View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

cMonetaryJ^olicy
and
7T
C>
CI. A .

P
in

(Economy
1971

A Prelude to the Annual




the

Report




FED. RES,

( L . t

Contents
Monetary

Policy and the

U.S. Economy in 1971
3

11

I N T R O D U C T I O N

W A G E S ,

11
13
14
15
19

D E M A N D S

21
22
24
26
28
31

A N D

F O R

G O O D S

M O N E T A R Y

T O T A L

43
46
48
49

52
53
56
57
I-VII

A N D

S E R V I C E S

A G G R E G A T E S

A N D

1 N I E R E S T

R A T E S

Developments prior to August 15
Later developments
C R E D I T

F L O W S

P R I V A T E

51

P R O D U C T I V I T Y

Residential construction
Consumer income and outlays
Business investment
Government
Manpower utilization

33
38
43

PRICES,

Wages
Productivity and unit labor costs
Prices
Effect of the new economic program

A N D

H I E

F I N A N C I N G

I N V E S T M E N T

Sources of credit supply
Private domestic financing
Saving and investment
Liquid assets
U.S.

BALANC

E

O F

P A Y M E N T S

Measures of August 15
Merchandise trade
Capital flows
Year-end perspective
Principal




Federal

Reserve

Policy

Actions,

1971:

Digest

O F




cMonetaryJ^olicy
and the
7T Q P
tl. Y
(bconomy
^
in 1971







Introduction
In 1971 monetary policy encouraged further substantial growth in
bank reserves, money, and bank credit in helping to stimulate economic recovery from the mild recession of 1969-70. Monetary aggregates in general expanded somewhat more rapidly than they had
the year before. Interest rates fluctuated widely—reflecting, among
other things, shifts in inflationary expectations and large flows of
funds between the United States and foreign countries. After the
President's mid-August announcement of new economic policies,
which included a program of wage and price restraint and far-reaching international measures to combat inflation and the deterioration
in the balance of payments, interests rates showed a declining trend,
and at the end of the year they were down somewhat, on the average,
from their beginning-of-1971 levels.
For 1971 as a whole the real gross national product rose only 2.7
per cent from the year before. Greatly increased spending for residential construction and larger expenditures by State and local governments helped to sustain economic activity. But economic recovery
was hampered by domestic and international economic uncertainties
and generally cautious attitudes on the part of both businesses and
consumers. Unemployment remained at about 6 per cent of the labor
force throughout the year. A n d prices, as measured by average
prices of the goods and services that make up the GNP, rose about
as much in the first half of the year, prior to the new economic program, as they had in 1970.
During the first half of the year, surveys of consumer attitudes
suggested that concern about rising prices, as well as fear of unemployment, was causing consumers to hold back on spending. Consumer outlays for goods and services did rise rather substantially, but
the increase reflected in large measure the first-quarter bulge in disposable personal income and auto sales following settlement of the
late-1970 auto strike, a Federal pay raise, and retroactive increases
in social security benefits. The personal saving rate remained exceptionally high.
With the strength of consumer spending uncertain, businessmen
pursued conservative inventory policies, although there was some




3

strike-related inventory-building during the first half of the year. In
addition, outlays for new plant and equipment were held down by
the sizable amount of excess manufacturing capacity already in place
and by the sluggishness of new orders for the output of these plants.
Defense and nondefense orders from the Federal Government remained at a reduced pace. The cumulative effect of rising costs and
prices limited the ability of U.S. industries to compete in foreign
markets, and in many cases to compete in domestic markets with
goods produced abroad.
During 1971 the U.S. balance of payments worsened dramatically.
The trade balance was only marginally in surplus in the early months
of the year; then it slipped into monthly deficits, making increasingly
evident the extent to which the competitive position of the United
States had eroded.
The worsening of the over-all balance of payments reflected also
the very large outflows of capital from the United States to foreign
countries that occurred in response to interest rate incentives and expectations of changes in currency values. In the early part of the
year U.S. interest rates declined much faster than those in leading
financial centers abroad, and U.S. banks continued to repay Eurodollar borrowings. Foreign official reserves were swollen by these and
other recorded and unrecorded flows of capital. German reserve
gains were especially large until the German mark was permitted to
float upward in May. As evidence of deepening difficulties for the
U.S. balance of payments mounted, international traders and investors shifted out of dollar assets into other currencies on a large scale.
From the end of 1970 to the end of July 1971, U.S. liabilities to
foreign official accounts increased by $12.5 billion to a level of $37
billion, while U.S. reserve assets fell by a little more than $1 billion
to $13.3 billion. In the first 2 weeks of August reserve liabilities
grew by a further $4.5 billion, while reserve assets dropped by another $1 billion.
The worsening in the balance of payments situation heightened
public concern about the effectiveness of policies being pursued to
contain inflation—a concern that was related to the continuation of
large wage settlements and to the lack of evidence that price increases were abating to any significant extent. Interest rates—which
had declined further in the very early months of the year—began to

4




1. SELECTED ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENTS
CHANGE. PER CENT

1970

1971

1

Excludes S D R allocations.
N O T E . — G N P a n d p r i c e d a t a are based o n seasonally a d j u s t e d a n n u a l rates data f r o m
B u r e a u o f E c o n o m i c A n a l y s i s , D e p t . o f C o m m e r c e ; changes f r o m preceding q u a r t e r at
c o m p o u n d e d a n n u a l rates; f i x e d - w e i g h t p r i c e i n d e x is f o r gross p r i v a t e p r o d u c t . F o r defin i t i o n s o f measures o f m o n e y a n d c r e d i t , see C h a r t 12, p. 34; f o r T r e a s u r y b i l l s a n d A a a
b o n d s , see C h a r t 11, p . 32.




5

rise. Long-term rates in particular were affected by renewed resistance to fixed-income securities on the part of investors who feared
that the value of such securities would be eroded over time through
inflation.
The decline in short- and long-term market interest rates early in
the year had been accompanied by three successive reductions of XA
percentage point in the Federal Reserve discount rate, to a level of
43A per cent by mid-February. And the monetary aggregates expanded at rapid rates in the first quarter, with growth in Mx (currency and private demand deposits) reflecting increased transactions
demands and the lagged effects of previous declines in interest rates.
Expansion in the broader monetary aggregates was even more rapid
as low levels of market interest rates relative to offering rates on
time and savings accounts, together with the high rate of personal
saving, led to a very large rise in time and savings deposits at banks
and nonbank thrift institutions.
These inflows, and the accompanying easing of over-all credit
conditions, supported a substantial rise in private housing starts and
in expenditures for new residential construction; starts rose from 1.4
million units in 1970 to more than 2 million units in 1971 and exceeded a 2.2-million-unit annual rate in the fourth quarter. Residential construction outlays, along with rising expenditures by State and
local governments, were important forces contributing to economic
recovery during the year.
Growth in the monetary aggregates continued to be rapid in the
second quarter; growth in Mx accelerated to an annual rate of
around 10.5 per cent from its 9 per cent first-quarter pace. This, together with the disappointing performance of prices, was causing
some concern at home and abroad about the adequacy of public economic policies then in effect to contain inflation. A t the same time,
the slack in the domestic economy made it clear that monetary policy needed to remain expansive. Under the circumstances, the Federal Reserve continued to provide reserves at a substantial rate, but
in the spring and early summer it did so less readily than earlier in
the year. This policy contributed to the rise in short-term rates that
developed during the second quarter. To bring the discount rate into
better alignment with market rates, the rate was raised by Vx of a
percentage point in mid-July to 5 per cent.

6




In an effort to maintain accommodative capital market conditions,
in view of the comparatively weak expansion of the economy, the
Federal Reserve stepped up its purchases of longer-term Treasury securities during the first quarter. Later in the year, it extended its outright purchases of securities in the open market to include Federal
agency issues. These operations were adopted within the over-all
objectives of System open market operations, and they did not contribute, net, to faster growth in the System's total portfolio of securities or to expansion in bank reserves.
Developments over the first 7 months of the year brought increasingly into question whether conventional monetary and fiscal policies
alone were adequate to combat the cost-push inflation and the
deterioration in the U.S. balance of payments, while at the same time
continuing to promote more vigorous recovery in the domestic economy. The new economic policies initiated in mid-August broadened
the mix of public policy measures with a view to dealing more effectively with the Nation's diverse and, in the short run, partly conflicting objectives.
The basic elements of the new program were a temporary 90-day
freeze on wages and prices, to be followed by a more flexible system
of restraints in the second phase; suspension of the convertibility of
the dollar into gold or other reserve assets; imposition of a temporary surtax of up to 10 per cent on dutiable imports; and certain
fiscal measures designed to stimulate spending, including proposed
elimination of the excise tax on autos and an investment tax credit to
encourage business capital outlays. The program of tax incentives,
with some modifications, was enacted by Congress late in the year,
as was legislation authorizing the continuation of a program of restraint on wages, prices, rents, dividends, and interest. The 10 per
cent surtax was rescinded following the international monetary agreement reached on December 18 in Washington.
The new economic program recognized the need for a sizable and
broadly based revaluation of foreign currencies vis-a-vis the dollar to
help restore the international competitiveness of U.S.-produced
goods. But in addition the new program was intended to encourage
improvements in the Bretton Woods Agreements and to eliminate at
least some of the major foreign trade practices injurious to U.S. exports. After August 15 all major countries allowed their currencies




7

to rise somewhat in price relative to the dollar, although foreign
official institutions added substantially more to their holdings of dollars.
The monetary agreement signed in Washington in mid-December
allayed international uncertainties that had threatened to impede the
flow of trade and to hinder U.S. economic recovery. Major foreign
countries agreed to an adjustment of exchange rates, the over-all effect of which was to produce a substantial appreciation, on the average, of foreign currencies in relation to the dollar. The settlement
also included a widening of intervention bands to V-A per cent on either side of the new exchange rates (or parities) as well as an increase of 8.57 per cent—from $35 to $38 per ounce—in the dollar
price of gold to be requested from Congress.
The new domestic and international economic program was immediately reflected in renewed confidence in credit markets. After midAugust, interest rates declined as inflationary expectations abated
and as fears eased that the worsensing balance of payments might
lead to tighter financial conditions in the United States.
The new wage-price program effectively constrained wage and
price increases during the freeze period. After the freeze ended in
mid-November, some catch-up of wage and price increases developed. The Phase I I program of wage and price restraint is being administered by a Pay Board and a Price Commission. The activities of
these two bodies, composed of private citizens, are coordinated by
the governmental Cost of Living Council. The objective of the Phase
I I program is to hold average price increases to no more than 2.5
per cent per year, in conformity with the Council's goal of reducing
the rate of inflation to a range of 2 to 3 per cent by the end of
1972. Such an achievement would halve the rate of inflation that had
prevailed in 1970 and the first half of 1971. A Committee on Interest and Dividends was also formed as part of the Phase I I program
to see that the behavior of dividends and interest rates—particularly
those that affect the American family, such as on mortgages and
consumer loans—is consistent with the program of wage and price
restraint.
The initial effects of the new economic program appear to have
been stimulative. Immediately after announcement of the price
freeze, there was a surge in purchases of new domestically produced




autos, and consumer purchases of other goods and services, in real
terms, also quickened. Employment gains accelerated as did the
over-all rate of economic activity. In the final quarter of the year,
real GNP rose at an annual rate of around 6 per cent, notably faster
than in the second and third quarters and the highest rate of gain,
except for the strike-recovery period in the first quarter of 1971,
since the first half of 1968.
Monetary developments in the latter part of 1971 were highlighted
by moderation in the growth rates of the monetary aggregates. In
particular, the level of the narrowly defined money stock ( M J
showed only a very minor increase from August to December. Following the sharp build-up earlier in the year, when economic uncertainties were pervasive, the public's demand for cash balances leveled
off, reflecting in part reductions in precautionary demands for liquidity as confidence increased. The broader measures of money
continued to expand at substantial rates in the latter part of the year,
although in these too the rate of growth moderated somewhat from
the rapid rates that had occurred in the first half.
A t the same time sufficient bank reserves were being provided to
encourage the interest rate declines initially set in motion by the
wage-price freeze. By the year-end longer-term interest rates were
about 1 percentage point below their mid-August levels, and shortterm rates were down by about 1.5 percentage points over the same
period. And in mid-December the discount rate was reduced to AVi
per cent in recognition of the lower levels of market interest rates
and to assist in encouraging a more rapid economic expansion.
Developments in 1971 laid the basis for an accelerated rate of
economic recovery in 1972 and for further moderation of wage and
price pressures. To be sure, effective administration of the Phase I I
wage and price program will be critical in maintaining public confidence in the containment of inflation. But this result should be encouraged also by basic economic forces, including continuation of an
ample supply of labor and materials, the absence of demand-induced
inflation generally, and the prospect that faster growth in productivity is likely to accompany more vigorous expansion in over-all
economic activity.
The outlook for a strengthening in demands for goods and services
appears highly favorable. Plant and equipment surveys suggest




