that Section 9 needs amending. We plan to hire approximately the same number of persons to carry out the forthcoming surveys as Treasury was authorized to employ in 1974. Given a staff of this size, up to 35 persons, the authorization contained in the 1976 Act is inadequate. More importantly, Treasury is requesting that beginning with fiscal year 1979, administrative expenses for the purpose of conducting international economic affairs that are presently being financed from the Exchange Stabilization Fund be budgeted, just as other administrative expenses are, and that expenditures for these B-846 -2purposes be authorized and appropriated. My appearance before you today is, of course, an essential initial step in that process. I would like to briefly explain our survey plans. The coverage of the surveys is in part dependent upon the amount of funds authorized. The more elaborate the surveys, the higher the costs. We believe the Act provides sufficient flexibility to select the survey coverage which is the most practical, efficient, and least burdensome on the public. Basically, three approaches to coverage are implied by three variant definitions of "portfolio investment." These definitions are (1) the market definition, essentially stocks and bonds; (2) the balance of payments definition, which covers other long-term debt, in addition to stocks and bonds (essentially the coverage of the 1974 survey of foreign portfolio investment); and (3) the definition contained in the Act, which added short-term items such as bank loans and deposits, short-term corporate claims and liabilities, and Treasury bills and certificates. The monthly and quarterly data collected by the Treasury International Capital (TIC) surveys provide information on levels outstanding for all financial instruments except stocks and bonds and certain -3obscure financial items. The TIC reports give us relatively good figures on the levels of foreign portfolio investment, except for securities. In the case of securities, we have monthly reports on transaction flows, but not on levels of foreign investment. We plan to collect in the benchmark survey only information on levels of foreigners securities market holdings -— stocks and bonds — and to supplement these reports with data on ownership of other financial instruments collected in the existing monthly and quarterly TIC surveys. We believe this approach meets the analytic requirements of most potential users of the data , and at the same time results in a minimum burden to the public and in significant cost savings. We assume the same staff will be able to conduct simultaneously a survey of foreign portfolio investment in the United States as of December 31, 1978, and a feasibility study of U.S. portfolio investment abroad. Since an outward survey would confront many unknowns, we plan to undertake a study in 1979 of the cost and feasibility of doing an outward survey. Once that study is complete, we can then present to you our conclusions and recommendations. In the light of these survey plans, which have been discussed with the staffs of this Committee and also of the House Committee on International Relations, and also -4considering the problem created by the prospective loss of authority to finance these surveys from the Exchange Stabilization Fund, when these international economic activities of the Treasury become subject to normal budgetary procedures, the funding authorized under the International Investment Survey Act of 1976 is inadequate. We therefore request that to fulfill Treasury's responsibilities in conducting surveys of foreign portfolio investment, authorizations be granted in the amount of $1.4 million for the fiscal year ending September 30, 1979, and for fiscal years 1980 and 1981 in the amount of such funds as may be necessary. oOo partmentoftheTREASURY SHINGTON, D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 19, 1978 RESULTS OF AUCTION OF 2-YEAR NOTES The Department of the Treasury has accepted $2,175 million of $5,272 million of tenders received from the public for the 2-year notes, Series N-1980, auctioned today. The range of accepted competitive bids was as follows: Lowest yield 7.75% 1/ Highest yield Average yield 7.82% 7.80% The interest rate on the notes will be 7-3/4%. At the 7-3/4% rate, the above yields result in the following prices: Low-yield price 100.000 High-yield price Average-yield price 99.873 99.909 The $2,175 million of accepted tenders includes $ 444 million of noncompetitive tenders and $1,716 million of competitive tenders (including 77% of the amount of notes bid for at the high yield) from private investors. It also includes $ 15 million of tenders at the average price from Federal Reserve Banks as agents for foreign and international monetary authorities in exchange for maturing securities. In addition, $ 983 million of tenders were accepted at the average price from Government accounts and Federal Reserve Banks for their own account in exchange for securities maturing April 30, 1978, ($428 million) and from Federal Reserve Banks as agents for foreign and international monetary authorities for new cash ($ 555 million) . 1/ Excepting 8 tenders totaling $1,965,000 B-847 partmentoftheTREASURY IHINGTON, O.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 19, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY DEPARTMENT FINDS STAINLESS STEEL PIPE AND TUBING FROM JAPAN ARE SOLD HERE AT LESS THAN FAIR VALUE The Treasury Department said today that welded stainless steel pipe and tubing from Japan are being sold in the United States at less than fair value. Sales at less than fair value, as defined by the Antidumping Act, generally occur when imported merchandise is sold in the United States at prices below those in the home market. Interested persons were offered the opportunity to present oral and written views prior to this determination. The case is being referred to the U. S. International Trade Commission (ITC), which must decide within 90 days whether a U. S. industry is being, or is likely to be, injured by these sales. If the ITC's decision is affirmative, dumping duties will be assessed on all imports of this merchandise from Japan except those from two producers, Toa Seiki Company, Ltd., and Yamato Industries Company, Ltd. Toa Seiki is being excluded because no dumping margins have been found on its export sales to the United States. Yamato is being given a discontinuance based upon minimal margins and written assurances that no future sales will be at less than fair value. Notice of this action will appear in the Federal Register of April 24, 1978. Imports of welded stainless steel pipe and tubing from Japan during calendar year 1977 were valued at about $20 million. o B-848 0 o ril 19, 1978 Contact: Bob Nipp 202/566-5328 Sale of Gold by the U.S. Treasury (Sale for Dollars) The Department of the Treasury announced that it is requesting the General Services Administration to initiate a series of monthly public auctions of gold beginning on May 23, 1978. Approximately 300,000 ounces of gold will be sold at each of the first six auctions. The Treasury expects to review the experience at these auctions to determine whether the amounts to be offered at succeeding auctions should be altered. These sales of gold will have the effect of reducing the U.S. trade deficit, either by increasing exports of gold or by reducing the imports of this commodity. The sales will also further the U.S. desire to continue progress toward the elimination of the international monetary role of gold. The Treasury plans to study the technical aspects of selling gold against payment in West German deutschemarks with a view to determining whether sales of gold also provide a technically feasible and advisable means of acquiring deutschemarks for use in countering disorderly conditions in foreign exchange markets. Invitations to bid at the initial auction will specify payment in U.S. dollars and provide for delivery at the U.S. Assay Office in New York or at other U.S. gold depositories. Any change in these arrangements will be announced prior to future auctions. Auctions will be conducted at 11:00 AM on Tuesday, May 23, 1978, and the third Tuesday of each month thereafter in the GSA Office at 7th and "D" Streets, S.W., Washington, D.C. At the May 23 auction, the minimum bid accepted will be for 400 ounces. A bid deposit of $10 an ounce will be required. The gold will be made available in bars each containing approximately 400 ounces. Sales will be by competitive bids with all successful bidders paying the price bid for each ounce of gold. .The Treasury reserves the right to reject any or all bids. Bids by or on behalf of foreign governments or central banks will not knowingly be accepted. Formal invitations to bid in the auctions will be issued by the GSA within ten days. Bid forms will be mailed to firms or persons on GSA's precious metal mailing lists. All others wishing to receive an invitation to bid should communicate with: General Services Administration B-849 Washinqton, 'Telephone: Metals 18th and Branch, "F"Area D.C. Streets, Office Code 20405 N.W. of 202-566-1986 Stockpile Disposal TABLE 13 GOLD AUCTION RESULTS Type of Auction treasury 975: Jan. 6 June 30 Amount Total Bids Auctioned (troy ounces) Price average or common London PM Fix bid price common price 954,000 4,000,000 754,000 499,500 $165.67 165.05 $173.50 166.25 2 July 14 Sept.15 Oct. 27 Dec. 8 common price common price bid price bid price common price 2,368,000 2,114,000 3,662,400 4,214,400 4,037,200 780,000 780,000 780,000 779,200 780,000 126.00 122.05 109.40 117.71 137.00 126.90 122.20 111.25 117.85 135.65 977: Jan. 26 March 2 April 4 May 4 June 1 July 6 \uq. 3 5ept. 6 )ct. 5 tov. 5 tec. 7 common price bid price bid price bid price common price common price common price bid price bid price bid price common price 2,003,200 1,632,800 1,278,000 1,316,400 1,014,000 1,358,400 1,439,200 1,084,000 971,200 1,356,400 1,133,600 780,000 524,400 524,800 524,800 524,800 524,800 524,800 524,800 524,800 524,800 524,800 133.26 146.51 149.18 148.02 143.32 140.26 146.26 147.78 155.14 161.86 160.03 132.15 145.05 148.60 148.10 143.85 140.55 146.00 147.65 155.05 161.50 160.30 common price common price bid price bid price 984,800 598,400 1,418,000 1,367,000 524,800 524,800 524,800 524,800 171.26 175.00 181.95 177.92 171.85 176.40 182.50 178.40 MF HiJune 111 ? fan. eb. 4 1 larch 1 *pril 5 For Release Upon Delivery Expected at 10:00 AM April 20, 1978 STATEMENT OF GARY C. HUFBAUER DEPUTY ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR INTERNATIONAL TRADE AND INVESTMENT POLICY BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON MERCHANT MARINE U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES Mr. Chairman, I appreciate the opportunity to present the Treasury Department's comments on H.R. 11422. Because this bill proposes fundamental changes in current U.S. international ocean shipping policy, it merits careful examination. As you know, the Administration has decided to undertake an in-depth study of U.S. maritime policy. This study was prompted by the need for the Administration to address the basic policy issues which this legislation raises. The study will involve a number of Executive Branch agencies, including the Treasury. We hope to have a report completed in six months. We believe that an Administration position on H.R. 11422 and similar legislation will be developed as a result of this study. Therefore, my testimony this morning will only cover the Treasury Department's initial comments on the legislation. B-850 - 2 - We believe that this legislation, if enacted, could sharply reduce competition in our ocean trades. As I indicated to you yesterday in my testimony on the controlled carrier bill, the government should protect our industry from unfair foreign competition. encouraged. But fair competition should be H.R. 11422 could reduce fair competition by legalizing two concepts: closed conferences and deferred rebates. We do not yet have a clear picture of exactly how closed conferences would function, but their intent seems to be to limit significantly the entry of new and competitive carriers in ocean shipping. The Congress could conceivably bar participation in the U.S. ocean trades by all nonconference carriers, depending on how a closed conference is defined. If this were to happen, closed conferences would have virtually absolute freedom to set rates, capacity limitations, sailing frequencies, and other aspects of the trade. The inefficiencies and excessive costs associated with closed conferences would not necessarily be avoided by the addition of shippers' councils or by extensive FMC regulation. Rates established by conferences and shippers' councils would not automatically reflect the rates of a free marketplace. Moreover, the established rates could well discriminate against shippers occupying a weak position in the council by comparison with shippers holding a stronger position. - 3 - Extensive FMC regulation would only tend to increase inefficiencies and red tape in shipping. Economists, businessmen, and government leaders are increasingly advocating more competition in transportation. Proposals to increase competition are being studied or implemented in various transportation sectors. The legalization of deferred rebates, also proposed by H.R. 11422, could exert an equally destructive effect on competition. The Alexander Committee, whose study formed the basis for the Shipping Act of 1916, reported that deferred rebates were the most effective tool then at the disposal of conferences to combat competition by outside carriers. The Committee declared that the practice was highly objectionable, and outlawed it in the Shipping Act. The Committee also recognized the the danger of a total elimination of competition, and therefore provided that entry to conferences was to be open. Rather than seeking ways to restrict competition, we believe we should move toward greater competition and less regulation in our ocean trades. The Treasury's view is that price maintenance and price-fixing arrangements are generally contrary to our nation's economic interests. We believe the national economic interest is best served when the market system is allowed to operate with as few - 4 constraints as possible. Attempts to reduce or restrict competition contribute to rigidity and wasteful inefficiency in our economy. The current conference arrangement can result in higher prices than the market will support. One symptom is the illegal rebating problem. The closed conference system, with even fewer competitive restraints than the open conference arrangement, would very likely result in still higher shipping rates over time. It could thus add to inflationary pressures in the economy. Mr. Chairman, these are some of the concerns the Treasury will raise as part of the Administration's study. We believe that the study will represent a thorough, balanced review of international ocean shipping problems. You may be sure the Treasury will cooperate fully in the search for an ocean shipping policy that meets our Nation's economic needs and interests. FOR RELEASE AT 4:00 P.M. April 20, 1978 TREASURY'S 52-WEEK BILL OFFERING The Department of the Treasury, by this public notice, invites tenders for $ 2,966 million, or thereabouts, of 364-day Treasury bills to be dated May 2, 1978, and to mature May 1, 1979 (CUSIP No. 912793 V7 8 ) . The bills, with a limited exception, will be available in book-entry form only, and will be issued for cash and in exchange for Treasury bills maturing May 2, 1978. This issue will not provide new money for the Treasury as the maturing issue is outstanding in the amount of $2,966 million, of which $1>435 million is held by the public and $ 1,531 million is held by Government accounts and the Federal Reserve Banks for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities. Additional amounts of the bills may be issued to Federal Reserve Banks as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities. Tenders from Government accounts and the Federal Reserve Banks for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities will be accepted at the average price of accepted tenders. The bills will be issued on a discount basis under competitive and noncompetitive bidding, and at maturity their par amount will be payable without interest. Except for definitive bills in the $100,000 denomination, which will be available only to investors who are able to show that they are required by law or regulation to hold securities in physical form, this series of bills will be issued entirely in book-entry form on the records either of the Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or of the Department of the Treasury. Tenders will be received at Federal Reserve Banks and Branches and at the Bureau of the Public Debt, Washington, D. C. 20226, up to 1:30 p.m., Eastern Standard time, Wednesday, April 26, 1978. Form PD 4632-1 should be used to submit tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. Each tender must be for a minimum of $10,000. be in multiples of $5,000. Tenders over $10,000 must In the case of competitive tenders, the price offered must be expressed on the basis of 100, with not more than three decimals, c -g-, 99.925. Fractions may not be used. (OVER) B-851 i -2Banking institutions and dealers who make primary markets in Government securities and report daily to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York their positions with respect to Government securities and borrowings thereon may submit tenders for account of customers, provided the names of the customers are set forth in such tenders. Others will not be permitted to submit tenders except for their own account. Payment for the full par amount of the bills applied for must accompany all tenders submitted for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. A cash adjustment will be made for the difference between the par payment submitted and the actual issue price as determined in the auction. No deposit need accompany tenders from incorporated banks and trust companies and from responsible and recognized dealers in investment securities, for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or for definitive bills, where authorized. A deposit of 2 percent of the par amount of the bills applied for must accompany tenders for such bills from others, unless an express guaranty of payment by an incorporated bank or trust company accompanies the tenders. Public announcement will be made by the Department of the Treasury of the amount and price range of accepted bids. Those submitting competitive tenders will be advised of the acceptance or rejection thereof. The Secretary of the Treasury expressly reserves the right to accept or reject any or all tenders, in whole or in part, and his action in any such respect shall be final. Subject to these reservations, noncompetitive tenders for $500,000 or less without stated price from any one bidder will be accepted in full at the average price (in three decimals) of accepted competitive bids. Settlement for accepted tenders for bills to be maintained on the records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches must be made or completed at the Federal Reserve Bank or Branch on' May 2, 1978, in cash or other immediately avail- able funds or in Treasury bills maturing May 2, 1978. Cash adjustments will be made for differences between the par value of maturing bills accepted in exchange and the issue price of the new bills. Under Sections 454(b) and 1221(5) of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954 the amount of discount at which bills issued hereunder are sold is considered to accrue when the bills are sold, redeemed or otherwise disposed of, and the bills are excluded from consideration as capital assets. Accordingly, the owner of bills (other than life insurance companies) issued hereunder must -3include in his Federal income tax return, as ordinary gain or loss, the difference between the price paid for the bills, whether on original issue or on a subsequent purchase, and the amount actually received either upon sale or redemption at maturity during the taxable year for which the return is made. Department of the Treasury Circulars, Public Debt Series - Nos. 26-76 and 27-76, and this notice, prescribe the terms of these Treasury bills and govern the conditions of their issue. Copies of the circulars and tender forms may be obtained from any Federal Reserve Bank or Branch, or from the Bureau of the Public Debt. Treasury Media Contact: Robert Nipp 202/566-5328 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE Customs Media Contact: Alan Bernstein April 21, 1978 202/566-5286 TREASURY ANNOUNCES ADDITIONAL TRIGGER BASE PRICES AND "EXTRAS" FOR IMPORTED STEEL MILL PRODUCTS The Treasury Department today announced additional trigger base prices and "extras" for imported steel mill products. The base prices and "extras" announced today cover a major portion of imports of steel wire products considered steel mill products (flat and shaped wire and barbed wire), cold finished bars and certain rails. Other products made of steel alloys are also included. Trigger prices on wire nails will be announced later because of the need to obtain additional information on such products from the Japanese government. All prices are per metric ton. A limited exemption is applied to shipments covered by contracts with fixed price terms provided the contracts were concluded before the publication date of this notice. For questions on Trigger Pricing, contact U.S. Customs at (202) 566-8235, 8236, 8651, or 5286. If those lines are busy, call (202) 566-8121 and leave your phone number. Your call will be returned. B-852 DEPARTMENT CF THE TREASURY OFFICE OF THE SECRETARY NOTICE Trigger Base Prices and "Extras" for Imported Steel Mill Products I am hereby announcing additional trigger base prices and "extras" for imported steel mill products. These trigger prices pertain to certain steel wire, barbed wire and cold finished bars, rails and alloys. The Treasury Department will use these trigger prices to monitor imparts of basic steel mill products in connection with the "trigger price mechanism." A description of the trigger price mechanism may be found in the "Background" to the final rulemaking which amended regulations to require the filing of a Special Summary Steel Invoice (SSSI) with all entries of imparted steel mill products (43 F.R. 6065). These base prices and extras are based upon evidence made available to the Treasury Department by the Japanese Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MTTI), as well as other information available to the Department. The methodology used in developing these trigger prices is essentially ths same as that described in the Federal Register Notice of January 9, 1978 (43 F.R. 1464). However, these trigger prices are based upon the production costs of the smaller Japanese fabricating mills, rather than the six integrated Japanese steel mills. The trigger prices being announced today will be used by the Customs Service to collect information at the time of entry on all shipments of the products covered which are exported after the date of publication ^ of this notice. However, the following rules will be applied to entries of these products covered by contracts with fixed price terms concluded before the publication date of this notice: 1. Contracts with fixed price terms between unrelated parties: If the importer documents at or before the time of entry that the shipment is being imported under such a contract with an unrelated party, the entry will not trigger an investigation even if the sales price is below the trigger price, provided that entry is made on or before June 30, 1978. However, failure to initiate an investigation will not diminish the^ right of affected interested persons to file a complaint with respect to such imports under the established procedures for antidumping cases. - 2 - 2. Contracts between related parties: If the importer docunents at the time of entry that the shipment is being imported under a contract with a related party and the shipment is to be resold to an unrelated purchaser in the United States under a contract with fixed price terms concluded before the publication date of this notice, the entry will not trigger an investigation even if the sales price is belcw the trigger price, provided that delivery is made en or before June 30, 1978. While these sales will not as a rule trigger a self-initiated antidumping investigation, informaticn concerning such sales will be kept as a part of the informaticn in the monitoring system and will be available in the event that an antidumping petition is filed with respect to such products sold by that producer or the Treasury Department decides to self-initiate an antidumping investigation of such products based upon subsequent sales. bjW'«j0o«£jauw>B^ Secretary of the Treasury Dated: April 21, 1978 2-1 I Category AISI 2 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 608.7880 0.375* per lb. + 4% + additional duties (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price per Metric Ton $466 es to CIF West Coast $3 $10 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes Ocean Freight $58 69 72 79 Hand 11ng Interest 5 4 4 13 14 17 nsurance \% of base price + extras * ocean freight Extras None 2-12 Spheroid I zed Annealed, Si-Mn-Cr High Carbon Steel Wire Rod AISI 9254, 5.5mm to 13mm Category AISI 2 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 608.7880 0.375* per lb. + 4$ + additional duties (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price per Metric Ton es to CIF $10 West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $446 Ocean Freight $58 69 72 79 Hand ng $3 5 4 4 nsurance \% of base price + extras • ocean freight Extras None Interest 13 13 16 2-13 Category AISI 2 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 608.7865 0.375* per lb. + 4% + additional duties (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price per Metric Ton $513 Charges toCIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest $3 $11West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $58 69 72 79 nsurance \% of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras None 5 4 4 15 15 18 Light Ralls 60 lbs./yd Category AISI 6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 610^2020 .05* per lb. Base Price per Metric Ton $292 es to CIF West Coast $9 $ 6 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes Ocean Freight Handling $33 35 38 44 9 9 9 Interest nsurance \% of base price + extras • ocean freight Extras Size 8 8 10 6-4 LIGHT RAIL EXTRAS Size (lbs/yd) % o* **se Price Extra 60 0. 0 45 2.,0 40 3,,9 30 3,,9 25 5,.9 20 5,.9 6-5 Tie Plates Category AISI 6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 610.2500 0.125* per lb. Base Price per Metric Ton $299 es to CIF West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes Ocean Fre Ight Handling $39 39 49 54 $8 1 8 8 Intere Insurance \% of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras None $ 6 8 9 1 1 Il-I Category AISI | | Tariff Schedule Number (s) 608.9240 10 1/251 + additional duties (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price per Metric Ton $391 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest West Coast $49 $3 $ 9 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes 51 63 79 Insurance \% of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras None 5 4 4 12 12 15 11-2 Spheroldlzed Annealed, High Carbon Cr Steel Round Bar Category AISI AISI 52100,40mm to lOOrrni II Tariff Schedule Number (s) 608.5225 10 1/2* + additional duties (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price per Metric Ton $437 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest West Coast $3 $10 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $49 51 63 79 5 4 4 Insurance \% of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras None 13 13 17 12-1 Cold Finished Carbon Steel Round Bar Category AISI AISI 1018, 19.05mm (3/4") 12 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 608.5015 8 1/2* Base Price Der Metric Ton $36| Charges toCIF Ocean Freight $3 $ West 8 Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $30 35 40 58 Handling 5 4 4 Insurance \% of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras Size, See Table p. 12-4 Interest 10 10 13 12-2 )ategory AISI 12 "ariff Schedule Number (s) 608.5005 8 1/2? Base D rice oer Metric Ton Charges to CIF $408 Ocean freight West Coast $30 $3 $ 9 r* 3ulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes 35 40 58 Handling 5 4 4 'nterest II 12 15 nsurance \% of base crice t extras -*• ocean *reich* Extras Size, See Table D . 12-4 12-3 Cold Finished Round Steel Bar (Free Cutting Steel-Lead) Category AISI AISI I2LI4, 19.05mm(3/4") 12 i- Tariff Schedule Number (s) 608.5005 8 1/2? Base Price Der Metric Ton $428 Charges to CIF $3 $ 9 West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes Ocean freight $30 35 40 58 Handling 5 4 4 nsurance \i of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras Size, See Table p. 12-4 Interes1 12 12 15 12-4 Size Extras for Cold Finished Steel Bars ($ Extra/M.T.) Shape Size Round Hexagon Up to 3/16" Including 63 154 3/I6M thru 5/16" 42 83 33 50 5/8" 17 33 5/8" 7/8" Base 8 7/8" 1-7/16" 8 17 13 29 1-3/4" " 2-11/16" 17 42 2-11/16" " 25 over 5/16" ff 7/16 7/16" 1-7/16" 3" 3-3/4" " " 1-3/4" 3" " 3-3/4" »» /t» 33 42 14-15 Welded Stainless Steel Pipe ASTM-A3I2, Tp 304, NB 3" x Sch. 109 Category AISI 14 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 610.3715 0.3* per lb. + 4? + additional duties (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price oer Metric Ton Charges to CIF West Coast $59 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $1874 Ocean Freight 86 86 86 H d 1 i ng $3 5 4 4 Insurance \% of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras None 1nterest $37 49 49 60 14-16 Welded Stainless Steel Round Ornamental Tube Category AISI AISI TP 304 I 5/8 x 0.065" 14 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 610.3715 0.3* per lb. + 4% + additional duti (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price oer Metric Ton $1689 es to CIF West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes Ocean Pre iaht Ha nd1 i ng $59 86 86 86 $3 5 4 4 Interest nsurance \% of base price + extras • ocean freight Extras A, Size B. Grade $34 44 44 55 14-17 Size Extras for Welded Stainless Steel Ornamental Round Tube (TSUSA 610.3715) Size (Inches) 0D W % of Base Price Extra I 5/8 0.065 Base I 1/2 0.065 0.6 I 1/4 0.065 2.8 I 0.065 3.8 3/4 0.065 I 1.1 Grade AISI 304 Base AISI 410 -417 AISI 430 -500 $ Ektra/M.T, 15-44 Hot Rolled, High Carbon CR Steel Tube, Suitable for Use in Manufacture of Ball or Roller Bearings AISI 52100, 60mm to 100mm Category AISI 15 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 610.4600 13? + additional duties (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price per Metric Ton $534 Charges toCIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest $3 $12West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $63 69 85 94 5 4 4 Insurance \% of base price + extras t ocean freight Extras None 16 16 21 15-45 Cold Rolled, High Carbon Cr Steel Tube, Suitable for Use in Manufacture of Ball or Roller Bearings AISI 52100, 60mm'to 100mm Category AISI 15 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 610.4600 13? + additional duties (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price per Metric Ton $792 Charqes to CIF West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes Ocean Freight $63 69 85 94 id 1 ing Interest $3 5 4 4 surance I? of base price t extras + ocean freight Extras None $18 23 23 29 15-46 Seamless Stainless Steel Round Ornamental Tube Category AISI AISI TP 304, I 1/4 x 0.049" 15 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 610.5235 13? + additional duties (see Headnote 4, TSUS) Base Price oer Metric Ton $1798 Charges to CIF West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes Ocean Freight $59 86 86 86 d 1 ing Interest $3 5 4 4 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freiaht Extras A. Size B. Grade $39 50 50 62 15-47 Size Extras for Seamless Stainless Steel Round Tube (TSUSA 610.5235) Size (Inches) 00 WT ? of Base Price Extra I 1/4 0.049 Base I 0.049 0.9 3/4 0.049 4.4 Grade $ Extra/MT AISI 304 Base AISI 410 -417 AISI 430 ' ~500 15-48 Seamless Stainless Steel Square Ornamental Tube AISI TP 304, I 1/2x1 1/2 x 0.065" Category AISI 15 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 610.5235 13? + additional duties (see Headnote 4 TSUS)' Base Price oer Metric Ton harges to CIF West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $1959 Ocean Freight $59 86 86 86 d 1 i ng $3 5 4 4 Interest $42 55 55 68 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freicht Extras A. Size B. Grade 15-49 Size Extras for Seamless Stainless Steel Souare Ornamental Tube Size ? of Base Price Fxtra I 1/2" x I 1/2" x 0.065" Rase I 1/4" x I 1/4" x 0.065" 2.6 I 1/4" x I 1/4 x 0.049" 3.2 I 1/3" x I 1/8 x 0.065 2.7 I x I x 0.065" 2.8 I x I x 0.049" 3.5 5/8 x 5/8 x 0.049" 8.0 Grade $ Extra/M.T. AISI 304 Base AISI 410 -417 AISI 430 -500 16-1 Cold Heading Round Wire, Hard Drawn, AISI 1018 Killed, 0.192" Category AISI '6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4105 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2? 609.4125 0.3* per lb. 609.4315 8 1/2? Base Price oer Metric Ton $400 Handling Charges to CIF Ocean Freight West Coast $41 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes 44 45 60 $3 $ 8 5 4 4 Insurance I? of base price • extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and pg. 16-13 Interest 10 10 13 16-2 I ~ Cold Heading Round Wire, Drawn from Annealed Rods, AISI 1018 Killed, 0.192" i I . Category AISI ' 6 T •*• sr-hedule Number (s) 609.4105 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2* 609.4315 8 1/2? T8r ,ff Schedule Number 6 0 9 . 4 , 2 5 0.3tf p e r , b . flase Price per Metric Ton $455 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Hand.ing Interest West Coast $4» $\ Jt Gulf Coast 44 3 Atlantic Coast 46 4 Great Lakes 6° Insurance I* of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and ng. 16-13 ^ 16-3 Cold Heading Round Wire, Drawn from Spheroldlzed Annealed Rods, AISI 1018 Killed, 0.192" Category AISI '6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4105 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2 ? 609.4125 0.3* per lb. 609.4315 8 1/2 ? Base Price per Metric Ton $46 4 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest $3 $ 9West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $41 44 46 60 5 4 4 Insurance I? of base price + extras • ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and pg. 16-13. 12 12 15 16-4 Cold Heading Round Wire Annealed In Process, AISI 1018 Killed, 0.192" Category AISI 16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4105 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2? 609.4125 0.3* per lb. 609.4315 8 1/2? Base Price per Metric Ton $468 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest West Coast $41 $3 $ 9 Gulf Coast . Atlantic Coast Great Lakes 44 46 60 5 4 4 nsura nee I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and pg. 16-13 12 12 15 16-5 Cold Heading Round Wire, Spheroidlze Annealed in Process, AISI 1018 Killed 0.192" Category AISI 16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4105 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2? 609.4125 0.3* per lb. 609.4315 8 1/2? Base Price per Metric Ton Charges t o C I F $3 $ 9West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $477 Ocean Freight Handling $41 44 46 60 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and ng. 16-13. 5 4 4 Interest 12 I? 15 16-6 Cold Headina Pound Wire, Annealed AISI 1018 Ki I led, 0.192" Category AISI in Process and Hrawn from Annealed Pods, ,6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 13ri 609.4.05 0.3* per lb. 609.4175 0.3* ner lb. Base Price oer Metric Ton es to CIF West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes 1 nsurance i* 1 P 609.4305 8 \/?t 609.4315 8 1/2* $504 Ocean Freight Ha ndli ng Interest $41 44 46 60 $3 5 4 4 $10 13 13 16 + ocean f reight of base orice + extras Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and pg. 16-3 16-7 Cold Heading Round Wire, Spheroidlze Annealed In Process and Drawn from Annealed Rods, AISI 1018 Killed, 0.192" _ Category AISI , __ _ _J |6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4105 0.3* oer lb. 609.4125 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2? 609.4315 8 1/2? Base Price oer Metric Ton J5j3 Charges to CIF Ocean Fre i ght Hand Ii ng Interest $3 $10West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $41 44 46 60 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables ng. 16-12 and pg. 16-13. 5 4 4 , 13 13 16 16-8 Cold Heading Round Wire, Annealed at Finished Size, AISI 1018 Killed, 0.192" Category AISI 16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4I05 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2? 609.4125 0.3* per lb. 609.4315 8 1/2? Base Price per Metric Ton $455 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest West Coast $41 $3 $ 9 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes 44 44 60 Insurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and 16-13. 5 4 4 12 12 15 Cold Heading Round Wire Spheroidize Annealed at Finished Size, AISI Killed, 0.192" Category AISI \e Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4105 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2? 609.4125 0.3* per lb. 609.4315 8 1/2? Base Price Der Metric Ton $464 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest $3 $ 9West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $41 44 44 60 5 4 4 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and pg. 16-13. 12 12 15 16-10 Cold Heading Round Wire, Annealed at Finished Size and Drawn from Annealed Rods, AISI 1018 Killed, 0.192" Category AISI 16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4105 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2? 609.4125 0.3* per lb. 609.4315 8 1/2? Base Price per Metric Ton $490 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest $3 $10West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $41 44 44 60 Insurance 1? of base p Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and pg. 16-13. 5 4 4 13 13 16 16-11 Cold Heading Round Wire Spheroidize Annealed at Finished Size and Drawn from Annealed Rod, AISI 1018 Killed, 0.192" Category AISI 16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4105 0.3* per lb. 609.4305 8 1/2? 609.4125 0.3* per lb. 609.4315 8 1/2? Base Price per Metric Ton $500 Ocean Freight Handling Interest Charges to CIF West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $41 44 44 60 Insurance 1? of base p Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-12 and pa. 16-13. $3 5 4 4 $10 13 13 16 16-12 GRADE EXTRAS FOR COLD HEADING WIRE Grade $ Extra/M.T AISI 1006 KiI led through 1022 Killed Steel base AISI 1010 Rimmed Steel -12 AISI 1038 Killed Steel +16 AISI I0B2! Killed Steel +20 16-13 SIZE EXTRAS FOR C O L D H E A D I N G W I R E ($ EXTRA/M.T.) Size (Inches) Processing Number3 (2) and (3) (1) (4) thru (7) (8) thru ( m 0 0.437 thru 0.999 II II 0.192 thru 0.436 base base base base 0.135 thru 0.191 8 8 14 14 0.105 thru 0.134 14 14 29 29 0.080 thru 0.104 25 25 62 41 0.062 thru 0.079 33 33 104 66 a) Processing numbers and descriptions: (I) Hard (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (II) Drawn Drawn from Annealed Rod9 Drawn from Spheroidized Annealed Rods Anneal in Process Speroidize Anneal in Process Anneal in Process & Drawn from Annealed Rods Spheroidize Anneal in Process & Drawn from Annealed Rods Anneal at Finished Size Spheroidize Anneal at Finished Size Anneal at Finfehed Size & Drawn from Annealed Rods Spheroidize Anneal at Finished Size e\ Drawn from Annealed Rods 0 16-14 Category AISI '16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4010 8 1/2? 609.4105 0.3* per lb. 609.4125 0.3* per lb. Base Price per Metric Ton $329 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest West Coast $40 $3 $ 6 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast ' Great Lakes 42 45 60 Insurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-16 and pg. 16-1 7, 5 4 4 8 8 11 16-15 Galvanized Iron Round Wire, AISI Type I Coating, 80 Category AISI ,6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4040 8 1/2? 609.4165 0.3* per lb. Base Price per Metric Ton J414 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest $ 3 $ West 8 Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $40 41 45 60 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Tables pg. 16-16 and pg. I 6-17. 5 4 4 II II 13 SIZE EXTRAS FOR BRIGHT BASIC WIRE AND GALVANIZED IRON WIRE $ Fxtra/M.T. Bright Basic Wire Galv. Iron Wire ase base 6 12 8 16 10 22 12 31 16 39 20 47 29 60 37 72 45 89 54 106 64 127 77 147 16-17 PACKING TXTRAS FOR BRIGHT BASIC WIRE AND GALVANIZED IRON WIRF Packing Description $ Extra/M.T Pare CoiI Base Paper Wrapping 12 To Iypropylane-backed 20 Paper Wrapping Paper and Hessian Wrapping 29 16-18 Round Bal ing Wire, 14.50 Category AISI 16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4120 0.3* per lb Base Price per Metric Ton $459 Charges to CIF $3 $ 9West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes Ocean Freight Handling $40 41 45 60 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras: None 5 4 4 Interest 12 12 15 16-19 Bright Annealed Cold Drawn Stainless Steel Wire, AISI 304, 0.080" Category AISI 16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4540 10 1/2? + additional duties (see Headnote 4, T.S.U.S) Base Price per Metric Ton $2182 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest West Coast $ 93 $3 $44 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes 109 109 142 Insurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras See "Extras" Table pg. 16-20 5 4 4 57 57 71 16 SIZE EXTRAS FOR COLD DRAWN, BRIGHT ANNEALED (or ANNEALED AND PICKLED) STAINLESS STEEL WIRE Size (Inches) $ Fxtra/M.T. 0..200 -142 0.131 -79 0.080 Base 0.040 117 0.032 208 0.020 633 0.016 750 0.012 1067 0.008 1504 16-21 Spring Hard Temper, Nickel Copper and Plastic Coat, Cold Drawn Stainless Steel Wire, AISI 302, 0.040" Category AISI ,6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4510 10 1/2? + additional duties (see Headnote 4, T.S.U.S.) Base Price per Metric Ton Charces to CIF West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $2745 Ocean Freight $ 93 109 109 142 >d f i n g Interest $3 5 4 4 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras Non» $55 72 72 89 16-22 Cold Heading OuaIity,Copper and Molybdenum Coat, Told Drawn Stainless Steel Wire, ASTM 493A, KM-7, 0.131" Category AISI ,6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4540 10 1/2? + additional duties (see Head note 4, T.S.U.S.) Base Price oer Metric Ton $2353 dl ing Charges to CIF Ocean Freight H West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $ 93 109 109 142 Interest $3 5 4 4 nsurance \% of base or.ce + extras + ocean freight Extras None $47 62 62 77 16-23 Cold Heading Quality, Copper and Molybdenum Coat, Cold Drawn Stainless Stee ]rfire, AISI 305, 0.131" Category AISI 16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4540 10 1/2? + additional duties (see Headnote 4, T.S.U.S.) Base Price per Metric Ton $2416 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest West Coast $ 93 $3 $48 Gu If Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes j Qg 109 142 5 4 4 63 63 7Q Insurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras None 16-24 Cold Heading Quality, Copper and Molybdenum Coat, Cold Drawn Stainless Stee Wire, AISI 410, 0.131" Category AISI 16 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4540 10 1/2? + additional Duties (see Headnote 4, T.S.U.S.) Base Price oer Metric Ton Charges to CIF West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $1562 Ocean Freight $ 93 109 109 142 andl ing $3 5 4 4 Interest $31 41 41 51 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras None 16-25 Cold Heading Quality, Copper and Molybdenum Coat,Cold Drawn Stainless Steel Wire, AISI 430, 0.131" Category AISI |6 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 609.4540 10 1/2? + additional duties (see Headnote 4, T.S.U.S.) Base Price per Metric Ton Charges to CIF $3 $32West Coast Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes $1602 Ocean Freight $ 93 I0O 109 142 Handling 5 4 •4 nsurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Extras None Interest 42 42 52 21-1 Category AISI 21 Tariff Schedule Number (s) 642.0200 Free Base Price oer Metric Ton $522 Charges to CIF Ocean Freight Handling Interest West Coast $42 $3 $ 9 Gulf Coast Atlantic Coast Great Lakes 50 55 60 Insurance I? of base price + extras + ocean freight Fxtrris: None 5 4 4 12 12 14 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 21, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal (202) 566-8381 TREASURY DEPARTMENT ANNOUNCES WITHHOLDING OF APPRAISEMENT ON MOTORCYCLES FROM JAPAN The Treasury Department announced today that it is withholding appraisement on imports of motorcycles from Japan. Under the Antidumping Act, the Secretary of the Treasury is required to withhold appraisement whenever he has reason to believe or suspect that sales at less than fair value are taking place. Sales at less than fair value generally occur when the prices of the merchandise sold for export to the United States are less than the prices of the same merchandise sold in the home market. The withholding of appraisement will not exceed six months. Withholding of appraisement means that the valuation for Customs duty purposes of goods imported after the date of the tentative determination in an antidumping investigation is suspended for up to six months, thus allowing any dumping duties which may ultimately be imposed to be levied on imports entered during the final stage of the investigation. If Treasury finds sales at less than fair value are occurring, the U.S. International Trade Commission must subsequently decide whether an American industry is being, or is likely to be, injured by these sales. Both "sales at less than fair value" and "injury" must be found to exist before a dumping finding is reached. For purposes of this investigation, the term "motorcycles" refers to motorcycles having engines with total piston displacement over 90 cc (cubic centimeters), whether for use on or off the road. Notice of this action will appear in the Federal Register of April 26, 1978. Imports of this merchandise from Japan were valued at roughly $360 million during calendar year 1976, and at roughly $95 million during the first quarter of 1977. B-853 0 0 0 REMARKS BY THE HONORABLE W. MICHAEL BLUMENTHAL SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE U.S.-ARAB CHAMBER OF COMMERCE, INC. INTERNATIONAL BUSINESS CONFERENCE WASHINGTON, D.C. APRIL 21, 1978 I am delighted to be here today to discuss U.S.-Arab economic relations and the importance for the world as a whole of our continued cooperation. It was the importance of improved cooperation in an increasingly interdependent world which took me to the Middle East last I i fall to discuss a number of matters of mutual interest and to .liiii! establish personal relationships with the key government officials of Egypt, Saudi Arabia and Kuwait. I returned from my visits with President Sadat, King Khaled and Crown Prince Fahd, and Shaykh Jabir al-Sabah and |ii;j f Minister al-Ateeqi very encouraged by their clear perception of the problems facing the world economy, and their willing- j ness to work with us in resolving them. We place a high priority on these relations^ We will work hard to maintain them. The problems we have dealt with go well beyond bilateral concerns. The actions we take in the areas of monetary B-854 j i ' - 2 policy, energy and trade, investment, and aid to the developing countries can have a lasting impact on the vitality and stability of the world economy. I would like to discuss today the actions the United States is taking in a number of these areas as a means of strengthening the monetary system and improving mutual cooperation. THE DOLLAR At the top of everyone's list is what we have come to to know (but not love) as the "dollar problem". The dollar came under pressure in the foreign exchange markets last year because of the unexpectedly large increase in our trade and current account deficits. Disorderly conditions led to excessively rapid rate movements which went beyond what was justified by underlying economic conditions. We recognized then and recognize now the concern of some OPEC nations that recent exchange market developments would reduce the dollar's purchasing power relative to that of some other major currencies. Yet for all the publicity about the dollar's decline, the real extent of exchange rate changes has been considerably smaller and less volatile than most people think. Although some bilateral exchange rates have undergone very substantial changes in the last few years, these changes have been in both directions. Since March 1973, the Swiss franc, the German mark and the Japanese - 3 yen have appreciated substantially against the dollar, while the dollar has appreciated against such currencies as the Canadian dollar, the pound sterling, and Italian lira. On a U.S. trade-weighted basis compared to all OECD countries, the dollar as of March 31 had actually appreciated by about one percent since the beginning of generalized floating in 1973. Against all currencies, the dollar appreciated by eight percent during this period. Thus, while the dollar has depreciated against some currencies, it went up by even more against others. Moreover, taking into account relative price movements among major countries, the extent of real exchange rate changes has been even more modest. But that is past history. The U.S. recognizes that a strong dollar is in the interest of both the U.S. and the world economy. And we are taking steps to address the exchange market problem in the only manner in which it can be truly resolved: by dealing with the fundamental economic situation. First, we are determined to implement a national energy program, either through Congressional or Administrative action, to reduce our oil import requirements and thus reduce our trade deficit. Second, we are determined to reduce inflation. The anti-inflation program which the President announced last week includes a long list of specific actions to help hold down the rate of inflation. Most important, perhaps, is - 4 - the President's determination to maintain a tight Federal budget which will meet the nation's most pressing needs without compromising our hopes for balanced economic growth. The President has said he would veto such legislative proposals as tuition tax credits to keep the budget in line. His position has already been recognized by the House of Representatives in defeating a highly inflationary farm bill and the passage of airline deregulation. Success or failure in this effort to restrain inflation will clearly be determined in large part by the actions of the private sector of the economy. A number of leaders of labor, business and industry have promised to cooperate with this program to decelerate price increases. We recognize that a reduction in the inflation rate will not be easy and will not come overnight, and that it will demand real sacrifice by many Americans. But we will pursue this program with vigor. And we will suceed. Our anti-inflation program will help maintain a domestic climate for investment which will continue to attract capital inflows. It will help preserve the real value of Arab dollar investments. It will justify the confidence which the oil producing states have shown in the United States. - 5 Third, we are determined to encourage U.S. exports and to maintain our competitive position in world markets. The President has already proposed to double Commodity Credit Corporation credits to support agricultural exports and to sharply increase Export-Import Bank lending activity in 1978. He has also asked a special cabinet-level task force, chaired by the Secretary of Commerce, to develop additional measures to promote U.S. exports. As progress*is being made along these fundamental lines, the U.S. will be ever ready to intervene to the extent necessary to counter market disorders and curb speculation. We~ have the resources for this purpose. The resources of the Treasury are being used in conjunction with the Federal Reserve's $22 billion swap network through establishment of a swap between the Exchange Stabilization Fund and the German Bundesbank. The Federal Reserve's swap facility with the Bundesbank has also been doubled, to $4 billion. We have agreed to sell up to $740 million worth of SDR's to Germany for marks. Furthermore, the U.S. has a res position in the IMF of $5 billion which can be drawn upon, if and as necessary, to obtain additional foreign currencies for intervention. - 6 I wish to make clear at this point that a shift from the dollar for oil pricing and investment holdings would not be a solution to the recent exchange rate changes. The dollar is the predominant currency of world investment, trade, and financing. While there are other outlets for OPEC investment, the dollar serves as the principal currency capable of accommodating OPEC's investment needs. To be sure, no unit of account can provide full protection against exchange risk. If, for example, the SDR had been used over the past 2-1/2 years, OPEC's oil revenues would have been lower than they have been with dollar pricing. Thus, despite significant exchange market fluctuations in the last five years, it comes as no surprise that one quarter of all OPEC surpluses have been invested in the U.S. and another 13 percent in U.S. banks abroad; and that the dollar component of official foreign currency reserves has remained constant at about 80 percent. A healthy dollar is vital to the world. And we will make significant efforts to preserve its integrity. As recognition of our determination spreads, markets will calm down. Our economy is outperforming all others in growth. The United States is an attractive place to invest. We intend to see that it remains so- And we are counting on other nations, including the OPEC countries, to help maintain the stability - 7 and vitality of the global economy. ENERGY It would be wholly inappropriate for me to neglect discussing energy before this distinguished group. For the United States, the increased price of oil and our continuing strong demand for energy imports were important factors in our $31 billion trade deficit in 1977. Oil imports last year totaled $45 billion, more than nine times the value of our oil imports just five years earlier. Delays in Congressional adoption of a comprehensive energy policy and the prospect of continued large U.S. trade deficits have clearly damaged confidence in the U.S. dollar. I must tell you that the American people are measurably cutting back on their energy consumption. Fuel efficiency standards, new insulation techniques and other conservation measures are beginning to take hold. Nevertheless, we are still in dire need of U.S. action on a domestic energy program which will pare further wasteful oil consumption, expand domestic energy production, and encourage Americans to use all forms of energy more efficiently. To accomplish this goal, President Carter proposed a National Energy Plan almost exactly one year ago. Unfortunately, Congress still has not given its final approval to this plan. - 8 - Time is running out. The President has indicated that this is an urgent matter. Moreover, as stated in his April 11 speech, he is willing to take Administrative action under the law, if necessary to accomplish the goals of the proposed Crude Oil Equalization Tax. We must have an energy bill. It is necessary for the sake of our economy and the integrity of our money, and for the sake of others, including the OPEC surplus holders who are concerned about the capital value of their investments. Thus, we are working hard with the Congress to assure that the COET and the rest of our legislation is passed on a timely basis. While we are working on an energy program at home, we are also cooperating with other industrial countries to conserve energy and stabilize energy markets, notably through the International Energy Agency. Within the IEA, we have negotiated an Emergency Oil-Sharing Program to reduce the effect of any supply interruptions. We have also cooperated with key oil-producing countries to bring down world inflation and promote recovery from the world recession which had been triggered by increases in oil prices. The oil producing countries have wisely recognized that further increases would be disruptive — for both them and the oil importing nations, and especially damaging to the developing countries. The responsible decision to freeze - 9 oil prices represents an important contribution to a healthier world economy. We hope they will maintain this freeze throughout 1978 at least. U.S." ARAB COOPERATION I would like to turn now to a few specific areas in which cooperation between the United States and the Arab nations is essential. First, we must work in a constructive manner to achieve an accommodation on the important issue of the Arab boycott of Israel. Our laws specifically acknowledge the legitimacy of a direct boycott of one country by another, although we regret the existence of such a boycott directed against another friendly country. Our anti-boycott laws draw a distinction, however, between a direct boycott, and indirect boycotts which call upon Americans to refuse to engage in certain types of transactions with Israel or with other entities which engage in such transactions, as a condition for trading in the Arab world. Such practices clearly run counter to our longstanding commitment to fair and open competition in the market place, and we cannot accept them. Indeed, Americans who comply with the indirect boycott are subject to the loss of foreign tax credit, deferral, and DISC tax benefits as well as criminal penalties. - 10 We believe that the laws which have been passed reflect substantial compromises on the part of the United States. We are hopeful that our Arab friends will also find it possible to adjust their boycott practices. We have seen evidence of their willingness to do so. Second, U.S.-Arab trade relations are becoming increasingly important to each of us, and we should do our best to assure that trade will continue to grow, unimpeded by artificial or unnecessary restraints. U.S. exports to your countries now represent almost 10 percent of our total exports. These exports reached $10 billion in 1977, an increase of more than 40 percent from 1976 and triple the 1974 level of $3.3 billion. Although the growth of imports by the Arab countries has been slowed by absorptive, and in some cases financial, constraints, there remains a great potential for continued expansion of U.S.-Arab trade and commercial relations, especially for the kind of goods and services in which U.S. companies excel: for example, transportation, communications and industrial machinery and processes. The Export-Import Bank of the United States had $740 million in direct loans to Arab countries and $600 million in insurance and guarantees, as of January 31. We expect - 11 Eximbank to play an increasingly important role in support of U.S. exports to Arab countries. For many of these countries, access to long-term private capital finance is limited. For many others, access to long-term World Bank loans is either limited or insufficient for their needs. An Eximbank guarantee to private lenders or an Eximbank long-term loan effectively fills the gap in the financial resources available to Arab countries. We should both benefit from the expanded use of these programs. Third, we are proposing changes in our tax laws to reduce the tax liability of Americans overseas and to make them more equitable. It has become increasingly apparent that the changes made in Section 911 of the U.S. Tax Code, which permits the exclusion of a portion of foreign earned income from taxable income, by the Tax Reform Act of 1976, are unsatisfactory and in some cases unfair. The net effect of the changes would be to increase greatly the U.S. tax which some Americans in the Middle East would have to pay, thus causing many to consider leaving the area or to decline jobs which they otherwise might accept. An overall reduction in American involvement in the economic development efforts of the Middle East would be - 12 severely injurious to U.S. policy objectives. Such involve- ment contributes positively and substantially to U.S. exports to the area, as well as to the economic development of an area of major importance. Therefore, the Administration has proposed special deductions for Americans living abroad for certain housing and education costs and for the cost of travel to the United States on home leave. We believe this approach to Section 911 is more equitable, and we hope for prompt Congressional action on this important issue. Finally, we should continue to expand our economic assistance to the poorer Arab nations and bilateral programs of economic cooperation. The immense oil earnings of the oil-producing Arab states have enabled them to contribute substantial amounts toward the development of other countries in the area, especially their Arab neighbors. We understand that bilateral aid commitments by Saudi Arabia, Kuwait, the UAE and Qatar last year were about $8 billion. Actual disbursements over the last three years probably totaled about $10.5 billion. The U.S. has also had extensive aid programs in effect in the area for many years. The U.S. has committed more than $2.3 billion in economic assistance to Egypt alone since mid1974. Congress recently appropriated an additional $750 million - 13 for FY 1978 and we expect food aid programs to add another $150 million to this amount. This is the largest single U.S. economic assistance program ever. The U.S. is also committed to the long-term development of the Jordanian economy. Our economic assistance to Jordan is planned to increase from approximately $80 million in FY 1977 and $100 million in FY 1978 to a proposed $150 million in FY 1979. In addition to these major assistance programs, the United States is also actively working with Saudi Arabia to aid its economic development, using U.S. technical expertise and Saudi capital deposited in a dollar trust with the Treasury Department. The U.S.-Saudi Arabian Joint Commission on Economic Cooperation currently is implementing projects valued at over $600 million, involving more than 100 U.S. experts nowJworking in Saudi Arabia. The Joint Commission provides a valuable forum in which the two governments can discuss a wide range of financial and economic matters of mutual interest. I personally am very enthusiastic about the work of the U.S.Saudi Arabian Joint Commission and the significant contributions its economic assistance programs are making to the strengthening of our bilateral economic and commercial - 14 relationship. This represents a new and vigorous effort in international economic cooperation. CONCLUSION President Carter has pointed to the high level of our oil imports and the increasing rate of inflation as the two developments which most seriously threaten our nation's economic health. They both imperil our economic recovery and threaten the strength of the dollar. They must be controlled. As I have discussed in my comments today, the United States is taking major initiatives in each of these areas. We depend upon other nations to play their appropriate roles, as well, in helping to promote world recovery. For the major Arab countries, and especially for the oil-producing nations, this means maintaining needed restraint on the price of their oil exports, continuing to offer substantial economic assistance to the developing nations, and meaningful, effect ive cooperation in seeking to resolve our mutual economic problems. I am confident that, by pursuing the cooperative economic efforts we now have underway, and by avoiding actions which could disrupt those efforts, the answers to these problems can be found. Further development of our economic relations with the Arab countries will continue to be an important U.S. - 15 policy objective. We hope that this will also encourage real progress toward a just and lasting peace in the Middle East, bringing with it the true promise of a better life for all of our people. partmentoftheJREASURY SHINGTON, D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY April 24, 147*4 10:00 a.m. STATEMENT OF EMIL M. SUNLEY DEPUTY ASSISTANT SECRETARY FOR TAX ANALYSIS BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON TAXATION AND DEBT MANAGEMENT OF THE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE Mr. Chairman and Members of this Distinguished Committee: I appreciate this opportunity to appear before you and discuss the subject of indexation of the tax system. The recent surge of interest in indexation, or inflation adjustment of the tax system, obviously stems from the high rate of inflation we have experienced for the last several years. If inflation were proceeding at a rate of only one or one and a half percent as it did in the early 1960's, there would be much less concern with as complex an alteration of the tax law as indexation. On the other hand, if the rate of inflation were to accelerate and reach a level of 20 or 25 percent as in some other countries, I believe almost everyone would favor indexation. Thus, one factor in deciding whether we want to index the tax system is the projection of likely future inflation rates. If we expect a moderate rate of inflation, say 6 to 7 percent, we must then decide whether the complexities involved in going to an indexed system are worth the gains, or whether there are other forms of ad hoc adjustments which could achieve the same ends of automatic indexation, but which would involve much less tax complexity. There are two separate issues in indexing the tax system: the definition of income and the proper tax treatment of income, once defined. I will begin by discussing the second issue, the tax treatment of nominal dollar amounts, because in this area proposals and recommendations have been most fully developed. -855 -2Fixed Dollar Amounts As inflation occurs, the real value of fixed dollar amounts declines; and thus, since income taxes are computed from tax brackets and exemptions which are denominated in fixed dollars, tax liabilities and effective tax rates rise. To illustrate this result, consider a family consisting of a husband, wife, and two children, with an income of $15,000. Their income tax based on 1977 rates would be $1,385 or about 9.2 percent of income. Now, let's assume that inflation runs at a rate of 7 percent this year, a bit higher than our current estimate but the average that we have experienced for the last several years, and assume further that this family's income increases by this same percentage. That would mean that their dollar income in 1978 would be $16,050, but, of course, their real income, that is, their actual spending power, would not have increased at all above last year's level of $15,000. Yet their income tax would rise to $1,613 and more importantly, their effective tax rate, which had been 9.2 percent in 1977, would rise to 10.0 percent in 1978. If this high rate of inflation were to continue for 10 years, this family, even though it had experienced no increases in real income, would see its effective tax rate climb to 17.8 percent, almost double what it had been in 1977 — if, and this is a big if, Congress did not make any income tax changes during the intervening period. In this instance, what is true for an individual family is true for taxpayers as a whole. If we experience 10 percent inflation, individual income tax receipts rise not by 10 percent, but by something closer to 15 percent. In the technical jargon of economics, the elasticity of the income tax with respect to inflation is about 1.5; that is, tax receipts rise one and a half times as fast as the rate of inflation. Since World War II, the rate of inflation has ebbed and flowed but the trend of prices has always been upward. Does this mean that the effective tax rate on individual income ias been constantly rising over time? Not at all, because Congress has in fact taken frequent action to reduce individual taxes so that the individual income tax as a percentage of personal income has actually fluctuated in a :ather narrow band. Since 1951, it has ranged from a low of >.2 percent (in 1965), to a high of 11.6 percent (in 1969 *hen the 10 percent surcharge was in effect). It is not just inflation which pushes taxpayers up into ugher tax brackets. Because the real productivity of the American economy has been rising, in the absence of -3)ffsetting legislation, our tax bills would also have risen, liven our progressive rate structure. This would have been Thus, the fact :rue even if there had been no inflation. :hat income taxes as a percent of personal income have not isen, means that Congress, with its periodic tax cuts, has ieen offsetting not ony the impact of inflation on tax rates, iut also the impact of the growth of real per capita income. n fact, if Congress had not cut taxes periodically but nstead had indexed the individual income tax for inflation •n the basis of the Consumer Price Index in 1960, taxes would n fact have been higher in 1975 than they were under the ctual 1975 law. Thus, I think the question we should ask is not: should e adjust the tax system for inflation? But rather, how hould we adjust the tax system for inflation: by an utomatic process called indexation or by periodic egislative read j ustments? utomatic Indexation I would like to discuss three issues concerning utomatic indexation: the impact of inflation on the overnment's share in the economy, the necessity of ongressional overview, and the impact of indexation on :onomic stability. Many people favor automatic indexation because they 5lieve that the government will automatically increase its lare of the total economy as inflation generates additional axes. Thus, they believe the government "benefits" from lflation. This view is mistaken. The historical record, mtioned above, shows that the response of the Federal )vernment to an upward trend in effective tax rates has not ;en to launch new expenditure programs, but rather to reduce ixes. The present proposed tax cuts illustrate this. Taxes e raised to pay for government programs; government ograms are not expanded just to spend increased tax venues. Automatic indexation by itself would lead to ither a smaller nor a larger government sector. Next, the argument is sometimes made that automatic dexing is desirable because Congress should not have to "be thered with" an inflation adjustment every year. It is ue that the automatic nature of indexation systems removes e need for frequent oversight by Congress, but this gument works both ways. The argument could be made equally 11, that encouraging the Congress to take a more frequent °k at what is happening to the tax system may in itself be -4lesirable. Also, even with indexation, Congress would have .0 adjust taxes downward periodically to offset the impact of ising real per capita incomes. The final argument, and one which I find very important, •oncerns the impact of automatic indexing on overall fiscal >olicy. Inflation represents an excess of purchasing power elative to the amount of goods and services available, and herefore tax increases are called for. Automatic indexation f the tax system, whatever its appeal on equity grounds, oves in the opposite direction. That is, under indexation, nflation would give rise not to tax increases but rather to ax cuts or at least, in real terms, no change in effective ax rates. Rather than give up its control over this aspect f fiscal policy, I feel the country would be better off if ongress continued with its existing ad hoc approach to tax ncreases and decreases. There have been occasions when we would have been better ff with an automatic tax reduction — 1974 or 1975 might ave been such occasions, given the increasing rate of nemployraent. But in general, if all we know about the conomy is that it has been experiencing inflation, economist ould generally prefer to have taxes going up rather than oing down. If the appropriate fiscal policy calls for a tax eduction, Congress can provide that reduction. ncome Measurement Let me now turn to the second and much more difficult ssue concerning indexation, that is, the definition of icome and specifically the measurement of real income from apital. Ideally, the base of the tax system should be real icome because that is the best measure of ability to pay. Lth reasonable price stability, nominal income provides a itisfactory approximation of real income, but under lflationary conditions, this is no longer the case. irticularly severe problems arise in four areas: jpreciation of fixed assets, inventory accounting, capital iins, and financed instruments. 