The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.
U.S. DEPARTMENT OF LABOR JAMES J. DA VIS, Secretary BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS ETHELBERT STEWART, Commissioner • BULLETIN OF THE UNITED STATES} BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS • M I S C E L L A N E O U S · · · · · No. 380 SERIES POSTWAR LABOR CONDITIONS IN GERMANY https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis By R. R. KUCZYNSKI "(,a,~Nl'o;;: . .~·y~ ~ ~~o■~i ~AITEsof."' MARCH, 1925 WASHINGTON GOVERNMENT PRINTING OFFICE 1925 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ADDITIONAL COPIES or THIS PUBLICATION MAY BE PROCURED FROM THE SUPERINTENDENT OF DOCUMENTS GOVERNllENT PRINTING OFFICJ: WASmNGTON, D. C. AT 30 CENTS PER COPY CONTENTS Introduction______________________________________________________ !.-General survey_______________________________________ Population___________________________________________________ Occupation___________________________________________________ Pace Unemployment_____________________________________________ __ Standard of living and wages___________________________________ Labor movement______________________________________________ 11.-Standard and cost of living ______________________ :_____ CHAPTER Food ________________________________________________________ Housing ______ . ______________________________________________ Standard and supply before the war _______________ r--------Housing conditions during the war------------------------~Situation since the war ____________________________________ 7 7 7, 8 9-67 9-33 33-47 33-38 38, 39 39-47 light======.========================================= ~~fht~: _______________________________________________ Transportation !Z:iY CHAPTER 1 2-8 2 2-7 52-55 Taxes ________________________________________________________ 55-62 Minimum cost of subsistence ___________________________________ 62-67 CHAPTER 111.-Collective agreements _______________________________ 68-77 68 Legislation_________________________________________________ __ Actual development ___________________________________________ 69-72 Legal regulation ______________________________________________ 72-77 Definition ________________________________________________ 73-75 75 Policy of nondeviation__ ____ _ _ __ __ _ ______ __ _ __ __ __ __ _____ __ Agreements declared generally binding _______________________ 75-77 CHAPTER IV.-Trade-unions_ _ ___ __ _ __ _ ___ _ ___ __ __ __ __ __ __ __ __ __ ___ 78-93 Membership __________________________________________________ 80-84 Finances _____________________________________________________ 84,85 Internal organization __________________________________________ 85-87 ___ -------------------- _____________________ 87-90 Internal difficulties 90-93 policy ______________________________________________ Economic CHAPTER V.-Hours of labor ______________________________________ 94-124 Situation before December, 1923 _______________________________ 94-107 94-98 Legislation_______________________________________________ 98-104 Actual development ______________________________________ Opposition to eight-hour day _____________________________ 104-107 Situation since December, 1923 ______________________________ 107-120 Decree of December 2, 1923 ______________________________ 107-112 Scope of decree _____________________________________ 108,109 ~ngth of working day _______________________________ 109-112 113 Enforcement of decree_________________________________ 113 Hours of labor in hospitals_____________________________ Actual development_____________________________________ 114-120 Spare-time work____________________________________________ 120, 121 Vacations __________________________________________________ 121-124 CHAPTER_ VI.-Wages and efficiency of labor _______________________ 125-145 General trend of real wages___________________________________ 125-134 Piecework __________________________________________________ 134-141 Efficiencyof labor ___________________________________________ 141-145 CH.A'.PTER VIL-Unemployment_ ________________ -----~-------- ___ 146-189 Number of unemployed workers ______________________________ 146-148 Unemployment relief________________________________________ 148-164 Legislation in 1918_ __ __ _ __ _ __ _ __ __ ___ ___ __ _ __ __ __ ___ __ _ _ 148, 149 Amount of unemployment relief_ __________________________ 149-158 Expenses of unemployment relieL-----~------------------- 159-161 Unemployment relief work _______________________________ 161-164 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis llI 1V CONTENTS VII.-Unemployment-Conclude d. Employment offices _____________________________ ___________ _ Operations of employment offices _________________________ _ Organization of employment offices _______________________ _ Communal public employment offices _________________ _ State employment offices ____________________________ _ Federal employment office __________________________ _ Trade departments __ ~ ______ -~ ______________________ _ Equipartisan boards ______________________________ __ _ Management of employment offices ___________________ _ Personnel of employment offices _____________________ -~ Appellate procedure ________________________ --·,- _____ .. Expenses of employment offices _____________________ "_ Private employment offices __________________________ _ Principles governing employment service_.: ____ - r ______ _ Obligatory reporting of vacancies _________ _: __________ _ Special departments __ ~ _________________ -~ ___ :_: ____ _:_: C~APTER VIII.;--Cooper~tive ~ov_ement __________________ --~-- __ "Consumers cooperative societies _____________________________ _ Position at outbreak of war_ ____________________________ _ Situation during the war _____________________________ ___ _ Condition after the war ______________________________ ___ _ Cooperative building societies and building guilds ______________ _ Cooperative building societies ____________________________ _ Building guilds _____________________________ ___________ _ CHAPTER https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Page 164-167 167-171 171-189 171,172 172,173 173,174 174,175 175-177 177 177-178 178 178 179-181 181-183 183 u,3-189 190-199 190-195 191 191, 192 192-195 196-199 196-198 198,199 BULLETIN OF THE U.S. BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS N0.380 WASHINGTON MARCH, tUS. POSTWAR LABOR CONDITIONS IN GERMANY INTRODUCTION ~ Before the war a person who went to Germany to study labor conditions S'enerally was at first struck by the a_p_parent rm.possibility of secunng adequate information. After a while, however, he was p)IZ~led by the great number of sources he could use with advantage. While no general census of production had ever been taken, no general investigation of housing had ever been made, and no general study of wages had• ever been attempted, the statistical publications of some States, of a large number of municipalities, and of many tradeunions, as. well as the annual reports ol factory inspectors, housing inspectors, chambers of commerce, employers' associations, etc., contained so much data on labor conditions that it was possible after ~II to get a. pretty clear insight into a large _number ~f labor sub3ects. The lack of adequate central statistical service, however; made• it impossible to cover the whole ground. The difficulties which the student of postwar labor conditions now encounters in Germ.any are still greater, but the extent to which such difficulties have increased is not generally known. No census of occupations, of manufactures, of agriculture, of mines, of transportation, etc., has been taken since 1907. Municipal statistical offices which, before the war, made a special feature of the study of labor conditions either have been closed or have suspended publication of their studies. State statistical offices, factory mspectors1 housing inspectors, chambers of commerce, employers' associations, ana tradeunions have considerably curtailed their investigations, and some·of them now.issue no reports. The number of labor subjects on which it is ·still possible to secure adeguate information is therefore much smaller than before the war and it is utterly impossible to give anything like a complete report on postwar labor conditions in Germ.any. All that can be done in the following chapters is to point out developments along certain lines. 1 1 The author is Indebted for assistance rendered to him In preparing this report to Theodor 0111!88U, Jrmgard Feig, and 4rthur Krause. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1 Chapter L-GENERAL Sl]JlVEY POPULATION. an At the outbreak of the World War Germany had area of 209,000 sguare miles, with a population of 67,900 1000. As a consequence of tlie treaty of Versailles she lost 27,000 .square miles and retained an area of 182,000 square miles, which at the outbreak of the war had a population of about 61,000,000, at the census of October 8, 19191 59,900,000, and at the end of 1923 al>ont 63,500,0,00. At the end 01 1923, the male population was almost·3,000,000 less than it was at the outbreak of tlie war, while the female population had decreased almost 1,500,000. The decrease ani(')ng- both sexes was gi;eatest am~ng children under 15 years of age; mdeed the decrease among females was confined to this single group. . The group from 15 to 20 y~ars among both males and females· remained about the same. While there was a considerable decrease among males from 20 to 45 years, among females of the same age there was a slight increase. Both males and females from 45 to 65 years are much more numerous now than before the war. The group of persons over ·55 years of age among both sexes held its own. The proportion of females to 100 males has increased from 102 to 108. Before the war the excess was practically confined to persons over 45 years of age. There were then about as many males as females m tlie group from 20 to 45 years, while there is. now an excess of females amounting to one-sixth, and in -the group from 25 to 30 years the excess reaches two-sevenths. The most conspicuous results of this development are:· 1. The decrease in the number of children (under 15 years) to be supported by the breadwinner-before the war they_ constituted 33 per cent and now they constitute 28 per cent of the· total population; 2. The increase of the proportio11; of females in ~he most productive age of life-befo:re the war they constitute~ 50~er cent and now they constitute 54 per cent of the total populat10n between 20 and 45 yea.rs of age, ' OCCUPATION .The tre~d toward the cities,.which before the wa~·resulted in a co~tin1;1ous .decre~e !ll .the ,proportion of the popw~tioii~ engaged in agncultu.ral pursU1ts,- does not seem to have been of.er-3it:rve after the war., , The dread of starvation and the certainty o being better fed in. a :rui:a.l than,ih an _urban district pi:evented young men ~ho otherWJSe might have drifted to the c1t1es .from leavmg '. tl;i.eir homes. Moreover, ·the compulsory military service,. a cause whiQh,before the war had led young agricultural laborers to the towns an.d had occasionally induced .tJ::i.em to stay there once _they_ had expe~enced the better opportumt1es and pleasures of city life, has disappeared. Also girls from the rural districts do not so frequently go as servant girls to the cities, as the demand for domestic servants decreased with the increasing impoverishment of the middle classes. On the other 2 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 8. OCCUPATION hand, some agricultural laborers who before the war had gone to live in the cities, out who still had relatives in the country, returned home. because of the scarcity of food in the cities. There is reason to assume that the agricultural breadwinners in the restricted territory a.re now almost as numerous a.s those in the larger pre-war territory of Germany. This, however, does not mean that there is everywhere a. sufficient supply of agricultural workers. . There wa.s a. scarcity before the war, the gaps at that time being filled by foreign migratory laborers from the East who came r0J?Ula.rly for a. few months ea.ch year and then returned home. These foreign la.borers do not now come to Germany, since they can earn a better living at home. This explains the la.ck of help in the culture of sugar beets, for instance, because, before the war, this work was performed to a very large extent by foreign labor. The number of persons employed in mines was considerably larger after the war than before in spite of the fa.ct that Germany lost a. considerable pa.rt of her mineral resources through the treaty of Versailles. The increase was especially conspicuous in the lignite mines, where 144,752 workers were employed in 1921 as against 58,958 in 1913. Workers in the lignite briquet plants also increased from 20,069 in 1913 to 38,989 in 1920; workers in the coal mines from 654,017 in 1913 to 812,804 in 1921; workers in the salt mines, from 43,232 in 1913 to 52,273 in 1921. There was1 on the other hand, a. decrease in the number of workers emplo_yed m iron-ore mines, from 42,296 in 1913 to 29,478 in 1921, as well a.s in most of the other mines; smelters and iron and steel works, too, showed in general a sli,ght decrease. Altogether the number of workers employed in mmes, smefters, and iron and steel works has increased from 1,290,000 in 1913 to 1,530,000 in 1920-21, or almost one-fifth. The number of persons employed in the different kinds of mines, smelters, • and iron and steel works is shown in Table 1. TABLB 1.-NUMBER OF PERSONS EMPLOYED IN MINES.L. SMELTERS, AND moN AND STEEL WORKS IN GERMANY, 1913 ·i·O 1921 Industry 1917 1919 Llgnlte mines Coal mlnes ••••______________________________________ -·-·--··------------------------------_ 654,017 Iron mines .• _______________________________________ _ liS,958 Lead, silver, and zlnc mines ________________________ _ 42,296 Arsenic and copper mines___________________________ _ 21,282 13,292 Other ore mines ____________________________________ _ 1,554 43,232 Salt mlnes---·----··-··-----------------------------Petroleum production. ______________ • ______________ _ 964 S68, 00) 63,583 36,660 661,581 103,614 28,068 17,047 12,196 3,473 31,919 3,094 20,069 29,256 Coal-6rlquet plants----------·----------------------_________________________________ _ Coke plants •••.••• Llgnlte-nrlquet plants--------·---------------------Llgnlte, slate, and peat distilleries __________________ _ 1913 1,022 41,908 Blast furnaces •••••• ·-·--··---·--···-··---··--------- 154,300 Jron and steel foundries----·------------------------- Weld-lrOn workS •••••• ---·--·--------------·--------lnltot Iron and Ingot steel works __ ------------------- Rolling mllls.·-·-··-·-··------·--------------------- Lead, silver, and Iron works·-----------------------· Zinc works •• ·--·--·-------------------------------·· Other metal works ___ ----------------·--------·----· Sulphuric acid factories ______________ • ______________ • 2,698 42,118 128,785 9,446 13,003 1,776 6,785 18,223 16,122 3,743 27,an 1,430 2,688 20,586 1,043 46,238 l,'llYT 38,083 3,072 32,933 1,497 36,724 33,879 139,196 134,660 1,279, 1,087 43,229 61, 142,849 107,212 10,605 9,266 9,273 10,3681 3,063 3,048 6,237 4,723 1681 1920 1921 na, 199 812, 804 136,484 144, 7112 29, 101 29, 478 18, 018 19, 336 10, 849 11, 436 3,271 2,673 69, 692 62, 273 1,624 1,918 37,864 -----·---2, 927 --------·38, 989 -----·---- 1, 863 ----·---·- 36, 745 ·----·---149, 062 ----·----- 973 -----·------------- 47, 186 119, 617 11, 767 8, 690 3, 157 6, 732 -----·---·---·-··-·--·--····------··· -------·-- The increase in the number of workers employed was probably still larger in the chemical industry, while there was a considerable decrease in the building industry where only about 1,000,000 workers https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 4 CHAPTER !.