greater capital outlays by business in 1972 than in 1971. Moreover,
the realignment of exchange rates should make domestically produced goods more competitive, thus enhancing the potential for exports by U.S. firms and perhaps shifting investment plans toward the
United States. And corporations are now in good financial positions
to expand operations—having worked over the past 2 years to restructure their debt and to improve their liquidity positions.
Residential construction outlays should increase somewhat further
in 1972, given the rising rate of housing starts in the latter part of
1971. The currently ample liquidity of banks and other financial institutions and the continuation of large net inflows of time deposits
suggest that credit will be available to finance construction activity
—even if there is a pick-up in business loan demands at banks. State
and local governments are also likely to increase their spending for
construction; these governments issued very sizable amounts of securities in 1971, and according to preliminary indications their demands
for funds will continue to be large in early 1972. Furthermore, the
Federal budget indicates a stimulative fiscal policy during 1972.
An acceleration of economic recovery will depend importantly on
a strengthening in consumer demands. The saving rate declined
somewhat in the latter part of 1971, suggesting an increased consumer propensity to spend and greater confidence in the longer-run
economic outlook. Increases in consumption together with increases
in construction, investment, and net exports would be likely to stimulate increased holdings of inventories since businesses have followed
comparatively conservative policies in this type of investment over
the past 2 years. Such a pick-up in inventory accumulation has been
a major feature of past cyclical recoveries, when it has played a significant role in inducing gains both in employment and in consumption expenditures.
Other sections of this report analyze developments in certain key
areas of the economy in 1971. A digest of the principal Federal Reserve policy actions in 1971 appears on pages I - V I I following page
28.
•

10




// agesj, Pricesj and
Productivity
On the basis of past experience, the continued slack in labor and
product markets that typified the year 1971 should have generated a
pronounced slowdown in the rate of inflation. However, that did not
happen. Whereas the rate of price increase did moderate in some sectors early in the year, much of the improvement reflected the influence of special factors instead of the usual forces of demand and
supply. In general, wages and prices continued to increase at a rapid
rate throughout the first half of the year. Workers sought higher
wage increases to make up for past reductions in real purchasing
power and to protect future gains in wages from expected further inflation. But businessmen too expected that inflation would continue,
and since their profit margins were already low, they passed the
higher labor costs on in the form of higher prices, where possible.
WAGES
Despite the relatively large amount of unemployment, compensation
per manhour continued to grow at a rapid pace in the first half of
1971. Average hourly compensation in the private nonfarm economy
increased at an annual rate of 7.2 per cent in this period, slightly
higher than the 7.0 per cent increase for 1970 as a whole. Relatively
large wage gains occurred in most industries, with the greatest being
in contract construction and in transportation and public utilities. In
manufacturing, average hourly earnings—after allowance for changes
in the industrial composition of factory employment and for overtime
—increased at a rate of 7.0 per cent in the first 6 months of 1971.
One factor contributing to the high rate of wage increases was the
disproportionately large number of major long-term contracts expiring and new settlements negotiated in the latter part of 1970 and in
the first half of 1971, including contracts in such highly visible and
pattern-setting industries as autos, railroads, containers, and communications.
Another factor was that wage increases of many union workers,
particularly in the manufacturing sector, had lagged behind price in-




11

2. C O M P E N S A T I O N PER M A N H O U R
Changes in Recent Business Cycles
A N N U A L RATE, PER CENT

NOTE.—Bureau o f L a b o r Statistics data, seasonally adjusted, f o r p r i v a t e n o n f a r m e c o n o m y .
P e r i o d s c o v e r e d are as f o l l o w s :
1957-58
Cycle
1960-61
Cycle
1969-70
Cvcle
Year before peak
1956 111-1957 I I I
1959 11-1960 I I
1968 I V - 1 9 6 9 I V
Peak to t r o u g h
1957 111-1958 I I
1960 11-1961 I
1969 I V - 1 9 7 0 I V
Year after trough
1958 I I - 1 9 5 9 I I
1961 I - 1 9 6 2 I
1970 I V - 1 9 7 1 I V

creases in the late 1960's. Consequently, there was strong pressure
by union members to catch up on their wages. As a result, contracts
were front-loaded—that is, they had larger increases in the first year
than in following years. In manufacturing, first-year increases averaged 8.7 per cent in the first half of 1971; in nonmanufacturing, they
were smaller than in 1970 but were still considerably larger than in
manufacturing.
Contract settlements in the construction industry, which had been
exceptionally high in recent years, moderated somewhat during
1971; this apparently reflected the efforts of the Construction Industry Stabilization Committee, which was set up in March 1971.
Nevertheless, wage increases allowed in the construction industry
continued to be much higher than the average for all workers.
A slowing in wage increases did become evident in some sectors.
In trade and services, which are typically not unionized, the rate of
advance in wage rates declined somewhat; among nonunion workers

12



3. A V E R A G E H O U R L Y E A R N I N G S
PERCENTAGE

NOTE.—Change f r o m corresponding
w i t h o u t seasonal a d j u s t m e n t .

quarter

a

year

CHANGE

earlier,

calculated

from

BLS

data

in manufacturing also, wage increases moderated and were less than
for union workers. Still, movements in wage rates in 1971 generally
continued to respond less to slack demands for labor than in previous periods of relatively high unemployment.
PRODUCTIVITY AND UNIT LABOR COSTS
Despite continued rapid increases in wages, pressures on unit labor
costs eased somewhat in the first half of 1971 as a result of a faster
growth in productivity. Output per manhour in the private nonfarm
economy rose at an annual rate of about 3.5 per cent in the second
half of 1970 and the first half of 1971, after showing no gain in late
1969 and early 1970. Productivity increases for the manufacturing
sector of the economy were slightly higher. The higher rate of productivity gains stemmed mainly from cost-cutting efforts by business,
which sought to restrict increases in employment even after demand
and output had started to expand. Hence, increases in unit labor
costs slowed from a peak annual rate of more than 6 per cent for
the private nonfarm economy in 1970 to about 3.5 per cent during
the first half of 1971. Even though cost pressures were reduced,




13

4. O U T P U T PER M A N H O U R A N D R E L A T E D D A T A
PERCENTAGE CHANGE

N O T E . — C h a n g e s , expressed a t a n n u a l rates, are based o n h a l f - y e a r averages o f B L S
for the private n o n f a r m economy.

data

they were still strong enough to generate unacceptably high rates of
price increase—since business was experiencing unusually low profit
margins and was unwilling or unable to absorb higher costs.
PRICES
Against this background, only a few signs of abatement in the rate of
price inflation were apparent during the first half of 1971. A significant reduction did occur in the rate of increase of consumer prices in
the first quarter of 1971, but this improvement reflected in large part
a decline in mortgage rates. I n the second quarter the general level
of consumer prices resumed a more rapid upward movement, increasing consumer and business doubts that inflation would be
brought under control in the near future.
Wholesale prices of farm products and food began to rise again in
early 1971. Inflationary tendencies were further intensified by a resurgence in the second quarter of price increases for industrial prod-

14




5. PRICES I N 1971
PER CENT

9

3

0

3
M

S

D

N O T E . — M o n t h - t o - m o n t h changes at c o m p o u n d e d a n n u a l rate.

ucts included in the wholesale index; prices of these products had
leveled off in the second half of 1970 and in early 1971. The resurgence reflected in part an upturn in the prices of materials. Prices of
construction materials accelerated sharply as the housing boom
gained momentum, and steel prices were increased in response to the
build-up in inventories and in anticipation of higher labor costs.
The fixed-weighted deflator for gross private product—the broadest measure of the prices of goods and services produced in the private economy—also showed a continued rapid rate of increase. In
the first half of the year the rise was at an annual rate of 5.4 per
cent, more than the increase in 1970.
EFFECT OF THE NEW ECONOMIC PROGRAM
The acceleration of price increases in the second quarter was a factor in the re-evaluation of economic policy. The new economic program announced by the administration in mid-August included, as
noted earlier, measures that temporarily stabilized wages and prices
as part of a package to restrain inflation while promoting faster economic growth and restoring the basis for balance of payments equilibrium.
The 90-day wage-price freeze included in the program was quite
effective. Gross hourly earnings of private nonfarm workers rose at
an average annual rate of only 2.3 per cent between August and November. Wholesale prices of industrial commodities actually declined




15

during this period, while the rise in consumer prices slowed to a 1.7
per cent annual rate. Moreover, since some price changes in the consumer price index are recorded with a time lag, it is likely that the
rise in consumer prices slowed even more than suggested by the published figures.
Before the end of the freeze in mid-November, a Price Commission with seven public members and a Pay Board composed of five
representatives each from labor, management, and the public were
established. The goal of the Pay Board was to reduce increases in
annual wage rates to an average of 5.5 per cent, and the objective
set by the Price Commission was to reduce price increases on the average to a rate of no more than 2.5 per cent—a rate consistent with
the Pay Board's guideline, given the expectation of a growth in productivity at the long-term average rate of about 3 per cent per year.
The Price Commission stated that price increases generally would be
allowed to cover cost increases, but only after productivity gains had
been taken into account, and only so long as profit margins did not
rise above the average of any two of the previous three fiscal years.
It was expected that after the end of the freeze there would be a
period of transition—one in which wage and price increases would
exceed the guidelines in part because of a bunching of increases
deferred during the freeze. Also, in the early months the Pay Board
was expected to have difficulty holding wage increases within the
guideline because of wage contracts previously negotiated that called
for either deferred or retroactive increases of more than 5.5 per cent.
In December, the first full month after the freeze, average gross
hourly earnings for private nonfarm workers increased at an annual
rate of 6.8 per cent.
By the end of the year only a few decisions had been announced
by the Pay Board. In the decisions covering coal miners and railway
signalmen, wage increases well above the guideline were allowed because the contract settlements had occurred prior to the end of the
freeze. For aerospace workers, the Board rejected a 12 per cent,
first-year wage increase negotiated in a new contract concluded after
the freeze and limited any increase in a new contract to 8.3 per cent.
The contracts considered by the end of 1971 covered only a minor
portion of the work force. Moreover, a vast majority of workers are
employed by small companies that are excluded from the prenotifica-

16



tion requirement. Thus, it is still too early to judge the ultimate
effectiveness of Phase I I in limiting wage rate increases.
The Price Commission requires that large firms give notification
of intended price increases, and by the end of December a large
number had filed such applications. The Commission appears to
have had some success in reducing requested price increases. Moreover, in some instances where price increases were approved by the
Commission, they have not been put into effect, due to competitive
pressures. However, as expected, an acceleration of price increases
occurred in the immediate postfreeze period. In December, the increase for consumer prices was 4.7 per cent at a compounded annual
rate (Table 1); and for all commodities excluding food, it was 4.2
per cent. Wholesale prices of industrial commodities advanced at an
annual rate of 3.2 per cent, with about half of the increase reflecting
a rise in prices of autos and trucks. The implicit deflator for GNP
rose at an annual rate of only 1.5 per cent in the fourth quarter—reflecting mainly the effects of the freeze.
In the second half of 1971, productivity rose at a 3.0 per cent annual rate in the private nonfarm economy while the rise in compensation per manhour slowed to a 5.5 per cent annual rate. As a
result, the increase in unit labor costs was reduced to a 2.5 per cent
annual rate. As economic activity continues to expand, productivity
gains at least as large as those experienced in 1971 seem likely.

Table 1: PRICE CHANGES
Per cent

1971, c o m p o u n d e d
a n n u a l rate

Year
Series

Wholesale prices, t o t a l
Industrial commodities
F a r m products, processed
feeds

foods,




Bureau

of

1969

1970

1971

DecAug.

Aug.Nov.

Nov.Dec.

2.5
2.6

3.9
3.3

3.7
3.8

3.2
3.6

5.1
4.9

-0.8
-1.3

8.9
3.2

and

Consumer prices, t o t a l
Food
O t h e r c o m m o d i t i e s (less f o o d )
Services

NOTE.—Based o n

1968

Labor

2.4

5.4

3.4

2.0

5.9

4.2
3.6
3.6
5.2

5.4
5.1
4.2
6.9

5.9
5.5
4.2
8.1

4.3
3.0
3.8
5.6

3.8
4.7
2.4
4.5

Statistics

28.2
1.7
1.7
3.1

4.7
8.3
4.2
3.7

data.