'preciation Generally, fixed assets are depreciated on the basis of eir historical cost. It is easy to see that this is appropriate in a period of inflation because the dollar lue of depreciation allowances will be worth less, as time e s on, than the "real" value of the assets being used up. -5Unfortunately, while the problem is clear, the solution is not: there has been much controversy in recent years, both here and abroad, concerning the appropriate accounting for depreciation of fixed assets in a period of inflation. One possible approach would be to adjust depreciation for each asset based on replacement cost, which would involve calculating a separate price index for every kind of asset. Even aside from the great difficulties in adjusting for quality changes and technological innovations over time, it is clear that the sheer numbers and recordkeeping involved here would lead to a very cumbersome system. Moreover, such practice would allow real changes in relative values to escape taxation. Another possibility would be to index on the basis of some measure of the general price level. Such a measure would refer not just to the prices of capital assets, but would be a reflection of the value of the dollar in broader terms. Although current law does not contain an explicit depreciation adjustment to account for the effect of inflation, accelerated depreciation methods provide some offset for inflation. In fact, until the high inflation rates experienced in the last few years, the use of accelerated depreciation on an historical cost basis has generally meant higher depreciation deductions (and hence lower income taxes) than if the law permitted straight-line depreciation on a replacement cost basis. The Commerce Department has estimated the net effect of these adjustments (accelerated depreciation and replacement cost accounting) on Capital Consumption Allowances, which is the National Income and Product Account concept analogous to depreciation and amortization. For corporations, the net effect was positive (i.e. lower taxes) for the years 1962-1973, while for the years since 1974, it has been negative. That is, for the last few years of high inflation, replacement cost depreciation on a straight-line basis would have meant lower taxes, whereas for earlier years historic cost depreciation on an accelerated basis meant lower taxes. (For sole proprietorship and partnerships, the net effect has been Inventory Accounting lower taxes ever since 1946.) In the area of inventories, the current LIFO (Last In, First Out) system of accounting is in fact a form of inflation adjustment similar to replacement cost depreciation. However, some have argued that it would be more appropriate to require FIFO (First In, First Out) inventory accounting but to permit an adjustment to reflect -6the change in the general price level from the time the item was put in inventory until the time it was removed from inventory and sold. Such a system would be much more complex than the LIFO method. Capital Gains One of the clearest areas in which inflation has an impact is capital gains. If an asset's market value increases due solely to inflation, the holder of that asset has really experienced no increase in wealth, yet he is required to pay a capital gains tax on the difference between the original purchase price and the sales price. In fact, this impact of inflation has been one of the key arguments in defending the present favorable treatment which capital gains receive in our tax system. The present 50 percent exclusion feature does indeed provide an offset for inflationary gains. However, in any given case it is usually either too much or too little; only rarely would inflationary gains amount to exactly 50 percent of the total gain. The proper taxation of capital gains under inflation depends on the way financial instruments are handled, as we shall see below. Financial Instruments If an individual earns an interest rate of five percent on a $1,000 savings account, at the end of the year he would have $1,050. Suppose, however, the rate of inflation has been 7 percent over the course of the year. This means that at the end of the year the individual has not gained from his investment, but is actually worse off, for he has less purchasing power than he did at the beginning of the year. His $1,050 is actually worth only $981 in terms of beginning-year prices, and even though he is experiencing this $19 decline in real purchasing power, he must still include $50 in his taxable income, and when he withdraws his deposit, he will not be allowed a tax deduction for his loss of purchasing power. On the other hand, consider a debtor who is able to pay off his debt in deflated dollars: he actually benefits from inflation. Moreover, for tax purposes he may deduct all of }is interest payments—even those which merely reflect inflation. Thus, inflation produces both gainers and losers in terms of real income, and this asymmetry poses real Problems for any practical system of indexation. Suppose for example, I purchased an asset for $1,000 and financed it -7entirely by debt. Would I be helped or hurt by inflation? The answer is that if the holding period of the asset and the debt are the same, I have completely protected myself from the effects of inflation; any inflationary loss on the asset is exactly offset by a gain on the debt. Market Adjustments We generally speak of the changes in value resulting from inflation as if they were always unanticipated, but this is not really the case. No one, for example, thinks that the price level 12 months from now will be precisely where it is today—while we may not agree on an exact number, everyone anticipates some rise in prices, and lenders, as well as borrowers, take this into account in deciding the terms of a loan. If the real rate of interest, that is, the rate for stable prices, is three percent, lenders will not continue lending money at three percent when the rate of inflation is five percent—they will demand a higher rate of interest. How much higher, depends on the lender's tax rate, for he will try to maintain his after-tax rate of return. Suppose a lender's marginal tax rate is 50 percent; that means that under stable prices, his after-tax rate of return was 1-1/2 percent. If inflation now rises to five percent, he will seek to raise the before-tax rate not just to eight percent (i.e. three percent + five percent), but to 13 percent, because after he pays taxes on 13 percent he will have 6-1/2 percent left, which in real terms (substracting five percent for inflation) is the same as the 1-1/2 percent he was earning before inflation. Thus, in this case the market rate of interest would adjust so that no inflation adjustment would be necessary for the lender. What about the borrower? If he is in the same tax bracket, no adjustment is necessary for him, either. In the absence of inflation, he had to pay three percent, but this was a deductible expense on his tax return, so his after-tax, real cost was 1-1/2 percent. Now he has to pay 13 percent interest, but this, too, is deductible, so after-taxes he pays only 6-1/2 percent, and he is repaying the loan in depreciated dollars, so his real cost is again, 1-1/2 percent. To the extent that market rates of interest adjust for anticipated inflation, then, it would appear that no tax ad]ustment for debt instruments is necessary. There are three qualifications to this, however. First, creditors and -8debtors may not be in the same tax bracket, so any rise in the rate of interest will have certain redistributive effects between them. Second, many people feel that the market does not fully adjust, that there are always lags and other discrepancies among nominal rates of interest, real rates of interest, and the rate of inflation. Finally, for many creditors there are institutional barriers which prevent them from adjusting their rate of return in response to inflation. Specifically, we have laws setting limits on the rate of interest which may be paid on savings in banks and other financial institutions. In some recent years, these limits have been less than the rate of inflation, which means that savings account holders have been unable to adjust the rate of interest they earn, and therefore have suffered an actual loss in the value of their assets while at the same time they have been forced to pay income tax on their nominal interest receipts. In brief, there is currently no agreement among economists, accountants, or businessmen on just how an adjustment for financial instruments should be made. This uncertainty reflects both differences of opinion concerning how well the market adjusts rates of return to take account of inflation, and concern with the equity and practicality of handling inflation premiums. Some economists have argued that the interest deduction should be reduced by the amount of interest that is caused by inflation, i.e. the "inflation premium." This of course would require an estimate of how much of the current nominal rate of interest is "real" and how much is just an inflation premium. Others have suggested that the full interest deduction should be permitted and the full amount of interest income taxed, but at the time debt is paid off, a gain or loss should be recognized to the extent that the debt is paid off with deflated dollars. Financial Accounting Similarly, no consensus has yet emerged concerning the appropriate way of adjusting depreciation for inflation. The Securities and Exchange Commission has required on certain large companies to provide supplemental accounting information concerning the cost of replacing productive capacity. The approximate amount of depreciation, depletion, and amortization which would have been recorded under such a scheme provides a measure of replacement cost depreciation. Another proposal for adjusting accounting data for inflation was made, somewhat tentatively, by the Financial Accounting Standards Board. The aspect of that proposal -9which drew the most attention was the inclusion in net income of changes in the purchasing power of net holdings of monetary assets. This turned out to be quite controversial, and the FASB subsequently withdrew its proposals for further study. A study of the impact of indexed accounting for two groups of corporations was undertaken by Sidney Davidson of the University of Chicago and Roman Weil of the Georgia Institute of Technology. They recalculated the financial statements of the 30 firms included in the Dow Jones Industrial Average and the 24 utilities included in the Dow Jones Utility Average. All of the utilities would have had higher income and hence presumably higher taxes under the FASB proposed accounting rules, mainly because of the large amount of debt they owed. In the case of the industrial firms, 21 would have had lower taxes and nine would have had higher taxes. Thus indexation is not an unmixed blessing from the point of view of corporate taxpayers. It seems to us that until there exists a greater consensus within both the accounting profession and the business community concerning the best manner of adjusting financial and operating statements for inflation, it would be inappropriate for the Treasury Department to attempt to impose any particular "correct" method. Until the accounting profession has worked out the technical details of how to index income, and until the business community is prepared to use an indexed financial statement in reporting to their stockholders and creditors, Congress should not permit the business community to report to the Internal Revenue Service on an indexed basis. Conclusion What we can conclude from this review of indexation? As I stated at the outset, at rates of inflation above a certain level almost everyone would feel that indexation is desirable. I feel that our present and prospective inflation rates are not at that level. To introduce indexation into the tax system would mean substantially increasing the complexity of the present system, greatly increasing the recordkeeping requirements of individuals and firms, and naking fairly arbitrary decisions in many areas of income measurement in which no consensus has emerged to date from economists, accountants, or businessmen. Until we know more, it would be a mistake to proceed too rapidly. -10Comments on S. 2738 I have been asked to comment on bill S. 2738 which provides for indexation of certain provisions of the tax laws. This bill essentially calls for indexing the fixed dollar amounts defined in the tax code by adjusting them upwards at two-thirds of the percentage change in the Consumer Price Index. As I indicated in the first part of my testimony, this is a fairly straightforward form of adjustment and while it does mean the recalculating of a number of factors, it requires no action on the part of Congress or the executive each year in response to inflation. It does mean, however, that the amount of fiscal stimulus (in the form of tax cuts) provided each year will be determined by the rate of inflation in the previous year: the more inflation last year, the more stimulus this year. Moreover, it would make it more difficult for taxpayers to make accurate estimates of their tax liability and therefore make appropriate adjustments in their withholding rates. The bill goes will beyond this simple form of indexation, however, and provides for a basis increase for capital gains. This basis increase would apply only to capital assets; no provision is made for adjusting financial instruments. Thus, the proposal encounters the difficulty which I mentioned of discriminating between leveraged and unleveraged investors, and between those investors capable of converting income into a capital asset and those unable to. While a heavily-leveraged taxpayer would receive a significant windfall from such a provision, many persons relying on fixed incomes would be relatively disadvantaged. The savings account depositor is a prime example. Because his savings account interest rate is limited by law, he is not in a position to obtain a real interest rate sufficient to compensate for his inflationary losses. Moreover, a fixed security like a savings account cannot increase in market value the way an equity can. Thus, while the equity holder might experience a rise in market value for his equity, only a portion of which would be taxed away, the holder of a bank deposit would see no rise in the value of his account. He would still be required to pay taxes annually on the full amount of his nominal interest income while the owner of a capital asset could adjust his gain for inflation as well as postponing the tax on that adjusted gain until the asset is sold. Further, under S. 2738, only half of that real capital gain would be taxed at all! There is a patent inequity in a tax system that would insulate holders of real estate and stock from the impact of inflation while ignoring the plight of low income taxpayers who tend to hold savings accounts. -11Current law with respect to capital gains has demonstrated that taxpayers will strive to change an ordinary income transaction into, a form qualifying for preferential tax treatment.' An inflation adjustment for capital gains would place an even greater premium on such manipulative practices and open new avenues for tax gamesmanship. A clear example of this is the collapsible corporation, a device used for the conversion of ordinary business profits into capital gains. If an inflation adjustment is permitted with respect to stock, such collapsible corporations would retain substantial tax advantages unless a significant holding period were required before the inflation adjustment would go into effect. If we attempt to restrict the categories of assets eligible for inflation adjustments, we would exacerbate problems involving corporate tax shelters. In the event corporate stock is eligible for an inflation adjustment which is denied most other assets, there will be pressure to incorporate scores of non-preferred investments. For example, taxpayers might be motivated to incorporate savings accounts, jewelry, and antiques if the basis of those investments could not be adjusted independently. Another area of complexity in the tax law would have to be developed in order to prevent such abuses. Finally, providing an inflation adjustment for capital gains as proposed in S. 2738 would add to the complexity of computing taxable gains. Currently, the amount of gain in a transaction is generally determined without regard to the length of time an asset has been held, once the holding period is such as to qualify as "long-term." With an inflation adjustment mechanism such as S. 2738, however, the date of any change in bais becomes all important. Even in the simplest of transactions, a taxpayer will have to account for the date an asset was purchased as well as the amount paid for that asset, and this determination could create significant administrative problems in those instances where basis is carried over from one taxpayer to another or from one asset to another by transfer where no gain is recognized. Further, an investor adding to or withdrawing from his investment over time would have to calculate a separate inflation correction for each such action. In brief, without the introduction of a comprehensive scheme of indexation throughout the tax law, a basis adjustment for capital gains might violate the neutrality standard and add new economic distortions to the tax laws. During periods of high inflation, the savings of individuals -12and businesses would tend to flow increasingly into those investments eligible for an inflation adjustment and away from "non-adjustable" investments. Once an inflation adjustable asset had been selected as an investment, there would also be a tendency for the investor to maintain that investment longer than would be desirable in the absence of the inflation adjustment. There are many difficult conceptual as well as practical problems involved in correcting the measurement of income for the effects of inflation. Until we have made much more progress in this area, it would be a mistake to proceed in piecemeal fashion to provide an adjustment for only one form of income, namely, capital gains, while denying any adjustment for other, equally deserving, types of income which do not enjoy the preferential treatment already accorded capital gains. 0O0 partmentoftheTREASURY TELEPHONE 566-2041 HINGTON, D.C. 20220 April 24, 1978 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE RESULTS OF TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL AUCTIONS Tenders for $ 2,301 million of 13-week Treasury bills and for $3,406 million of 26-week Treasury bills, both series to be issued on April 27, 1978, were accepted at the Federal Reserve Banks and Treasury today. The details are as follows: RANGE OF ACCEPTED COMPETITIVE BIDS: Price High Low Average a/ Excepting b/ Excepting 1 26-week bills maturing October 26, 1978 13-week bills maturing July 27, 1978 Discount Rate Investment Rate 1/ 6.282% 6.47% 98.412 a/ 6.298% 6.49% 98.408 6.294% 6.48% 98.409 98.409 6.294% 6.48% 1 tender of $475,000 tender of $15,000 Price : Discount Rate Investment Rate 1/ 96.582b/ 6.761% 7.10% 7.12% 96.572 6.781% 96.574 6.777% 96.574 6.777% 7.11% Tenders at the low price for the 13-week bills were allotted 90%. Tenders at the low price for the 26-week bills were allotted 13%. TOTAL TENDERS RECEIVED AND ACCEPTED BY FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTS AND TREASURY: Location Received Boston $ 25,285,000 New York 4 ,214,315,000 25,760,000 Philadelphia Cleveland 32,255,000 Richmond 22,085,000 Atlanta 57,925,000 Chicago 375,620,000 St. Louis 45,310,000 29,760,000 Minneapolis 30,015,000' Kansas City Dallas 18,080,000 San Francisco 224,785,000 Treasury 11,535,000 TOTALS $5,112,730,000 Accepted :, Received $ 19,585,000 2,018,645,000 25,535,000 29,835,000 18,085,000 32,580,000 36,115,000 18,310,000 20,760,000 24,400,000 18,080,000 27,965,000 17,815,000 : $ : 4,757,445,000 8,070,000 : 15,630,000 : 58,225,000 :: 46,260,000 : 226,980,000 :: 39,415,000 :. 23,915,000 :: . 22,660,000 . 8,665,000 612,550,000 : $ 7,815,000 3,017,075,000 7,515,000 10,630,000 22,175,000 26,160,000 40,860,000 10,615,000 13,435,000 20,750,000 8,665,000 213,180,000 11,535,000 6,820,000 6,820,000 $2,301,430,000^/ $5,844,450,000 £/Includes $382,905,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. J Includes $179,355,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. 1/Equivalent coupon-issue yield. B-856 Accepted $3,405,695,000d/ FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 9:00 E.S.T. APRIL 25, 1978 STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE ROGER C. ALTMAN ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY (DOMESTIC FINANCE) BEFORE THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS SUBCOMMITTEE ON DOMESTIC MONETARY POLICY Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: I am pleased to respond to your request for the views of the Treasury Department on H.R. 7800, the Solar Energy Bank Act. My remarks will address the financial structure of the proposal from the standpoint of the Treasury's overall policies regarding Federal credit assistance programs. Other Administration witnesses will address the energy policy implications. The bill would create a new Federal instrumentality, the Solar Energy Development Bank, whose function would be to make long-term low interest loans to encourage the use of solar energy and insure adequate investment in new or improved solar technology. The proposed Bank would be authorized to make loans directly or through banks and other lending institutions, which would receive fees for their services. The loans would be made to organizations, corporations, partnerships, and individuals to purchase energy equipment and for other, solar energy-related purposes. Loans would be made at annual interest rates not to exceed 3 percent for periods not to exceed 30 years. At least sixty percent of the amounts authorized for loans would have to be used in residential dwellings. Loans for commercial buildings could not exceed $100,000 and loans for residential buildings could not exceed $7,500. Routine credit examinations of applicants would be required. B-857 2 All loans would be made from a Solar Energy Fund, which would be administered by the Secretary of the Treasury. Monies in the fund not needed for current operations could be invested in direct or guaranteed obligations of the United States Government or any Federal agency. Five billion dollars would be authorized to be appropriated to the fund initially. In this connection, the President indicated in his anti-inflation speech on April 11 that we must work to reduce the budget deficit. The proposed 3 percent loans could result in unintended and uncontrolled subsidies that would vary with changing credit market conditions, rather than with the needs of the borrowers. The subsidies would be greatest when market interest rates were at their highest, and would decline as market rates fell. The consequent volatility in the demand for loans would put the greatest pressure on financial and credit markets precisely when they were most strained and would impede the Government's overall financial policies. As an illustration, consider a $1,000, thirty year loan made at 3 percent when the cost of long-term funds to the government is at the current level of about 8k percent. The present value of the subsidy would be $439; thus, a fixed interest loan at 3 percent would be equivalent to a $561 "break-even" loan at the Treasury's cost of funds — %h percent — and a cash grant of $439. If the cost of funds to the government were to increase to 10 percent, the present value of the subsidy would be $519, over half the value of the loan. The bill would not require a finding that credit is not otherwise available at reasonable terms and conditions from private market sources. As a general principle, and to provide a built-in control over program growth, Federal credit programs should be designed to facilitate the flow of credit to those borrowers who are unable to obtain credit in the private market. The needs of more creditworthy borrowers should be met in the market without Federal credit aid. Such aid should be contingent on a requirement for evidence that borrowers cannot obtain credit from conventional lenders. thus helping to assure that the limited Federal funds available are directed to the areas of greatest need. 3 The bill contains no requiremert that the amount of each loan be less than the value of the equipment being financed. Nor would the bill require that the term of the loan be less than the economic life of the equipment being financed. Thus, the bill does not provide adequate protection of the financial interests of the Federal Government, and the bill could encourage excessive demands for loans and less efficient projects. In addition, the bill lacks restrictions concerning default procedures and other features common to Federal loan programs which would minimize the exposure of the Government to unnecessary risk and insure that Federal credit resources were being most effectively utilized. Finally, we are concerned with the provisions of the bill which, on the one hand, would provide the Bank with interest-free money from the Treasury but, on the other hand, would permit the Bank to invest any excess funds in interest-bearing obligations of the Government. This concludes my formal remarks. I would be pleased to respond to any questions you may have. 0 o 0 FOR RELEASE WHEN AUTHORIZED AT PRESS CONFERENCE April 26, 197 8 TREASURY MAY QUARTERLY FINANCING The Treasury will auction two securities in a total amount of $4,000 million, consisting of $2,500 million of 10-year notes and $1,500 million of 22-1/4-year bonds. The bonds will be an addition to bonds which are currently outstanding. The proceeds will be used toward the payoff of $5,884 million of publicly held securities maturing May 15, 1978. The balance of the maturing issues, $1,884 million, will be redeemed from the Treasury operating cash balance. The $5,884 million of maturing securities are those held by the public, including $746 million held, as of today, by Federal Reserve Banks as agents for foreign and international monetary authorities. In addition to the public holdings, Government accounts and Federal Reserve Banks, for their own accounts, hold $2,499 million of the maturing securities that may be refunded by issuing additional amounts of new securities. Additional amounts of the new securities may also be issued, for new cash only, to Federal Reserve Banks as agents for foreign and international monetary authorities. Details about each of the new securities are given in the attached "highlights" of the offering and in the official offering circulars. oOo Attachment H5* HIGHLIGHTS OF TREASURY OFFERINGS TO THE PUBLIC MAY 1978 FINANCING TO BE ISSUED MAY 15, 1978 Amount Offered: To the public Description of Security: Term and type of security Series and CUSIP designation Maturity date Call date Interest coupon rate Investment yield Premium or discount Interest payment dates Minimum denomination available Terms of Sale: Method of sale Accrued interest payable by investor Preferred allotment Deposit requirement , Deposit guarantee by designated institutions Key Dates: Deadline for receipt of tenders Settlement date (final payment due) a) cash or Federal funds b) check drawn on bank within FRB district where submitted c) check drawn on bank outside FRB district where submitted Delivery date for coupon securities. ... y $2,500 million 10-year notes Series A-1988 (CUSIP No. 912827 HS 4) May 15, 1988 No provision To be determined based on the average of accepted bids To be determined at auction To be determined after auction November 15 and May 15 $1,000 Yield Auction April 26, 1978 $1,500 million 22-1/4-year bonds 8-3/8% Bonds of 1995-2000 (CUSIP No. 912810 BV 9) August 15, 2000 August 15, 1995 8-3/8% To be determined at auction To be determined after auction August 15 and February 15 $1,000 Price Auction None Noncompetitive bid for $1,000,000 or less 5% of face amount Acceptable $20.59047 per $1,000 Noncompetitive bid for $1,000,000 or less 5% of face amount Acceptable Tuesday, May 2, 1978, by 1:30 p.m., EDST Monday, May 15, 1978 Wednesday, May 3, 1978, by 1:30 p.m., EDST Wednesday, May 10, 1978 Wednesday, May 10, 1978 Tuesday, May 9, 1978 Monday, May 15, 1978 Tuesday, May 9, 1978 Monday, May 15, 1978 Monday, May 15, 1978 FOR RELEASE AT 4:00 P.M. April 25, 1978 TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL OFFERING The Department of the Treasury, by this public notice, invites tenders for two series of Treasury bills totaling approximately $5,800 million, to be issued May 4, 1978. This offering will not provide new cash for the Treasury as the maturing bills are outstanding in the amount of $ 5,806 million. The two series offered are as follows: 91-day bills (to maturity date) for approximately $2,300 million, representing an additional amount of bills dated February 2, 1978, and to mature August 3, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 S5 6), originally issued in the amount of $3,505 million, the additional and original bills to be freely interchangeable. 182-day bills for approximately $3,500 million to be dated May 4, 1978, and to mature November 2, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 U2 0) . Both series of bills will be issued for cash and in exchange for Treasury bills maturing May 4, 1978. Federal Reserve Banks, for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities, presently hold $2,370 million of the maturing bills. These accounts may exchange bills they hold for the bills now being offered at the weighted average prices of accepted competitive tenders. The biJls will be issued on a discount basis under competitive and noncompetitive bidding, and at maturity their par amount will be payable without interest. Except for definitive bills in the $100,000 denomination, which will be available only to investors who are able to show that they are required by law or regulation to hold securities in physical form, both series of bills will be issued entirely in book-entry form in a minimum amount of $10,000 and in any higher $5,000 multiple, on the records either of the Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or of the Department of the Treasury. Tenders will be received at Federal Reserve Banks and Branches and at the Bureau of the Public Debt, Washington, 0. C. 20226, up to 1:30 p.m., Eastern Daylight Saving time, Monday, May 1, 1978. Form PD 4632-2 (for 26-week series) or Form PD 4632-3 (for 13-week series) should be used to submit tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the* Treasury. B-859 -2Each tender must be for a minimum of $10,000. Tenders over $10,000 must be in multiples of $5,000. In the case of competitive tenders the price offered must be expressed on the basis of 100, with not more than three decimals, e.g., 99.925. Fractions may not be used. Banking institutions and dealers who make primary markets in Government securities and report daily to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York their positions in and oorrowings on such securities may submit tenders for account of customers, if the names of the customers and the amount for each customer are furnished. Others are only permitted to submit tenders for their own account. Payment for the full par amount of the bills applied for must accompany all tenders submitted for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. A cash adjustment will be made on all accepted tenders for the difference between the par payment submitted and the actual issue price as determined in the auction. No deposit need accompany tenders from incorporated banks and trust companies and from responsible and recognized dealers in investment securities for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or for bills issued in bearer form, where authorized. A deposit of 2 percent of the par amount of the bills applied for must accompany tenders for such bills from others, unless an express guaranty of payment by an incorporated bank or trust company accompanies the tenders. Public announcement will be made by the Department of the Treasury of the amount and price range of accepted bids. Competitive bidders will be advised of the acceptance or rejection ol their tenders. The Secretary of the Treasury expressly reserves the right to accept or reject any or all tenders, in whole or in part, and the Secretary's action shall be final. Subject to these reservations, noncompetitive tenders for each issue for $500,000 or less without stated price from any one bidder will be accepted in full at the weighted average price (in three decimals) of accepted competitive bids for the respective issues. Settlement for accepted tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, and bills issued in bearer form must be made or completed at the Federal Reserve Bank or Branch or at the Bureau of the Public Debt on May 4, 1978, in cash or other immediately available funds or in Treasury bills maturing May 4, 1978. Cash adjustments will be made for differences between the par value of the maturing bills accepted in exchange and the issue price of the new bills. -3Under Sections 454(b) and 1221(5) of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954 the amount of discount at which these bills are sold is considered to accrue when the bills are sold, redeemed or otherwise disposed of, and the bills are excluded from consideration as capital assets. Accordingly, the owner of these bills (other than life insurance companies) must include in his or her Federal income tax return, as ordinary gain or loss, the difference between the price paid for the bills, whether on original issue or on subsequent purchase, and the amount actually received either upon sale or redemption at maturity during the taxable year for which the return is made. Department of the Treasury Circulars, No. 418 (current revision), Public Debt Series - Nos. 26-76 and 27-76, and this notice, prescribe the terms of these Treasury bills and govern the conditions of their issue. Copies of the circulars and tender forms may be obtained from any Federal Reserve Bank or Branch, or from the Bureau of the Public Debt. oOo FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 25, 1978 Contact: George G. Ross 202/566-2356 TREASURY RELEASES RESULTS OF A. S. HANSEN STUDY OF PENSION PLANS The Treasury Department today released the results of a study designed to assist in evaluating the impact of the Administration's proposal to change the present pension-social security integration rules in the Internal Revenue Code. Plans which relate private pension benefits or contri-^ butions to social security benefits or contributions are said to be "integrated." Under present law, it is possible for workers whose earnings are lower than the social security wage base to receive little or nothing from an integrated private plan. The study was conducted by A. S. Hansen, one of the largest actuarial firms in the country at the request of the Treasury. The Hansen firm undertook the study voluntarily in the public interest and at no cost to the government. A proposal included in the President's 1978 tax program would provide at least some benefits to those who now are not receiving any benefits, and would improve the benefits of other participants who are also affected by present integration rules. In large part, employees who would benefit most from the proposed change are low paid or moderately paid. The Administration's proposal generally is that plans can provide pensions based on pay in excess of the social security wage base no greater than 1.8 times the pensions based on pay below the social security wage base. Alternatively, the Administration's proposal will allow plans integrated by the social security offset method to use as a maximum offset the same portion of social security benefits as the portion of pay provided by the plan formula. For example, a plan could provide a pension of 50 percent of final average pay reduced by 50 percent of Social Security; or, 60 percent of final average pay reduced by 60 percent of Social Security. B-860 - 2 - The Hansen study finds that under the Administration's proposal, a large majority of the plans which are described as social security offset plans would meet the new rules without any plan adjustments, or additional costs. Under an offset plan an employer can now reduce the amount of the private pension benefit by as much as 83 1/3 percent of the social security benefit the employee receives. Only minor cost adjustments would be needed for some of the remaining offset plans which would not meet the proposed standard. These include offset plans which now provide benefits in the range of 40 percent to 45 percent of earnings offset by 50 percent of social security benefits. These plans, therefore, fall just short of the Administration's proposed standard for offset plans. In another type of integrated plan - the step-rate excess plan - the Hansen study finds that under the Administration's proposal, a large majority of such plans also would meet the proposed rules without any plan adjustments or additional cost. Here, too, only a nominal low cost adjustment would be needed in many of the remaining step-rate plans which would not meet the proposed rule. Under an excess plan, an employee can receive a pension up to 37 1/2 percent of compensation above a plan's integration level. Employees below that level need not receive any pension. In a step-rate excess plan, they do get some benefits. About one-fourth of the step-rate plans, and about onefifth of the offset plans would need more than a nominal adjustment to meet the proposed standard. Treasury interprets these results to indicate that the Administration's proposal would provide improved pension benefits for a significant number of workers without imposing widespread or disruptive revisions among existing defined benefit pension plans. A study is now being made of the cost impact on plans requiring change. The study comprises a survey and analysis that covers a large sample of pension plans on which the Hansen firm performs recurring annual valuations. About 1,200 plans are included in the study covering about 1,200,000 active participants. Hansen reports that practically all types of plans are included in the sample, and that the sample is representative of all plans serviced by the firm. However, there are no data as yet available to measure the degree to which the sample is representative of all plans in the country. - 3 - Since Hansen services a relatively small number of defined contribution plans and those usually in a consulting capacity, only defined benefit plans were included in the study and the data provided are for defined benefits plans only. A defined benefit plan may be described as one for which the monthly pension is determined by a formula usually involving the employee's pay and service. In a defined contribution plan, the benefit depends on the amount in the employee's account at retirement. The 1,200 plans included in the study are sorted into categories of: (1) non-integrated plans, (2) pure excess plans, (3) step-rate excess plans, and (4) Social Security offset plans. Two-thirds of the 1,200 plans in the Hansen study are integrated - these number 814. One-third are not - these number 38 6. The 814 integrated pension plans include 80 percent which are Social Security offset plans and 19 percent which are step-rate excess plans. Only 1 percent are pure excess plans. The Treasury also is obtaining results of an impact study of small plans which are typically money purchase or profit-sharing, and among which there is a large representation of pure excess plans. For further information, contact: Gabriel Rudney (Treasury) 202/566-5911 Thomas McSweeney (Treasury) Richard Keating (A. S. Hansen, Inc.) 202/566-864 7 312/234-3400 The Hansen study, "Analysis of Private Pensions Plans," is attached. o 0 o PRIVATE PENSION PLANS Number of Employees in Plan Under 10 Total Plans in Survey Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees 2. Non-Integrated Plans Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees 10 - 25 26 - 50 51 - 100 101 - 1000 Over 1000 Total I. 124 712 6 186 3,204 17 142 5,051 36 197 14,668 74 433 144,775 334 118 1,025,954 8,695 1,200 1,194,364 995 18 (15%) 108 (15%) 6 32 (17%) 608 (19%) 19 51 (36%) 1,836 (36%) 36 74 (38%) 5,846 (40%) 79 169 (39%) 54,925 (38%) 325 42 (36%) 453,492 (44%) 10,797 386 (32%) 516,815 (43%) % of 1 1,339 3. Integrated Plans Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees 106 (85%) 604 (85%) 6 154 (83%) 2,596 (81%) 17 91 (64%) 3,215 (64%) 35 123 (62%) 8,822 (60%) 72 264 (61%) 89,850 (62%) 340 76 (64%) 572,462 (56%) 7,532 814 (68%) 677,549 ( 5 7 % ) % of 1 820 A. Plans Integrating Under Proposed Rules (1.8) Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees 69 (65%) 429 (71%) 6 112(73%) 1,890(73%) 17 73 (80%) 2,685 (84%) 37 97 7,020 72 200 (76%) 66,144(74%) 63 (83%) 423,318 (74%) 6,719 614 (75%) 501,496 ( 7 5 % ) % of 3 950 B. Plans Not Integrating Under Proposed Rules Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees 37 (35%) 175 (29%) 5 42 (27%) 706 (27%) 17 18 (20%) 530(16%) 26 (21%) 1,802(20%) 64 (24%) 23,706 (26%) 370 13 (17%) 149,144(26%) 11,473 200 (25%) 176,053 ( 2 5 % ) % of 3 880 29 69 331 Types of Integrated Plans 4. Pure Excess Plans Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees 1 7 7 4 72 18 1 29 29 3 408 136 9 516 37 A. Plans Integrating Under Proposed Rules None B. Plans Not Integrating Under Proposed Rules 5. Step Rate Plans Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees Using 1.8 Ratio Test A . fj a n s Integrating Under Proposed Rules Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees B. Plans Not Integrating Under Proposed Rules Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees Using 2.0 Ratio Test A . Plans Integrating Under Proposed Rules Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees B. Plans Not Integrating Under Proposed Rules Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees 9 11 63 6 26 481 19 14 546 39 32 2,112 66 62 22,942 370 13 37,455 2,881 158 63,599 403 3 (27%) 15 (24%) 5 13 (50%) 247 (51%) 19 9 (64%) 351 (64%) 39 16 (50%) 1,120(53%) 70 44(71%) 14,608 (64%) 332 9 (69%) 22,023 (59%) 2,447 94 (59%) 38,364 ( 6 0 % ) % of 5 408 8 (73%) 48 (76%) 6 13 (50%) 234 (49%) 18 5 (36%) 195 (36%) 39^ 16 (50%) 992 (47%) 62 18 (29%) 8,334 (36%) 463 4 (31%) 15,432 (41%) 3,858 64 (41%) 25,235 (40%) % of 5 394 10 (91%) 60 (95%) 6 16 (62%) 304 (63%) 19 7 (50%) 280 (51%) 40 20 (63%) 1,380(65%) 69 55 (89%) 20,460 (89%) 372 11 (85%) 31,163(83%) 2,833 119(75%) 53,647 ( 8 4 % ) % of 5 451 1 ( 9%) 3 ( 5%) 3 10 (38%) 177 (37%) 18 7 (50%) 266 (49%) 38 12 (37%) 732 (35%) 61 7(11%) 2,482 (11%) 355 2 (15%) 6,292 (17%) 3,146 39 (25%) 9,952 ( 1 6 % ) % of 5 255 Hansen 6. Flat Dollar Offset Plans Number of Plans Number of Employees Average Number of Employees ANALYSIS OF PRIVATE PENSION PLANS Number of Employees in Plan Under 10 10 - 25 26-50 51 - 100 101 - 1000 29 172 6 26 402 15 12 432 36 10 706 71 8 1,808 226 Over 1000 1 5,945 5,945 no None B . Plans Not Integrating Under Proposed Rules Social Security Offset Plans Number of Plans N u m b e r of Employees Average Number of Employees 86 9,465 All A. Plans Integrating Under Proposed Rules 7. Total 65 362 6 98 1,641 17 64 2,208 35 81 6,004 74 191 64,692 339 62 529,062 8,533 561 603,969 1,077 A. Plans Integrating Under Proposed Rules N u m b e r of Plans N u m b e r of Employees Average Number of Employees 37 (57%) 222 (61%) 6 73 (74%) 1,241 (76%) 17 52 (81%) 1,872 (85%) 36 71 (88%) 5,254 (88%) 74 148 (77%) 49,728 (77%) 336 53 (85%) 395,350 (75%) 7,459 434 (77%) 453,667 ( 7 5 % ) % of 7 1,045 B. Plans Not Integrating Under Proposed Rules N u m b e r of Plans N u m b e r of Employees Average Number of Employees 28 (43%) 140 (39%) 5 25 (26%) 400 (24%) 16 12 (19%) 336 (15%) 28 10 (12%) 750 (12%) 75 43 (23%) 14,964(23%) 348 9 (15%) 133,712 (25%) 14,857 127 (23%) 150,302 (25%) % o f 7 1,183 The plans in the survey are those serviced by actuarial units in Atlanta, Dallas, N e w York City, and Lake Bluff, Illinois. These offices were chosen so as to provide geographic distribution. The plan formulas were analyzed to see if they fell into the integrated or non-integrated category. The integrated formulas were further examined to see if the plans — all of which satisfy present integration rules — would continue to satisfy the proposed rules. The plan characteristics and data shown are as of December 31, 1976 for the most part. Census dates for some of the plans are spread through the years 1976 and 1977. 13144-115-146 4/10/78 -2Hansen ppartmentoftheTREASURY TELEPHONE 566-2041 5H5HINGTON, D.C. 20220 April 26, 1978 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE RESULTS OF TREASURY'S 52-WEEK BILL AUCTION Tenders for $ 2,967 million of 52-week Treasury bills to be dated May 2, 1978, and to mature May 1, 1979, were accepted at the Federal Reserve Banks and Treasury today. The details are as follows: RANGE OF ACCEPTED COMPETITIVE BIDS: Price High Low Average - Discount Rate 92.883 7.039% 92.828 7.093% 92.849 7.072% Investment Rate (Equivalent Coupon-Issue Yield) 7.54% 7.60% 7.58% Tenders at the low price were allotted TOTAL TENDERS RECEIVED AND ACCEPTED BY FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTS AND TREASURY: Received Location Boston New York Philadelphia Cleveland Richmond Atlanta Chicago St. Louis Minneapolis Kansas City Dallas San Francisco Treasury Accepted $ 12,280,000 $ 12,280,000 3,868,575,000 2,539,475,000 8,365,000 8,365,000 49,230,000 40,550,000 50,455,000 34,455,000 10,690,000 KL32SL 00052-WEEK BILL RATES DATE HIGHEST SINCE TOTAL April 26, 1978 LAST MONTH Q.J77 % The $2,967 million < noncompetitive tenders fr Federal Reserve Banks fo international monetary a LOWEST SINCE TODAY An additional $ 55 Reserve Banks as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities for new cash. * * * * * * * * T e Treasur a A •1 o y lso wants to announce that the weekly bill offering of April 25 reported that Federal Reserve Banks, for themselves and as agents ot foreign and international monetary authorities hold $2,370 million Mrs 5 a t U r 5 n 8 b i l l s > which are eligible in exchange for the bills to be auctioned uonaay, May 1._. JU**- ssrrect amount held by those accounts is $3,236 million. B:861 lepartmentoftheTREASURY TELEPHONE 566-2041 HINGTON, D.C. 20220 April 26, 1978 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE RESULTS OF TREASURY'S 52-WEEK BILL AUCTION Tenders for $ 2,967 million of 52-week Treasury bills to be dated May 2, 1978, and to mature May 1, 1979, were accepted at the Federal Reserve Banks and Treasury today. The details are as follows: RANGE OF ACCEPTED COMPETITIVE BIDS: Price High Low Average - Discount Rate 92.883 7.039% 92.828 7.093% 92.849 7.072% Investment Rate (Equivalent Coupon-Issue Yield) 7. 7. 7. Tenders at the low price were allotted TOTAL TENDERS RECEIVED AND ACCEPTED BY FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTS AND TREASURY: Location Received Accepted Boston New York Philadelphia Cleveland Richmond Atlanta Chicago St. Louis Minneapolis Kansas City Dallas San Francisco Treasury $ 12,280,000 3,868,575,000 8,365,000 49,230,000 50,455,000 10,690,000 242,510,000 32,045,000 21,890,000 17,990,000 3,130,000 317,925,000 2,675,000 $ 12,280,000 2,539,475,000 8,365,000 40,550,000 34,455,000 10,520,000 123,510,000 16,045,000 21,890,000 10,990,000 3,130,000 142,925,000 2,675,000 TOTAL $4,637,760,000 $2,966,810,000 The $2,967 million of accepted tenders includes $ 77 million of noncompetitive tenders from the public and $ 1,208 million of tenders from Federal Reserve Banks for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities accepted at the average price. An additional $ 55 million of the bills will be issued to Federal Reserve Banks as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities for new cash. * * * * * * * * The Treasury also wants to announce that the weekly bill offering of April 25 reported that Federal Reserve Banks, for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities hold $2,370 million of maturing bills, which are eligible in exchange for the bills to be auctioned Monday, May 1. The correct amount held by those accounts is $3,236 million B-86* FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 25, 1978 REMARKS BY THE HONORABLE C. FRED BERGSTEN ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS BEFORE THE ASIAN DEVELOPMENT SACK'S ELEVENTH ANNUAL MEETING VIENNA, AUSTRIA Mr. Chairman, President Yoshida, Distinguished Delegates, Ladies and Gentlemen: It is a great pleasure for me to be in Vienna today to address the governors of the Asian Development Bank on the occasion of this Eleventh Annual Meeting. I would particularly like to thank our hosts for this meeting, Vice Chancellor Androsch and the Austrian Government for their warm hospitality. The charm and beauty of Vienna are an inspiration to all of us. The United States strongly supports the Asian Development Bank. We view it as an important contributor to development in Asia, and as a focal point for cooperation in the region. We are delighted with the opportunity provided by this meeting to continue our efforts in support of the Bank. I join my fellow governors in welcoming the Republic of Maldives as the Bank's forty-third member. I would also like to extend special recognition to Mr. C. S. Krishna Moorthi, who recently retired from the Vice Presidency of the ADB. His unceasing efforts in behalf of the Asian Development Bank, which date from the Bank's beginnings, are well known to all those assembled here today. I would like to wish Mr. Krishna Moorthi every success in his future endeavors. His contributions to making the Asian Development Bank an effective force for economic development will not soon be forgotten. At the same time, I would like to congratulate and extend our warmest greetings to Mr. Bambawale and Mr. Katz, the two new Vice Presidents of the Bank. The World Economic Outlook The success of our joint efforts in the Asian Development Bank and ^cind are deeply affected by developments in the' world economy: rates of economic growth and inflation, levels of unemployment, international monetary stability. Each of these issues is of critical importance to the prospects of th§ member countries of the Bank, particularly its developing member B-862 countries. - 2 - I would like to address briefly our view on each of these issues, and report to you on the efforts of the United States to contribute to their improvement. There are numerous encouraging signs for the global economy in 1978. We expect somewhat faster real growth this year than last, both within the OECD area and among developing countries. Within the OECD, we believe that real growth outside the United States will be about one percent faster than in 1977. Japan, in particular, is making a noteworthy and laudable effort to expand its economy more rapidly. In addition, substantial progress has been made in reducing rates of inflation. Disparities in inflation rates among countries are being reduced. There has been considerable success in improving the distribution of current account imbalances, though some large surpluses and deficits still remain. At the same time, unemployment rates and inflation remain too high throughout the world. Some payments imbalances are still too large. Stability needs to be maintained in the exchange markets. But our outlook is one of cautious optimism, and a belief that the global economic picture is improving in both the industrialized and developing worlds. U. S. Policy The United States has embarked on a comprehensive effort to promote such an outcome, as part of our effort to assist the developing nations as well as to meet our broader responsibilities for the effective functioning of the world economy. The first requirement is a strong United States economy, which is the foundation of all our commitments in the international arena. Currently, the United States is growing faster than most other industrial countries. We achieved a growth rate of 5.7 percent in the last quarter of 1977, while the industrial production of our major trading partners fell, and grew at a rate of 4.9 percent for the year as a whole. We expect a growth rate of 4.5 to 5 percent in 1978, and a further reduction in unemployment from the late 1977 level of 6.5 percent to 5.7 percent toward the end of 1978. At the same time, we are experiencing greater success than most countries in holding inflation under control. The United States fully recognizes that the stability of the international monetary system rests heavily on a stable dollarIt is our clear, and clearly stated, view that a strong and stable dollar is in the interest of the United States, as well as the interest of the world economy and the developing countries including those in Asia. - 3- Such stability can be achieved only by dealing with the fundamental economic situation. We are doing so. On April 11, President Carter made clear the priority we attach to the fight against inflation. He announced that, if Congress did not quickly pass meaningful energy legislation, he would move to limit oil imports by administrative action. He announced that we will be taking a series of actions designed to enable U. S. business to compete more effectively in world markets. We are thus working on strengthening each of the underlying economic conditions in the United States needed to support the dollar — a reduction of our oil imports, a reduction in our rate of inflation, and a greater export effort. In the meanwhile, we have taken a number of bridging actions, including exchange market intervention, for the purpose of countering disorderly conditions in those markets. I am confident that by dealing with the fundamentals, and by our bridging actions, we will restore stability to the exchange markets and thereby provide a sound financial basis for ongoing prosperity in the world economy. We are also pursuing our commitment to an efficiently functioning system of world payments by giving strong support to the Witteveen Facility in the IMF. Legislation authorizing U. S. participation in the Facility has been enacted by the U. S. House of Representatives, and we are hopeful that final legislative action will be completed in the near future. Once in place, the Witteveen Facility will help assure that adequate official financing is available to deficit countries — developed and developing alike — during the years ahead. In the trade area, we are determined to continue to resist the imposition of new barriers to imports — particularly from developing countries. In every case that has come before him, President Carter has rejected proposals for comprehensive import controls. Indeed, we are seeking further reductions of existing barriers through the multilateral trade negotiations (MTN). We will continue to offer to developing countries the largest, most open market in the world. This is of critical importance to those developing Asian economies which have so successfully followed strategies of exported growth. We fully intend to preserve an open world economy in which their outward-looking development strategies -- and similar strategies by other countries -can prosper and succeed. Commodity policy is another area in which the United States has sought to be highly responsive to the problems of the developing countries. We understand their concern over excessive price fluctuations and resultant disruptions in foreign exchange earnings, domestic investment and employment. We support the Principle of stabilizing prices around market trends, and believe - 4 - that it is in our own national economic interest to do so wherever feasible. Thus we have participated in, or expressed a willingness to examine participation in, international commodity arrangements covering sugar, coffee, cocoa, tin, rubber and copper. Some of these commodities are of particular importance to developing countries in Asia, and we look forward to continuing to work with them in this area in pursuit of our common economic goals. Our bilateral development assistance has risen substantially. For the developing countries of Asia, it has risen sharply from $266 million in FY 1977 to a requested $470 million for FY 1979. Asia's share has risen from 31 percent of the total in 1977 to 37 percent in 1979. In addition, we are providing approximately $1 billion in food aid for Asian developing countries. U. S. Policy Toward the International Development Banks Our support for the International Development Banks also clearly manifests United States concern for the aspirations and strivings of the developing countries. United States supoort for the Banks, which has become a centerpiece of our foreign assistance effort, extends back over one-third of a century. From the original Breton Woods plan for an international bank for reconstruction and development to the recent creation of the Asian and African Development Funds, the United States has steadfastly promoted the principle of multilateralism in foreign assistance. We are proud of our record of sustained support, and we pledge our continued support for this principle. In 1977, the Carter Administration obtained Congressional support for over $2.3 billion for the development banks — supplemental appropriations of $396 million for FY 1977 and $1,925 million for FY 1978. This represents a dramatic increase — more than a tripling — of the $745 million appropriated in 1976. For this fiscal year, the Administration submitted to Congress a request for the largest yearly appropriation in history for the international development banks — $3.5 billion. We believe that these actions clearly indicate the major efforts of our nation to carry out its responsibilities to the poor people of the world. Indeed, these actions are based on our judgment that the banks, with their corps of highly professional development experts, have become extremely effective instruments for development — translating assistance from donor countries into sound development programs for recipient countries. To assure efficient utilization of their loans, the banks promote sound economic policies which serve to generate substantial private resource flows as well. Largely unencumbered by narrow political factors, the development banks have been able to devote their energies - 5 - and resources to the central task at hand — effective development. At the same time, the banks multilateralize the foreign assistance effort and thus ensure fair burdensharing among donor countries in the pursuit of world development. Within the tenets of multilateralism, the United States — like all other member countries — has a responsibility to seek to ensure that the development banks remain responsive to new directions in development policy. To this end, we have encouraged the development banks to pay close attention to the technology employed in their loan projects so that the resulting resource utilization reflects underlying factor availabilities. We have encouraged the banks to target project benefits so as to better aid the most disadvantaged of a country's population. We have urged that the sector distribution of lending be modified to focus the banks' resources more on meeting basic human needs. Basic infrastructure projects traditionally financed by the banks should of course continue to be supported, as they have recognized expertise in these fields which should continue to be employed. We are, however, seeking a reshaping of sectoral priorities to better address the needs of the poor without neglecting the key infrastructure areas. I am pleased to note the extent to which the Asian Development Bank has already moved to focus its lending program on these "growth with equity" concerns, as stressed yesterday by President Yoshida. Finally, we seek to incorporate concern for human rights into the activities of the development banks. We believe that the goals and purposes of the banks must encompass a broad range of fundamental concerns, including human rights as well as freedom from economic privation land want. We seek to cooperate with all members in finding ways to best advance the common commitment to human rights and meeting human needs, while at the same time ensuring the integrity and effectiveness of the multilateral process. This is a substantial list of concerns. B\jt we see it as a legitimate expression of, our responsibilities within a multilateral framework. Multilateralism does not imply abdication of responsibility to voice concern, or to express preferences. Constructive proposals and suggestions from member nations are necessary ingredients of effective international action. We intend to continue to exercise that responsibility. The Asian Development Bank The Asian Development Bank draws together into one effort perhaps the most varied group of developing nations in any region. Its developing members include some of the most dynamic and fastest growing countries in the world. Korea, The Republic of China, Singapore, Hong Kong and Malaysia all experienced growth in real GNP greater than 7#5 percent in 1977. They have - 6 - become effective competitors for a wide range of products in international trade. These countries have all exhibited impressive flexibility in adapting to the new parameters of the international economy. They are clearly among the most advanced developing countries in the world. At the same time, the bank's membership includes countries heavily dependent upon agricultural and raw material exports. These countries found their progress slowed in 1977 by sluggish growth in world trade and output. The Philippines Thailand, Pakistan and Bangladesh all experienced reduced rates of growth. Indeed, economic growth failed to match population growth in Pakistan and Bangladesh. Along with Nepal, Burma, Sri Lanka and Afghanistan, these countries face some of the most pressing and difficult development problems in the world. Finally, the bank includes among its membership a number of small island economies, from Tonga and the Cook Island? to Western Samoa and the Gilbert Islands — countries which face their own unique set of development problems. This diversity in the bank's developing country membership represents both a challenge and an opportunity. No one development strategy, no single project preparation technique, no one set of lending terms nor single sector focus will be adequate to meet the varied needs of such a diverse group of countries. The bank must maintain a high degree of flexibility and adaptability if it is to respond effectively to the diversified problems of development it confronts. The United States has strongly supported the Asian Development Bank from its beginning. Growing out of a pledge made by President Johnson in his April 1965 speech at Johns Hopkins University, the United States actively participated in the creation of the Bank — and I had the personal privilege of participating, as a member of the U. S. delegation, at the charter signing ceremonies in Manila in December 1965. As one of the initial charter signatories, the United States joined with Japan in subscribing the largest shares to the original capital mobilization of the Bank — a position which we intend to maintain. In addition, the United States has been the second largest contributor, next to Japan, to the Bank's concessional loan window, the Asian Development Fund. We and other developed member countries have in fact just completed negotiations for the second replenishment of the Asian Development Fund. I am pleased to announce that the United States will be joining the other donor countries in a substantial replenishment of the Fund's resources, which will enable the Bank to greatly expand the its concessional next four years. lending to its poorest member countries over - 7 The United States pledges $445 million to the replenishment, subject to authorization and appropriation by the U. S. Congress, thereby maintaining our agreed ADF share of 22.25 percent of the basic replenishment target of $2.0 billion. This substantial increase,, from our pledge of $180 million to the first replenishment of the -fund, reaffirms our support for the Fund's activities and our desire to see some of the additional concessional resources directed toward the marginally eligible countries of Indonesia, Thailand and the Philippines for projects meeting basic human needs. The pledge has been approved personally by President Carter, and has been made after extensive consultations with our Congress which have reaffirmed the widespread support.throughout our government for the activities of the ADB. I would like to add the deep satisfaction which we take from the widespread support of other donor countries for ADF III. We believe that these expressions of confidence in the Fund, and in its management by the Bank, are fully justified — and bode well for the future of our joint efforts for Asian Development. This replenishment of the Asian Fund draws attention to the Bank's recent efforts to recast and reshape its priorities, by placing greater emphasis on meeting basic human needs and on reaching the poorest people in the developing member countries. We approve of the greater emphasis given to agriculture and agro-industry. We applaud the critical analysis that is presently underway, on the basis of the findings of the banksponsored second Asian agricultural survey, to modify existing practices of project design and project implementation. We believe that the Bank can increase its effectiveness in coping with the hardcore poverty problems found in developing member countries by incorporating a greater emphasis on off-farm employment, on appropriate technology and on targeting benefits to the marginal farmer and landless laborer — recommendations highlighted in the survey. In other sectors as well, the Bank is demonstrating creative adaptability. We especially applaud the initiatives taken in the energy field. The Bank's recent power projects — which emphasize improved efficiency for existing power systems and the use of indigenous resources such as hydro, thermal and coal — are examples of admirable responsiveness to changing conditions and the needs of developing member countries. These projects, and the example they set, have great importance both for the recipients and for the world energy balance. I would also like to commend the Bank for its sound financial and administrative policies. We supported the recent increase in the Bank's commitment charge to 0.75 percent. The Bank's prudent budget policies are well known, and deserve support from all member countries. - 8 - The United States supports the Bank's expressed interest in devoting greater attention to sub-regional development cooperation, in the South Pacific and through the Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN). We support this development and hope that, in addition to the feasibility studies for ASEAN industrial projects already planned by the ADB, the Bank can continue to work closely with ASEAN in future project financing. This can be done both from the Bank's owri resources and through co-financing from other sources. We would also encourage the Bank to do more to involve the private sector in its activities. The Bank should make lending to private, small-scale industry an increasingly important focus of its industrial development program. Such industries are generally labor-intensive, and thus create more jobs per dollar invested than do larger enterprises; they also strengthen private entrepreneurial skills and allow greater scope for the utilization of light capital technology. Finally, we encourage the Bank to expand its efforts in private sector co-financing. We think the Bank's maturity and reputation make it more feasible to do so now than at any time in the past. As yet, the Bank has preferred to co-finance with national public sector entities or inter-v national institutions. Public sector co-financing should continue to be encouraged, and we would especially like to see more OPEC co-financing with the ADB. But private sector co-financing is also a fertile and promising area. For the Bank to maximize its contribution as a catalyst for development finance, this type of cooperation should be actively explored. Conclusion In conclusion, I want to re-emphasize the firm commitment of the United States to the Asian Development Bank and Fund. We are proud that the United States played an important role in creating the Bank, and has helped it become an effective instrument of development. Over the next decade, the Bank will play an increasinglv important role in the economic development of the Asia-Pacific region—a region of great importance to the world economy, and of great importance to the United States. The Bank's management and staff, as well as the member countries, deserve considerable praise for the Bank's record to date. The United States is gratified to be a part of this endeavor. I am sure it will warrant our continued and growing support in the years ahead. FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE April 27, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY DEPARTMENT FINDS VISCOSE RAYON STAPLE FIBER FROM BELGIUM IS SOLD HERE AT LESS THAN FAIR VALUE The Treasury Department said today that viscose rayon staple fiber from Belgium is being sold in the United States at less than fair value. Sales at less than fair value, as defined by the Antidumping Act, generally occur when imported merchandise is sold in the United States at prices below those in the home market. Interested persons were offered the opportunity to present oral and written views before this determination. The case is being referred to the U. S. International Trade Commission (ITC), which must decide within 90 days whether any U. S. industry is being, or is likely to be, injured by these sales. If the ITC's decision is affirmative, dumping duties will be assessed on all imports of this merchandise from Belgium. Notice of this action will appear in the Federal Register of May 1, 1978. Imports of viscose rayon staple fiber from Belgium were valued at approximately $1.4 million in 1977. o B-863 0 o FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 1, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY ANNOUNCES COUNTERVAILING DUTY INVESTIGATION OF IMPORTS OF NON-RUBBER FOOTWEAR FROM INDIA The Treasury Department today announced an investigation to determine whether the Government of India is subsidizing exports of non-rubber footwear. The investigation results from a petition filed on behalf of domestic interests. The Countervailing Duty Law requires that the Secretary of the Treasury collect an additional duty that equals the size of the "bounty or grant" (subsidy) paid on the exportation or manufacture of merchandise imported into the United States. A preliminary determination in this case must be made not later than September 10, 197 8, and a final determination no later than March 10, 1979. Notice of this action will appear in the Federal Register on May 2, 1978. Imports of non-rubber footwear from India amounted to approximately $9.2 million during calendar year 1977. o B-864 0 o partmentoftheTREASURY TELEPHONE 566-2041 SHINGTON, D.C. 20220 May 1, 1978 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE RESULTS OF TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL AUCTIONS Tenders for $ 2,300 million of 13-week Treasury bills and for $3,507 million of 26-week Treasury bills, both series to be issued on May 4, 1978, were accepted at the Federal Reserve Banks and Treasury today. The details are as follows: RANGE OF ACCEPTED 13-week bills COMPETITIVE BIDS: maturing August 3, 1978 High Low Average a/ Excepting 1 Price Discount Rate 98.377a/ 98.365 98.367 6.421% 6.468% 6.460% 26-week bills maturing November 2, 1978 Investment Rate 1/ Price 6.62% 6.67% 6.66% Discount Rate 96.512 96.490 96.494 6.899% 6.943% 6.935% Investment Rate 1/ 7.25% 7.30% 7.29% tender of $500,000 Tenders at the low price for the 13-week bills were allotted 65%. Tenders at the low price for the 26-week bills were allotted 31%. TOTAL TENDERS RECEIVED AND ACCEPTED BY FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTSAND TREASURY: Location Received Boston $ 25,640,000 New York 3 ,916,405,000 Philadelphia 39,430,000 Cleveland 41,375,000 Richmond 34,765,000 Atlanta 33,955,000 Chicago 371,355,000 St. Louis 49,200,000 Minneapolis 20,475,000 Kansas City 39,040,000 Dallas 17,740,000 San Francisco 172,060,000 Treasury 9,785,000 TOTALS $4,771,225,000 Accepted :: Received Accepted $ 25,640,000 1,899,185,000 38,800,000 41,375,000 30,065,000 31,765,000 60,605,000 22,200,000 19,425,000 35,135,000 17,740,000 68,315,000 :•$ 14,340,000 :: 5,256,340,000 19,020,000 :: 68,515,000 : 19,525,000 :: 28,585,000 : 419,675,000 : : 41,115,000 : 22,535,000, :: 32,935,000 :: 9,395,000 :: 237,635,000 :; $ 9,340,000 3,242,650,000 19,020,000 25,065,000 19,525,000 23,485,000 31,775,000 13,115,000 18,465,000 32,935,000 9,395,000 52,735,000 9,290,000 9,290,000 $2,300,035,000b/: $6,178,905,000 $3,506,795,000 9,785,000 :: /Includes $ 374,335,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. i/Includes $188,980,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. /Equivalent coupon-issue yield •865 TREASURY WAIVES COUNTERVAILING DUTIES AGAINST HANDBAGS IMPORTED FROM COLOMBIA The Treasury Department today determined that the Government of Colombia subsidizes exports of handbags to the United States but waived imposition of countervailing duties. Treasury's decision to waive was based on steps taken by the handbag exporters to phase out the export subsidy. Under the Countervailing Duty Law, the Secretary of the Treasury is required to impose an additional duty equal to a "bounty or grant" paid on the imported merchandise in question. In the handbag investigation, Treasury found that Colombian handbag exporters benefit from bounties in the form of tax certificates, known as "CATS," that are paid on the value of the exported handbag. Under the waiver provision of the Countervailing Duty Law, the Treasury Secretary can waive assessment of countervailing duties until no later than January 4, 1979, if the following criteria have been satisfied: (1) Adequate steps have been taken to reduce of eliminate the adverse effect of the bounty or grant; (2) There is a reasonable prospect that trade agreements will be reached with other foreign countries that will reduce or eliminate barriers or distortions to international trade; and (3) To countervail in this situation would seriously jeopardize the trade negotiations. Treasury decided to waive countervailing duties after the Colombian manufacturers/exporters agreed to give up that portion of the subsidy found to be countervailable. A 50-percent reduction of the bounty is to take place immediately, followed by its total elimination by January 1, 1979. In addition, the Colombian manufacturers have promised not to market their handbag exports aggressively to the United States. Some $6 million in handbags were imported from Colombia to the United States during 1977. Notice of this action will be published in the Federal Register of May 2, 1978. B-866 o 0 o FOR RELEASE AT 4:00 P.M. Ma Y 2/ 1978 TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL OFFERING The Department of the Treasury, by this public notice, invites tenders for two series of Treasury bills totaling approximately $5,700 million, to be issued May 11, 1978. This offering will not provide new cash for the Treasury as the maturing bills are outstanding in the amount of $5,717 million. The two series offered are as follows: 91-day bills (to maturity date) for approximately $2,300 million, representing an additional amount of bills dated February 9, 1978, and to mature August 10, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 S6 4), originally issued in the amount of $3,504 million, the additional and original bills to be freely interchangeable. 