-GENERAL SURVEY were employed after the war as compared with 1,7501000 before the war. Altogether there seems to have been a slight mcrease in the number of men employed in mines and manufactures, and certainly there was a large increase in the number of females employed. Although statistics of the plants subject to mine and factory inspection can not convey a true picture of the development of the country at large, it may be incidentally mentioned that from 1913 to 1922 the number of males employed in such plants increased• from 5,794,037 to 6,196,433, and the number of females from 1,592,138 to 2,019,189. There a.re no data available to show the increase in the number of persons employed in commerce, but there is not the least doubt that this incre8$e was enormous. This is especially true of the banks, which in 1923 probably employed ten times as many employees as before the war. A strong increase of personnel likewise took place in transportation. The average number of officials and workingmen employed by the State railways (excludim? Alsace-Lorraine) in 1913-14 was 741,000; in 1919-20-in spite of the reduction of railway mileage, due to the treaty of Versailles-1,122,000, or 51 per cent more. In 1920-21 the number was 1,090,000; in 1921-22, 1,051,000; and in 1922-23, 1,028,000. The exact figures for the separate years are as follows: 1913-14 _______________ 740,504 1914-15 _______________ 719,452 1915--16 _______________ 692,996 1Q16-17 _______________ 714,609 1917-18 _______________ 768,775 1918--19_____________ 913,396 1919-20 _____________ 1,121,745 1920-21 _____________ 1,089,839 1921-22----~-------- 1,050,898 1922--23 _____________ 1,027,522 In the report submitted in January, 1924, to the committee of experts of the Reparations Commission (Dawes committee), the German Government estimated the average railway personnel for 1923-24 • (April 1, 1923, to March 31, 1924) at 975,000, an increase of 32 per cent as compared with 1913. In the meantime officials and especially workers have been dischar~ed on a very large scale, but it is doubtful whether the railway service· can be permanently maintained at its . full efficiency with the reduced force. ·In the postal department the postwar increase of personnel was still greater. ·The average number of officials and workers in 1913-14 was 266,404; in 1921-22, 427,109; and in 1922-23, 408,492. The Government's estimate for 1923-24 was 374,871. The reduction in the last few months has not been so sharp as that in the railway service. · . · It may seem surprising that the number of breadwinners in agriculture, mines, manufactures, commerce, transportation, and government service should have either remained the same or increased as compared with. pre-war times while the population as a whole has decreased. There are four main reasons for this: 1. The decrease of the population was to a large extent due to a· decrease in the number of children under breadwinning age; 2. The number of women who have to earn their own living has considerably increased; moreover, the decrease in the demand for domestic servants induced some hundreds of thousands of women (who ordinarily would have gone to other households) to follow other pursuits; 3. Men who had retired from business were obliged to return to work when the revenues on which they had theretofore lived dwindled with the https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis OCCUPATION 5 depreciation of the currency; 4. The reduction of the army from 800,000 to 100,000 automatically increased the number of men looking for employment. It may also seem astonishing that the number of breadwinners increased at a time when production in agriculture and manufacture decreased, and transportation, bank transactions, exports and imports, etc., were considerably reduced. There are three princiJ>al reasons for this: 1. The reduction of the working hours; 2. The increase in unproductive work; 3. The diminished efficiency of the employees. 1. The hours worked by the total number of employees was reduced by the introduction of the eigJit-hour day and by the extension of vacations. (Both facts are fully discussed in Chapter V.) 2. The main cause of the increase in unproductive work was the dl;lpreciation of the currency. It affected wages, prices, taxes, and investments and led to a large increase in clerks and officials. Prior to 1918 some employers, such as :mining companies and the railway adlninistration, paid their workers once a month. With the depreciation of the money it became necessary to pay wages weekly. In the case of the railw~s this change resulted in the emJ>loyment of 3,548 more clerks. . When the depreciation oontinued, 1t became unavoidable to pay wages twice a week, and even oftener. At the same time, changes of wages became, of course, more and more frequent (see Chapter VI). As early as 1921, 4,000 clerks in the railway administration did nothing all year round but compute the (nominal) rises in salaries a.nil wages due to the fall of the mark. The de_preciation of the money necessitated a constant change of prices, wliich actually changed much more frequently than salaries and wages. In the c:lepartment stores, as elsewhere, all prices had to be adapted each day to the exchange rate of the dollar. Bills for electric light and gas, which in former times were pa.id monthly, had to be collected every week. Payments by check became unacceptable to the creditor, and so all bills had to be paid. in ca.sh at once. E~imates of costs had to be made again and a.gain. All this necessarily absorbed the time of a large number of clerks. With tlie changes in wages and prices, taxes had to be continually changed. This ca.used a large increase in the number of revenue officials, but it also meant a heavy burden for industry. It may suffice to mention in this connection the deduction l:>y the emplo:yer of the income tax from wages (see Chapter II). This tax, which was introduced in 1920, would under any circumstances have necessitated the appointment of a l~e number of additional clerks. Indeed, from the vecy beginning the railway administration employed 1,706 clerks on the deduction of this tax exclusively, and this task became the more cumbersome the oftener the wages changed. The same was true as to the deductions from wages for compulsory social insurance, etc. · The depreciation of the currency made it impracticable to keep money in cash or to deposit it at a savings or commercial bank. As the purchase of foreign exchange, which would have been the safest way of preservinE the value of one's ea.mi~, was forbidden to the general public, tlie only possibility of diminishing the risk of deprecijl,tion of money was to mvest it m shares of stock. This was done https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 6 CHAPTER I.-GENERAL SURVEY b_y millions of people who never before had thought of buying such shares. They could not, however, keep such secunties for any length of time, but had to resell them after some day;s or weeks, perhaps buying new shares the next month. This was the main cause of the enormous increase in the number· of bank clerks and explains why the banks, which had lost a large part of their overseas connections and which in view of the lack of deposits could do very little to finance industries, employed as many hundreds of thousands of employees in 1923 as they had employed tens of thousands in 1913. While the depreciation of the money was the main cause of the · increase of unproductive work, it was not the only one. Another cause, whose importance has been in' general overrated, was that after the creation of works councils some of the council members devoted .their time exclusively to work~ council affairs and did no productive work, but yet were paid by the employer. The Ministry of Railways estimated that at the end of 1920 the duties of works councils absorbed 2,212· railway officials and workingmen. · . The influence of the increase of unproductive worlt upon the mnn_ber of employees-was, of course, very different in the various industries and vaned greatly between establishments in the same industry. .One of the largest German· elec~rical plants, located in Berlin, which from 1914 to 1923 increased the number of its workers by 29 ~er cent and the number of its clerks by 71 per cent, experienced the following "inflation" of clerks in "unproductive" departments: NUMBER OF CLERKS :tN SPEOinED DEPARTMENTS OF A LAROE GERMAN ELECTRICAL PLANT, 1914, AND um, AND PER CENT OF INCREASE ' · Department 'fe:o~e1::::::::::::::::::::::::::: _· :::::::.:::::::: .::::::::::::::::: Sickness lnsurance--------------·-----------·-··-----------·-----------·-- !~~~~-~~~=====================-----------·---··-::::::: Clerks, 1111, 180 46 20 13 32 Clerks, 1923 520 229 67 95 131 Per cent of Increase 189 897 235 631 309 While .the additional work after the war was in general unpro.ductive work, there were cases where additional work was absolutely ,nec~sary •for the .sake of production. For the railways all the ite,ms heretofore mentioned cut very little figure as compared with the considerable· increase in the amount of work.to be done in the rehabili·tation of the railway·equipm,ent. Even if the war had terminated 'with a peace more ,favorable to Germ.any, the German railwap would have come out of the war in. a-bad state. Practically all the loco·motives needed to· l;>e repaired, and the same was true o_f most of the cars. The lack of copper and other materials not produced in Germany and which could not be imported during the war had led to the use of substitutes, which had greatly impau:ed the condition of the locomotives especially. The obligation to surrender after the 'armistice 5,000 locomotives, 20,000 passenger cars, and 150,000 freight cars made necessary their repla~ement, resultin____g_ ~ the employment 'of tens of thousancls of additional' workers. While befo;re tlie war :the Prussian-Hessian railways employed 70,000 men in their repair shops, the number of sucli workers on November 11 1918, was https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis LA.BOB MOVEMENT 7 108,000; on January 1, 1919, 143,000; and in July, 1919, 166,300. The decrease of traffic did not always make it possible to dispense with a corresponding number of employees. A good many- operations in railway work require just as many men whether they are repeated often or seldom during a day. Just as many switchmen must be employed whether 8 or 12 trains pass. As to the train personnel, where one would first expect a diminution, the reduced efficiency of the railways has partly resulted in the employment of even more men. The reduction of the speed of the trains, for example, which was necessary immediately after the war on accoun~ of the bad condition of the road and the lack of coal, has caused the employment of more fersons. · 3. The efficiency o labor was reduced through the moral effect of the war upon the workers, thro~h the insufficient feeding of the workers, through the abolition of piecework; through bad man~gement of the plants, and through legal provisions which compelled employers to appoint incompetent employees and prevented them from dismissing inefficient employees. (These items are discussed in Chapters II and VI.) UNEMPLOYMENT While on the whole there was, then, a strong demand for workers and especially for.clerks, at certain times-for example, immediately after the war and again at the end of 1923 when the Government ceased to print paper money-there was a good deal of unemployment. Measures were therefore taken to asSist the unemployed and to increase the public employment offices. (The amount of unemployment and tlie provisions as to unemployment relief and employment agencies are fully discussed in Chapter VII.) STANDARD OF LIVING AND WAGES In spite of the g~nerally favorable situation of the labor market and in spite of all efforts to reduce the hardship connected with unemployment, the general standard of living was very low. Food, fuel, and clothes were very_ scarce immediately after the war, and when the blockade ceased and imports might have filled the gaps, the low level of real wages prevented much improvement in the standard of living. For many years after the war the majority of German workers did not earn the minimum cost of subsistence of a family, and no noticeable illlprovement took place until after the stabilization of the mark. (The standard and cost of living and the trend of real wages are fully discussed in Chapters II and VI.) LABOR MOVEMENT The situation of the German working class after the war was, . however, not due to a lack of organization on their part. As a consequence of the :political revolution, trade-unions became very strong and succeeded m enlisting practically all workers in mines, manufactures, and transportation, as well as many farm laborers, salaried employees, and officials. Their strength manifested itself especially in the conclusion of collective agreements which are now protected by law. The wage terms agreed upon were, however, most of the time https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 8 CHAPTER I,-GENERAL SURVEY very unfavorable. Moreover, the power of the unions dwindled with increasing inflation and their situation became most precarious, with their financial breakdown in the fall of 1923. They became so weak that they were unable to·prevent the suspension of the 8-hour day. With the stabilization of the mark they liave recovered to a certam extent. The cooperative movement, in general, did not make any considerable progress after the war. The consumers' societies were hampered by the scarcity of food and by the reduced purchasing power of their members, and the building societies by £he lack of building material and the high cost of building. The only noticeable exception has been the building guilds, which m the few years of their existence have attained considerable success .. (The trade-union movement is discussed in Chapter IV, collective agreements in Chapter III, and the cooperative movement in .Chapter VIII.) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Chapter Il.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING FOOD The best general information on the fluctuations in the cost of foocf can be derived from the food-cost index computed since February, 1920, by the German Federal Statistical Office. The articles comprised in this index are as follows: 47~900 grams of rye bread; 4,000· grams of fl.our; 11,000 grams of nooru.es, oat flakes, barley groats, beans, peas, rice, etc.; 70,000 grams of potatoes; 15,000 grams of vegetab1es; 3,000 grams of meat; 1,500 grams of haddock; 1,500 grams of baconi 4,500 grams of fats; 1,000 grams of salt herring; 3,000 grams of dried truits (cheapest kind); 3,500 grams of sugar; 10 eggs; 28 litersof milk; and 1,750 grams of skim-milk cheese. Table 2 compares the total price (weighted average price for all cities included m index) of these quantities in 1913-14 with that in each month from February, 1920, to December, 1924. It will be· seen that the total price was 1,512 billion times as high in December,. 1923, as in 1913-14. From and after Januarv, 1924, the index is. based on rentenmarks, one rentenmark being ~equal to one trillion paper marks. TABLE 2,-INDEX NUMBERS OF THE ~(~ltJT~.FOOD IN GERMANY, 1920 TO 1924, BY [1913-M-1) Month 1920 ~'!ii~.::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: .....9"" Ag. March............................................. 11. 01 .:============================================ i~t:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ~~ ~ November......................................... December......................................... 13. 43 14. Zl e ~! i:ber..... --· ····-···-.. ·---.... -............. fr = 1 Based on rentenmarks. 1 Mllllons. 1921 14. 23 13. 62 13. 52 13.M 13. 20 13. 70 14. 91 15.89 16.M 17.57 21.89 , 23. 57 1922 1924 1923 24.63 30.20 36.02 43. M ttl.80 51.19 68.36 97.46 154.17 266. 23 5411. 82 807.02 11.27' 11. 1T 11.20· 11.23 . 11. 26· 11.20 11.26 11.22' 11.25 11.M 11,35 11. 85 1366 3183 3315 3500 4620 9M7 46510 670485 1 17.8 14301 '862 11512 •Billions. Table 3 gives similar figures for each date on which prices were· ascertained from the time of the stabilization of the mark on the basis of $1 equals 4.2 trillion paper marks, which equals 4.2 renten•· marks, i.e., from and after November 26, 1923. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ~- 10 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING TABLE 3.-INDEX NUMBERS OF THE COST OF FOOD IN GERMANY ON SPECIFIED DATES, NOVEMBER 26, 1923, TO DECEMBER 30, 1924 [1913-14-1] Date Nov. 26, 1923••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Dec. 3, 1923.•.••••••••••••••••••••••••••. Dec. 10, 1923•••••••••••••••••·•••••••••••• Dec. 17, 1923•.••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Dec. 22, 1923.••••••••••••••••••••• a •••••• Dec. 29, 1923..•••••••••••••••••••• + ••••• Jan. 7, l924,. .••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ~~: ~f: '1:t:::~::::::::::::::::::::::::: ~~~·1t9:.. ·········~·················· Feb. 11, 1924••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Feb. 18, 1924•••••••••••••••.••••••••••••• Feb. 25, 1924•.••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1 Mar: 17, 1924••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Mar. 24, 1924•••••••••••.••••••••••••••••• Mar. 31, 1924.. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Apr. 9, 1924.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Apr. 16, 1924..••••••••••••.•••••••••••••• ~:: ~o. r~~ :: :::::::::::::::::::::::: VIy~:J~............................. ~:~ ~t }~::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: May 28, 1924•••••••••••.••••••••••••••••• June 4, 1924•••••••••••• ·•••••••••••••••••• June 11, 1924 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Index number 2. 05 1.94 LM L38 1.36 1.36 1.33 1.29 1.25 1.21 1.17 Ll6 1.17 LIS l. 19 1.19 L20 L20 l. 20 1.21 1.23 1. 24 1.25 1.27' 1.28 1.25 1.22 l. 22 1.21 Index number Date June 18, 1924 .•.••••••••••••••••••••••••• Ifu!ri:t::::::::::::::::::::::::::: i; ?1~::::::::::::::~::::::::::,:::. July 16, 1924•••••••••••••••••••••••••••.• i:· ~: ~~-··························· Aug. 27, 1924 ••••••••••••••••••••• ••• ' ••. 1~ .....••.•••.• ••.•••.••.••. Sept. 17, 19~••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Sept. 24, 1924...••••••••••••••••••••••••.• Oct. l, 1924.•••••••••••••••••••••••••.••• Oct. 8, 1924..••••••••••••••••••••••••••.• _ t~t ~0. ~ ~ f!_ijll!. ~·· ·-·-· · · · · -:"~·· · ig: E:• g: m~· ·······-···~··~········,··· Pi~=========================== ·· Dec.10, 1924•••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Dec. 30, 1924•••••••••••· •••••••••••••••• 1.21 1.19 L27 1. 31 1.25 1.26 1.23 1.22· 1.22 1.22 1.23 1.24 · 1.25 1.26 1.28 1.30 1.34 1.36 1.36 1.37 1.36 1.35 1.36 1.36 1.34 1.35 L36 1.36 1;36 Table 4 shows how many times as high as in 1913-14 the dollar e~chan,ge rate of German marks at Berlin. was in each month from January, 1920, to December, 1924. From and after December, 1923, the index is based on rentenmarks. TABLE 4.-INDEX NUMBERS OF DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE OF GERMAN MARKS IN BERLIN, 1920 TO 1924, BY MONTHS [1913-14-1] Month 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 ·----•-: ~~~::~:> ~=' :::::::·::::::::::::::::::: :: : March•••••••••••••• · -···-·-·····-·-·············•· April ............