17

Wage pressures should be less in 1972 than in 1971, particularly
if price increases are smaller. Most of the Pay Board's decisions relating to large contracts associated with the pre-freeze round of bargaining should be resolved early in 1972, and fewer major labor
contracts are scheduled to be negotiated than in 1971. In addition,
wage increases scheduled in existing contracts are smaller for the
second and third years than for the first. If wage pressures are moderated and productivity gains are relatively strong, unit labor costs
should come under appreciably better control. Moreover, such a
slowing of the rise in labor costs would help to limit price increases.
As price increases moderate, worker demands for wage increases in
anticipation of future inflation should also abate, and thereby assist
the Pay Board and the Price Commission in achieving their goals.

18




Demands for Goods
and Services
The expansion in demands for goods and services was quite modest
during 1971. The year began with an upsurge in real GNP, which
increased at an 8 per cent annual rate in the first quarter following a
4 per cent decline in the preceding quarter. But this rise reflected in
considerable measure a rebound in auto output and sales after the
end of the auto strike in late 1970.
I n the second quarter the increase in real GNP was less than half as
large as that in the first quarter despite an impressive gain in residential construction activity and stockpiling of steel inventories in anticipation of a possible strike in midsummer. Federal defense spending
continued to be cut, and a further deterioration in U.S. foreign trade
eliminated the positive balance in net exports of goods and services.

6. C H A N G E I N GNP

60

20

0
it

6

2
0
q1

1969
Note.—Based
Commerce.

on




1970

quarterly

data

1971
(seasonally

q2

q3

q4

1971
adjusted annual rates)

f r o m B E A, Dept.

of

19

Gains in industrial production were slight, growth in employment
was slow, and unemployment remained at around 6 per cent of the
civilian labor force. Furthermore, prices continued to increase rapidly during the first half.
The new economic program introduced on August 15 led to an
improvement in the outlook for economic activity. There were signs
that consumer confidence improved in response to the strong measures taken to control inflation. The prospect for consumer spending
was favorably affected by this as well as by fiscal measures included
in the program, such as proposals to remove the excise tax on autos
and to advance to the beginning of 1972 certain personal tax reductions previously scheduled for 1973. Prospective business spending on
capital goods was encouraged by a proposed investment tax credit.
The fiscal elements of the program were enacted, with some modifications, by Congress in December.
Final sales, measured in real terms, rose somewhat more rapidly
in the third quarter than in the second, spurred by a sharp increase

Table 2: GROSS N A T I O N A L PRODUCT
1971
Item

1969

1970

1971
I

II

I n b i l l i o n s o f dollars
G N P , current dollars
I n v e n t o r y change
F i n a l sales
Private 2
Federal
G N P , constant dollars

III

IV

1,072.9

1

929.1

974.1

1,046.8

1,020.8

1,040.0

1,053.4

7.4

2.8

2.2

3.1

4.6

-1.2

2.4

921.7
822.6
99.2

971.3
874.1
97.2

1,044.5
946.9
97.6

1,017.7
921.4
96.4

1,035.4
939.4
96.0

1,054.6
957.0
97.6

1,070.4
970.1
100.3

724.7

720.0

739.4

729.7

735.8

740.7

751.3

Percentage change f r o m preceding period
(at a n n u a l rates)
G N P i n c u r r e n t dollars
G N P in constant (1958) d o l l a r s . .
G N P i m p l i c i t deflator (1958 = 100).

1

7.5
2.6
4.8

4.8
-.6
5.5

7.5
2.7
4.6

Q u a r t e r l y d a t a are seasonally a d j u s t e d a n n u a l rates.
A d j u s t e d t o include State and l o c a l governments.
NOTE.—Basic data f r o m D e p a r t m e n t o f C o m m e r c e , B E A .

2

20




13.7
8.0
5.4

7.8
3.4
4.2

5.2
2.7
2.5

7.6
5.8
1.7

in purchases of domestically produced autos after announcement of
the new economic program. However, liquidation of inventories, particularly excess steel stocks, resulted in a further slowing of the
growth in GNP (Table 2 ) . Late in the year over-all economic activity accelerated as inventory accumulation was resumed, as outlays
for residential construction continued to rise, and as the rate of real
business capital spending picked up. Surveys made late in the year
indicated that businesses planned a sizable increase in outlays for
plant and equipment in 1972.
Although the economy was showing increased evidence of upward
momentum late in the year, this momentum was not yet reflected in
a significant reduction in the unemployment rate or in an increase in
the rate of capacity utilization in manufacturing. The unemployment
rate remained at 6 per cent as growth in new jobs was offset by an
increase in the number of new jobseekers.
RESIDENTIAL CONSTRUCTION
Residential construction continued to expand vigorously throughout
1971, as mortgage funds were in ample supply and interest rates
were declining. Private housing starts rose from an average annual
rate of 1.3 million units in early 1970 to an average rate of 2.2 million units in the final quarter of 1971. For the year as a whole, such
starts approached 2.1 million units—a new high, which surpassed by
7 per cent the record that had stood since 1950. There was some
shift in the mix away from the smaller, less expensive single-family
homes that had characterized the market in 1970 when subsidized
units had accounted for a larger proportion of the total. But builders
continued to feature a high proportion of townhouses and apartments
in an attempt to offset higher land and construction costs. In addition to the record number of housing starts, shipments of mobile
homes reached one-half million units, which also represented a new
high.
The improvement in housing starts was reflected in strong increases in residential construction expenditures, which were still rising as the year drew to a close. Spending for new homes also helped
to keep consumer outlays for such durable goods as furniture and
appliances on a generally upward path. For 1971 as a whole overall expenditures for residential construction were some $10 billion,




21

7. PRIVATE H O U S I N G A C T I V I T Y

N O T E . — B u r e a u o f t h e Census m o n t h l y d a t a
v e r t e d t o q u a r t e r l y averages b y F e d e r a l Reserve.

at

seasonally

adjusted

annual

rates,

con-

or 34 per cent, larger than in 1970; in real terms this represented a
gain of about 27 per cent.
CONSUMER INCOME AND OUTLAYS
Because of tax cuts, a Federal pay raise, and an increase in wages
and salaries that reflected the resumption of auto production and related activities following the strike, disposable personal income rose
by more than $20 billion in the first quarter of 1971, almost twice
the average quarterly increase in 1970. The rise in consumption almost equaled that in disposable income, with more than half of the
increase being attributed to renewed auto buying. Sales of domestictype autos in the first quarter were at an annual rate of 8.4 million
units—up sharply from the 5.4 million annual rate of the strike-depressed fourth quarter of 1970. According to surveys, however, consumers continued to be concerned about inflation and unemployment. For the most part, therefore, they remained cautious, and the
saving rate remained above 8 per cent.
Growth in consumer spending tapered off in the second quarter
despite a sizable further rise in disposable income. In real terms such
spending increased at an annual rate of about 4 per cent, but this
was less than half the rate in the preceding quarter.

22




8. CONSUMER I N C O M E , O U T L A Y S ,
A N D SAVING
PERCENTAGE CHANGE

10

5

0
NT
9

8

7

0
N O T E . — B a s e d o n s e a s o n a l l y a d j u s t e d a n n u a l rates d a t a f r o m B E A , D e p t . o f C o m m e r c e .
I n c o m e a n d e x p e n d i t u r e s are c h a n g e f r o m p r e c e d i n g q u a r t e r . S a v i n g r a t e is p e r c e n t a g e o f
disposable personal income.

I n response to the new economic program, sales of new domestictype autos, which had leveled off after the first quarter, spurted sharply to an average annual rate of 9.7 million units during the 90-day
period, mid-August to mid-November, when the price freeze and the
import surcharge were in effect and the proposal to remove the excise tax on autos was being considered. Sales of foreign auto models
fell during this period, in part because newly imported autos (subject
to the import surcharge) became more expensive relative to domestic cars during the freeze, and later because of limitations on supply
as a result of the dock strikes. In late November and in December,
after the price freeze had ended, sales of domestic units dropped
back to an average rate of 8 million units.
Purchases of durable goods other than autos and of nondurable
goods and services rose moderately in the latter half of the year
(Table 3 ) , and in real terms increases in total consumer spending
continued at about the 4 per cent rate of the second quarter. The
saving rate remained above 8 per cent until the fourth quarter when
it edged down to about 7.8 per cent as gains in consumption ex-




23

Table 3: CHANGES I N MAJOR COMPONENTS OF GROSS N A T I O N A L
PRODUCT
I n b i l l i o n s o f dollars, except f o r saving rate

1971
Item

1969

1970

1

1971
I

II

III

IV

Gross national p r o d u c t

64.9

45.0

72.7

32.4

19.2

13.4

19.5

Personal consumption expenditures
D u r a b l e goods
N o n d u r a b l e goods
Services

43.4
5.9
16.8
20.8

36.2
-1.3
17.1
20.4

46.3
11.9
13.9
20.5

20.2
11.7
2.3
6.1

12.5
2.5
4.6
5.5

11.4
3.7
2.4
5.3

8.4
.8
3.1
4.5

Saving rale (level, in per cent)
Fixed investment
Residential structures
Nonresidential

6.0

7.9

8.2

8.1

8.6

8.1

7.8

11.5
1.1
9.8

2.1
-1.4
3.5

16.8
10.2
6.6

6.6
2.6
3.9

8.1
4.6
3.6

3.7
2.7
1.0

5.0
1.7
3.3

.3

-4.6

-.6

-.6

1.5

-5.8

3.6

Net exports o f goods and services
Exports
Imports

-.5
5.0
5.5

1.6
7.3
5.7

-3.6
2.4
6.0

2.0
3.0
1.0

-4.6
.3
4.9

-.1
1.7
1.8

-4.6
-7.8
-3.2

Govt, purchases of goods and services
Federal
Defense
Other
State a n d l o c a l

10.1
.4
.1
.2
9.8

9.7
-2.0
-3.0
1.2
11.6

13.6
.4
-4.0
4.3
13.3

4.2
.5
-.6
1.0
3.7

1.7
-.4
-1.2
.9
2.0

4.2
1.6
-1.2
2.8
2.6

7.0
2.7
1.2
1.5
4.3

Inventory change

1

S e a s o n a l l y a d j u s t e d a n n u a l rates.
NOTE.—Based on data f r o m B E A , Dept. of Commerce.

ceeded those in income and the increase in consumer instalment debt
accelerated.
BUSINESS INVESTMENT
The relatively small increases in 1971 in business spending for new
plant and equipment and for inventories were among the most important reasons for the sluggish economic growth during much of the
year. Business investment in new fixed capital, while increasing by
more than 6 per cent in current dollars, showed little change over
1970 in real terms. Businessmen's continued cautiousness in regard
to capital investment reflected several factors: the lack of ebullience
of consumer and business sales; the continued low rate of manufacturing capacity utilization—less than 75 per cent; and the continuation of before-tax corporate profits at levels significantly below those
of 1968-69, although such profits did show a notable improvement
through midyear.

24




Attempts were made to stimulate capital investment early in the
year through liberalization of depreciation allowances, but the measures proposed were subject to legal challenges until near the yearend when the allowances, in considerably reduced form, were included in the Revenue Act of 1971. This Act also included a 7 per
cent retroactive investment tax credit.
Investment was particularly weak in the manufacturing sector. Declines in spending were pronounced in the primary metals, machinery, and transportation equipment industries; these industries suffered
not only from cutbacks in spending for defense and for aerospace but
also from sluggish demands generally. Investment was also cut by
railroads, where cyclical problems predominated, and by airlines,
where seating capacity was well in excess of passenger traffic. Capital
spending by electric utilities, communications, and commercial firms,
however, remained relatively strong throughout the period.
9. BUSINESS I N V E S T M E N T A N D
CAPACITY UTILIZATION
B I L L I O N S OF DOLLARS

80

70
0
1969
NOTE.—Fixed
Commerce.