182-day bills for approximately $3,400 million to be dated May 11, 1978, and to mature November 9, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 U3 8) . Both series of bills will be issued for cash and in exchange for Treasury bills maturing May 11, 1978. Federal Reserve Banks, for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities, presently hold $2,972 million of the maturing bills. These accounts may exchange bills they hold for the bills now being offered at the weighted average prices of accepted competitive tenders. The bills will be issued on a discount basis under competitive and noncompetitive bidding, and at maturity their par amount will be payable without interest. Except for definitive bills in the $100,000 denomination, which will be available only to investors who are able to show that they are required by law or regulation to hold securities in physical form, both series of bills will be issued entirely in book-entry form in a minimum amount of $10,000 and in any higher $5,000 multiple, on the records either of the Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or of the Department of the Treasury. Tenders will be received at Federal Reserve Banks and Branches and at the Bureau of the Public Debt, Washington, 0. C. 20226, up to 1:30 p.m., Eastern Daylight Saving time, Monday, May 8, 1978. Form PD 4632-2 (for 26-week series) or Form PD 4632-3 (for 13-week series) should be used to submit tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. B-867 -2Each tender must be for a minimum of $10,000. Tenders over $10,000 must be in multiples of $5,000. In the case of competitive tenders the price offered must be expressed on the basis of 100, with not more than three decimals, e.g., 99.925. Fractions may not be used. Banking institutions and dealers who make primary markets in Government securities and report daily to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York their positions in and Dorrowings on such securities may submit tenders for account of customers, if the names of the customers and the amount for each customer are furnished. Others are only permitted to submit tenders for their own account. Payment for the full par amount of the bills applied for must accompany all tenders submitted for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. A cash adjustment will be made on all accepted tenders for the difference between the par payment submitted and the actual issue price as determined in the auction. No deposit need accompany tenders from incorporated banks and trust companies and from responsible and recognized dealers in investment securities for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or for bills issued in bearer form, where authorized. A deposit of 2 percent of the par amount of the bills applied for must accompany tenders for such bills from others, unless an express guaranty of payment by an incorporated bank or trust company accompanies the tenders. Public announcement will be made by the Department of the Treasury of the amount and price range of accepted bids. Competitive bidders will be advised of the acceptance or rejection of their tenders. The Secretary of the Treasury expressly reserves the right to accept or reject any or all tenders, in whole or in part, and the Secretary's action shall be final. Subject to these reservations, noncompetitive tenders for each issue for $500,000 or less without stated price from any one bidder will be accepted in full at the weighted average price (in three decimals) of accepted competitive bids for the respective issues. Settlement for accepted tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, and bills issued in bearer form must be made or completed at the Federal Reserve Bank or Branch or at the Bureau of the Public Debt on May 11, 1978, in cash or other immediately available funds or in Treasury bills maturing May 11, 1978. Cash adjustments will be made for differences between the par value of the maturing bills accepted in exchange and the issue price of the new bills. -3Under Sections 454(b) and 1221(5) of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954 the amount of discount at which these bills are sold is considered to accrue when the bills are sold, redeemed or otherwise disposed of, and the bills are excluded from consideration as capital assets. Accordingly, the owner of these bills (other than life insurance companies) must include in his or her Federal income tax return, as ordinary gain or loss, the difference between the price paid for the bills, whether on original issue or on subsequent purchase, and the amount actually received either upon sale or redemption at maturity during the taxable year for which the return is made. Department of the Treasury Circulars, No. 418 (current revision), Public Debt Series - Nos. 26-76 and 27-76, and this notice, prescribe the terms of these Treasury bills and govern the conditions of their issue. Copies of the circulars and tender forms may be obtained from any Federal Reserve Bank or Branch, or from the Bureau of the Public Debt. oOo FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 2, 1978 RESULTS OF AUCTION OF 10-YEAR NOTES The Department of the Treasury has accepted $2,502 million of $5,017 million of tenders received from the public for the 10-year notes, Series A-1988, auctioned today. The range of accepted competitive bids was as follows: Lowest yield 8.26% 1/ Highest yield Average yield 8.30% 8.29% The interest rate on the notes will be 8-1/4%. At the 8-1/4% rate, the above yields result in the following prices: Low-yield price 99.933 High-yield price Average-yield price 99.665 99.732 The $2,502 million of accepted tenders includes $ 585 million of noncompetitive tenders and $1,918 million of competitive tenders (including 33% of the amount of notes bid for at the high yield) from private investors. In addition, $1,600 million of tenders were accepted at the average price from Government accounts and Federal Reserve Banks for their own account in exchange for securities maturing May 15, 1978. 1/ Excepting 7 tenders totaling $446,000 B-868 FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY May 3, 1978 - 9:20 PDST STATEMENT BY THE HONORABLE RICHARD J. DAVIS ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY AT THE 35TH ANNUAL CONVENTION OF THE WINE AND SPIRITS WHOLESALERS OF AMERICA LAS VEGAS, NEVADA When I received the invitation to address you I wondered whether I really should accept. I must confess that it is not wholly consistent with my self-image to fly to Las Vegas, with all its glamour, in order to make a speech. But on reflection, I decided that it was important that I accept. I was concerned that there was confusion as to what was transpiring in Washington. It was time, therefore, that communications stopped taking place by rumor. It was time that you stopped learning about ideas by leaks — leaks which are often imcomplete and inaccurate. I, therefore, decided to accept your invitation and to speak directly to a topic I believe is of interest to all of us: "Liquor Regulations: Current Issues and Future Options." There are many matters being considered in Washington which will affect all of us. Regulatory reform, ingredient labelling, health warnings and wine labelling: all are issues about which you are concerned; all are issues which affect the American public at large. My goal here today is not to announce decisions on any of these issues. None have yet been made. Each alone is probably sufficiently intricate to warrant more discussion than the time alloted to me here. Rather, my hope B-869 - 2 - is to provide you with some insight about our perspective and t highlight some of the issues which must be addressed in the months ahead. Probably the most significant long-range issue confronting us today is regulatory reform: should changes be made in the manner in which the liquor industry is regulated? Should changes be made in the substance of those regulations, both those imposed by statute and those the result of agency rules? I cannot answer these questions today with any precision. I can, however, say that they plainly require serious study and resolution. This has been clear to me from the day I assumed my responsibilities last summer. It was revealed by the multitude of liquor related issues described in the briefing book given me on the day I arrived. It was accented by a mere reading of the Federal Alcohol Administration Act and some of the relevant regulations. The volume of regulation and control — covering trade practice rules, production methods, advertising, labelling, tax collection and so on — impressed me then. It continues to impress me as various issues reach my desk on a regular basis. Another thing struck me immediately in addition to the complexity of the regulatory requirements — the apparent competition among regulatory agencies. FDA, FTC, ATF, whatever their initials, they all appeared to have a regulatory claim over you. And their assertions of authority, it was clear, were not always coordinated. - 3This then is what I perceived when I surveyed the situation: an agency — ATF — working hard to administer a detailed and complex regulatory scheme; the appearance of jurisdictional jealousies; and a regulatory scheme based on a statute passed 43 years ago as we emerged from Prohibition. The need for careful study of the liquor regulatory scheme was clear. And that is what we are doing. Now, I have already said that our study has not yet produced any answers. What I would like to share with you is some of the underlying conceptions which will contribute to those answers. I do not think you will find these conceptions particularly novel; they are also plainly easier to recite in a speech than to implement in practice. I hope, however, that they will assist you in understanding our goals. The first underlying premise is that simplicity is a critical goal of any scheme. When I was a trial lawyer, I used to observe some of my colleagues develop highly ingenious theories of proof, which involved the use of detailed and complex evidence. Such theories worked well in the office: they generally failed in the courtroom. Their complexity made them unintelligible to the jury, and thus unpersuasive to them. So, too, with regulatory schemes. What is imaginative and logical in the office may fail in real life. As the language of regulation becomes more detailed and complex, - 4 inconsistancy and confusion are likely to follow. The result will soon be that a system that ceases to be understandable to the regulated, or helpful to the consumer. Simplicity is thus an essential — though admittedly highly illusive — goal. Our second premise is that destructive competition among enforcement and regulatory agencies is bad. I say this so often that some of my colleagues in Washington, I think, are tired of hearing me use this refrain. But as a prosecutor I have observed the impact of this kind of competition first hand it is not beneficial to anyone; it causes investigations to be more difficult; and causes a loss in necessary public confidenc So, too, with the regulatory world — destructive competition helps no one, neither the regulated nor the consumer. If destructive competition is bad, how are we to avoid it? As a general matter, we try to do so simply by coordinating our efforts where we have overlapping responsibilities. It is important also, however, that the lines of responsibility be drawn as clearly as possible. For us this means looking at the responsibilities of various agencies — ATF, FTC, FDA and the Justice Department — and seeing if the lines of authority really are clear. Now as you know, this raises a significant issue. There is one school of thought which believes that liquor is not a special commodity; that FDA, the FTC and the Justice Department should exercise fully their responsibilitie over this industry; that there is no need for a single agency dedicated solely to liquor. Others feel equally as strongly that the opposite is true. mm 5 - This is obviously a core issue. From any perspective one of the strongest arguments in favor of continuing the single agency concept is the dedicated manner in which the men and women of ATF have carried out their responsibilities and the expertise concerning the liquor industry which they have, as a group, developed. We certainly should not recommend a change in the single agency concept unless we were convinced it would mean real improvement. In any event, it will be important no matter what specifically is proposed, or not proposed, that ultimately responsibility, and thus accountability, for all aspects of regulatory enforcement is as clearly defined as possible. The third underlying premise is the need to develop a better definition of criminality as it applies to conduct in the liquor industry. We are increasing our reliance on the criminal sanction in appropriate cases, particularly where there is no voluntary disclosure. And, as you know, the Federal Alcohol Administration Act makes a wide variety of conduct criminal, but only slightly criminal. That is, those who violate many of its provisions may be called criminals, but the potential jail sentences are virtually non-existant. This, I believe, leaves all in an uncomfortable position. The notion that particular conduct is criminal is a serious one: we should not lightly ascribe this characterization to particular acts. It should be reserved for conduct that society truely intends to condemn. We should recognize also - 6 that the criminal sanction is not the only alternative for a government seeking to regulate conduct. Civil penalties, license suspensions, and injunctive relief: all can be effective enforcement tools. Thus, one key thing that must be considered is to review the conduct now proscribed by the FAA; to define that which is really criminal and to provide real criminal penalties for that conduct and define that which is not and for it provide other sanctions. Finally, any analysis of this question must have one additional underlying premise: a recognition of the unique history of liquor as a product. It is the only product banned by one constitutional amendment, and allowed by another. It is a product which produces for various levels of government an extraordinary amount of revenue; yet it is a product which also has always been understood to have important health implications for those who overuse it. While it is not clear whether all these qualities have specific logical significance, it is clear that it is part of the reality of understanding your industry, and its concerns, as well as the concerns of the public. The issues of regulatory reform are not simple. Their resolution will involve examining regulations we have issued, as well as the underlying statutes. That will take time. There is no certainty that it will be decided to make major proposals. - 7At the same time, however, issues exist which must be decided under the existing framework. What, for example, should we do about the various labelling issues? I would like to spend a few minutes describing what we view as some of the considerations involved in an analysis of these issues. Labelling is undoubtedly one of those regulatory issues which always seems to be with us. We are struggling with some aspects of it right now. How should one address such issues? Plainly there are a variety of factors present. They often point in opposite directions. All, however, must be considered and balanced. First, the value of the proposal must be analyzed — will it assist the consumer, will it avoid deception, will it deter some questionable processing. Regulation can provide a positive benefit to society. It can, however, be an unnecessary burden when it becomes an end itself. Both of these truisms must be remembered. Second, the cost of any proposal must be considered. We recognize that by adding to industry's costs, we inevitably are adding to the prices we all must pay. While the cry of increased cost cannot be allowed to become a claim that defeats all proposals, it is one that plainly cannot be ignored. And it must be considered at two levels — in determining whether to impose a requirement and, also, how any requirement should - 8 be implemented. We sometimes forget that if we put in the effort and remain flexible, regulations can be designed in a way to minimize their cost while still accomplishing basic goals. Third, and finally, we must consider the appropriateness of imposing particular requirements. This issue has legal aspects; it also has highly philosophical implications. There are many different views as to the appropriateness of governme intervention in private conduct. It is, I believe, important to assure that our citizens have adequate information to make reasonable choices in the consumer market. At the same time there plainly is some point at which a requirement becomes too detailed, too intrusive. We undoubtedly will not always agree when that point has been reached. It is important that decision makers, however, always remember that such a limit exists as they wrestle with particular issues. These then are some of the issues confronting us. Issues of regulatory reform are never simple. Those involving the determination of appropriate requirements always involve honest conflicts. One thing, I hope is clear. We understand that wisdom does not reside in Washington alone. Policy — if it is to be both wise and workable — must be the product of many minds and many ideas. On all the issues I have discussed today — and those others that may arise — we want your views? - 9 we want the views of other interested individuals and groups, both business and consumer. We cannot always agree with everyone. Hopefully, however, by learning all we can and trying to act rationally, we can minimize our mistakes and improve the quality of what we try to do. 0O0 rOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY Expected at 10 AM Wednesday, May 3, 1978 STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE ROBERT CARSWELL DEPUTY SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON UNEMPLOYMENT COMPENSATION, REVENUE SHARING & ECONOMIC PROBLEMS OF THE SENATE COMMITTEE ON FINANCE ir. Chairman and members of this distinguished Committee: I welcome this opportunity to present the Administration's Dill for a Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program, S.2975. This Drogram is an essential element of the President's recently announced policy for distressed areas and is aimed at alleviating fiscal distress of local governments throughout the Nation. The program is the product of careful study by the Administration over the course of the past year. It is intended ;o succeed the Anti-Recession Fiscal Assistance program (often Jailed countercyclical revenue sharing or ARFA), which expires on September 30. The Administration recommends that Supplementary Fiscal issistance (SFA) be authorized for two years, with approximately »1 billion of outlays in both fiscal 1979 and fiscal 1980. The '•1.04 billion already included in the President's fiscal 1979 'Udget for countercyclical revenue sharing, would be applied to •his program. The Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program preserves the asic concept of targeting the distribution of funds which nderlies countercyclical revenue sharing. Targeting means, of ourse, that a relatively higher proportion of total funds would e provided to those governments which suffer the greatest istress. In addition, the eligibility test for SFA allocations ould be based on broader measures of economic need than were mployed in the ARFA targeting formula. We believe these easures will permit fairer treatment for a number of urban and ural governments for which unemployment is not an adequate easure of distress. -870 -2The program would also be funded at higher levels than would countercyclical revenue sharing were it continued under its present formula which provides that no funds can be distributed following a quarter in which the national unemployment rate is at 6 percent or below. Unemployment is already near 6 percent and we estimate that the national economic recovery will have proceeded to the point during the first half of fiscal 1979, where the rate will fall to 6 percent. As a result, substantially less than $1.04 billion would be available under the countercyclical revenue sharing program during fiscal 1979, were it simply extended in its present form. In addition, local governments would be uncertain of the amount of funds they would receive were the countercyclical program so extended. ORIGIN OF THE PROGRAM The Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program reflects months of intensive study by the Administration, primarily at the Treasury, of the fiscal condition of State and local governments and the fiscal impact of certain Federal programs on those governments. The Treasury analyzed the effects of President Carter's 1977 Economic Stimulus Program, including Anti-Recession Fiscal Assistance, on local fiscal conditions. That study was nade available to the Congress in January. Fiscal Distress, Need for Supplementary Assistance and Targeting The Treasury study devised a fiscal strain index which determined which of the 48 largest municipal governments in the Jnited States — those governments for which the Bureau of the Census maintains the most complete statistical information — should be considered high, moderate or low strained cities. A lumber of these governments were found to be in a serious state 5f fiscal distress. Their local tax rates were at legal or economic limits, and thus tax revenues could not be meaningfully •ncreased in the immediate future. Moreover, despite efforts to Jut their budgets, these governments experienced inflationary pressures which were driving local expenditures higher. Subsequent research has demonstrated that the same combination of stagnant revenues and inflation-driven expenditures is also >ressuring many rural governments. The study showed that the more seriously strained local overnments received a proportionately greater share of ountercyclical payments and concluded that such governments ould not easily offset the loss of such payments. For example, he ten most severely strained of our largest municipalities were btaining ARFA funds representing between approximately 2 percent ^d 7.5 percent of their so-called "own-source" revenues. Loss i these funds would mean that these localities would have to md alternative revenue sources or cut back essential services. -3Theoretically, if ARFA funds were discontinued, governments could raise taxes or cut expenses to replace them. Unfortunately, neither of these alternatives is readily available to distressed local governments. Accordingly, the Administration decided to recommend continued fiscal assistance to distressed local governments which have not enjoyed the benefits of the Nation's improved general economic condition. The proportionately greater distribution of ARFA funds to the most severly strained large urban governments, indicated that countercyclical revenue sharing was well targeted for relief of fiscal strain in urban areas. Further examination of available data led us to conclude, however, that the allocation formula used in the countercyclical program did not fully measure economic distress in all areas. Hence we modified the formula for the Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program to include three additional measures of economic distress — relative growth of employment, of per capita income and of population. Let me discuss briefly these measures of distress. The Selection of Eligibility Criteria as Measures of Distress Countercyclical revenue sharing distributed funds based on local unemployment rates exceeding 4.5 percent. The Treasury study indicated this was a good measure of urban secular economic distress, reflecting declines in employment, lower assessable base growth, and higher tax burdens. Moreover, it was determined that the unemployment rate served as a proxy of a local government's social welfare burden. Unemployment rates are also readily available on a current bases. For these reasons, the Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program retains the use of local unemployment rates and measures them against a 4.5 percent base to provide a link with the existing distribution pattern under ARFA. The local rate of growth in employment has been included in the SFA formula because it is a good indicator of the long term -rend of the local economy. As local economies expand, employment opportunities increase. Employment growth may give a setter indication of economic conditions in certain urban and *ural areas than unemployment rates since these areas generally suffer more from underemployment than unemployment. Also, employment growth appears to be a better indicator of the Potential growth of local government revenues. We have also included the local rate of growth in per capita JIcoroe in the SFA formula because it is a good measure of the jrowth in taxable wealth and the level of economic activity. The local rate of growth in population is also considered a !ood indicator of a community's future economic health by l easuring its ability to attract new taxpayers. -4The Congressional Budget Office used similar criteria — growth in population, per capita income and earnings which is a proxy for employment -- to measure local economic distress in its report, Troubled Local Economies. Similar indicators were also used in the Brookings Institution's "Hardship Index" which is now part of HUD's Community Development Block Grant formula. The Urban Institute's "Economic and Fiscal Indicators Project" addressed the question of how shifts in a city's economic base effect the revenue-expenditure balance by analyzing components of such base as measured through its population, employment and income. We checked the results of our new targeting formula and found that the formula targets assistance to those governments which are the most fiscally distressed. THE PROGRAM Let me now describe how the Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program would work. The program would authorize the distribution of $1.04 billion in fiscal year 1979 and $1.00 billion in fiscal year 1980. Eligible local governments would receive 98.7 percent Df the total funds. The share of each local government would be determined by a formula designed to reflect the level of its distress relative to the other eligible local governments. The remainder of the funds would be distributed to the Commonwealth Df Puerto Rico, Guam, American Samoa, the Virgin Islands, which in aggregate would receive one percent of total SFA distributions, and the Indian Tribes and Alaskan native villages. State governments would not be eligible to receive SFA funds under the Administration's proposal because our studies indicate that, as a group, State governments are not fiscally strained at present. Most State governments are currently in ;ood fiscal condition with many states planning tax decreases luring the next fiscal year. Moreover, the major State revenue sources, sales and income taxes, are more responsive to -mprovements in the national economy than the predominant local avenue source, property taxes. Accordingly, as the economy has .mproved, State revenues have increased at a faster rate than .ocal revenues. For the purpose of test determinations under SFA, local governments are divided into two categories — those wholly or >artly within a Standard Metropolitan Statistical Area (SMSA) and •hose entirely outside a SMSA. Because of techniques used to ather and categorize general employment and unemployment data, eparation into SMSA and non-SMSA groups minimizes measurement iscrepancies among members of each group and permits governments 'ithin each group to be treated more fairly. -5Only eligible local governments would receive SFA funds. The eligibility test is a statistical test based on the most recent data available to the Departments of Commerce and Labor prior to the beginning of each Federal fiscal year. For a local government to be eligible, it must have an unemployment rate in excess of 4.5 percent or exhibit slower than average growth in two of the three following categories: employment, per capita income and population. The local unemployment rate is to be determined on a four calendar quarter basis while local growth rates for employment, per capita income and population are to be determined by comparing data for the present year with a base er period five or six year. However, shorter periods for the latt_ three measurements may be used if the required data is available Dnly for such shorter periods. The local growth rates for employment are likely to be determined initially with a four year Dase period. The Bureau of Labor Statistics has announced that Improved unemployment and employment data will be available in June. We would, of course, use this data for SFA purposes and, accordingly, any current estimates should be viewed as )reliminary. Once a local government is determined to be eligible, its allocation is determined by a formula which is designed to n eflect the relative fiscal distress of the local government. The formula is detailed in Exhibit 1 to my testimony. As you can see, it is complex and merits your careful review. I would like ;o describe briefly the general way in which it works. The factor in the formula which reflects the relative fiscal strain of a particular government is determined by that economic .ndicator -- rate of unemployment, growth in employment, growth .n per capita income or growth in population — which shows the 5reatest relative severity of distress. This factor is then adjusted to reflect the population and per capita income of, and *ax effort being made by, each eligible government based on 'igures developed under the General Revenue Sharing program. The distribution formula constructed in this manner would etermine each government's share of total funds. To avoid xcessive administrative burdens, no distributions will be made o governments which would receive less than $200 annually. No local government could receive more money under the upplementary Fiscal Assistance program than the amount it eceived under countercyclical revenue sharing during the twelve onths through April, 1978. This cap was established to avoid ^creasing the dependence of local governments on supplementary ederal fiscal assistance. There is no limit on the amount of unds allocated to local governments which did not receive ARFA unds during the most recent twelve months. Limiting these funds ould preclude the advantages of more equitable distributions articularly to those areas whose level of fiscal distress was °t accurately reflected under the countercyclical targeting ormula. -6Both the eligibility of, and allocation of funds to, each local government is to be determined during the September preceeding each Federal fiscal year. This will eliminate the uncertainty governments now face under the countercyclical program which makes these determinations quarterly and leaves governments uncertain of the amounts they will receive during the full year. SFA payments, however, will be made quarterly to permit more efficient cash management. Recipient governments may use SFA funds as part of their general revenue. We have eliminated certain restrictions on the use and timing of expenditures to permit more efficient use of funds at the discretion of recipients. S.2975 also contains nondiscrimination, auditing, labor, and reporting requirements and provides withholding and rulemaking powers similar to those in the Anti-Recession Fiscal Assistance legislation. The general enforcement rights under ARFA have also been retained. Estimated Allocation of Supplementary Fiscal Assistance As I stated earlier, we checked our modified distribution formula to make certain that it targeted distributions to distressed local governments at least as well as the countercyclical formula. We have also compared the Supplementary 7 iscal Assistance formula with other alternative formulas. Our preliminary estimates show that during fiscal 1979 approximately twenty-six thousand (26,000) governments would receive funds under SFA. During the most recent four quarters of ARFA, twenty-four thousand (24,000) local governments were eligible recipients. This increase in the number of eligible recipients is the intended result of adding new eligibility criteria to our formula to include local governments, both in urban and rural areas, whose long term economic problems were not adequately neasured under countercyclical revenue sharing. Of the 26,000 eligible recipients under SFA, about 5,000 did not receive money Jnder the countercyclical program during the most recent twelve nonths. Despite the addition of new recipients, the allocation of >FA funds will be targeted to the most distressed governments. A •umber of governments which receive ARFA funds have become lealthier and have falling unemployment rates. In effect, because they now will receive less or even nothing, funds are Teed up for new entrants into the program. In addition, the new •ntrants generally have small budgets. Although the amount of 'unds received will be important to them, the funds will be a wall part of total distributions. The most distressed recipients of countercyclical revenue •oaring will still receive proportionately greater funds under p A. We estimate that approximately 23 percent of SFA 1979 -7disbursements would be received by the ten cities which ranked highest — meaning most distressed -- on the fiscal strain index contained in our January report. Only 11 percent of the disbursements would be received by the other 38 large municipal governments included in our study. In short, the Administration's program would be well targeted because those who are neediest would receive the largest amounts. Exhibit 2 to my testimony illustrates this conclusion. CONCLUSION As you know, this fiscal assistance program constitutes a very important part of the President's program for distressed areas. The financial health of local governments depends primarily on their economies. The Carter Administration has recommended several proposals to assist distressed areas and will be working with the Congress to implement a program that will foster the development of these economies across the Nation. We believe local governments in distressed areas will need Supplementary Fiscal Assistance until a broader economic redevelopment program is fully established. It is our hope that this effort will reduce the need for Supplementary Fiscal Assistance in the future. Obviously, this process will take time. In the meanwhile, the Administration's Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program is a necessary and critical part of our efforts to strengthen and assist local areas which have not shared fully in the Nation's general economic recovery. We have purposefully designed this program to bridge the two years remaining until the expiration of General Revenue Sharing in 1980, when the results of a zero based review of general Federal assistance will have been completed by the Administration. On the )asis of that review and an evaluation of the effects of other aspects of the President's fiscal and economic programs, we expect -o present recommendations to the Congress in 1980 on the future of ^oth SFA and GRS. I appreciate this opportunity to present the Administration's Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program. I look forward to forking with you and the other members of Congress to implement the urogram. oOOo wwMoftheTREASURY TELEPHONE 566-2041 HlfrHlNGTON, D.C. 20220 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 3, 1978 RESULTS OF AUCTION OF 22-1/4-YEAR TREASURY BONDS AND SUMMARY RESULTS OF MAY FINANCING The Department of the Treasury has accepted $1,500 million of the $3,100 million of tenders received from the public for the 22-1/4-year 8-3/8% Bonds of 1995-2000, auctioned today. The range of accepted competitive bids was as follows: . „. _ , A Approximate Yield To First Callable To Price Date Maturity High Low Average - 99.23 1/ 98.91 99.02 8.46% 8.49% 8.48% 8.45% 8.48% 8.47% The $ 1,500 million of accepted tenders includes $170 million of noncompetitive tenders and $1,330 million of competitive tenders (including 38% of the amount of bonds bid for at the low price) from private investors. In addition, $895 million of tenders were accepted at the average price from Government accounts and Federal Reserve Banks for their own account in exchange for securities maturing May 15, 1978. 1/ Excepting 2 tenders totaling $19,000 SUMMARY RESULTS OF MAY FINANCING Through the sale of the two issues offered in the May financing, the Treasury paid off approximately $1.9 billion of the $8.4 billion of securities maturing May 15, 1978. The following table summarizes the results: New Offerings 8-1/4% Notes 5-15-88 8-3/8% Bonds 8-15-19952 00 o Nonrnarketable Special Issues Maturing Securities Total Held Net Pav-off Pa ^ ott ^blic $2.5 $1.5 - $4.0 $5.9 $1.9 Government Accounts and Federal Reserve Banks Foreign Accounts for Cash 1.6 .9 _ - TOTAL $4.1 $2.4 - $6.5 $8.4 $1.9 Details may not add to total due to rounding. B-871 2.5 2.5 _-_ - FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY Expected at 9:30 AM Thursday, May 4, 1978 STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE ROBERT CARSWELL DEPUTY SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON INTERGOVERNMENTAL RELATIONS AND HUMAN RESOURCES OF THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON GOVERNMENT OPERATIONS Mr. Chairman and members of this distinguished Committee: I welcome this opportunity to present the Administrations bill for a Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program, H.R.12293• This program is an essential element of the President's recently announced policy for distressed areas and is aimed at alleviating fiscal distress of local governments throughout the Nation. The program is the product of careful study by the Administration over the course of the past year. It is intended to succeed the Anti-Recession Fiscal Assistance program (often called countercyclical revenue sharing or ARFA), which expires on September 30. The Administration recommends that Supplementary Fiscal Assistance (SFA) be authorized for two years, with approximately $1 billion of outlays in both fiscal 1979 and fiscal 1980. The $1.04 billion already included in the President's fiscal 1979 budget for countercyclical revenue sharing, would be applied to this program. The Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program preserves the basic concept of targeting the distribution of funds which underlies countercyclical revenue sharing. Targeting means, of course, that a relatively higher proportion of total funds would be provided to those governments which suffer the greatest distress. In addition, the eligibility test for SFA allocations would be based on broader measures of economic need than were employed in the ARFA targeting formula. We believe these measures will permit fairer treatment for a number of urban and rural governments for which unemployment is not an adequate measure of distress. B-872 -2The program would also be funded at higher levels than would countercyclical revenue sharing were it continued under its present formula which provides that no funds can be distributed following a quarter in which the national unemployment rate is at 6 percent or below. Unemployment is already near 6 percent and we estimate that the national economic recovery will have proceeded to the point during the first half of fiscal 1979, where the rate will fall to 6 percent. As a result, substantially less than $1.04 billion would be available under the countercyclical revenue sharing program during fiscal 1979, were it simply extended in its present form. In addition, local governments would be uncertain of the amount of funds they would receive were the countercyclical program so extended. ORIGIN OF THE PROGRAM The Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program reflects months of intensive study by the Administration, primarily at the Treasury, of the fiscal condition of State and local governments and the fiscal impact of certain Federal programs on those governments. The Treasury analyzed the effects of President Carter's 1977 Economic Stimulus Program, including Anti-Recession Fiscal Assistance, on local fiscal conditions. That study was made available to the Congress in January. Fiscal Distress, Need for Supplementary Assistance and Targeting The Treasury study devised a fiscal strain index which determined which of the 48 largest municipal governments in the United States -- those governments for which the Bureau of the Census maintains the most complete statistical information — should be considered high, moderate or low strained cities. A number of these governments were found to be in a serious state of fiscal distress. Their local tax rates were at legal or economic limits, and thus tax revenues could not be meaningfully increased in the immediate future. Moreover, despite efforts to cut their budgets, these governments experienced inflationary pressures which were driving local expenditures higher. Subsequent research has demonstrated that the same combination of stagnant revenues and inflation-driven expenditures is also pressuring many rural governments. The study showed that the more seriously strained local governments received a proportionately greater share of countercyclical payments and concluded that such governments could not easily offset the loss of such payments. For example, the ten most severely strained of our largest municipalities were obtaining ARFA funds representing between approximately 2 percent and 7.5 percent of their so-called "own-source" revenues. Loss of these funds would mean that these localities would have to find alternative revenue sources or cut back essential services. -3Theoretically, if ARFA funds were discontinued, governments could raise taxes or cut expenses to replace them. Unfortunately, neither of these alternatives is readily available to distressed local governments. Accordingly, the Administration decided to recommend continued fiscal assistance to distressed local governments which have not enjoyed the benefits of the Nation's improved general economic condition. The proportionately greater distribution of ARFA funds to the most severly strained large urban governments, indicated that countercyclical revenue sharing was well targeted for relief of fiscal strain in urban areas. Further examination of available data led us to conclude, however, that the allocation formula used in the countercyclical program did not fully measure economic distress in all areas. Hence we modified the formula for the Supplementary'Fiscal Assistance program to include three additional measures of economic distress — relative growth of employment, of per capita income and of population. Let me discuss briefly these measures of distress. The Selection of Eligibility Criteria as Measures of Distress Countercyclical revenue sharing distributed funds based on local unemployment rates exceeding 4.5 percent. The Treasury study indicated this was a good measure of urban secular economic distress, reflecting declines in employment, lower assessable base growth, and higher tax burdens. Moreover, it was determined that the unemployment rate served as a proxy of a local government's social welfare burden. Unemployment rates are also readily available on a current bases. For these reasons, the Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program retains the use of local unemployment rates and measures them against a 4.5 percent base to provide a link with the existing distribution pattern under ARFA. The local rate of growth in employment has been included in the SFA formula because it is a good indicator of the long term trend of the local economy. As local economies expand, employment opportunities increase. Employment growth may give a better indication of economic conditions in certain urban and rural areas than unemployment rates since these areas generally suffer more from underemployment than unemployment. Also, employment growth appears to be a better indicator of the potential growth of local government revenues. We have also included the local rate of growth in per capita income in the SFA formula because it is a good measure of the growth in taxable wealth and the level of economic activity. The local rate of growth in population is also considered a good indicator of a community's future economic health by measuring its ability to attract new taxpayers. -4The Congressional Budget Office used similar criteria — growth in population, per capita income and earnings which is a proxy for employment -- to measure local economic distress in its report, Troubled Local Economies. Similar indicators were also used in the Brookings Institution's "Hardship Index" which is now part of HUD's Community Development Block Grant formula. The Urban Institute's "Economic and Fiscal Indicators Project" addressed the question of how shifts in a city's economic base effect the revenue-expenditure balance by analyzing components of such base as measured through its population, employment and income. We checked the results of our new targeting formula and found that the formula targets assistance to those governments which are the most fiscally distressed. THE PROGRAM Let me now describe how the Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program would work. The program would authorize the distribution of $1.04 billion in fiscal year 1979 and $1.00 billion in fiscal year 1980. Eligible local governments would receive 98.7 percent of the total funds. The share of each local government would be determined by a formula designed to reflect the level of its distress relative to the other eligible local governments. The remainder of the funds would be distributed to the Commonwealth of Puerto Rico, Guam, American Samoa, the Virgin Islands, which in aggregate would receive one percent of total SFA distributions, and the Indian Tribes and Alaskan native villages. State governments would not be eligible to receive SFA funds under the Administration's proposal because our studies indicate that, as a group, State governments are not fiscally strained at present. Most State governments are currently in good fiscal condition with many states planning tax decreases during the next fiscal year. Moreover, the major State revenue sources, sales and income taxes, are more responsive to improvements in the national economy than the predominant local revenue source, property taxes. Accordingly, as the economy has improved, State revenues have increased at a faster rate than local revenues. For the purpose of test determinations under SFA, local governments are divided into two categories — those wholly or partly within a Standard Metropolitan Statistical Area (SMSA) and those entirely outside a SMSA. Because of techniques used to gather and categorize general employment and unemployment data, separation into SMSA and non-SMSA groups minimizes measurement discrepancies among members of each group and permits governments within each group to be treated more fairly. -5Only eligible local governments would receive SFA funds. The eligibility test is a statistical test based on the most recent data available to the Departments of Commerce and Labor prior to the beginning of each Federal fiscal year. For a local government to be eligible, it must have an unemployment rate in excess of 4.5 percent or exhibit slower than average growth in two of the three following categories: employment, per capita income and population. The local unemployment rate is to be determined on a four calendar quarter basis while local growth rates for employment, per capita income and population are to be determined by comparing data for the present year with a base period five or six year. However, shorter periods for the latter three measurements may be used if the required data is available only for such shorter, periods. The local growth rates for employment are likely to be determined initially with a four year base period. The Bureau of Labor Statistics has announced that improved unemployment and employment data will be available in June. We would, of course, use this data for SFA purposes and, accordingly, any current estimates should be viewed as preliminary. Once a local government is determined to be eligible, its allocation is determined by a formula which is designed to reflect the relative fiscal distress of the local government. The formula is detailed in Exhibit 1 to my testimony. As you can see, it is complex and merits your careful review. I would like to describe briefly the general way in which it works. The factor in the formula which reflects the relative fiscal strain of a particular government is determined by that economic indicator -- rate of unemployment, growth in employment, growth m per capita income or growth in population -- which shows the greatest relative severity of distress. This factor is then adjusted to reflect the population and per capita income of, and tax effort being made by, each eligible government based on Hgures developed under the General Revenue Sharing program. The distribution formula constructed in this manner would aetermine each government's share of total funds. To avoid excessive administrative burdens, no distributions will be made to governments which would receive less than $200 annually. No local government could receive more money under the supplementary Fiscal Assistance program than the amount it rnn fJ V e :, U n d e r countercyclical revenue sharing during the twelve months through April, 1978. This cap was established to avoid Fpd i 1 ^ 6 t h e d e P e n d e n c e of local governments on supplementary furri ii C a l a s s i s t a n c e There is no limit on the amount of ailocated to furri local governments which did not receive ARFA lng the m o s t would recent twelve months. Limiting these funds P e c l u d e the> oari* ^ advantages of more equitable distributions r l y t0 t h o s e are not a a s whose level of fiscal distress was CUrately r e f l e c t e d formul under t h e countercyclical targeting -6Both the eligibility of, and allocation of funds to, each local government is to be determined during the September preceeding each Federal fiscal year. This will eliminate the uncertainty governments now face under the countercyclical program which makes these determinations quarterly and leaves governments uncertain of the amounts they will receive during the full year. SFA payments, however, will be made quarterly to permit more efficient cash management. Recipient governments may use SFA funds as part of their general revenue. We have eliminated certain restrictions on the use and timing of expenditures to permit more efficient use of funds at the discretion of recipients. H.R.12293 also contains nondiscrimination, auditing, labor, and reporting requirements and provides withholding and rulemaking powers similar to those in the Anti-Recession' Fiscal Assistance legislation. The general enforcement rights under ARFA have also been retained. Estimated Allocation of Supplementary Fiscal Assistance As I stated earlier, we checked our modified distribution formula to make certain that it targeted distributions to distressed local governments at least as well as the countercyclical formula. We have also compared the Supplementary Fiscal Assistance formula with other alternative formulas. Our preliminary estimates show that during fiscal 1979 approximately twenty-six thousand (26,000) governments would receive funds under SFA. During the most recent four quarters of ARFA, twenty-four thousand (24,000) local governments were eligible recipients. This increase in the number of eligible recipients is the intended result of adding new eligibility criteria to our formula to include local governments, both in urban and rural areas, whose long term economic problems were not adequately measured under countercyclical revenue sharing. Of the 26,000 eligible recipients under SFA, about 5,000 did not receive money under the countercyclical program during the most recent twelve months . Despite the addition of new recipients, the allocation of SFA funds will be targeted to the most distressed governments. A number of governments which receive ARFA funds have become healthier and have falling unemployment rates. In effect, because they now will receive less or even nothing, funds are freed up for new entrants into the program. In addition, the new entrants generally have small budgets. Although the amount of funds received will be important to them, the funds will be a small part of total distributions. The most distressed recipients of countercyclical revenue sharing will still receive proportionately greater funds under SFA. We estimate that approximately 23 percent of SFA 1979 -7disbursements would be received by the ten cities which ranked highest — meaning most distressed -- on the fiscal strain index contained in our January report. Only 11 percent of the disbursements would be received by the other 38 large municipal governments included in our study. In short, the Administration's program would be well targeted because those who are neediest would receive the largest amounts. Exhibit 2 to my testimony illustrates this conclusion. CONCLUSION As you know, this fiscal assistance program constitutes a very important part of the President's program for distressed areas. The financial health of local governments depends primarily on their economies. The Carter Administration has recommended several proposals to assist distressed areas and will be working with the Congress to implement a program that will foster the development of these economies across the Nation. We believe local governments in distressed areas will need Supplementary Fiscal Assistance until a broader economic redevelopment program is fully established. It is our hope that this effort will reduce the need for Supplementary Fiscal Assistance in the future. Obviously, this process will take time. In the meanwhile, the Administration's Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program is a necessary and critical part of our efforts to strengthen and assist local areas which have not shared fully in the Nation's general economic recovery. We have purposefully designed this program to bridge the two years remaining until the expiration of General Revenue Sharing in 1980, when the results of a zero based review of general Federal assistance will have been completed by the Administration. On the basis of that review and an evaluation of the effects of other aspects of the President's fiscal and economic programs, we expect to present recommendations to the Congress in 1980 on the future of both SFA and GRS. I appreciate this opportunity to present the Administration's Supplementary Fiscal Assistance program. I look forward to working with you and the other members of Congress to implement the program. oOOo EXHIBIT 1 SUPPLEMENTARY FISCAL ASSISTANCE ELIGIBILITY AND DISTRIBUTION Eligibility: An SMSA government is eligible if: (A) its unemployment rate for a 12 month period averages over 4.5% or (B) its rates of growth in at least 2 of the following 3 indicators are lower than the average rates of grcwth for SMSA areas: (1) employment (2) per capita income (3) population A non-SMSA government is eligible if it meets the same criteria above, when "non-SMSA" is substituted for "SMSA." Distribution: For all eligible SMSA and non-SMSA jurisdictions, distribution is determined by the product of its latest completed entitlement period general revenue sharing allocation and its local distribution index, divided by the sum of all such products. The resulting fraction multiplied times the national allocation determines the local annual allocation, to be paid quarterly: local GRS amount x local distribution index National Allocation Sum of all numerators 2 SUPPLEMENTARY FISCAL ASSISTANCE INDEXES The local distribution index for SMSA jurisdictions is the largest of the following four quotients: local unemployment rate - 4.5% (1) SMSA unemployment rate weighted standard deviation SMSA group pci growth - local pci growth (2) SMSA pci growth rate weighted standard deviation SMSA group pop growth - local pop growth (3) SMSA pop growth rate weighted standard deviation SMSA group emp growth - local enp growth (4) SMSA enp growth rate weighted standard deviation The local distribution index for non-SMSA jurisdictions is determined as above, substituting "non-SMSA" for "SMSA." iixnit>it z. Estimated Targeting of Supplemental Fiscal Assistance in Fiscal 1979 (to the 48 Largest Cities) SFA Allocation ($ in millions) High Strain Cities (10) $236.8 2 Moderate Strain Cities (28) 3 Low Strain Cities (10) % of SFA Allocation to 48 Largest Cities as as a group of total SFA Allocation % Per Capita SFA Allocation 67% 23% $14.06 98.1 28 9 6.14 18.6 5 2 3.09 Ratio of High Strain to Low Strain Per Capita Allocations: 4.55 to 1 Ratio of High Strain to Moderate Strain Per Capita Allocations: 2.29 to 1 The ten high strain cities are: Boston, Buffalo, Chicago, Cleveland, Detroit, New Orleans New York, Newark, Philadelphia, St. Louis 3'The ten low strain cities are: Columbus, Denver, Houston, Memphis, Norfolk, Oklahoma City, Phoen •hoenix, Portland, San Diego, San Jose Source: Office of the Secretary of the Treasury, Office of State and Local Finance FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 3, 1978 Contact: Charles Arnold 566-2041 IRS PUBLISHES AMENDMENTS TO REGULATIONS DEALING WITH STATE AND LOCAL OBLIGATIONS Washington, D.C. -- The Treasury Department today announced amendments to previously proposed regulations dealing with the tax treatment of interest on state and local government obligations. The Internal Revenue Service today filed the amendments for publication in the Federal Register. Section 103 of the Internal Revenue Code generally exempts interest on these obligations from tax. However, section 103(c) provides that interest on state and local obligations will not be tax exempt where a major portion of the proceeds of the issue Is reasonably expected to be used to purchase securities or obligations that will produce a yield materially higher than the yield on the state or local bond issue. Under the regulations as previously proposed, some issuers attempted to avoid the restrictions on investment yield by contributing taxes or other revenues to a sinking fund that is then invested at a rate allowing the issuer to retire the entire issue at the end of a fixed period while making a profit on the investment of the fund. B-873 - 2Because of this abuse, the proposed regulations are amended to provide that contributions made to a sinking fund for an issue are treated as proceeds of the issue to the extent the issuer reasonably expects to use the fund to pay principal or interest on the issue. These amounts will thus be subject to the limitation on yield rules. This amendment and related conforming amendments will not apply to issues sold before May 16, 1978, provided that one of three specified actions was taken before May 3, 1978. These actions are: (A) The sale of the bonds was either authorized or approved by the governing body of the governmental unit issuing the bonds or by the voters of such governmental unit, (B) Notice of sale of the bonds was given as required by law, or (C) A bona fide