· •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• May.: ••••••••· ·••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• June.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• · July ••••• ·········-•••••••••••••• •••••••••••••••••• August .•.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.• September .•••••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• October.--·-····················-················· November••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• December ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1 Based on rentenmarks. 15.44 23. 61 19. 98 14. 21 11.07 9.32 9.40 11.37 13. 81 16.24 18. 40 17. 39 I Millions. 15. 46 14.60 14. 88 15.13 14. 84 16. 52 18. 27 20.08 24. 99 35. 78 62.64 45. 72 45. 69 49.51 67. 70 69.32 69.11 75.62 117. 49 270, 26 349.18 757. 73. 1m.os 1807, 83 4281 6650 5048 5826 11355 26202 84186 1100632 2 23. 5 2 6017. 2 a 522. 3 IJ 11.00 11.00. 11.00 1 1.00 1 1.00 11.00 11.00 11.00 11. 00 · 11.00 11.00 11.00 • Billions. Table 5 shows the fluctuations of the general food~cost index from month to month, beginning with February, 1920, on the basis of the average dollar exchange value: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ll FOOD T.lBLII So-INDEX NU:MBERB OF THE 0OBT OF FOOD IN GERMANY,_ 1920 TO, 1924, ON BASIS OF DOLLAR EXCHANGE RATE, BY M0.'1THts [1913-14-1) Month 1920 1921 0.92 ~~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ••••• 0. 40 March............................................... tfa1;1·.:-:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::,:::::::::: June................................................. July................................................. A11g11St.............................................. ~~~~ber·:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: November........................................... December........................................... .93 . 56 .91 .88 .89 .83 1:: L 37 .82 L 35 L 03 • 79 .65 .49 .35 .62 -.: 73~ . 82 1922 O.M .61 .53 .63 .68 .68 .53 .36 .44 .36 ,32 .46 1923 0.32 .48· .66 .60 .41 .36 .56 ..61 73 .n L65 1.51 1924 L27 Ll7 L20 L23 1.26 1.20 1.26 1.22 1.25 1.34 1.35 1.36 . This table shows very !'.llearly the irregular course of the cost offood in Germany when measured by the dollar. In February, 1920, food cost in Germany only 40 per cent of what it cost before the war, while in the United States 1t cost 200per cent.1 By June, 1920, the German food cost, measured by the dollar, had climbed to 137 per cent of the pre-war cost (the highest po_int reached from the begmning of 1920 until November, 1923), while the American food cost in the same month was 219 per cent 1 (a maxim.um never reached before or after that· month). From September, 1920, to October, 1923, the food cost in Germany was in each month "below par," but it went up to 165 per cent in November, 1923 (when in tlie United States it was only 151 per cent),2 and it was as high as 205 per cent on November 26; i. e., more than six times as higli 'as in January, 1923. It then dropped to 116 per cent on February 11, 1924, but again somewhat increased, on December 30 being 136 per cent. The food-cost index calculated by the Federal Statistical Office comprises a large number of cities and is therefore necessarily inelastic, i.e., it hardly takes into consideration the market situation prevailing at different times in the different places. There has therefore been computed for January, 1920, to December, 1924, the minimum cost in Greater Berlin of the weekly food requirements of a c~d (11,200 calories), a woman (16,800 calories), and a man (21,000 calories). In case the quantities of food rationed in 1920 and 1921 did not contain a weekly average of 11,200 calories, these rationed quantities were supplemented by foodstuffs having sufficient nutritive value to brin_g the total to 11,200 calories. A woman would have to buy 5,600 calories more than the amount allowed for a child and a man a further additional quantity of 4,200 calories. The computation was limited as far as possible to the cheapest foodstuffs; i. e., if the supply of the cheapest foodstuff was practically unlinnted, each person was supposed to ea~ as much thereof as could reasonably be demanded, then as much as possible of the next cheapest, and so on. But if the supply of the cheapest foodstuff was limited, each person was supposed to eat thereof in proportion to the supply, and then to proceed to the next cheapest. The figure shown for January, 1920, 41.34 marks means, then, that, taking into consideration the pnces, the supply, and the _physiological and _psychological necessity of a certain variety of food, a man could not buy foodstuffs having a nutritive value of 21,000 calories for less than 41.34 marks. Table 6 shows the results of this computation for each month from January, 1920, to December, 1924. 1 Monthly Labor Review, A11g11St, 1920, p. 53. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis I Idem, January, 1924, p. 41. TABLE 6.-MINIMUM WEEKLY FOOD REQUIREMENTS OF CHILD, WOMAN, AND MAN, AND COST THEREOF, IN GREATER BERLIN, 1ANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924 .JANUARY TO January .TUNE, February I-' .~ 1920 March May April June Article Quantity Cost Quantity Cost 2,!n 2:~ 2, *' 2Ji i~i~;~~~~~~~::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ----~::- -----2~:- \i ~~ ~~:a~· Rationed: CHILD Gra1118 Marb Gra1118 Marb Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost GraTM Marb Grams Marks GraTM Marks Gram• .Marb 2,000 2. 74 1,900 4.04 2.65 4. 50 1,900. 1,900 456 1.27 190 .52 172 .47: 178 .52 25 .06 •••••• 280· 31 .12 100 • 70 125 • 50 50 .20 1.60 475 3.29 112 .85 2,000 1.20 1,900 1.37 2,125 1. 70 3,750 2. 65 2o0 4.33 250 5.36 ·-250 ••• 5.4s·······250·······4.57 20 . 68 20 . 71 20 • 75 20 . 75 Butter_------··-·-·-·-·---········-···-·--·-····· 20 . 50 20 . 55 67 1. 28 59 1. 12 125 4. 41 187 5. 93 Margarine, coco faL------··-···-··-·---·--··-··· 56 .82 105 2.00 123 4. 13 150 5. 69 125 5. 00 50 2. 00 Lard, tallow···-·-·-·-············-···-·-·--····· 82 2.01 45 1. 52 175 .49 175 .49 175 .70 269 1.06 Sugar.-··-·····-···-······-····-···-··-··-- ___ --· 175 • 36 175 . 49 125 . 92 100 . 74 125 1. 13 187 1. 92 Jam, honey substitute•••••••••••• -·---·--·-·--·----··-·--····-······· 62 . 37 Total.······-····-······------·····-·-·-··--·-· ;...-••-.••-.••-.1---l-l-.3-9-+-._-••-.-••-.-__+--13-.-07-+---+--17-.30-:1-.•• --••-.• •-.-.1---20-.26---1---+--27-.-09-1------1---24.-7-5 etc________________________________ Beans, peas______________________________________ In open market and by Illicit trade: Vegetables_······-···················-····--·---- --····-··· ··-····-·· 500 Total, child_-···.-··_._ •••••••• _••• _••••••••••• _••••••••• 11. 39 •••••••••• . 22 -········· -·-······· 1,500 13, 29 17. 30 ·····-··-· 2. 25 I 25.'19 .••••••••• 22.50 1 22. 28 WOJIIAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) [;J!i:l~~.::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: -·---·=- ···•-:::. -··•--::- -·---:::. -···•-:= -·-•-:.:-. ~ . !:il ......~......!:~. Potatoes-----·····-······------·----·-------·-··-········----········--·--·----·----------·----·-------··-····-·--···-·-----··-·--·-·····-·-·-·-·-··-·-·Vegetables __ ······--·-·-·-·--··---·-·-···-·-·····-··· · 4,500 1. 80 3,500 1. 54 4,500 2. 70 2,000 3. 00 1,500 3. 00 J'am_·············-·····-·-----·--················-··· 500 Total, woman___ ······-·.···--·····-···--··-·-· •••••••••• 3. 50 500 22. 34 3. 70 26.23 500 4. 00 31.20 500 7. 00 500 750 3. 40 250 1,500 500 1.20 1.05 6. 50 43. 74 42.40 1. 76 32.15 JIIAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Noodles, etc--··-···-········--·--·---·-·-··--····-·-· •••••••••• -····---·-······-------·--·--···-····--···--···-·-··-···-··- .. ··-----· ·····-···· ········-· Rice .. ···--··················-·-··---·------·-·-···-· 250 3. 75 250 4. 60 250 6. 00 250 6. 00 125 2. 60 Beans, peas------·······--·-·-·····-·-·-···---·~-·-·- 250 2. 25 125 1.15 250 y~~!!bles_ •.• -········-·-·----·--·-··---········-··· ·······-·· -··--·---· -·-·----·- ----··-··- -·----500- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 2. 70 250 2. 25 250 2. 25 250 260 250 2.00 4. 00 1. 75 -··· 'foo· ..•. ~:~•....• ~:~•••••~:~•..••• ~:~. :::::::::: :::::::::: C 0 ~ !! ~ E::~:=::::::::::::::::::::::::::=::=:= ------=- -----~ =-----=- -----:=- ------=- ---~-:- ------=- ----~~-:=::~:r: :•~~1: :=:t•~= I: ~ Total, m!III.. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• -··-·····- 41. 34 ·······-·- 47.18 -·-······· 58. 90 -·-······- 69. 90 ---·····-- 68. 49 00 l t.:>---------------------.--------,------.------""T"""----------July August September October lULY TO NOVEMBER, 1920 o t November Article r~r:.~s. Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Gra'ITI/J Marks Gra'ITI/J 1,900 Mark, 4.50 2. 61 Gram., 1,900 120 Marks 4. 50 .97 Orama 1,900 88 Marki Gram, Marki CHILD Rationed: etc::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 2 ' ~ ~~ ,~::~···-···-·--·---··-···-···-·-·---·---·---·-----------·------ - ---1,300 -···- L 06Meat •••• -········---···-------·-----···---·- ----·-----·-------------260 6. 11 Butter_-·---·----------·-·-·-·-----·-------------------------------·-- 20 l~~ ra~~~w~-~t_::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: f::,1"honey substitute_________ -· _____ ._. ______ --··-•••• _---· ---· --- ___ ff~ Total---·-·-----·----------------·--·-----·-·-·-·----··--··------·-----···-·-- t= • 75 .: 340 31 3• ~ 20 187 269 125 23. 02 ······-·-- 4. 50 .52 1,900 4.50 • 22 -·-·------ ---·------ -·······-- ·······-·· 37 • 27 t.75 g} • 1•;gg t :t ······200- ·----a.-si- -·-··-200- -···--4.-53 .75 12 .47 20 6. 60 2. 13 1.47 150175 50 25. 76 ---·-·---- ID ifou'::8:"e~:~~~~t:._~~l~~~t-~~~~~~-------··---------------------------·-- ____________________ --······- _---·-····· 0 • 70 • 73 - 250 62 18. 69 --------·· 1. 25 .80 1. 10 --·-··---· -···-----· 3. 75 .91 87 175 62 16. 06 -·--·--·-· 16.18 2. 75 ,~::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: :::::::: :::::~:~: :::::::::: :::::::::: ____ ~:~. ---·-~~~- t~ itig t~ . fl:: 22. 21 22. 93 24. 27 • 24. 21 20. 99 500 3. 85 1.33 .90 500 Total, chfld ____ ·-----------------------------------------··--·····-- ---·-·---- 250 20 32 6.10 2. 75 WOYAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTTTIF~) ~l gg 25 250 2.00 500 3.40 ---- 500 - -- 2. 70 ·----500 -- 2. 40 - - 500 1,500 __________ a: oo 1, ooo 90 ·-·------1, ooo ···------. 70 1,500 Vegetabt,i:i_. ________________________________________________ -----··------- __________ 1,500 l.. 50 1,500 Margarine ___ ----·-----·······-··----·-----·--··-----···-·----·---·--·---125 2. 90 ------·-·- ---·-·---250 6. 25 250 ··-·-a. 00 ·-· "500 t, 500 2,000 •••• 3. 00 1. 50 2. 00 125 3. 60 36.43 rl~~· etc::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: B n peas rgg 250 P~a:~----·---·------·------------- -----------------------------·------- Total, WOmBD---···-··-·· --··---·--········- ··--·----·-······--··--· .......•.• 1 7 per cent deduction· for requirements Inferior to the ration. • 10 per cent deduction for requirements inferior to the ration. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 750 3.00 500 2. 50 1. 20 l. 50 7.15 37.06 33. 86 •••••••••• 32. 84 ···-······ 1 6 per cent deduction for requirements Inferior to the ration. TABLE 6.-MINIMUM WEEKLY FOOD REQUIREMENTS OF CHILD, WOMAN, AND MAN, AND COST THEREOF, IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, f920, TO DECEMBER, 1924-Continued IULY TO NOVEMBER, 1920-Conc!uded September August July November October Article MAN (AllDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Gra1118 Mark., Gra11111 Mark., Gra1118 Mark., Gra1118 Mark., Gra11111 Mark, -----s:1s- ------500- -----6.-sii- ------500- -t: i ~ ------soo~~~-~:-~t:_-_::::::~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ______ ____ __________ __ ____ ___ ------500·____ -----6.-45peas_------------------------------------------------ ·______________________________________ ;;:i~:~~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ___ _.· ::------:: ---- 250 1. 75 250 Beans, 2, : - -----: : - ----~~:- -----~~:- ::::~:~: :::::~:~: t o. 50 1. 90 m i; 6. 90 ___________________ _ 125 Lard__________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ 4. 75 _______________________________________ _ 500 Jam----------------------------------------------------------------------______________________________ __________ Total, man _____________________________ .---------------------------- _________ _ 48. 46 56. 26 ---------51. 22 ---------48. 34 ---------- DECEMBER, 1920, TO APRIL, 1921 January December February April March Article Quantity CHILD Gram, Rationed: Rye bread ________ ------------------ __________________ ---------------1,900 180 etc::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Y~11Ji:1'e~• 50 Meat, bacon _____________________________________________ •• • _. _______ • Butter __ ----------------------- -- ---- -- -- --- --- -- --- -- ------ ---- ------ Sugar - - - ---------- --------- -- ------------------ -- --- -- - ---- - --- ------ - 250 16 'i!l5 Total _______________________________________________________________ ---------- In °8~ Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Marka 4. 50 1. 80 .80 Gra11111 Marks Gram, Marki 4. 50 Gram, Mark, 4. 50 Grams 1,900 150 4. 50 1.'i!l .64 2. 09 250 - --- 5. 50 .90 23 1. 33 175 14. 52 13. 50 4. 69 1,900 150 3t 250 175 2. 20 90 ~!~~~~~-~=-~~~~:-~:~~~~-----------------------------------------------------------------------------0------------ ---------- ---------- ______ 250 ______1· 45 _______ : ~ : groats_ -- - Potatoes______________________________________________________________ Vegetables____________________________________________________________ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 250 3,000 750 1. 250 1,900 1.43 .50 5. 80 - 1.33 13. 56 Marki 5.38 1.45 100 2. 52 1.26 30 'i!l5 1. 50 2. 09 3( ------ 1. 60 1. 33 175 11. 87 9. 76 285 - 2,200 200 Cost 1. 80 ---------- ---------- ---------- -------··250 250 ______ 1· 40 _ ------iisii3. 30 3,000 3. 30 3,000 3. 30 3,000 ------i2s- ------:sii- ------rio 3. 09 3,000 • 90 ______________________________________________________________________ -··-··-·-· 3. 30 I-" ~ Canned meat ___________________________________________________________________ ---------- ---------- ---------- ---------- ---------Margarine____________________________________________________________ 125 3. 60 125 3. 25 125 2. 88 Total, child ______________________________________________________________ •• __ _ 22.94 23.49 24. 22 ---------WOYAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) t i ~::l.Sr~q _________________________________________________________________ ----- 375 - --·--2. 85 - ~ gg ~ ~ Barley groats _________________________________________ ·------------------- __________ ---------- __________ ----------____________________ Beans_____________________________________________________________________ 500 3. 25 500 2. 85 500 2. 50 250 4.45 2. 70 125 - 250 - -----1. 67250 1. 40 250 1.13 250 1. 25 1,500 1. 65 1,250 2. 00 Potatoes_----------------------------------------------------------------1,500 1. 65 1,500 1. 55 1,500 1. 65 Vegetables________________________________________________________________ 3,500 4. 20 2,000 2. 80 1,250 1. 88 Salt herring _____________________________________________________________________________________________ ---------- __________ --------------------__________ ~arlne ______________________________________________________________________ 125 ______3. 60 _______ 125 ______3. 25 _ 2. mi r: 38. 74 39. 77 125 22.88 Peas ______________________________________________________________________ ------------------------------------------------------------ Total, woman________________________________________________________________ _ 4. 00 2. 40 250 20.56 ------uo· ---·-·1:00 1. 40 . 55 1. 25 250 125 250 1,500 1,250 500 1. 65 2. 50 2.15 ii ------~~- ------~-~ gi 36. 91 35.63 aa..ll6 YAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Rice---------------------------------------------------------------------500 6. 500 6. 500 4. 1. 50 250 1. 00 75 250 1. 25 50 ~~~bles ____________________________________________________________________ 1, 500 ______1. SO _____2,500 _____ 3. 50 _____2, 500 _____ 3. 75 _ 90 500 250 3.60 1.25 500 Margarine________________________________________________________________ Jam_______________________________________________________________________ 3. 60 2. 50 125 125 125 s. oo -i2ii125 125 Peas______________________________________________________________________ 250 125 250 Total, man ____ • __ -------------- _____ ------------------ ______________________ _ 125 125 3. 25 1. 13 125 125 2. 70 . 95 50.42 53.37 &6.07 2. 88 1. 13 250 3. 70 1.25 ------a:oo 47.13 2. 41> 1. 20 45.51 MAY TO AUGUST, 1921 May July June August Article Quantity CHILD Rationed: Rye bread ________________________________________________________________ _ Flour, cereals, etc ____________ ----- ---------- ----- --- --- ---- ------ -------- --Sugar ___________________________ --- -- ---- ----- -------- -- ----- ------ -------- GramB 1,900 294 234 Cost Mark3 5. 00 1.96 1.87 Quantity Cost GramB 1,900 Mark3 5.00 105 .48 375 3.00 Quantity Grams 1,900 212 175 Cost Mark3 5. 00 }: : Quantity Cost Grams Marks 1, 900 5. 98 -287- --------2. 30 f----1--------,f-----!----+----+---+---+---- Total __ ------------------------------------------------------------------ -----------In open market and by illicit trade: Rye Oat groats ,.___________________________________________________________ Barley 125 8. 83 ------------ 8. 48 7.93 flour ____________________ ---------------------------------------------- ____________ ____________ 250 2. 