1970
investment:

Seasonally

1971
adjusted

annual

rates

data

from

BEA,

Dept.

of

25

The relatively low rate of inventory investment, which totaled only
$2 billion for the year 1971, reflected the relatively high ratio of
inventories to sales with which businesses had started the year. In
contrast to experience in previous cyclical downturns, total inventories had not been reduced in 1970, and sluggish consumer demand,
lack of ebullience in capital spending, and the decline in spending for
defense purposes contributed to holding down inventory investment
in 1971.
Steel was stockpiled early in the year in anticipation that there
might be a strike in the steel industry when labor contracts expired
on July 31, but after that date steel stocks were sharply reduced, resulting in an over-all net inventory liquidation during the third quarter. Thus, stock/sales ratios, which had been declining irregularly
throughout 1971, ended the year at appreciably lower levels than
had prevailed at the beginning. Although inventory investment remained modest in the fourth quarter, the swing from liquidation to
accumulation contributed importantly to the acceleration of growth
in GNP.
GOVERNMENT
Federal Government purchases of goods and services showed relatively little net change from 1970 to 1971. Increased purchases for
nondefense purposes were about offset by further declines in defense
outlays. The average size of the Armed Forces was cut by nearly
371,000 from 1970, while civilian employment was little changed.
However, Federal spending was sustained by a Government-wide pay
increase early in the year and a further increase in pay of the armed
services in November; the latter increase was designed to facilitate
the building of an all-volunteer service.
On the other hand, purchases of military hardware declined further. The cumulative effects of such cutbacks were severe on the defense products industries and their suppliers. Production of defense
and space equipment edged down through April and remained sluggish thereafter, and at the year-end employment in defense products
industries was more than 100,000 below year-earlier levels.
In contrast to purchases of goods and services, total Federal Government expenditures rose substantially in the calendar year 1971
(Table 4 ) . Grants-in-aid to State and local governments, which ran

26




Table 4: F E D E R A L G O V E R N M E N T RECEIPTS A N D EXPENDITURES
Federal Sector N I A Accounts
In billions of dollars

C a l e n d a r year

1971

1

Item
1969

Receipts
Expenditures
Purchases of g o o d s a n d
services
Other
S u r p l u s o r deficit

1970

1971

I

II

III

IV

196.9
189.5

191.5
205.1

198.7
221.4

196.5
212.7

197.7
221.4

197.8
224.6

2 202.8
228.7

99.2
90.3
7.3

97.2
107.9
-13.6

97.6
124.3
-23.1

96.4
116.3
-16.2

96.0
125.4
-23.7

97.6
127.0
-26.7

100.3
128.4
2 - 25.9

1

Seasonally adjusted a n n u a l rates.
- I m p l i e d i n c a l e n d a r year t o t a l s .
N O T E . — B a s e d o n d a t a f r o m D e p t . o f C o m m e r c e , B E A . T h e F e d e r a l sector i n the n a t i o n a l
i n c o m e a c c o u n t s ( N I A ) m e a s u r e s F e d e r a l r e c e i p t s a n d e x p e n d i t u r e s as t h e y d i r e c t l y affect
p r i v a t e i n c o m e s i n t h e n a t i o n a l a c c o u n t s . T h u s i t e x c l u d e s a l l F e d e r a l l e n d i n g , w h i c h affects
p r i v a t e d e b t b u t n o t i n c o m e s . A l s o the t i m i n g i n s o m e t r a n s a c t i o n s is o n a n a c c r u a l basis;
i n o t h e r s , o n a d e l i v e r y basis.

$5 billion more than in 1970, together with higher social security
benefits and increases in other transfer payments, boosted Federal
Government expenditures by about $17 billion from 1970. A t the
same time, additional tax reductions enacted during the year—including the auto excise tax reduction and the retroactive investment
tax credit—and a slower-than-anticipated rate of economic growth
caused increases in receipts to fall short of original expectations.
Consequently, the Federal budget deficit (national-income-accounts
basis) was $23 billion in calendar year 1971, nearly $10 billion
larger than in 1970.
The strong growth trend of recent years in purchases by State and
local governments continued in 1971; such purchases rose by over
$13 billion, nearly $2 billion more than the increase in 1970.
Wages paid by these governments continued to move up at a brisk
pace, but the gain in employment was somewhat less than the average for other recent years. This slowing reflected in large part resistance by taxpayers to higher costs and reduced needs for hiring new
teachers because of a smaller rise in school enrollments. New Federal legislation subsidizing specific kinds of public service employment in State and local government had only a limited impact,
mainly because the program was operational only in the last few
months of the year.




27

Although State and local government borrowing was facilitated by
easier conditions in financial markets and lower interest rates, a large
portion of the additional funds so obtained were apparently used to
strengthen financial positions, and construction expenditures appear
to have increased relatively little over the year as a whole.
MANPOWER UTILIZATION
The labor market continued slack in 1971 and unemployment remained relatively high (Table 5 ) . After a year of decline, nonfarm
payroll employment began to rise in early 1971, but the gains were
small and they were concentrated in the nonindustrial sectors of the
economy—particularly in services and in State and local government.
Manufacturing employment, which had fallen sharply throughout
1970, continued to edge down, and prior to the introduction of the
new economic program it was 1.8 million below the peak reached in
1969. Employment of both production and nonproduction workers
was cut as businesses continued to take measures to limit increases
in labor costs. Nor was there any indication at midyear that employers were lengthening the workweek, as was typical of previous recovery periods.
The unemployment rate, which had risen to slightly over 6 per
cent at the end of 1970, went no higher in the first half of 1971 because there was little growth in the civilian labor force. Many workers who might normally have sought jobs were discouraged from
Table 5: LABOR M A R K E T INDICATORS
Changes in thousands o f persons, except f o r u n e m p l o y m e n t rate,
w h i c h is r a t e i n final q u a r t e r o f each year.

Year ending f o u r t h quarter o f —
Item
1969

1970

1971

T o t a l l a b o r force
A r m e d Forces

2,339
-53

1,330
-444

1,268
-352

C i v i l i a n l a b o r force
Total civilian employment
Unemployment rate (per
cent)....

2,392
2,168
3.6

1,774
- 1
5.8

1,620
1,428
5.9

Nonfarm employment:
Total
Manufacturing

2,033
187

-719
-1,473

893
-81

N O T E . — B a s e d o n B L S d a t a n o t a d j u s t e d f o r seasonal v a r i a t i o n .

28




c

Principal



*

Federal Reserve Policy Actions, 1971: Digest

Principal
Period, or
announcement date

Federal

Reserve

Policy

Actions,

Action

1971: D i g e s t — C o n t i n u e d

Purpose

January 7

Reduced the discount rate from 5 V2 per cent
to 5 Va, per cent at 10 Reserve Banks, effective
January 8. (By January 15, the 5V4 per cent
rate was in effect at all Reserve Banks.)

To bring the discount rate
into better alignment with
short-term interest rates, which
had declined further since the
previous reduction in the discount rate was announced on
November 30.

January

Directed that System open market operations
be conducted with a view to maintaining bank
reserves and money market conditions consistent with the objective of promoting accommodative conditions in credit markets and moderate expansion in monetary and credit aggregates.

To foster financial conditions conducive to the resumption of sustainable economic
growth, while encouraging an
orderly reduction in the rate
of inflation and the attainment of reasonable equilibrium
in the country's balance of
payments.

January 15

Amended Regulation M to permit U.S. banks
to count toward maintenance of their reservefree Euro-dollar bases any funds invested by
their overseas branches in Export-Import Bank

A further step to temper the
adverse impact of Euro-dollar
outflows on the U.S. balance
of payments.




securities offered under the program announced
on January 15 by the Export-Import Bank. For
those banks that have had a minimum (3 per
cent of deposits) reserve-free base, postponed
for 4 weeks, through the computation period
of February 17, 1971, the application of the
automatic downward adjustment of their bases.
Reduced the discount rate from 5!A per cent
to 5 per cent at 6 Reserve Banks, effective
January 19. (By January 29, the 5 per cent
rate was in effect at all Reserve Banks.)

To take into account the
further declines that had taken
place in short-term market
rates.

Early February
through early
April

Directed that System open market operations
be conducted with a view to maintaining prevailing money market conditions while accommodating downward movements in long-term
rates, with a provision for modification of operations if it appeared that the monetary and
credit aggregates were falling short of (after
early March, deviating significantly from) the
growth paths expected.

To foster financial conditions conducive to the resumption of sustainable economic
growth, while encouraging an
orderly reduction in the rate
of inflation and the attainment
of reasonable equilibrium in
the country's balance of payments.

February 12

Reduced the discount rate from 5 per cent to
43A per cent at 11 Reserve Banks, effective
February 13. (By February 19, the 43A per
cent rate was in effect at all Reserve Banks.)

To accord with the System's
recent practice of making small
changes in the discount rate to
keep it in closer alignment
with short-term market rates.




Principal
Period, or
announcement date

Federal

Reserve

Policy

Actions,

1971:

Digest—Continued

Action

Purpose

April 1

Amended Regulation M to permit U.S. banks
to count toward maintenance of their reservefree Euro-dollar bases any funds invested by
their overseas branches in U.S. Treasury securities offered under the program announced
on April 1 by the Treasury.

To temper the adverse impact of Euro-dollar outflows
on the U.S. balance of payments.

Early A p r i l
through early
May

Directed that System open market operations
be conducted with a view to attaining temporarily some minor firming in money market
conditions, while continuing to meet some part
of reserve needs through purchases of coupon
issues in the interest of promoting accommodative conditions in long-term credit markets,
with a provision for modification of operations if it appeared that the monetary - and
credit aggregates were deviating significantly
from the growth paths desired.

To foster financial conditions conducive to the resumption of sustainable economic
growth, while encouraging an
orderly reduction in the rate
of inflation, moderation of
short-term capital outflows,
and attainment of reasonable
equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments.

Early May through
late August

Directed that System open market operations
be conducted with a view to maintaining bank
reserves and money market conditions consistent with the objective of achieving more mod-

To foster financial conditions conducive to the resumption of sustainable economic
growth, while encouraging an




erate growth in monetary aggregates over the
months ahead, while taking account of developments in capital markets.

orderly reduction in the rate
of inflation, moderation of
short-term capital outflows,
and attainment of reasonable
equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments.

July 15

Raised the discount rate from 43A per cent
to 5 per cent at 4 Reserve Banks, effective July
16. (By July 23, the 5 per cent rate was in
effect at all Reserve Banks.)

To bring the discount rate
into better alignment with
short-term rates, which had
increased, and to reflect the
Board's concern over the continuation of substantial costpush inflation in the economy.

Late August
through late
September

Directed that System open market operations
be conducted with a view to achieving bank
reserve and money market conditions consistent with the objective of achieving more moderate growth in monetary and credit aggregates.

To foster financial conditions consistent with the aims
of the Government's new economic program, including sustainable real economic growth
and increased employment,
abatement of inflationary pressures, and attainment of reasonable equilibrium in the
country's balance of payments.

August 24

Amended the continuing authority directive
with respect to domestic open market operations to authorize outright operations in Federal agency securities.

To widen the base of System
open market operations and at
the same time add breadth to
the market for agency issues.




Principal
Period, or
announcement date

Federal

Reserve

Policy

Actions,

1971:

Digest—Continued

Action

Purpose

Late September
through midNovember

Directed that System open market operations
be conducted with a view to achieving bank
reserve and money market conditions consistent
with the objective of achieving moderate growth
in monetary and credit aggregates, taking account (through mid-October) of developments
in capital markets.

To foster financial conditions consistent with the aims
of the new governmental program, including sustainable
real economic growth and increased employment, abatement of inflationary pressures,
and attainment of reasonable
equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments.

November 10

Reduced the discount rate from 5 per cent to
43A per cent at 7 Reserve Banks, effective
November 11. (By November 19, the 4 3 A per
cent rate was in effect at all Reserve Banks.)

To bring the discount rate
into better alignment with
short-term rates generally, in
recognition of the reductions
that had taken place in those
rates.

Mid-November
through midDecember

Directed that System open market operations
be conducted with a view to achieving bank reserve and money market conditions consistent
with the objective of promoting somewhat

To foster financial conditions consistent with the aims
of the new governmental program, including sustainable




greater growth in monetary and credit aggregates over the months ahead.

real economic growth and increased employment, abatement of inflationary pressures,
and attainment of reasonable
equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments.

December 3

Reduced the margin requirement for purchasing or carrying stocks from 65 per cent to
55 per cent, effective December 6.
Reduced the required deposit on short sales
from 65 per cent to 55 per cent, effective
December 6.

To be less restrictive in
view of the moderate level of
outstanding stock market credit and the absence of indications of the excessive use of
such credit.

December 10

Reduced the discount rate from 43A
to 4Vi per cent at 4 Reserve Banks,
December 13. (By December 24, the
cent rate was in effect at all Reserve

per cent
effective
4Vi per
Banks.)

To recognize the prevailing
levels of market interest rates
and to assist the progress of
economic expansion.

Mid-December
through year-end

Directed that System open market operations
be conducted with a view to promoting the
degree of ease in bank reserve and money market conditions essential to greater growth in
monetary aggregates.