written offering statement (or preliminary offering statement) was circulated to potential purchasers. Other significant amendments are also being made to the proposed regulations. However, these amendments will apply only to bonds issued after September 1, 1978. oOo FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 3, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY DEPARTMENT EXTENDS PERIOD OF INVESTIGATION OF STEEL WIRE ROPE FROM KOREA The Treasury Department said today that it will extend its antidumping investigation of steel wire rope from the Republic of Korea for an additional period not to exceed 30 days. The decision was made because more time was needed to analyze the data provided. Under the Antidumping Act, "sales at less than fair value" generally occur when the price of merchandise sold for exportation to the United States is less than the price of such or similar merchandise sold in the home market or to third countries. If Treasury determines "sales at less than fair value" occur, the case is referred to the U. S. International Trade Commission for an injury determination. An affirmative ITC decision would require dumping duties. Notice of this action will appear in the Federal Register of May 4, 1978. Imports of steel wire rope from the Republic of Korea were valued at approximately $13 million during calendar year 1976. o B-874 0 o FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 3, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY ANNOUNCES START OF FOUR ANTIDUMPING INVESTIGATIONS ON VISCOSE RAYON STAPLE FIBER The Treasury Department said today that it will begin antidumping investigations of imports of viscose rayon staple fiber from Finland, France, Italy and Sweden. Treasury's announcement followed summary investigations conducted by the U. S. Customs Service after receipt of four petitions filed by Avtex Fibers, Inc., alleging that firms in these four countries are dumping viscose rayon staple fiber in the United States. Information contained in the petitions indicates that viscose rayon staple fiber is being sold in the United States at "less than fair value." In all four cases, "fair value" was based upon the constructed value of the merchandise because the petitioner presented information indicating that this product may be selling in the home markets for less than its cost of production. If Treasury finds there have been sales at less than fair value, the U. S. International Trade Commission will subsequently decide whether there is injury, or the likelihood of injury, to a domestic industry. Both "sales at less than fair value" and "injury" must be found to exist before a dumping finding is reached. For purposes of this investigation the term "viscose rayon staple fiber" means viscose rayon staple fiber, except solution dyed. Notice of the start of these investigations will appear in the Federal Register of May 5, 1978. Imports of this merchandise from these four countries during 1977 were valued at approximately $3.9 million, as follows: Finland - $0.9 million, France - $1.7 million, Italy - $0.5 million, Sweden - $2.1 million. o B-875 0 o Contact: Carolyn Johnston (202) 634-5377 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE MAY 5, 1978 TREASURY SECRETARY BLUMENTHAL NAMES GERALD C. SMITH SAVINGS BONDS CHAIRMAN FOR WEST VIRGINIA Gerald C. Smith, president of the West Virginia Water Company, has been appointed Volunteer State Chairman for the Savings Bonds program in West Virginia. The appointment, by Secretary W. Michael Blumenthal, is effective immediately. Mr. Smith succeeds James R. Thomas, II, President, Carbon Industries, Inc. of Charleston. Mr. Smith, who also lives in Charleston, will head a committee of business, financial, labor, media, and governmental leaders, who. --in cooperation with the Savings Bonds Division -- promote the sale of Savings Bonds. Mr. Smith started his career with the Monongahela Valley Water Corporation in Elizabeth, Pa. He served as manager of the Armstrong Water Company in Kittanning, Pa., and the Marion Water Company in Marion, Oh. In September 1965 he -- more -- B-876 - 2 - was promoted to manager of the Kentucky-American Water Company in Lexington, Ky., and in 1967 he was elected vice president of the company. He is past president of the National Association of Water Companies, having served as president in 1970, and currently is a member of its board of directors. Only July 15, 1974, Mr. Smith was appointed to his present position. Mr. Smith is active in business and civic affairs and serves on the board of directors for the Kanawha Valley Bank, the Charleston Regional Chamber of Commerce and Development, the United Way, and the West Virginia Chamber of Commerce. Mr. Smith is married and has two daughters. FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 3, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY EXTENDS PERIOD OF INVESTIGATION OF CARBON STEEL WIRE ROD FROM FRANCE The Treasury Department said today that it will extend its antidumping investigation of carbon steel wire rod from France for an additional period not to exceed 90 days. The decision was made because more time was needed to obtain and analyze data. Under the Antidumping Act, "sales at less than fair value" generally occur when imported merchandise is sold in the United States at prices below those in the home market or in third countries. If Treasury finds that "sales at less than fair value" occur, the case is referred to the U. S. International Trade Commission for an injury determination. An affirmative ITC decision would require dumping duties. Notice of this action will appear in the Federal Register of Mav 9, 1978. Imports of carbon steel wire rod from France were valued at approximately $38 million during calendar year 1976 and at roughly $28 million1during the first seven months of 1977. o B-877 0 o FOR RELEASE THURSDAY AM'S May 4, 1978 Contact: George G. Ross 202/566-2356 TREASURY PUBLISHES REPORT OF EFFECTIVE TAX RATES PAID BY CORPORATIONS IN 1972 The Treasury Department today released a report of estimated effective income tax rates paid by U. S. Corporations in 1972. The report, first of its kind, is intended to clarify widespread misunderstanding about the ambiguities of effective tax rate construction and their interpretation. The report, titled "Effective Income Tax Rates Paid by United States Corporations in 1972," relies on data derived from individual corporations income tax returns. According to the report, among all nonfinancial corporations, effective tax rates increase with size of assets. Additionally, among 19 industry categories identified in the report, manufacturing paid the highest effective tax rate (4 2 percent), while coal mining and banking paid the lowest (19.4 and 18.6, respectively). The report contains tables of effective tax rates for corporations by size and industry; for worldwide, domestic, and foreign income. Copies of the report are available for sale by the Superintendent of Documents, U. S. Printing Office, Washington, D. C. 20402. The cost is $2.30 per copy. o B-878 0 o FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY MAY 4, 1978, 9:30 a.m. PDST STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE RICHARD J. DAVIS ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR ENFORCEMENT AND OPERATIONS BEFORE THE HOUSE JUDICIARY COMMITTEE SUBCOMMITTEE ON CRIME Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: I very much appreciate the opportunity to discuss with you today various proposed regulations designed to reduce the criminal misuse of firearms. With me is Rex Davis, Director of the Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco and Firearms (ATF). I believe that these hearings are very timely. We are in the midst of a comment period on these regulations; this period will close on May 22nd. It is therefore an important time for us all to take steps to make certain that those interested in these matters have an accurate understanding of what is being proposed. I am not certain however, that is currently the case. Much of the debate we hear, and the comments we receive, claim that these regulations would create a national registration system or complain that they represent an attempt to prevent the sportsman or law abiding citizen from acquiring or keeping a firearm. These regulations would do neither. They create no registration system. They add no new restrictions on the ability of private citizens to purchase firearms. They usurp no Congressional prerogatives. They involve only what Congress has authorized and what the public has a right to expect — that we seek ways to enforce our current laws more effectively. They are aimed at C-379 - 2 identifying the criminal who uses a weapon, and those individuals who are his sources of supply. Hearings such as these will assist in removing some of the confusion which has been created by some private interest groups concerning the scope of these regulations. At the outset I would like to set out some of the underlying premises and general goals involved in proposing these regulations. Our basic goal, of course, is to strive to improve the manner in which we enforce existing firearms laws. In doing so one of our principal premises is recognition of the fact that the explicitly stated purpose of the Gun Control Act of 1968 was "to provide support to Federal, State and local law enforcement officials in their fight against crime and violence ....". One of the principal ways we can do this, of course, is to trace weapons found at crime scenes or otherwise used in crimes. Another of our operating premises is that violent crime continues to be a serious problem and that firearms continue to be used in many of these crimes. In 1976 over 12,000 murders, 190,000 robberies and 120,000 aggravated assaults were committed with firearms. Approximately 12,000 people were killed in that year alone with firearms. From 1967 to 1976, over a thousand police officers were shot down in the line of duty. Last year 94 police officers were shot and killed in the line of duty . As the agency charged with responsibility for enforcing our firearms laws, the Treasury Department believes that it should take those steps it can to seek to provide our police officials — and particularly those at the state and local level — with increased capabilities to meet this growing problem. Our third operating premise is a belief that we have to try to develop an approach which involves something other than simply adding an endless number of agents to the Federal payroll. ATF's Concentrated Urban Enforcement Program, Project CUE, for example, involved the assignment of over 200 additional personnel to only three cities at a cost of over eight million dollars. It is unrealistic to suggest, however, that we will be able to add similar numbers of agents to all our cities. What is needed, therefore, is a program which impacts not just selected cities, but which provides benefit to all parts of our country. What is also needed is a program which minimizes the need for additional resources by providing a basis for more effective targetting, of those resources we have. - 3 And finally another of our premises is to concentrate our efforts on the lawbreaker, not the law abiding citizen. Information must be available so we can track down the criminal, without affecting those who obey our laws. It is with these thoughts in mind that proposed new regulations were drafted. They are designed to: * Increase significantly the ability of ATF to trace firearms used in crime; * Provide ATF with essential information to identify unusual flows of firearms to particular areas or dealers so that resources can be meaningfully targetted; * Allow a more organized effort against the problem of stolen firearms which are used in so many crimes. * Assist State and local governments who are seeking to deal with the problem of street crimes. By taking these steps we hope to enhance the ability first to apprehend those who use firearms in crime and, second, to identify — and where possible, stop — sources of firearms which are entering the illegal market. The ultimate beneficiaries of these proposals will include state and local police officials, law abiding gun owner, and the public at large. The proposed regulations can provide us with these improved capabilities without putting new restrictions on the ability of citizens to acquire firearms, without adding to the burdens of firearms ownership and without creating any national file or registry of citizen purchasers or owners of firearms. These regulations would help take weapons from the criminal; they would not make it easier to take weapons from our law abiding citizens. Now I would like to summarize for you specifically what these regulations, if implemented, would require. While the package of regulations published on March 21 has a number of provisions, the three principal aspects would require the following: 1. That licensees — not private citizens — promptly report to ATF all thefts and losses of firearms by manufacturers, wholesalers, and dealers; - 4 2. That quarterly reports be made to ATF of all commercial transactions between licensees, that is from manufacturers or importers to wholesalers, from wholesalers to retailers, from retailers to other retailers; and 3. That each firearm manufactured or imported into the United States contain a unique serial number. These proposed regulations do not place any requirements on individual citizens. Rather, they only affect licensees who are engaged in the business of manufacturing, importing, or selling firearms. In addition, and given the statements of some, we cannot be too clear on this point: these regulations do not require the name or address of citizen purchasers or owners of firearms to be reported to ATF; they do not require firearms purchasers or owners to register their firearms; and they do not create a "national registration system." We have not suggested such requirements in these proposals and we have no intention of issuing regulations which would involve such requirements. Any decision to impose such requirements should require legislative action by the Congress. This is simply not a first step to "gun registration". Nothing in these regulations would make it easier for Congress to adopt such a program. While some have questioned the authority of the Department to issue these regulations, it could not be more cle that the Secretary was given full authority by the Congress to impose these requirements. Section 923 paragraph (g) of Title 18, Chapter 44 specifically provides: (g) Each licensed importer, licensed manufacturer, licensed dealer, and licensed collector shall maintain such records of importation, production, shipment, receipt, sale, or other disposition, of firearms and ammunition at such place, for such period, and in such form as the Secretary may by regulations prescribe. Such importers, manufacturers, dealers, and collectors shall make such records available for inspection at all reasonable times, and shall submit to the Secretary such reports and information with respect to such records and the contents thereof as he shall by regulations prescribe. (emphasis supplied) Authorization for the unique serial number is found in Section 923 paragraph (i) of the Act. In addition, Section 926 gives the Secretary of the Treasury general authority - 5 to issue regulations. These regulations therefore represent no more than an attempt by the Treasury Department to faithfully enforce a law passed 10 years ago by Congress. We believe it is long past time such an effort was made. I would now like to explain in more detail how the information secured by these proposals could be used. The first way would be to enhance our ability to trace firearms used in crimes. To understand the benefits which would accrue, it is necessary to understand how the current tracing system works, and what its drawbacks are. While in a crisis case — such as an assassination or mass murder — ATF can trace a firearm very quickly, it is misleading to assume that the isolated exceptional case is at all typical. The average case takes weeks, not minutes. Under the current system, after receiving the request for a trace, ATF must call the manufacturer or importer and various wholesalers before ultimately contacting the retailer. Studies have indicated that there are an average of three commercial transactions before the gun is sold to the retailer. Of course, in each instance, ATF must await the answer from one licensee before contacting the next one. Once the retailer is finally identified ATF or the law enforcement agency who requested the trace then contacts that retailer to find out the name and address of the individual who purchased the firearm. Under current rules, retailers are required to keep names and addresses of purchasers of firearms. These regulations would not change this. This trace by telephone system, despite the efforts of ATF, simply does not meet the needs of our law enforcement agencies, Federal, state or local. Last year ATF attempted only 62,498 traces, 55% of which were for state or local officials. The Bureau actually lacks the capacity to expand this number of traces and is forced into the extraordinary position of not encouraging law enforcement officials to seek its assistance in tracing guns used in crime. When one considers the large numbers of robberies, assaults, murders, narcotics cases, rapes in which firearms are used, this inability to trace a firearm is unacceptable. This creates a gap in the nation's efforts to fight crime. Attempting a trace is not, however, completing it, and the current system makes success difficult to achieve. In -6fact, in 1977 of the 62,498 traces attempted, 45% were incomplete. In 10,000 of these failures, the inability to complete the trace was caused by the unavailability or incompleteness of the records that the licensees were required to keep at their premises. Records are often reported lost or destroyed and it is impossible to complete the trace. Even when we can complete a trace, the current system often produces unfortunate delays in doing so. There are three categories of traces: urgent, expedite, and routine. Where urgent the goal is to complete the trace in 24 hours, where expedite in 4 working days, and where routine, in 7 working days. Approximately 76% of all traces are routine, 19% expedite, and 7% urgent. Even these rather long time limits are often not met: as of April 5 there was a backlog of 23 urgent requests, 177 expedite requests and 390 routine requests. Our best estimate is that the average urgent trace took 2 days; the average expedite took 8 days; the average routine case took 11 days. When there are difficulties with retail or wholesale records these averages can double or triple. This delay becomes even more distressing when it is only common sense that the speed with which police receive evidence may determine whether they can solve the crime. Thus a fast and successful trace can be the difference in determining whether or not local police are able to apprehend a murderer, a rapist, or a robber. Ideally, we should trace any gun used in a crime or found at a crime scene. Where a suspect has been apprehended such a trace could identify possible criminal associates, provide leads as to how the gun got into the criminal market, supply additional evidence to assure successful prosecutions, and solve earlier thefts of firearms. Where the gun, but not the suspect, is in custody, tracing can provide at least an assist in identifying the criminal. But, as you can see, our capability to do this is plainly insufficient. These regulations promise to correct this situation. If the proposed system were in effect, ATF could skip the intermediate steps and not bother the manufacturer, wholesaler and so on. They would have this information already and within hours or even minutes, be able to identify the final retail seller. The problem of incomplete or unavailable records would be diminished. The service would be fully available to state and local, as well as Federal law enforcement officials. An important part of -7the assistance Congress wanted us to provide when it enacted the 1968 Gun Control Act would thus finally be available. In addition to enhancing its tracing ability, these regulations, as I mentioned at the outset, would also provide information necessary for ATF to more effectively develop strategies of enforcement and target its resources. As you are probably aware, there are approximately 170,000 individuals who are licensed by ATF to engage in the business of manufacturing, importing, distributing or selling firearms. Under Federal firearms law, ATF has the responsibility to regulate the interstate commerce of firearms, ensure that licensees are complying with the law, and identify those diverting weapons illegally. However, as you know under current regulations there is no requirement that copies of the record of transaction with other licensees be sent to ATF. The Bureau therefore lacks the ability to target their inspection or investigative resources so as to focus their attention on dealers where there is reason to believe may be engaged in illegal commerce or the selling of firearms on a regular basis to criminals. Instead, for example, inspections inevitably must be on a more random basis that is desirable. These regulations will change this situation. They will provide ATF with essential information to identify unusual flows of firearms. ATF could then assign its inspectors and agents to investigate those areas or dealers who are receiving firearms in quantities that may not be explainable by the demands of normal legal business. With such information to guide its efforts, the average law abiding dealer would be bothered less by the government. Those possibly abusing their license and selling into the criminal market would however, receive more attention, as they should. There is another benefit to this proposal, one not usually associated with reporting requirements. Ultimately it will reduce tne recordkeeping burden now placed on licensees. Currently it is necessary to require that records of firearms transactions be maintained indefinitely. This is essential if firearms traces are to always be possible. Under these proposals, however, this would no longer be necessary. ATF would have the information it needs. Record retention requirements could than be reduced, easing the burden on our licensees. Also, once the system is fully operational, licensees would probably have to respond to fewer requests from ATF to assist in traces. -8Other aspects of these proposals would also assist our enforcement efforts. A unique serial number would include in one number all that is necessary to submit for a firearms trace; would avoid confusion for the street officer seeking to determine what information or numbers he must submit; would end the duplication in numbers used by different manufacturers; and would simplify the computerization of this information. This change is long overdue. The theft reports would enable ATF and local police to address more effectively the problem of stolen firearms. As you may know, it has been estimated that stolen weapons are used in 20 percent of all crimes committed with firearms. Though there is some voluntary reporting, under current regulations there is no requirement that a licensee report a theft or loss of a firearm. Without knowledge of a theft, however there is no way local or Federal law enforcement can investigate the incident. Thus, law enforcement in some cases also is unaware of the problem until the firearm is used in a crime. Knowing whan a gun was stolen would help identify the criminal who uses it in a crime. In addition, with more complete information on firearms thefts, vulnerabilities in the distribution process would be identified, so that methods to remove them could be developed. The regulations proposed on March 21 also include other provisions. One would require members of the military to obtain authorization prior to importing weapons for their personal use. Civilians must do so now. The other proposals seek to simplify and revise certain procedures relating to the importation and transportation of various weapons. In addition, they would require licensees to supply information when needed by ATF over the telephone. Most do so on a voluntary basis now. The comment period for these regulations is scheduled to close on May 22. We are, of course, interested in the arguments and information these comments will provide. We know, for example, the advantages of requiring a unique serial number; we need to obtain a better notion as to the costs to industry, as well as any suggestions for alternatives. So too, with the other proposals. We welcome all comments so that the most meaningful decisions on this matter can be made. We have, of course, already received many comments. Support has come from the National Conference of Mayors -9and the League of Cities; the International Association of Chiefs of Police (IACP), which has 11,000 members? the Police Executive Research Forum comprised of the' police chiefs of 50 cities; the Police Foundation which did an extensive two year study of the problem of firearms abuse and various police chiefs. We also have letters from individual police chiefs in support. The NRA and the Firearms Lobby have opposed the regulations even though they are aimed at tracing firearms used in crimes and do not effect, in any way, law abiding gun owners and purchasers. We expect many additional comments. They will take time to sort and analyze. A final decision will be based upon this analysis. Because of this process there is no possibility that implementation could be earlier than sometime in 1979. Whenever they are implemented, we will have to come to Congress for the necessary funds. If implemented in their current form, it is our estimate that the costs will be approximately $4.1 million. The Administrations fiscal year 1979 budget submitted to the Congress contains no funds with which to implement the regulations. In sum, we have proposed these regulations as part of an effort to use our current firearms laws more effectively in the fight against crime. They take no really dramatic steps; they create no national registration system; they usurp none of Congress1 authority. Rather, they are simply an attempt to what all — both pro and anti gun control people — have urged us to do to enforce existing laws more effectively and to direct our attention at the criminal misuser of firearms. After Rex Davis summarizes his statement we will both be happy to answer any questions. TITLE 18—CRIMES AND CRIMINAL PROCEDURE § 923. Licensing ' (i) Licensed importers and licensed manufacturers shall identify by means of a serial number engraved or cast on the receiver or frame of the weapon, in such manner as the Secretary shall by regulations prescribe, each firearm imported or manufactured by such importer or manufacturer. § 926. Rules and regulations The Secretary may prescribe such rules and regulations as he deems reasonably necessary to carry out the provisions of this chapter, including— (1) regulations providing that a person licensed under this chapter, w h e n dealing with another person so licensed, shall provide such other licensed person a certified copy of this license; and (2) regulations providing for the issuance. at a reasonable cost, to a person licensed under this chapter, of certified copies of his license for use as provided under regulations issued under paragraph (1) of this subsection. T h e Secretary shall give reasonable public notice, and afford to interested parties opportu-. njt£Jor~hearing. prior to prescribing'such rules and regulations/ (Added Pub. L. 90-351, title IV. § 902. June 19. 1968, 82 Stat. 234, and amended Pub. L. 90-618, title I. § 102, Oct. 22, 1968, 82 Stat. 1226.) rtmentoftheJREASURY HNGTON,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 4, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY OFFICIALS DEFEND NEW GUN TRACING RULES Senior officials of the Treasury Department today defended proposed gun tracing rules as a way to "take weapons from the criminals...not make it easier to take weapons from our law-abiding citizens." Treasury Assistant Secretary for Enforcement and Operations Richard Davis testified before the House Judiciary Subcommittee on Crime chaired by Congressman John Conyers. Davis said, "In 1976 over 12,000 murders, 190,000 robberies and 120,000 aggravated assaults were committed with firearms. Approximately 12,000 people were killed in that year alone with firearms. From 1967 to 1976 over a thousand police officiers were shot down in the line of duty." Davis said the new rules are designed to provide police officials, expecially at the state and local level, with increased capabilities to trace guns used in crime and to stop the flow of guns to illegal hands. The new regulations provide for the following: 1. That licensees — not private citizens — promptly report to the Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco and Firearms all thefts and losses of firearms by manufacturers, wholesalers, and dealers; 2. That quarterly reports be made to ATF of all commercial transactions between licensees; that is, from manufacturers or importers to wholesalers, from wholesalers to retailers, from retailers to other retailers; and 3. That each firearm manufactured or imported into the United States contain a unique serial number. Commenting on the widespread public confusion over the proposals, Davis testified, "Much of the debate we hear, and the comments we receive, claim that these regulations would creat a national registration system or complain that they represent an attempt to prevent the sportsman or law-abiding citizen B-880 (More) - 2 - from acquiring or keeping a firearm. These regulations would do neither. They create no registration system. They add no new restrictions on the ability of private citizens to purchase firearms. They usurp no Congressional prerogatives. They involve only what Congress has authorized and what the public has a right to expect — that we seek ways to enforce our current laws more effectively. They are aimed at identifying the criminal who uses a weapon and those who are his sources of supply." Testifying that the power to issue these regulations "could not be more clear," Davis cited specific statutory language authorizing rules for the submission of "such reports and information with respect to such records and the contents thereof," as the Secretary of the Treasury determines necessary. Davis noted that manufacturers already are required to put serial numbers on guns and to keep records of commercial transactions. Davis said that; under current procedures, the Bureau of Alcohol, Tobacco and Firearms, which traces guns used in crime at the request of Federal, state and local law enforcement officials, has the resources for only 5,000 traces a month. However, he said that almost half of the 62,498 traces attempted in 1977 were failures. More than a third of the time, the inability to complete the trace was caused by poor recordkeeping by importers, manufacturers, wholesalers or dealers who are required to keep records of commercial transactions on guns on their premises. Davis said that, under current procedures, the successful gun trace often takes twice as long as necessary. ATF is required to call the manufacturer and wait for him to search his records and identify the wholesaler before the wholesaler can be contacted. ATF must then wait for a search by the wholesaler. The average successful gun trace involves three commercial transactions before the gun is purchased by a private citizen. "This delay becomes even more distressing when it is only common sense that the speed with which police receive evidence may determine whether they solve the crime. Thus, a fast and successful trace can be the difference in determining whether or not local police are able to apprehend a murderer, a rapist, or a robber." Davis said that, under the proposed (More) rules, ATF could have a gun traced to a retailer "within hours or even minutes." - 3- Under existing inspection programs, ATF agents make random inspections of the more than 170,000 gun dealers. Under the new rules, Davis explained, ATF could concentrate on suspected sources of illegal guns. Thus, "The average law-abiding dealer would be bothered less by the government. Those possibly abusing their licenses and selling into the criminal market would, however, receive more attention— as they should." Davis also said that the new regulations would reduce the recordkeeping burden now placed on gun licensees and the time and manpower cost of responding to gun tracing would be reduced. Davis said that the requirement for a unique serial number on all guns manufactured or imported into the U. S. is "long overdue." Under the existing haphazard system, he said, guns often have more than one serial number, or the same number appears on more than one gun. "The theft reports would enable ATF and local police to address more effectively the problem of stolen firearms," Davis testified. He said that "stolen weapons are used in 20 percent of all crimes committed with firearms." Under current rules, some gun licensees voluntarily report thefts and losses. "Without knowledge of a theft, however, there is no way local or Federal law enforcement can investigate the incident. Thus, law enforcement in some cases also is unaware of the problem until the firearm is used in a crime. Knowing when a gun was stolen would help identify the criminal who uses it in a crime." Davis said that the new proposals have received widespread support from local police chiefs and law enforcement organizations such as the International Association of Chiefs of Police, the Police Executive Research Forum, and the Police Foundation, as well asothe National 0 o Conference of Mayors. The complete text of Davis's testimony is attached RELEASE ON DELIVERY REMARKS BY THE HONORABLE ROBERT CARSWELL DEPUTY SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY AT THE SECRETARY OF LABOR'S CONFERENCE FOR LABOR EDITORS HYATT REGENCY HOTEL WASHINGTON, D.C. MAY 4, 1978 — 3:30 P.M. I am delighted to be with you this afternoon. I would like to take this opportunity to discuss a matter of great significance to members of the labor movement throughout our country. On January 20, the President sent to the Congress a comprehensive package of tax reduction and reform. The proposals call for $34 billion in reductions, $9 billion of which is to be paid for by a broad spectrum of reforms designed to eliminate various preferences and to simplify our tax laws. $17 billion of the net reductions are in the form of income tax relief for individuals, and 94% of that $17 billion goes to taxpayers with incomes under $30,000. The balance of income tax relief goes to business as an incentive for increased capital investment to produce more jobs. This package was designed with America's working men and women firmly in mind. On February 20, the Executive B-88L - 2 Council of the AFL/CIO announced its unanimous support for the vast majority of the President's proposals. This support was gratifying and reaffirmed our belief that the President's program merits the active support of labor union members. Let me tell you why it does. The reform proposals close up loopholes few American workers can enjoy. The tax reductions, paid for in part by the closing of the loopholes, are concentrated in the income brackets where most union members find themselves. The reforms are also badly needed to start the process of improving a tax system which the President has correctly described as a disgrace. And the reductions are needed to be sure that our economy continues to move ahead in 1979 and beyond. If it does not, union members will be among those who will feel the shortfall first. It is now more than three months since the President sent his tax message to the Congress, but as of today, the proposals have made very little progress. Two weeks ago the Ways and Means Committee — after agreeing to some minor reforms — alternated between rejecting reform proposals and adding more loopholes. Last week it temporarily suspended operations to consult with the Administration about the course of future action. To date the message from the Congress is clear: drop significant reform proposals and change the focus of the reductions to increase benefits for those in higher brackets. - 3One Representative has proposed an amendment to the bill to reduce the tax treatment of capital gains back to the 1969 level of 25%. This change, which appears to have considerable support, would substantially decrease the progressivity of the individual income tax system. Two-thirds of the benefits of such a change would go to individuals with annual incomes of $200,000 or more. Such taxpayers would receive an average annual reduction of $14,128 as compared with present law; whereas those with $15,000 to $20,000 of income would receive an average cut of 26$. The President has been equally clear that he rejects this type of change. He has stated repeatedly that the Administration proposals are fair and right, and we intend to fight for them. He rejects the notion that broad-based tax cuts for average taxpayers should be sacrificed in favor of tax preferences for high-income individuals and large corporations. He resists the fashionable argument that there is something wrong with having a progressive tax cut — one that focuses relief on low- and middle-income workers. - 4 - The President deserves to hear your support and the support of your readers for his stand. The polls show that an overwhelming majority of Americans, when asked, are in favor of tax reform. But they have not been writing letters to, or visiting with, their Congressmen. Those interests which enjoy tax preferences and tax shelters and can afford organized campaigns on the Congress have been conducting such campaigns. This is all many Congressmen are hearing, and most Congressmen respond to what they hear. Why shouldn't they? That means they tend to vote benefits for the small minority of wealthy taxpayers — a curious result in a democracy and an unhappy one for most taxpayers. Taxes are a complex subject and except on April 15, they are generally considered dull or too technically complex to write about for the ordinary man. Weeks and months go by without general press coverage of - 5tax provisions. The taxpayers, who are paying the freight, pay little heed to the special provisions that make our tax system unfair and complex. Radio and TV find other stories that appear to be of more immediate interest. Except for Sunday panel interviews now and then, a spate of three-martini jokes and the lonely voice of the President, there has been little national media coverage of the details of our tax package. I do not know what each of you is telling union members in America today. But I do know they have a considerable stake in what is happening to the President's tax proposals. And if the early retreat of the Congress under stiff pressure from anti-reform lobbyists is an indication of what the summer will bring, union members will not like the results. They need to be told — and told now — of their real interest in the success of the President's package or they may not put up a fight. History is not replete with instances where the Treasury Department's activities are of direct and immediate interest to the labor press. But they are now. Despite the Executive Council's announced support of the President's tax proposals, labor's voice has rattled no legislative window panes. In my view, that is regrettable. - 6 Let me remind you of what the President's program would do: • It would crack down on tax shelter abuses that drain funds from job-creating, productive investments into uneconomic ventures designed to produce tax write-offs for affluent individuals. We cannot continue to ask low- and middle-income workers to provide more tax support for this country than is furnished by some of our wealthiest citizens. • It would eliminate the $2 billion DISC and foreign tax deferral preferences that are enjoyed primarily by America's largest multinational corporations. These proposals have been priority reform recommendations of organized labor, and this Administration believes it is time the recommendations become law. • It would eliminate some of the least significant itemized deductions and translate the savings into lower tax rates. Six million taxpayers will switch to standard deductions; three million will switch to 1040A. Those people will actually be able to prepare their own returns. - 7 • It would produce tax reductions that should add one million additional jobs to the economy by the end of 1979. • It would eliminate certain deductions — including deductions for hunting lodges, pleasure boats and Astrodome boxes -- that allow a privileged few to charge off luxuries that the rest of us cannot afford. The situation we have today inevitably leads some to feel the system is not fair. It erodes our self-assessment system, and it should not be permitted to continue. I will not attempt to go through the details of the President's proposals here today. They are available from the Treasury both in the technical splendor the tax lawyers try to pass off as English and in something approaching layman's language. There are hundreds of pages of hearings and explanations that one can consult as well. I hope that you will pursue this material and make it available to your readers. At stake is a dollars and cents issue, one that is worth billions of dollars to labor union members. There is also a chance to correct some fundamental inequities. Yet- - 8these issues have not yet risen even to the level of a public debate. Without a public debate, I am afraid that most taxpayers — and most union members — ultimate losers. Thank you. 0O0 will be the wtmentoftheTREASURY ||NGTON,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 5, 1978 Press Contact: Non-Press Contact John P. Plum 202/566-2615 202/566-8235 566-8651 566-5286 THIRD QUARTER STEEL TRIGGER PRICE REVISIONS PUBLISHED The Department of the Treasury today announced third quarter revisions of trigger base prices and extras for those of the 32 categories of imported steel mill products (as defined by American Iron & Steel Institute) being monitored under the trigger price mechanism. The revisions are effective for steel exported to the United States on or after July 1, 1978 The revisions reflect the increases in raw material and labor costs including the annual wage settlement, and appreciation in the exchange value of the yen for those Japanese steel producers whose cost data was used in computing the trigger prices: Integrated producers --A 5.5 percent increase will be applied to the products of integrated producers^ such as cold and hot rolled sheets and plates. Electric furnace producers —Increases of 13.9, 14.5 and 14 percent will be applied to angles, flat bars and reinforcing bars, respectively. Fabricating mills —A 5.5 percent increase will be applied to the products of Japanese fabricating mills (e.g. wire and wire products, cold finished bars, and light rails) until complete data is available from the Japanese government to compute revisions for these products. Treasury also announced its intention to gather more information to complete the steel mill product coverage of trigger prices and to correct claimed anomalies in the calculation of certain trigger prices. Persons other than from the press seeking additional information should call the above non-press telephone numbers at the U.S. Customs Service. If those lines are busy, call 202/566-8121 and leave your phone number so that your call may be returned. B-882 # DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY OFFICE OF THE SECRETARY NOTICE Imported Steel Mill Products Trigger Price Mechanism: Quarterly Revision of Trigger Prices The Treasury Department is hereby announcing increases in trigger prices for imported steel mill products reflecting increased costs of production for the Japanese steel industry and appreciation in the value of the yen, effective for all shipments exported on or after July 1, 1978. A. Integrated Producers With respect to the categories of steel mill products produced primarily by the integrated steel producers, the price revision is based on changes since the end of 1977 in the costs of basic raw materials and labor and in the rate of exchange. Coal and iron ore costs increased in the aggregate by 3.5 percent in dollar terms. In April 1978, the integrated companies agreed to a new industry-wide labor contract which provides for an estimated overall 4.2 percent increase in hourly labor costs for the current fiscal year ending March 31, 1979. Finally, as reflected in the average daily exchange rate from March 1 through April 30, the Japanese yen has appreciated to a level of 226 yen to the dollar. These changes in costs and the exchange rate have increased by approximately 5.5 percent the average costs of production and, correspondingly, both the base prices and "extras" for products in Categories 2, 1/ 3, 2/ 4, 5, 10, 3/ 14, 1/ 15, 1/ 22, 23, 25, 26, 27, and 37 will be increased by 5.5%. The magnitude of this increase is due to the coincidence of the timing of the bulk of the annual wage increases in Japan and the appreciation of the yen. The calculation leading to the indicated increase for these products was made as follows: 1/ With the exception of those specific products listed in Table 3. 2/ Only wide flange beams and bearing piling (Trigger Price Handbook pp 3-1 to 3-4). Other products in this category are covered in Table 3. 3/ Only hot rolled carbon bars: special quality (Trigger Price Handbook pp 10-1 and 10-2). Other products in this category are covered in Table 3. - 2 Table 1 Estimated Japanese Costs of Production ($ per metric ton of finished product) Revision for Third January 9, 1978 Basic Raw Materials Other Raw Materials Labor Other Expenses Depreciation Interest plus profit Less scrap credit Quarter 120.62 67.10 83.61 22.70 19.65 39.59 (6.97) 346.30 116.91 65.12 75.60 21.38 18.51 37.28 (6.57) 328.23 Increased Estimated Cost of Production: 5.5% B. Electric Furnace Producers - Trigger prices for products produced by electric furnace producers were published on Monday, March 27, 1978 (43 FR 12783). Trigger price revisions for these steel mill products reflect only an adjustment for scrap prices and the exchange rate since these companies have not yet concluded their collective bargaining for the current fiscal year. A complete description of the methodology used in computing the original trigger prices for these products is set forth below. The original input costs are provided in Table 2. The revised input costs are provided in Table 3. The trigger prices for the carbon steel products listed below are based upon the costs of production of Japan's main electric arc furnace steel mills, submitted to the Treasury Department by the Japanese Ministry of International Trade and Industry. Three sets (A, B, and C) of cost data for these electric arc mills were submitted. The cost of particular products within a cost group were obtained by applying relative cost coefficients provided by the Japanese to the appropriate group average cost. COST GROUP PRODUCTS Equal A Angles A A A Unequal Angles Channels I Beams (S4 through S8) - 3 B Hot Rolled Strip produced on bar mills B Merchant Quality Hot Bars B Merchant Quality Hot Rolled Round Bars B Merchant Quality Squares and Round Cornered Squares B Bar Size Channels C Plain Concrete Reinforcing Bars C Deformed Concrete Reinforcing Bars Because of a different input mix, output mix and production technology, the base production costs estimated for the electric furnace steel mills differ from the base costs reported for the six major Japanese producers. The principal assumptions originally utilized by Treasury in estimating the Japanese electric arc furnace costs are (the only assumptions affected by the quarterly revisions are the exchange rate and the scrap netback): a. Exchange rate. Where relevant, Japanese cost data have been converted to U.S. dollars on the basis of 240 yen per dollar (revised to 226 yen per dollar for the third quarter). b. Capacity utilization. All costs pertain to a standard operating rate of 85 percent. c. Labor productivity. Group A products (equal angles) require 3.3 man hours per metric ton of raw steel, Group B products (flat bars) 3.6 man hours per metric ton of raw steel, and Group C products (reinforcing bars) 2.9 man hours per metric ton of raw steel. d. Yield. The electric arc furnace products are generally fabricated from continuously cast semifinished shapes. Therefore, the yield of Group A (angles) and Group C products (reinforcing bars) per ton of raw steel is taken to be 0.95 and the yield of Group B products (flat bars) of 0.92. - 4 - e. Capital costs. Total depreciation charges, net interest expenses and a margin for profit on average amount to slightly over 13 percent of total assets related to steel production. f. Scrap netback. As previously, yield factors reported by the Japanese electric furnace mills were not used in the calculation of trigger prices in the belief that some of the products considered "finished" would be regarded by U.S. standards as low quality. However, this low quality product receives a cost credit based on the current market price of scrap, which increased for the third quarter. The total costs of production for products in Groups A, B, and C, based on the above assumptions, are estimated to be: TABLE 2 ORIGINAL ESTIMATED JAPANESE ELECTRIC FURNACE MILL BASE PRODUCTION COSTS ($ per metric ton of finished product) Group A Group B Group C Raw Materials 147.19 Labor 24,52 Other Expenses 10.06 Depreciation 5.47 Interest Plus Profit 21.46 Less Scrap Credit (1.94) 159.59 27.94 12.28 6.96 25.85 (2.14) 148.33 19.55 12.68 5.60 20.81 (2.00) 230.48 204.97 Total original 206.76 average cost - 5 TABLE 3 REVISED ESTIMATED JAPANESE ELECTRIC FURNACE MILL BASE PRODUCTION COSTS ($ per metric ton of finished product) Group A Group B Basic Raw Materials (primarily scrap) Other Raw Materials Labor Other Expenses Depreciation Interest Plus Profit Less Scrap Credit Revised average cost Original average cost Increased Estimated Cost of Production C. Other Products Group C 140,.42 32,.29 26..05 10,.68 5,.81 22,.79 (2,.49) 235,.55 206,.76 150.92 38.16 29.64 13.04 7.39 27.45 (2.80) 263.80 139.16 34.88 20.76 13.47 5.94 22.10 (2.56) 233.75 230.48 204.97 13.9% 14.5% 14.0% Data from which to compute quarterly revisions on a number of items has not yet been received from the Japanese government. When this data is available, quarterly revisions will be computed and published. Until such time, the 5.5% increase applicable to the products made by the integrated producers will be applied to such products as well. Trigger Price Handbook Page Item Alloy wire rod Light rails Tie plates Hot rolled bar Cold finished bar Welded stainless steel pipe Hot rolled tube Cold rolled tube Stainless steel ornamental tube Wire Barbed wire 2-11 to 11-1 and 12-1 to 14-14 to 15-46 to 16-1 to 21-1 2-13 6-3 6-5 11-2 12-4 14-17 15-44 15-45 15-49 16-25 -6D. Other Revisions Aside from these general revisions to the trigger prices now in effect, the Treasury Department hopes in the course of the current calendar quarter to undertake analyses of individual trigger prices in the light of comments received with respect to their relationships with other trigger prices. Further, apparent gaps in product coverage as well as the prior inclusion of trigger prices for products not imported in significant quantities will be reviewed. The results of these studies should be available not later than the next quarterly revisions in trigger prices to be published from 60 to 90 days prior to their effective date. Secretary of the Treasury Dated: Ma ^ 5' 1978 Contact: FOR RELEASE A.M. MONDAY, MAY 8, 1978 John P. Plum 566-2615 NAC REPORTS ON INTERNATIONAL MONETARY-ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS The Department of the Treasury has released the annual report of the National Advisory Council on International Monetary and Financial Policies (NAC) for 1977. The 368 page report provides detailed information on significant international monetary, economic and financial developments and the relationship of those developments to policies and programs of the United States. Included is coverage of global economic trends; the evolution of relationships among the developed and developing countries; U.S. support of the international development lending institutions such as the World Bank, Inter-American Development Bank, the Asian Development Bank and the African Development Fund, and major events in international monetary affairs, foreign trade policy and finance, foreign investment, and policies and problems involving foreign indebtedness to the United States. Appendices to the report provide extensive statistical material on U.S. balance of payments, foreign assistance and other U.S. Government international programs, and the activities of the principal international lending and financial institutions of which the United States is a member. The NAC is chaired by the Secretary of the Treasury. Other members of the NAC at the end of the year were the Secretaries of State and Commerce, the Chairman of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, and the President and Chairman of the Board of Directors of the Export-Import 3ank of the United States. Details on the organization, functions and operations of the Council are contained in Appendix A to the report. Compiled and edited by Robert S. Watson, the Secretary of the Council, the report is available from the NAC Office in the Treasury Department and from the Superintendent of Documents, Government Printing Office, Washington, D.C. 20402. (Stock No. 052-071-00560-9) - Price: $5.25. # B-883 FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 10:30 P.M. May 8, 1978 TESTIMONY OF ASSISTANT BEFORE THE OF THE THE HONORABLE ROGER C. ALTMAN SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY COMMITTEE ON WAYS AND MEANS HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES Mr. Chairman and Members of the Committee: I am pleased to be here today to advise you of the Treasury's financing needs through the fiscal year 1979. The present temporary debt limit of $752 billion will expire on July 31, 1978, and the debt limit will then revert to the permanent ceiling of $4 00 billion. Legislative action by July 31 will be necessary, therefore, to permit the Treasury to borrow to refund securities maturing after July 31 and to raise new cash to finance the estimated deficits in the budgets for the fiscal years 1978 and 1979. In addition, to permit the Treasury to continue borrowing in the long-term market, it will be necessary to increase the $27 billion limit on the amount of bonds which we may issue without regard to the 4-1/4 percent interest rate ceiling on Treasury bond issues. Finally, we are repeating our earlier request for authority to permit the Secretary of the Treasury, with the approval of the President, to change the interest rate on U.S. Savings Bonds if that should become necessary to assure a fair rate of return to savings bond investors. B-884 - 2 Debt Limit Turning first to the debt limit, our current estimates of the amounts of debt subject to limit at the end of each month through the fiscal years 1978 and 1979 are shown in the table attached to my statement. These estimates are based on the latest budget revisions, which were released by the Office of Management and Budget on March 13, 1978. The table indicates that the debt subject to limit will increase to $771 billion on September 30, 1978, and to $860 billion on September 30, 1979, assuming a $12 billion cash balance on those dates. The usual $3 billion margin for contingencies would raise these amounts to $774 billion on September 30, 1978, and $863 billion on September 30, 1979. Thus, the present debt limit of $752 billion would need to be increased by $19 billion to meet our financing requirements through the remainder of fiscal 1978 and by an additional $89 billion to meet the requirements in fiscal 1979. Bond Authority I would like to turn now to our fiscal 1979 need for an increase in the Treasury's authority to issue long-term securities in the market without regard to the 4-1/4 percent ceiling. This limit has been increased a number of times, and in the debt limit act of October 4, 1977, it was increased from $17 billion to the current level of $27 billion. To meet our requirements next year, the limit should be increased to $37 billion. The Treasury to date has used $21 billion of the $27 billion authority, including the $1-1/2 billion bond issue which was auctioned on May 3 and will be settled on May 15. This leaves the amount of unused bond authority at $6 billion. While the timing and amounts of future bond issues will depend on prevailing market conditions, a $10 billion increase in the bond authority would permit the Treasury to continue its recent pattern of bond issues throughout fiscal year 1979. Thus, the Treasury would be able to make further progress toward achieving a better balance in the maturity structure of the debt. - 3 Savinqs Bonds In recent years, Treasury has recommended frequently that Congress repeal the ceiling on the rate of interest that the Treasury may pay on U.S. Savings Bonds. The current 6 percent statutory ceiling was enacted by Congress in 1970. Prior to 1970 the ceiling had been increased many times, as market rates of interest rose, and it became clear that an increase in the savings bond interest rate was necessary to provide investors in savings bonds with a fair rate of return. Mr. Chairman, we do not feel that an increase in the interest rate on savings bonds is necessary today. Yet, we are concerned that the present requirement for legislation to cover each increase in the rate does not provide sufficient flexibility to adjust the rate in response to changing market conditions. The delays encountered in the legislative process could result in inequities to savings bond purchasers and holders as market interest rates rise on competing forms of savings. Furthermore, Treasury relies on the savings bond program as an important and relatively stable source of long-term funds. On that basis, we are concerned that participants in the payroll savings plans and other savings bond purchasers might drop out of the program if the interest rate were not maintained at a level reasonably competitive with comparable forms of savings. Anv increase in the savings bond interest rate by the Treasury would continue to be subject to the provision in existing law which requires approval of the President. Also, the Treasury would, of course, give very careful consideration to the effect of any increase in the savings bond interest rate on the flow of savings to banks and thrift institutions. Our request to remove the statutory interest rate ceiling on savings bonds was approved by your Committee in the debt limit bill you reported on March 3, 1978, and we understand that that bill was not passed by the House because of its debt limit provisions rather than the savings bond provision. Accordingly, we are renewing our request to remove the savings bond interest ceiling. I will be happy to try to answer any questions. 