00 125 1. 00 flakes------------------------------------------------"----------------- ------------ ____________ 250 1. 45 -----------375 ___________ 2. 29_ • 70 ________________________ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 8. 28 250 250 250 1. 70 1.91 1. 86 TABLE 6.-MINIMUM WEEKLY FOOD REQUIREMENTS OF CHILD, WOMAN, AND MAN, AND COST '.l'HEREOF, IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, 1920. TO DECEMBER, 1924-Contlnued MAY TO AUGUST, 1921-Concluded May June July August Article Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Gram Marki Gram, Marki Gram, Marki Gram, Marki cnn.D-concluded ID open market and by illicit trade-Concluded. Beans______________________________________________________________________ 250 1. 05 . 125 ~it~rii::~~-------------------------------------------------------------- ______a,:--------::: ::::::1, Margarine._--------------------------------------------------------------125 -----------2. 44 Milk_______________________________________________________________________ -----------Total, child _________ - --------------------------------------------------- ___________ _ 0. 54 125 0. 56 ~ 760 :::::::2. 80: ------ :::______ } (') 125 20. 22 ------------ 2. 60 4. 00 125 (1) i _ 2, 000 ll&_ :::::::::::: :::::::::::: 2. 54 60 3. (') 125 24.28 21. 87 a. 60 3. 3. 00 75 24.00 WOMAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) ifI;~~·:.-::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ill250 ! --------~250 ------- I. f:l~:Y~e~i:::::::============================================================ ____ }~________!:~~ I. 1. 500 Peas._------------------------------------------------------------------------- 1 : Bacon______ -------------------------------------------------------------------- ___________ _ ____________ Salt herring____________________________________________________________________ 500 60 Margarine.-------------------------------------------------------------------125 2. 44 Jam________________________________________________________________________________________ ____________ Total, woman_ ______________________________________________________________________ _ 1: :• 1. 25 1 , 125 125 250 a.. 79 --------?: -------1: gf --------:- ________;~ 250 I. 29 1 • 125 t!00 28 ~ t 250 ~ 600 44.66 43.04 46. 60 HAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Rice___________________________________________________________________________ 600 3. 26 3.60 600 1.08 250 Beans. _______________ -- -- __________ - --- --- ----- -- -- ------- --- -- -- ---- --- --- ---- --------- - -- - ------- -- -Peas._------------------------------------------------•-----------------------250 1. 25 ________ _ _______ Bacon_________________________________________ ·-------------------------------125 ._ 25 125 ._ 25 Salt herring____________________________________________________________________ Margarine.. ___________________________________________________________________ 250 125 • 80 2. 44 250 125 t* :: ._ :: 25 4. 63 125 5. 00 76 2. ..J.. 25 2. 125 2. 60 125 3. 00_ 2. 60 25 _______________________________________________ . 88 2. 60 3.60 1.12 250 _ _____ _ 125 ._ 63 ·260 1. 125 2. 60 500 ________ 00 500 .. 25 250 125 250 125 l. 60 5. 00 1. 25 3. 00 l---r--l----+----+----+----l----+----1---Total, man __________________________________________________________________________ _ 61.60 67.61 65.46 46. 78 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis J-1 ~ SEPTEMBEB TO DECEMBER, 1921 October September November December Article Rationed: CHILD ffo~r::eals, etc:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Quantity Cost Quantity Grama Marki Grama 1,900 160 370 6. 95 L16 3.25 2,025 269 125 Cost Marki 7.53 1.81 1.00 Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Grama Marki Orama Marki 2,050 325 Bu.gar - -------------- ---- -- --- ------- ---- ---- -- ---- ------- --- -- ---------- -- Total ___ ----------------------------------------------------------------- ____________ lL 36 ____________ 10 34 ___________ _ In o~~ ~!et and by illicit trade:_ 1 ----------------------------------------- _______________________________________________ _ 250 Barley groats_______________________________________________________________ 250 1. 96 250 2. 11 t: tlfr ________________________________________________________ -------------- ---- <•f ____ -------a.so if!:~e::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 3' ~ Total, child------- __________________________________________________________________ _ r: <•> 2' 125 24.38 i.: l :g 2, 500 125 250 (') 7.65 2. 00 2,150 160 1.16 9. 65 ------------ 9.41 2. 60 250 3.10 5. 65 6. 65 2. 60 5. 00 3, 000 125 250 (') 7. 44 6. 90 2. 90 6. 20 32.15 26.65 8. 25 35.95 WOMAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Rye bread ________________________ :____________________________________________ 500 2. 50 Rye flour______________________________________________________________________________________________ 250 1. 28 250 1. 60 ____________ ____________ ____________ ____________ 250 125 1. 92 1.15 ~~1'i!:8:::::::::::::::_:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: --------~~- -------~:~- --------~~- -------~:~~- --------125- ------Tso- --------125- --------1~m !!~rf~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ t~~X:U.ine::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ~: illi · tt:fi Total, woman _________________________________________________ ----------_ ------------ tm ~: iu i: ~: m g~ 52. 32 48,26 t~:li 1: m ~: 66.60 Jt:~ 74. 78 MAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Rice - - - ---------- _____________________________________________________________ _ Peas __________________________________________________________________________ _ Bacon_________________________________________________________________________ _ 500 250 125 250 125 4. 60 L95 5. 50 1.25 3.42 Total, man _____________________________ - ---- ---- ------- --- - --- -------- - -- -- --- --- ------ 64.98 tii::..'T~~g:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: • 1 liter. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 500 250 125 250 125 4. 75 2. 02 5.88 1. 31 4.06 70.34 500 250 125 250 125 6.40 2. 60 7.50 L50 6.65 91.25 500 250 125 250 125 7.90 3.05 8. 25 L 75 6. 90 102. 63 TABLE 6.-MINIMUM WEEKLY FOOD REQUIREMENTS OF CHILD, WOMAN, AND MAN, AND COST THEREOF, IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924-Continued JANUARY TO JUNE, 1922 January February April March May June .Article cmLD Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Grams Marks Grams Marks Grams Marks Grams 2,012 50 250 250 125 2,000 Marks 14. 85 . 36 Grams 2, 000 125 250 125 8.50 5. 40 2. 50 8. 75 W-:ei'[EJr~-,_-_::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ----~~~~~-----~-~R fl 250 2.30 2, g~ lf: ~: oif fl~~==:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 250 3. 05 ----·-2:so- ----~a:o:s1~~1~!~~~:s::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::!':::::::::: ----2;wii- -----ii:iio- ______ '.~~- ____ :'.~~~Vegetables___________________________________________ 1, ooo 2. 80 1,250 6. 75 Margarine___________________________________________ 125 5. 85 Jam __________________________________________________ --------·- •••..•...• tll~~=::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: <·/50 Total, child.-·--···-·-·-·-· .. -·-·-·-·-·-----·-· _··--·---- ~Jg 125 125 (1)250 6. 60 1. 80 2,300 15. 48 -•----250- -----3.40250 3. 50 J~ 1, 1,000 125 250 7. 40 4. 50 250 Quantity ·Marks · 15. 36 4. 35 ·- Grams 2, 000 • 250- • Cost Marks 15. 97 4. 50 250 3, 000 5. 00 ---· -250 · ··---- 5. 25 16. 20 3, 000 12. 60 125 250 125 s.75 -- ·125·- -··9_50 6. 00 250 7. 00 3. 50 125 4. 50 8. 85 (') 10. 00 ui - - - - 1 - - -ui- + - - - - t - - - - - t - - - - t - - - - + - - - · 1 - - - <·/25 43. 24 38.00 !:5. 30~8 3.80 4.45 2. 30 12. 40 Cost (') 54. 97 (') 68. 01 63. 31 69. 32 WOMAN (ADDITIONAL (;'UANTITIES) Rye bread·-···-·-····--··--···-·-·-··---···---·-·-·250 2. 00 500 4. 30 500 5. 50 500 6. 20 Oat flakes·-·---······-··-----·-··-"··-··-····----·--· ·-··--···· ·····-···· ·-~····--- -····--·-- -·-···-··· -····-···· -·-··-···· ·--···-··· ~!~!~-~~:s_-:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ~~g . ~: ~ i~g 500 250 6. 35 5. 05 500 250 6. 55 5. 50 }~g ·-····'.~~- -···-~~~~- ··-··-'.~~- ..-.. ~~~~. ···--·2:so· -··-·4:iio· -····-2:so· ·--·--4;75 Peas·-·--·····-···-··-··-···---··-···--······-·-·---····-·····-··-·---··········-·-······-··· 250 3. 75 250 4. 30 ····-··-·- -···•-···· -········- ···---·-·Potatoes_ ..••••.. _._._ .••• _._._ ••...• --·····--·-····1,000 2. 65 ······---- ······---· 1,000 4. 40 1,000 6. 20 500 2. 70 500 2.10 Vegetables ...•.... ·-·--··-·-·-···---·····-···----·-·· 1,500 2. 40 1, 750 9. 45 ·-····250· ···-11. 10· ·- ···250· .• ·15_00- ···- 250 16.00 -· ·250 • 18.00 Canned meat.·-·-·-·······--···-·-···-·-···-··-···-·· 250 9. 75 250 10. 00 125 9. 80 125 14. 00 125 14. 80 125 17. 00 Bacon.·-··-···-·--·-···-···--··-·-···--······-·--···· 125 8. 20 125 8. 25 250 3. 45 250 4. 00 250 5. 00 250 6. 00 Salt herring .• ·-·-·-··-····-······-····-····-·-········-····-··· ··-······· 250 2. 45 125 7. 40 125 8. 50 125 8. 75 125 9. 50 Margarlne.·--···---·-·-·-··----·-·-·---·-·--·-·-·--· 125 5. 85 125 6. 60 Jam·-·----··-··-··-··-·--·-·----·-·-·--··-·--·-·-···· .......... ··--······ 125 1. 80 ·-·-··---· -····--··· --··-··-· -· .-·-···· ---··-·-·- ·-···-···· --······-· ······-··103. 02 123. 81 131. 26 138. 72 Total, woman.·-·-·-·-·----·-·-··-··-·····--····---·----· 77. 00 ·--··---·· 91. 04 MAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Rice.---------···-····-··-·-····--·-··········-···--· 500 7. 75 500 9. 40 Beans __ ·····-·-·-··-·····-------·-·-··-··-··-··--·-· •. ··-·--··. ··-·--- .. _ ···-···. __ .•.•. ·- ... Peas •. ·--···--······-·-··------··-·-··----·--··--·-·· 250 3.15 250 3.40 Bacon_··-·--·-······-··-····-·-·-···-·····----···-··· 125 8. 20 125 8. 25 Salt herring··-··--··--··-······-·-···-····--·-·-····· 250 1. 75 250 2. 45 Margarine ••••••• ·--·----···-···-····-----------·--·· 125 5. 85 125 6. 60 500 250 10. 15 4. 05 500 250 11.60 4. 30 125 250 125 9. 80 3. 45 7. 40 125 250 125 14. 00 4. 00 8. 50 lioo 12.45 500 13. 00 250 125 250 125 4.70 14. 80 5. 00 8. 75 250 125 250 125 4.90 17. 00 6. 00 9. 50 ----1----1-----+---+----l----l---'---+----f----l----t----f---- Total, man .. ·--·---·····-·-·-·-----····-·-··-·--·-······· https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 103. 7~ 121.14 137. 87 166. 21 176. 96 189. 12 1--' 00 IULY TO NOVEMBER, 1921 1uly Augost September November October Article CBJLD Bye bread• ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Bye flour ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Oat :flakes••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Barley groats•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Potatoes •• ····················-······-···········--·················-··-·· ~-:.::::::::::::::::::·::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: LT:·::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Gt-am11 Marki 17.15 5. 50 Gt-am11 .ICIZJ'b Gt-am11 Marb 36.0li Gt-am11 .Marb Gt-am, Marb 46.00 35.00 1,900 2,000 250 125 250 1,250 1,000 125 250 250 (•) Total, ohild·-·········································-' •••••••••••• -········· 3. 75 6. 50 14.00 12. 00 13. 00 8.00 11.90 11.70 1,940 250 25.95 1,,900 10.45 250 250 3, 250 12. 10 25. 60 125 28. 15 • 250 3, 000 1, 000 125 21. 75 ~- 00 11. 00 48. 60 250 250 3, 000 1, 000 125 250 24. 30 19. 10 250 (•) 34. 40 37. 60 (•) (') 1,900 250 232. 70 145.65 103. 50 19.30 •••33. 75. 40. 50 20. 00 78. 76 42. 00 60. 85 107.85 250 85.00 ·····-250 - ···--87. 50 3, 000 46. 20 1, 000 25. 50 125 207. 60 • 250 (') •••48. 00 134. 25 741.80 366.85 WOMAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) fli:il~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ····-·~· --···~:~. --··--~· ....~~:~. :l :~ :l :. : Beans·-·································-··-·······-······--··-·········· 250 22. 25 250 37. 50 ·········- ····-····· Oat :flakes••••••••••••••••••• _•••• -···--·-····-······················-····· 125 250 3. 75 6. 25 250 250 :l 1: : Ml 1-' 60 ······-·-- -··-·----· ·····--·-- ---·------ •••••••••• ·--··--··· 13. 50 Peas ••••••••••••••••·--···························--···-···-······-······· ······---- ---··----- -··-··-·-· ······-·-· ······---- ··--·---·· ···------- ·-··--·-·· ···-----·- ----··-··· Potatoes •• ·················--·····-········-·-···········---········---··· 1,000 11. 20 500 3. 96 500 4. 00 500 6. 75 1,000 15. 40 1,000 250 125 ~ : -·-··· 125 ·-- Vegetables •• ·-············-··-·······-···--·---··--·············--·--·····--·-··-·-- --···--·-· -····--·-· ······---250 28. 00 250 53. 00 125 28. 00 125 45. 00 Caimed meat-·- •••• ·······················-·--········--···-··--········· Bacon--··-··················-·-······-····--·-········-··-···--········-· t1~::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ~ Total, woman. ___ -····················-·--···-····················- •••••••••• 1t ~ ~ 519. 20 •••••••••• 332.85 210. 06 11. 00 1,000 20. 00 2,000 51. 00 75. 50 250 135. 00 250 280. 00 70. 00 125 126. 25 125 266. 25 48. 60 •• - 125 • 78. 75 ·····-125- ----207. 60 863. 96 1,802.60 ll'.AN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Bice._.··············---·····················-···--··-··················-· 500 18. 60 500 34. 20 500 55. 60 500 94. oo Peas_ ••••••••••••••••••• --···-·····················--·········-········--· Bacon •••• ···········-·····-·················----···-······· ···········--· Salt Mlll's:arine---································-·---········-·-···········-· 250 125 250 125 6. 75 28. 00 7. 00 13. 00 250 125 250 125 .14. 70 45. 00 11. 60 28.15 250 125 71.10 70. 00 21.10 48. 60 250 125 40. 00 126. 25 Beans.----·-·-·---·-··············-······--·--··-···-···········-·--·------- -·-··-·--- ---·------ --·····--- ··--··---· ·-··------ ····--·--- -····----- herring-······················-·········-··--···-··----·-···········-- Total, man ____ --···················-······-··········-···--····-·-· ··-·-···-· https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis • l llter. 283. 30 466. 60 I Rationed. 250 125 741.60 250 125 500 250 200.00 85.00 78. 75 125 • ·-266. 25 250 86.00 125 207.50 l,~L96 2,647.35 39. 00 •• T.illLE 0.-MINIMUM WEEKLY FOOD REQUIREMENTS OF CHitD, WOMAN, AND MAN, AND COST THEREOF, IN OREATE-R BERLIN, JANUARY, _ 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924-Continued DECEMBER, 1922, TO MAY, 1923 December Article January February March April May Cost Quan• tity Cost Quan• tity Cost Quan• tity Cost Quan• tity Cost Quan• tity Gra'TTI/J 1,900 250 250 :l~oats :: : : : : : : : : : : : :: :: :: : : : : : : :: : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : :: : : : : : 3,000 1,000 125 250 Milk••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•••••••..••••.••.....•..•••••••. (') Mark3 275.35 102. 50 112. 50 48.90 35.00 246. 25 90.00 185. 80 Gra'TTI/J 1,900 250 250 3,000 1,000 125 250 (') Mark3 458. 75 140.00 170. 00 87. 00 65. 50 367. 50 140. 00 255. 25 Gram, 1,900 250 250 3,000 1,000 125 250 (') Mark3 708."45 412. 50 437. 50 363. 00 117.50 1, 050- 00 252. 50 616.85 Gra'TTI/J 1,900 250 250 3,000 1,000 125 250 (') Mark3 871.60 332. 50 452. 50 330.00 '01.50 800.00 415. 00 715. 35 Gra'TTI/J 1,900 250 250 3,000 1,000 125 250 (') Marks 900.00 357. 50 437. 50 228. 00 232. 50 725.00 557. 50 917. 35 Gra'TTI/J 1,900 250 250 3,000 1,000 125 250 (') -------- 1,096.30 -------- 1,684.00 -------- 3,958.30 ~~::: 500 270. 90 Quan• tity CHILD Rye bread• •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.••.••••. J Fu$!ri!ie:::::::::. :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: :::::::::::::::: Total, child •••••••••••••••••..••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 4,144.45 4,355.35 Cost Marks 917. 74 475.00 520.00 366.00 370.00 1,325.00 562. 50 956.13 6,492.37 WOMAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) ~:~~~························································ ~ •••••.••.. Oat flakes .••••••••••••••••••••••••..•••••.•.••••••••.•••..•.. · ... ....•••• 500 756. 60 500 681.00 500 681. 55 ·500 934. 16 250 186. 00 250 497. 50 250 487. 50 • 250 •• 440. 00 • • 250 587. 50 · Potatoes......................................................... 1,000 16. 30 1,000 29. 00 1,000 121. 00 1,000 110. 00 1,000 76. 00 1,000 122. 00 Vegetables •.••••••.•.•••.•.•••....••••....•••••••...••......·•.... 2,000 70. 00 2,000 131. 00 2,000 235. 00 2,000 455. 00 2,000 465. 00 2,000 740. 00 Canned meat ••••.•..•••.•.......•.•••....•...••....•••..•....•• '-". 250 365.00 250 600.00 250 1,650-00 250 1,550-00 250 1,550-00 250 2,800.00 Bacon............................................................ 125 337 r.o125 662. 50 125 1,537.50 125 1,452.50 125 1,387.50 125 2,075.00 Margarine....................................................... 125 246. 25 125 367. 50 125 1,050.00 125 800. 00 125 725. 00 125 1,325.00 ,---1----+-------1---+-----t----+---1-----1---+---1----1--Total, woman.............................................. •••••••• 2, 429. 05 3, 93o. 90 9,805.90 9, 680-45 9, 68o. 40 14,076.03 MAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) 500 416.00 500 990.00 975. 00 Rice •••••••••••••....•••••••••••••••••••.•••.•• - ••••••••••....... 500 265. 00 500 1,160.00 500 500 1,400. 00 250 182. 50 475. 00 250 465.00 451. 25 Beans............................................................ 250 115. 00 250 250 250 625. 00 125 1,452.50 125 662. 50 125 1,387.50 Bacon............................................................ 125 337. 50 125 1,537.50 125 2, 075. 00 250 240.00 625. 00 250 600.00 587. 50 Salt herring...................................................... 