To foster financial conditions consistent with the aims
of the new governmental program, including sustainable
real economic growth and increased employment, abatement of inflationary pressures,
and attainment of reasonable
equilibrium in the country's
balance of payments.







10. E M P L O Y M E N T A N D U N E M P L O Y M E N T
CHiMifirMILUOHSOFPERSpNS

N O T E . — Q u a r t e r l y d a t a , seasonally a d j u s t e d , f r o m B L S .

doing so by high unemployment and by the lack of new hiring. A t
midyear the unemployment rate of white workers was 5.5 per cent,
about the same as at the start of the year, but for Negroes and other
races combined it had reached a rate of about 10 per cent.
Nonfarm employment, after declining slightly in the third quarter,
began to rise again in the closing months of the year, as manufacturing employment stabilized and service-type industries continued to
add workers. By the year-end employment in service-type industries
had risen by 1.1 million from a year earlier, with both trade and
State and local governments showing sizable gains. But as economic
prospects improved in the second half, strong increases in total employment were matched by stepped-up growth of the civilian labor
force. As a result the unemployment rate continued at about the 6
per cent level. However, an increase in the average workweek after
September and a reduction in insured unemployment toward the yearend indicated some strengthening in the labor market.
•




29




Monetary Aggregates and
Interest Rates
The money and bank credit aggregates expanded substantially in
1971 (Table 6), while market interest rates receded further from the
already reduced levels of late 1970. During the year, however, both
interest rates and rates of growth in the aggregates varied over a wide
range.

Table 6: SELECTED M O N E T A R Y
AGGREGATES, 1971
Change, i n per cent

Molhey stock:
Mi
Ml
Mi

6.2
11.1
13.3

Adjusted credit proxy

9.5

T o t a l reserves

7.3

N o n b o r r o w e d reserves

8.1

N O T E . — F o r definitions of the three measures o f
the m o n e y s t o c k a n d t h e c r e d i t p r o x y , see C h a r t
12, p. 34. T o t a l reserves are r e q u i r e d reserves h e l d
a g a i n s t m e m b e r b a n k deposits a n d n o n d e p o s i t i t e m s
subject
t o reserves, p l u s excess reserves.
Nonb o r r o w e d reserves are t o t a l reserves less m e m b e r
bank borrowings f r o m F.R. Banks.

In the early weeks of 1971 the cyclical decline in interest rates
that had accompanied the 1970 recession continued. And for a
while growth of the narrowly defined money stock (A/,) was sluggish. In the course of the first quarter, however, both of these tendencies were reversed. Money and bank credit aggregates showed
rapid growth until midsummer, and some interest rates—influenced
in part by disappointment as to progress in curbing inflation—rose
as much as 200 basis points to levels well above those that had prevailed at the end of 1970.
After the mid-August announcement of the new economic program, inflationary expectations abated and interest rates declined
again, reaching year-end levels generally below those that had pre-




31

vailed at the beginning of the year. A t the same time, growth of the
money and bank credit aggregates slowed. The deceleration was particularly marked in the narrowly defined money stock, where there
had been a sharp build-up in cash balances earlier in the year. For
the year as a whole, M 1 grew at an annual rate of 6.2 per cent,
somewhat more than in 1970, while M., ( M , plus time and savings
deposits other than large negotiable certificates of deposit) and the
adjusted bank credit proxy grew by 11 and almost 10 per cent, respectively. Total reserves of member banks rose by over 7 per cent.
Strong demands for credit in 1971 were a factor limiting interest
rate declines, particularly in long-term markets. Total funds raised in
all credit markets exceeded the previous record, of 1970, by about
$50 billion. Borrowing by the Federal Government to finance a record postwar deficit accounted for a sizable part of this increase, but
private financing also expanded substantially. New records were set

11. I N T E R E S T RATES
PER CENT PER A N N U M

3 S O H M 10
LONG-TERM

1970

1971

1970

1971

N O T E . — M o n t h l y averages. Y i e l d s : U . S . T r e a s u r y b i l l s , m a r k e t y i e l d s o n 3 - m o n t h issues;
c o r p o r a t e b o n d s , w e i g h t e d averages o f n e w p u b l i c l y o f f e r e d b o n d s r a t e d A a a , A a , a n d A
b y M o o d y ' s I n v e s t o r s S e r v i c e a n d a d j u s t e d t o an A a a basis; U . S . G o v t , b o n d s , m a r k e t
y i e l d s a d j u s t e d t o 10-year c o n s t a n t m a t u r i t y by U . S . T r e a s u r y ; State a n d l o c a l g o v t , b o n d s
( 2 0 issues, m i x e d q u a l i t y ) , B o n d B u y e r . H o m e m o r t g a g e s , F N M A a u c t i o n ; c o m m i t m e n t s
o n 3 - m o n t h m a t u r i t i e s u n t i l m i d - O c t o b e r 1971, a n d 4 - m o n t h m a t u r i t i e s t h e r e a f t e r .

32




in mortgage debt expansion; in total financing by nonfinancial corporations, including stocks'and bonds; and in borrowing by State and
local governments.
Bank and nonbank thrift institutions were of particular importance
in supplying the increased volume of funds raised. The generally
easy and accommodative stance of Federal Reserve policy contributed to a sharp growth in thrift deposits at these institutions because
interest rates in short-term markets remained low relative to those
paid on time and savings accounts.
The ample availability of funds at commercial banks encouraged
sizable increases in real estate and consumer lending and in loan
commitments to business. Takedowns of business loan commitments were quite small, however, as businesses, in lieu of bank
credit, continued to rely heavily on capital market financing and as
they obtained increased amounts of funds internally through improved profits and rising capital consumption allowances. Banks also
channeled a large share of their deposit inflows into security investments, adding in the process to their own liquidity.
A t nonbank thrift institutions too, heavy inflows of deposits supported an improvement in liquidity along with a large increase in
mortgage lending. In addition, mutual savings banks invested a substantial portion of their deposits in the corporate bond market. A
part of the improvement in liquidity reflected large paydowns by the
savings and loan associations of advances from the Federal home
loan banks. Reduced reliance on the home loan banks and on the
Federal National Mortgage Association permitted these institutions,
in turn, to reduce substantially their own demands on securities markets.
DEVELOPMENTS PRIOR TO AUGUST 15
Early in 1971 growth of the narrowly defined money stock remained
quite small, carrying over the pattern of sluggishness that had developed during the auto strike in late 1970. Once the sharp poststrike
catch-up in current-dollar GNP was under way, however, growth in
the money stock accelerated at a rapid pace. From February through
July, M i grew at an unusually high annual rate, about 11 per cent.
To a considerable extent this expansion reflected the enlarged
need for transactions balances created by the rapid rate of growth in




33

current-dollar GNP during the first half of 1971. I n addition, the
over-all demand for money in this period appears to have been reinforced by the lagged effects of the sharp decline in short-term interest rates that had started in the summer of 1970 and had carried
through the first quarter of 1971. Finally, demands for liquidity may
also have been enhanced by prevailing uncertainties about the domestic economic and employment outlook and international financial
conditions.
The increased demand for liquidity was also reflected in public acquisition of thrift-type deposits at financial institutions. Such demands were reflected in the two broader measures of the money
stock, which grew even faster than M j during the first half of 1971.
I n addition to the general demand for liquidity—and the high rate of
consumer saving—the sharp growth in thrift accounts represented a
continuation of the expansion in such deposits that had been triggered by the drop in market rates of interest during the latter half of
1970. Since average rates paid on thrift accounts declined only a lit-

12. M O N E T A R Y AGGREGATES
Growth in 1971
PER CENT

02
1

M

04

02

l

04

02
m

^
MEASURES

OF

MONEY

04
3

02
|

04

ADJUSTED
CREDIT

PROXY

M i : C u r r e n c y h e l d outside the T r e a s u r y , F . R . Banks, a n d the vaults o f all c o m m e r c i a l
banks, plus d e m a n d deposits o t h e r than interbank and U.S. G o v e r n m e n t .
My. M\ p l u s t i m e d e p o s i t s at c o m m e r c i a l b a n k s o t h e r t h a n l a r g e c e r t i f i c a t e s o f d e p o s i t .
Ms:
M'i p l u s d e p o s i t s o f m u t u a l s a v i n g s b a n k s a n d savings a n d l o a n shares.
A d j u s t e d c r e d i t p r o x y : T o t a l m e m b e r b a n k d e p o s i t s s u b j e c t t o reserves, p l u s E u r o - d o l l a r
b o r r o w i n g s , b a n k - r e l a t e d c o m m e r c i a l paper, and certain other nondeposit items.
N O T E . — Q u a r t e r l y r a t e s o f g r o w t h d e r i v e d f r o m d a i l y - a v e r a g e d a t a f o r last m o n t h o f t h e
quarter relative to t h a t f o r last m o n t h of preceding quarter.

34



tie despite the rapid fall in market rates, the relative attractiveness of
interest-bearing accounts to savers increased dramatically. Although
the process of rcintermediation was particularly sharp in the first
quarter, both M 2 and Ms continued to grow faster than Mx during all
of 1971.
Measures of growth in bank credit, which had remained relatively
strong during the auto-strike period of late 1970, showed substantially less variation in 1971 than did the various measures of money.
This relative stability was attributable in the main to trade-offs that
developed in the sources of funds being tapped by banks. In particular, banks reduced their reliance on high-cost Euro-dollar borrowing,
which dropped by more than $7 billion during the first half of
1971, as demand balances and time and savings deposits—including negotiable CD's—rose sharply. 1
The further decline in interest rates early in 1971 reflected a combination of persistent weakness in the economy, substantial reservesupplying operations by the Federal Reserve System, and widespread
expectations that the lower level of day-to-day money market rates
would continue. As conditions in securities markets eased, the Federal Reserve discount rate was cut successively from 5Vi per cent in
early January to 43A per cent in mid-February. In several stages
too, commercial banks adjusted their prime loan rate in relation to
market rates—from 6 p e r cent in late 1970 to 514 per cent in
March.
In early February the first of a series of sudden shifts in market
expectations led to a marked, but temporary, back-up in long-term
market yields. In this case, a combination of influences—including
the arrival of somewhat better business news and evidence that the
forward calendars of new corporate and municipal debt offerings
were expanding—created a market consensus that the cyclical decline in rates had run its course. Because the Treasury was engaged
1
Some of the reduced borrowing of U.S. banks f r o m their branches reflected the transfer of funds to foreign branches to acquire special ExportImport Bank and U.S. Treasury securities. These special securities were
designed to provide an investment outlet for branch Euro-dollar funds in
order to reduce incentives to return funds to the Euro-dollar market. Such
repayments to the market would have added to dollar holdings of foreign
official accounts, complicating the U.S. balance of payments problem. These
special issues began in January, reached a high of $3.2 billion in August, and
were completely retired by October.