0o0 1977 PUBLIC DEBT SUBJECT TO LIMITATION FISCAL YEAR 197 8 Based on: Budget Receipts of $400 Billion, Budget Oultays of $454 Billion, Unified Budget Deficit of $53 Billion, Off-Budget Outlays of $12 Billion ($ Billions) Operating Public Debt With $3 Billion Cash Subject to Margin for Balance Limit Contingencies -Ac:tual- September 30 $19.1 $700.0 October 31 7.7 698.5 November 30 5.5 709.1 December 31 12.3 720.1 January 31 12.5 722.7 February 28 7.4 730.9 March 31 6.4 739.1 April 19 10.8 745.7 April 30 9.3 737.7 1978 -Est imatedMay 31 12 751 $754 June 30 12 744 747 July 31 12 752 755 August 31 12 766 769 September 30 12 771 774 Office of the Fiscal Assistant Secretary Office of the Secretary of the Treasury May 3, 19 7 8 PUBLIC DEBT SUBJECT TO LIMITATION FISCAL YEAR 1979 Based on: Budget Receipts of $440 Billion, Budget Outlays of $499 Billion, Unified Budget Deficit of $60 Billion, Off-Budget Outlays of $12 Billion ($ Billions) Operating Public Debt With $3 Billion Cash Subject to Margin for Balance Limit Contingencies -Estimated- 1978 $12 $771 $774 October 31 12 782 785 November 30 12 793 796 December 31 12 798 801 January 31 12 801 804 February 28 12 817 820 March 31 12 829 832 April 18 12 833 836 April 30 12 821 824 May 31 12 838 841 June 30 12 832 835 July 31 12 840 843 August 31 12 856 859 September 30 12 860 863 September 30 1979 3ffi.ce of the Fiscal Assistant Secretary Office of the Secretary of the Treasury Ma Y 3 ' FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 10:00 A.M. MAY 8, 1978 STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE ANTHONY M. SOLOMON UNDER SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR MONETARY AFFAIRS BEFORE THE SENATE FINANCE COMMITTEE U.S. EXPORTS AND THE TAXATION OF AMERICANS WORKING ABROAD I am pleased to be here today to discuss the United States taxation of the earned income of Americans working abroad. In particular, I would like to comment on the impact that our system of taxing Americans working abroad may have on U.S. exports. The Administration values the role of overseas Americans. It wants to assure that they are taxed fairly. At the same time, it wants to put this troubling issue to rest so that overseas Americans can continue their work free from the uncertainties of a changing tax law. This Administration also recognizes that our tax policy regarding overseas Americans has important consequences for our trade interests. The Administration does not believe that the present provisions of Section 911, as set forth in the Tax Reform Act of 1976, adequately reflect the important considerations B-885 - 2 - which must be weighed in formulating our policy towards overseas Americans. On February 23, in testimony before the House Ways and Means Committee, the Administration recommeded a system for taxing Americans working abroad which permits those taxpayers to deduct: (a) the amount by which reasonable housing costs abroad exceed average U.S. housing costs; (b) the cost of educating dependents through grade 12, subject to a ceiling of $4,000 per year, plus the cost of two round trips per year between the school and the foreign residence; and (c) the cost of home-leave travel for each family member every other year. In addition, the Administration proposal would liberalize certain other provisions of the tax law affecting nonresident citizens such as the moving expense deduction and construction camp provisions. The basic approach and rationale of the Administration's proposal are similar to those of the Ribicoff bill, S9251, which this Committee has voted on favorably. I would like to explain how these proposals respond to the competing interests which arise in formulating a tax policy for the foreign earned income of overseas Americans. The debate concerning the taxation of Americans working overseas, and the various bills introduced in Congress on this subject, including the Administration's proposal, reflect a - 3 fundamental policy decision: the U.S. chooses to tax its citizens whether they reside in the United States or overseas. The United States is the only major country that taxes wage and salary income of its nonresident citizens simply because they are citizens. On administrative grounds, taxation of Americans on the basis of residence rather than citizenship might be easier to apply. It may also be true that nonresident citizens derive fewer benefits from government spending than do taxpayers living in the United States. But these arguments ' overlook two basic precepts of our tax policy. First, U.S. citizenship carries with it very considerable lifetime benefits, and with these benefits come lifetime responsibilities. Second, the basic determinant of tax due in our system is the ability to pay, and not the extent of benefits received during any given year. If we accept the citizenship basis of taxation — and I have heard few people criticize that fundamental principle — we are left with two principal arguments directed against the present manner in which we now tax nonresident citizens. I am sure you have heard these arguments before, and I am sure you will hear them again today. It is important that these arguments be made and heard, but it is equally important that they be placed in proper perspective. The first argument essentially is that the tax system is insufficiently sensitive to the special conditions faced by Americans overseas. The argument is that a citizen's - 4 foreign earnings are frequently inflated to compensate him for unusually high costs of moving and living abroad. In some countries, housing which is barely adequate by U.S. standards costs several times what more comfortable housing would cost in the United States. In non-English speaking areas, Americans may have to spend considerable amounts to obtain education for their children comparable to that available without cost at public schools in the United States. In addition, costs associated with moving abroad or returning to the United States on home-leave can be substantial. If a citizen must earn more to maintain a U.S. standard of living overseas and the United States taxes the additional earnings, then that citizen will pay more U.S. taxes than a citizen maintaining a comparable standard of living at home. In this sense, our tax laws may place our citizens overseas in a worse position than they would have been had they remained in the United States. The Administration recognizes the validity of this eguity argument, as have virtually all the sponsors of legislation relating to the taxation of Americans working abroad. But without additional facts, this argument is no more compelling than a similar case which can be made for recognizing the wide variation in living costs within the United States itself, for which no special tax treatment is provided. Living costs in the United States also vary considerably, and those who are compensated for the added cost of living in expensive areas - 5 of the United States must pay a higher percentage of their income in taxes even though they do not necessarily enjoy greater purchasing power than those with lower incomes in relatively inexpensive areas of the United States. For example, living costs in Alaska and Hawaii are substantially higher than they are in Mississippi and Alabama. Although overseas living costs often exceed the costs of living in even the most expensive parts of the United States, equity considerations alone would not necessarily dictate that overseas Americans be treated differently from residents of the United States. But when these issues of equity are combined with the competitive realities facing many overseas Americans, special consideration seems advisable. Indeed, these competitive realities facing overseas Americans can have important consequences for our trade balance. Unlike Americans working within the United States, Americans working overseas are often subject to higher tax burdens than persons of other nationalities in the same income bracket. Because the United States is virtually unique in taxing the earned income of its overseas citizens, Americans working in a country imposing low tax rates must pay higher taxes than citizens of other nations living in that country. In countries imposing taxes comparable to or higher than those in the United States, Americans are not placed at a disadvantage by virtue of U.S. taxes since the local tax system acts to equalize the taxes paid by local residents, - 6American or otherwise. As you know, Americans are permitted to credit such foreign income taxes paid against their federal income tax liability, and, thus, are not subjected to double taxation. These points may be simply illustrated: An American and a French citizen living in New York City pay approximately the same income taxes assuming they have comparable incomes and situations; this same relative position holds true if they move to Stockholm, Sweden, because of the fact that Swedish income taxes are higher than United States income taxes. But these same individuals living in Jeddah, »n Saudia Arabia bear very different tax burdens. Although them American in Jeddah continues to pay U.S. income taxes, the Frenchman living in Jeddah does not pay any income taxes, ri either to France or to Saudia Arabia. This basic disparity supports treating the earned income of overseas Americans differently from the earned incomes of United States residents. The consequences of this disparity for our trade balance are difficult to quantify. To the extent that overseas Americans must bear a heavier tax burden than other nationals, they either will expect higher compensation or must accept less take-home pay than others with comparable incomes. In either case, the result is to foster the replacement of Americans in overseas employment by nationals of other countries. When overseas Americans are replaced by foreign nationals, the U.S. economy loses an employment opportunity and the remittances to the U.S. which normally accompany such - 7 employment. However, from a trade perspective there can be even more important adverse effects. From my own experience in living and doing business abroad, I know that an American engineer is much more likely to specify American products, which he has used and with which he is familiar, than a French engineer who is familiar with French products. The overseas employment of an American engineer thus creates jobs in the United States. Given the falling share of the U.S. in world manufactures trade, and our present trade deficit, we need the exports that are created by the employment of overseas Americans. The Administration proposal does not totally eliminate the disparity in the tax treatment of overseas Americans and persons of other nationalities. The disparity is rooted in our citizenship approach to taxation. But our proposal ameliorates that disparity. By recognizing excess overseas costs in the tax law, Americans residing in countries where they would experience the most extreme tax disparity in comparison with nationals of other countries would obtain the largest tax benefits while those experiencing relatively small disparities would receive lesser benefits. In particular, our proposal will confer a significant portion of its tax benefits on Americans working in the Middle East, where there is a considerable promise of generating U.S. exports. Reasonable people may differ on how to resolve the competing considerations which arise in formulating tax policy - 8 in this area. We believe the Administration's proposal represents a fair and practical solution to this important problem. Mr. Chairman, I will be happy to answer questions. REMARKS BY W. MICHAEL BLUMENTHAL SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY AT THE ANNUAL CONFERENCE OF THE FINANCIAL ANALYSTS FEDERATION BAL HARBOUR, FLORIDA, MAY 8, 1978 Today's subject for discussion, capital formation, raises some of the most vexing and important economic problems facing the country. Like college football, economic policy has too many candidates for the "number one" position: inflation, unemployment, growth, poverty — a parade of problems, each vying for priority attention. In this spirited rivalry, capital formation often gets shoved to one side. In the popular mind, it is too often labelled a "business issue" and for that reason assumed to be of only parochial concern. This is unfortunate, for the subject, despite all its technicalities, boils down to questions of overriding public importance: Are we saving enough? Is our financial system adequately tapping those savings and presenting then in optimal form to those wishing to make productive use of them? Is the resultant real investment sufficient to our future needs, both in volume and in composition? Unless we are doing each of these things — saving enough, passing those savings optimally through the financial system, and then investing them wisely — we are going to find ourselves in serious, long term trouble. I wish I could say with confidence that we are doing each of these things and doing them well. But my conclusion is exactly the opposite. In my judgment, this economy shows dangerous signs of underinvestment and misinvestment. As with every important issue in economics, the evidence is much more fragmentary and murky than we'd like. But the record here cannot be explained away. What it says is that we are not laying an adequate foundation for our future prosperity. Let me begin with the evidence on savings. For some time n ow, American households have been saving no more than 6 percent of their disposable income. We are, in that basic respect, the quintessential "consumer society." This—we are told by all B-886 -2prophets—is where every other successful nation is heading, or wishes to head. I wonder. Our 6 percent looks very strange in international comparisons. The Canadians save 10 percent of personal disposable income, the British 14 percent, the Germans 15 percent, the French 17 percent, the Japanese 25 percent. These are not comforting figures. Of course, they do not tell the whole story. The low savings rate of American consumers has traditionally been balanced by the relatively high savings rate of American business. By international standards, our business sector finances an exceptionally large share of its capital formation through internal cash flow. The problem is that, while our personal savings rate has remained low, the financial self reliance of our business firms has apparently suffered a secular decline. In the mid-1960's, the flow of internal funds just about matched the fixed and variable capital expenditures of our business firms. By 1977, however, internal funds stretched to cover only about 80 percent of capital spending. Whether we look at personal savings or business savings, whether we compare ourselves internationally or to our own past experence, we arrive at the same conclusion: We are not setting aside enough of today's income for tomorrow's growth. We are skimping on our future. The growing dependence of our busines firms on external financing leads me to the second area of inquiry: the fitness of our financial system. As business looks increasingly to the financial markets to fund its investment, those markets assume central importance to our prospects for capital formation. We have of course exceptionally well developed capital markets, the most sophisticated and efficient in the world. These markets clearly do an excellent job of tapping savings. But do the markets make those savings available in optimal form to businesses wishing to make real investments? Again, the evidence is disquieting. More and more, what the capital markets offer is loans. By contrast, what is needed, more and more, is equity financing. The capital structure of American enterprise increasingly reflects this questionable tilt in the financial system. The ratio of debt to equity for manufacturing companies has risen from about 25 percent in the early 1960's to 40 percent at the end of last year. This piling up of fixed claims makes our businesses much more vulnerable to the swings of the business cycle, in the extreme case by heightening the risk of bankruptcy. An increasing reliance on debt reduces the willingness and ability of companies to venture into untested markets and new technologies. -3- The problem is greatest for new companies, and for small and medium sized ones trying to market new ideas and new technology. For these enterprises, the relative shortage of equity financing translates into an absolute shortage of any kind of capital. They never get started, or they die young, or they sell out swiftly to larger, established concerns. What these financial trends mean no one can say with certainty. But I find it hard to argue with common sense: the fall-off in equity capital, it seems to me, can hardly help but encourage a trend toward dominance by larger companies, a corporate sector abnormally skittish about economic fluctuations, and a dearth of new, small companies dedicated to testing, generating and spreading technological innovations. I turn now to real investment in plant, equipment, and productive processes. This is the crux of the matter. nfThe record here is particularly grim. Consider the period 1960-to-1974, before the last recession. In the United States, non-residential fixed investment averaged 13-1/2 percent of national output. The average was 18 percent for the larger OECD countries. It was 20 percent for West Germany, 25 percent for Japan. As one might expect, these differentials in investment contributed to sharp differentials in average real growth rates over the period: For the U.S., 3.8 percent; for Germany, 4.6 percent; for Japan 9.7 percent. Last year, of course, the situation reversed itself. We grew considerably faster in real terms than most OECD countries. Our rate of growth in real investment, about 8 percent, also outpaced that in many of those countries. But I see little to suggest that this relative success of ours, in climbing out of 1974-75 recession, portends a long term recovery of our growth prospects. For that to occur, a genuine sea change is needed in the trend of private investment. kedly " I V / L C UllO.11 1 Q O U J f C C l l . . J- L. A »3 V C t JT «i» Sm t~r »J \- w. * * v, J. V* -t J. J roore than recenttrends. Looking at the 1970's as a whole, the ^ increase -mv^^aoc in real investment has been less than 2 percent. annual We are very far behind schedule. Unless we begin catching up, and quickly, we will pay a serious price in the 1980's. Our recent investment experience stands in sharp contrast wn uhe 1 9 6 ° l s During those 10 years, productive capital per porker was growing at about 3 percent. In the last five years, has been virtually stagnant. As a consequence, the growth in -4productivity - output per worker - has fallen off by about 25 percent since the 1960's. If this trend persists, we will fail to build plants and to supply tools fast enough to keep our labor force adequately employed. At the same time, we will ensure that every wage increase is inflationary and that each major increment of output runs into inflationary bottlenecks. In a word, we will ensure a future of stagflation. Quite apart from the volume of investment, we have serious problems concerning its composition. There is not time today to explore in any depth whether we are making the right investments, in the right kind of enterprises and in the right sectors. But I do want to mention briefly two of these structural issues. One is that we are now devoting a very sizeable chunk of• our private investment to meeting government regulatory standards. This investment will, in many cases, produce needed social benefits: cleaner air, purer water, a healthier populace. But, like every other desirable product, these things come at a cost, and in some of these areas we may well be reaching a breaking point. Investment in environmental capital now accounts for about 9 percent of investment outlays in the manufacturings sector. If you exclude those mandated expenditures, investment as a share of value added has actually declined in the manufacturing sector since 1966. s Lu My other major concern about the composition of our investment relates to advanced technology. The stakes here are exceptionally high. In international trade, we depend very heavily on our exports of R&D intensive manufactured products. Indeed, in manufactured products that are not R&D-intensive, our trade balance is negative. Unfortunately, our investment patterns are doing far too little to preserve our comparative edge in high technology products. As a share of GNP, R&D spending declined in the United States by more than 25 percent between the mid 1960's and the mid 1970's. Scientists and engineers, as a share of the population, have also declined, while that ratio has increased in the Soviet Union, West Germany, and Japan. The number of U.S. patents granted to foreign residents has doubled. Our acquisition of foreign patents has declined. These are mere straws in the wind; but it seems quite clear to me that the wind is blowing strongly in the wrong direction. Our technological supremacy is not mandated by heaven. It can disappear. Unless we pay close attention to it, and invest in it, it will disappear. All this leads me to the big questions: Why has capital formation, in nearly all its aspects, reached such a sorry state in this country? And what can we do about it? One hears all sorts of sociological explanations: Americans have lost their spirit or nerve; our entrepreneurs have become less entrepreneurial; the genius for invention has fled -5away, across the Pacific; some sort of cultural exhaustion has crept in, fog-like, from across the Atlantic. Such theories are entertaining, but I don't believe them. In my judgement, investment is lagging for the simple reason that it has become less profitable. The rational investor, before he leaps, looks to expected real returns and to the probability of getting them. This vista of return and risk has been deteriorating. After-tax rates of return on capital — reflecting the replacement cost of captial — have declined from around 8 percent in the mid-1960's to between 3 and 3-1/2 percent in recent years. That's a very substantial fall-off. As a percent of corporate product, profits have declined from more than 11 percent in the mid-1960's to around 8 percent in recent years. We are under investing because it no longer pays enough to invest enough. At the same time that real returns have fallen, the riskiness of investment has substantially increased. The sources of uncertainty have been many and powerful. The 1970's brought back the business cycle with a vengeance, and then twisted the cycle so as to give us both unemployment and inflation simultaneously. Government added to the shock by controlling wages and prices. These controls eventually disintegrated, but memories of them have lingered on. All through this period, the government applied layer after layer of complicated new regulations, some cost effective, some clearly not. Perhaps more important, the very process of regulation introduced bureaucratic delays and costly confusions into nearly every productive enterprise in the nation. For many businesses, particularly small and new ones, the gap between a productive idea and a foreseeable profit widened into a forest of red tape. So the sources of our plight are many, but they come down to a simple diagnosis. Profits are too low, and they are too uncertain. How do we turn this situation around? The most important thing is to assure that the fact of, and the causes for, our plight receive the highest level of attention within the federal government. I have made today a number of international comparisons of a statistical nature. But the most important comparison cannot °e quantified. It concerns the atmosphere of relations between government and those responsible for private capital formation. in the case of most of our major trading rivals, these relations are close, supportive, and understanding. In the United States, this has not been the custom. The public and private sectors have viewed each other with a certain, prickly mistrust. This -6has had consequences across the board. The most important consequence is that government has a very imperfect knowledge of what it can do—and what it must refrain from doing—in order to promote capital formation. President Carter is acutely aware of this problem and has elevated the issue of private capital formation to a high level of Administration concern. The White House is conducting an important Presidential review of technological innovation in the American economy. The President has also established a Cabinet-level task force on national export policies, to report within the next few months. The need to increase investment has dominated many meetings of the Cabinet Economic Policy Group, which sets our overall fiscal policies. -1B Given my own deep concerns, I have now established a permanent Treasury task force, at the highest levels, to examine the financial aspects of capital formation and what can be done about the shortage of equity finance. This group will reach beyond the Treasury and integrate, for the first time, the expertise and policy views of the several executive and 3U independent agencies that regulate, and operate in, the nation's capital markets. What the federal government does in and to the financial markets very substantially determines their vigor and efficiency. This task force will give us, finally, a means to analyze and coordinate those federal actions in a coherent fashion. Much of this work is in an early stage. There is a great deal about the problems of capital formation that we simply do not know. But already, some things are clear enough. The first is that government must work to reduce the uncertainties and risks which its own mistakes have injected into the investment process. Above all, this means controlling inflation. Inflation is now, indisputably, the chief threat to our continued prosperity. Bringing it to heel is item one on the Administration's economic agenda, overriding all other concerns. Public attention now centers on a possible re-acceleration of wage and price increases. Preventing a re-acceleration is obviously essential. However, it is also not enough. I am firmly convinced that private investment in this country will remain sub-optimal until we bring down the rate of inflation. Inflation raises construction costs ahead of prices, squeezes profits, generates high interest rates, and - most importantly creates pervasive uncertainties. In such a climate, this economy cannot and will not build adequately for the future. To reduce the cost and riskiness of investment, we must also rethink our approach to government regulation. Before we add further layers off regulation, for whatever purpose, we owe -7it to our furture prosperity to undertake a meticulous audit of the economic trade-offs. Last month, the President put in place, through Executive Order, a stringent inter-agency procedure to assure that just such an analysis takes place, in the case of every new Executive Branch regulation. I personally hope we can move toward a genuine "zero base" regulatory budget — a system of accounting and control to assure that the costs of existing regulations are weighed against the social gains expected from them. In the meantime, we need a significant streamlining of regulatory procedures — to bring a measure of certainty, clarity, and common sense to the daily interaction of government and industry. Mi By acting on inflation and over-regulation, we can reduce the abnormal, economy-wide risks that are retarding investment. The chief drag on investment, however, is low profitability, an inadequate real rate of return on capital. For this problem one of the important remedies has to be tax policy. In constructing the tax package for this year, we consulted exhaustively with all sectors of the business and financial communities and conducted a very thorough examination of the structure of capital income taxation. We reached several major conclusions, shared by nearly everyone we consulted. The key conclusion was that, to increase investment, it is vital to increase the profitability of American industry. This means cutting business taxes — to boost the real rate of return, to provide an increased cash flow, and to improve the ratio of equity to debt on corporate balance sheets. The second conclusion concerned the way taxes should be cut on capital income. We were advised, by virtually every segment of the business and financial communities, that the simplest, most balanced, most effective—and most popular—way to reduce taxes was through broad and general reductions in corporate tax rates. inally, LUL sma-L± Dusmess, we provide simplified procedures for depreciation. -8- Obviously, there are other ways to cut taxes on capital income. In taxation, nothing is simple. We gave careful study to such issues as the special tax rate on capital gains, the double taxation of dividends, the distinction between earned and unearned income, and the problem of inflation adjustments in the tax system. The complex structure of taxes on capital income offers virtually endless opportunity for innovation and tinkering. But the advice we received, uniformly, was to stay away from any such tinkering this year, to keep our package simple, and thereby minimize delay and uncertainty. To alter the intricate structure of capital income taxation is not a job for a short legislative session. Each of the structural issues is technically difficult and politically controversial on its own, and the issues are so closely related to each other that it is not only irresponsible but virtually impossible to alter one piece of the structure without dealing with many other pieces at the same time. For the longer term, a thorough review of this structure is clearly in order. I personally would like to see the double taxation of dividends receive very close attention in any such study. But this, of necessity, requires reconsideration of the capital gains issue and also a review of the present distinction between earned and unearned income in the individual tax system. Obviously, there is no time in this Congress to undertake such an effort. A detour into these structural issues can only endanger the broad consensus needed to enact the President's program of deep, general corporate and individual rate cuts. If that should happen, the prospects for urgently needed, long term investment would be seriously prejudiced. That is why the Administration is strongly resisting any and all efforts to open up the structual issues of capital income taxation. This has been a very rapid tour of a very complicated and controversial subject. At almost every stage, I'm afraid, my conclusions have been rather somber. The facts are inescapable: we are not saving enough; our financial system is providing insufficient equity capital; we are not investing near enough in productive plant, equipment and technological innovation; profits are too low, and they are too uncertain. We must turn this situation around. I am convinced we can do so. The President not only appreciates the problem; he has oriented his entire fiscal policy toward solving it, and he is mobilizing the full resources of the government to subject every aspect of the issue to expert scrutiny. We in the Treasury are fully dedicated to this effort. -9What is now essential is that the Congress and the country also understand the dimensions of these problems. Your program today is an important step in that direction. I congratulate you on your prescience and thank you for the opportunity to participate. FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY SATURDAY, MAY 6, 1978 REMARKS BY HELEN B. JUNZ DEPUTY ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR COMMODITIES AND NATURAL RESOURCES BEFORE THE COMMITTEE ON FOREIGN AFFAIRS CHICAGO COUNCIL ON FOREIGN RELATIONS WOODSTOCK, ILLINOIS United States Trade Relations With Developing Countriels Only a few years ago, we used to discuss trade'relations with developing countries in terms of "trade, not aid," or of how cyclical disturbances that affect demand for primary goods tend to disrupt development'plans.'On the whole, our discussions were'couched in terms of the developing countries' dependence on us. Recently,' however, the focus has shifted and we now hear increasingly about LDC import penetration, with some even talking about "overcompetitive" LDCs. These kinds of concerns have been given further impetus by the massive U.S. trade deficit and by high unemployment in a number of industries/ This has led to considerable pressure for solutions that would shield affected industries from import competition. In this process, however, it is B-887 - 2 often forgotten that the LDCs are not only major suppliers to our markets, but are also among our best customers. Furthermore, the solutions to our external payments and unemployment problems do not lie in closing our borders to foreign competition. The U.S. Trade Deficit yV ' Our trade deficit in 1977 rose to $31 billion and we expect a deficit of similar size in 1978. We cannot and should not look upon such deficits with equanimity. But, we should neither accept them as prima facie evidence of economic weakness on our part nor seek their causes in LDC competitiveness. First, we must not forget that the one trade surplus we have registered since the. oil price increases of 1973-74 — that of 1975 — reflected the trough of the deepest recession we have experienced since World War II. Since then, we have not only have recaptured our previous peak level of output, but have actually surpassed it by 9.3 percent. In addition, we created four million new jobs in 1977 alone and have reduced the unemployment rate to its lowest level since 1974. In our economy, which is increasingly inter-linked with others, such growth is necessarily associated with - 3sizeable increases in imports. Second, in contrast with the healthy growth of our domestic market, foreign economies have made much less progress in absorbing spare capacity. Consequently, our export markets have been growing slowly. The third, and most important, factor in the shift in our trading position is our high foreign energy bill. U.S. oil imports cost $45 billion in 1977 — up from less than $5 billion as recently as 1972. Increased import volume alone would have raised the bill only to $9 billion; higher prices account for the remaining $36 billion. While our sales to OPEC countries have increased, our trade deficit with them has amounted to about $20 billion. As long as oil exporting nations cannot spend all they earn on imports of goods and services, we, as other major oil importing nations, should expect to run continuing deficits with them. However, $20 billion clearly is excessive. Some part of our deficit with OPEC, however, has not been demand-related. The volume of our oil imports, in contrast to developments in virtually all other oil-importing countries, has risen because of reduced domestic energy output as well as higher domestic consumption. Over the last five years, domestic production has declined by 1.5 million barrels per day, while consumption has increased by 2.5 million barrels per day. Roughly 40 percent of the increase in the volume of U.S. imports since 1972 can thus - 4 be attributed to reduced production and 60 percent to increased oil consumption. As a consequence, for every one percent increase in GNP, our oil imports have grown by two percent. The erosion of energy output in the lower 48 States, of course, was underway before the oil price increases. It it is now being partly offset by rising Alaskan oil production. Consequently, our dependence on foreign oil — now around one-half of total requirements — is no longer increasing. But there is no question that it remains much too high. Fourth, we may have seen some deterioration in our competitive strength, mainly because we have not made as much progress on reducing inflation as is needed. Recent changes in exchange rates, however, have improved our relative price position vis-a-vis foreign suppliers. In sum, the major factors in the large increase in our trade deficit are: (1) relatively strong economic growth at home; (2) relatively slow growth of our export markets; (3) large energy imports; and (4) insufficient progress on reducing inflation. Clearly, we must continue our policies of sustained growth which requires accepting the import increases associated with it. We must guard against a resurgence of inflationary pressures and must take advantage of the compe titive potential created by the recent depreciation of the - 5 dollar. Finally, and most important, it is imperative that we address our energy problem in a fundamental manner. Trade Creation Versus Trade Restriction While appropriate macro-economic policies here and abroad and an active energy policy will do much to reduce our trade deficit, there remains the need for adjustment, or accommodation, to structural changes in the world economy. During the last generation, the world trading system remained open, and in fact was liberalized in the face of considerable adjustment needs. The most notable adjustment took place in the late 'Forties and early 'Fifties as we moved from a post-war supply shortage to a more normal demand and supply balance. Because of the post-war supply constraints, adjustment to the increase in productive capacity that accompanied post-war reconstruction, particularly in Germany, was achieved relatively easily. The need to adjust to the emergence of Japan as a modern industrial nation in the 1960s posed different problems. These, however, were smoothed by rapid expansion of world demand. During the 'Seventies and 'Eighties, we will need to adjust to the increase in productive capacity that is occuring in a growing number of developing countries. Currently, we face the task of accommodating these changes in a climate of subdued growth, complicated by the external and internal - 6 problems associated with the adjustment to the higher relative price of energy. Under these circumstances, the rapid industrialization of a number of developing countries, particularly as it is concentrated on a relatively small number of industrial sectors, such as textiles, shoes, electronics, steel and more recently shipbuilding, is causing friction in a number of markets. Thus, it is not surprising that certain industries or segments of industry have become increasingly concerned about import competition. And, it may be only natural that many of these concerns are focused on imports from developing countries, which benefit from the double advantage of low wages and preferential tariff treatment. Although these concerns are justified to some extent, they have given rise to the unjustified conclusion that the only way to deal with these problems is to close our border to protect our industries and labor from import competition. It is true that in developing countries, wages are significantly lower than in the United States. But these wage differentials in themselves do not indicate anything about competitive positions. Higher U.S. wages reflect our higher productivity and our industrial structure, which are the mainspring of our greater wealth and higher living standards. Our output embodies not only a very large amount of physical - 7 capital investment, but also an enormous amount of investment in human capital. As a result, our competitive performance and our comparative advantage are greatest in the areas of high technology goods and product innovation, and least in areas requiring the input of unskilled labor. This is evident across the whole spectrum of economic activity, be it agriculture, industry or services. In the older, more basic industries, higher wage levels may handicap our competitive position, but our high level of productivity — as distinct from change in productivity — continues to assure a certain market share even in those sectors. Nevertheless, there is no question that with growing industrialization in LDCs, the industrialized countries cannot expect to maintain the same dominant position in world markets to which they have become accustomed. We, as other developed countries, must expect to meet increasing competition from developing countries in our own and in world markets. However, I believe proponents of the protectionist argument view these developments in a one-dimensional way. As developing countries become more highly industrialized, they also become increasingly profitable markets for our products and absorb a wider range of goods and services. On the same basis, we reject the assertion that our foreign aid and investment abroad are detrimental to our own economic interests. Aid and investment flows to the developing countries — like Marshall Plan aid to Europe — assist in raising per capita - 8 incomes and foreign exchange earnings in recipient countries. As a consequence, these countries are better able to satisfy growing pressure for increased standards of living at home and in the process buy more goods and services from abroad. As purchasing power rises, so will social and economic aspirations, and gaps between wage payments among developed and developing countries will begin to narrow. We are already seeing some evidence of this process. For example, although levels of wage compensation, on average, continue to be well below those of the industrialized countries, hourly compensation in manufacturing industries in a number of rapidly developing countries, such as Brazil and Korea, have tended to double over a two to three year span, while increases in developed countries tend to average around six to nine percent per annum. The consequences of industrialization and concomitant rises in per capita income are reflected in the substantial growth of the import markets of developing countries. Recently, of course, the limelight has been on the increased purchases of oil exporting countries. But the markets of non-OPEC developing countries also have expanded rapidly. U.S. exports to all LDCs rose from $12-3/4 billion in 1970 - 72 to $41-3/4 billion in 1977, lending considerable support to economic activity during the recession. Although exports to OPEC rose from about $2-1/2 billion in 1970 - 72 to $14 billion in 1977, those to non-OPEC LDCs rose to an even greater extent -- from $10-1/4 billion to $27-3/4 billion. In fact, we often tend to overlook that as a market the - 9 non-OPEC LDCs are more important to us than the entire European Community. Non-OPEC LDCs account for about onequarter of our total export market, as well as for onequarter of our exports of manufactured goods. The EC accounts for more than one-fifth of total U.S. exports and for a shade under one-fifth of exports of manufactured goods. When OPEC is included, LDCs account for more than one-third of our total exports and almost two-fifths of exports of manufactures. Interestingly enough, our exports of manufactures to non-OPEC LDCs have grown faster than our manufactured imports from them. Exports rose from $7 billion in 1970 - 72 to $18-1/2 billion in 1976, while our imports grew from $4 billion to $13 billion, raising our surplus to $5-1/2 billion. This illustrates the point that with growing industrialization, both imports and exports of manufactured goods expand as intra-industry trade intensifies. Although all LDCs have shared in the rise in our imports, the major portion, about $11 billion of the total $13 billion of manufactured imports from LDCs is concentrated among eight suppliers. These are: Brazil, Mexico, Taiwan, Hong Kong, Singapore, Philippines, South Korea and Malaysia. Our structure of trade with these countries has changed over time with the importance of manufactured goods increasing. Whereas in 1971 - 72, manufactured goods accounted for - 10 55 percent of our imports from these countries, by 1976 that share had risen to 65 percent. Total imports into the United States from these countries rose from about $6 billion in 1970 - 72 to $21 billion in 1977, an average annual growth rate of close to 25 percent. This approximates the annual growth rate of their exports to all industrial countries. Consequently, these countries account for the major portion of the expansion of LDC import penetration into industrial country markets. In addition, they are turning out to be formidable competitors in third world markets, particularly in OPEC countries. Brazil, for example, has captured a significant share of the automobile market in OPEC. Looking at our export performance in the markets of OPEC, it appears that we have been losing some competitive edge. Between 1970 - 72 and 1977, we experienced a loss of market shares in almost all major commodity categories, except in electrical machinery. In a number of these markets, particularly Venezuela and Saudi Arabia, we have long been the dominant supplier. It is not surprising that we should experience some diminution of our market shares as other countries discover them to be lucrative markets and compete more fervently to offset their oil deficits by sales of goods and services. Thus, we, as well as the British and -lithe French, have lost market shares in OPEC especially to Germany, Japan and Italy, who have tended to increase their shares from a relatively low base. But, part of our loss in OPEC market shares has been in countries which experience particularly dynamic growth — the so-called "high absorbers" — and are not part of our traditional markets. We apparently have been unable or unwilling to capture a significant share of this rising demand. For example, we are currently spending about $6 billion, largely on oil, in Nigeria and have become Nigeria's most important customer. Nevertheless, out of total industrial country exports of $7-3/4 billion to Nigeria, we supply less than $1 billion. However, when we look at our competitive performance in the markets of non-oil developing countries, it appears that we have done relatively well. In real terms, we have either maintained or increased our average 1970 - 72 market share. When we break down our market shares by commodities, we also appear to have done well, except in automobiles. One particularly interesting trend is that we have increased our exports of consumer goods significantly since the dollar devaluation of the early 1970s. While consumer goods still represent only about 16 percent of our total exports, it is evident that the downward trend of the 1960s of our market share has been reversed. - 12 The most dynamic markets among the non-oil LDCs have been those of the eight rapidly growing countries noted earlier. Industrial countries' exports to these eight LDCs rose from $13-1/2 billion in 1970 - 72 to $40 billion in 1977. U.S. market shares improved slightly as our exports rose from $5-1/4 billion in 1970 - 72 to $15-1/2 billion in 1977. Our performance in 1977, however, fell well below the average annual rate of growth of over 20 percent for the period and also below that of other industrial countries. To some extent, this reflected the stabilization programs adopted by Brazil and Mexico, two of our most important customers, but also some loss in market share in some of the other countries. Adjustment Needs and Policy Responses The emergence of some LDCs as increasingly important and complex trading nations may have some implications for the way in which we think about the division of labor among countries. We normally view the comparative advantage of less developed countries as residing in their natural resource endowment and in the fact that labor is relatively cheap. But, this view may no longer be fully adequate. The fast growth of capital formation in most of these countries means that competition is manifesting itself not only in terms of the relative cost of labor, raw materials and transportation, but perhaps to an even greater extent - 13 in terms of competition of modern capital equipment against an aging capital structure in the more mature economies. The fact that private investment is continuing to lag in most of the industrial economies, while a number of the newer industrializing countries provide promising investment opportunities, strengthens this argument as does the determination of a number of OPEC countries to increase their industrial potential. Continuing pressures of competition from developing countries, thus will be a fact of life for the foreseeable future. But, defensive actions against such competition would only be counterproductive. Developing countries, already among our most important customers, are likely to become even more so. Even the most optimistic forecasts of growth for the OECD area do not foresee growth rates much above those achieved during the last couple of years; and the explosive growth of OPEC markets has begun to stabilize. Consequently, the non-OPEC LDCs are likely to furnish the most dynamic markets for exports of industrial countries for some time to come. U.S. import restraints vis-a-vis LDCs could, therefore, result in a considerable loss of high wage export jobs and income. First, because income losses abroad would cut into foreign purchasing power and second, because such restrictive - 14 actions could easily spread across borders. But, all the benefits from keeping an open trading system can be realized only if we maintain our competitive position in these expanding markets. Positive adjustment to the growing industrial potential of LDCs requires not only that we avoid an increase of rigidities in our economic system, but that we act to reduce them. Where there is a legitimate need for assistance to domestic producers in case of substantial injury from import competition due to unfair foreign trade practices or disruptive changes in trade flows, measures should aim to facilitate adjustment rather than shield the economy from competition. And such measures should be decided on a case-by-case basis. More generally, we need to assure flexible responses of the economy to competition at home and abroad. This can best be achieved through policies of sustained non-inflationary growth on the macro side and policies aimed at reducing risks and uncertainties associated with government regulations on the micro side. Positive adjustment must, however, be a two-way street. The success of a number of developing countries in world markets reflects the fact that they have invested in export oriented industries and have channelled their savings largely into productive investment rather than consumption. However, past experience shows that at a certain point in - 15 the development process, adjustment measures need to be taken so as to avoid the emergence of chronic surpluses, which reduce the welfare of the domestic population and put strains on the international trading system. Thus, some of the surplus LDCs have recognized the desirability of reducing their surpluses. In general, they have tended t£ reduce tariffs and liberalize imports rather than remove export subsidies or appreciate their exchange rates. It may be natural for them to believe their surpluses only to be temporary and therefore to be cautious in liberalizing their trade relations. But for some, the time may have come when it is appropriate to begin to accept more fully the general rules and obligations applying to trading nations under the GATT and the IMF. The developing countries seek to establish a new set of trading rules in the current Multilateral Trade Negotiations (MTNs) that would recognize permanently preferential treatment for their products in industrialized countries' markets and would permit protection of their own markets for the benefit of their "infant industries." Institutionalizing "special and differential treatment" for developing countries in a generalized way would be harmful to the international trading system. There are circumstances and cases which - 16 temporary. As the development process proceeds and countries emerge as important trading nations, they must increasingly undertake the full obligations of the trading system. This means not only gradual reduction in preferential status, but also an increasing degree of reciprocity for tariff reductions and other concessions extended by the industrialized countries. This would include a graduation from the benefits extended by generalized systems of preferences and reductions in subsidies to exports and in tariff barriers. Not only would a gradual acceptance of the rules of the international trading system actually benefit those developing countries that are increasingly in a position to accept them, but it would also assure that those developing countries which continue to need the benefit of unilateral trade concessions can, in fact, continue to receive them. For example, the eight countries discussed earlier receive about three-quarters of the benefits extended under our generalized system of preferences. The political support for continued extension of such preferences is not strong, to say the least, under current circumstances. If the lion share of such benefits continues to accrue to countries that no longer appear to need them, and for commodities that - 17 tend to compete with the weak sectors in our economy, such preferences may well erode and, as a consequence, be withdrawn from those who need them and those who no longer appear to need them alike. Our trade relations with developing countries indeed should be based on differential treatment, that is, we must differentiate among LDCs, so as to be able to continue to accord "preferential and differential" treatment to some. For those who have become successful trading nations, active participation in international trade must increasingly come to mean active and" more equal participation in the rules and obligations that keep the system liberal. Only in this way can protectionist pressures in industrialized countries be resisted and special benefits continue to be extended to those who need them most. o 0 o Table 1. Exporter: Share o:f Exports to OPEC 1977 1976 1970-72 Share of Industrial Countries' Exports to LDCs (Percent Based on 1975, Dollars) Share of Exports to Non-OPEC LDCS Total Non-OPEC LDCs 1970-72 F97"6 VTTT Africa Latin America 1970-72 "T37T5— wrr 1970-72—Tm Asia 1970-72 vrrr —T97o" 1977 24.8 23.2 22.0 30.5 32.6 30.9 45.3 49.7 48.8 10.3 10.7 10.2 27.4 29.3 28.0 Canada 2.3 1.5 1.5 2.8 2.3 2.4 4.0 3.6 3.5 1.0 1.2 1.1 2.4 2.0 2.2 Japan 14.5 18.1 18.1 20.5 22.1 22.7 7.9 10.2 11.0 10.5 6.3 6.7 39.2 42.1 42.1 France 12.4 10.0 9.7 9.5 10.2 10.6 6.4 6.4 6.9 27.5 32.7 32.4 3.7 4.2 4.1 West Germany 13.1 15.8 16.7 10.1 10.0 9.7 12.1 10.6 10.1 11.1 12.5 12.7 7.5 6.9 7.2 7.9 8.6 9.1 4.4 3.9 4.2 4.3 3.7 3.6 7.5 6.7 7.5 2.0 1.6 1.8 12.3 10.1 10.2 10.1 7.9 7.9 7.4 5.4 5.4 13.5 10.6 9.7 9.7 7.0 6.8 Belgium 2.4 2.5 2.9 2.3 2.1 2.3 1.9 1.4 1.4 5.0 4.2 4.3 1.6 1.6 2.1 Netherlands 3.7 3.3 3.1 3.0 2.6 2.6 2.7 2.0 2.2 4.8 5.1 4.9 1.9 1.5 1.5 Sweden 1.5 1.9 1.6 1.9 1.6 1.6 2.3 2.1 1.7 3.0 2.6 3.1 1.0 1.0 1.0 Switzerland 2.6 2.2 2.4 2.2 1.9 2.0 2.6 2.2 2.2 1.5 1.6 2.0 2.0 1.6 1.8 Ireland .1 .2 .3 .1 .1 .2 .1 .1 .2 .1 .2 .2 .0 .1 .1 Austria .7 1.1 .9 .5 .6 .5 .4 .4 .4 .6 .8 .9 .4 .4 .3 Denmark .8 .7 .7 1.1 .8 .8 1.3 1.1 1.2 1.6 .9 1.0 .6 .3 .4 Finland .5 .4 .5 .4 .3 .3 .6 .4 .3 .3 .5 .5 .2 .1 .1 Norway .4 .4 .4 .7 .9 1.1 .7 .7 1.1 1.8 3.4 2.9 .3 .3 .5 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 United States Italy United Kingdom Total Table 2. Shares of Industrial Countries* Exports to OPEC, by Commodity* (Percentages based on current dollars) Agricultural Manufactures Raw Materials Total Motor Vehicles Consumer Goods Heavy Machinery Electrical Machinery 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 45.7 43.6 40.5 28.9 23.4 22.7 13.5 7.2 32.5 29.5 20.8 24.3 24.2 21.3 Germany 3.5 6.0 9.0 13.1 15.1 17.8 6.9 7.3 17.6 22.8 17.4 19.8 19.9 23.2 Japan 3.5 3.2 6.4 12.5 18.0 20.4 44.8 55.7 8.4 10.0 14.0 13.3 13.7 22.9 12.2 13.3 9.1 5.8 12.2 10.3 10.1 8.0 11.4 10.7 13.4 11.0 11.6 10.4 United Kingdom 8.9 8.9 10.0 7.6 13.7 10.5 8.5 10.2 14.0 10.4 16.5 13.5 14.9 7.7 Italy 3.9 4.2 5.8 6.3 8.5 8.7 14.4 10.2 9.3 8.4 7.9 7.0 5.1 5.3 Canada 5.9 2.9 8.9 11.5 2.1 1.7 .1 .2 .6 .9 2.0 1.4 7.2 4.3 Belgium/Luxemburg 2.4 2.1 3.3 4.3 2.6 2.7 1.0 .9 2.0 1.9 1.6 3.5 .5 .6 10.2 11.4 3.0 3.7 2.4 2.5 .5 .2 1.9 2.7 1.5 1.2 .9 1.0 .5 .4 3.8 5.9 1.5 2.2 .0 .0 1.2 1.4 4.3 4.5 1.8 3.1 Denmark 3.2 4.0 .4 .3 .6 .5 .1 .1 1.2 1.2 .6 .5 .1 .2 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 Exporter: United States France Netherlands Sweden * Note: Commodities are defined as follows: Agricultural, SITC 0,1, 22 and 4; Raw Materials, SITC 2 (excluding 22 and 266) and 68; Manufactures, SITC 5-9 (excluding 68); Consumer Goods, SITC 84 (clothing), 85 (footwear) and 7241, 7242, 8911 (consumer electronics); Heavy Machinery, SITC 71 (excluding 7114 and 7115); Electrical Machinery, SITC 72 (excluding 7241 and 7242); Motor Vehicles, SITC 732 and 7115. Table 3. Shares of Industrial Countries' Exports to Non-OPEC LDCs, by Commodity* (Percent based on current dollars) Agricultural Raw Materials Manufactures Total Consumer Goods Heavy Machinery Electrical Machinery Motor Vehicles 1970-72 1970-72 1976 26.4 23.6 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 1970-72 1976 48.8 58.6 51.4 55.3 26.7 28.3 25.5 33.7 31.3 33.9 Germany 2.8 3.0 4.0 4.1 11.3 11.2 4.0 4.7 16.5 17.3 10.3 9.8 14.9 16.3 Japan 7.6 3.5 13.8 16.8 29.0 30.7 47.4 42.3 17.8 18.0 24.5 24.0 20.2 26.8 France 10.8 12.9 4.5 4.6 8.8 9.9 12.4 9.4 7.2 8.4 9.0 10.3 11.3 11.3 United Kingdom 6.8 5.2 5.3 3.0 11.0 8.1 5.7 4.5 13.1 9.9 11.4 7.4 17.0 11.7 Italy 2,2 1.1 1.6 1.2 4,7 4.1 3.4 3.2 6.9 5.8 4.4 3.7 5.1 4.9 10.3 6.2 13.4 10.7 1.8 1.5 .6 .3 1.2 1.1 2.2 1.6 2.1 1.1 Belgium/Luxemburg 2.2 2.5 2.1 1.5 2.3 2.0 .7 .6 1.6 1.6 2.0 1.2 .7 .9 Netherlands 5.9 5.1 1.5 1.0 1.9 1.8 .3 1.1 1.5 1.4 .8 .5 .5 .6 .2 .5 2.0 1.6 1.9 1.9 .0 .0 1.8 1.8 4.3 3.7 1.6 2.5 Denmark 2.3 1.4 .2 .7 .5 .1 .1 1.1 .8 .4 .4 .3 .3 Total 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 )0.0 100.0 1976 Exporter: United States Canada Sweden 30.6 37.4 *Note: Commodities are defined as follows: Agricultural, SITC 0, 1, 22 and 4; Raw Materials, SITC 2 (excluding 22 and 266) and 68; Manufactures, SITC 5-9 (excluding 68); Consumer Goods, SITC 84 (clothing), 85 (footwear) and 7241, 7242, 8911 (consumer electronics); Heavy Machinery, SITC 71 (excluding 7114 and 7115); Electrical Machinery, SITC 72 (excluding 7241 and 7242); Motor Vehicles, SITC 732 and 7115. Table 4. Imports by Industrial Countries 3 U.S. from Eight Selected LDCs and From the World ($ million and percent) Imports by Industrial Countries Exporter: 1977 Value ($million) Imports by United States • •71- •76 Ave. Annual Giowth 1977 Annual Growth 1977 Value •71-•76 Ave. Annual Growth ($million) 1977 Annual Growth Taiwan 7,059 30.0% 19.5% 4,052 28.5% 22.9% Hong Kong 6,683 21.9% 12.4% 3,157 18.6% 19.8% Singapore 2,649 36.1% 24.0% 916 33.7% 25.8% Philippines 2,937 14.7% 23.8% 1,230 14.1% 23.7% Brazil 8,018 19.7% 25.8% 2,392 17.6% 26.7% Mexico 5,857 19.9% 28.2% 4,759 20.2% 30.2% South Korea 7,403 44.3% 19.8% 3,175 37.2% 20.0% Malaysia 4,608 26.6% 23.0% 1,393 27.3% 40.1% 733,674 21.0% 13.4% 156,708 21.0% 20.9% 45,214 25.3% 21.4% 21,074 23.4% 25.1% World 8 Selected LDCs Table 5. Exports by Industrial Countries 6 U.S. to Eigfot Selected LDCs and to the World ($ million and percent) Exports by united States 1977 Value (fmillion) •71-*76 Ave. Annual Growth 1977 Annual Growth Taiwan 5,105 22.5% 11.91 1,798 24.1% 10.0% Hong Kong 5,361 17.1% 23.0% 1,292 20.5% 15.9% Singapore 4,157 21.8% 17.9% 1,172 25.2% 21.5% Philippines 2,618 18.3% 5.3% 876 17.9% 7.0% Brazil 6,535 22.1% -7.6% 2,482 22.5% -11.6% Mexico 6,620 21.6% -4.6% 4,807 23.0% -3.71 South Korea 7,535 25.6% 33.6% 2,371 24.1% 17.71 Malaysia 2,218 24.5% 17.9% 561 42.6% 4.7t 689,333 20.1% 13.4% 120,172 20.3% 4.51 8 Selected LDCs 40,149 21.7% 10.1% 15,359 23.3% 3.2% Importer: World 1977 Value ($million) •71-'76 Ave. Annual Growth 1977 Annual Growth epartmentoftheTREASURY fiHIHGTOH, D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 Tuesday, M a y 9, 1978 CONTACT: G e o r g e G. Ross (202) 5 6 6 - 2 3 5 6 Treasury D e p a r t m e n t A n n o u n c e s A d v a n c e P u b l i c a t i o n of I n t e r n a t i o n a l B o y c o t t R e p o r t Form FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE The Treasury Depar tment today released a d v a n c e c o p i e s of revised Form 5 7 1 3 , I n t e r n a t i o n a l B o y c o t t R e p o r t , to tax services whose p u b l i c a t i o n s reach tax p r a c t i t i o n e r s . The form is expected to be a v a i l a b l e to all t a x p a y e r s t h r o u g h local district o f f i c e s of the I n t e r n a l R e v e n u e S e r v i c e about June 1, 1 9 7 8 . The T r e asury D e p a r t m e n t also a n n o u n c e d that the time for filing Fo rm 5713 has been e x t e n d e d to J u l y 1 5 , 1978 for taxpayers w h o se income tax r e t u r n s are d u e on J u n e 15, 1978. Filing of Form 5713 As detailed in A n s w e r A - 7 of the I n t e r n a t i o n a l B o y c o t t Guidelines issued J a u a r y 2 0 , 1978 (published J a n u a r y 2 5 , 1978 in 43 FR 3 4 5 4 ) , one copy of Form 5713 should be sent to the Internal R e v e n u e S e r v i c e C e n t e r , 11601 R o o s e v e l t Boulevard, P h i l a d e l p h i a , P e n n s y l v a n i a , 1 9 2 5 5 , and another copy should be attached to the t a x p a y e r ' s income tax return that is filed with the t a x p a y e r ' s c u s t o m a r y I n t e r n a l R e v e n u e Service C e n t e r . Both c o p i e s n o r m a l l y m u s t be filed w h e n the income tax return is d u e , i n c l u d i n g e x t e n s i o n s . Interim Procedures By News Release B-821, dated April 7, 1978, the Treasury Department announced interim p r o c e d u r e s for filing Form 5713 applicable to t a x p a y e r s w h o s e tax r e t u r n s are due in 1978 before June 1 5 , 1 9 7 8 . T h o s e interim filing p r o c e d u r e s also 197ft t 0 t a x p a y e r s w h ° s e tax r e t u r n s are due on J u n e 1 5 , B-888 mrtment of theJREASURY TELEPHONE 566-2041 iSHlNGTON, D.C. 20220 May 8, 1978 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE RESULTS OF TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL AUCTIONS Tenders for $2,302 million of 13-week Treasury bills and for $ 3,401 million of 26-week Treasury bills, both series to be issued on May 11, 1978, were accepted at the Federal Reserve Banks and Treasury today. The details are as follows: RANGE OF ACCEPTED COMPETITIVE BIDS: High Low Average 13-week bills maturing August 10, 1978 26-week bills maturing November 9, 1978 Price Discount Rate Investment Rate 1/ Price 98.370 98.365 98.366 6.448% 6.468% 6.464% 6.65% 6.67% 6.66% 96.486 6.951% 96.465 6.992% 96.468 6.986% Discount Rate Investment Rate 1/ 7.30% 7.35% 7.34% Tenders at the low price for the 13-week bills were allotted 7 Tenders at the low price for the 26-w-ek bills were allotted TOTAL TENDERS RECEIVED AND ACCEPTED BY FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTSAND TREASURY: Location Received Boston New York Philadelphia Cleveland Richmond Atlanta Chicago St. Louis Minneapolis Kansas City Dallas San Francisco $ 31,680,000 4,106,415,000 16,340,000 43,115,000 33,760,000 28,385,000 307,665,000 53,375,000 21,985,000 25,165,000 15,470,000 289,680,000 Treasury 8,285,000 $ Accepted :: Received 21,680,000 2,036,380,000 15,090,000 34,585,000 26,485,000 25,185,000 30,210,000 26,175,000 9,680,000 23,780,000 12,470,000 31,830,000 >' $ 33,555,000 J: 5,194,805,000 >' 48,085,000 141,015,000 : 35,390,000 '23,400,000 :: 294,895,000 :: 45,990,000 J 20,275,000 :: 23,450,000 : 15,460,000 : 321,255,000 : 8,275,000 TOTALS $4,981,320,000 $2,301,825,000 a/ : 7,760,000 $6,205,335,000 /IiM S 3 6 3 > 9 1 0 > 0 0 0 noncompetitive tenders from the public. nc udes $209,425,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. equivalent coupon-issue yield. •889 Accepted $ 13,555,000 3,139,005,000 12,035,000 55,595,000 15,390,000 21,150,000 53,180,000 17,990,000 4,275,000 23,450,000 11,960,000 25,905,000 7,760,000 $3,401,250,000b/ FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 8, 1978 Contact: Alvin M. Hattal 202/566-8381 TREASURY LIBERALIZES RULES FOR CUBANS TRAVELING HERE The Treasury Department said today that it is liberalizing the rules involving transactions by Cubans traveling to, from, and within the United States. The action applies to those entering the United States on visas issued by the Department of State• The transactions affected include payment of travel and living expenses in the United States, as well as other transactions directly related *to that travel, such as arranging domestic charter flights and hotel reservations. The authorization does not apply to any transactions involving transfers of any money ot other property to Cuba. The Treasury also said it will issue specific licenses in appropriate cases for non-travel transactions related to cultural exchange events (such as public exhibitions and performances). Specific licenses will be available for transactions with Cuban nationals participating in events in the United States and transactions by U. S. nationals participating in events in Cuba. Specific licenses issued under this policy will not authorize any transfers of money or other property to Cuba, apart from ordinary travel expenditures. Notice of this action will appear in the May 9 Federal Register. o B-890 0 o FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY May 10, 1978 — 10:00 a.m. EDST STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE RICHARD J. DAVIS ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR ENFORCEMENT AND OPERATIONS BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON ADMINISTRATIVE LAW AND GOVERNMENTAL RELATIONS HOUSE JUDICIARY COMMITTEE Mr. Chairman and Members of the Subcommittee: It is a pleasure to appear before you this morning to discuss Treasury's position on HR 9219, the bill to amend the Federal Tort Claims Act, and the proposed amendments to that bill. Treasury supports the approach followed in HR 9219 as originally introduced and in the amendments proposed by the Department of Justice. The proposals which this Committee are now considering involve an attempt to balance varying, and sometimes competing, concerns. We desire a system of justice which compensates citizens whose rights have been violated, which holds Government officials accountable for their actions and which provides a deterence against illegal actions by those we entrust with the responsibility of enforcing our laws. It must be a system which has both the fact, and the appearance, of fairness. Any system designed to deal with citizen allegations of violations of their constitutional rights must also recognize, however, certain other realities. The responsibility of enforcing the law — whether in the hands of prosecutors, police, investigators, or tax collectors — always brings the Government official into confrontation with individual citizens. And it generally brings about this confrontation in the context of the citizen being suspect of, accused of, or involved in some wrongdoing. B-891 -2In this situation overreaching by the Government official is possible. At the same time, however, this is the kind of situation which breeds false accusations and complaints by citizens who simply do not like being in this position. If we want our law enforcers to do their jobs effectively, the system must also be fair to them. It must not allow them to become victims of a desire for revenge on the part of those they have properly investigated, arrested or prosecuted. We believe that the approach taken in this bill and the proposed amendment is an appropriate balance of these considerations. One principal effect of HR 9219 would be to enlarge the liability of the United States under the Federal Tort Claims Act to include actions which violate an individual's constitutional rights. Giving persons whose constitutional rights have been invaded a right of action against the Government, where they now have only a right against the Government employee, reflects the continuing attempt to find appropriate ways to protect individuals whose rights have been violated by the Government. This change recognizes that in reality the officer is usually acting for the Government in these situations. It also recognizes that the opportunity for citizens to actually receive compensation will be increased if the Government is a defendant. Another principal effect of these proposals is to protect Government employees from personal liability for damages they may cause while performing their official duties. This is done by establishing a procedure by which actions filed against Federal employees personally for damages caused by something done under the color of their office are transferred into Tort Claims actions against the Government. This provision will enable officers to perform their responsibilities, which often involve difficult situations, without concern that they will have to personally defend claims — even when they turn out to be baseless — which may be made. It also recognizes the fact that the Government is a more solvent potential defendant than the law enforcement officer who, in the case where serious damage is found, is unlikely to be able to afford the resulting judgment. -3The Government official - wrongdoer is not, however left free by these proposals. In the first instance he would be liable to disciplinary action and, where appropriate, criminal prosecution. The Department of Justice has also recommended an amendment to HR 9219 to allow persons whose constitutional rights have been violated to initiate, and to participate in, inquiries into the conduct of employees whose actions were the basis for the claims. The amendment would allow this where the claim resulted in a monetary settlement or a judgment paid by the United States. Under the amendment the complaining citizen can also appeal decisions on the disciplinary actions taken against Government employees to the Civil Service Commission and ultimately to court. This amendment reflects the fact that there is a need to continue to make certain that individual wrongdoers are held accountable if similar conduct is to be deterred in the future. The Treasury Department thus supports this proposal. In doing so, however, we are not unmindful of certain risks inherent in this approach. Settlement of a dispute does not in the world of litigation always mean that a wrong has taken place. This is particularly true since the Justice Department has agreed that the Government will not have the "good faith" defense now available to the employee. Settlement could however, trigger a series of potential actions against the employee which could require him to defend himself in both administrative and judicial tribunals. Nevertheless, we believe that the approach taken in this bill, and the proposed amendment, is a sound one, we support it and we are prepared to work with the Justice Department and the Congress to resolve any remaining issues. In addition to this amendment concerning disciplinary actions against employees, the Department of Justice has proposed additional amendments. Some would amend sections 3 and 4 of HR 9219. If adopted, these would meet objections that have been made to the provisions of the bill in the form it was originally introduced. In addition to some technical changes in the language, these proposed amendments would provide in constitutional tort cases, that a claimant may recover attorney's fees and costs, that the United States may not assert as a defense the "good faith" belief of the employee in the lawfulness of his conduct, and that class action may be used. Treasury supports each of the proposed amendments. -4Additional amendments have been proposed by the Department of Justice that would change sections 6 and 8 of HR 9219 to limit the effect of the exceptions to liability provided for in 28 USC §2680 to common law tort cases, and prohibit the urging of these exceptions as a defense in constitutional tort cases. Treasury particularly urges the adoption of these amendments. In sum, the Treasury Department strongly believes in the need for a system which holds Government officials accountable for their acts, and is fair to both them and to our citizens. We will continue to implement this philosophy within the Department and to work with this Committee to assure that we are doing the best we can. I will be glad to answer any questions you may have. oOo garment of theJREASURY SHINGTQM.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 12:00 NOON, EST TUESDAY,MAY 9, 1978 REMARKS BY THE HONORABLE C. FRED BERGSTEN ASSISTANT SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR INTERNATIONAL AFFAIRS BEFORE THE BRAZILIAN-AMERICAN CHAMBER OF COMMERCE NEW YORK, NEW YORK ECONOMIC RELATIONS BETWEEN THE UNITED STATES AND BRAZIL: A FOCUS ON TRADE The economic relationship between Brazil and the United States has undergone substantial change in recent years. Today Brazil is clearly one of the most important participants in the international economic system. We fully recognize and welcome that position, as the basis for strengthened cooperation between LO our countries in a wide range of policy areas and a^s a basis for helping to achieve a more effectively functioning world economy. In the past, economic discussions between the Unii:e3 States and Brazil have tended to focus on bilateral relations between our two countries. Today, I am pleased to report that there are no major bilateral economic problems between us. This is doubly fortunate because our economic relationship B-892 o - 2 should now, in any event, focus increasingly on the global roles of the United States and Brazil — and on our potential contributions to the future strength of the world economy, for our own benefit as well as that of other nations. In recognition of the sharp distinctions which exist within the universe of less developed countries (LDCs), we will henceforth refer to Brazil and other advanced developing countries as ADCs — as opposed to the poorer developing countries (PDCs). These ADCs in particular have as vital an interest as our own in the future of the international economy: in the continued operation of an open international trading system; in maintaining stable international monetary arrangements; in ensuring adequate rates of growth of global production; and in assisting the poorest countries in eradicating extreme poverty. The key issue for Brazil and other ADCs, as well as for the world's industrialized economies, is how to work together to translate their enhanced economic positions into more effective participation in the affairs of the world economy. The United States has actively supported the increased participation of the ADCs in international institutions, as well as through our bilateral relations. For example, the IMF's currency basket for purposes of denominating Special Drawing Rights was recently expanded to include the currencies of two key ADCs — Saudi Arabia - 3 and Iran. We must also remember, however, that leadership implies responsibility, and we regard as extremely important the principle of graduation along a continuous spectrum from least to most advanced levels of economic achievement. In the trade field, graduation involves the transition from having preferential access to the markets of others through opening up one's own markets to eventually providing preferences to less fortunate nations. In development assistance, it involves a gradual shift from receiving foreign resources and technical expertise to providing such resources to others. For Brazil in particular, but also for other ADCs, this new economic situation raises fundamental, and profound, questions: — What should be their relationship with the United States, with the other industrial countries, and with the developing world? — Do they lie closer to the countries which still receive large amounts of outside assistance or to those which extend such assistance? Should they be somewhere in the middle, neither giving nor receiving? Should they continue to receive in some areas, and give to PDCs in others? - 4 — How should the monetary, trading and invest- ment rules apply to these countries: as they do to the industrial powers, or as they apply to the poorer countries? Or are new rules needed for Brazil and others in a more intermediate position? How are these nations' own vital interests affected by the impact on others of their answers to these questions — in terms, for example, of the willingness of the United States and other industrial countries to maintain policies which help foster their further economic growth? We in the United States have no clear answers to these questions. Indeed, it would be highly presumptuous for us to suggest answers even if we thought we had them. We feel, however, that it is essential to raise the questions — because the answers to them which emerge over the next few years will go far to determine the economic future of Brazil and other ADCs, the United States, and perhaps the world economy as a whole. Indeed, Brazil has already taken some important steps in accepting the responsibilities that go along with its new economic strength. It participates as a donor in - 5 the African Development Fund and has become a donor to the Inter-American Development Bank. It has agreed not to borrow convertible currency from the soft window of the Inter-American Bank. It extends bilateral assistance to several less fortunate countries in Latin America. U.S.