250 140. 00 250 250 250 750- 00 125 367. 50 125 soo. 00 125 725. 00 125 1,050.00 Margarine ••••••.••••• -•••••••••••••••••.••••••••...••.••.•..•••• ,___1_25--1--24-6._25-+----+----+---+---1-----1------1---+----+--12_5--+--1,_3_25._oo 13,987.95 20,251.03 6,799.40 Total, man•••••••••••••••••••••••••.•.•••..••••••••.••••••••••••••• 3,532.80 14,653.40 13,806.65 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -------- -------- -------- ta O IUNE TO NOVEMBER, 1923 July June Article Quan• tity Cost Quan• tity August Cost Quan• tity October September Cost Quantity Cost Quan• tity Cost November Quan• tity Cost - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - - -----1----+-----1---1-----1----1·----1--CHILD Grams Marks Grams Marks Gra1118 Marks Gra1118 Marks Gra1118 Million marks Grams Billion marks Rye bread•.................................................. 1,900 2,523 1,900 6,203 1,900 98,967 1,900 2,703,000 1,900 3,077.6 1,800 378 1,850,000 Rye flour.................................................... 250 1, 100 250 4,250 2_50 250 60,000 467.5 250 250 75. 5 Oat flakes.................................................... ........ .•...•.... 250 5,400 Barleygroats................................................. 250 1,200 250 5,000 250 82,500 250 2,350,000 250 515.5 250 86.3 Beans..............................•.................•.•·...•................... 125 2, i25 ........•.••..•...••••••.••.......•...•...••...••.•..•.••••••.••••••••••..•• Peas......................................................... 125 606 ..•..... ···-··---· ..................•..•....................••....•......••.•.....•.••••...••• Potatoes..................................................... 3,000 1,575 2,000 17,200 3,000 138,000 3,000 2,070,000 3,000 885 3,000 117 Vegetabl•····················-··-···-·-·-··················· ........ .•........ ........ .•........ 1,000 77,500 1,000 945,000 1,000 227 1,500 76.5 Margarine................................................... 125 2,975 125 7,500 125 162,500 125 4,062,500 125 912.5 125 133. 7 Sugar........................................................ 250 750 250 1,650 250 56, 000 250 2,070,000 250 762. 5 250 143 Milk......................................................... (') 1,663 (4) 4,734 (4) 75,097 (') 3,152,533 (•) 756. 5 (') 132. 5 Total, child.................................................... 12,392 54,662 19,203,033 • 750,564 7,604.1 1,142.5 WOMAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES)• Rye bread ... ············--··--··--··--··---·--·············· 500 1,993 750 12,779 500 99,140 500 2,800,617 500 822 500 105 Oat flakes.................................................... 250 1,275 ........ .........• 250 95,000 250 2,575,000 250 531.3 250 92.3 Rice............................................................................ 250 5,625 .....••.•.••.•••.••••••..•...••..•....••.......•....•.....•••..•.••••••.•••• 250 5 450 250· ···· 1,212· .••• •...• ' . Potatoes..................................................... 1,000 525 .....••• ••...•...• 1,000 46,000 1,000 690,000 1,000 295 1,000 39 Vegetables........................................................................................ 2,000 155,000 2,000 1,890,000 2,000 454 2,000 102 Cannedmeat..•.•..........•.....•.•.......•................. 250 5,350 250 17,500 250 325,000 250 9,500,000 250 2,065 250 •••• 500 ·• Frozen meat .. ·······--·········-········--·················· .......... ·................•.................................................................. Bacon........................................................ 125 4,375 125 15,750 125 325,000 125 9,2.'i0,000 125 2,542.5 125 756. 2 Margarine................................................... 125 2,975 125 7,500 125 162,500 125 4,062,500 125 912. 5 125 133. 7 J::!'s: ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ···· Total, woman.................................................. 1:::::::: :::::::::::: :::::::: :::::::::::: :::::::: :::::::::: :::::::: :::::::::: 30,097 119,266 49,071,150 1,958,204 15,226.4 2,870.7 MAN (ADDITION AL QUANTITIES) Rice ..•.••••••..•....... _.................................... 500 3, 400 Beans........................................................ 250 1,250 Peas......................................................... . .... ... ...... .... Bacon........................................................ 125 4,375 Salt herring.................................................. 250 1,600 Margarine................................................... 125 2,975 11,250 500 210,000 500 5, 200, 000 500 1,162.5 100, 000 325,000 92,500 162,500 2,875,000 9,250,000 2,500,000 4,062,500 250 125 250 125 185.5 100.5 250 125 250 125 250 125 250 125 500 250 5,500 15, 750 3,600 7,500 708. 8 2,542.5 574 912. 5 125 250 125 756. 3 152 133, 7 1---+----11----t-----1---t-----+----t-----+---+----+---•1---- Total, man............................................. .•.•.••• https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 500 250 125 250 125 •lllter. 43,697 • Rationed. 162,866 2,848,204 73,858,650 • Rationed, June to September. 21,126. 7 4,198. 7 'l'ABLE 6.-MINIMUM WEEKLY FOOD REQUIREMENTS OF Cii:ILD, WOMAN, AND MAN, AND COST THEREOF, IN GREAT.ER BERLIN, 1ANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924-C~ncluded DECEMBER, 1923, TO A.PBIL, 1924 7 January December February March April Article CHILD Quantity Cost Quantity Grams Pfennigs Grams ~ I~:~~:~----------·------·----------------------------------·-----·--·-·· ~~ ~ Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Quantity Cost Grams ptennios Grams Pfenniga Grams Pfennigs Pfmnigs ~ ~ ~ ~ 1, 1, 6g 1, 1, g:1!:~ats.-----------------------·-------·----·-·-----··-·-·---··--··-- -·---· 250 • ···---· 15• ·-·---250 -------12- ----- •250• -------10- --·-•-250 • ·------1024 3,000 23 3,000 ZT 3,000 26 3,000 Potatoea. ··------····-----·---------:--.--------~-·-·········-············ 20 1,500 18 1,500 21 1,500 16 1,500 Vegetables.-·---··----·------·········--·································· 15 126 16 126 17 126 20 126 Margarine.·-········-···················································· :~ (')250 ~ (')250 :~ (•)250 :; (•)250 t~::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Total, child •••••••••••••••••••••••• ····-··-· •••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••• _•• 213 177 199 1,800 250 250 50 8 3,000 '}{T 1,500 126 250 (') 10 26 15 21 29 186 180 WOHAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) 14 500 14 500 14 500 • 16 500 20 500 Rye bread·-··-····························-······························ 10 •••••• • .••••••• 250 10 250 12 250 Oat flakes .• ·•··--····-···············---·································· .•.•.•.... .•.•••.•.. 10 250 Barley groats••••.••.•••..•••••••• ·-···-··-····································-········----·-··---·-····----·---·- __________ ---------··-··-········-----·· 16 250 Rice_.··---·-·-··········--······-······················-················· 9 1,000 8 1,000 8 1,000 9 1,000 34 2, 000 26 2, 000 24 2, 000 28 2, 000 ~: 38:l ~:!=es···---·· •• ·-···-_ ••• ·-•.•••.•••••.••. ·-· ••.•.••..• ·····-........ 30 250 29 250 28 250 33 250 40 250 Frozen meat_·-··......................................................... 34 125 38 125 36 125 47 125 80 125 Bacon....••• ·--········-·-·········----··-·······-·····-.................. 15 125 15 125 16 125 17 125 20 125 l\llargar!ne __ • __ •••.• ···-·-·---· •• ·-. ·--· ••.•. -·. ·-·-·-·-. _. ..• . ••••. •• ••• . 2! 1----1----+----1----1-----l----f----1-----1-----~--- 313 361 Total, woman .••. --··-.··-.··-· •••• ··- __ ••.•.•. ·-····--····-··-•••.. _··--··-•• 332 320 HAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Rice ..... ····-·-··-·--·------ --- ··-- - ·-·· ··· · · ··· · · · · ·· ··--··-··-···-·--· · Semolina .•. --·-····------·-------·--····--·--··············-········-···· Beans.•••• ·-·-·-··-·--·---------··--···-·····-···············-·······--··· Bacon.••.• ·-········--·----·-·---····-·····················-·············· f:1~::-t~::::::::::::: ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 250 250 250 126 250 125 Total, man... ·- ____________ ·--·-----····-----·-·---------··--··-··-•.•.• ·····- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 16 16 20 500 200· ··-----17 47 125 19 250 17 125 695 488 20 80 26 • 25 500 260 ••••• 14 36 125 18 250 16 126 422 500 250 125 250 125 24 ••• 13 38 17 15 427 500 250 125 250 126 23 - • 13 34 18 15 1!¢ tQ HAY TO DECEMBER, 1924' Cost Quantity 1----,----,----,-----,-----""T"----""T"-------May June July August September October November December Article Grama CHILD 1,800 Rye bread_-------------------- -- -- ---- ---- -- --- ------ --------------------Rye flour _____ -- -- -_________ ------- ---- -- _______ --- _---------------------·Oat flakes ___ ·---- --·--·-·---·---·---·-·-···--------·---··-·--·--. -·--·---Barley groats. -• -- --·--·--•••• --• --• ·---·--•• --- ---·-. ·--··----·-·---·--··- 250 250 250 Peas_________ --·····----. _·--· ----. ·-------------------·-···-·-------. ··--- Potatoes _____ --··-·---···········-···. --- --·-. ·-· •-- •--•-·. •-·- -•- -·- •-· --Vegetables ___ ··--- -• --··-----------·--·--- -- --- --- --- • -- ----- • -• ---·------Margarine---······-·----·-------------·--------------·-------------------Sugar ____ ---------·-···-----·--- __________________________________________ _ Milk ____ -·-· ·------·- ______ ----··········-·--- ---·-··-- ____ ·----- ________ _ 125 3,000 1,600 125 260 (') Pfennigs 60 8 10 .... -.... ------ Pfennigs 60 Pfennigs 60 Pfennigs 60 8 7 10 10 15 5 1 31 •••••••·'rl · 33 30 16 17 18 20 29 31 8 ••••••••10. ...................... ••• ··37 ·······-25" 'rl 36 16 16 21 19 30 26 Pfennigs 61 • • • Pfennigs Pfennigs 67 67 9 10 11 • 10 ••••••••11. ····-··11 Pfennigs 67 11 ••••••••12 21 •••••••• 24" ·-······ 24• ••••••••• 24 24 24 21 18 19 19 19 20 20 17 16 33 35 33 34 24 1-----i--------,i---------,1-------,----1------i------t----+---- T ot al, child._··--------·--·---·-·-·-·-- _________ -· ______ ••••••••••••• ········-·· 199 100 600 14 14 10 250 1,000 2,000 • 10 11 36 204 WOMAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) Rye bread_ •••••• ·-.•••••••••••.• _.. ·•.•••••.••• ·- __ • _____ --·-- ---·-·-----Oat flakes. _____ --·----·----- _______________ ·----·- ___ ·----··----·----·---· Barley groats._ •• __ ···----··- _____ ·--· •• ·-- __ • __ • __ -·-·--- •• ____ ··----·--·Potatoes- -.---·-·--- --- -- --- - -- -- -- -- --·-·---• --- -·-·------ ---- - -• -·- -•· ··Vegetables_ ·---·-·-·-··--- •••. ---- -- -·-----.••• ·-.•• --•• -. ---- •• ---- • -----· Frozen meat_ ••• __ •• ··-·--····- __ ·-·-·- ____ ·-. __ -·-•• __ •.••. ___ •.. ___ • ____ _ Bacon ___ ... _. _________ ···---·.·-·-·-·--··-·-···-··-·-••• _____ ·--. _______ •• Margarine.. __ ._. ___ • _____ ---···- __ -········----···-·- ___ ·--•••• ---· --·--·- 260 260 125 125 10 28 •• ·········s. •••••• 48 29 28 32 16 30 16 15 44 193 1116 14 18 11 ----------10 •••••••••• 7. II 40 26 30 16 29 33 17 32 30 40 18 353 345 352 210 206 204 19 19 19 12 12 13 ·······-·8- ·······--8. ··········8 32 32 28 32 32 35 45 45 45 111 111 19 !,;I 0 g 1----1----1------"1--------,r----1----+----+----+---- Total, woman. ___ -·- __ ·-. _____ •• ____ • _____ ··-··-·.···--···--······- __ --········ 348 377 373 371 MAN (ADDITIONAL QUANTITIES) 24 'rl 28 30 500 22 23 30 23 Rice ••••••••••••• -•. ···-·--·--·-----------------·-------------·----··-·-·-· 13 13 11 11 12 13 H 260 13 Peas·-·---·---··-·-··········-··--·-·--·-·---·-----·--·--------·---·--···-Bacon .••••• _-· __ • -· _-·-· __________ -· -· -· __ --· _____ • --- ___ ------ ----- -----40 45 45 30 125 32 30 33 45 16 16 16 16 18 16 17 260 16 Salt herring .•••••••••••••••••••••••• -·· •••••••••••••••••.••.•••••••• -···-· 17 19 111 16 125 16 16 18 19 Margarine·-··········-·-·-····--·-······--·-···-·········-·········-······ 1----1-----1-------------,r----f----+------i----+---466. 498 4116 4115 Total, man •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• __ ••••••••••• 448 446 ~9 4431 • l liter. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis r Prices based on rentenmarks. 1 l25arama. 1 2,000Kram&. 111,000 grama to Ci:» 24 CHAPTER II,-STANDAB.D AND COST OF LIVING While, as previously mentioned, th~ physiolo~cal and psychological necessity of a certain change of food (or the necessity of a certain minimum of protein) was not disregarded, the monotony in the diet chosen for the calculation of the minimum cost of subsistenc& doubtless characterizes it as a true minimum; yet this minimum, as will be shown in the chapter on wages (pp. 125 to 134) could not be attained by the great majority of married workers having children. It will be interel!tmg,· then, to· note how such families lived before the war. The followin_g six families may serve as exam_ples: Family No. 1.-Bricklayer with wife and three cliildren of 15, 14, and 13 years of age. Total expense for food 'in April and May, 191'3, 253.35 marks·: Family No. 2.-Unskilled laborer with wife and three children of 7, 5, and 3 years. Total expense for food in April and May, 1913, . ,. 200.59 marks. Family No. 3.:......ci.ty employee, laborer, with wife and two children of 14 and 12 years. Total expense for food in April and May, 1913, • ., 231.74 marks. Family No .. 4.-City employee, gardener, with wife and two children of 8 and 5. years. Tota.I expense for food in April and May, 1913, 186.16 marks. Family No. 5.-Machinist with wife and 'one child of 19 years. Total expense for food in April and May, 1913, 259.58 marks. Family-No. 6.-Printer, with wife but no children. Total expense for food in April and May, 1913, _149.95 marks. The average food expense per capita per day was 91 pf~nnigs~ equivalent to 22 cents. · Table 7 sets forth with all necessary detail the quantities of food . consumed by each of these six families in April and May, 1913, and the total amount spent therefor. · · T.t.BLB 7.-FOOD OONSUMPTION OF SIX WORKERS' FAMILIES IN GREATER BERLIN IN APRIL AND MAY, 1913, AND TOTAL OO8T THEREOF ME~T Quantity comwned b)"Article Total Unit Beef: . Round of beef, top part Kllo __ of sirloin steak. Bolling beef---------•-- ___do__ Soup meat"(brl$ket) _______ do__ Liver----------------,-- ___ do__ ~=y Family Family Family Family Family Family Q~tlty Oost No. 1 No. 2 No. 3 No. t No. 5 No. 6 2. 250 1. 500 3. 625 O. 625 3. 075 . • 375 -------2. 750 1. 500 -,------ 3. 375 • 625 1. 000 0. 625 • 750 2. 750 L 125 ________ 3. 659 L 250 1. 250 0. 500 L 000 ________ 8. 075 3. 750 17. 309 '- 375 ·-:::::::::::::::::do::: . :::.: :::::". · :::::::: :::::::: :::::::: ___: 750______ : 750_ Udder---------------•-- Kilo __ -------- -------- ________ ________ ________ • 750 • 750 . 750 ________ ________ ________ ________ • 750 .155 ________ .875 L375 .625 3.405 • quality. . • 250 ________ ________ .-750 Minced meat, mixed ___do __________ ----···- • 500 with fat. . . Beef and pork: . . Minced beef and pork, ___ do__ • 625 • 813 ________ . 500 • 875 L 875 '- 688 Oanned meat ______ ,_: _____ do__ ________ Minced meat, best ___ do__ .375 mixed. Stewing (goulash) _________ do__ LOOO • 750 • 750 .500 -------- ,375 Pork: Small steaks from best ___ do __________ -------- ________ ----···· •••••••• • 8711 D8rt of leg. · Clio_ps, lower end of • __ do -- 2. 826 L 750 2. 500 1. 750 Ii. 876 L·ooo lom. Thin end of shoulder _._do •• L 71111 ~ •••••• _ -------- L 3711 • 500 • . ••••• 3.375 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis L8711 ••••••• .8711 • 7IIO 16. 911 1.1r. 29.911 10.60 .90 .20 .60 L80 7.76 L25 7.96 6. 811 • 3711 .90 16. 200 38. 'IO 3. 625 6. 'IO B.000 11.10 (&Au/t). Flank--·-•-·•-········ ...do •••••••••••• '.... Marl:a 25 FOOD 'TABLB 7,-FOOD OONSUMPTION OF SIX WORKERS' FAMILIES IN GREATER BERLIN IN APRIL AND MAY, 1913, AND TOTAL OOST THEREOF-Oontlnued MEAT-Concluded Quantity consumed by- Total Unit Article Family Family Family Family Family Family Quantity Oost No. 1 No. 2 No. 3 No. 4 No. 5 No. 6 Pork-Ooncluded. Kilo ____________________________ ·----l'igs' knuckles and pigs' ___ do__ l 000 1500 3. 500 ________ Loin-------------------- feet. Ears _______________________ do __ ________ l 875 _______ _ l 000 _______ _ • 760 _______________________________ _ Tripe ------------------ ___ do -- -------- -------- -------- -------- Minced pork, SBtlSOned ___ do -- -------- -------.1215 and unseasoned • • 500 2. 000 . Smoked best end ofloin____ do __ 1375 Salt lower end of loin ______ do__ ________ ________ • 375 Ham, rolled ham __________ do__ 2. '37 1. 400 1375 Lean bacon ________________ do__________ ________ ________ Fat bacon _________________ do __ • 625 • '35 2. 250 Mutton: 1. 000 -------l 760 -------- -------l 000 2. 000 • 500 ________ ________ • 250 ________ ________ • 625 ________ .125 _______ _ • 660 • 500 1. 175 a~ ---------- .~ ---. ~ = ~uey ____________________ 760- -------- -------Thin end of flank __________ do__ • 375 ________ ________ • 500 .876 • 760 Liver ______________________ do__ .375 .250 ________________ -------· .500 Not spooifted ______________ do__ ________ ________ ________ • 500 l 875 _______ _ Veal: J~ __ · Mara 1.875 7.000 3. 75 5. 60 • 760 1000 .56 !-871> ~25 7.375 .625 li.837 .125 li.635 14. 00 125 20.20 1. 796 1.250 2.500 1. 125 2. 375 . 3. !Iii . 2. 4li 4. 4li 2.80 4. 60 .70 • 35 1185 1. 760 3.85 1.000 2. 00 1500 2. 50 7.925 16. 30 1.250 2. 20 Not specified ______________ do__ 2. 760 _______________________________________ _ 2. 760 5.50 Miscellaneous: • Bones ___________________________________________________________________________________ _ .80 Skin____________________ Kilo__________________________ 1000 ________ ________ 1.000 (() OhicJren________________ .Each __ -------- 1. 000 ________ ________ 1. 000 ________ 2. 