35

13. B A N K FUNDS
Major Sources in 1971
B I L L I O N S OF DOLLARS

wmmmmjmmmmmm^mmmmmmqmmmmmmm^m^^^^^^^mmiqmmmmmmm^mmmmmmt^^mimmmmYmmm^m— |
D
J
F
M
A
M
J
J
A
S
O
N
D
N O T E . — T i m e a n d savings d e p o s i t s o t h e r t h a n l a r g e certificates o f d e p o s i t a n d p r i v a t e
d e m a n d d e p o s i t s are f o r a l l c o m m e r c i a l b a n k s . T i m e a n d savings deposits o t h e r t h a n l a r g e
C D ' s e x c l u d e those d u e t o d o m e s t i c c o m m e r c i a l b a n k s a n d t o the U . S . G o v e r n m e n t as w e l l
as b a l a n c e s a c c u m u l a t e d f o r r e p a y m e n t o f p e r s o n a l l o a n s . L a r g e C D ' s are n e g o t i a b l e C D ' s
issued i n d e n o m i n a t i o n s o f $100,000 o r m o r e b y m a j o r c o m m e r c i a l b a n k s . U . S . G o v e r n m e n t
d e p o s i t s a n d n o n d e p o s i t sources o f f u n d s d a t a are f o r m e m b e r b a n k s o n l y .

in a large debt refinancing and a pre-refunding at the time, the market was especially sensitive. Later, when it became apparent that
money market conditions were continuing to ease and that the basic
strength of the economy was subject to question—once allowance
had been made for the auto-strike catch-up—long-term rates declined again, notwithstanding the heavy volume of capital market
financing. This further decline was abetted by large Federal Reserve
purchases of longer-maturity Treasury securities.
After mid-March, however, both short- and long-term rates began
a sustained uptrend that extended to midsummer and again raised

36



|

|

rates generally to levels above those of late 1970. A number of factors contributed to this over-all advance. One was the stronger-thananticipated demands for borrowing; in particular, capital market
financing by businesses and State and local governments became
larger and more sustained than had earlier seemed likely. A t the
same time U.S. Treasury borrowing remained large, and estimates of
the volume of financing to be undertaken by the U.S. Government in
the second half of the year expanded as the year progressed.
During the spring of 1971 the Federal Reserve, in an effort to
slow the continued rapid growth of the monetary aggregates, began
to supply reserves less aggressively and thus contributed to a tightening of money market conditions. The accelerated rate of growth in
the monetary aggregates in the first quarter offset the relatively sluggish growth of the preceding quarter and supported the poststrike
catch-up in current-dollar GNP. But persistence of such rapid
growth rates into the spring raised questions in the minds of some
observers as to the prospects both for success in controlling domestic
inflation and for the future course of monetary policy.
Over the second quarter, the gradual tightening of money market
conditions tended to accentuate the upward pressures on interest
rates being exerted by other factors. In an effort to promote accommodative conditions in longer-term markets, the System supplied reserves to the extent feasible through purchases of Treasury issues
maturing in more than a year.
Market rates, particularly short-term rates, were also influencing,
and were being influenced by, international flows of liquid or speculative funds during this period. The marked further widening of
spreads between U.S. and foreign interest rates that had developed in
early 1971 appeared to be encouraging an increase in capital outflows over and above the large repayments of Euro-dollar borrowing
by major banks. With deterioration of the trade balance also contributing to a marked over-all worsening in the U.S. balance of payments, large dollar outflows in anticipation of possible adjustments in
exchange rates began to develop during April. Although these outflows subsided temporarily after several key European currencies
were allowed to float or were revalued upward in May, uncertainties
about the international monetary outlook persisted.
Around midyear the pace of the general advance in interest rates




37

seemed about to quicken. A t that time deepening concern about the
state of the U.S. trade balance appeared to be threatening a resurgence of speculative dollar outflows on an even larger scale than in
April. This trend, together with the continued active expansion of
the monetary aggregates and growing frustrations about the stubborn
persistence of wage and price pressures, seemed to presage an immediate further firming of money market conditions.
This market expectation was strengthened by an increase in the
discount rate in July by Vi of a percentage point to 5 per cent. With
the period of heavy deficit financing by the Treasury just getting
under way, and with long-term rates remaining high in an environment marked by disappointment about the progress being made to
curb inflation under prevailing policies, further general rate increases
were beginning to seem inevitable.
LATER DEVELOPMENTS
Once the President had announced his new economic policies, however, interest rates reversed course. The ensuing downtrend reflected,
in large part, the diminution of inflationary expectations resulting
from the institution of wage-price controls. This, together with the
new measures to improve the balance of payments and the functioning of international exchange markets, also led market participants to
modify their earlier view that monetary policy would have to seek
more restrictive money market conditions.
Treasury bill yields had declined somewhat even before the President's new policies were announced, and after the announcement
they dropped faster than other market rates of interest. The decline
in bill yields in July reflected the relative ease with which the Treasury had met its first large financing needs of the new fiscal year. Purchases of Treasury bills by foreign official accounts contributed to
the easing of conditions in the bill market after midyear as foreign
official institutions were acquiring dollars in support of their own
currencies as speculation against the dollar mounted.
Dollar outflows continued at a high rate following the general floating of exchange rates in mid-August, and foreign official demand for
U.S. Government securities remained strong. A t the same time, the
supply of new bill offerings in the market was substantially less than
had previously been anticipated because acquisitions of special issues

38



by foreign central banks had reduced the need for other Treasury
borrowing. Altogether, foreign and Federal Reserve acquisitions of
Treasury debt during the third quarter totaled about $12 billion; this
compared with Federal net cash borrowing of about $9 billion during the period.
Other market rates of interest also fell after the President's announcement. By the end of October short-term yields—other than
those on bills—had declined by 50 to 75 basis points from their levels in mid-August, 90-day bills were off 90 basis points, 1-year bills
had fallen 140 basis points, and some long-term yields were lower
by about a full percentage point. The bank prime rate, which had
been raised in two steps from 5 % per cent in March to 6 per cent in
July, began to decline in October. In that month a few large banks
announced that they would henceforth follow a more flexible primerate policy—adjusting their quoted rates automatically to changes in
short-term market rates of interest. While most banks continued to
set their prime rate administratively, the prime rate did decline in a
series of frequent, small changes from 6 per cent in July to 5 % by
the year-end.
The general decline in market rates of interest that had begun in
August was temporarily interrupted in November by congestion in
the securities market that was associated with uncertainties about
Phase I I of the President's program and the apparent stalemate in
international monetary negotiations at the time of a large Treasury
refinancing and pre-refunding. By early December, however, market
sentiment had improved and sizable Federal Reserve purchases of
Treasury coupon issues greatly reduced dealers' excess inventories.
In November and December the discount rate was lowered in two
stages from 5 to 4Vi per cent and around the turn of the year both
short- and long-term interest rates dropped sharply further as the
Federal Reserve System moved in a more aggressive way to supply
reserves and as liquidation of short-term Treasury debt by foreign
central banks failed to materialize in the volume anticipated. By late
January 1972, the bank prime rate had been cut further to a general
level of 43A per cent, and at a few large banks to 4 Vi per cent—in
the latter case, the level for the period 1960 through late 1965.
Although interest rates declined following the President's mid-August change in economic policy, growth in M , slowed appreciably.




39

The initial phase of the slowdown appeared to be associated with the
increased outflow of dollars during August. Speculators and hedgers
had sought to profit from, or protect themselves against, the expected
rise in value of foreign currencies relative to the dollar. Some domestic holdings of dollar balances were drawn down in the process, but
the bulk of the outflow was probably financed in other ways. For example, both domestic and foreign demands for loans at U.S. banks
increased sharply in August, and the proceeds of many of these
loans were used to prepay liabilities in foreign currencies or to acquire foreign currencies for future payment or to profit from future
revaluations.
The public's demand for money in the late summer and early fall
remained lower relative to income than it had been in preceding
months. In this period the public may have shifted out of cash balances built up earlier for precautionary reasons and into market securities in an effort to capture peak yields, in view of the widespread
expectations that the new economic program would lead to lower interest rates. I n addition, improved public confidence in both the
domestic and the international economic outlook probably reduced
the demand for liquidity. Finally, the increases in interest rates during the spring and early summer had made it cost more to hold
money, and this earlier rise in rates continued into the fall to affect
the demand for money.
By the third quarter the higher level of interest rates had already
contributed to a significant slowing of the growth in consumer-type
time and savings deposits at banks, despite a reversal of the scattered
rate cuts that had been instituted at a number of major institutions
in the spring. Inflows also had slowed at nonbank thrift institutions
—but to a lesser degree inasmuch as these institutions still paid
higher rates on deposits than banks did and fewer of them had reduced offering rates in the spring. With savings inflows thus more
moderate, growth of M., and M 3 decelerated, although not so sharply
as M , .
Growth in bank credit—as measured by the adjusted credit proxy
—did not fall off nearly so much in the third quarter as the money
stock aggregates. Cutbacks in the expansion of private demand and
consumer-type time deposits at banks were generally offset by an expansion in large negotiable CD's (many of which were taken by for-

40




eign accounts), by increases in U.S. Government deposits (arising
from the large foreign official purchases of special Treasury certificates), and by a virtual cessation of U.S. bank repayments of Eurodollar borrowings to their foreign branches.
Similarly, in the fourth quarter, even though Mr expanded at an
annual rate of only 1 per cent, the credit proxy rose at close to a 10
per cent annual rate, or a little faster than in the third quarter. This
fourth-quarter expansion reflected a sharp acceleration in time and
savings deposits other than CD's to a 15 per cent annual rate; as a
result M-, in this period accelerated to an 8 per cent rate of growth,
despite the slow growth in Mx.
Over 1971 as a whole, the monetary aggregates expanded substantially. While growth in M t was sluggish in the latter part of the
year, it had been very rapid earlier in the period. Broader measures of
the money stock grew considerably faster than W, and contributed to
greater public liquidity, while credit from banks and other financial
institutions remained ample throughout the year. By the year-end
most interest rates were at or near their lows for the year. Rates in
short-term markets had declined quite sharply as monetary policy
was directed toward promoting the degree of ease in bank reserves
that would lead the monetary aggregates to grow at a rate sufficient
•
to support accelerated economic recovery.




41




Total Credit Flows and the
Financing of Private
Investment
The net flow of credit through domestic markets was at an unprecedented rate in 1971, both in dollar amounts and in relation to economic activity. Net funds reached a total of $151 billion, about 50
per cent more than in any previous year. The total was 14 per cent
of GNP, well above the 1968 high of 11 per cent and the 10 per
cent average for the 1960's.
This record volume of credit consisted mainly of a combination of
heavy Federal borrowing to cover the year's deficit, a volume of private financing that was large relative to capital outlays, and State
and local government borrowing well in excess of fiscal needs. Foreign borrowing in U.S. markets was also sharply higher than in 1970
and earlier years, but it remained a small part of the total.
SOURCES OF CREDIT SUPPLY
The financing of such large credit flows was accomplished with market interest rates declining somewhat over the year, although sizable
fluctuations in such rates occurred during the year. Rates in shortterm markets were unusually low relative to long-term rates—such
as those for mortgages and corporate bonds—and savings institutions
that lend predominantly in long-term markets offered yields on deposits that were very attractive relative to money market rates. In
view of this rate advantage, time and savings deposits grew by an
unprecedented 17 per cent in 1971, and these institutions were a
dominant source of funds to credit markets.
A n important element in short-term markets and in the forms of
credit flow in 1971 was the very large volume of U.S. Government
securities purchased by foreign official reserve holders; sizable acquisitions of Treasury bills by foreign central banks accounted in
part for the decline in the Treasury bill rate relative to other market
rates. During the year these institutions bought $27 billion of U.S.




43

Government securities, more than total Treasury borrowing; over the
same period domestic private holdings of Treasury issues decreased.
I n the absence of these outflows, private investment in U.S. markets
would have been larger and foreign official acquisitions of U.S.
Treasury securities smaller.
Purchases by foreign official accounts were the counterpart of the
weak current-account position in the U.S. balance of payments and
the large volume of private capital outflows. The capital outflows
took a variety of forms, such as bank repayment of foreign borrowings, loans to foreign borrowers, and liquidation of dollar assets held
by private foreigners. Some of the borrowing, both foreign and domestic, shown in Table 7 reflects the strong demand for foreign exchange, but there is a great deal of uncertainty as to the form of
much of the outflow.
The relation of foreign inflows to U.S. credit markets is indicated
in Table 8, where the sharp increase from 1970 in U.S. Government
borrowing is more than offset by larger foreign purchases. Private
domestic lending in credit markets increased less sharply than total
borrowing, and all of the domestic credit supply was in the form of
private loans and securities.
Although private domestic lending increased less, proportionately,
than total borrowing from 1970 (Table 8), the $112 billion flow
from the private sector was sharply higher in relation to activity and
income than in any other year of the preceding two decades. Moreover, the flow originated entirely in banks and nonbank financial inTable 7: FUNDS RAISED I N CREDIT MARKETS BY N O N F I N A N C I A L
SECTORS
Percentage o f G N P

Amount
Sector

Total

1

I n billions o f dollars
1970

1971

Percentage
change,
1970 to
1971

97.5
12.8
12.2
2.6

151.1
25.5
18.7
5.4

55.0
99.2
53.3
107.6

10.1
.9
1.1
.3

14.4
2.4
1.8
.5

69.9

101.5

45.2

7.8

9.7

196670 avg.

1971

Households a n d n o n f i n a n c i a l busi-

1

I n c l u d e s n e t issues o f c o r p o r a t e equities.

44



Table 8: T O T A L FUNDS RAISED A N D P R I V A T E DOMESTIC CREDIT
SUPPLY
Amount
(in b i l l i o n s o f dollars)
Sector, or supplier
1969
A. Funds raised in credit markets by nonfinancial sectors .
B. U.S. G o v e r n m e n t
C. Other 1
Funds supplied directly b y :
Foreign
Public agencies, n e t 2

D.
E.
F.
G.
H.

Private domestic lenders ( A — D — E)
T o : U.S. Government
Other

I.
J.
K.
L.

By: Commercial banks
Savings institutions
Other finance
Nonfinancial investors

3

1970

1971

Percentage
change,
1970 t o
1971

90.4
-3.6
93.9

97.5
12.8
84.7

151.1
25.5
125.6

55.0
99.2
48.3

1.3
6.9

10.9
9.4

28.4
11.0

160.6
17.0

82.2
4.6
77.6

77.2
5.8
71.4

111.7
-6.0
117.7

44.7
-203.4
64.8

12.2
10.4
19.7
39.8

31.3
14.7
24.2
7.1

47.5
40.8
27.9
-4.5

51.8
177.6
15.3
-163.4

1

I n c l u d e s c o r p o r a t e equities.
- U . S . G o v e r n m e n t , f e d e r a l l y sponsored c r e d i t agencies, a n d f e d e r a l
o f security issues by sponsored agencies.
1
H o u s e h o l d s , n o n f i n a n c i a l business, a n d State a n d l o c a l g o v e r n m e n t s .