-BRAZIL TRADE RELATIONS It is the area of international trade however, which perhaps offers the best opportunity for improving mutual cooperation between Brazil and the United States. The United States fully recognizes the high priority which Brazil places on access to our markets and to those of other industrialized countries — access for its exports of manufactured goods and primary products, as well as access to private capital. The other ADCs have similar interests. U.S. policy is to provide such access to our markets to the maximum extent possible. We are also fully aware of concern, in Brazil and elsewhere, that — to the contrary — the United States is on the verge of going protectionist. I believe that concern to be unjustified. Soon after President Carter took office last year, he had to make decisions on a number of recommendations from the International Trade Commission for comprehensive controls on imports of several major products. At least - 6 two of these, shoes and sugar, were of major importance to Brazil. Brazilian exports of shoes to the United States totaled $120 million in 1977, and of sugar about $90 million. Domestically, the President risked Congressional override if he rejected the Commission's proposals. But the President did reject them. He viewed the imposition of such controls as harmful to our own economy, because they would intensify inflationary pressures and insulate us from the beneficial effects of international competition. But he also rejected import quotas because of their injurious impact on other countries, notably developing countries. The impact on Brazil was a specific consideration in both those decisions. Congress subsequently legislated an increase in the U.S. sugar tariff, but even that action will be superseded as soon as the new International Sugar Agreement is able to raise world prices to its floor level. This Agreement, which was negotiated last fall in large part due to the efforts of the United States and Erazil, will help sugar exporters such as Brazil by raising prices from their current low levels. Early this year, the President also rejected an International Trade Commission recommendation for import - 7 relief to domestic producers of high-carbon ferrochromium. Brazil has been among the top five exporters of this product to the United States over the past five years, with exports of $8 million for 1976. In addition, there have been a multitude of proposals to remove specific products — many of interest to Brazil — from eligibility under the system of generalized tariff preferences (GSP) which we extend to exports from developing countries. In some cases, Brazilian products have been removed from GSP eligibility because of the requirement in U.S. trade law that exports of specific products from individual countries must be disqualified from preferences once that country becomes internationally competitive in those articles. Beyond these, however, very few products have been withdrawn. One result of this policy is that Brazil's exports to the United States under GSP increased significantly in 1977. In 1976, the first year the GSP program was in effect, Brazil exported about $215 million under it to the United States. In 1977, this figure grew by more than 60 percent to almost $344 million. A large percentage of the increase was accounted for by manufactured goods, especially automotive and electrical parts and equipment. More than ten percent of Brazil's exports to the United - 8 - States in 1977 entered free of duty under GSP. For the future the United States has taken the lead in infusing new life into the Multilateral Trade Negotiations in Geneva. We are seeking further liberalization of world trade, by steep cuts in tariffs and meaningful reductions of non-tariff barriers. We are encouraged by the active engagement of other major trading countries, including Brazil in the last few months. We hope and expect that the negotiations will bring major success this year. The record is thus clear. Partly in order to provide growing markets for world trade, we have taken steps to assure continued rapid growth of our own economy and urged the other stronger countries around the world — notably Japan and Germany — to do the same. We have consistently rejectd comprehensive new import restrictions. We have sought renewed trade liberalization. Our concern to maintain market access for Brazil and other developing countries has been central to these efforts. Our success can be measured by the fact that Brazil significantly reduced its bilateral trade deficit with the United States from 1975 to 1977, accounting for nearly $1.5 billion of the adverse swing in the U.S. trade balance during that period. - 9 - Trade, however, reveals the intimate interaction of national policies. We do face serious pressures to restrict imports, as do all other industrialized countries. And we are now seeing clearly how policies and economic performance in one major country, Japan, can jeopardize the openness of the entire trading system via the reactions which it triggers in other major countries. It is not too soon to ask whether Brazilian policies might have somewhat similar effects in the future. Brazil maintains extremely high tariffs. In recent years, it has instituted and tightened quantitative import restrictions on a wide array of products. It extends export incentives, often of considerable magnitude, to many of its manufactured products — some of which can run directly afoul of countervailing duty statutes in the United States and elsewhere. Through the "performance requirements" which it levies on incoming multinational enterprises, such as minimum export quotas and value-added tests, Brazil's policies also impinge upon economic developments in other countries. We fully recognize that Brazil has adopted many of these measures in recent years under extreme balance of - 10 - payments pressures, and in response to a marked slow down in world economic growth (and thus export markets). We recognize that many, of them are intended to offset distortions elsewhere in the economy, and to accelerate the diversification of Brazil's economy. We recognize that some are intended to counter what is perceived as the excessive strength of firms based outside Brazil. We know that current practices cannot be eliminated overnight. Yet we are deeply concerned that prolonged continuation, and certainly any further tightening, of such policies will help bring about the very response which Brazil is so right to fear, and which would be so injurious to its own vital interests. EXPORT SUBSIDIES AND COUNTERVAILING DUTIES In particular, we are facing potential problems on subsidies and countervailing duties which, if a solution is not found speedily, could be a major source of conflict in U.S.-Brazil trade relations — and, indeed, in overall relations between our countries. The problem is not a new one. Brazil's export promotion policies have prompted numerous countervailing duty complaints, and as a result the United States has placed additional duties on several products imported from Brazil. - 11To date, there have been no serious disruptions to trade. Several pending events, however, threaten to change that picture for the worse. First, Treasury's authority to waive the application of countervailing duties under certain circumstances expires on January 3, 1979. Loss of the waiver authority would elimin- ate any flexibility to work out bilateral arrangements on subsidy /countervailing duty problems. Given the wide array of Brazilian export subsidies, it would almost certainly produce a large number of tariff hikes against Brazilian sales to the United States. A major trade impact could result. There are also several specific results which can be foreseen. There would be an immediate imposition of counter- vailing duties on handbags from Brazil. Late in the last Administration, Treasury ruled that these handbags were receiving bounties or grants and should be assessed a 14 percent countervailing duty. imposition of the duties. However, it agreed to waive Brazilian exports of handbags to the United States accounted for $6 million in 1977. - 12 Two other countervailing duty cases are cause for serious concern — footwear and textiles. The countervailing duties now in effect on Brazilian footwear were calculated according to conditions prevailing in 1973. Treasury at present is seriously considering recalculating these duties to take into account apparent recent changes in Brazilian policy. We are not certain what changes would result from a recalculation. Higher duties are a possibility. Recalculation in itself could have an unsettling effect on imports of Brazilian footwear. Textiles also pose potential problems. Treasury is now investigating a countervailing duty complaint against a wide array of Brazilian textile imports. Exact figures are not available, but millions of dollars in annual imports are at stake. I would not want to prejudge this case in any way — Treasury has not yet issued a final determination, and will not do so until it conducts a thorough investigation. But I do want to flag it as an example of the potential trade disruption that could ensue if we do not resolve the subsidy-countervailing duty issue. The importance and urgency of this matter has led us - 13 to conclude that the old case-by-case waiver approach is grossly inadequate for dealing with the problem, and may indeed even be counterproductive by falsely allaying concern over the need to find a comprehensive solution. This is why, early in the current Administration we decided not to provide such waivers on imports from Brazil of cotton yarn and scissors and shears. To deal with the problem effectively, we instead place top priority on reaching an agreement on subsidies and countervailing duties in the Multilateral Trade Negotiations: — We need to put a lid on the growing use of subsidies to spur export-led growth at the expense of other trading nations. — We need to reinforce the commitment already accepted by most industrial nations not to use export subsidies. -- We need new international discipline to guard against the disguised protection of domestic markets through internal or production subsidies. -- We need to strengthen the present GATT provisions on dispute resolution to ensure that these rules are enforced effectively. - 14 This approach must be balanced, however. New guide- lines on the use of countervailing duties should go hand in glove with increased discipline on subsidies. As a general rule, duties should be applied only when a subsidy threatens or causes injury to a domestic industry. However, when there is a specific commitment not to use certain subsidies, countries should be able to take quick counteraction if that commitment is violated. There must be effective implementation of rules on both subsidies and countervailing duties. We of course recognize that subsidies can play an important role in national economic policymaking. Flexibility in the rules is needed for countries on different rungs of the development ladder. We expect fully developed countries to subscribe to all the provisions of an eventual agreement. At the other extreme, the poorest developing countries with the greatest need should be accorded special and differential treatment. For those nations which lie between these two categories ~ Brazil and other ADCs — the new code should recognize their growing responsibility in the world trading system, and provide for increased obligations as their industries become internationally competitive. Naturally, we do not expect - 15 this to happen overnight. A commitment to freeze the existing level of subsidization of exports might be a first step. And then might it not be sensible for Brazil, and other ADCs, to embark on a deliberate and announced course of winding down — and eventually eliminating — their export subsidies? This could be negotiated to occur over a certain period of time. In return, guarantees might be included in the MTN agreement to ensure that other countries respond constructively, and apply countervailing duties only when a subsidy is shown to have injured an industry in the domestic market. Such an arrangement would be similar in many respects to a recent agreement between Treasury and the Government of Uruguay regarding subsidies and countervailing duties. Uruguay agreed to phase out all its export subsidies on leather products by the beginning of 1979, and on all other products by 1983. In return, Treasury agreed to waive application of countervailing duties on footwear and leather products receiving export subsidies. We believe this agreement, which demonstrates both the merits and the practicality of a comprehensive approach, will greatly improve the climate for trade between Uruguay and the United States by neutralizing a major disruptive threat to Uruguayan exports. - 16 An agreement regulating the use of subsidies and countervailing duties is one area of the MTN where positive action by Brazil is crucial. It seems to us that the United States and Brazil should work closely together on all these issues, shari as we do the perspective of great exporters of both industrial and primary products. Surely it would seem that such an emphasis would more benefit Brazil's stature and interests than any continuing focus on receiving "special and differential treatment" and bindings of tariff preferences — which hardly seem likely to be the central issues for Brazil's trade relations through the 1980s, the period for which the MTN will provide the global trading framework. None of the steps mentioned are easy to undertake, for either our countries. All confront economic and political pitfalls. Yet a failure to face them would be a dereliction of duty on the part of countries, like ours, whose own vital interests would be deeply affected by a relapse into trade restrictions around the world. We will of course take into consideration Brazilian efforts in this area (as well as in the tariff negotiations and work on other NTB codes), as part of the overall MTN package, in determining the concessions which we will offer in return. CONCLUSION I have spoken at some length today about U.S. trade - 17 relations with Brazil as an example of measures which each of our countries can take to improve their economic ties and begin to implement a greater sharing of the responsibilities for maintaining an open and mutually beneficial international trading system. Brazil today is clearly one of the most advanced of the world's developing economies. It is moving toward the front ranks of the world's economic powers. We fully recognize this new status and welcome Brazil, as we welcomed Japan in the late 1950s and early 1960s, as a nation prepared to play an enhanced role on a whole range of international economic issues. The economic relationship between the United States and Brazil — indeed, much of our political relationship as well — is likely to focus increasingly on ways in which these responsibilities can be exercised more effectively. The recent lengthy discussion in Brasilia of problems of the Middle East between President Carter and President Geisel is a further indication of our desire to more fully consult with Brazil on the widest possible range of issues. Brazil's new position offers a unique opportunity to help pave the way for other ADCs to also share in the greater responsibilities and benefits of enhanced consultation on the management of the international economic order. We hope that Brazil will accept this challenge and this opportunity, both for - 18 itself and for other nations who may soon be ready to follow in its footsteps. tartmentoftheTREASURY HINGT0N,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 i FOR RELEASE AT 4:00 P.M. May 9, 1978 TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL OFFERING The Department of the Treasury, by this public notice, invites tenders for two series of Treasury bills totaling approximately $ 5,600 million, to be issued May 18, 1978. This offering will not provide new cash for the Treasury as the maturing bills are outstanding in the amount of $5,628 million The two series offered are as follows: 91-day bills (to maturity date) for approximately $2,200 million, representing an additional amount of bills dated February 16, 1978, and to mature August 17, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 S7 2 ) , originally issued in the amount of $3,509 million the additional and original bills to be freely interchangeable 182-day bills for approximately $3,400 million to be dated May 18, 1978, and to mature November 16, 1978 (CUSIP No. 912793 U4 6 ) . Both series of bills will be issued for cash and in exchange for Treasury bills maturing May 18, 1978. Federal Reserve Banks, for themselves and as agents of foreign and international monetary authorities, presently hold $3,228 million of the maturing bills. These accounts may exchange bills they hold for the bills now being offered at the weighted average prices of accepted competitive tenders. The bills will be issued on a discount basis under competitive and noncompetitive bidding, and at maturity their par amount will be payable without interest. Except for definitive bills in the $100,000 denomination, which will be available only to investors who are able to show that they are required by law or regulation to hold securities in physical form, both series of bills will be issued entirely in book-entry form in a minimum amount of $10,000 and in any higher $5,000 multiple, on the records either of the Federal Reserve Banks and B r a n c h e s , or of the Department of the Treasury. Tenders will be received at Federal Reserve Banks and Branches and at the Bureau of the Public Debt, Washington, • C. 20226, up to 1:30 p.m., Eastern Daylight Saving time, Monday, May 15, 1978. Form PD 4632-2 (for 26-week series) or Form PD 4632-3 (for 13-week series) should be used to submit tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the T r e a s u r y . B-893 -2Each tender must be for a minimum of $10,000. Tenders over $10,000 must be in multiples of $5,000. In the case of competitive tenders the price offered must be expressed on the basis of 100, with not more than three decimals, e.g., 99.925. Fractions may not be used. Banking institutions and dealers who make primary markets in Government securities and report daily to the Federal Reserve Bank of New York their positions in and borrowings on such securities may submit tenders for account of customers, if the names of the customers and the amount for each customer are furnished. Others are only permitted to submit tenders for their own account. Payment for the full par amount of the bills applied for must accompany all tenders submitted for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of the Department of the Treasury. A cash adjustment will be made on all accepted tenders for the difference between the par payment submitted and the actual issue price as determined in the auction. No deposit need accompany tenders from incorporated banks and trust companies and from responsible and recognized dealers in investment securities for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, or for bills issued in bearer form, where authorized. A deposit of 2 percent of the par amount of the bills applied for must accompany tenders for such bills from others, unless an express guaranty of payment by an incorporated bank or trust company accompanies the tenders. Public announcement will be made by the Department of the Treasury of the amount and price range of accepted bids. Competitive bidders will be advised of the acceptance or rejection of their tenders. The Secretary of the Treasury expressly reserves the right to accept or reject any or all tenders, in whole or in part, and the Secretary's action shall be final. Subject to these reservations, noncompetitive tenders for each issue for $500,000 or less without stated price from any one bidder will be accepted in full at the weighted average price (in three decimals) of accepted competitive bids for the respective issues. Settlement for accepted tenders for bills to be maintained on the book-entry records of Federal Reserve Banks and Branches, and bills issued in bearer form must be made or completed at the Federal Reserve Bank or Branch or at the Bureau of the Public Debt on May 18, 1978, in cash or other immediately available funds or in Treasury bills maturing May 18, 1978. Cash adjustments will be made for differences between the par value of the maturing bills accepted in exchange and the issue price of the new bills. -3Under Sections 454(b) and 1221(5) of the Internal Revenue Code of 1954 the amount of discount at which these bills are sold is considered to accrue when the bills are sold, redeemed or otherwise disposed of, and the bills are excluded from consideration as capital assets. Accordingly, the owner of these bills (other than life insurance companies) must include in his or her Federal income tax return, as ordinary gain or loss, the difference between the price paid for the bills, whether on original issue or on subsequent purchase, and the amount actually received either upon sale or redemption at maturity during the taxable year for which the return is made. Department of the Treasury Circulars, No. 418 (current revision), Public Debt Series - Nos. 26-76 and 27-76, and this notice, prescribe the terms of these Treasury bills and govern the conditions of their issue. Copies of the circulars and tender forms may be obtained from any Federal Reserve Bank or Branch, or from the Bureau of the Public Debt. oOo Contact: Carolyn M. Johnston (202) 634-5377 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE MAY 11, 1978 TREASURY SECRETARY BLUMENTHAL NAMES WILLIAM D. UTZINGER SAVINGS BONDS CHAIRMAN FOR WYOMING William D. Utzinger, President of Salt Creek Freightways, Casper, Wyoming, has been appointed Volunteer State Chairman for the Savings Bonds Program in Wyoming by Treasury Secretary W. Michael Blumenthal. The appointment is effective immediately. Mr. Utzinger will head a committee of business, banking, labor, government, and media leaders who, in cooperation with the U.S. Savings Bonds Division, will assist in promoting bond sales throughout the state. He succeeds Robert L. Parmalee, Vice President and Wyoming General Manager, Mountain Bell. Mr. Utzinger is a graduate of the University of Wyoming where he received a Bachelor of Science degree in Business Administration. He served in the U.S. Army for two years, where he was commissioned a 1st lieutenant. Upon his discharge in 1955, he went to work for Salt Creek Freightways. -- over -B-894 - 2- In 1969 Mr. Utzinger was elected President of the Wyoming Trucking Association and served in that capacity for two years. He has served on the Board of Directors of the United Fund, Chamber of Commerce, First National Bank, Western Highway Institute and Rotary Club. In 1969 he was elected Industrialist of the Year by the Wyoming Realty Association. In 1971 he was appointed Vice President of Wyoming for the American Trucking Association of Washington, D.C. In 1972 he served as President of the Rotary Club and as SecretaryTreasurer of the Federal Highway Administration Unit, a National Defense Executive Reserve. He is also a member of the Board of Governors of Truck Insurance Exchange, Los Angeles, California. Mr. Utzinger and his wife, Jackie, reside in Casper. They have two children, Jalene of Jamestown, North Dakota, and Jim, a student at the University of Wyoming. FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 1:30 P.M., EST THURSDAY, MAY 11, 1978 REMARKS BY THE HONORABLE ANTHONY M. SOLOMON UNDER SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR MONETARY AFFAIRS BEFORE THE CONFERENCE BOARD NEW YORK CITY Competition and Change In the International Trading System The challenge of "Meeting Foreign Competition", which you have chosen as the theme for this conference, is both timely and critical. American businessmen, I know, are seriously concerned about our record trade deficit last year. There is a need for a clearer perception of the reasons for the deterioration in our trade position, and what we must do to correct it. I propose to concentrate on the issue of the U.S. competitive position and measures we need to take now to meet foreign competition better in the future. I will then turn to some of the longer-term problems of the present international trading system and propose some specific objectives which I consider important in creating a "new international trading framework" to meet the demands of a rapidly changing global economy. B-895 . - 2 - The U.S. Competitive Position In discussing the U.S. competitive position, I want to emphasize that there is a distinct difference between price competitiveness and market performance. Changes in relative price competitiveness should produce their full effect on market performance only after an 18-month to two-year lag. Our record 1977 trade deficit and the slight reduction in the U.S. share of industrial country exports of manufactured goods to countries other than the United States during the past two years may partly reflect the trade weighted average appreciation of the dollar in 1975. In nominal terms, that appreciation has now been roughly reversed. But a more meaningful picture of changes in international price competitiveness is offered by trade-weighted exchange rate movements adjusted for different national inflation rates. In price adjusted terms, exchange rate movements between December 1976 and March 1978 have resulted in: A substantial deterioration in the trade competitiveness of: Japan, where yen appreciation outpaced relative price gains; France, where relative inflation increases - 3 - outstripped exchange rate depreciation; and The U.K. , where exchange rate appreciation and relatively poor price performance combined to worsen competitiveness. At the same time, trade competitiveness was improved for : Canada, as exchange rate depreciation exceeded m V relative price worsening; and The U.S., where some exchange rate depreciation occurred in the presence of no loss in relative price performance. On the other hand, German trade competitiveness was virtually unchanged as exchange rate appreciation matched superior inflation performance. The trade weighted real exchange rate of the dollar relative to the currencies of seven major industrial countries has fallen about 3 percent since the third quarter of 1977. These adjustments in the real value of the dollar should in time be reflected in improved U.S. market performance abroad and a modest reduction in our trade deficit, provided U.S. industries take advantage of the improvement in their price competitive position. The current debate about market shares and whether the United States is gaining or losing against other suppliers - 4 has focused on share calculations made vis-a-vis other industrial country suppliers. This focus misses a major development in the world economy: the emergence of developing countries as important competitors in industrial markets has risen steadily during the 1970's. LDCs increased their share of industrial country non-oil imports by two percentage points between 1970/72 and 1977, a gain worth over $12 billion. Much of this gain has come from the powerful economic advances in Asia — South Korea, Taiwan, Singapore, Hong Kong. Perhaps the most dramatic result of that gain can be seen in changes in the U.S. share of the Japanese market. Since 1968-70, developing Asia has significantly increased its share of the Japanese market in each of six major categories of manufactures imports — capital equipment, chemicals, finished metals, consumer durables and nondurables and textiles. Increases range from 6-10 percentage points (chemicals, finished metals, capital equipment, textiles) to 20-30 percentage points (consumer durables and nondurables). At the same time, the U.S. share fell in each category. Compared with 1968-70, the U.S. share of Japan's imports in 1976-77 fell from 32 to 12 percent for consumer nondurable goods, from 39 to 27 percent for consumer durable goods, from 61 to 51 percent for capital equipment, and by lesser amounts in other categories. This has happened despite the - 5 - fact that the United States has advantages over other industrial country suppliers: a history of close trade ties with Japan and a high technology economy. Clearly, it is no longer sufficient to look at market shares only by comparison with other industrialized countries. I would also note that these rapidly advancing developing nations are by and large outside the "adjustment process" as we usually think of it. Most have tied their exchange rates to the dollar or to-other major currencies. Some maintain capital and trade controls, yet benefit from special LDC status in trade relations. More effort is needed to bring the advanced developing nations more fully into the system — and they must accept the responsibilities as well as gain the benefits of a growing and open world economy. At the same time, we must recognize that the growth of these developing countries also provides us with export markets for our manufactures. Our exports of manufactures to these four dynamic Asian countries more than doubled between 1970 and 1976, making them together rival Japan as a market'for our manufactured goods by the latter year. The development of these emerging markets presents new opportunities to exporters. - 6 Increasing U.S. Exports President Carter has created a Cabinet-level task force chaired by Commerce Secretary Juanita Kreps to look into possible measures to improve U.S. export competitiveness in world markets. The task force will address both the current impediments to our exports (whether due to governmental measures or to the failure of private business to take advantage of available opportunities overseas) and possible remedies for these problems. The Administration has already proposed to double Commodity Credit Corporation credits to support agricultural exports and to increase Export-Import Bank lending activity sharply. We intend to make sure that American business has full support from the government in meeting export credit competition from official agencies of other governments. Nevertheless, there are some problems which only private business can address: Competition with subsidiaries. We may not, for example, be getting energetic competition for foreign markets because many of our firms have subsidiaries abroad with which they are not prepared to compete for markets. There may even be a tacit geographical division of markets among .related firms which greatly slows the response to relative price changes and to new market opportunities. - 7Improved competition, even with our own subsidiaries, may stimulate both greater efficiency and U.S. exports. Market sales. It is natural that U.S. producers concentrate their sales effort on a U.S. market whose size is increasing by $90 billion a year rather than on a series of individual foreign markets, the very largest of which is growing at a rate of $35 billion per year. On the other hand, foreign producers may also find that the huge and dynamic U.S. market is the most profitable place to concentrate their sales effort. Foreign manufacturers may make a special "export model" just to sell in the U.S. Not many U.S. manufacturers will make a special model to sell in Japan— or in France, or in Brazil. Consequently, we have often failed to take foreign market tastes, preferences, specifications and opportunities into account in the design and production of U.S. goods. For example, although there are a few U.S. mills that cut lumber to Japanese measurements, most do not, and those that do can't keep up with the demand. Distribution Systems. U.S. industry has become accustomed to highly organized, sophisticated distribution/sales systems which reap the benefits of economies of scale. In most foreign economies, exporters still face "mom and pop" stores, non-integrated markets, and inefficient distribution systems which deal with small volume. Inventory management and distribution - 8 networks are far more complicated. This is particularly true in Japan, where there are hundreds of thousands of retail outlets, most small, poorly financed and located on small premises. No company could conceivably bear the cost of reaching a significant number of these shops through direct distribution. In retail food distribution, for example, nearly all of the successful U.S. export efforts have been achieved through using the distribution system of a well-established Japanese company. For industrial or large ticket consumer products, the situation is considerably different. Here, U.S. exporters too often try to obtain market entry without out-of-pocket expense. A general trading company may b« engaged as a distributor, but these are not generally effective distributors of products requiring promotion and service. More effort must be put into studying the market and selecting the proper distribution network, even at substantial initial expense. Also, under traditional U.S. accounting standards, the costs of establishing a customs clearing firm, creating a network of distributors, applying for product approval, and other start-up costs are treated as expenses for the year in which they are incurred, even though benefits from these capital outlays may - 9 not be seen for five to ten years. The heavy toll of these expenses on the income statement for the period of start-up costs tends to further discourage U.S. business from even trying to enter the market. The export promotion task force is looking into these kinds of problems to see what can be done to alleviate them. Japan in particular seems to provide an excellent example of the potential for closer cooperation between U.S. exporters and Japanese distributors, or between U.S. marketing chains and Japanese importers. Market information. There may be a good bit more we can do, both through the public and the private sector, to get better market information about trade opportunities abroad. The U.S.-Japan Trade Facilitation Committee inauguarated in October is a recent effort on the part of both of our nations to enhance information about what we have to sell and they want to buy, as well as providing a forum for reviewing particular trade problems. Investment. At home, our goal must be to assure that we produce efficiently those goods in which we can be competitive — markets. in both domestic and foreign This means more effort to encourage invest- ment where it can be most productively used, stronger research and development programs, new flexibility - 10 - to keep up with changes in domestic market tastes, and a conscious effort not to write off sectors in which we can be competitive with the proper production and investment strategies — whether these be consumer goods or intermediate products which we tend now to import because of superior quality, individual preference, or effective marketing techniques. I don't mean that we should try to produce to meet all our domestic needs — too great a cost. that would be impossible and come at But we can choose more rationally the goods in which we can realistically compete and begin now to adjust production with that objective in mind. These are by no means the only measures we can take to reduce our trade deficit. But they may provide some food for thought as we tackle the problem of meeting foreign competition both at home and abroad. And we can anticipate a more comprehensive picture of both government and private steps to improve our trade position once the interagency task force has had an opportunity to study these problems in more detail. Toward a New International Trading Environment The steps I have mentioned so far and the work of the interagency task force will address primarily -lithe immediate problems of a record U.S. trade deficit and our need to improve our export performance. There are longer-term problems, however. In the Multilateral Trade Negotiations which began in 1973 and are slated to be completed this summer, we are not only engaged in the traditional efforts to further reduce national tariff barriers, but also are seeking to negotiate new international codes. The codes would be designed to deal with the increasing tendency of many governments — including the United States — to intervene actively in domestic and international markets to regulate or distort trade flows. Such intevention may take the form of restrictive government procurement policies which discriminate against foreign suppliers; "safeguard" action to restrict imports of particular products which appear to threaten the competitive position of domestic industries in home markets; and direct and indirect subsidies to domestic industries. With economies grpwing slowly and unemployment high, as in Europe at the present, there has developed a destructive tendency to subsidize production at inefficient plants simply to maintain employment. It is reliably reported that such subsidies total a startling 2-3 percent of GNP in several European countries, and the amounts appear to be growing rapidly in some cases. - 12 - The present rules and regulations on trade - as incorporated in the General Agreement on Tariffs, and Trade - do not adequately cover these problems. We need a series of codes which would provide a new trading framework for this purpose. They should provide: (1) rules that deal with the growing government involvement in trade; (2) an understanding on acceptable measures of response to unfair trade practices or to disruptive surges in import competition, with special rules for trade with the developing nations; and (3) a new mechanism for cooperative dispute settlement. The new framework would have to be flexible, and recognize that the needs and problems of domestic economies will differ among nations. Yet it must pro- vide acceptable guidelines and limitations upon actions that interfere with trade flows. As Bob Strauss has pointed out, one of the sine qua non of U.S. adherence to a final MTN package is an agreement on the use of subsidies and countervailing duties. This is an area of critical interest to the Treasury, the administraing agency. We need to reinforce the commitment already accepted by most industrial nations not to use export - 13 - subsidies on manufactured goods. We need new discipline to guard against the disguised protection of domestic markets through internal or production subsidies. And we need to strengthen the present GATT provisions on dispute settlement to ensure that these rules are enforced effectively. This approach must be balanced, however. New guidelines on the use of countervailing duties should go hand in glove with increased discipline on subsidies. As a general rule, duties should be applied only when a subsidy threatens or causes injury to a domestic industry. When there is a specific commitment, however, not to use certain subsidies, countries should be able to take quick counter-action if that commitment is violated. Although we recognize that flexibility in the rules is needed for countries in different phases of development, we expect developed countries to subscribe to all provisions of an eventual agreement. And for the most advanced developing nations, the new code should reflect their growing responsibility in the world trading system, and provide for increased acceptance of obligations as they become full-fledged international competitors. - 14 - An understanding is also essential on the use of safeguard measures which governments may take in. emergency situations to permit domestic industries to adjust to dramatic changes in trade flows. Such an understanding should clearly limit the circumstances in which governments can impose restraints on trade and should assure that those restraints are temporary. We have achieved some success in bilateral talks with Japan in helping to open the door to foreign suppliers on public procurement of computers. Negotiations with the European Community have been difficult partly because the EC has not been able to achieve an internal consensus on the use of "buy European" policies in such important sectors as telecommunications, computers, and heavy electrical equipment. Countries in strong balance of payments positions might wish to consider opening their procurement markets unilaterally, as one additional measure of encouraging increased imports. Clearly, however, we must address this issue in the MTN. Excessive and disruptive government procurement regulations are wasting tax dollars, increasing consumer costs, and barring efficient foreign industries -15 - : from competing for government contracts in many domestic markets. In addition to these new codes and understandings, we also need to begin now to look beyond the MTN. We need improved mechanisms for cooperation in tradeso that trade problems can be addressed and mutually resolved before they erupt in open conflict. And we need to maintain the momentum for continuing trade liberalization as an essential element of trade cooperation. We must begin to consider now the means and mechanisms for increasing participation by the more advanced developing nations in the global economy — both through improved consultation and rights, and through their acceptance of greater responsibilities in international trade. *** These are important goals for us and for the future of the international community as a whole. We will work to strengthen our governmental mechanisms to promote exports in the immediate future, and we urge American businesses to give careful attention to the steps that only they can take to improve U.S. export performance. We hope that the MTN will provide a - 16 - meaningful basis for the regulation of government intervention in trade and the resolution of future trade disputes. And we look forward to continued cooperation in the years ahead as we strive to maintain a trading framework which responds effectively to the demands of an ever-changing world economy. Department theTREASURY WASHINGTON, D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 For Release at 11 a.m Friday, May 12, 1978 EDT REMARKS OF THE HONORABLE W. MICHAEL BLUMENTHAL SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE BUSINESS COUNCIL HOT SPRINGS, VIRGINIA MAY 12, 1978 Today and tomorrow you will hear an array of both private and official views on the dollar. To spare you from repetition, and to get right to the point, I will keep my comments brief. I shall be glad to expand upon them in the discussion which will toiiow Mr. Emminger*s speech. Over the past year there have been complaints that United states authorities have engaged in deliberate "neglect" of the dollar. During the last few weeks these expressions of concern have subsided. I would like to assure you now that it has not been, is not now, and will not be the policy of the United States government to "neglect" the dollar either benignly or in any other Greater way. stability of exchange rates is a widely-held objective and one which the United States supports strongly. But tne experience of recent years is vivid proof that such stability is impossible without stable economic and financial conditions in tne major economies of the world. Th f, e United States government is ever ready to intervene in rtiL 2 r e J g n e x c h a n 8 e market to bring order to an otherwise axsorderly market. The resources available for this purpose are flihVi - The F e d e r a l Reserve/Bundesbank swap has been doubled to m.rb "£ W e h a V e a S r e e d t o s e l 1 600 million SDR's for German a $5 b i l l i o n will H W S reserve position in the IMF which we 0 3S n e c e s s a r y currencies "' ' t o acquire additional foreign m*ri,.?J\.Wf:,?? n0t mea5ure a country's interest in exchange 2 ? u " l t y b y i t S r e a d * n e s s to send its monetary raiu 6 S i n t ° t h e f o r e i S n exchange markets to hold or fix a - | H - We measure that interest by the readiness to adopt and at.h-i . ? r o u g n s o u n d domestic economic policies. Lasting rec ui nati 5 J"es both a readiness on the part of all major ad the »!!fi.? ° P t t n e appropriate macro-economic programs -- and <-ne ability to do so. B -896 -2We must acknowledge that our economies and our societies are not all alike. Our economic priorities differ. Some countries place higher priority on price stability than others. Some governments have more control over economic policy than others. There are important differences in our basic political systems which make policy approaches feasible in one country but impossible in another. Yet we can work toward exchange market stability by developing some common views on the relative priorities to be assigned to the various objectives of economic policy, such as price stability and rates of growth, and on the approaches required to achieve these objectives. In all candor we must acknowledge that such a set of common views does not yet exist today. Nevertheless', we are striving for improvement and I am confident that we can achieve important progress. We well know that nations will pursue what they believe to be the best interest of their own people. No nation will always do what others urge it to do. In the final analysis German and Japanese growth policy.is made by German and Japanese authorities. French and British trade policy is made by the French and British authorities. American policy is made by American authorities — the President and the Congress. Our political system is democratic and broad domestic support is required for all our policies. Only if all nations perceive a "best interest of others policy" to be in their own long-run interest as well, will they attempt sucn a policy. Thus, the United States places high value on consultation and exchange of information with its trading partners. We acknowledge our interdependence. %» All of the major countries have a responsibility to wor,^ toward the internal discipline that is essential to meaningT stability in the international monetary system. This is the reason why President Carter will be meeting with his counterparts at the Bonn Summit in July. The Summit will not be a dramatic decision making event. It is designed instead to foster the very kind of gap bridging of domestic macro-economic policies that is necessary in our interdependent world for a smoothly functioning exchange market for goods and money. Tne United States* Role As the largest economy and the provider of the world's vehicle and reserve currency, the burden falls especially heavily on the United States to achieve economic discipline, and to set the fundamentals right. Last year, we had a deficit in our current account of $20 billion. That is only 1 percent of the U.S. GNP. But in absolute terms and in the eyes of the foreign exchange markets that was a large number. And when the market saw no action on -3our part to temper our imports of energy, no progress in reducing inflation and no clear prospect of a reduction in the deficit, exchange rates began to move rapidly. In six months the dollar rate, measured on a trade weighted basis against all OECD countries declined 7 percent, reversing the appreciation which had occurred in 1975 and 1976, and dropping the dollar 1 percent or so below the level which immediately followed the general move to floating in 1973. Against some countries, the dollar depreciated markedly, while against others it appreciated almost as much. That is past history. Now our responsibility is to pursue domestic policies that achieve both the growth which brings high employment and rising living standards, and the stability of prices which preserves the value of the assets of individuals and firms. And critically, we must reduce our current account deficit. ^ In the current situation the United States faces three basic tasks: (1) To recuce our dependence on imports of energy; (2) To reduce the rate of domestic inflation; and 9» (3) To increase the export consciousness of American firms. We will pursue these goals in our own interest and in the interest of all others. We will pursue them with vigor. Our success will preserve the integrity of the dollar. It will promote greater exchange market stability. Energy On the energy front, we are now enjoying a temporary respite from the growth of oil imports. Alaskan production is reaching pipeline capacity, enabling us to meet from domestic sources the increase in oil consumption which accompanies rising GNP. For 1978 the oil price freeze combined with the effects of Alaskan production should enable us to avoid any significant increase in our oil import bill, while putting some 100 million barrels of oil in the Strategic Petroleum Reserve. Unfortunately, we do not have an Alaska coming into production each year. As the economy continues to grow in 1979 we will again face the spectre of a rising oil import bill, despite our increased conservation efforts. We must do something to alter that prospect. Thus, in his address to American newspaper editors on April 11, President Carter urged the U.S. Congress to adopt meaningful energy legislation without further delay and indicated that, if Congress did not act, oil imports would have to be limited by administrative action under present law. We are working hard with the Congress to have action on energy and we must have it soon. -II- Inflation We are also working hard to stem inflation. The inflation situation has worsened a little in recent months. Consumer prices rose at more than a 9 percent annual rate during the first three months of the year and at an 8 percent rate even after the food and energy components are removed. It is not clear that the current upswing in the inflation rate has run its course. Wholesale prices at early stages of the chain of production, primarily agricultural products, have been rising rapidly and these increases may not have worked their way fully through the retail level. Some relief is likely to be felt later in the year. Last year, consumer prices also rose more rapidly in the first half of the year, at about an 8-1/2 percent annual rate before falling back to less than 5 percent in the second half. We hope history repeats itself. But we cannot afford to depend upon it. There are worrisome signs of deterioration in the crucial wage-productivity area. This is fundamentally more serious than any temporary upswing in food and raw material prices. The .* upward ratcheting of cost pressures tends to be reflected broadly across most sectors of the economy. Productivity, as we measure it, fell off in the first quarter partly for special causes. Labor compensation per manhour rose more rapidly, partly due to some self-inflicted wounds in the form of Federally mandated cost increases and because wage settlements came in quite a bit higher — the coal settlement was a major factor. The net result has been more pressure on costs and prices. There is no reason for extreme pessimism. We see no evidence that the inflation rate has been jolted upward more than temporarily. But at a time when a deceleration of inflation is clearly in the national interest, recent cost and price developments should serve as a warning — and an incentive. There is a need for an even deeper resolve and a closer spirit of cooperation. The present inflationary process is benefiting no major group. We must make greater progress in turning the inflation situation around. The clear need now is to wind the process down, rather than see it intensify any further. In his April 11 speech, the President announced a set of comprehensive new measures to combat inflation. This was not a toothless pledge. We mean business. President Carter is committed to: — limiting the size of the 1979 and future federal budget deficits, by veto if necessary; — restricting the salary increase of Federal government employees to about 5.5 percent this year and urging simil wage restraint on state and local governments and private businesses; -- reducing the inflationary effect of past and future regulatory actions by the government. -5His speech signalled a dogged determination to bring inflation down without resort to wage or price controls. The government bureaucracy and the business community are beginning to respond. I am confident that we will see widespread support and steadily growing success towards this end from all of you. Exports The success of this anti-inflation program is critical to restoring confidence in. the U.S. economy. It is also needed to maintain the price competitiveness of U.S. goods and to sustain the growth of U.S. exports. In addition, it is essential to the maintenance of a domestic investment climate which will attract capital inflows. U.S. export growth in recent years has, frankly, been disappointing. In the last two years the volume of our exports nas only grown by H percent, compared to a 40 percent rise in our volume of imports. In part, this has been due to the slow rate of growth of U.S. export markets. During the 1960's the United States experienced a slower rate of average real growth than the rest of the industrial world, but since the energy crisis this relationship has been dramatically reversed. This divergence in the paths of growth is obviously a major factor in explaining why our current account position has shifted from a $12 billion surplus in 1975 to a $20 billion deficit in 1977. It has made it difficult for us to balance the surge in imports we have experienced with a compensating increase in exports. At the same time, it is evident that the U.S. business sector is not exploiting all of the opportunities which are available in foreign markets. We need to know why. For this reason, the President has commissioned the special Cabinet-level task force under Secretary of Commerce Kreps announced in his speech. Let me make it clear that we will not engage in trade warfare. We are only seeking to activate what we believe is a dormant export potential. We have proposed an expansion of the activities of our Export-Import Eank in an effort to make sure that U.S. exporters have available a source of supplementary financing that matches the terms offered by the export credit agencies of other industrial countries. We have already proposed to double Commodity Credit Corporation credits to support agricultural exports. And the Export Tax Force is investigating now best to encourage the exports of small and medium firms, offset the heavy initial costs of opening up foreign markets, and provide tax incentives to export sales in a more efficient manner than is currently offered by DISC and other devices. But in the final analysis, there are limits to what the government can do to enhance exports. Our success will depend on whether business takes advantage of the opportunities available ln foreign markets. -6We are not now an export-oriented nation. We must become one. Doing so will require recognizing the structural changes that have been taking place here and abroad. For example, in the case of our second largest export market, Japan, we have lost our earlier market share, especially to a group of rapidly developing Asian countries. There are real economic factors at work, which cannot be ignored. Still, our difficulties in selling to the Japanese market are too often attributed to presumed protectionist measures and internal restrictions in Japan which may no longer exist. Certainly impediments to U.S. exports remain which need to be addressed on a government-to-government level. But there are now large sectors of the Japanese economy wnich are highly competitive and open to foreign producers. U.S. companies must continually re-assess export opportunities in foreign markets like Japan, in the light of rapidly changing conditions and not solely on the basis of past experience. The evidence is that we are now more price competitive. There is good potential for profit in exports. Our firms will! benefit by going after export markets with the same kind of h> tenacity as our trade rivals. In its own interest, U.S. business should waste no time and lose no opportunity to get on with the job. New Investment To export competitively and retain a sound economy at horr^e, tne United States must also aggressively pursue an expansion of real investment in plant, equipment, and productive processes. Tne record here is distressingly grim. Consider the period 1960-to-1974, before the last recession. In the United States, non-residential fixed investment averaged 13-1/2 percent of national output. The average was 18 percent for tne larger OECD countries. It was 20 percent for West Germany, 25 percent for Japan. As one might expect, these differentials in investment contributed to sharp differentials in average real growtn rates over the period: For the U.S., 3.8 percent; for Germany, 4.6 percent; for Japan 9.7 percent. Last year, of course, the situation reversed itself. We grew considerably faster in real terms than most OECD countires. Our rate of growth in real investment, about 8 percent, also outpaced that in many of those countries. But there is little to suggest tnat this relative success of ours, in climbing out of 1974-75 recession, portends a long term recovery of our growth prospects. For that to occur, a genuine sea change is needed in the trend of private investment. Tne task before us is truly enormous. The Administration estimates that, to bring this recovery along a safe and balanced path to full employment, and to prepare for the massive capital needs we will face in the 19P0»s, real fixed investment in productive facilities must rise by about 10 percent annually. That is markedly more than last year. It is very substantially -7more than recent trends. Looking at the 1970's as a whole, the annual increase in real investment has been less than 2 percent. We are very far behind schedule. Unless we begin catching up, and quickly, we will pay a serious price at home and abroad in the 1980's I am especially concern ed about how the composition of our investment relates to advanc ed techn ology. The stakes here are exceptionally high. In inte rnationa 1 trade, we depend very heavily on our exports of R& D intens ive manufactured products. Indeed, in manufactured prod ucts tha t are not R&D-intensive, our trade balance is negative. Unfortun ately, our investment patterns are doing far too 1 ittle to preserve our comparative edge in high technology prod ucts. A s a share of GNP, R&D spending declined in the Uni ted Stat es by more than 25 percent between the mid 1960's and t he mid 1 970's. Scientists and engineers, as a share of our populat ion, have also declined, wnile that ratio has increas ed in th e Soviet Union, West Germany, and Japan. Tne number of U. S. paten ts granted to foreign residents has doubled. Our acquisit ion of foreign patents has declined . These are mere straws in the wind; but it seems quite clear to me that the wind is blowing strongly in the wrong direction. Our technological supremacy is not mandated by heaven. It can disappear. Unless we pay close attention to it, and invest in it, it will disappear. Along with it will go our competitive edge. Conclusion Successful efforts on the energy, inflation and export fronts, together with judicious monetary management by the Federal Reserve, are needed to protect the integrity of the dollar. Accelerated investment in our economic plant is needed to sustain the dollar's strength. The Carter Administration is dedicated to these goals. But to repeat once more, we need your help. The Business Community plays a critical role. Energy conservation in the business sector can make an important contribution to reducing our dependence on imported oil. Business* cooperation in decelerating U.S. inflation is essential if the dollar is to maintain its value at home and abroad. The extent of businessmen's efforts to maintain or recoup their share of the U.S. market and of world export markets will determine the success or failure of our export expansion efforts. Government can help, and will do so. But it cannot succee alone. oOOo FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 12, 19"78" t Contact: Brian M. Freeman 376-0321 EMERGENCY LOAN GUARANTEE BOARD ISSUES FINAL REPORT TO CONGRESS The Emergency Loan Guarantee Board's Sixth Annual and Final Report to Congress was made available in printed form today for public distribution. The Report reviews the history of the guarantee program and the operations of the Board and Lockheed Corporation under it. Congress established the Board in 1971 to extend and monitor the Government's guarantee of up to $250 million of private bank debt to Lockheed Corporation which was then experiencing a severe liquidity crisis in which it was unable to obtain private financing. The guarantee terminated on October 14, 19 77, by mutual agreement of the parties. On January 31, 1978, the Board formally completed the Final Report and terminated its operations. The Report indicates that, in approving termination, the Board found that Lockheed had restored itself to a position which afforded it access to the normal credit markets under reasonable terms and conditions without further need for the guarantee. It also found that the risks facing Lockheed were no longer materially different than those facing other major airframe manufacturers. In requesting early termination, Lockheed and its banks also expressed confidence in Lockheed's financial condition, fundamental viability and future prospects. The Report closes by stating that "the successful operation and conclusion of the . . .program. . .demonstrated that business and Government can work together to solve their mutual problems when their relationships are properly structured. B-897 -2"...The program served its...intended purposes, especially the broader public interest. It permitted the avoidance... to the California and national economies of a Lockheed failure and such a failure's potential adverse ramifications for Lockheed's suppliers, customers, and others. It also avoided a potentially large negative impact on Federal, state, and local revenues, as well as the accompanying social welfare costs. It assured Lockheed's continued production under national defense contracts without disruption, permitted airlines. . .to obtain the aircraft in which they had invested, and allowed continued competition by Lockheed in the commercial passenger aircraft manufacture industry." The Government earned $26.6 million in fees on the program, plus $5.6 million in interest on those fees, without being called on to lend or otherwise expend funds on behalf of Lockheed or its lending banks. The Government's administrative costs were slightly more than $1 million. Throughout, its position was secured by a first lien on Lockheed's assets consistently valued in excess of the maximum guarantees. oOo PRESS CONFERENCE OF THE HONORABLE ANTHONY M. SOLOMON U.S. UNDER SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY FOR MONETARY AFFAIRS AT THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY INTERIM CONFERENCE HOTEL PRESIDENTE CHAPULTEPEC MEXICO CITY APRIL 29, 1978 As you know, the ground rules here are that we don't talk about what other countries representatives say. So I'm simply going to give you a summary of what Secretary Blumenthal said today, and then I will be able to take a few questions. I have to get back into' the room so this cannot be too protracted. The Secretary started in by saying that with ratification this month of the new IMF Articles, we are entering a new phase of monetary history. We are launching our new system at a time when the world economy shows some signs of improving in some respects, and has some discouraging aspects in other respects. We believe that the world outlook is somewhat brighter; there is slightly higher growth; lower inflation and a better payments balance. But, on the other hand, there are two formidable and related problems, low investment and high unemployment, which may reflect structural changes in the world economy that are not yet clearly preceived or understood, and which we may have to deal with if we are to find the key to widespread and supstained economic growth. Even though the OPEC current account surpluses are declining very sharply this year, you do have still remaining and very prominent imbalances among • the industrialized countries, with the United States on the one hand with a large deficit of about 20 billion and the aggregate surpluses of Japan, Germany and Switzerland of an equivalent amount. Now, there are different ways of approaching a large payments imbalance. The United States has approached the problem in accordance with the philosophy of the new monetary system and the new Article IV. We believe that the new Article IV is at the very heart of that system, and surveillance is at the heart of Article IV. The concept of that article is that international monetary stability cannot be imposed on countries from without as in the par value system but must be developed by countries B-898 - 2 from within through the application of sound, underlying economic and financial policies appropriate to the situation in those individual countries. We in the United States are trying to attack those fundamentals—one by the adoption of a program to reduce our dependence on foreign oil; two, by the President's initiation of comprehensive effort to counter inflation using fiscal restraint as well as the cooperation of business and labor in slowing down price and wage advances, as well as some other means; and three, a new emphasis on improving our export performance. I would like to emphasize that point again— that the new system permits a variety of exchange arrangements but emphasizes a more comprer hensive and continuous analysis and attention to fundamental^ factors such as the ones that I have just discussed. As con-v trasted to the old system, with its emphasis on par values, which was more mechanical in approach. The future of the system depends on how well the Fund performs its surveillance and we must make sure, as the Secretary said, we are doing everything possible to see that this is performed successfully. And then he made some specific suggestions for strengthening the processes of surveillance and thereby improving the balance of payments adjustment process. First, in the category of provision of information it is absolutely essential, we believe, for the Fund to get much more information than it presently has if it is to play its surveillance role correctly. Information on intervention and exchange market conditions is one important area where it must be adequately informed. Data on borrowing in international capital movements might be another. A careful survey should be made of the possible needs for all kinds of information. In the area of organizational changes, the Fund has already taken some important steps both on a set of procedures that were agreed on by the committee, the Interim Committee, at this last meeting. Also, the Managing Director has established a separate office within the Fund's organization to concentrate on surveillance and the operation of the adjustment process. One further possibility that the Secretary suggested today is that since the new Articles permit the establishment of the Council as a permanent organ with decision-making powers to replace the Interim Committee, he felt that this should be seriously explored — this possibility — at an early date. The United States sees merit in the Council and provided there is the necessary widespread support would agree to its establishment. - 3 ^ In a third area — submission of reports — we feel that the Fund might consider the preparation, and perhaps the publication, of a separate annual report or other periodic reports on the operation of the adjustment process and how it is being affected by economic developments in, and policies of, individual countries, both those in surplus and those in deficit. The Secretary went on to address a different area by saying that in addition to preparing the Fund for handling its new surveillance duties effectively, we want to make sure it's well equipped for its other responsibilities, and that brings us to the question of resources and other developments of the monetary system in the quotas and the SDR. He went on to indicate that with respect to the seventh quota review, the United States does not feel that the time is yet right for a decision. We believe that there is still a wide diversity of views, both with respect to the overall size and with respect to distribution, and we believe it is worth getting a few more months experience before deciding about a quota increase, which also will give us some experience on the level of resources, additional resources that the Fund might need, because recently there have been come changes in that situation. With respect to the SDR--well, perhaps I should also say he also indicated that with regard to the SDR interest rate which has been discussed in the board, we would agree to an increase above present levels, and we also believe that it will be desirable for the remuneration rate to remain equal to the SDR interest rate. In regard to an SDR allocation, the Secretary pointed out that there are arguments against it on grounds that there is an excess of international liquidity and we must consider those arguments. There are also arguments in support of an allocation on grounds of the need to maintain viability and credibility of the asset. He pointed out that the SDR is a key component of the monetary system with important long-run potential, and therefore he made the suggestion that one possibility would be to have a modest allocation for three to five years with provision that the next quota increase call for some SDR payment by members. He suggested that the executive board in the coming months study these points and consider a tie between allocations and a quota increase with a view to preparing recommendations for our next meeting. - 4 He went on to comment in addition, regarding the associated proposal for currency substitution, pointing out that . the United States does not seek any such agreement and we would not ourselves propose its consideration — that he has doubts as to its helpfulness to the system and its feasibility. On the other hand, if others wish to see the idea studied, we would not object. I believe that that sums up the various points he made and the broad philosophy in regard as to how the United States sees the monetary system and.Its evolution. I'll take some questions now for about ten minutes. Q: Why are the new surveillance provisions so important for the United States? A: We believe that they focus attention on what we call fundamental policies, as opposed to the previous mechanical arrangements in the par value system. We believe that surveillance will promote a healthy adjustment process both by surplus countries and by debtor countries. Q: * Why is the time right for decision on the modest allocation of SDR's but not in the seventh quota increase? A: I think you misunderstood me. I specifically said that the two should be considered together and the board should consider them together and should also consider our suggestion that part of the quota increase would be paid with SDR's. So, I think you misunderstood. Q: Mr. Solomon, how much is modest, when you speak of modest allocation? 1 billion? 