000 4. 4li Bllced cold meat and Kilo __ 5. 813 7.1133 6. 313 9. 760 7. 375 5. 314 a. 498 104.M !i:~nd of loin________ ·-1.000- ---. 500- --~-:- ________ --~-~- ____: _ li~1e:::::::::::::::: :::1~ :: --~:~- ___ :~~ ___:~- ::::::::1 t ~ ___:~- . S8US8g8. Thick S8US8g8S (bock- Each__ 4. 000 -------- -------- -------- -------- -------wurst). 8mall sausages__________ Pair __ 11. 000 5. 000 30. 000 ________ 3. 000 6. 000 4.000 55. 000 .M 4.80 FISH Lemon sole_________________ Kilo___________ 0. 500 ________ ________ l 000 _______ _ · Plaice _________________________ do __ -------- -------- 2. 500 _______________________ _ Flounders and mackerel. ______ do__ ________ ________ ________ ________ 2. 500 _______ _ Pike ___________________________ do-- -------- -------- -------- ________ ________ 1. 000 Haddock (fresh) and cod ______ do __ -------1. 643 2. 000 -------- -------- 1. 250_ Roach---------------------___ do-1. 500 _______________________________________ Herring_____________________ Each-- 15. 000 53. 000 15. 000 ________ -------- _______ _ Salt herring ___________________ do-- 8.000 -------- 4.000 -------- 6.000 13.000 Bricklinge of bloater) ____ do.- -------- -------3. 000 -------9. 000 6..125 000 Kiel spratts(kind (smoked)_______ Kilo___________ ________ ________ 0.125 ________ Smoked "salmon" herring Each__________ ________ 2. 000 ________ 1. 000 3. 000 L ~ large -variety). --- ___ Kilo ___ -------21;0 Smoked salmon-----------do__________ •• 236 Anchovies! Mediterranean __ -do •• ________ • 125 (sardelleJ. in on______________ can___ ________ 1. ooo Sardines Herring and eel in Jelly _____________________________ Pickled herring_____________ Each__ -------- 2. 000 Pickled herring rolled do-- -------- -------with cucumber ( li'ol mopa). butter ____________ Tube__________________ Anchovie uf. ___ 1.500 2. 500 2. 500 1.000 4.893 1.500 83.000 31.000 18. 000 .260 6.000 -------- -------- -------- -------________ ________ ________ .125 ________ ________ ________ • 045 .250 .361 .170 ________ ________ ________ ________ 1. ooo -------- _________________________________ _ -------- -------- -------- -------2. 000 ________ 4. 000 -------~ 2. 000 6. 000 1. 000 _______________________ _ 1.30 1.90 LOO .90 3. 70 1.80 2. 00 3. 10 1. 55 .55 1.10 .36 • 9li .M • 4li 1. 00 .25 .30 1.000 .30 39. 735 9. 946 .250 lo. 688 lo. 675 1.100 .050 109. 09 FATS Butter______________________ Kilo __ Margarine_____________________ do__ Palmine (vegetable fat) _______ do __ Lard __________________________ do__ Lard, purest ___________________ do.. Suet ___________________________ do •. Oalve's fat ____________________ do •• https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 11. 250 6. 860 7. 000 4. 250 7. 875 2. 500 ________ ________ 1.125 1. 875 4. 250 2. 695 -------• 250 _______________________________ _ 3. 000 1. 250 1. 750 .125 • 375 4. 188 3. 500 -------- 2. 500 3.175 1. 500 _______ _ -------500 -------________ • 600_ ________ -------________ •• 050 _______________________ 18. 34 .35 15. 98 16. 30 1.10 .10 26 CHAPTER Il,-STA.NDARD AND COST OF LIVING TABLB 7,-FOOD CONSUMPTION OF SIX WORKERS' FAMILIES IN GREATER BERLIN IN APRIL AND MAY, 1913, AND '.1'OTAL COST THEREOF-Continued CBBESB AND BGGS Total Quantity consumed by- Article Unit ~ Roquefprt ohees&-----·····- 1 ~{ ~l ~l ~l ~/ Quantity Kilo ___ ----·--- ________ -···-·-- -·-·---- ________ 0. 313 0.313 Romadour cheese___ ··-·-·- __ ~do-_ ________ 0. 840 ________ -······· ·····-·- ----·-·· Limburg cheese--··~····-·- -·-do.. 0. 500 • 750 Gru:rirecheese •••••••••••• _ -·-do •• -----·-· .125 L938 ·····--- 0.125 .500 Tilsft cheese•••••••••••••• -••• -do.. L 375 •••••••• L 2liO 0.125 • 500 .125 .840 =,:=-..::......_ 1.260 2.688 3.375 .250 .125 9. (MM) 7. (MM) 11. (MM) 68.(MM) -E!i__ -··-~· -·9.<MMl •••••••• ······-· ····-·-· -·--:. Cream cheese----··········· ___ do._·······---·----···-·-····-··-·-· 6.<MMl L<MMl Cheese de Soldin-·········- ___ do •• -···-··· 11.<MMl ··-·--·· ·--·-·-- ····-··· -··--·-· Cheese -from the Herz _._do.-.-·-····· 8.<MMl 42.<MMl . 6.<MMl 2.<MMl Mountains. Caraw~-··-····-·-· ___ do •• -···-··· •••••••••••••••• 6.<MMl Cost Nara L18 L36 1.90 6.36 6.69 .60 .25 1.00 2.16 .62 2.66 · 6.<MMl 2. (MM) .66 .Ill> Y'orkcheese(Quarll:) mostly ___do •• 3.<MMl 8.<MMl 11.<MMl •••••••••••••••• 8.<MMl 30.<MMl from skimmed milk. · Cheese, not specl1led_ •••••• __ .do•• ··---·-· ··---·-- -·-·--·- 6. <MMl L <MMl ________ 7. <MMl EUB···•···········-······· •• _do•• 246. <MMl 108. <MMl 228. <MMl 184. <MMl 182. <MMl 118. <MMl 1,060. <MMl 3.21> B = milk). (from sklm-. 0.. do •• ··-•·--- ·--·•··· •••••••• L (MM) 1. (MM) .76 65.42 POTATOES AND VEGETABLES Potatoes..·--·---··~·-··-··-· Kilo•• _ 145. <MMl 4L 500 Savoy cabbage_ ••••••••••• _ Each__ --··-··- 2.(MM) 84. <MMl LOOO 42. 500 67. 500 64.500 2.000 ···---·- -··-···- ~~~ba~- -·-~----- ___ gg___ ·-1. 000- --··--·- ·-··-·-- ________ C11ul111.ower_______ ~····----- ••. do... 445.(MM) 11.<MMl t ~ ----·--- ~~ 2.000 ··------ -·-····· 1. <MMl 1. <MMl L 000 6. <MMl Cabbage turniPB---··-·-·--- ••• do ___ --·----- LOOO 2.000 ------·- ······-- 1.000 4.<MMl Carrota._·--····-·-····-·--· Kilo___ ····---• 500 l. 500 3. 500 1. (MM) L 000 7. 500 French do___ 1. 250 • 21iO ····-·-• 500 2. <MMl A~--······-·······-· ___ do._. L 500 • 500 • 2liO L 2liO L 125 1. 000 6. 626 SplnllOll.-·------·-·-······- •.• do___ 1. 000 2. 500 4. 500 ·------- 3. 500 S. 000 19. 500 Lettuce, round--···-····-·· Each •• 51.000 8.(MM) 2.000 14.000 2.<MMl 6.000 83.000 Radishes.---·········-···-- Bunch_ 11. 000 12. 000 8. 000 18. <MMl 16. <MMl 65. 000 CUOllmbers.. ••••••••••••••• _ Each__ 3. 000 ···-···· ·······- ···-···- 13. 000 16. 000 Tomatoes---·············-·· ___ dn ·- ·····--· ·······- -··-·-·- -·--·-·· -·------ 1. 000 1. 000 Onions ••• --·-·············- Kilo ••• ···-···········- 1.000 1.250 1.000 3.300 6.-500 Soup Canned vegetables: • 500 2. 500 6. 000 lL 000 French beana·--·-···--· Kilo... 1. 500 •••••••• 1. 500 Peas.. •• ·-·-············· ___ do•••••••••••••• _.:__ ••••••••• ·-·--··- 1. 000 • 500 1. 500 Mixed vegetables. •••·-··-·· ·--do._.-·-·--·• 500 ·-······ 1. 000 ________ 3. 000 4. 500 Beets. ••·-·-·-·-··-········· •••do ..• ________ 1. 000 ·-····-• 500 , 500 ····---2. 000 Salt oucui:nbers ••• -.•······- Each__ 14. 000 . 3. 000 6. 000 4. 000 7. 000 7,000 4.0. 000 Pickled cucumbers_ •••••••• ------·· ·-······ -·-·---- -·------ -···-·-· ·--·---- -·-····- -··-----·· Sauer Kilo... • 500 2. 000 a. 500 •••••••• 2. 000 , 500 s. 500 beans.·-··-····-··-· ___ greens-···--·-··-··-·--··-··········-- ...•.... -·-··-········-· .•••.... ····--·--········· krllut-~·······-···-··- 33.4& .90 .36 .76 1.00 .55 1.60 1.70 6. 70 2.33 6.00 1,76 4.16 .10 .9S 2.30. 4.81 .30 2.88 .80 3.25 ,25 L~ CONDIMENTS Salt--····~·-··············· Kilo••• · 3.000 0.300 2.000 2. 700 2.000 0. 700 10. 700 [~~bay leaves::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Bovru cubes. •• ----····-·--• Each._ 4.000· 8.000 •••••••• 4.000 ..•....• 10.000 26.000 Vanllla, cinnamOD...-··-····- --···-·· ····-·-- ·-··--·- ··-••··· -·-··-·· •••••••••• ··--·- -·····-·-· Capers·--·····-·-·-·······-···-·-···--··-·--·-··-·--····-·--···--·--···-·--·--·--··--··---·-· prepared_·····-·- Kilo.__ • 400 , 200 • 200 .100 • 300 ,-----·-- 1. 200 Xhnegar·--··-·-··-·········_Liter__ ••: 500• •• : 150 •• 2. ooo ·······- •• 1.000 ___ • 500_ ...... 750. Mustard, 2.46 .46 .20 L2: .10 .15 .60 1.27 .30 SUGAB AND SWEETS I I Sugar········-·············· Kilo___ 12.5001.7.500 8.625111.250 8.500 2.7li0 HoneY--····-··-··········-· ·--do__ .-·--·-•········-····-·-·-·-··-·-·---·-·.125 • 500 -······· ·······- -·····-· ··--·-·· ·-······ Sweets . ·-·-·····-·········- _._do._. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 46.1215 .125 .500 21.40 .86 .115: 27 FOOD TABLB 7.-FOOD CONSUMPTION OF SIX WORKERS' FAMILIES IN GREATER BERLIN IN APRIL AND MAY, 1913, AND TOTAL OOST THEREOF-Continued ll'LO'V& AND ll'ilINACEOUS PBODUCTS QnantJ_ty consumed by- Article Total Unit Flour______ ••••••••••••••••• Kilo___ 3. 000 3. 050 4. 750 2. 000 6. 875 2. 750 Semolina•••• _••••••••••• -•• ___ do___ . 250 • 400 • 875 2. 000 1. 000 Rioe---·······-····--·····-· ___ do___ . 250 -·------ ··-----· ··---··· • 600 • 375 Sago_____ ···---·----······-- ___ do ___ ···--·-- .150 ······-· -······· ----·--- --·----· Oats and oat flakes--···---· ___ do ___ -··--··· • 350 ····---· ··--···· -----·-• 250 ,~~i! tc:!~·-·····-···---· ___a~----·------···----· ··1.000- -·-. 125· ---.600- -··-~· -···-··- ··--··-· -···-··· .313 -··----· •••••••• 1. 250 • 250 -··---·· -·-····· • 250 1. 250 -····--· • 250 _______ _ -······· •••••••• 2. 000 .500 2:400 1.500 .600 6.000 bags. .09 ,28 ,16 .70 .600 .250 1.625 • 250 Corn meal---·-·-···-·-----· ___ do ___ -··--·-- ······-- • 250 Corn meal (prepared with fruit Jui!'e) ________ ._. __ •••• -do ___ -·······________ .187 Noodles (vermloelll)-••••••• ·--do___ -·-····· . 400 • 600 Macaroni.-----·-----·-·--·· ___ do ___ ---····· ·------- ________ Yeast----------------·-----· ___ do ___ -······- ________ • 250 Soup cubes, split peas soup Each__ -······· 3. 000 •••••••• Maru 10.67 2. ll8 ,70 2U25 4.625 1.125 ,150 .as . .69 1.95 1. l!O .80 .66 LEGUMES Peas----·---············--· Kilo ____ ....... n liOO White beans--·····-····-··· __ do ____ -··········----· Lentils-_-·················· •• do-•• - -······· • 600 I 2. 000 0. 500 ···-··-- 1. 000 2. 000 • 750 -------- -------2. 000 •••••••• o. 600 1. 000 I 2. 750 4.000 4.000 I 1.94 1.46 2.12 RUITS, PBESEBVE8, AND ll'BUIT SIBUPS I 12. 000 • 750 221.000 39.000 13.000 75.000 2.600 .750 ,030 4.600 L600 3.600 3.40 .60 10.05 2.50 .65 6.00 3.00 1.00 .10 3.55 1.50 6.00 Kilo... 81. 600 45. 900 68. 000 33. 600 38. 875 21. 000 288. 876 Rolls_···········-·······-·- Each__ 810. 000 600. 000 Mo. 000 501. 000 604. 000 270. 000 3,335.000 Rusks ••• ·-·····-····-······ ._do__ •••••••••• -······· •••••••• •••••••• P 000 ····-·-· o 000 72.11 8L65 .15 .20 29.90 .90 .30 1.00 Apples----···········-·-···· Kilo._. 6.500 Cherries __ ••••••••••••••••••• _do____ • 250 Oranges ___ ·······--···-·-·· Each__ '6- 000 Bananas...........·-···-···- •• do_ ••• 11. 000 Lemons-······-··-········· ._do___ .····--·Rhubarb_ ••• --······-···-·- Bunch 7.000 Fruit, dried, mixed-........ Kilo __ • • 500 ·1.000 3.000 0.600 1.000 •••••••• ________ ····---• 600 ________ ·-······ 78. 000 36. 000 16. 000 46. 000 --······ 6. 000 15. 000 8. 000 ··-····· 4. 000 2.000 2.000 --···-·- 9.000 ··-··--14.000 7.000 19.000 25.000 3.000 1. 250 • 250 • 600 -···---- -···---· currant•···--···-· ~ 600 ··-····· Jams and marmalade ••••••••• do._ •• ·-······ 2. 750 1. 600 • 250 ···-···· -······Preserves••••• _•• _••••••••••• _do ___ .··-·--·- . 376 ·-······ .125 I. 000 Raspberry slrup_........... Liter_......... •••••••• L 500 •••••••• 2. 000 i'f~~~s ·-a~--·--····--··-··-··· . . BREAD, BOLL8, AND PASTRY .Bread...................... =~'.~~~-·····-····- .:i;o. __ •••••••• ·-····-· •••••••• •••. 750- ·······- •••••••• •••••• 750· Grated rolls •••••••••••••••••. do............ •••••••• •••••••• . 250 •••••••••••••••••••••••••• Baking charge•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• COl!'ll'EE, TEA, COCOA, CHOCOLATE Coffee...................... Kilo... 1. 438 0. 900 1. 625 L 750 2. 600 1. 185 Malt coffee and coffee substJtute (chicory) •••••••••••• do•• _. L 875 • 650 3. 600 .125 2. 000 • 475 Tea_ •.•••••••••••••••••••••••• do............ • 300 •••••••••••••••• ·····-·- •••••••• Cocoa •••••••••••••••••••••••• do.... • 625 •••••••• •••••••• 1. 000 1. 000 • 250 Chocolate_ ••• ~ ••••••••••••••• do.... • 600 .188 •••••••• • 600 • 600 •••••••• Cbooolate bonbons ••••••••••• do.c.. •••••••• •••••••• •••••••• .125 •••••••• • 250 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 9.398 29.20 8.625 4.92 1.68 8. 75 3.65 L20 .300 2.875 1.688 .375 28 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING ,TABLB 7.-FOOD CONSUMPTION OF SIX WORKERS' FAMILms IN GREATER BERLIN IN APRIL AND MAY, 1918, AND TOTAL CQST THEREOF-Concluded MILK Quantity oonsomed byArticle Unit Total Family Family Family Family Family Family Quantity Cost No. l No. 2 No.3 No. 4 No. 6 No. 6 -- Milk........... , . -..... Liter•• ~2.80 Buttermilk••••••••••••••••• •• do•••• 12.00 Cream (sweet and sour)._ •• •• do•••• .35 68.50 -------- 66. 76 23.50 -------· --·----- 66.20 1.00 .10 64.00 7.00 -···~40· 2. 50 .20 21. 00 83. 30 20. 00 32. 80 318. 25 39.00 Mar~ 76.27 L06 3.93 L06 78. 00 306. 60 104.20 BEVERAGES Beer, In barrels............. Liter.. Beer, In bottles ••••••••••••••• do.... 17. 00 86. 80 20. 00 •••••••• •••••••• 47. 20 69. 30 46. 20 ~~~:::::~:::::::::::::: .?J:.::: ~ ~ :::::::: :::::::: ~~ ~ :::::::: ...~.~. tt ~ Nonalcohollo drinks •• , ••••• -······· •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ···-··-· •••••••••• Cider••••••••••••••••••••••• Bottle ••••••.• ••••••.• ••••.••• •••••••• 1. 00 ··-····· 1. 00 Rum ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Brandy, gin •••••••••••••••• Glass......... 7.00 1•••••••• •••••••. .•••.••• •••••••• 7.00 8.60 6.35 L46 6. 20 .35 6. 98 .80 HISClllLLANEOUS ~~:...<::·l········l········I········ ········l········I~······· ········l··········l Meals.................. ...•..•. ..•..•.• .••••... •...••.. ..•..... ..•.•.•. ..•••••. .•.•.••••• Tips.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ······-··· 11. 25 2. 50 l. lO The great variety in the diet of the average Berlin worker before the war can be seen from the px:eceding table. It is not necessary to emphasize the beneficial effect of such food upon the mentality and efficiency_ of the workers. After 1915 such a diet was, of course, practically out of the question for the entire city population of Germany. Conditions were at their worst in 1917 and 1918, and improvement was very slow thereafter. It may be interesting to compare conditions in April and May, 1920, with those of April and May, 1913, as conditions in the spring of 1920 represent average conditions in the quinquennial period following the war. In the spiing of 1920, not even 5 per cent of the population of Greater Berlin could have the variety of food enjoyed by the average worker seven years before. Part of the foodstuffs formerly consumed in great quantities could not be had at a.IL In order to compute how much the pre-war nourishment of these six families would have cost in April and May, 1920, it is necessary to group certain articles of food. It would, indeed, be a mere juggling with.fiiures if one were to try to compute how large the expenses of a famify with a total meat consumption of 175.56 kilograms would have been in April and May, 1920, if it had insisted on eatmg specified quantities of mutton, of ham, etc. It will be necessary, therefore, to make the following assumptions: The 23 persons covered br this investigation ate in April and May, 1913, 175.56 kilograms o meat, for ·which they spent 363 marks. In April and May, 1920, 23 persons of corresponding ages were entitled to 46.84 kilograms of rationed meat at 1,038 marks. If they bought the balance, 128. 72 kilograms, from illicit traders, they https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 29 FOOD had, by always taking the kind of meat most abundant, to pay an average of 37 marks per kilogram or 4,763 marks for the 128.72 kilograms. Their meat consumption, if reckoned on the basis of the quantities consumed in April and May, 1913, cost, then, 1,038 marks plus 4,763 marks, or 5,801 marks. The same method was applied to all other items of food, all legumes being combined in one group, all flours in another, all pastes, vermicelli and the like, in another, etc. Table 8 contains the results of the investigation, showing the consumption of the six families in April and May, 1913, how much a similar diet would have cost in April and May, 1920, and the quantity and co~t of those foods which were rationed: TABLE 8.-FOOD CONSUMPTION OF SIX WORKERS' FAMILIES IN ORE.ATER BERLIN IN .APRIL AND MAY, 1913, AND COST THEREOF IN 1913 AND 1920 1920 Article Unit Quan• tlty Cost, Rationed food 1913 Cost Marks Meat, sausages, etc.••••••••••••••••••••. Kilogram.. 175. 560 PoultrY-····---·-···-·-···-···-······-·- Each...... 2 Fish, fresh_............................. Kilogram.. 13. 900 Herring •.•••• ·---··----···········-····- Each...... 114 Smoked and dried ftsh •• -••••••••• -•• -._ --·--······· ·--------· 363. 05 4. 45 10. 60 5.10 4. 50 ,~h&~~~~~.~~~:::::::::::::::::::::: -Kiiograiii: ·--aii:m- 1J:gg Margarine, palmine (vegetable fat) •• ··- -·-dO--····· 10. 200 18. 69 Animal fats-··-··-·-·--·-·----·-··-·-··- ___do_...... 22. 500 Cheese---·-·-·-·-··-··-·-··--·-·-·-····-·--·---·····-··-······ Eggs········--··-··-··-·········-·-·--·· Each .••••• 1,060 Potatoes................................ Kilogram • 445 Vegetables, fresh and canned, etc....... ..•••.•••••• ........... Condiments..•••. ·-·······-·············...................... Sugar................................... Kilogram • 46. 125 Honey, sweets..•.••••••••••••••••••••• -· •.. do....... . 625 Flour ..•••••••••..•..••.•••...••..•••••.•.. do....... 24. 050 Rice ..••••••••••..•••••..•.•••••••••••••.••. do....... 1.125 Groats, etc ••.•••.•.•••.•••••.•••• ·-····· ••• do....... 6. 275 Noodles, vermicelli, macaroni•.••••• -·· •••.. do•••• _._ 3. 900 Yeast •.••••.....•..•..••••• ·-··········· ... do .••••• .500 Soup cubes, split peas soup bags•••••• _.. Each...... 5 Legumes .•• ·-·············-············· Kilogram. 10. 750 Apples, cherries •••••••••••••••••••.••• _•... do....... 12. 750 Subtropical fruits •• ·-··················· Each...... 273 Rhubarb................................ Bunch.... 75 Mixed dried fruit .••••·-·-··············· Kilogram • 2. 500 Sultanas, currants, almonds •••••••••••••.•. do....... . 780 Marmalade and Jams••••••••••••••••••• _•.• do....... 4. 