Reserve System. N e t

stitutions; nonfinancial investors liquidated holdings of credit market
instruments, net, over the year. The extent to which the domestic
credit supply was intermediated was as unprecedented as the size of
the flow for a period as long as a year, and it indicated the yield advantage of deposits over money market instruments as liquidity holdings during the period.
As indicated earlier in this report, the flow into time and savings
accounts supplied an unusually large volume of funds to lenders who
specialize in mortgage credit. Thus, it provided a strong financial
base for the high and rising rate of housing construction, which continued through the year, and also for some forms of business investment. Savings institutions were the source of 60 per cent of total
mortgage funds supplied in 1971, a higher proportion than in the
1961-65 period of rapid deposit growth, and mutual savings banks
also bought one-fifth of the net new corporate bond issues, and savings and loan associations repaid borrowings from the Federal home
loan banks. Commercial banks were also substantial lenders in mortgage markets, with loans on real estate absorbing a fourth of total
bank credit flows.




45

PRIVATE DOMESTIC FINANCING
Funds raised by households and nonfinancial business in credit and
equity markets were far larger than would have been expected, based
on past relationships to private saving or capital investment. Both
net residential mortgage financing and business credit flows were up
sharply from recent years in relation to capital spending (Table 9 ) ,
and the ratios for both types of financing were well above those for
any other year of either the 1950's or the 1960's. During the 1960's
total external financing by households and business had stayed within
a fairly narrow range of 31 to 34 per cent of total capital outlays on
an annual basis, in spite of wide variations in credit conditions and
in the relation between saving and capital spending. The 41 per cent
relationship in 1971 is a sharp departure from this experience.
The upward pace of residential mortgage flows in 1971 accompanied a sharp upsurge in outlays for construction of both single-family
and multifamily housing units. However, not all of the increase in
net flows of such credit reflected new lending to finance the record
Table 9: E X T E R N A L F I N A N C I N G BY HOUSEHOLDS A N D
N O N F I N A N C I A L BUSINESS
Amount
(in bi lions o f dc)llars)
Item
1966-70
avg.
NET FUNDS RAISED:
A . Residential mortgages
B.
Percentage of residential
C.
D.
E.
F.
G.

construction

1

C o r p o r a t e equities
C o r p o r a t e bonds 1
Business loans a n d nonresidential mortgages
T o t a l nonresidential business
Percentage of nonresidential
business capital

H . O t h e r external financing 2
I . T o t a l external financing
J.
Percentage of total capital

outlays

expenditure

3

CAPITAL OUTLAYS:
K . Residential c o n s t r u c t i o n
L . N o n r e s i d e n t i a l business p l a n t a n d equipment outlays
a n d net i n v e n t o r y change
M . C o n s u m e r durable goods a n d n o n p r o f i t - i n s t i t u t i o n plant
and equipment
N.

Total

Percentage
change,
1970
to
1971

1970

1971

17.5
61

18.7
62

33.8
83

80.7

2.7
14.0
20.7
37.4
40

6.8
20.3
14.9
42.0
43

13.5
18.3
19.6
51.4
50

98.5
-9.9
31.5
22.4

12.5
67.4
33

9.2
69.9
32

16.4
101.5
41

78.3
45.2

33.6

28.5

30.4

40.6

92.7

97.6

103.1

5.6

86.1

93.9

105.8

12.7

207.3

221.9

249.5

12.4

1

Nonfinancial corporations only.
- C o n s u m e r c r e d i t , p o l i c y loans, a n d b o r r o w i n g b y n o n p r o f i t i n s t i t u t i o n s .
C a p i t a l o u t l a y s i n c l u d e those f o r consumer d u r a b l e goods and n o n p r o f i t - i n s t i t u t i o n
and equipment.

46




plant

pace of construction. Much of it derived from borrowing on existing
houses, following an extended period in 1969 and 1970 when transactions in older houses were particularly difficult to finance because
of the limited availability and exceptionally high cost of mortgage
credit.
The increase in business financing was dominated by corporate
equities, which supplied almost one-fourth of net new funds for nonfinancial business. Beginning in 1966, the gross flow of new equity
capital had risen steadily and rapidly from a $3 billion annual rate
in the first half of the 1960's to $13.5 billion in 1971; the growth in
such offerings not only compensated to some extent for the relative
decrease in retained earnings as a source of corporate funds but also
helped to slow the growth in debt ratios. Through some of this period the growth of new offerings was offset by sizable retirements of
equities in mergers. But more recently these retirements have fallen
off sharply—from a 1968 rate of $7 billion to less than $1 billion in
1971—and net equity funds available to business have risen even
more sharply than gross offerings. As in recent years, most of the net
funds supplied to corporations through equities in 1971 came from
pension funds and life insurance companies, which together increased
their purchases over the 1970 total by almost as much as the rise in
net issues.
Net new bond issues were close to the very high rate established
in 1970—reflecting the continued strong demand by corporations for
long-term credit even though interest rates on bonds remained relatively high. One-fifth of this net flow represented purchases by mutual savings banks; life insurance companies increased their net buying sharply, but purchases by individuals were significantly reduced
from the very high 1970 levels. Commercial mortgages, another form
of long-term credit, increased from a net flow of $5 billion in 1970
to $9 billion in 1971; almost all of the increase represented loans
from commercial banks and savings institutions.
The net amount of new long-term financing through equities,
bonds, and commercial mortgages accounted for a dominant part—
80 per cent—of the total funds raised by business in 1971. These
long-term funds reduced sharply the importance of short-term credit
in business debt structures and brought short-term debt ratios back
to their pre-1969-70 levels. Business loans at banks grew moderately
during 1971—except in the third quarter when international devel-




47

Table 10: P R I V A T E DOMESTIC SAVING A N D
Amount

Relative to G N P

I n billions o f dollars
Item
1970

1971

INVESTMENT

Per cent
Percentage
change,
1970 to
1971

1966-70
avg.

1971

Change
(percentage
points),
1966-70
avg. to
1971

Households and nonfinancial business:
A . Gross saving

245.5

276.4

12.6

25.5

26.4

.9

B. C a p i t a l expenditures
C. Less: External financing
D . Equals: Internal financing (B — C ) .

222.0
69.9
152.1

249.5
101.5
148.0

12.4
45.2
-2.7

24.1
7.8
16.3

23.8
9.7
14.1

-.3
1.9
-2.2

E. N e t financial uses o f f u n d s ( A — D ) . .

93.4

128.4

37.5

9.2

12.3

3.1

State and local governments:
F. N e t current surplus
G . External financing
H . N e t financial uses o f f u n d s ( F + G )

-6.0
12.2
6.2

-4.0
18.7
14.7

-33.3
53.3
137.1

-.5
1.1
.5

-.3
1.8
1.4

.2
.7
.9

Private financial investment:
I. T o t a l net financial uses of funds
(E + H)
J.
C u r r e n c y a n d deposits
K.
Credit market instruments
L.
O t h e r , net

99.6
61.1
7.1
31.4

143.1
93.0
-4.5
54.6

43.7
52.2
-163.4
73.9

9.7
4.4
1.8
3.5

13.6
8.9
-.4
5.2

3.9
4.5
-2.2
1.7

opments generated a temporary surge in loans. There was very little
growth in commercial paper or in loans from nonbank financial institutions.
SAVING AND INVESTMENT
The high rates of external financing by households and business in
1971 relative to capital outlays were matched, for the group as a
whole, by comparably large flows into financial assets. Private saving increased by a somewhat larger amount than capital expenditures
from 1970, but cach continued to have approximately the same relation to GNP as the average for 1966-70 (Table 10). Because the increase in external financing was larger in absolute amount than the
increase in outlays, financial uses of funds rose to an unprecedented
46 per cent of gross private saving, as compared with an average of
36 per cent for 1966-70.
State and local government financing was also very large in 1971
relative to the total need for funds. Municipal borrowing had picked
up sharply after mid-1970, when commercial banks increased their

48




purchases of tax-exempt securities, and by the end of 1970 the liquidity of State and local governments had recovered from a low position at the beginning of the year to a level that was more normal in
relation to expenditures. Early in 1971, however, net issues of municipal securities increased even further. Banks were able to absorb
most of the increase in offerings during the year, and there was little
incremental buying of such securities by nonfinancial investors.
With households, businesses, and State and local governments all
active during the year both as borrowers and as lenders, their total
financial uses of funds increased sharply from 1970 in dollar amount
and to a new high level in relation to GNP. Of total financial uses,
the flow into money, time deposits, and savings accounts was about
65 per cent—a higher proportion than for 1970 and also above the
1961-65 average, when institutional flows were also a large component of total credit flows.
Direct purchases of credit market instruments by private domestic
investors were negative in 1971, as was mentioned earlier. "Other"
financial uses of funds, however, were extremely large. These "other"
uses are to some extent unidentified in the statistics, and they probably include part of the private capital outflows to foreign countries,
both recorded and unrecorded, which rose to such large proportions
in 1971. Capital outflows were an important counterpart of foreign
official purchases of Treasury securities during the year.
LIQUID ASSETS
The total liquid asset position of the domestic private nonfinancial
economy increased slightly during 1971 as a result of the unusual
size and structure of flows. On the basis of a simple measure of liquid assets—holdings of money, time and savings accounts, U.S.
Treasury and agency securities, and commercial paper—the 1971
year-end total was slightly more than 83 per cent of GNP (Table
11). This represents a departure from a narrow range of 82 to 83
per cent of GNP, a level that has been maintained for well over a
decade, except in the two tight-credit periods of 1966 and 1969.
The deposit component of liquid assets rose sharply as a result of
institutional flows in 1971 and reached a level well above preceding
peaks. This rise was partly offset, however, by the decrease in holdings of Government securities and of commercial paper.




49

Table 11: P R I V A T E L I Q U I D ASSET HOLDINGS
End-of-year figures as a percentage o f f o u r t h - q u a r t e r G N P , seasonally adjusted annual rate

Year

Total

Currency
and deposits

U.S. G o v t ,
securities 1

Commercial
paper

1959

82.0

59.7

22.1

.2

1965
1966
1967
1968
1969

82.8
80.6
82.5
82.4
80.4

66.3
64.0
66.9
66.7
63.2

15.6
15.5
14.4
14.1
14.8

.9
1.1
1.2
1.6
2.4

1970
1971

82.5
83.3

66.8
70.2

13.5
11.2

2.1
2.0

1

I n c l u d e s F e d e r a l agency issues.

This measure of liquid assets probably understates to some extent
the 1971 position of private holders. As mentioned earlier, "other"
financial uses of funds by this group undoubtedly included part of
the unrecorded private capital flows that occurred in 1971. Insofar
as those funds were placed abroad in liquid forms for higher yields
and/or to await readjustments in exchange rates, they are statistically a missing component of private liquidity; they will appear in
the totals whenever they are returned to U.S. markets.
If allowance is made for unknown assets held abroad, it is probable that the large scale of private borrowing and lending during 1971
was sufficient to lift liquidity holdings of the nonfinancial economy
even further out of the narrow range of recent years. The heavy emphasis by business on long-term financing also reduced sharply the
position of short-term debt in business capital structures. Both of
these developments have put the private economy in a favorable
position for further growth of activity.
•

50




U.S. Balance of Payments
During 1971 it became evident that the balances of both current and
capital transactions between the United States and the rest of the
world had worsened to such an extent that conventional changes in
monetary or fiscal policies here or abroad could not be expected to
reverse the trend. I n fact, the cyclical situation was adverse for the
balance of payments because demand in the United States was
strengthening whereas in most major foreign countries—where resource utilization was still relatively high—the pace of economic
advance was slowing.
The international monetary scene in the first half of the year was
dominated by huge flows of funds to Germany, as that country continued to pursue a relatively tight monetary policy, while the revaluation of the mark in 1969 did not appear to have diminished Germany's strong trade surplus. By A p r i l these flows reflected market
expectations that the mark would be revalued, and on May 10 the
German authorities allowed the mark to float; at the same time the
14. U.S. B A L A N C E OF P A Y M E N T S
SEASONALLY ADJUSTED A N N U A L RATES
BILLIONS OF DOLLARS

S E A S O N A L L Y AOJUSTED A N N U A L RATES
B I L L I O N S OF D O L L A R S

I 60

Excludes S D R

allocations.