2 billion? A: We don't have a view on that one. There have been various discussions at previous times as to what modest means, and I think probably most people would assume it's somewhere in the neighborhood of two, three, four. We don't have a particular view. We have not focused at this point on the exact number. I think the concept and the possible structure adaptation—all these are much more important than the exact... Q: Is that two, three, four, over a period, or annually? A: The usual discussion has been annually, but I think you are overemphasizing. I wouldn't want you to carry away the impression that we have focused on a number — we feel that the concept, the credibility of the concept, is one chief argument for considering an allocation in connection with the quota increase — that we are suggesting a - 5 new possibility. There are more important points in our suggestion and we ourselves have not particularly examined the exact size within what might be called the modest range. Q: Can you say anything about the reaction to linking the quotas with this modest allocation? A: We haven't heard any reaction yet. The Secretary has just made this statement... Q: There's been no discussion of it yet? A: Right, no*. Q: Did the Secretary mention or indicate that the Carter Administration expects very soon the ratification of the Witteveen facility? Did he indicate that this ratification of the Witteveen facility might also ease up American consideration of a quota increase in the seventh review? A: The agenda item reporting on the status of the Witeveen facility comes this afternoon. The Secretary did not make any comments on that but he will this afternoon. Q: Aside from getting more information for the IMF to do its job, do you discern whether the United States or anybody else favors any further sanctions in country situations? A: I'm not sure I understand what you mean by sanctions. Sanctions, in the sense that if the Fund were to feel that a country has basically broken principles - agreed upon principles — I would not underestimate the importance of the Fund initiating a special consultation because of concern about the member's exchange rate policies and the discussion of that both first with that member country, and then under certain conditions, the management can bring that to the board for a discussion. This is, I think, an important factor, and given the way the Fund operates, it should not be underestimated in terms of the weight of public opinion, of broad international monetary opinion, as reflected by all the member countries in the Fund. And I think that this is more of a factor, and I don't think that sanctions as such, as I see it at this point, make much sense — any explicit sense. Now, we recognize this is going to be an evolving role, this is, in a certain sense a new area and I don't know that will happen in the long run, and whether we will perceive a need for some changes. - 6 Q: While the Minister of Finance of Japan has pointed out that the dollar must be supported so that it continues being the strong currency, the Finance Ministers of Great Britain and France are in favor of SDR' s becoming the reserve of the Fund. What is the United States attitude on this, taking into account the weakness of the dollar in the international exchange markets? A: Your question was, as I understood it, the actual question was, what does the United States think about the weakness of the dollar? Is that it? Q: Yes. A: Sorry, I wasn't sure I understood. If you look at the history of important bilateral exchange rate movements, since we went on floating rates, not just the dollar, but if you look at the charts you will see very substantial cyclical type swings. The particular swing that we have seen this year, starting from the beginning of 77 or the middle of 77 depending on how one measures it, until now, is not greater on a tradeweighted basis than it was in some earlier swings early in the 70's. Now, there have been some larger swings, in regard to one or two other currencies. There also one has to look at questions of differentials in inflation and one has to look at the real exchange rate relationships. The dollar, as I say, has been stronger in the past, will be stronger in the future; there are periods in the flexible exchange-rate system where there will be movements down as well as up, and one has to accept that and recognize that if this is what the world wants — and this is what seems the best type of monetary system, namely a flexible exchange rate system — that there will be these kinds of movements. One has to be reasonably sophisticated about this and these kinds of adjustments have to be understood. There is no country in the world that believes that stronger and stronger and stronger currencies make sense; there has to be a balanced relationship in terms of the adjustment process. This is the only way I can answer your question. If you look at it in the very narrow shortterm frame then obviously you are aware that the United States has taken actions in the last few months to show its concern about the disorderly markets, to intervene as necessary. It's taken some further actions; we determined to protect the integrity of the dollar and will continue to do so. But I think that one should not assume that the fact that there will be periods of decline as well as strength in most any currency, that does not mean that there is a fundamental weakness. That is our view. - 7 Q: Do you think the dollar is now bottoming out as some of the experts may hold? A: I wouldn't want to give a hard view. Obviously there is a considerable sentiment around. One hears this in foreign exchange markets, financial circles, industrial circles. There is a fairly widespread view along those lines. I think it is quite possible. I don't like to make forecasts pn exchange-rate movements. Thank you. * * * * * * * * * * partmentoftheTREASURY IHINGTQN.D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 PRFSS CONFERENCE OF THE HONORABLE W. MICHAEL BLUMENTHAL U. S. SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY AFTER THE INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND INTERIM COMMITTEE TREATY MEXICO CITY APRIL 30, 1978 I will make some brief comments to being with, essentially summarizing our view of the outcome of this meeting. As I understand it, M r . Witteveen and Mr. Healey will be having a press conference later at which the communique will be available to you, so I will not be commenting on the contents of that, nor will I comment on the positions of other countries, but rather on our views and our impressions of this meeting. I would just like to refer briefly to the two major elements that were discussed here in the course of the two days that we m e t — o n e relating to our discussion of the world economy, and in particular, the U. S. economy in that context, and secondly, with regard to the various IMF-related issues that were mentioned. With regard to the world economy, I think there was good progress made in exchanges of views and in understanding of the problems that different countries have. The general feeling was that there is a problem of unsatisfactory growth rates, and high unemployment in the world, as well as a problem of difficult-to-solve inflation, a general feeling that if these factors are not brought under control, the pressures for protectionism will intensify. That is certainly a view that we expressed as well, emphasizing that the multilateral trade negotiations in Geneva, therefore, assume particular importance. We found an encouraging degree of support for our position that we really had to deal with the fundamental issues as far as the United States is concerned, and in that regard the addressing of these issues by the President in the statement of April 11th relating both to the anti-inflation program and the emphasis on the final passage of the energy program, received a great deal of support and encouragement. There clearly was a lot of attention on energy and I would say that we were told clearly that that is an important matter that will contribute greatly to world stability and growth, and to exchange rate stability in the future. B-899 - 2 ~ I was encouraged by the fact that there is a general understanding that intervention in exchange markets is not the way to bring about stability, that one has to deal with the fundamentals, that under certain circumstances to counter disorder intervention is appropriate, but that basically the fundamentals of fighting inflation, of dealing with proper domestic non-inflationary growth policies, are what will determine our overall progress. Generally speaking we were encouraged that at this point most of the countries acknowledged and are in agreement with the sum total of the efforts that we have made to make our contribution to achieving greater exchange rate stability. Although some countries expressed the view that there is concern — that they are concerned about the lack of stability— I was impressed by the fact that there is general agreement that the fundamentals are what come first. On the IMF issues, again, the emphasis was on fundamentals, Our comments were tied very much to the amended articles and to the importance of making the surveillance mechanism work as efficiently as possible. I guess you are aware of the proposals that we made, to make a contribution toward making the surveillance mechanism work better— to provide more information, to make certain organizational changes, and possibly for the preparation of certain reports. All these matters are going to be studied and I*m satisfied that they were well received. On guota increases and SDR allocations, I feel that we made progress although no decisions were, of course, reached here. I think that we have set a stage for further work so that hopefully in the fall we can try to achieve some decisions on these matters after some further work by the IMF, I guess you will see these matters described in the communique to some extent. I think, basically, that describes our general feeling that it's been a productive meeting. No major decisions were made; there was progress in the discussions , identifying the orders of priority, indicating further work that needs to be done, leading toward, hopefuliy, some decisions later in the year. I should say a word about the so-called Witteveen Facility. There's obviously a great deal of interest in putting that facility into effect. There was obviously some interest a^bo>ii'tour progress, since they cannot come into effect without action by the United States. - 3 We explained that there had been some initial delays, and explained to our colleagues that we now were satisfied that progress was accelerating. We said we were optimistic that we could expect action by the Congress within the foreseeable future, that is some time over the next two or three months. I think that's all I'll say. Q: Mike, can you discuss the "Big Five" meeting this morning with us briefly? A: No, I cannot. We met for breakfast and had a very general discussion., of some of the same issues ; that I have touched on, obviously in a more relaxed atmosphere, discussing also the fact that we will be seeing each other again in various other meetings — at the OECD ministerial meeting, for example, and then at the summit in July. Q: Mr. Blumenthal, you discussed at the very outset the fact that there was a general need for world-wide economic growth. Was there any discussion, and will a communique contain any explanation of the general feeling of whether stimulus in a number of countries is required at this time or in the near future? A: You will be able to read the communique. Obviously there was a considerable amount of discussion, both formally and informally, on the need for adequate growth in the principal countries and some descriptions by various countries of the measures that were being taken, the kinds of aims and objectives that they had. Talking about our own situation, we did explain that we were satisfied that based on the track that we're on at the moment, and based on the tax proposals that the President has presented to the Congress, we would achieve our target which I thought would be around four and a half percent in real terms. Q: Mr, Secretary, did you discuss the role and position of the dollar and whether or not the dollar might continue at the current rate, or whether it might fluctuate at different levels? A: We did not get into the problem either of what the proper rate was or whether we expected it to go up or down. We really dealt essentially with the underlying policies that countries were following and should follow, and emphasized the point that it is these policies that will determine the fundamental exchange rate levels. -4Q: Mr. Blumenthal, I would like you to explain, in simple terms that common people will understand, the position of the United States towards the developing countries. A: The United States has a long history of supporting growth and development in the developing countries. We are particularly concerned that the opportunities for meeting basic human needs are achieved as rapidly as possible in all of these countries. And the long history of my country in that regard, of a policy which has really been unchanged over many years, is exemplified by the substantial amounts-" of foreign assistance that we have made available from ove£; many years. It is for this reason that we support strongly the work of the various international financial institutions, particularly the World Bank, the Interamerican Development £ Bank, the Asian and African Development Banks, and so forth-. We believe that is is also important that the developed ^' countries work together with the developing countries harmoniously to lower trade barriers to the exports of the developing countries wherever possible. We further believe that we must cooperate together to help the developing countries which are primarily exporters of commodities and primary products to achieve better prices, and stable prices, for their products. Q: (In Spanish) Mr. Secretary, you say that the rate ofn growth has been slowed down and that in the United States unemployment is creating grave problems for your economy. This does not mean that the contributions which the United States makes to international organizations such as IDB could be reduced? That is to say, not only to the IDB but also to the IMF? A: I think I understood your question. We are presently testifying before the Congress and working with the Congress for the approval of very substantial amounts of resources for the Development Banks. Actually, this year more than in the previous year, and in a good many years; so there's no intention to reduce those contributions. Equally so in the Supplementary and Financing Facility — the Witteveen Facility — we are asking for approval for support of that facility in a very substantial amount, involving some 1.7 billion dollars. Q: Mr. Secretary, was there discussion here by you of the recent Federal Reserve Board moves to increase the federal fund rate unless it tends to slow down excessive growth, and what do you think of that...? A: There was no specific discussion of that point. There was obviously a discussion of the totality of the moves in the United States, both fiscal and monetary, and the impact that we felt these moves would have both on the domestic economy, on confidence as well as on international exchange rates. - 5 Q: Mr. Secretary, do you think that at the summit in Bonn there will be decisions made by the surplus countries to stimulate, or do you think it would be a stand-off where everybody does what he really wants? A: It's difficult for me to speculate what the Heads of State will decide in Bonn next July. I'm encouraged by watching the preparations for the Summit —that there is a good spirit of cooperation, and that the responsibility that each of the countries that will be represented at the Summit feels, not only for the health of its own economy, but also for the impact that its policies have on other countries, is very keenly felt. I think in the light of that sense of responsibility I certainly expect that the decisions will reflect that. Q: Will the instability of the dollar affect that spirit of cooperation? A: I think that based on the measures that have been taken by the United States and the cooperation that exists between the Federal Republic of Germany and ourselves in various ways, the basic soundness of the dollar is being underlined. And I think that, based on the discussions that I've had here, I'm convinced that most of the countries, all of the countries, recognize that we are dealing with the fundamentals, that we are collaborating to eliminate disorderly market conditions, and that that is generally appreciated. Q: Mr. Blumenthal, you mentioned at the outset that there are problems of unsatisfactory growth and went on to say that if these problems are not dealt with, protectionist pressures won't intensify. How are we going to deal with this problem of unsatisfactory growth? A: Obviously, the goal has to be for all of the developed as well as the developing countries to bring about faster growth rates than those that have pertained over the last year. That is a decision, the specific steps that countries have to take. That depends, obviously, on each individual situation, and that is a decision that each country must make on its own. In some instances it relates to increased government spending, in other instances it relates to reduced taxation, and in other instances it relates to specific measures to deal with structural requirements, to stimulate business investment, and to reduce unemployment, and assistance to the developing countries to achieve better growth, requires that the overall level of growth in the OECD countries also is accelerated. Thank you very much, ladies and gentlemen. 0O0 MmentoftheJREASURY MGTON,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 QUESTIONS AND ANSWER PERIOD FOLLOWING ADDRESS BY THE HONORABLE W. MICHAEL BLUMENTHAL SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY AT THE FINANCIAL ANALYSTS FEDERATION BAL HARBOUR, FLORIDA MAY 8, 1978 QUESTION: Mr. Secretary, would you comment on Congressman Ullman's proposal to relieve some of the double taxation of dividends by integrating corporate and individual taxes? REPLY: Well, I think you got a hint of my view on this. We oppose that in this particular bill, not because we oppose the basic notion; indeed, as most of you know, we favor the basic notion. Indeed, it was one of the issues that President Carter felt very strongly about, and we examined it in great detail. The cost of doing this is high. We^only have about $7 billion available for the total effort in this area, and we asked ourselves the question of how that $7 billion can most usefully applied, and we concluded that a reduction in the corporate tax rate by 4 percentage points, based on all the information and evidence we got, was the most effective way of doing that. If we got into the question of...if we took some action on reducing the double taxation of dividends, we would have to take the money from some place, and it would mean that we would be reducing our proposed reduction of the corporate tax rate — four to three or to two. And, on balance, that in our judgement would not be a desirable step to take at this time. Secondly, we believe that, once you get into this problem, you're really into -- logically, technically and equitably — into the whole question of dealing with capital gains, and the marginal rates of unearned income as well. And we feel that, when you approach this problem, you need to approach it as a whole, and you need to look at the totality of this, rather than this one issue. It is for this reason that we have been indicating to Chairman Ullman that in our view this is not the right time, regrettably B-900 to move in that direction. - 2 QUESTION: Mr. Secretary, I have a series of questions here about capital gains taxes and specifically the Steiger proposal in the Ways and Means Committee to roll back the capital gains tax to a maximum of 25 percent. There have been a series of studies, I think -7 the Chase Econometrics model, the Data Resources Econometrics model — that indicate that, over a period of several years, the Government's revenues will actually increase with this proposal. Would you comment on that? REPLY: Well, let me again reiterate the basic point that I am making, which I guess boils down to saying that the President or the Treasury is broke. We don't have the money, and I wish some of you could participate in the excruciating meetings in which I have the dubious pleasure of participating, when we look at the Budget and try to figure out how to bring the Budget'toward balance. Incidentally, one of the key requirements to getting inflation under control, in my judgement, is to get that deficit down, down as quickly as possible and get it toward balance. How to do that'—given the fact that most of the Budget is mandated by law and that it is just virtually impossible to get the Congress to agree to change some of those laws? We're locked in. So you begin with some of these very good ideas, and the first thing you ask yourself, particularly when you're Secretary of the Treasury, is how much? Well, I'll tell you* in 1978 numbers, the Steiger proposals would cost about $4-1/2 billion. That's by 1978 numbers, and I learned at the Bendix Corporation and on various other financial committees, under the "falling off the cliff theory," it is useful to ask: How much is it in'79,'80, and'82? There's a favorite sport in Washington called "phasing in." "Let's phase it in slowly," they say. Well, you phase things in slowly—we've been phasing them in slowly for the last 20 years — and that's why we have the kind of Budget problems we do, because we have now laws and statutes under which things" only cost a quarter of a billion dollars," and now they cost $10 billion, because we phasedthem-in a few years ago. The $4-1/2 billion in 1978 will rise substantially in succeeding years. Secondly, the large portion of the benefits of that kind of proposal would accrue to people making more than $200,000 a year. We don't think that that's acceptable. Ninety-seven percent of the Steiger proposal, as it relates - 3to the changes in the alternative tax, would accrue to people making more than $200,000 a year. Fifty-six percent of the revenues would go to people making more than $200,000 a year, as it refers to that part of the proposal which deals with the elimination of the minimum tax. And so forth and so on. So, if we did it, we would virtually have to scrap the reduction in the corporate tax rate — which in my judgement would not be desirable — for we couldn't afford $7 billion and another $4-1/2 this year, which would rise to $5 or whatever next year and beyond. And then I just don't see how we could defend giving that kind of break essentially to people that make more than $200,000 a year and certainly most of it to those who make more than $100,000 a year. It would accelerate capital formation to some extent, but as my presentation, I think , intended to show, the best way to increase capital formation, along with controlling inflation and government regulations, is to increase profitability of American business overall. And we think that the reduction in the corporate tax rate really does that better than any of these alternative approaches. COMMENT: I've been asked by my fellow panelists to request of those who make questions that they print plainly —we're having a little difficulty interpreting some of these. QUESTION: Mr. Secretary, I have a question for you. It's of a little different dimension. The capital formation problem is a worldwide one. It weakens the dollar and causes inflationary pressures on other economies. What series of steps are next in mind, or what's the next line of defense, should the dollar come under attack again. I know we've taken some, but it's never a certainty. What proposals will be introduced next if that event should occur? REPLY: Do you really expect me to tell you? This is a very, very difficult problem, and it requires a great deal of care and caution, and if there is one thing that I have learned in the last 16 months, it's just how much care and caution it does require. We are living in a world of flexible exchange rates. We have $500 billion of capital out there in the Euro markets—$500 billion—floating around, able to move rather rapidly. There is no way in which we can seek to maintain an exchange rate at a particular point or in a particular target zone as we did under the old Bretton Woods system. We scrapped that system some years ago because we recognized that. Under flexible system in the aUnited States,, and of exchange rates, we believe - 4 we have been following that policy steadfastlyB that countries must deal with the fundamentals of economic circumstance. The fundamentals relate to the control of inflation, for it is differential rates of inflation that cause changes in exchange rate relationships; the rate of growth, for it is differences in the rate of growth that cause these same changes; and the elimination of surpluses and deficits in the current accounts of the major countries. The United States has been following and will continue to follow a policy of emphasizing these fundamentals in order to deal with the exchange rate problem. If we do not bring the problem of inflation under control, the maintenance of stability in the dollar will be that much more difficult. If we do not maintain an adequate growth rate, and if other countries do not achieve adequate rates of growth, then again, the stability of the dollar will be that much more difficult to maintain. That indeed has been one of the problems over the last year or two—that we were more successful emerging from the recession than other countries. We grew at a substantially faster rate than other countries. As a result, we were unable to export to the slow-growing economies where many of our customers are, and we sucked in imports more quickly into our more-quickly growing economy. The only thing we can do beyond that—dealing with these fundamentals, and that is increasingly understood by other countries—is to, well let me deal with one other fundamental first, which is to reduce our unacceptably large balance-of-trade deficit, over $30 billion last year. And, again, that relates importantly to the competitiveness of American industry in traditional products, technology^-intensive products, and we are specializing in the exports of technology-intensive products, and that's why the lack of investment in R & D is such a worrisome thing in this country but, also the question of energy. Amongst the problems that are the most important, or candidates for the most important, clearly the problem of energy is high up on the list. And our inability after 13 months of showing the national will to pass energy legislation and to show the world that we have an energy policy clearly is also an important factor that causes the instability of the dollar. If we can pass an energy policy, which means that the world can see that we will be reducing gradually dependence on imported oil, we will be reducing that very, very large bill of $45 billion for imported oil—or at least not increasing beyond to deal exchange of disorder. that with markets, it—that are the Wecertain elimination have to toocounteract will done measures have a of great disorderly impact speculation that deal. are on available the We conditions and have dollar. that anto kind agreein And usthe - 5ment with the Germans—this was announced some time ago— which signals a variety of ways in which we can marshall and are marshalling the resources, and it is that kind of policy that we will continue in close collaboration with other countries. QUESTION: Mr. Secretary, there are a number of questions focusing on the general issue of the level of government spending which are summed up, I think, by this one question. Total spending by Federal, State, and local government in the U.S. is about 34 percent of the GNP. What can the Administration do to bring it down more in line with 19 to 21 percent spending level in Japan and West Germany? REPLY: Well, a year ago, many of the business and financial audiences that I addressed, and many of the discussions that I had, and questions and comments, that I got, reflected a concern by the listeners that there was not a clear indication of the philosophy and goals of the new Administration as regards econ^nic policy. I certainly was impressed by the prevalence of that concern, and therefore I, along with some of my colleagues, urged strongly that we correct that impression. I think the President's Budget statement and Economic Message of January of this year does so. It states clearly that there is an intention of his part to bring the government Budget into balance by 1981, substantially reducing the deficit in the interim, and that Federal expenditures as a percentage of GNP are to be reduced from the 22.6—23 percent—down to 21 percent, over this period. This being done by a tight lid on Federal spending, a tight lid which is very, very difficult to keep tight. And you look at the daily reports in the newspapers of actions in the government to increase spending—for foreign purposes, for water projects, for a whole host of things that make some sense in an individual setting but that tend to bust the Budget—and you look at all of the good ideas for reducing taxes and therefore revenue, which would further unbalance the Budget—for tuition tax credits, for urban tax credits, for Social Security and a whole host—there are dozens of good tax credit ideas... We are going to move down to 21 percent, we are trying to keep income taxes at no more than 14 percent of personal income— no, total taxes at no more than —for Federal, 14 percent— and income taxes at about 10.4 percent. - 6 The only way to do this is, month after month, year after year, to try to implement that policy, and the President in his April 11 speech said it clearly. He is prepared to use all the powers of his office, which means veto powers, to avoid the spending of additional money and to let the economy grow while keeping the government Budget down. It's a very difficult job, and it needs your support. - 7QUESTION: Mr. Secretary, in contrast to your comments on the high consumption rate in this country, the tax program still seems to be focused primarily on increasing consumption rather than on increasing investment. Are decisions in this area based on what's good politics rather than what's good economics? REPLY: Well, if I told you that decisions on economic matters are made without an eye toward the political impact, you wouldn't believe me, anyway. (Laughter) So I would not say in a democracy, both as regards the executive as well as the legislative branches of government, the political impact of particular decisions is not considered. But, I would say that the program that the President proposed is not a political program in that sense. Witness the fact... and I would say it is a pro-business program in the sense that about between a third and a quarter of the cuts are directed to business; they are, in fact, designed to increase profitability and to stimulate capital investment, which has been lagging; and they tend to concentrate the personal income tax cuts to those levels of taxpayers who are most hurt and most affected by the high level of taxation, because of inflation, and by the increasing need to tax more on Social Security in order to keep the Trust Funds in good shape. I don't think that you can say it's political to have most of the tax reductions go to people who make 14, 15, 16, 18 thousand dollars a year, for it's hard to raise a family on that. But we have put a great deal into the business sector, we have responded to the desires of the business community, and I therefore think it would be unfair and incorrect to label the President's program as being political without due consideration of the economic goals that we're seeking to achieve. QUESTION: Mr. Secretary many of the questions that have been submitted reflect a great deal of cynicism about the prospective efficacy of the inflation program—namely, exhortation or jaw-boning. I think the basic debate relates to how much room is left in the economy to grow without putting increasing inflationary pressures into play. There've been several studies that suggest that perhaps our estimates of our ability to output goods are too high. To introduce on that basis the full employment deficit notion in formulating fiscal policy may meet with an endless trap, because it seems to take more and more to do less and less. What kind of test, or what kind of examination, can be done to resolve what I think is really kind of a pivotal question? REPLY: I think it's a very important and a very good knows question, enough andabout I would thesay problem, that no the country, causes and including the cures our own, of - 8 modern inflation. I once was an economist, and I don't mention that too often because I don't have much pride in my former profession, in that regard. For the economic profession really is bankrupt when it comes to the theory of modern inflation. When I look at the mail that I receive, or samples— I get so much of it I can't see all of it—samples of the mail that I receive, I'm impressed by the fact that thoughtful people throughout the country all have a simple explanation of inflation. Generally, inflation-fighting and the cures for inflation that people suggest are much like taxation; it's somebody else's ox that is to be gored. Most people think inflation is caused only by the government—my colleagues in the government think it's caused only by big companies, and many big companies think it's caused only by monopolistic unions. The fact of the matter is—this is the Blumenthal theory of inflation, probably worth as much as the others—(Laughter) that inflation is caused by a number of factors that act together and interact in strange and mysterious ways. Some of it clearly is government fiscal policy and monetary policy; some of it is government regulation; some of it is external factors, the price of oil, the decisions OPEC makes, the weather, these exogenous factors have an impact on inflation. Some of it is clearly is business and labor trying to run faster in order to keep up and thereby pushing up wages and prices. The solution on the problem of inflation, therefore, at any level in an economy which is not truly flexible and which does not function the way classical theory teaches us has to be to attack all of these problem in some coherent fashion. But clearly, as long as we have still six million people unemployed, as long as we still have 83 percent of industrial plant utilized there is room, although there are these inflexibilities. We have found that, even at much lower levels of plant utilization, we have these inflationary pressures. I don't think that we can cure inflation with a low level of economic activity—even when there's no growth we've had inflation—we've seen that. The worst inflation we've had was when we were in the worst recession. But if that's true, if you can't cure inflation by stagnating the economy, then at 83 percent also we have some room for reducing the number of unemployed further and at the same time dealing with the problem of inflation. What we're trying to do is to attack both of those problems at the same time because they do not fully interact in the way in which we originally thought they did. - 9 - QUESTION: Mr. Secretary, you mentioned in your prepared remarks the greater productivity in capital formation in several other nations. Would you please comment on the capital gains taxation in other countries, specifically, West Germany and Japan. REPLY: I think it is difficult to ascribe a particular result to any one... related to any one particular cause. Actually, the level of taxation on individuals, on the average, is higher in most of Europe than it is in the United States. Relatively speaking, we pay—although we don't feel that way, we feel very oppressed—on the average, we as individuals pay somewhat less in taxes than the Europeans do. Equally, business taxation in many of the European countries is as high er higher on the average than it is in this country. And it is my feeling that it is the overall level of taxation and of profitability which tends to determine how much people save and how they apply those savings. I think it is true that the climate, the relationship, between government and business is very different in Germany and in Japan and in Europe than it is in this country. We tend to look upon each other with a certain amount of skepticism, and government and business does not have a close relationship, and as someone who has been on both sides of the fence, I think I have a very clear feeling of the depths of this sense of suspicion. That's not true in the European countries and in Japan. Therefore, questions such as government regulations—the extent of those—the form of taxation, what needs to be done, how much needs to be exported, how R & D is to be financed and applied are really settled in a much more cooperative spirit. I can tell you that that's difficult to do in the United States, even the problem of inflation. The President took a decision to keep government wage increases to 5-1/2 percent if he can. He took a decision to freeze executive pay. He took a number of other important decisions which politically are very difficult—talking about the politics of these things. It's very, very difficult to get a private sector to do its part and to comply. They don't want regulations, and also don't really feel comfortable about supporting these kinds of government initiatives. I think that's the essential difference between these other countries and ourselves. And I think we need to work on that and establish a better climate in which these decisions are made, rather than any particular one. - 10 - QUESTION: Mr. Secretary, would you comment on the proposition that a reduction of capital gains tax would actually increase government revenues through the stimulative effect on investment. REPLY: I can aomment very simply—there is no evidence, no objective evidence that this is so. Let me give you one example—people frequently say the Kennedy tax cut, and they say, "look at the Kennedy tax cut. He cut taxes greatly and government revenues increased greatly in succeeding years." The problem is that cause and effect are very difficult to ascertain—to correlate. You can correlate the amount of sunshine in certain years with the numbers of births in Bangladesh... But it's not necessarily true that one had anything to do with the other. We don't know what would have happened in the American economy in the absence of that kind of a tax cut. Indeed, there is a lot of evidence that the U. S. economy.was, willynilly, in a strong growth mode during this period, and that much of the increase in revenue had very little to do with that particular tax cut—we just don't know. All of the evidence that we have indicates that a reduction in the capital gains tax certainly would be £ beneficial thing, and I'd love to see it. It would be stimulative in many ways, but it would not increase Federal revenues... If that were clear, I would be really out there—so would the President and everyone else—cutting the dickens out of capital gains taxes, because that would be the way to balance the budget. Unfortunately, that is an option that none of the computers, and none of the economists, and none of the observers that do that analysis tell us is open to us. Thank you very much. (END) FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY "EXPECTED AT 10:00 EDST MAY 17, 1978 STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE BETTE B. ANDERSON UNDER SECRETARY OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON HISTORIC PRESERVATION! AND COINAGE OF THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS Thank you, Mr. Chairman, for this opportunity to appear before your Subcommittee today in support of legislation the Secretary has recornnended for a new dollar coin. We particularly appreciate the promptness with which this hearing has been called following the submission of the proposal, since time is an important element in the Department's recommendation. The proposal before you, Mr. Chairman, is essentially simple. Ws are reconmending that the current dollar coin, which, because of its size and bulk, has never achieved acceptance by the American public, be replaced by a smaller, lighter dollar coin. The objective of our proposal is basically twofold — to provide for a useful denomination in our coinage system and, at the same time, to effect savings for our Government and the economy as a whole. By way of a brief background, the current cupro-nickel clad dollar was first authorized by the Cbngress in the Act of B-901 - 2 - December 31, 1970, as a replacement for the standard silver dollar. In that Act, the Congress repealed the Department's statutory authority to mint and issue the standard 90% silver dollar and authorized in its stead a base metal dollar coin having essentially the same size. Thus, the current dollar has a diameter of 1.5 inches and weighs nearly 23 grams. Since 1971, when the Mint first started to issue the clad dollar coin, it has not succeeded in becoming a useful part of our coinage system. Because of the lack of public demand, the dollar coin has represented less than one percent of the Mint's annual production each year. Indeed, even this minimal demand for the dollar can be attributed, to a great extent, to its usage in gaming machines rather than to its useability as a medium of exchange. According to our studies, the lack of public interest in the current dollar coin is directly attributable to its cumbersome size and weight. It cannot readily be carried by our citizens in their purses and pockets. In addition, the large size of the coin has made it iitpracticable for the automated merchandising industry to adjust their equipment to accept the large dollar coin. The smaller coin we are now proposing would be sized between the quarter and half-dollar with a diameter of approximately one inch and a vreight of approximately 8 grams. We hope that such a smaller, more conveniently sized coin would be far more acceptable to the general public and would ultimately gain widespread usage. - 3 - If the proposed dollar is accepted by the general public, it could result in considerable savings both for our Government and the economy as a whole. Since the coin would last at least 15 years in circulation, conpared to 18 months for a one-dollar note, each coin wDuld save over 80% of the production costs of the notes displaced. With nearly 3 billion one-dollar Federal notes in circulation today, even a modest displacement by the dollar coin could result in savings of millions of dollars in production costs. Moreover, according to our estimates, even a 20% displacement of notes by the coins would permit Treasury to defer a costly facility expansion at the Bureau of Engraving and Printing for the foreseeable future. To the extent that the new coin circulates at least as widely as the current clad dollar, there would be immediate savings for the Government. The cost of producing the proposed dollar would be 3 cents a coin as conpared to the current production cost of 8 cents per dollar coin. Thus, even if the Mint were to issue no greater quantity of the new dollars than the large dollar coins it has produced annually since 1971, the Government would still save approximately $4.5 million a year. To comment briefly on the design of the new dollar, the Department has selected a modernized version of the classic Liberty design for the coin. At the same time, to honor and commemorate President Eisenhower, whose image now appears on the dollar coin, the Department would continue to be authorized to mint 40% silver - 4 clad Eisenhovrer dollar coins in the current 1.5 inch diameter size. These silver clad dollar coins would not be part of our circulating coinage but would only be available to collectors and the general public in proof and uncirculated quality. This, Mr. Chairman, completes my general comments on the dollar proposal. The Director of the Mint, Mrs. Stella B. Hackel, will describe some of the more technical aspects of the proposal for the Subcommittee. # # # partmentoftheJREASURY 5HINGT0N,D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 10:00 EDST MAY 17, 1978 STATEMENT OF THE HONORABLE STELLA B. HACKEL DIRECTOR OF THE MINT BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON HISTORIC PRESERVATION AND COINAGE OF THE HOUSE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, FINANCE AND URBAN AFFAIRS As Under Secretary Anderson has indicated, Mr. Chairman, my testimony will deal with the technical aspects of the dollar coin proposal. I appreciate this opportunity to appear before you, Mr. Chairman, in support of this proposal. If the proposed bill insets the approval of the Congress, it would result in a significant iirprovement in our coinage system. The limited usefulness of the current dollar coin has been of concern to the Bureau for several years. It has been clear to us for some time that, primarily due to its cumbersome size and weight, the dollar coin cannot effectively serve as a medium of exchange. Our views have been reaffirmed by an independent study conducted by the Research Triangle Institute, concluded in 1976. It was the finding of the study that a smaller $1 coin, sized between the current quarter and half-dollar, would be far more acceptable to the general public than the existing coin. B-902 - 2 PHYSICAL CHARACTERISTICS In determining the appropriate physical size of a new coin, the Mint has considered several factors, including handling convenience and the potential for counterfeiting or slugging. The recanriended weight of 8.1 grams is the lcwest possible weight for convenient handling by the general public, while at the same time, being sufficiently heavy to be readily distinguishable from the quarter. The quarter weighs 5.67 grams, thus, the proposed coin would be 43% heavier than the quarter. I should point out, Mr. Chairman, that the weight for the new dollar proposed in our legislation is specified as 8.5 grams. However, after submission of the proposal, we were advised by the coin sorting manufacturers that a dollar coin with a slightly lcwer weight would facilitate high speed coin sorting. Since coin sorting machines are used by all major retailers and banks, we feel this is a legitimate consideration; thus, we now recommend that the weight be changed in the proposed bill from 8.5 grams to 8.1 grams. The new dollar would be distinguishable from the quarter by touch as well as by sight. The design proposed would have an eleven-sided inner border on both sides of the coin within the outer circular configuration. This design element would provide a means for tactile recognition by the visually handicapped. - 3 - For purposes of high uti.lizat.ion in automatic niee hmdi-;i.n<| devices, it is essential that the size of the coin preclude she usi. of readily available low value foreign coins of identical sL/e to slug the equipment. A diameter of 1.043 inches in size (20. > :ui.1.1.ureter best meets this requirement and has been endorsed by the rna jor manufacturers of automatic coin handling equipment. Further, to prevent the slugging of the new coin by reducing the diameter of the current half-dollar, the thickness of the cupro-nickel outer layers would be increased. The clad layers would constitute 50% of the total thickness of the coin as conpared to one-third in our current cupro-nickel clad on copper coins. COMPOSITION Except for the two minor coin denominations, the cent and the nickel, all circulating U.S. coins are made of a cupro-nickel alloy bonded on both sides to a pure copper core. This composition has many advantages, including superior surface wear and appearance, and relative low cost to produce. Overall it is approximately W co. *-er, and economically, fabricated into coinage strip for high relief. coins. Also, the unique electrical properties and density of this cupro-nickel ("sandwich") laminate make it very difficult to counterfeit- or sluq. Many materials — including several copper alloys, tj.tam.Di, and other clad combinations — were tested to determine the rnr.t suitable composition for the new coin. The results of the studies - 4 indicate that the best overall material is a 75% copper/25% nickel alloy clad on a 100% copper core. Except for the thickness of the cupro-nickel cladding for the new smaller dollar coin, this laminate is the sane material now being used in all of our coin denominations other than the five cent and one cent coins. Manufacturing cost is estimated at 3 cents per coin compared to 8 cents for the current 1.5 inch diameter dollar coin DESIGN Throughout our history various Liberty designs have been predominant on our circulation coins until the last few decades when, on historically significant occasions, U.S. Presidents were selected for such honor. Benjamin Franklin, who holds a unique position in our history, appeared on the half-dollar for a period of fifteen years and is the lone exception to the abstract or Presidential designs. The recommended design for the obverse is a modern or stylized female Liberty Head. This historic design appeared on the first U.S. coins minted in 1793, and appeared in various forms on almost all denominations of our coins through modern times. The female Liberty Head is symbolic of and honors all women rather than any particular individual. It is accompanied by the Phrygian Cap which has been a symbol of freedom for over 2500 years and has repeatedly appeared on our coins. It is most appropriate that such a historic American design once again return to an American coin. - 5 - The recommended design for the reverse is a Soaring or Volant Eagle. The eagle has appeared on the reverse of every dollar coin since 1794 with the exception of the gold coins. The recomirended design, though similar to the 1916 quarter-dollar eagle, is a irore vivid rendition emphasizing the independence and spirit which characterizes this national symbol. Many distinguished American men and women have made substantial contributions to our country which are worthy of recognition. A select few have been honored on limited issue comremorative coins. The new dollar coin is intended to circulate widely; thus, a design consistent with the historical precedents established by the Secretary of the Treasury and the Congress would be most appropriate. In our view, expanding the field of design selection beyond historical abstracts and U.S. Presidents would set an unwise course in coin design, and invite a controversial debate which would tend to damage the overall success of the proposal. EISENHOWER DOLLAR As the Ifiider Secretary noted in her testimony, the proposed bill would authorize the Department to continue the minting of the 40% Eisenhower silver dollar in its present size. If approved by the Congress, the bill would thus authorize the first commemorative U.S. coin to differ not only in design and alloy but also in size from the circulating coin of identical denomination. - 6 - PRODUCTION PLAN At such time as the legislation is approved by the Congress, the Mint would immediately start the contracting process for the necessary coinage strip. This would take approximately three months; at that point, we could start the actual production of the coins. Were the recommended, design adopted, approximately two months would be required for the Mint to complete the fabrication of dies and the procurement of the production tooling necessary for the new coin, during which time the coinage strip would also be procured. Our plan is to undertake production at an accelerated rate, producing 500 million pieces of the new coin in six months, prior to their release to the public. Such a large inventory of coins prior to initial distribution would assure an equitable and adequate supply of coins throughout the Nation. This statement concludes my prepared remarks, Mr. Chairman. I would be pleased to answer any questions you may have. # # # FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May lb, 1978 Contact: Charles Arnol'd 566-2041 TREASURY ANNOUNCES COUNTERVAILING DUTY INVESTIGATION OF IMPORTS OF OLEORESINS FROM INDIA The Treasury Department today announced an investigation to determine whether the Government of India is subsidizing exports of oleoresins. The investigation results from a petition filed on behalf of domestic interests. An oleoresin is a thick liquid extract of the flavor of a spice used primarily as a seasoning in the food industry. The Countervailing Duty Law requires that the Secretary of the Treasury collect an additional duty that equals the size of the "bounty or grant" (subsidy) paid on the exportation or manufacture of merchandise imported into the United States. A preliminary determination in this case must be made not later than September 21, 1978, and a final determination no later than March 21, 1979. Notice of this action will appear in the Federal Register on May 16, 1978. Imports of oleoresins from India amounted to approximately $1.5 million during calendar year 1977. «.».. /» B-903 «.»«. /» •.»/> Department of thefREASURY TELEPHONE 566-2041 IN6T0N, D.C. 20220 May 15, 1978 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE RESULTS OF TREASURY'S WEEKLY BILL AUCTIONS Tenders for $2,200 million of 13-week Treasury bills and for $3,400 million of 26-week Treasury bills, both series to be issued on May 1 8 , 1978, were accepted at the Federal Reserve Banks and Treasury today. T h e details are as follows: RANGE OF ACCEPTED COMPETITIVE BIDS: High Low Average 13-week bills maturine August 1 7 , 1978 26-week b i l l s maturing November 16, 1978 Price Discount Rate Investment Rate 1/ Price 98.411 98.396 98.403 6.286% 6.345% 6.318% 6.48% 6.54% 6.51% 96.466 6.990% 96.447 7.028% 96.454 7.014% Discount Rate Investment Rate 1/ 7.35% 7.39% 7.37% Tenders at the low price for the 13-week bills w e r e allotted Tenders at the low price for the 26-week bills w e r e allotted TOTAL TENDERS RECEIVED AND A C C E P T E D BY FEDERAL RESERVE DISTRICTSAND T R E A S U R Y : Location Received Accepted Received Boston New York Philadelphia Cleveland Richmond Atlanta Chicago St. Louis Minneapolis Kansas City Dallas & an Francisco $ $ $ Treasury TOTALS 29,490,000 3,484,550,000 22,730,000 46,565,000 31,120,000 36,835,000 297,975,000 46,745,000 24,725,000 43,305,000 13,930,000 295,805,000 5,925,000 $4,379,700,000 29,490,000 1,697,350,000 22,730,000 46,565,000 31,120,000 36,835,000 72,975,000 24,705,000 24,725,000 43,305,000 13,930,000 150,805,000 5,915,000 33,145,000 5,057,955,000 23,410,000 161,545,000 32,995,000 28,215,000 386,385,000 41,190,000 26,175,000 32,730,000 8,680,000 314,820,000 8,600,000 $2,200,450,000a/: $6,155,845,000 eludes $397,760,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. ^eludes $212,910,000 noncompetitive tenders from the public. bivalent coupon-issue yield. Accepted $ 23,145,000 2,851,055,000 23,410,000 91,545,000 13,995,000 27,660,000 94,835,000 13,190,000 23,175,000 32,730,000 7,680,000 189,350,000 8,600,000 $3,400,370,000 b/ FOR RELEASE ON DELIVERY (Approximately 1;30 PoM0> May 15, 1978) Remarks by The Honorable Anthony M. Solomon Under Secretary of the Treasury for Monetary Affairs Before the International Herald Tribune^ Forex Research Ltdo Conference on "Managing Foreign Exchange Risk" New York, May 15, 1978 Exchange Market Developments and U0S0 Policy I appreciate the opportunity to participate in this conference on managing foreign exchange risko Many here today are in a real sense on the front lines of the international monetary system, making operating decisions that collectively can have a profound effect on the operation of that system and the stability of the world economyG It is important that we in government understand your concerns and problems and that you understand the objectives of government policies0 The Value of the Dollar The UoSo current account balance deteriorated rapidly in the latter half of 1976 and in 1977. By the fourth quarter of last year, the deficit was running at an annual rate of $28 billion0 The rapidity and extent of the deterioration did not become fully apparent until the third quarter of 1977 and, to some extent, caught the markets by surprise0 B-905 - 2- Two major factors in the deterioration are by now well known: The UoS0 has been growing markedly faster than other industrial countries., Since 1975, industrial production in 13 other leading OECD countries has grown only 14 percent compared to 25 percent for the U 0 S 0 Last year, U a S 0 industrial production grew almost 6 percent while production abroad failed to grow at alio — UoSo oil imports in 1977 were $45 billion, up from $27 billion in 1975 and less than $5 billion in 1972„ Continued delay in Congressional action on the energy legislation served to highlight the difficult structural adjustments that have to be made to curb our voracious energy appetite» As the fourth quarter of 1977 approached, growing awareness of the change in our position and doubts about early correction led to a change in expectations about the dollar exchange ratee Changing expectations, in turn, brought uncertainty and disorder in the markets0 In this atmosphere, there was an outflow of private capital, plus unrecorded transactions, of some $10 billion in the fourth quarter of 1977, compared to an outflow averaging $1% billion during each of the first three quarters0 With exchange markets - 3- under substantial pressure, countries in surplus intervened heavily to slow the appreciation of their currencies. Official dollar holdings rose $15% billion in the fourth quarter, primarily through accumulations by a small group of industrial countries in strong surplus positions. Uncertainty and disorder continued periodically through most of the first quarter of this year. Gradually, in recent weeks, the tone of the foreign exchange market has improved. The amount of official intervention has abated sharply, and the intervention that has taken place has more frequently taken the form of dollar sales rather than dollar purchases -indeed, there have been net invention sales of dollars on the order of $2-3 billion since March. The dollar has appreciated against OECD currencies by about 1% percent since the end of March, with larger increases against the currencies of the main industrial countries in surplus. In part, this change in tone reflects greater awareness of U.S. determination to take the fundamental measures required for a sound dollar. It may also reflect greater recognition of some important improvements in the underlying economic situation. With an improvement in market confidence, interest rate differentials have begun to exert more influence on the direction of capital flows. The performance of the stock market may also be having an impact. - 4 Before discussing the U.S. approach to exchange market developments, I want to put recent exchange rate movements in perspective,. The two formal dollar devaluations in 1971 and 1973 were part of major multilateral realignments of exchange rates designed to correct the over-and-undervaluation of a wide range of currencies that had accumulated during the post-var period. Since the general move toward more flexible rates in March 1973, several currencies have appreciated substantially against the dollar -- the Swiss franc by 64 percent, the German mark 35 percent and the Japanese yen by 17 percento However, during the same period, other currencies have depreciated against the dollar, including the Canadian dollar by 11 percent, the pound sterling by 26 percent and the Italian lira by 35 percento There are various calculations that attempt to measure overall changes in the exchange values of currencies. The Treasury publishes an average for the dollar vis-a-vis the currencies of all other OECD countries, with individual exchange rate changes weighted on the basis of U 0 S 0 bilateral trade with the countries concernedo On this basis during the past few years, the dollar has fluctuated within a narrower range than against some individual currencies. The recent move- ment, a decline of about 6 percent since September, is large but substantially less than the press reports might suggest. Such changes have occurred in the past in both directions when economic conditions were particularly unsettled. In the latter - 5 half of 1973 the dollar rose by 13 percent, and during the last three quarters of 1975 by 8 percent. On balance the dollar is at present about 2 percent above its March 1973 level on this average basis. That the dollar should have depreciated in relation to some currencies while rising in relation to others over the past five years should not be surprising, in view of the wide disparities in economic performance among major countries on growth, inflation, and external imbalances. less There have nonethe- been charges that the U.S. has practiced a policy of benign or even malign neglect on exchange rate matters in order to gain a competitive advantage. The evidence simply does not support such a charge, and I can assure you that that is not and will not be U.S. policy. The impact of exchange rate changes on competitiveness is extremely difficult to measure. Exchange rate changes reflect capital movements as well as trade. quality, delivery, financing — competitiveness. Non-price factors -- also play an important part in Comparisons are also sensitive to the base from which one starts. However, independent analyses show that changes in dollar exchange rates have generally offset relative inflation rates and that there was virtually no net change in the U.S. competitive position — price adjusted exchange rates — first three quarters of 1977. as measured by between mid-1975 and the The most recent exchange rate movements have, of course, led to a modest improvement in the U.S. competitive position. But even taking these changes - 6 into account, at the end of March 1978 the dollarfs position on this measure was only about 1 to 2 percent above the level prevailing at the time of the general move to more flexible rates five years earlier. Exchange rate changes for the dollar have broadly kept pace with inflation differentials in the last few years ~ not significantly more. The experience of other major countries on this measure of "real" exchange rates since the move to more flexible exchange rates in March 1973 has been mixed. As of the end of March 1978: -- Italy, Canada and Japan had experienced modest improvements in their competitive positions. In Italy and Canada, the rate of exchange rate depreciation more than offset relatively poor price performance producing "real" exchange rate changes on the order of 5 - 10 percent. In Japan, yen appreciation was more than fully compensated by a relatively good record on inflation, resulting in a gain in price competitiveness of somewhat less than 5 percent. -- Germany and the United Kingdom had experienced deterioration in their competitive position on the order of 5 - 10 percent. The appreciation of the German mark has more than offset relatively - 7 - good price performance. Relatively poor price performance in the U.K. was only partly offset by a depreciation of sterling. -- France, like the United States, was in roughly the same position as five years ago, with only a very minor deterioration in the competitive position. The evidence suggests that, with some exceptions, exchange rate changes over the period as a whole have tended to stabilize "real" exchange rates. That is, they have been in the direction needed to offset or partly offset relative price differentials, and thus have resulted in smaller "real" exchange rate changes than would have occurred otherwise. This is a sensible result: it has probably helped in the correction of existing imbalances in some cases, and has certainly helped to avoid the emergence of even larger imbalances in others. The Outlook In terms of the market, what happened yesterday, let alone last year, is history. Your concerns are about today, tomorrow and, perhaps, next year. Your program suggests that some - 8 speakers may be willing to offer exchange rate forecasts. I wish them success but will not join in a forecasting effort. What I will do is offer my view of underlying trends in the world economy and discuss U.S. exchange rate policy. As I look at the world economy for 1978,three positive points stand out. First, real growth will be somewhat better balanced among countries. U.S. growth will be somewhat slower than last year although the 4 to 4% percent rate which we now expect will still be enough to reduce unemployment further. Although first quarter growth has been disappointing in Europe — as well as in the U.S. — European and Japanese growth should pick up modestly later in the year. On average, these countries may reach 3% percent this year, about % percent higher than in 1977. The EC is aiming at an average growth rate of 4% percent by mid-1979. The developing countries should experience more vigorous growth than their industrial country counterparts, perhaps 5% percent. By the latter part of the year, growth rates abroad should be nearly equal to that of the U.S. This expected convergence of growth rates among industrial countries should tend to reduce existing payments imbalances„ - 9 - Second, the OPEC current account surplus should drop a startling $10-15 billion in 1978 to about $20 billion or so. The principal factors include the decision to freeze prices, new sources of supply from the North Sea and Alaska, more efficient utilization of energy, and the slower growth in industrial countries which leaves total demand below earlier expectations. Moreover, an increasing portion of OPEC's financial surplus is being invested at medium term, and, as the world's largest capital market, the U.S. receives a substantial share. We estimate that some 70 percent of the cumulative OPEC surplus has been placed in dollar instruments, about 25 percent in the U.S. market itself. Contrary to some press reports, there is no evidence of an OPEC shift away from dollar investments during the recent exchange market disorders. Indeed, very preliminary information for the first quarter of this year indicates that a high and perhaps even larger proportion of OPEC assets was placed in the United States. An OPEC surplus in the range expected in 1978 is manageable in the medium term and should allow the industrial countries to return toward a more traditional position of current account surplus. Third, inflationary pressures are continuing their slow decline—at least for the developed world as a whole. In 1978, consumer price rises in industrial countries may average 7 percent, following 8 percent last year, with the disparity in inflation rates narrowing. Inflation in the U.K. is moving below double digit rates for the first time in five years. With the possible exception of the United States, all OECD nations are expected to hold current inflation rates or register some - - JLU improvement this year. Even with the prospect of somewhat higher growth and slower inflation in most areas, there is widespread concern about the economic outlook. This is particularly true in Europe where even the higher growth rates now in prospect are too low to reduce unemployment. In many of these countries, unemployment continues at near-record levels. The short-term outlook for plant and equipment investment in most European countries remains weak, especially for this phase of the recovery cycle, and particularly in light of the need to replace capital stock rendered obsolete by the sharp increase in energy costs. The current account imbalances among industrial countries remain large. The U.S. deficit was $20 billion last year. It is likely to be at least as large in 1978 as a whole given the very high trade deficit of more than $11 billion in the first quarter, though that deficit is expected to decline in the last three quarters. The surpluses of Japan, Germany and Switzerland are equally large. the OPEC surplus. In fact they now proximate Clearly there is a need for more adjustment by all four of these major industrial countries. For Japan, Germany and Switzerland, that adjustment should come primarily from faster growth, an opening up of markets, and structural change in production patterns. - 11 - For the United States, the responsibility is three-fold. On April 11 President Carter announced important new action to carry out those responsibilities. He has: first, announced a comprehensive program to curb inflation by limiting the size of federal budget deficits; by restricting federal wage increases as part of a general deceleration of wage and price rises; by acting to reduce the inflationary consequences of government regulations, and by resisting legislative proposals that would add to inflation. second, pressed hard for Congressional action on comprehensive energy legislation and indicated that oil imports would be limited by administrative action under present law if Congress fails to act. third, initiated work on a program to promote exports. The President has chosen his course. one. It is the right Now we must deliver, and we are determined to do so. We trust that others will meet their responsibilities as well. U.S. Exchange Rate Policy Recent exchange market developments have raised fears that exchange rate instability may thwart economic recovery by undermining business investment and consumer spending. In - 12 part, such concerns reflect the difficulty other major countries are having in spurring domestic expansion — but which they were clearly experiencing before the recent exchange market disturbances. For many countries, the foreign sector plays a much more dominant role than in the U.S. and has traditionallj been a major source of economic growth and employment. Thus, the Netherlands exports 54 percent of its GNP, Germany 28 percent, Japan 14 percent and France 19 percent. The U.S. exports about 7% percent of GNP. It is not surprising that such