500 Fruit preserves .••••••••••·-············· ... do....... 1. 500 Raspberry slrup......................... Liter...... 3. 500 33. 48 29. 49 65. 42 33. 46 Marks 5,800. 61 Quan• tity Cost 46. 839 1,037. ll3 Marks 6fl 00 ••••••·•• ••••••••• 117 9,() 111. 80 92. 00 3?. 00 2, 718. 22 303. 32 871. 56 4611 4D 1,696.00 ••••••••• ••••••••• ••••••••• ···-····· ••••••••• ••·•·•••• •••·••··· ••··•·••• 4. 009 145. 95 10. 200 303. 32 22. 500 871. 56 •••••••••••••••••• •••••·••• ••••••••. 375. 38 400. 857 304. 75 44. 74 53.?. ll3 .•••••••• ·-······· 6. 74 21. 40 . 90 11. 37 . 70 4. 14 44.29 486. 90 11. 25 127. 34 24. 76 9. 81 22. 75 8. 00 3. 00 42. 99 88. 50 501. 80 45. 00 37 !iO 33. 50 37. 15 3. 45 .80 • 55 5. 51 4. 00 13. 20 5. 00 3. 00 1. 10 3. 55 1. 50 5. 00 •••••••.• ·-······· 36. 000 122. 40 •••••••••••••••••• 14. 950 36. 34 6. 275 9. 81 2. 875 11. 50 ••••••••• ••••·••·• ••.•••••• •••••·••• 10. 750 42. 99 ••••••••• ••••••••• ••••••••• ••••••••• ••••••••• ···-····· •••••••••••••••••• •••·••••• ·-·-····· 4. 500 37. 15 7 !iO ••••••••• ••••••••• 32. 45 29. 20 4. 92 1. 68 8. 75 4. 75 80. 20 1. 05 112. 80 6. 20 7. 13 21. 65 !)ii /JO 500. 21 1, 400. 50 458.00 63!120 104 IJO 18.00 178.25 123. 78 1, 138. 50 25. 20 1,175.50 41100 178. 25 216. 50 •·•·•••·• ••••••••• 288. 875 500. 21 60. 129 121. 05 1.875 9.75 ······-·- ••••••••• ••••••••• ··-······ •••••·•·· ••••....• .125 1.75 ••••.••••••••••••• 106. 25 212. 50 ••••••••• ••••••••• ••••••••• ·······-· •••••••••••••••••• ······-·· ••••••••• •••••••••••••.•••• Total_•••. - - - - - - · · · · •••••••••••••••••••••• 1;281.37 20. 996. 74 ·········I 3,768. oo f~sd. ············ -·· -···· ·············· .~~ · ~ ~: Cake, biscuits, etc ··--··-··-············ ··-········· ••.•.••••• Coffee.••• -· •••• ····-· •.• ·-···........... Kilogram • 9. 400 Coffee substitute••••• _•••••••••••••••••.... do .•••• -. 8. 625 Tea ••••••••••••••••••• ·-················ ...do·-····· . 300 Cocoa.••••.•• ·-······················· .....do....... 2. 875 Chocolate, chocolate bonbons •••••• ·-··· •.. do....... 2. 063 Milk, buttermilk........................ Liter...... 357. 250 Cream ••••.......•••••••••••••••••••••••.•. do....... 1. 050 Beer •••••••.......••••••••••••••••••••••••• do .••••• 383. 600 Nonalcoholic drinks •••••••·-····-·······...................... Cider, rum,gin.......................... ..•••.•••••. .••••••••• Restaurant expenses (excluding drinks). ·····-·····- •••••••••• 20168°·-25t-3 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ~: ~ 30 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING In reading Table 8, one must always bear in mind that, on account of the combinations previously mentioned, the cost in 1920 appears lower than it actually was. One example may serve: The six families consumed in April and May, 1913, 4 kilograms of peas for 1.94 marks, 2¾ kilograms of beans for 1.45 marks, 4 kilograms of lentils for 2.12 marks, or a total of 10¾ kilograms of legumes for 5.51 marks. The 4 kilograms of lentils alone would have cost in April and May, 1920, not less than 60 marks. Nevertheless, the 10¾ kilograms of legumes for April and May, 1920, appear in the table as costing only 42.99 marks because 10¾ kilograms of legumes (including, it is true, no lentils) could be bought for this amount from the municipal food administration. · Allowing, then, for a smaller variety of food, the total food expense of the six families would have increased from 1,281 marks in April and May, 1913, to 20,997 marks in April and May, 1920. A family wishing a diet similar, though by no means as manifold and as savory, to the one of seven years before would have had to spend 16 times as much. It is interesting to note in this connection that the wages of bricklayers in April and May, 1920, were only 6.2 times as high as before the war and those of printers 5.4 times as high. The average weekly food expense of these six families in April and May, 1913, was 24.51 marks, while before the war the weekly union wage of bricklayers was 41.82 marks and that of printers 34.38 marks. The average weekly food expense, with a similar diet, in A_pril and May, 1920, would have been 401.50 marks, while the weekly union wage of bricklayers was 259 marks, that of married printers 185.50 marks, and that of married bank employees with two children from 243 to 282 marks. It has just been shown how much a diet similar to the pre-war diet would have cost seven years later. It is likewise possible to state what the postwar diet would have cost seven years before. With this object in view, there has been first ascertained the rationed quantities which were distributed in April and May, 1920, to six families of the above age classification, what these quantities actually cost, and what they would have cost in April and May, 1913. We find that the same quantities which in April and May, 1920, cost 4,951 marks .wo~ld liave cost 406 marks m April and May, 1.913. Th~se rationed quantities were, •of course, not sufficient to satisfy the food requirements of the six families, as their nutritive value-amounted to only 2,337,000 calories while such families needed 3,294,000 calories,, and in fact consumed in 1913 foodstuffs with a nutritive value of 3,450,000 calories. In order to cover the balance, 957,000 calories, the same method has been applied as in computing the minimum cost of subsistence. The results are shown in Table 9. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 31 FOOD TABLB 9.-FOOD CONSUMPTION OF SIX WORKERS' FAMILIES IN GREATER BERLIN IN APRIL AND MAY, 1920, AND 008'1' THEREOF IN 1ll13 AND 1920 Cost Article Unit J::ft'erall kinds ___________________________________________ ~~am- Bationed: t!;Fille..-:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ::=~~:: :::: Suet __________________________ · -------------------------- ___ do _____ _ Potatoes •••••••••.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• do•••••• ~Te!t flour.::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::~~:::::: Potato flour --········--····-···························· ••. do_ ••••• Semolina. •..•..•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ' •••••••••••• do •••••• Oats and oat flakes ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• do .••••• Barley groatJt .•••.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••. do .••••• Barley, prepared grain .••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.do ••.••• Sago ••••••••••••••••••.••••••..••.•••• ••••••••••••••••••• ••• do .••••• Corn meal prepared with fruit Juice••••••••••••••••••••••••• do .••••• Quantity•i-----11113 1920 46. 8311 4.009 17.464 11.500 17. 250 {00. 857 36. 000 5. 750 Marki 1,037.93 145. 95 519.34 460. 00 653.66 304. 75 122. 40 8. 74 Marb 88.119 10.82 27.114 17.25 24.15 28. 06 17.28 2. (K 3. 78 31.68 2. 07 6. 56 8. 05 13.80 2. 76 11.50 10.40 6.44 .57 2.16 E¾f£:F~nl::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: :::ag:: :::: .375 12. 875 1.~ 4. 313 2.300 1.~ .180 2.875 2. 000 27.60 .69 Beans.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••. do •••••• Peas ••.••.•.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••. do .••••• 43.850 17. 250 306.36 15. 711 6.90 6.15 1.44 12.82 95.20 2. 25 Legume&- Bea:~~~illed::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: :· =~~:::::: lams••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.. do •••••• Bread••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• do •••••• Rusks••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•••••.•••••••••••••••• do .••••• Cocoa. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• do •••••• Mixture of oatmeal and cocoa (50 per cent cocoa) •••••••••••• do .••••• Milk..................................................... Liter •••• ll.200 11.829 2.875 21.367 380. 814 1.875 .125 . 750 106. 25 Total.................................................. •••••••••••• •••••••••• ID oroia=ket and by Dlicit trade: •••••••••••••••••••••••••• Kilogram • Vegetables •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•. do ..•••• ~:i:r·_::::::·.-.-.-.-:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: :::a~:=:::: Oat flakes ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••. do •••••• Beans•••.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•. do •••••• Peas ..•...•..........•................................... ... do •••••• 300. 000 700.000 25. 000 35.000 70.000 .20. 000 20.000 124. 20 47.31 11.50 176. 41 658. 711 II. 75 1. 75 34.80 212. 50 .111 1.38 2.87 .60 2.30 3.00 .40 1.80 23.37 4, 1151. 25 i===I=== 480. 00 1, 05o. 00 225. 00 28o. 00 472. 50 lSO. 00 190. 00 21.00 105. 00 7.00 17.50 35.00 7.20 8. 00 Total.···························------··· ............ .......... 2,877.50 200. 70 Grand total............................................ •••••••••••• •••••••••• 7,828. 75 606.M The supplementary foodstuffs, with a. nutritive value of 957,000 calories, cost 2,878 marks in April and May, 1920; they would have cost 201 marks in April and Ma;r, 1913. The six families which, with a similar diet to that in April and May, 1913 would have spent 20,997 marks had, then, to spend 7,829 marks in order to satisfy in the cheapest possible way their minimum food requirements. This same modest diet would have cost 607 marks in April and May, 1913, i.e., one-thirteenth of what it cost in April and May, 1920. But before the war, when there was an unlimited supply of cheap bread, cheap lard, chea:p potatoes, and cheap sugar, it would have been possible for these SIX families to secure a much more manifold and savory diet for less than 607 marks, in fact for about 520 marks, i. e., for onefifteenth of the :erice of April and May, 1920. The most striking changes in the diet of the Germ.an workingmen a.re the smaller variety of food, the poorer quality, and the reduced consumption of meat, dairy products, and practically all imported foodstuffs. The lack of variety in food during the war was due to the blockade, and after the war to the difficulties m the way of increasing https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 32 CHAPTER Il.-STANDARD AND COST OF LlVING imports caused by the money depreciation, and to the low level of real wages. The lowering of the quality was the necessary consequence of the scarcity of food, which__J>reyented competition among producers and also among retailers. While there are, of course, no statistics available as to the quality of the food, a few data can be given as to the consumption of some articles. According to calculations made by the Prussian Statistical Office, the consumption of meat in Prussia dropped from 49.02 kilograms per ca.pita. in 1913, to 31.85 kilograms in 1921 and to 29.67 kilograms in 1922. As to the inha.bita.nts of the rural districts, who had to a large extent been pra.ctica.lly vegetaria.ns before the war but who had acq_uired the lie.bit of eating meat in the army, it is safe to assume that then- meat consumption was at leai;t as high after the war as before. The decrease in meat consumption was more conspicuous in the cities, where the worki.m? class probably at no time after the war until 1924 consumed more tlian 30 or 40 per cent of the quantity it had ea.ten prior to the war. The shortage of milk was especially detrimental to the physical condition of the workers' children. Recently conditions have somewhat improved, but they are still far from satisfactory. The average daily consumption in Greater Berlin, which had been 1,200,000 liters before the war, was in 1924 as follows: · Liters January... ·------·--------------·-·-------------·-Febru.ary··--·---------·-·-------------------------March. ________ ·--·---·---------------------------~Pril-----------------·---------·------------------ May.·--------------·---------------·-------------- June.·--------·-----·-----------------------------JulY------------------------------------·---------September _____________________________ l ___________ August------------------·-----·------------------October_____________________________________________ __________________________________________ December November.·---------------------------------------- 398,000 489,000 629, 000 694,000 751,000 904,000 821,000 673,000 740,000 640,000 758,000 672,000 Butter is sijill a 1 ~ which the average workingman ca.n not afford to buy, as his daily wages genera.lly do not exceed the price of 2 pounds, and ~ have completely disappeared from his taole. The production of eggs has considerably decreased, and the imports, which before the war furnished three-eighths of the total consumption and which in 1913 amounted to 3,300,000,000, totaled 29,000,000 in 1920, 24,000,000 in 1921, and 2,300,000 in 1922. The per ca.pita consumption of other articles of food was as follows: TABLB 10.-ANNUAL PER OAPITA OONBUMPTION OF BPEOIFmD ARTICLES OF FOOD, 1913, 1920, AND 1922 Article Unit ~heirfug..............••••••.................· •Klb!fn8111··•···•···... Rice .•.......••..•..•.•....•..••....•••.•••••.... ...•• do •••••••••••••••• Green coffee....................................... ..••. ck> ............... Tea•.••.•••.•••••••••.••.. · - - - - - · · ..••.do,_ _ _ _ , Oocoa. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• do •••••••••••••••• Subtropical frnlts ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• do •••••••••••••••• Impotted spices.•••••••.•.•.•...•.•.••••..••..•••....•do •••••••.•....•.. Beer............................................. U&,,r ••••••••••••••••• Brandy•••.- •••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ·•••••••••••••do•••••••••••••••• https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1913 · 19.2 3.66 2.49 2.44 • 06 .77 4.44 .16 102.1 6.4 1922 13.6 8.81 2.07 .66 .03 L24 1. 30 .09 20. 7 L97 LM .69 .06 L88 .811 .11 3i~ ······u HOUSING 33 It must always be borne in mind, however, that the J?Cr capita consumption does not tell the whole truth about the deterioration of the diet of the working class in the cities, as both the rural population and the well-to-do in the urban districts have suffered much slighter changes in their diet than the industrial workers. HOUSING STANDARD AND SUPPLY BEFORE THE WAR Stan<lara of lwusing.-Up to the first part of the nineteenth century1 it was usual in Germany for every family to live in a house by itself-what we now call a one-family house-and this manner of living still prevails in the rural districts. In the cities and towns, however, large houses rented out in flats or single apartments-socalled a:eartment houses-have more and more taken the place of the one-family house. In 1910 there were 580,114 dwellings in Berlin. Of these, 410,237, or 71 per cent, were in houses containing more than 20 apartments. In some parts of the city the percentage of families living in such apartment houses exceeded 90. In Neukolln, a suburb inhabited mostly by workers, the proportion was 73 per cent. But Berlin with its suburbs was by no means the only city in which such conditions prevailed. In Stettin appro.ximately one-half, in Breslau two-fifths, and in Posen fully one-third of all the families lived in apartment houses containing more than 20 apartments. In western Germany on the other hand./ the apartment house had hardly come into use at all. In Dussel<iorf the percentage of families living in this kind of house was 0.8, in Cologne 0.4, in Essen 0. 3. With the growing frequency of the apartment house type, the average number of stones in a house have increased. No doubt apartments in the fourth and fifth stories, at least those in houses recently built and which are situated in the front part of the house, have· been rendered easily accessible by elevators, in which case they are frequently }?referred by tenants because of the greater distance from the n01se of the street traffic and because they receive more light. In spite of these exceptional cases-which concern only the well-to-do, as the houses in the districts inhabited by workers have no elevators-the apartments in the fourth and higher stories are considered less desirable, which is indicated by the fact that with very few exceptions the uppe:r stories contain mainly small apartments designed for the working class and that in ~eneral the rent of an apartment is lower the higher up in the house it 1s situated. Formerly, the proportion of apartments situated in fourth and fifth stories, was, even in the largest towns, very small. Sixty years ago the proportion (including all the attics) in Berlin (1861) was only 3.6 per cent, and in Konigsberg it was not more than 0.3 per cent. Before there was a modern water ~stem in the towns, which supplied the houses with running water, 1t was simply impossible to live so far above the pump in the street. It is these modern improvements that have allowed apartments so unfavorably situated to be generally used for living purJ;>oses. In 1910 the proportion of apartments in fourth and fiftli stones in Berlin and Breslau amounted to 20 per cent, in Dresden to 13 per cent, in Hamburg, Kiel, and Leipzig to 10 per cent. In Cologne, Dusseldorf, Essen, and Lubeck, on the other hand, it was below 1 per cent. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 34 CHAPTER Il.