51

Netherlands guilder was allowed to float and Switzerland and Austria
revalued their currencies.
For a brief period thereafter there was a partial reversal of speculative flows and some relaxation of tensions in international markets,
but as evidence of the deepening troubles of the U.S. balance of payments mounted, another and much more massive flow of funds got
under way. Demands for the currencies of most other industrial
countries built up, and foreign official reserve accruals accelerated.
By the end of July U.S. liabilities to foreign official accounts stood at
$37 billion, compared with $24 billion at the end of 1970; meanwhile, U.S. reserve assets had fallen from $14.5 billion to $13.3 billion. In the first 2 weeks of August reserve liabilities grew by about
$4.5 billion, while reserve assets were reduced by $1.2 billion. Reductions in reserves occurred mainly in connection with repayments
by other countries to the International Monetary Fund. Moreover, the
United States made large drawings on swap lines with some countries
that were accumulating large holdings of liquid dollar assets.
MEASURES OF AUGUST 15
The external measures announced on August 15 as part of the new
economic program represented an effort by the United States to exercise an initiative to restore, via a change in the exchange rate for the
dollar, the country's competitive position in world trade, to obtain an
easing of restrictive trading arrangements, and to arrange for a more
equitable sharing of mutual defense expenditures. As a first step to
effect these changes, the U.S. Government suspended the convertibility of dollars held in foreign official reserves into gold and other reserve assets. Other actions taken—imposition of a temporary 10 per
cent surcharge on dutiable imports and the limitation of tax relief for
capital expenditures to domestically produced capital goods—were
intended to emphasize the seriousness with which the U.S. Government viewed the need for exchange rate adjustments. These measures
were eliminated once agreement on such adjustments was reached in
the meetings held in Washington on December 17 and 18.
In the period between August 15 and the weekend of December
17 and 18 the currencies of other industrial countries were allowed
to float above their previous parities. In most cases, however, the extent of the appreciations of these currencies was limited by official

52




intervention in the market or by various measures intended to limit
inflows of speculative and interest-sensitive funds. In that period the
outflow of funds from the United States (reflecting not only flows of
liquid funds but also leads and lags in payments of all kinds) was
again very great, and liabilities to foreign official accounts rose by almost $12 billion. Japan was the principal recipient, as that country
was reluctant to accept at an early stage the major revaluation that
was generally expected.
As negotiations toward a realignment of exchange rates proceeded,
the extent of the change in the U.S. balance of payments that was
required came to be better understood, though it was actively debated. In particular, the U.S. trade balance had clearly tended to deteriorate more rapidly in recent years than could be accounted for by
changes in general demand conditions here and abroad. By 1972 the
trade balance could be expected to register a deficit substantially
larger than that already in prospect for 1971. It also seemed clear
that, in the absence of major adjustments of exchange rates, the balance on current and long-term capital transactions would be headed
for a deficit even larger than in 1971, whereas a surplus of some size
for these transactions would be necessary to produce a satisfactory
balance on official settlements.
MERCHANDISE TRADE
The U.S. trade balance in 1971 dropped to a deficit of nearly $3 billion compared with a surplus of $2 billion in 1970 (Table 12). The
trade deficit stemmed from a very weak showing in exports, which
were only slightly higher in value than in 1970, while imports advanced sharply—by about 15 per cent. Part of the difference reflected a somewhat larger increase in import prices than in export
prices.
On the export side, increases in sales of agricultural commodities,
in sales of automotive vehicles and parts to Canada, and in deliveries
of commercial aircraft were just about offset by declines in shipments of machinery and industrial materials. The declines in these
exports were attributable mainly to the easing of demand in foreign
industrial countries. In volume terms, exports as a whole were
slightly lower in 1971 than in the previous year.
The gains in imports in 1971 were broadly based, with all major




53

Table 12: U.S. I N T E R N A T I O N A L TRANSACTIONS
I n b i l l i o n s o f dollars, seasonally adjusted

1971
Item

1970

1971 »
I

M e r c h a n d i s e trade balance
Exports
Imports
Services, remittances, pensions, net
U . S . G o v t , grants a n d credits, net
L o n g - t e r m p r i v a t e capital, net
Balance on current
capital

account

and

Of which: L i a b i l i t i e s t o f o r e i g n c o m m e r c i a l
banks
1

III

IV P

2.1
42.0
39.9

-2.9
42.8
45.7

.3
11.0
10.8

-1.1
10.7
11.8

-.6
11.5
12.0

-1.5
9.6
11.1

.1
-3.8
-1.5

1.4
-4.2
-5.1

.6
-1.1
-1.0

.7
- 1.1
-1.8

.2
-1.1
-1.7

-.1
-1.0
-.5

-3.0

-10.9

-1.3

-3.2

-3.2

-3.2

-.5
-1.1
-6.0

-2.8
-9.3
-7.2

-.4
-1.0
-3.0

-.4
-2.3
.1

-1.2
-5.1
-2.8

-.9
-.8
-1.5

long-term

N o n l i q u i d short-term private capital
E r r o r s a n d omissions
L i q u i d private capital

O f f i c i a l settlements balance

II

-6.5

-6.6

-3.1

-.1

-2.1

-1.3

-10.7

-30.3

-5.7

-5.9

-12.3

-6.4

p F o u r t h - q u a r t e r d a t a are p a r t l y e s t i m a t e d .
Excludes S D R allocations.
N O T E . — D e p t . o f C o m m e r c e d a t a , w i t h some F e d e r a l Reserve estimates. D e t a i l s m a y
a d d t o t o t a l s because o f r o u n d i n g .
1

not

categories of goods—foods, industrial materials, capital equipment,
automobiles, and other consumer goods—increasing over 1970 levels. The greatest increase was in imports of autos, especially from
Japan. Despite this increase, sales of imported autos other than those
from Canada accounted for about the same share of total U.S. sales
of autos as they had in 1970—about 15 per cent of the number of
vehicles— but this was a much higher share than the 10 per cent average for 1967-69.
A rise in prices of foreign goods accounted for about one-third of
the increase in the value of imports in 1971, whereas in 1970 nearly
two-thirds of the increase in imports had stemmed from price increases—as measured by unit values.
Trade movements in 1971 were greatly affected at times by such
factors as actual or anticipated domestic strikes (mainly in port operations, steel, aluminum, and coal), anticipation that "voluntary"
controls would be imposed by foreign governments on their industries' sales to the United States, and the increasing possibility of
changes in currency values. Therefore it is difficult to determine how

54



15. I N D U S T R I A L P R O D U C T I O N

160

150

140

130

120

0
1969

1971

NOTE.—Seasonally a d j u s t e d q u a r t e r l y d a t a f r o m the O r g a n i z a t i o n f o r E c o n o m i c
t i o n a n d D e v e l o p m e n t . D a t a f o r f o u r t h q u a r t e r o f 1971 p a r t l y e s t i m a t e d .

Coopera-

much of the 1971 deterioration in the U.S. trade position resulted
from these factors rather than from more enduring ones. In addition,
the deceleration in business activity abroad and the easing of supply
conditions in Europe and Japan were major causes for the downturn
in U.S. exports of machinery and industrial materials—and probably
also for the rise in imports, as foreign producers intensified their selling efforts in the United States. A t the same time, however, continued sluggishness in domestic economic activity held imports to levels
below what they would have been if output and consumption here
had been more buoyant.
The steady deterioration in the trade balance of recent years is expected to be slowed or arrested in 1972 as the recently announced
changes in exchange rates begin to shift competitive advantages.
However, it may take 2 or 3 years before rearrangements of production and consumption patterns both here and abroad will have
gone far enough to produce substantial improvement. In the short
run, the U.S. trade balance is likely to be affected mainly by general
business conditions, as economic activity in the United States gains
momentum while foreign economic activity may remain below opti-




55

mal levels. Under such conditions, foreign demand for U.S. products
will be blunted, even at relatively favorable prices, while foreign suppliers to the U.S. market may be inclined to accept lower profit
margins.
CAPITAL FLOWS
The net outflow of private capital from the United States—taking
into account both recorded and unrecorded elements—reached enormous proportions in 1971. For most of the year there were interest
rate incentives for U.S. investors and banks to add to assets abroad
or repay foreign borrowings and for foreigners to borrow dollars.
Outflows spurted at times when the market became convinced that
appreciations of foreign currencies were imminent. Larger-than-usual
outflows, or smaller inflows, of private capital were recorded in all
major categories.
Recorded outflows of U.S. private capital reached about $10 billion—some $3 billion larger than in 1970 and more than double the
average of the 1960's. Outflows for direct investment rose, reflecting
both a further increase in outlays for foreign production facilities and
an extension until the end of February 1972 of the requirement to
meet the ceilings for 1971 under the direct investment controls. Net
additions to foreign assets reported by U.S. banks rose sharply to
about $3 billion, as relatively higher interest rates abroad focused
demands for funds on the U.S. market. The exemption of export
credits from the voluntary ceilings toward the end of the year may
also have led to increased foreign lending. Foreign claims reported
by U.S. nonbank institutions also rose, but it is believed that many of
the transactions affecting the foreign assets of U.S. corporations and
of other investors other than banks were of types that are not captured by the statistical reporting system, and are therefore reflected
in the residual "errors and omissions" in the balance of payments accounts.
The recorded inflow of foreign private capital (apart from liquid
assets in U.S. banks) dropped sharply from $5 billion in 1970 to
only about $2 billion in 1971. Foreign investors had placed substantial amounts in U.S. direct investments and corporate stocks in 1970,
but under the pressures of exchange rate uncertainties and a weak
U.S. economic performance in 1971, such inflows ceased, and at

56




times there were sizable net outflows. Borrowing abroad by U.S. corporations to finance overseas direct investment or for other purposes
also diminished in 1971.
U.S. banks further reduced their borrowings from the Euro-dollar
market in 1971, as the increase in the cost of funds in that market
relative to costs in the United States outweighed the advantages of
retaining the reserve-free Euro-dollar borrowing bases established by
the Federal Reserve with a view to moderating the liquidation of
such borrowing. By the end of the year borrowings of U.S. banks
from their foreign branches as registered in the U.S. balance of payments accounts had dropped to $1.3 billion, a reduction of $5.0 billion for the year and $14.1 billion from the peak in October 1969.
U.S. Government securities that had been offered to the branches at
attractive rates earlier in the year in order to slow the pace of the
withdrawal of funds borrowed abroad were allowed to run off after
mid-August.
In addition to tHe net recorded outflow of U.S. and foreign private
capital in 1971—which aggregated about $15 billion—the unrecorded payments element in the U.S. international accounts rose to
more than $9 billion. The combined total of $24 billion was about
$15 billion greater than the comparable figure for 1970. Such unrecorded net outflows reached their peak in the period of hectic speculation preceding the August 15 measures taken by the United States.
YEAR-END PERSPECTIVE
As 1972 began, the events of 1971 clearly had set in motion strong
forces tending to restore equilibrium in the U.S. balance of payments. The exchange rate realignments achieved in December were
substantial, and they could be expected over time to move the trade
balance into a surplus position more in accord with the normal role
of the United States as a supplier of real resources to less wealthy
countries. Moreover, such a realignment of rates should also have favorable effects on capital transactions—reducing the incentives for
outflows of U.S. capital and restoring the basis for resumption of sizable inflows of foreign investment capital to the United States. In addition, impetus has been given to work on remodeling the structure
of the international monetary system—especially regarding the management of international reserves and the process for adjusting ex-




57

change rates—so that the system will be less crisis-prone and more
capable of making the timely adjustments required to avoid persistent deficit or surplus positions among countries.
There can be little doubt that the process of strengthening the
U.S. trade and payments balances will take considerable time. It will
probably be a year or more before there are clear signs that the necessary adjustments in basic transactions are taking place. Such adjustments are slow to develop even under the best of conditions, and
in 1972 they will probably be further delayed by a faster growth of
demand for goods and services in the United States than elsewhere.
Consequently, there should be no cause for undue concern if the
U.S. deficits are not quickly reversed. On the other hand, restoration
of a secure equilibrium will require the pursuit of active policies both
here and abroad to foster noninflationary economic growth and to
accommodate the necessary redistribution of trading surpluses and
deficits.
•

58




This material will appear as Part 1 of the Board's




ANNUAL

REPORT

for

1971.