concerns generally surface during episodes of dollar weakness in the exchange markets. The U.S. economy is substantially larger than any other individual country, accounting for 40 percent of total OECD GNP. The yearly increase in U.S. output is equivalent to half the total output of a country the size of the United Kingdom. Countries are naturally concerned about a loss of their competitive position in the large U.S. import market or vis-a-vis U.S. exporters. In addition, the large role of the U.S. capital market and the dollar in international financial transactions and balances also leads to concerns at times of dollar instability. The U.S. capital market is as large as all other major financial markets combined and constitutes a major source of finance and investment for the entire world economy. In the past few years, 60 percent of all Euro-bond issues have been denominated in dollars. proportion of external claims denominated in dollars by The - 13 banks in G-10 countries is about 75 percent. The dollar is also the principal vehicle for international transactions and continues to constitute over 80 percent of official foreign currency reserves. Concerns about the possible effects of exchange rate instability have spawned suggestions which focus on efforts to achieve greater stability through financial means, including exchange rate zones supported by massive official intervention, greatly expanded credit arrangements, foreign currency borrowing by the U.S., and "substitution" arrangements to sterilize official currency reserves. Such proposals treat the symptoms rather than the causes of present economic problems. Experience of the past decade has demonstrated repeatedly that exchange rate stability cannot be imposed on the system but must be the result of sound domestic economic policies. The world economy has undergone fundamental changes since the Bretton Woods par value system was established. The growth of international trade and payments, the ability of many countries to tap world capital markets and the existence of large liquid balances provide a scope for capital movements that dwarfs the ability of official institutions to control rates through exchange market intervention or artificial barriers. Attempts to prevent exchange rates from reflecting basic trends would lead to a repetition of the disturbances that punctuated the latter part of the Bretton Woods era and could be extremely disruptive for the world economy. - 14 In recognition of this fact of life, the members of the IMF have agreed on a different approach. The basic philosophy of the new monetary system incorporated in the amended IMF Articles, in particular Article IV on exchange arrangements, is that international monetary stability cannot be imposed from without, but must be developed by countries from within, through the application of sound irnderlying economic and financial policies. In line with that concept, our program for assuring a strong and healthy dollar relies on fundamental economic performance, not on market operations to hold or attain a particular exchange rate or maintain a particular exchange rate zone. We do recognize, of course, that markets can become disorderly, subject to great uncertainty, dominated by psychological factors and speculation. We have made clear that we are fully prepared to intervene in the markets to counter such disorders. We have intervened, at times in large amounts, for that purpose. And we have taken other steps, such as interest rate moves by the Fed and announcement of gold sales by the Treasury, that appear to have been useful in strengthening the tone of the market. The resources at our disposal for intervention are very large and we are prepared to use them if and as required to counter market disorders. - 15 - IMF Surveillance With the entry into force of the new IMF Articles, we are emerging from a long period in which the international monetary system has been operating without the benefit of an effective legal foundation. The new exchange rate provisions give members wide latitude in the choice of exchange rate practices best suited to their needs, and can accommodate a wide variety of exchange rate mechanisms — for example, freely or managed floating rates, rates pegged to a currency or basket of currencies, and the common margins arrangements of the EC snake. One can easily imagine expanded European monetary arrangements in the broad framework of the new system, as some European leaders seem to be considering in an effort to give renewed impetus to their longstanding goal of monetary union. But neither such arrangements,nor other exchange rate mechanisms, can create stability if there is instability in the domestic economies of major countries. It is the underlying stability which, correctly, is the focus of the obligations placed on countries by the new Article IV. Under this provision, each member undertakes a general obligation relating to efforts to direct its policies toward orderly growth with reasonable price stability, and a specific obligation to avoid manipulating exchange rates to prevent balance of payments adjustment or gain unfair competitive - 16 - advantage. The IMF is given the responsibility for conducting a continuing surveillance over the operation of the international monetary system and members' compliance with their obligations regarding exchange rate policies. This is the heart of the new system, and it represents the potential both for a stronger IMF role in the operation of the balance of payments adjustment process and for a more effective and symmetrical operation of that process. The central, recurrent international monetary problem in the past half-century has been the system's inability to encourage orderly adjustment in a manner that was generally considered to be equitable and balanced — and which was elastic enough to accommodate widely differing political and social systems and to provide time and scope for adjustment measures that were not unduly harsh or abrupt. The mechanisms of the gold standard and the Bretton Woods system in the end could not meet these tests. Efforts over the years in the IMF, in the OECD and in periodic Summit meetings have not produced lasting improvements in the adjustment process» Nor were the negotiators in the C-20 reform effort able to construct a mechanical apparatus that was adequate to the task. - 17 - The new Article IV thus focuses on the fundamental sources of imbalance and instability -- national policy. All agree in principle that countries in both surplus and deficit have responsibilities for balance of payments adjustment. To date, the IMF's ability to influence national policies has been limited for the most part to those members borrowing in the IMF's credit tranches. The new provisions on IMF surveillance provide the potential for IMF influence on the policies of all members, in surplus and deficit alike, as they bear on the operations of the international adjustment process. In a real sense, the new system will rely on analysis and judgment -- rather than mechanical rules and operating procedures --in the continuing effort to achieve a stable and smoothly operating international balance of payments adjustment process. The key to successful implementation of the new provisions rests with governmental commitment and efforts to work with and through the IMF to make "surveillance" effective. The United States is committed to making this process work and thereby improving the balance of payments adjustment process. We have made a number of proposals of a procedural nature aimed at ensuring that the IMF has a) the information it needs to ensure that surveillance applies equally t<^surplus and deficit countries; - 18 b) a political level body that is capable of dealing effectively with the difficult issues involved in adjustment; and c) a means of bringing the full force of its moral suasion to bear on individual countries. We will continue to work to make the new system of IMF surveillance a strong force for a stable international monetary system. We hope that others will join us in this important task. Conclusion Some have argued that flexible exchange rate arrangements remove discipline from the world economy by providing governments with an easy way out of their economic problems. Events of the past year highlight the fallacy of that view. Exchange rate changes are a highly visible and merciless barometer of whether a country is pursuing the right policies on growth, inflation and balance of payments adjustment. The market sets an exacting standard which governments cannot ignore. Some progress has been made in the past year on achieving underlying economic and financial stability, and the new IMF provisions on surveillance represent the potential for much greater — and lasting — progress. Much obviously remains to be accomplished. The daily decisions regarding exchange risk management which you in this audience will make will constitute the report card of howwell governments meet the challenge. oo 00 oo FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE May 15, 1978 Contact: George G. Ross (202) 566-2356 Secretary Blumenthal Opposes Ad Hoc Changes In Tax Rules for Capital Gains The Treasury Department today released a letter from W. Michael Blumenthal, Secretary of the Treasury, to members of the House Ways and Means Committee, in which he stated Treasury's strong opposition to any attempt to reverse the reforms of capital gains taxation enacted since 196 9. In addition to the more than $2 billion annual cost to the Treasury that reverting back to pre-1969 tax rules would incur, Secretary Blumenthal noted that the fairness of the tax system was at issue. Rolling back the tax treatment of capital gains would erode the progressivity and equity of the U.S. income tax system, he wrote. In the letter, Secretary Blumenthal emphasized that President Carter has placed a substantial increase in the rate of real capital formation "at the heart of his strategy for sustaining the economic recovery into the 1980!s." The capital gains tax accounts for only about 10 percent of the total tax burden on capital income. "Focusing tax relief in this limited area would severely unbalance the allocation of resources within the investment sector," the letter states. A copy of the letter, with the three tables which accompanied it, is attached. B-906 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE Wednesday, May 15, 1978 Contact: Charles Arnold 202/566-2041 THE TREASURY DEPARTMENT REQUIRES RECORDS OF CERTIFICATES OF DEPOSIT Under Secretary Bette B. Anderson announced today that beginning June 1, 1978, financial institutions will be required to keep records identifying persons buying or cashing certificates of deposit. Treasury has amended its recordkeeping regulations (31 CFR 103) so that banks, savings and loan associations, and credit unions will record the name, address, and taxpayer identification number of customers involved in such transactions. A similar requirement has been in effect with respect to other types of bank deposits for several years. The additional recordkeeping is expected to make the concealment of financial transactions related to illegal activities more difficult. The amendment will also affect the sale of so-called "honor bonds" and other bearer certificates of deposit which have been promoted on the basis of the anonymity offered to investors. The amendment will appear in the Federal Register on May 19, 1978. oOo B-907 FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY Estimated at 10:00 A.M. May 16, 1978 STATEMENT BY GARY HUFBAUER BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON INTERNATIONAL FINANCE OF THE COMMITTEE ON BANKING, HOUSING, AND URBAN AFFAIRS AND THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON SCIENCE, TECHNOLOGY AND SPACE OF THE COMMITTEE ON COMMERCE, SCIENCE AND TRANSPORTATION UNITED STATES SENATE U.S. TECHNOLOGY AND U.S. TRADE PERFORMANCE Mr. Chairman, I am pleased to testify on an issue that has sparked the concerns of many in government, industry and the academic community: a perceived decline in U.S. technological leadership and its effects on U.S. trade performance. The scientific and technological resources of the United States are essential both for maintaining our domestic standard of living and for advancing our international trade position. We should thus carefully consider the evidence available to us in order to determine whether there has, in fact, been a decline in innovation and research, and what effect this might have on our exports. Mr. Hufbauer is a Deputy Assistant Secretary of the Department of the Treasury. However, this statement reflects his private views and is not an Administration position. B-908 - 2 Let me begin by reviewing the status of industrial research and development (R&D) expenditures in the United States and abroad. Research performed outside of industry has less importance in the context of international competitiveness. Medical research, for example, has obvious social value, but only indirectly affects the rate of productivity growth in American industry. Total industrial R&D spending, that is, spending by both the Federal Government and business on R&D performed within industry, has barely kept up with inflation. Measured in constant 1972 dollars, this spending has hovered within the range of $19 to $21 billion during the last ten years. Much of this stagnation in total real industrial R&D has been accounted for by a shrinkage in federallyfunded R&D, which declined in every year but one between 1966 and 1975, averaging a 5.5 percent yearly drop. However, industry's own funding for R&D, which now accounts for two-thirds of total industrial research, increased in real terms in every year except two since 1966, averaging a 3.8 percent annual real gain over that period. Preliminary figures suggest that real increases accelerated in 1976 and 1977, averaging a 5.3 percent annual rise. As might be expected, the two periods when industry-funded R&D did not rise at all or rose very slowly were in recessionary periods, namely 1970-71 and 1974-75. - 3 In my opinion, private industry spending on R&D probably exerts a more immediate payoff for the economy than federally-funded industrial research. Federal spending is mostly associated with Defense Department and NASA projects. Occasionally these projects create spectacular offshoots in the private economy, for example narrow and wide-bodied jets and advances in integrated circuit technology. But on the whole, I am inclined to think that private R&D spending produces findings which are more readily translated into new products and processes. Thus, I find the solid gains in industry-funded R&D encouraging, and I would contrast them with the generally somber pronouncements made about R&D trends in the United States. For example, economists commonly attempt to show a deterioration in our national R&D effort by comparing R&D spending with Gross National Product (GNP). Industrial R&D spending as a percentage of GNP did in fact decline gradually in the last decade, from 2 percent in 1967 to 1.6 percent in 1977. However, as an indicator of U.S. performance in industrial growth and productivity, the ratio of R&D spending to GNP is misleading. The composition of GNP has shifted over the last twenty years. In particular, the manufacturing sector, where a major portion of federally-funded and enterprise-funded research and -4development in the U.S. is performed, has been declining relative to total GNP. The service sector, where relatively little R&D is undertaken, has contributed a rising share of GNP. Therefore, a measure which compares R&D with GNP has become progressively more distorted because GNP is growing faster in those sectors which are less R&Dintensive. A comparison of our R&D performance with the performance of other nations reveals that the United States still leads in absolute levels of gross expenditures on R&D, in concentration of R&D spending to industrial production, and in the ratio of R&D manpower to total population. But while the data for cross-country comparisons are weak, it appears that the United States lead is being slowly eroded, most notably by Japan and Germany. Perhaps the most telling statistic is that, in Continental Europe and Japan, Government R&D efforts are considerably less devoted to space and defense programs that in the United States, and are much more heavily focused on industrial programs, university programs, and private non-profit research institutes. Japan for example, allots fully 78 percent of its federal R&D budget for these activities; this amounts to one-fifth of all R&D carried out in Japan. As I mentioned earlier, R&D spending for defense and space research may be less effective in stimulating growth in the economy of a nation than R&D expenditures - 5 which are more directly related to the problem of discovering new products and improving production methods. Taken as a whole, then, the various measures do suggest that in the past decade overall R&D effort in industry for the United States has been sluggish, except , for industry's own R&D financing, and that governments and firms abroad have raised their own levels of R&D activity. Yet these developments on their own do not automatically support a conclusion that the U.S. economy is weakening or that our trade position will deteriorate. Many other factors, such as the availability of capital, labor attitudes, and government regulatory policies, must be taken into account when examining trends in industrial production and trade. Product innovation and research are surely important, but they are only one contributing factor out of many. I would like to turn now to our trade performance. Technology-intensive goods, that is goods produced by industries with above-average concentrations of applied R&D spending, comprise about 40 percent of U.S. manufactured goods exports. A recent Staff Economic Report of the U.S. Commerce Department found that this compared with only about 28 percent for Germany, Japan, France and the United - 6 Kingdom, and somewhat lesser percentages for the rest of the OECD. Technology-intensive goods included electronics, aircraft, computers, engines, petrochemicals and drugs. The low-technology category contains such items as automobiles, construction machinery, semi-manufactures and textiles. Our overall manufactures trade balance has fluctuated markedly in the past half-decade: in 1972 we experienced our first post-war manufactures trade deficit; in 1975 we had a record surplus close to $20 billion, and by the end of 1977 we were down to a $3.3 billion surplus. This uneveness is the cause of some concern, and has prompted fears that the traditionally strong U.S. trade position in manufactures has been eroded, in part due to a slowdown in U.S. R&D activities. If we examine our trade balance in technology-intensive goods it appears that, prior to 1972, we had a fairly constant surplus of about $6 billion. In the past four years the average yearly surplus in this category of goods has doubled to over $13 billion. Thus, high technology goods trade has been a source of strength in our trade picture. By contrast, low-technology goods trade has largely caused the recent fluctuations in our overall manufacturing balance. This is not to say that we have excelled with all our trading partners in all high technology products. Our - 7 experience with Japan in the consumer electronics industry, namely in televisions, radios, audio and transceiver equipment, shows some of our weaknesses. We had a $3.6 billion trade deficit in 1977 with Japan in high-technology goods, and about two-thirds of this was accounted for by imports of consumer electronics goods. Japan's consumer electronics production has quintupled in the last decade, from $2 billion in 1967 to $10 billion in 1977 by one estimate. Our trade relations with Japan have of course been a major concern for this Administration. We want to see greater U.S. exports to the Japanese market, both through a reduction in Japanese import barriers and through more energetic export efforts by American firms. So much for past performance. Is it possible to establish a connection between levels of R&D spending in the U.S. and a possible future worsening of our trade performance? The few statistical studies that have attempted to find a correlation between R&D intensity and exports show a positive and significant relationship. These findings have been based on various definitions of export performance. For example, the Commerce Department study I referred to earlier found that the United States exported a greater share of total OECD country exports in those product groupings which had higher concentrations of R&D. Other studies, such as one undertaken by Branson - 8 and Junz, show that the U.S. trade balance is more favorable in those product groups which were more R&D-intensive. What the studies do not show is how R&D affects trade performance independently from other important influences, such as skilled labor effects, industryconcentration effects, and scale economy effects. These other effects are frequently associated with just those industries which have high R&D levels. In addition, there are often long lag times between particular expenditures on R&D and observed effects on trade. Past studies have examined a cross-section of goods in a given time period, and have not attempted to quantify changes over time. " Finally, there is an important circularity in causation. R&D. R&D stimulates trade, but trade also stimulate Most academic analysis has focused on only one half of the loop. Yet market demand is commonly viewed as an important determinant of technological innovation in the firm, and these effects should apply to export demand as well as domestic demand. In sum, while we can safely presume that there is a positive connection between R&D spending and exports, the relationship is not simple, nor can it be mechanically quantified. It is unlikely that larger R&D spending would improve our trade balance in the short-run, but it could well have a positive impact in five or ten years. - 9 However, we should recognize that certain shifts in comparative advantage away from the U.S. and in favor of other countries are probably inevitable. Since at least the early 1950s foreign markets have grown faster than American markets, and it should not be surprising that some foreign industries have likewise matured and become more competitive With U.S. industry. Two other issues have emerged in the debate on technology and export competitiveness. First, what are the experiences of small versus large firms in technological innovation and trade? Second, does the transfer of technology and research activities abroad undermine the technological superiority and trade position of the United States? The data are very thin for comparing the technological activity of small and large companies. One study by Gellman Research Associates composed a sample list of major U.S. technological innovations, and then examined the distribution of the innovations in five size groupings. For 1967 to 1973, firms of 100 or less employees accounted for 20 percent of the innovations, while whereas firms with 10,000 or more employees accounted for 43 percent of the total. A measure was then devised to compare major innovations per R&D dollar, by size group. Companies - 10 with 1-1000 employees produced 24 times as many innovations per R&D dollar as companies with over 10,000 workers. The Gellman study should be interpreted with care since the underlying samples of major innovations may not accurately represent the "true" distribution of the population. The data do suggest, however, that small companies are more "efficient" with their R&D money. It should be noted that minor innovations, such as modest improvements in efficiency, were not considered. Much R&D expenditure is devoted to these improvements, and they are an important source of productivity growth. It is widely recognized that developing and commercializing a new product or process is the most costly phase of the innovation process: the rule of thumb, according to Gilpin and others, is that the cost ratios between basic research, applied research and commercial development are one to ten to one hundred. The last stage may be best suited for the large firm which has greater production, financial and marketing resources. The trade of small high-technology companies has not been examined to my knowledge. The 1975 "White Paper" prepared under the supervision of the Commerce Technical Advisory Board on the role of new technical enterprises in the U.S. economy claims that these companies have the -liability to create new job opportunities and products competitive in world markets, but the paper does not investigate their actual trade performance. As a general rule, we know large manufacturing companies in the U.S. export a higher proportion of their total shipments than do small firms, twice as much by some calculations. Using Census of Manufactures data for 1972, firms with less than 1000 employees exported an average 2.5 percent of their total shipments, whereas firms with greater than 1000 workers exported 5.7 percent of their total shipments. More recent data from U.S. corporate tax returns also support this point. Domestic International Sales Corporations (DISCs) with small corporate majority shareholders ($5 million or less in assets) accounted for 4.4 percent of gross receipts from DISC exports, while that same size category of all U.S. companies accounted for 14.6 percent of all business receipts. The figures suggest that large companies play a relatively more significant role than small companies in exports. This relationship makes economic sense, since large firms have a bigger foreign sales base to spread out the high overhead costs of exploring foreign markets. Turning to the transfer of technology, we know less about the scope and magnitude of these transfers than - 12 we should. A basic problem is finding a satisfactory measuring stick for technology transfer. In the absence of a better figure, we are forced to rely on royalty and fee data, namely payments made for technology sales through licenses of patents, know-how and other intangible property. These data tell very little about the nature of the technology being sold. Another difficulty is that the data do not measure the technology embodied in personnel who might transfer their know-how by working overseas. A final drawback is that the fee and royalty channel includes payments for trademarks and other purposes unrelated to the transfer of technology. In general, these data show that fourth-fifths of the royalty and fee income from overseas is from affiliated enterprises and one-fifth from unaffiliated enterprises. Fourth-fifths come from Europe, Japan, and Canada and one-fifth from the developing world. We receive ten times the amount of fees and royalties from abroad that we pay out. One notable finding from these unsophisti- cated measures of technology flow is the very close connection between direct investment and technology transfers. The location and size of R&D facilities of U.S. multinational corporations is not readily known. A U.S. Government census of U.S. MNCs undertaken this year will - 13 eventually provide this information, along with data on R&D personnel overseas and other aspects of technology transfer. A 1974 study done by the Conference Board suggests that about 10 percent of U.S. MNC-financed spending on R&D was undertaken abroad in 1974, and a study done by Edwin Mansfield projects that this will rise to about 12 percent in 1980. The Mansfield study goes on to state that principal reason given by companies for undertaking R&D overseas was to answer the special design needs of overseas markets. Other reasons included lower cost of R&D talent, and the ability to monitor foreign R&D activity. Specialized studies looking at particular industries or licensing agreements offer a better picture of what and how technology is transferred. These studies often attempt to make estimates of the impact on the economy and comparative advantage of the United States. One recent study by Jack Baranson indicates that in the twenty-five case studies he examined of transfers of technology to unaffiliated foreign enterprises, the technology released was frequently the most sophisticated and competitive technology possessed by the U.S. firms, and that these transfers could conceivably exert an adverse impact on U.S. trade and employment. However, the Baranson study also found that in at least eighty percent of the case . - 14 studies there were alternative foreign sources for the technologies. While it is probably true that the increase in foreign skill levels arising from certain transfers of technology to other countries will create greater competition for U.S. goods, it is equally true that the U.S. stands to gain from other transfers. New export markets for U.S. products may result from technology licensing agreements. Improvements in the technology may flow back to the United States. And foreign firms often locate production facilities in the United States in order to exploit their new technology here. In short, it is virtually impossible to determine the overall effect of the technology transfer process. While the analysis is incomplete, and while definitive answers may never be possible, I believe that restrictions on the outflow of technology would not be in the national interest. The administrative aspects of a technology licensing system are truly mind-boggling. A Technology Review Board would be a boon to Washington attorneys and bureaucrats, but very costly to firms with technology to sell. Many U.S. firms rely on their earnings from foreign sales of goods and technology both to finance and to justify new research activity. If U.S. firms are forced to pass-up foreign opportunities, French, Japanese, and German firms will very probably step in. Competition - 15 from abroad can also stimulate the design of better products in the United States: I mention automobiles and consumer electronics as examples. Finally, the flow of technology goes in both directions, and the street can be blocked at one end as well as the other. In sum the generation of new technology can be stimulated in various ways by the diffusion of technology from the existing pool. Our national interest lies not in the creation of new barriers but in exposing U.S. firms to the stiff breeze of competition and fresh ideas from abroad. I have covered much ground this morning, skimming over the surface of complex questions. One fundamental topic that I have not attempted to examine can be summarized in two questions: What is the role of R&D in furthering economic growth and productivity? And what policies should the U.S. Government adopt to increase our R&D activity? I will leave these vital questions for another occasion. 0O0 eparlment of theJREASURY ASH1NGT0N,D.C20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE HAY 17, 1978 CONTACT: (Treasury) Charles Arnold 202/566-2041 (Smithsonian) Geraldine Sanderson 202/381-6586 TREASURY DEPARTMENT TRANSFERS TO SMITHSONIAN INSTITUTION UNIQUE COLLECTION OF UNITED STATES CURRENCY The Treasury Department today transferred to the Smithsonian a collection of 800 pieces of U.S. currency with a face value of more than a half a million dollars. Many of the pieces of currency are rare and the numismatic value of the collection is incalcuable, according to O.H. Tomkinson, Deputy Assistant Commissioner for Banking and Cash Management in the Treasury Department's Bureau of Government Financial Operations. The formal transfer of the collection will take place at 2 p.m. May 17t in the reception suite of the National Museum of History and Technology, Constitution Avenue between 12th and 14th St., N.W. Deputy Secretary Robert Carswell will represent the Treasury Department while the collection will be accepted for the Smithsonian by John Jameson, Assistant Secretary for Administration. The collection, with a face value of $578,365.79 includes at least one note from nearly every issue of currency between the Civil War and the early 1960's. The earliest item in the collection is an interest bearing note yielding 7 3/10 percent with a face value of $51.82 issued by Treasury in 1861. The collection includes several unissued notes of each of four denominations of Gold Certificates, Series 1934. This series was issued only to Federal Reserve Banks in exchange for gold the banks turned over to the Treasury and includes the only $100,000 note issued. This series was added recently to the collection. According to Mr. Tomkinson, the collection is "among the most complete, if not the most complete, anywhere," and contains the first notes of some issues. A very rare item is the S100 Federal Reserve Note 1914 Series B 1726775 A on which the front a nd the back are reversed. Dr. and Mrs. Vladimir Clain-Stefanelli, the Smithsonian's curators of numismatics, praise the collection. "Before today, our coin collections were renowned but our collection of U.S. paper currencv was extremelv limited," thev said in a statement. "We are now t h e grateful recipients of one of the best currency collections in the world.1' B-909 - 2The Treasury and the Smithsonian arranged the transfer because the Smithsonian has the unique facilities to secure, preserve and display the currency. Attached is an inventory of the collection and a reproduction of a $100,000 Series 1934 Gold Certificate. oOo Page 1 of 45 INVENTORY OF TREASURY CURRENCY COLLECTION TRANSFERRED TO SMITHSONIAN INSTITUTION MAY 17, 1978 BOOK 1 Kind Interest Bearing Note, 7 3/10% Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No $ 51.82 1861 Red oonmn 227602 Refunding Certificate 21.30 Apr. 1, 1879 Red A 3103479 Compound Interest „..rt Bearing Note 23.88 Apr. 15, 1864 Compound Interest ,0-70/1*' Bearing Note 59.70 One Year S% Bearing Note 10.50 Mar.30, 1864 Red 52149 Red 12786^ Red 64784 One Year 5% Bearing Note 21.00 Apr.18, 1864 , Red 191534 Two Year 5% Bearing Note 110.00 Apr.14, 1864 Red 18114 Compound Interest Bearing Note 119.40 Dec.15, 1864 Red 59535 U.S. Fractional Currency .25 1874 Ked No. # U.S. Fractional Currency .25 1874 ^d No. # U.S. Fractional Currency .50 1875 , Red V! u No. - Page 2 of 45 Kind Face Value Three Year 7-3/10% $ Series or Date Seal Serial No. 60.95 1865 Red 126378 Compound Interest Bearing Note 11.94 Jul.15, 1864 Red 40993 Two Year 5% Bearing Note 55.00 May 27, 1864 Red 32596 Three Year 7-3/10% Note 107.30 Jun. 15, 1865 Red 272963 1.00 Jul. 24, 1866 Red A 635032 Treasury Note ti tt 1.00 Jul 24, 1866 Red K 1181640 ii tt 1.00 1890 Brown A 113- u it 1.00 1890 Brown A 4645210 it tt 1.00 1891 Red B 4132733! tt it 2.00 1891 Red B 975496 ti tt 2.00 Jul. 24, 1866 Red E 5152488 tt tt 2.00 Jul. 24, 1866 Red E 4964756 tt tt 2.00 1890 Brown A 806927 tt tt 2.00 1891 Red B 8363384 it tt 2.00 1891 Red B 8363383 it tt 5.00 Jul. 24, 1866 Red K 2755734 tt tt 5.00 Jul. 24, 1866 Red K 2755762 tt it 5.00 Jul. 24, 1866 Red K 1203341 it tt 5.00 1890 Brown A 28 tt tt 5.00 1891 Red A 3885814 tt ti 5.00 1891 Red B.2489390 M tt 5.00 1891 Red B 12464264 Page 3 of 45 Kind Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. Red A 2599784 Blue A 25928190 A Treasury Note ? 5.00 1891 Red B 17259901 n » 10.00 1869 Red H 3364279 it »i 10.00 1869 Red H 5719007 tt II 10.00 1869 Red H 5719011 ti " 10.00 1891 Red B 2 tt " 10.00 1891 Red B 3205745 II » 10.00 1891 Red B 6027901 u it 10.00 1890 Brown A 3074026 tt " 20.00 1890 Brown A 172211 " » 20.00 1890 Red A 1214279 it II 20.00 1891 Red B 1147901 II " 20.00 1891 Red B 30 II II 20.00 1890 Brown A 571191 20.00 1869ttRed A 1575551 ti tt 20.00 1869 * ti 50.00 1869 Red Y 13549 tt 50.00 1891 Red B 3 it 100.00 1890 Brown A 104451 it 100.00 1891 Red B 79901 ii 1,000.00 1890 Brown A 11623 n 1,000.00 1891 Red B 31973 Fed. Res. Bank Note Boston 1.00 1918 Page 4 of 45 Kind Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No. Fed. Res. Bank Note New York $ 1.00 1918 Blue B 97414503 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Cleveland 1.00 1918 Blue D 543 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Kansas City 1.00 1918 Blue J 2445613 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Dallas 1.00 1918 Blue K 2057376 A Feci. Res. Bank Note San Francisco 1.00 1918 Blue L 13619363 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Boston 2.00 1918 Blue A 8960932 A Fed. Res. Bank Note New York 2.00 1918 Blue B 12810497 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Cleveland 2.00 1918 Blue D 543 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Minneapolis 2.00 1918 Blue I 1478876 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Chicago 2.00 1918 Blue G 9122059 A Fed. Res. Bank Note San Francisco 2.00 1918 Blue L 2835307 A Fed. Res. Bank Note New York 5.00 1918 Blue B 3910636 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Cleveland 5.00 1918 Blue D 2278152 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Atlanta 5.00 1918 Blue F 840723 A Fed. Res. Bank Note San Francisco 5.00 1918 Blue L 407162 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Kansas City 5.00 1915 Blue J 472 A Page 5 of 45 Kind Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. Fed. Res. Bank Note Kansas City $ 1918 Blue J 87979 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Kansas City • 10.00 1915 Blue J 382411 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Chicago 10.00 1918 Blue G 157407 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Atlanta 10.00 1918 Blue F 65643 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Dallas 20.00 1915 Blue K 45855 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Atlanta 20.00 1918 Blue F 76341 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Kansas City 20.00 1915 Blue J 3372 A Fed. Res. Bank Note Kansas City 1.00 1918 Blue J 13321189 A Fed. Res. Bank Note St. Louis 50.00 1918 Blue H 3396 A Fed. Res. Bank Note St. Louis 50.00 1918 Blue H 797 A Total Value, Book 1 $ 3,459.79 5.00 Total number of notes (81) Page 6 of 45 BOOK 2 ue Scries or Dat Seal Serial No. 00 257-New York Red 452 00 153-New York Red 3475 00 3-New York None 66352 00 11-Phila. None 51880 00 12-Boston None 59787 00 82-New York Red 3160 00 32-New York Red 16401 00 58-New York Red 17890 00 New Series 68 New York Red 37734 00 New Series 56 New York Red 98538 00 Series 5 New York None 49557 00 33-New York Red 73245 00 New Series 50 New York Red 33570 00 New Series 1 New York Red 83920 00 1861-Phila. None 36687 00 25-New York Red 51 00 3-New York Red 62052 00 New Series 2 New York Red 33579 Page 7 of 15 Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No. $ New Scries 9 New York Red 64202 50.00 Series 2New York Red 83666 50.00 Series 5 New York Red 8100 Red 73149 100.00 New Series 1 New York Red 95812 100.00 New Series 1 New York Red 50986 Red 49519 New Series 2 New York Red 23657 1.00 1874 Red H 341843 1.00 1875 Red H 5126730 1.00 1875* Red K 1158825 1.00 1878 Red A 3828439 1.00 1878 Red A 494351 1.00 1880 Brown Z 14451012 1.00 1880 Brown Z 44888682 1.00 1880 Brown Z 31237654 1.00 1880 Brown Z 44S88684 ].00 1880 Red A 3041315 1.00 1880 Red A 5628322 1.00 1917 Red A 47184370 A 1.00 1917 Red II 97209609 A 3.00 1917 Red T 4 345809 A 20.00 * 100.00 1862-New York 500.00 New Series 1 New York 1,000.00 . Page 8 of 45 Kind Face Value U.S. Note $ 1.00 Series or Date Seal Serial No. 1923 Red A 320 B ti 2.00 1874 Red B 6730509 tt 2.00 1875 Red B 7477937 tt 2.00 1875 Red B 3246522 tt 2.00 1878 Red A 3022248 n 2.00 1878 Red A 3022737 n 2.00 1880 Brown Z 21928590 tt 2.00 1880 Red A 3687510 tt 2.00 1880 Brown Z 22717861 it 2.00 1917 Red A 148505 A it 2.00 1917 Red A 89705059 A it 2.00 1917 Red D 23540241 A u 2.00 1917 Red A 74434291 A tt 1.00 1917 Red N 555 A it 2.00 1917 Red D 48332460 A ti 5.00 1875 Red B 4993269 it 5.00 1875 Red B 3284700 tt 5.00 1880 Brown Z 10733265 u 5.00 1880 Brown A 19516253 ti 5.00 1880 Brown A 18509853 it 5.00 1880 Brown Z 14855365 ti 5.00 1880 Red A 7034259 ii 5.00 1880 Red A 33152363 u 5.00 18S0 Red A 53727014 M 5.00 1880 Red A 44931648 Page 9 of 15 Kind Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. U.S. Note $ 5.00 1907 Red D 21 5.00 1907 Red E 34085107 5.00 1907 Red E 80846626 5.00 1907 Red M 48005929 u 5.00 1907 Red M 29146947 it 5.00 1907 Red A 52 5.00 1907 Red B 50277643 5.00 1907 Red B 121*27950 5.00 1907 Red E 67022880 ti tt Total Value, book 2 $ 2,220.00 Total number of notes (74) Page 10 of 45 BOOK 3 Face Value Scries or Date Red A10.00 34809161880 $ Brown10.00 Z 3244151 1880 Brown10.00 A 10057021 1880 Brown10.00 A 10057014 1880 Brown10.00 Z 986135 1880 Brown10.00 Z 5962590 1880 Red A10.00 18011061880 Red A10.00 67598341880 Red A10.00 50676851880 Red A10.00 11921641875 Red A 10.00 23810962 1880 Red A 10.00 33673406 1880 Red A 10.00 12966894 1880 Red A 10.00 29247879 1880 Red A 10.00 19503058 1880 Red E 10.00 14902794 1901 Red * 10.00 28219991 1901 Red D 10.00 43318461901 Red A 10.00 8 1901 Red B 10.00 9669710 1901 Red D 10.00 4331845 1901 Seal Serial No. Page 11 of 45 Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. $ 1901 Red E 1947730 10.00 10.00 1901 Red D 13558750 » 10.00 1901 10.00 1901 Red E 57675550 10.00 1923 Red A 14685 B 10.00 1923 Red A 672036 B 20.00 1880 Red A 2520525 20.00 1880 Brown Z 653358 20.00 1880 Red A 5372741 20.00 1875 Red A 1067250 20.00 1878 Red A 682666 20.00 1880 Brown Z 246205 20.00 1880 Brown Z 1150156"' 20.00 1880 Red A 660059 20.00 1880 Red A 1646188 20.00 1880 Red A 356179 A 20.00 1880 Red A 8501096 20.00 1880 Red B 8124 20.00 1880 Red A 2956323 A 20.00 1880 Red A 11904104 20.00 1880 ^d D 163369 20.00 1880 Red A 2929994 A Red E 1947718 Page 12 of 45 Kind Face Value U.S. Note $ 20.00 1880 Red D 375654 tt ft 50.00 1874 Red E 420462 tt n 50.00 1878 Red A 160519 tt it 50.00 1880 Brown A 434450 ti it 50.00 1880 Red A 385343 II " 50.00 1880 Red A 45264 it ii 50.00 1880 Red A 806713 II II 100.00 1880 Red A 1634 »• H 100.00 1880 Red A 4437 " II 100.00 1869 Red W 346542 » » 100.00 1875 Red A 18075 tt »i 100.00 1878 Red A 148731 ti ti 100.00 1880 Brown Z 111882 it it 100.00 1880 Red A 81780 II II 100.00 1880 ' Red A 249293 ti tt 100.00 1880 Red A 623328 ti it 500.00 1869 Red N 16035 n it 500.00 1874 Red Z 30645 II M 500.00 1875 Red A 20164 ii it 500.00 1875 Red A 46900 ti II 500.00 1878 Red A 12336 ii H 500.00 1880 Red A 13468 Scries or Date Seal Serial No Page 13 of 45 Kind Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. U.S. Note $ 500.00 1880 Red A 43029 500.00 1880 Red A 48235 500.00 1880 Red A 75902 500.00 1880 Red A 88070 1,000.00 1880 Red A 27395 1,000.00 1880 Red B 10050 1,000.00 1878 Red A 21998 1,000.00 Brown Z 6498 Total value, book 3 $10,810.00 1880 Total number of notes (73) Page 14 of 45 BOOK 4 Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No. $ 1st. N.B. of Portsmouth, N.1I. Jan. 2, 1865 Red 9185 2.00 Valley N.B. Lebanon, Pa. Jan. 17, 1865 Red 875 5.00 1st. N.B. Ithaca, N.Y.. Feb. 20, 1864 Red U 89781 1.00 5.00 1st. Nat. Gold Bank Stockton, Ca. Feb. 15, 1873 Red K 929857 5.00 1st. Nat. Gold Bank San Fran, Ca Nov. 30, 1870 Red K 275970 10.00 1st. Nat. Gold Bank San Fran, Ca Nov. 30, 1870 Red Z 784366 10.00 The Nat. Bk. of 111. Chicago, 111 Aug. 25, 1871 Red B 899761 10.00 1st. Nat. Gold Bank Stockton, Ca - Feb. 15, 1875 Red B 233265 20.00 1st. Nat. Gold Bank Oakland, Ca Feb. 15, 1875 D 525117 Red 5.00 Central N.B. Bait. Md. Mar. 15, 1871 Red H 61178 5.00 The Stockgrowers N.B. (scries 1875) of Cheyenne, Wyo. Jul. 10, 1890 Red Y 358331 Page 15 of 45 Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No $ The West Chester County N.B. of Peekskill, N.Y. (series 18S2) June 14, 1885 Red R 249897 The Cumberland N.B. of Portland Maine (series 1875) Oct. 2, 1865 Red H 8480 10.00 5.00 The Rochester N.B. (series 1875) Rochester, N.H. Mar. 20, 1874 Red B 919945 The Stones River N.B. (series 1875) of Murfreesboro, Tn. Jul. 15, 1872 Red X 123300 5.00 1902-May 4, 1 T 177156 5.00 1902-Jun. 11, 1904 Red R 291243 1902-Apr. 25, 1905 Red N 764050 1902-Jun. 30, 1902 Red A 48197 5.00 5.00 5.00 5.00 K 175254 5.00 1902-Jul 1, 1 5.00 1902-Feb 25, 1903 Red T 116238 1902-Nov 6, 1904 Red D 145328 1902-Nov 6, 1904 Blue E 913017 E 5.00 5.00 5.00 1902-Apr 2, 1912 Blue A 780137 D Page 16 of 45 Face Value al Currency $ 5.00 Scries or Date Seal Serial No. 1902-Nov 13, 1902 Blue Y 325892 A tt 5.00 1902-Sep S, 1916 Blue 346619 tt 5.00 1902-Sep 12, 1917 Blue X 305133 H 1902-Feb 25, 1903 Blue 9481 11 5.00 tt 5.00 1882-May 4, 1885 Brown A 176666 A u 5.00 1882-Apr 12, 1898 Brown R 779275 B 1882-Apr 26, 1885 Brown Z 824808 1882-Jan 14, 1885 Brown B 233559 B 1882-Jun 20, 1900 Blue D 35721 tt n it 5.00 5.00 5.00 it 5.00 1882-May 6, 1895 Blue E 482649 ii 5.00 1882-Aug 29, 1900 Blue U 292791 ti 5.00 1882-Nov 2, 1901 Blue U 128177 it 5.00 1882-Aug 11, 1900 Blue N 226379 ti 5.00 1882-Jan 4, 1902 U 498539 Blue ti 5.00 1902-Jan 11, 1905 Blue D 440373 tt 10.00 June 25, 1897 Blue N 527631 ti 10.00 May 19, 1900 Blue R 273298 M 10.00 Apr 19, 1905 Blue A 271590 11 10.00 May 31, 1892 Blue D 619280 Page 17 of 45 Face Value $ Scries or Date Seal Serial No. 10.00 1882-Feb 9, 1902 Blue U 576693 10.00 1902-Sep 6, 1909 Blue 5855 10.00 1902-Oct 13, 1906 Blue B 155610 K 1902-Nov 15, 1922 Blue R 984697 H 1902-Jan 20, 1911 Blue 142106 10.00 1902-Sep 2, 1919 Blue V 516875 E 10.00 1902-Aug 7, 1912 Blue Y 136468 10.00 1902-Jun 3, 1903 Red B 126131 10.00 1902-Nov 2, 1902 Red A 379916 10.00 1902-Apr 13, 1905 Red N 468472 1902-Jan 10, 1903 Red T 353070 1902-Aug 9, 1907 Red A 479464 Red H 631369 10.00 10.00 10.00 10.00 10.00 1902-Nov 21, 1902 • • 10.00 1882-May 1, 1885 Brown X 9261896 10.00 1882-Sep 3, 1895 Brown B 81365 B 10.00 1882-May 11, 1901 Brown Y 953359 10.00 1882-Jan 12, 1901 Brown Y 438210 Brown II 589150 II 10.00 1882-Dcc 21, 1901 Page 18 of 45 Kind Face Value National Currency $ it it ti Series or Date Seal Serial No. 1882-Dec 15, 1897 Brown B 750519 10.00 1882-Jan 14, 1885 Brown U 871712 10.00 1875-Jul 10, 1890 Red K 919064 1882-Oct 24, 1895 Brown V 508500 V 10.00 10.00 n 10.00 1882-Mar 1, 1888 Brown V 119286 H 10.00 1875-Mar 15, 1879 Red D 202992 1875-Jan 23, 1883 Red R 105985 Red D 751648 ti 20.00 u 20.00 1882-Jul 1, 1865 it 20.00 Aug 7, 1865 ti 20.00" 1875-Feb 3, 1865 Red E 564440 ti 20.00 1875-Jul 15, 1880 Red K 855816 1882-Feb 26, 1883 Brown B 605591 1882-Dec 30, 1898 Brown U 473073 U 1882-Jan 14, 1885 Brown U 766910 Blue M 822697 it it tt 20.00 20.00 20.00 ^ A 126219 Red it 20.00 Oct 15, 1900 it 20.00 Apr 5, 1901 Blue M 953642 it 20.00 Jul 23, 1S95 Blue T 125833 tt 20.00 1902-Dcc 27, 1906 Red Y 30833 Page 19 of 45 Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No $ 1902-Jun 3, 1902 Red A 804179 20.00 1902-Feb. 25, 1903 Red K 84081 20.00 1902-Feb 25, 1903 Red V 419681 20.00 1902-Sep 24, 1902 Red N 985788 20.00 1902-Jan 28, 1903 Red U 80881 20.00 1882-Jul 31, 1886 Brown Y 77316 20.00 1882-Feb 17, 1885 Brown Y 928981 20.00 1882-Jul 31, 1901 Brown Z 172556 20.00 1882-Oct 16, 1900 Brown R 627993 R 20.00 1882-Jan 18, 1891 . Brown 20.00 1882-May 11, 1885 Brown Z 344130 20.00 1902-Feb 24, 1912 Blue X 575204 II 20.00 1902-Mar 15, 1922 Blue R 984696 H 20.00 1902-Mar 19, 1906 •' Blue 20.00 B 574592 B K 820530 H 20.00 1902-0ct.l, 1902 Blue 7560 20.00 1902-Nov 30, 1909 Blue M 552100 E 20.00 1902-Feb 20, 1920 Blue 8474 Page 20 of 45 Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No. $ 20.00 1875-Nov 2, 1863 Red E 519956 20.00 1882-Oct 12, 1S82 Brown A 163359 50.00 1875-Jul 1, 1865 Red A 59097 50.00 Oct. 6, 1864 Red 10581 50.00 Sep. 13, 1901 Blue A 150013 50.00 Jan. 24, 1890 Blue A 35129 50.00 1882-Oct 23, 1901 Brown B 566774 50.00 1882-Oct 7, 1892 Brown A 746799 50.00 1902-Jan 29, 1905 A 847118 Blue 50.00 1902-Apr 3, 1817 Blue 1250 50.00 1902-Feb 25, 1903 Red A 377437 50.00 1902-Dec 14, 1921 Blue A 938277 100.00 1882-Jan 16, 1907 Brown B 605886 100.00 1882-Jan 16, 1907 Brown B 605822 100.00 1882-Feb 10, 1900 Brown B 396588 100.00 1875-Jul 1, 1865 Red A 145208 100.00 July 24, 1901 Blue A 148915 100.00 Jan 16, 1907 Blue A 27468 100.00 1882-Dec 15, 1901 Blue A 168622 100.00 Sep 13, 1901 Blue A 149828 Page 21 of 45 Kind Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No. National Currency $ 1902-Feb. 25, 1903 Blue 5008 1917 Blue 698 1921 Blue A 938341 1908 Blue A 268347 1902-Nov 2, 1904 Red A 146473 100.00 n " 100.00 1902-Jul 3, 1905 Blue 11744 u " 100.00 1902-Sep 2, 1910 Blue A 894668 ii " 100.00 1902-Aug 30, u " 100.00 1902-Dec 14, u it 100.00 1902-May 7 1902 Red A 180069 ti n 100.00 1902-Jun 1, 1905 Red A 303249 II » 100.00 1902-Nov 21, n 100.00 it 500.00 May 10, 1865 Red M 16428 Total value, book 4 $ 3,823.00 Total number of notes (126) Page 22 of 45 BOOK 5 Kind Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No. Fed. Res. Note $ 5.00 1914-1A Red A 373SS4 A 5.00 1914-2B Red B 4475251 A 5.00 1914-3C Red C 1194260 A 5.00 1914-4D Red D 540890 A 5.00 1914-5E Red E 970323 A 5.00 1914-6F Red F 1161454 A 5.00 1914-7G Red G 944120 A 5.00 1914-8H Red H 1084680 A 5.00 1914-91 Red I 30817 A 5.00 1914-2B Red B 13598237 A 5.00 1914-11K Red K 1255908 A 5.00 1914-12L Red L 548231 A 10.00 1914-1A Red A 66813 A 10.00 1914-2B Red B 1992586 A 10.00 1914-3C Red C 608893 A 10.00 1914-4D Red D 779242 A 10.00 1914-5E Red E 578903 A 10.00 1914-6F Red F 378864 A 10.00 1914-7G Red G 168652 A 10.00 1914-8H Red 11 716585 A 10.00 1914-91 Red I 591809 A 10.00 1914-10J Red J 341638 A 10.00 1914-11K Red K 527503 A Page 23 of 45 Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. $ 10.00 1914-12L Red L 183100 A 20.00 1914-1A Red A 34543 A 20.00 1914-2B Red B 4400 A 20.00 1914-3C Red C 228654 A 20.00 1914-4D Red D 246212 A 20.00 1914-6F Red F 89949 A 20.00 1914-7G Red G 82257 A 20.00 1914-10J Red J 6646*2 A 20.00 1914-12L Red L 125603 A 50.00 1914-1A Red A 31536 A 50.00 1914-2B Red B 44812 A 50.00 1914-3C Red C 22764 A 50.00 1914-4D Red D 16079 A 50.00 1914-5E Red E 32976 A 50.00 1914-6F Red F 19741 A 50.00 1914-7G Red G 2418 A 50.00 1914-8H Red H 167 A 50.00 1914-91 Red I 1088 A 50.00 1914-10J Red J 11571 A 50.00 1914-11K Red K 19629 A 50.00 1914-12L Red L 6918 A 100.00 1914-1A Red A 53 A 100.00 1914-2B Red B 55426 A Page 24 of 45 Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. $ 100.00 1914-3C Red C 4765 A 100.00 1914-4D Red D 24997 A 100.00 1914-5E Red E 23614 A 100.00 1914-6F Red F 8126 A 100.00 1914-7G Red G 1142 A 100.00 1914-91 Red I 2882 A 100.00 1914-10J Red J 13688 A 100.00 1914-11K Red K 15774 A 100.00 1914-12L Red L 24803 A 5.00 1914-1A Blue A 6079828 A 5.00 1914-2B Blue B 25617903 A 5.00 1914-3C Blue C 70525005 A 5.00 1914-4D Blue D 22879631 A 5.00 1914-5E Blue E 14313792 A 5.00 1914-6F Blue F 1684343 A 5.00 1914-7G Blue G 45232762 A 5.00 1914-8H Blue H 21872318 A 5.00 1914-91 Blue I 22546972 A 5.00 1914-10J Blue J 28701810 A 5.00 1914-11K Blue K 11659088 A 5.00 1914-12L Blue L 70555784 A 1914-1A Blue A 3590237 A ID. 00 Page 25 of 45 Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. 10.00 1914-2B Blue B 75092854 A tt 10.00 1914-2B Blue B 63813922 A n 10.00 1914-5C Blue C 37286075 A tt 10.00 1914-4D Blue D 22007862 A tt 10.00 1914-5E Blue E 882915 A tt 10.00 1914-6F Blue F 15783903 A tt 10.00 1914-7G Blue G 12336977 A ti 10.00 1914-8H Blue H 21475107 A tt 10.00 1914-91 Blue I 1762926 A it 10.00 1914-10J Blue J 16060568 A tt 10.00 1914-11K Blue K 11778978 A it 10.00 1914-12L Blue L 40540249 A n 20.00 1914-1A Blue A 22338746 A it 20.00 1914-2B Blue B 58563985 A n 20.00 1914-3C Red C 220864 A n 20.00 1914-3C Blue C 15321407 A ii 20.00 1914-4D Blue D 19605065 A n 20.00 1914-5E Blue E 16507699 A ii 20.00 1914-6F Blue F 356432 A ii 20.00 1914-7G Blue G 4914419 A it 20.00 1914-8H Blue H 2929040 A ti 20.00 1914-91 Blue I 5871923 A 20.00 1914-10J Blue J 8742110 A Note $ Page 26 of 45 Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. 20.00 1914-11K Blue K 4467310 A 20.00 1914-11K Blue K 2782865 A 20.00 1914-12L Blue L 12013259 A 50.00 1914-1A Blue A 802093 A 50.00 1914-2B Blue B 4081541 A 50.00 1914-3C Blue C 1036248 A 50.00 1914-4D Blue D 48336 A 50.00 1914-5E Blue E 482.330 A 50.00 1914-6F Blue F 767873 A 50.00 1914-7G Blue G 3941929 A 50.00 1914-8H Blue H 389213 A 50.00 1914-91 Blue I 138520 A 50.00 1914-10J Blue J 21910 A 50.00 1914-11K Blue K 185392 A 50.00 1914-12L Blue L 1021128 A 100.00 1914-1A Blue A 195372 A 100.00 1914-2B Blue B 1726775 A 100.00 1914-2B Blue B 563823 A 100.00 1914-3C Blue C 384635 A 100.00 1914-4D Blue D 96955 A 100.00 1914-5E Blue E 284215 A 100.00 1914-6F Blue F 441397 A Page 27 of 45 Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. $ 1914-7G Blue G 156433 A 100.00 1914-8H Blue H 168231 A 100.00 1914-91 Blue I 57175 A 100.00' 1914-10J Blue J 178122 A 100.00 1914-12L Blue L 1045400 A 500.00 1918-1A Blue A 290 A 500.00 1918-2B Blue B 1A 500.00 1918-3C Blue CIA 500.00 1918-4D Blue D 1 A 500.00 1918-6F Blue F 19990 A 500.00 1918-7G Blue G 1 A 500.00 191S-8H Blue H 2515 A 500.00 1918-10J Blue J 5156 A 500.00 1918 12L Blue L 6451 A 1,000.00 1918 1A Blue A 16149 A 1,000.00 1918-2B Blue B 1 A 1,000.00 1918-3C Blue CIA 1,000.00 1918-4D Blue D 1 A 1,000.00 1918-6F Blue F 28477 A 1,000.00 1918-7G Blue G 15703 A 1,000.00 1918-8H Blue II 1998 A 100.00 Page 28 of 45 Kind Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No Fed. Res. Note $ 1,000.00 1918-12L Blue L 13607 A II n II 5,000.00 1918-2B Blue B 1 A n n n 5,000.00 1918-4D Blue D 1 A n n II 10,000.00 1918-2B Blue B 1 A it u it 10,000.00 1918-4D Blue D 1 A Total value, book 5 $46,810.00 Total number of notes (139) Page 29 of 45 Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. $ N.Y. Oct 1, 1869 Red 112853 100.00 100.00 N.Y. Jan 2, 1877 Red B 13104 500.00 N.Y. May 1, 1874 Red A 25770 20.00 Dept Scries-1882 Red C 15318215 20.00 1882-Sep 1, 1882 Brown A 293447 20.00 Dept Serics-1882 Brown A 337644 Sep 1, 1882 20.00 Dept Series-1882 Sep 1, 1882 Brown20.00 C 145614 Dept Series-1882 Brown50.00 A 965691882-Sep 1, 1882 Red C50.00 5745 Sep 1, 1882 Brown 50.00 C 57783Dept Series Red E 50.00 46231 Dept Series Red H 50.00 229816 Dept Series Red M100.00 205662 Dept Series Brown100.00 A 2281 Sep 1, 1882 100.00 Red C 6389 Dept Series Sep 1, 1882 Brown100.00 C 73783Dept Series Red D100.00 223468 Dept Series Red E100.00 33954 Dept Series Red H100.00 442655 Dept Scries Red N100.00 1992256 1922 Brown A 5230D2 Page 30 of 45 Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. $ Dept Series Red K 182639 100.00 Dept Series Red M 99456 100.00 Dept Series Red M 769739 500.00 Dept Series Red C 110795 500.00 Dept Scries Red D 2104 500.00 1922 Red E 29435 1,000.00 Sep 1, 1882 Brown A 10199 1,000.00 Dept Series Sep 1, 1882 Brown A 18818 Dept Series Sep 1, 1882 Red C 6477 1,000.00 Dept Series Brown C 23847 1,000.00 Dept Series Red D 15131 1,000.00 1922 Gold E 66888 10.00 1907 Gold A 50 100.00 1,000.00 10.00 1907 Gold B 1059909 10.00 1907 Gold B 29331089 10.00 1907 Gold E 5075887 10.00 1907 Gold D 2033040 10.00 1922 Gold K 56452476 10.00 1907 Gold E 29910995 20.00 1905 Red A 2689605 20.00 1906 Gold D 3373921 Pago 31 of 45 Kind Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. Gold Certificates $ 20.00 1906 Gold D 13922828 20.00 1906 Gold H.7863196 20.00 1906 Gold H 11541535 20.00 1922 Gold K 60842422 50.00 1913 Gold A 369927 50.00 1913 Gold A 483109 50.00 1922 Gold B 290455 tt 50.00 Dept Series Red H 180618 tt 100.00 1922 Red N 2192022 1,000.00 1907 Gold A 13296 it it Total value, book 6 $11,140.00 Total number of notes (52) Page 32 of 45 BOOK 7 Face Value $ Scries or Date Seal Serial No. 1.00 1886 Red B 17 1.00 1886 Red B 23584379 1.00 1886 Red B 41706835 1.00 1886 Brown B 55745598 1.00 1886 Brown B 67199805 1.00 1891 Red E 1957127 1.00 1891 Red E 50087787 1.00 1896 Red 117 1.00 1896 Red 56091554 1.00 1899 Blue H 7548992 1.00 1899 Blue R 29759029 1.00 1899 Blue Y 68426490 1.00 1899 Blue H 23 H 1.00 1899 Blue 69371718 1.00 1899 Blue N 21 N 1.00 1899 Blue X 50311091 X 1.00 1899 Blue D 82572755 A 1.00 1899 Blue K 41086080 A 1.00 1899 Blue X 36 A 1.00 1923 Blue A 12 D 1.00 1923 Blue V 66202020 D Page 33 of 45 Kind Face Value Seric Seal Serial No. Silver Certificates $ 1.00 1923 Blue Z 90566961 D n 2.00 1886 Red B 7 it 2.00 1886 Red B 13055187 ti 2.00 1886 Brown B 18870546 it 2.00 1891 Red E 40 tt 2.00 1891 Red E 20987902 it 2.00 1896 Red 27 2.00 1896 Red 196029L83 ti 2.00 1899 Blue K 21395533 it 2.00 1899 Blue 58 n 2.00 1899 Blue M 21 tt 2.00 1899 Blue N 1999 ii 2.00 1899 Blue N 97299001 ti 2.00 1899 Blue D 45684458 it 2.00 1899 Blue N 61297059 ti 2.00 1899 Blue N 35395125 it 5.00 1886 Red B 1930976 ti 5.00 1886 Red B 11988734 n 5.00 1886 Brown B 31807386 it 5.00 1886 Red B 21136331 n 5.00 1886 Red E 27610006 n 5.00 1886 Red E 3625090 ti 11 Page 34 of 45 Kind V Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No. Silver Certificates $ 1896 Red 5054048 5.00 1896 Red 34428996 it 5.00 ti It 5.00 1899 Blue 18 ti It 5.00 1899 Blue B 20 it II 5.00 1899 Blue D 82761967 11 tt 5.00 1899 Blue E 43494189 M tt 5.00 18*99 Blue E 80953807 it tl 5.00 1899 Blue M 31808598 ti II 5.00 1899 Blue H 1750835 11 It 5.00 1899 Blue N 64421333 n tt 5.00 1899 Blue M 94077308 ti tt 5.00 1923 Blue A 334 7311 it tt 5.00 1923 Blue A 2070083 B tt 11 5.00 1923. Blue A 3347310 B it It 10.00 1878 Red A 12509 it 11 10.00 1880 Brown B 2841993 tt tt 10.00 1880 Red A 245437 ti ti 10.00 1880 Brown B 7313302 it It 10.00 1880 Brown B 4178616 tt tt 10.00 1880 Brown B 383514 It 11 10.00 1886 Red B 9507261 II It 10.00 18S6 Red B 3299448 Page 35 of 45 Certificates Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. $ 1886 Brown B 12208347 10.00 " 10.00 1886 Red B 1274823 " 10.00 1891 Red E 3 " 10.00 1891 Red E 34159690 » 10.00 1891 Red E 17154258 » 10.00 1891 Red E 23153739 " 10.00 1908 Blue B 954904 " 10.00 1908 Blue D 2249108 » 10.00 1908 Blue A 10 " 20.00 1878 Red A 70140 » 20.00 1878 Red A 28862 " 20.00 1880 Brown B 3153820 " 20.00 1880 Brown B 2903031 20.00tt 1886 " Red B 131 20.00ii1886 Brown B 779807 20.00n 1891 Red E 3 20.00it1891 Red E 7467239 20.00 1891 Red E 1709726 20.00u 1891 Red E 9090364 20.00 ti1891 ' Blue H 42900 50.00 H 1880 Brown B 15875 50.00 n1880 Red A 219274 Page 36 of 45 Kind Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. Silver Certificates $ 50.00 1880 Brown B 168478 50.00 1880 Brown A 67173 50.00 1891 Red E 456253 50.00 1891 Red E 824260 50.00 1891 Red H 175704 50.00 1891 Blue K 610812 100.00 1878 Red A 8782 100.00 1880 Red A 116022 100.00 1880 Brown A 16546 100.00 1891 Red E 184127 500.00 1878 Red A 672 500.00 1880 Brown B 1742 1,000.00 1880 Brown B 12638 Red E 1 1,000.00 1891 Total value, book 7 $ 4,342.00 Total number of notes (101) Page 37 of 45 BOOK 8 Face Value $ Series or Date Seal Serial No. 1.00 1928 Blue A 00000001 A 1.00 1928 A Blue Y 00777777 B 1.00 1928 B Blue V 51000250 A 1.00 1928 C Blue B 29449621 B 1.00 1928 D Blue D 82598421 B 1.00 1928 E Blue F 72000212 B 1.00 1934 Blue A 00001065 A 1.00 1935 Blue C 00000015 B 1.00 1935 A (R) Exp erimental Blue S 71563941 C 1.00 1935 A (S) Experimental Blue S 73884850 C 1.00 1935 A Blue Z 76518101 A 1.00 1935 C Blue M 90551120 D 1.00 1935 F Blue P 81000039 I 1.00 1935 F Blue P 81000040 I 1.00 1935 F Blue P 81000041 I 1.00 1935 G Blue B 54000104 J 1.00 1957 Blue A 00002500 A 1.00 1957 Blue A 00004000 A 1.00 1957 A Blue A 00000646 A 5.00 1934 Blue A 00000330 A 5.00 1934 A Blue F 76928701 A • Page 38 of 45 Kind Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No. Silver Certificates $ 5.00 1934 B Blue K 97810424 A II u 5.00 1934 D Blue S 34739061 A it it 5.00 1953 Blue A 00000001 A tt it 10.00 1933 Blue A 00000005 A tt it 10.00 1934 Blue A 00000170 A it ii 10.00 1934 A Blue A 85340015 A it u 10.00 1934 C Blue B 30422989 A tt tt 10.00 1953 Blue A 00004001 A it it 10.00 1953 A Blue A 10440001 A tt 11 1.00 1935 A Yellow B 99003407 C ti it 5.00 1934 A Yellow K 37465004 A tt it 10.00 1934 A Yellow A 94486001 A it ti 1.00 1935 A-Hawaii Brown 5.00 1934 A-Hawaii Brown L 55592993 A Federal Reserve Notes C 00000417 C it it tt 10.00 1934 A-Hawaii Brown L 50410047 B u tt ti 20.00 1934 A-Hawaii Brown L 77867361 A 1.00 1928 Red A 00000001 A 2.00 . 1928 Red A 00000001 A 2.00 1928 A Red B 08319203 A 2.00 1928 B Red B 08325766 A 2.00 1928 C Red B 89579S00 A 2.00 1928 D Red D 07775007 A U.S. Note Page 39 of 45 Kind Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. U.S. Note $ 2.00 1953 Red A 00000004 A ti 11 2,00 1953 A Red A 45363697 A u ii 5.00 1928 Red A 00000001 A ii it 5.00 1928 A Red C 80075030 A it H 5.00 1928 B Red E 08222222 A it tt 5.00 1928 C Red G 31369409 A it it 5.00 1928 D Red G 56190151 A it ti 5.00 1928 E Red G 64406510 A H tt 5.00 1953 Red A 00000002 A 5.00 1929 Brown A 048896 5.00 1929 Brown B 00001022 A n 10.00 1929 Brown A 012979 A it 10.00 1929 Brown B 00312011 A 20.00 1929 Brown A 000056 20.00 1929 Brown D 00000010 A 50.00 1929 Brown B 00004005 A 50.00 1929 Brown C 001716 A 100.00 1929 Brown B 000211 A 100.00 1929 Brown D 00000010 A 5.00 1928 Green J 04S22471 A National Currency it Federal Reserve Notes it ti 5.00 1928 A Green J 05907348 A it tt 5.00 1928 B Green J 09045947 A Page 40 of 45 erve Notes Face Value Series or Date Seal Serial No. $ 1928 Green G 00004000 A Green E 00001000 A 10.00 " » 10.00 1928 B Green B 64206990 A II II 10.00 1934 A Green B 16S66S07 D II «i 10.00 1934 B Green B 76982505 D II II 10.00 1950 Green E 00280033 A ii it 20.00 1928 Green G 00003000 A it II 20.00 1928 A Green D 09920678 A n it 20.00 1928 B Green D 12769810 A it it 20.00 1934 Green E 09883210 A it it 20.00 1950 Green E 00280010 A it it 50.00 1928 Green J 00012718 A n it 50.00 1934 Green J 00000007 A it t» 100.00 1928 Green G 00000077 A II it 100.00 1934 Green G 00000001 A n ti 500.00 1928 Green G 00000001 A 500.00 1934 tt it 11 tt 1,000.00 1928 Green G 00000001 A ti tt 1,000.00 1934 Green G 00000001 A tt tt 5,000.00 1928 Green G 00000001 A tt ti 5,000.00 1928 Green E 00000654 A ti tt 10,000.00 1928 Green B 00000001 A tt it 10,000.00 1934 Green E 00000390 A Page 41 of 45 Face Value Kind Gold Certificate ti it U.S. Note tt Federal Reserve Note Total value, book 8 Series or Date Seal Serial No. 10.00 1928 Gold A 00000001 A 20.00 1928 Gold A 00000001 A 50.00 1928 Gold A 00000001 A 100.00 1928 Gold A 00000001 A 500.00 1928 Gold A 00000001 A 1,000.00 1928 Gold A 00000001 A 5,000.00 1928 Gold A 00000001 A 10,000.00 1928 Gold A 00000001 A 2.00 1963 Red A 01576301 A 5.00 1963 Red A 01792001 A 1.00 1963 Green E 05833601 A $50,729.00 Total number of notes (98) Page 42 of 45 DISPLAY NOTES Face Value Kind Old Demand Notes $ 5.00 Series or Date 58 Seal Serial No. 17889 n tt tt 5.00 50 43656 it tt it 10.00 42821 it 11 tt 10.00 6 42002 Treasury Notes of 1890' 1.00 1891 B 54815431 n ti tt tt 1.00 1891 B 6156714 u tt tt n 10.00 1891 B 543635 ti it ti ti 10.00 1891 B 2705237 1.00 1917 M 97983038 A n 1.00 1917 M 37889195 A it 2.00 1917 B 9799645 A it 2.00 1917 D 78718614 A tt 5.00 1907 II 6363136 ti 5.00 1907 H 17207320 it 10.00 1901 E 9896466 tt 10.00 1901 B 45451934 1.00 1899 K 79565710 A U.S. Notes Silver Certificates ti it 1.00 1899 V 35551300 A ti it 5.00 1896 15479925 tt it 5.00 1896 33906616 n it 10.00 1908 D 3428646 Page 43 of 45 Kind Face Value Scries or Date Silver Certificates $ 1908 u 10.00 Seal Serial No. A 4059209 it 50.00 1891 H 124693 u 50.00 1891 E 1018973 5.00 1875 V 314073 National Bank Notes n it it 5.00 1875 V 314172 it ti tt 10.00 1882 H 20329 H II tt n 10.00 1882 V 573037 it ti tt 20.00 1882 W 922984 E ti ii ti 20.00 1882 U 766951 E II u 50.00 1882 A 980904 E tt tt 50.00 1882 A 980886 E u Federal Reserve Bank Notes tt 1.00 1918 J 19276299 A 1.00 1918 J 19276292 A tt it it u 5.00 1918 B 3655557 A it ti 5.00 1918 B 910385 A it u 10.00 1918 F 15368 A ti H 10.00 1915 J 233452 A it tt 20.00 1915 J 48751 A u ti 20.00 1915 J 157979 A 5.00 1914 E 17628217 A Federal Reserve Notes u it 5.00 1914 G 64876000 B it ti 10.00 1914 A 37739399 A n it 10.00 1914 A 46827529 A Page 44 of 45 Face Value Kind , « vt 4-~o Federal Reserve Notes n ii ti ii n Series or Date Seal Serial No. <: 90 no 1914 G 40170146 A ? zu.uu 20.00 i->i * 1914 G 43250136 A 50.00 1914 F 695340 A 50.00 1914 Total value, Display Notes $632.00 • F 695339 A Total number of notes {AS)_ Page 45 of 45 UNISSUED COLD CERTIFICATES Kind Face Value Scries or Date Seal Serial No. Gold Certificate $ 100.00 1934 A 00000001 A 100.00 1934 A 00000510 A 100.00 1934 A 00000511 A 100.00 1934 A 00000512 A 1,000.00 1934 A 00000001 A 1,000.00 1934 A 00000058 A 1,000.00 1934 A 00000059 A 1,000.00 1934 A 00000060 A 10,000.00 1934 A 00000001 A 10,000.00 1934 A 00000538 A 10,000.00 1934 A 00000539 A 10,000.00 1934 A 00000540 A 100,000.00 193.4 A 00000001 A 100,000.00 1934 A 00020108 A 100,000.00 1934 A 00020109 A 100,000.00 1934 A 00020110 A Total value of unissued Gold Certificates $444,400.00 Total number of notes (16) This is a Gold Certificate Series 1934 Treasury note issued only to Federal Reserve Banks in exchange for gold they turned over to the Treasury. It is the only $100,000 note ever issued as United States currency, and is part of a collection transferred from the Treasury to the Smithsonian Institution. Federal law 18 U.S.C. 5 0 4 permits illustrations of paper m o n e y in black and white of a size less than % or more than 1J4 times the size of the genuine obligation for newsworthy purposes in books, journals, newspapers or albums. Other reproductions are strictly prohibited. foment of theJREASURY GTON.D.C. 20220 TELEPHONE 566-2041 FOR RELEASE UPON DELIVERY EXPECTED AT 10 A.fiT MAY 16, 1978 STATEMENT OF JOHN E. RAY DIRECTOR, OFFICE OF INTERNATIONAL TRADE DEPARTMENT OF THE TREASURY BEFORE THE SUBCOMMITTEE ON MERCHANT MARINE U.S. HOUSE OF REPRESENTATIVES Mr. Chairman, I am pleased to discuss with you the Treasury Department's preliminary comments on H.'R. 11862. This bill is intended to facilitate implementation of reciprocal ocean transportation agreements between United States and foreign flag carriers. The Treasury Department shares your concern that the United States should have a coherent, rational ocean shipping policy. As you are aware, Mr. Chairman, the Administration has begun a thorough study of U.S. ocean shipping policy. This review will address a broad range of issues involved in ocean shipping. We believe that the issues raised in H.R. 11862 can best be addressed as part of the larger study of shipping policy. B-910 - 2 A unified approach is much preferable to a piecemeal analysis of separate but related proposals designed to aid the U.S. shipping industry. As with other maritime legislation this Subcommittee has considered recently, the Treasury is prepared to offer preliminary comments. We expect to present a more definitive position when the Administration's review is completed. H.R. 11862 is particularly appropriate for consideration in a broader policy context because it touches on a fundamental question concerning U.S. ocean shipping policy — should we encourage competition in our ocean trades, or should we permit "rationalization, that is, extensive collective action by carriers to regulate rates, capacity, sailing frequencies, and other aspects of a trade. The particular approach suggested in this legislation can only be evaluated once the broader questions about the direction of our ocean shipping policy have been answered. As you know, the Treasury Department believes that competition in ocean shipping, as in other sectors of the economy, is desirable. We welcome the pro-competitive measures announced by the Civil Aeronautics Board. We would like to see a similar approach to ocean shipping. We fear that new limitations on competition between shipping firms could lead to greater inefficiencies and increased costs, without providing improved services to the shipping - 3 public. Since the intent of this legislation is to sanction private agreements that would otherwise violate U.S. antitrust laws, and thereby reduce competition in shipping, we think it should be evaluated carefully. I would like to comment on specific aspects of this legislation. Section 2(c) of the bill appro- priately places on the proponents of a sanctioned agreement the burden of proof to show that the agreement should become effective. We are concerned, however, by the provision that agreements will automatically become effective unless the FMC acts positively to suspend them. Automatic approval could result in abuse. To be sure, the FMC is granted authority to suspend agreements if it suspects they are unjustly discriminatory, unfair, detrimental to U.S. commerce, or are contrary to the public interest. However, we believe it would be difficult for the FMC to police effectively all the agreements that would result. If private shipping agreements are sanctioned by U.S. law, we may wish to consider whether private parties should have the right to question those agreements in court and win multiple damages if those agreements are unjustly discriminatory, unfair, detrimental to U.S. commerce, or are contrary to the public interest. We would also want to ensure that new carriers would not be blocked from entering a trade as party - 4 to an agreement. Section 2(b)(1) specifies that new carriers shall not be prevented from participating on a "fair, reasonable and equitable basis." We are not sure how these terms would be defined and we are concerned that, in practice, potential entrants could find it difficult to join an existing agreement. We are similarly concerned about the bilateral approach in this bill. Agreements entered into under this legislation would be between carriers of countries in which the cargo originates and for which it is destined? Section 2(b)(1) also provides that third flag carriers may not be prohibited from entering any agreement "on a fair, reasonable, and equitable basis." Again, since these terms are not defined, third flag carriers might be excluded from the trade. A proliferation