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING Another type of hygienically undesirable apartments had happily decreased in importance before the war. Experience showing that cellars are unfit to serve permanently as human habitations had led more and more frequently to building regulations forbidding the establishment of underground apartments in newly constructed houses. Thus underground apartments have been forbidden in Berlin since 1887, those still existing there having been built and :fitted up before that time. The proportion of un<lerground apartments in Berlin decreased from 11 per cent in 1871 to 3 per cent in 1910, in Altona from 9 per cent in 1890 to 4 per cent in 1910, in Kiel from 8 per cent in 1890 to 2 per cent in 1910, in Breslau from 5 per cent in 1875 to 2 per cent in 1910. Hamburg had a comparatively high proportion of und~ound apartments (5 _per cent in 1910). In the suburbs of Berlin, the greater _part of which was la.id out in the decades before the war, the proportion of underground apartments is less than 1 per cent. The same was true of the greater part of the large German towns before the war. One of the bad features of the apartment house is that as a rule it contains only a few larger apartments-those in the front part of the house facing the street-and that the side wings and rear contain innumerable comparatively small apartments that receive air and light, and frequently not too much of either, only from a narrow court. In consequence of this., the number of rear apartments that liave no windows on the street .na.s increased with the growing frequency of the apartment house. For instance, the :proportion of such apartments in Berlin increased from 28 per cent m 1861 to 48 per cent in 1910. The percentage is probably lower everywhere else, though in 1910 it amounted to 33 per cent in Ma.gdeburg and to 21 per cent in Cologne. The proportion is still more unfavorable in the case of the very small •apartments. Of 100 apartments of not more than two litjng rooms, in Berlin 70 are rear ~artments, in the suburb of Schoneberg, 79, in Madgeburg, 61, and in Cologne, 39. In the case of large apartment3 of seven and more living rooms, the proportion of rear apartments does not exceed 2 per cent in any of these cities. The drawbacks of the apartment house are aggravated immeasurably by the cramped accommodations. If we classify dwell~ acco~ to the number of liv~ rooms-the term "living room" in this case including the kitchen and habitable closets-we find that in those cities in which the apartment house is the preva~ type, apartments with not more than three liv4ig rooms are the most frequent. Whereas the increase in the number of stories and of rear apartments are drawbacks inseparable from the apartment house, tlie inadequacy of the accommodation is not unavoidable. Diminutive houses and apartments are to be found in the rural districts and there are very larg_e apartments in. the apartment houses in large towns and cities. In fact, in the course of the twentieth century the proportion of apartments of not more than three living rooms has decreased in the cities where the apartment house prevails as well as elsewhere. From 1900 to 1910 tlie percentage of this type of apartments in Berlin fell from 76 to 74 per cent, in Breslau from 75 to 63 per cent, in Cologne from 60 to 53 per cen!, and in Munich from 56 to 52 per cent. The _percentage of smau apartments exceeded 75 in Lichtenberg and Neukolln, suburbs of https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ROUSING 85 Berlin; it was between 50 to 75 in Berlin, Dortmund, Konigsberg, Posen, Stettin, Aix la Chapelle, Breslau, Dusseldorf, Essen, Charlottenburg, Cologne, Magdeburg, Munich, and Berlin-Schoneberg; it was between 25 and 50 in Chemnitz, Halle, Kiel, Dresden, Berlin-Wtlmersdorf, Altona, Lubeck, Hamburg. In Nuremberg it was 25, in Leipzig 19, and in Hanover only 11. Even a very small apartment can make a comfortable home if there are not too many occupants. An apartment consisting of one room and a kitchen 1s after all sufficient for a couple with one or two children and if a further habitable room (or closet) is added, accommodation can be found for two more children without much inconvenience. But a larger number of persons could not be accommodated. in an apartment of that size without overcrowding. In general an apartment may be considered as overcrowded which contains more than two persons per habitable room; that is, if in an apartment of one room and kitchen more than four persons, or in an apartment of one room, kitchen, and a second small room or closet more than six persons, have to be accommodated. The number of apartments that are overcrowded according to this standard is very large in the German towns and cities. Before the war considerable progress had, however, been made in this respect, the percentage of persons living in overcrowded small dwellings having decreased everywhere, even in the large cities. From 1900 to 1910, for instance, the ~ercentage fell in Essen from 47 to 37 and in Berlin from 32 to 22. In Posen (a city now belonging to Poland) it was still very high in 1910, 53 per cent of the occupants of small dwellings being thus crowded together; in Dortmund the percenta~e was 41, in Dusseldorf 38, in Aachen and Essen 37, in Breslau 33, m Munich 29, and in Cologne 27. The proportion was comparatively low in Lubeck (15 per cent), in Hamburg (14 per cent), in Dresden (13 per cent), in Leipzig (9 .per cent), ana in Hanover (7 per cent). There were various reasons for this decrease in the number of overcrowded small apartments, which was the .most satisfactory development as regards living conditions of the workers. One of these was the decrease in the number of children; another was the decrease in the number of lodgers living with families. These lodgers were chiefly of three kinds: Men who lived with their employers, lodgers in furnished rooms, and night lodgers (who rented a bed and w.ere not entitled to stay in the room in the daytime). The number of households in German towns that lodged journeymen employed by the head of the family was formerly extraordinarily high, and even 50 years ago it was not inconsiderable. Since then, however, the proportion of households with this kind of lodgers has diminished everywhere, e. g., from 1871 to 1910 in Berlin from 4.2 to 1.4 per cent, m Breslau from 6 to 2 per cent, in Frankfort on the Main from 9 to 2.7 per cent, and in Leipzig from 8.6 to 2.5 per cent. The taking in of lodgers in furnished rooms and of night lodgers was not extensively practiced in former times but became more and more frequent up to the beginning of the 20th century. It was only in the last ten years before the war that a certain improvement took place. Of all the cities in Germany, Munich and Stuttgart had the highest percentage (26) of households with lodgers. In Berlin the _proportion was 18 per cent, and in Cologne 11 per cent. Crefeld had the lowest percentage (only 5). The average percentage in the German https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 36 CHAPTER ll.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING cities was 16 and in the rest of Germany only 6. It is remarkable that the night lodgers were generally to be found in the most indifferent apartments. But even where conditions in this respect were most unsatisfactory in 1910, they had been considerably worse some time before. • The same applies to the equipment of the dwellings. The worst feature in this respect is the sanitary arrangements. Hardly anywhere has the standard, so eminently desirable from a eygienic as well as a moral point of view, that every household should have its own water-closet been even approximately realized. In 1910 only 65 :eer cent of the apartments m Breslau and Kiel were provided with separate water-closets, in Halle 61 per cent, in Posen and Stettin 59 per cent, in Berlin 47 per cent, in Essen 46 per cent, in Cologne 44 per cent, in Hanover 43 per cent, in Strassburg (Alsace) 38 per cent, in Lubeck 29 per cent, m Leipzig 28 per cent, m Nuremberg 26 per cent, in Dresden, Konigsberg, and Plauen 23 per cent, in Karlsruhe 21 per cent, and in Altona 15 per cent. Among the small apartments the J>roportion without a separate water-closet was especially high. In Breslau the percentage amounted to 85, in Halle to 83, and in Posen and Stettin to 80. Even in Cologne 67 per cent, and in Berlin 58 per cent of all small apartments liad no separate water-closet. Yet the sanitary arrangements were better than in former times. The town of Essen may be pointed out as an example of improvement in this respect. In 1900 onl;r. 22 per cent of the small apartments had separate water-closets, while in 1910 the prQPortion had increased to 38 per cent. The number of bathrooms in apartments has greatly increased. From 1890 to 1910 the percentage of dwellings provided with these hygienically important accommodations increased in Berlin from 6 to 14, in Breslau from 4 to 15, in Halle from 5 to 13, and in Altona from 3 to 8. In 1910 less than 5 per cent of the dwellings in Dusseldorf had bathrooms, and a bathroom in a small apartment was rare. In Cologne out of 62,480 small dwellings only 137, that is two per thousand, had a bathroom. Almost nowhere did the working class have such accommodations. The greatest l?rogress has, of course, been made in the more modern improvements, m the equi_pment of dwellings with gas and electric lighting. As late as 1910, however, the majority of tlie dwelljngs had neither gas nor electric lighting. In Essen, the proportion of dwellings provided with this convenience was 53 per cent, in Berlin and Chemnitz 54 per cent, in Nuremberg 57 per cent, in Hanover 65 per cent, in Konigsberg 70 per cent, in :Altona and Dusseldorf 71 per cent, in Breslau 74 per cent, in Kiel 75 per cent, in Cologne 76 J>er cent, in Posen 83 per cent, and in Stettin 87 per cent. Small dwellings provided with .gas and electric lighting were still rare exceptions m many large towns. In Konigsberg in 1910 such apartments formed 7 per cent, in Breslau 6 per cent, and in Cologne 2 per cent of the total number. , Thus the standard of dwellings in lar~ cities had in some respects declined in the decades before tlie war. The proportion of a:eartments situated in fourth and fifth stories and in the rear had mcrea ed. On the. other ·hand, a certain improvement had taken place. The number of underground apartments,· of .small and overcrowded ~partments, and of apartments with insufficient sanitary equipment; https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis HOUSING 87 had decreased. If we balance the favorable and unfavor!l,ble points of development we find a small but undoubted imll~~;ment. Housing Bupplu.-The ratio of the vacant dwe · to the existing dwellings is usually taken as the standard for gauging the state of the market, in the same way that the ratio of the unemployed to the total number of workmen in employment plus the unemployed is used as a standard to gauge the state of the labor market. The landlord considers the state of th;e mark~t to be fayo:able when the percentage of vacant apartments 1s low; m the oprmon of the tenant, on the contrary, the state of the market is favorable when the percentage of vacant a.partments is high. In the public interest it is preferable that the supply of apartments be neither too abundant nor too small. This desirable state of things prevailed for the last time in 1910. At that time people looking for an apartment could not complain of lack of supply from which to choose and1 on the other hand, the loss to the landlords through apartments remaming vacant was by no means excessive. In the following years, however, building activity was on the whole low,· and it sank to an unusually low level just before the outbreak of the war. In the four years from 1910 to 1913 the net increase in the number of dwe11.i.nj?S-that is, the surplus of newly built apartments over those pulled clown-amounted in Hamburg to 15,478, 10,670, 10,387, and 7,402, respectively, and in Nuremberg 3,078, 3,105, 3,120, and 1,260, respectively. In the 47 German towns for which we have comparable data the number of dwellings in newly erected houses fell from 68,022 in 1912 to 50,169 in 1913. The increase in the number of dwellings was no longer in relation to that in the number of households, and consequently the number of vacant dwellings decreased. From the winter of 1910-11 to the winter of 1913-14 it fell" in Cologne from 5,298 to 3,006, in Breslau from 4,308 to 2,348, in Stettin from 2,502 to 535, in Bremen from 1,636 to 412, in Essen from 1,509 to 674, and in Lubeck from 941 to 142. In the 49 municipalities for which we have comparable data, it fell.from 111,177 to 90,785, a result which is the more remarkable as the total number of available dwellings was added to in the period in question by the erection of new houses and by the incorporation of neighboring communities. It is no wonder, therefore, that the state of the market for dwellings shortly before the war differed altogether from the guite satisfactory aspect which it had offered in 1910-11. The statistics for the perioi:l from October, 1913, to July, 1914, show nothing like the percentages (6 to 10) which prevailed in Greater Berlin and Hamourg in the winter 1910-11. In only 8 of the 69 municipalities for which we have data for the period the outbreak of the war was the proportion of vacant dwe · higher than 3 per cent, and in only 33 was it higher than 1½ per cent. In only a very few cities was the supply abundant, in one-half it was decidedly short, and in many there was an actual dearth of apartments. The supply of small apartments is of special importance, as touchi~ the greatest number of people and especially the working class. For while well-to-do persons can, after all, if large apartments are scarce, make shift with a smaller one or t~ke two adjacent small apartments, the workers have no way_ out of the difficulty. They can not rent a large dwelling if a small one is not to be found. It was in small https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ~~~;d!ng 88 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING apartments that the scarcity was most severe before the outbreak of the war1 as private buildine: enterprise had failed altogether in this respect. Tne outbreak of the war relieved the situation; HOUSIWG CONDITIONS DURING THE WAR .At the beginning of the war a large number of apartments were left vacant. Unmarried men and widowers who had had apartments of their own and were obliged to enter the army gave them up. Many wives of soldiers did the same, go4:ig to live with their parents or renting part of the apartments of other tenants, either furnished or unfurnished, or moving into the country etc. Bridal couples who, before the outbreak of the war1 had rented apartments to be occupied in the autumn, gave up setting u_p separate households. From the last census (taken on different dates between October, 1913, and June, 1914) before the war to the autumn of 1914 the number of vacant apartments increased in Berlin from 27 1831 to 39,728, in Breslau from 2 1348 to 3 1838 1 in Leipzig from 1,634 to 3,2241 in Dresden from 11432 to 2,817 1 in Essen from 674 to 11278 1 and in Dortmund from 124 to 747. Only in Kiel, where immigration was from the first very active, did the number decrease (from 11538 to 1,060). In the 32 towns for which we possess data for the _period before and after the outbreak of the war the number of vacant dwellin~ increased from 72 1276 to 100,7431 but even then the proportion of vacant apartments reached 3 per cent in 11 towns only, while in 7 it did not exceed 1½ per cent. Thus, though the number of vacant dweµings was far larger than in the year before the war1 with its painful scarcity of accommoda-· tion1 yet it did not materially exceed the normal average in time of peace. In comparin~ the pro_portion of vacant apartments in the winter of 1910-11 with that m the winter of 1914-15 we find an increase in 15 cities and a decrease in 11 cities. While a large number of apartments connected with business premises and other large and medium-sized apartments became vacant, the supply of small apartments suitable for workers, though it was nearly everywhere larger than in the :year preceding the war, did not in general exceed the normal supply m time of peace. If the outbreak of the war and its consequences altered the conditions r0j?U}ating the supply of dwellings in an unusual manner, the longer tli.e war went on the more the state of the market continued to develop on lines diverging from those of normal times. The number of existing dwellings continued to increase by the erection of new houses and t~~lfl!~titioning of large dw~, and to be reduced by fires, by the p down of houses, by the a_ppropriation of dwellings to business purposes, and by the thro~ oftwo or more apartments into one1 but the erection and the _pulling down of houses became rarer and rarer occurrences, till at last building ceased almost completely. (.According to statistics of the Federal Statistical Office for :37 German towns the number of apartments in newly erec.ted houses .in the period from 1912 to 1917 amounted to 61,335 in 1912, 45,220 in 19131 321330 in 1914, 13,171 in 1915, 4,685 in 1916, and 1,712 in 1917.) The partitioning of dwellings was a comparatively frequent occurrence and consolidation of apartments was rare, there being little demand for large apartments. The diverting of apartments to business purposes ceased almost entirely, owing to the abundant https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis HOUSING 89 supply of workshops and business premises on the market. The only place where it was resorted to, to some extent, was in Berlin where many apartments were hired by corporations organized to meet the exigencies of the war. On the other hand, hardly anywhere were offices converted into living apartments to any appreciable extent, and the same may be said of the release of a_partments that had formerly been declared unfit for use. The result was that the number of available dwellings did not increase much in the course of the war. The longer the war continued the more did the establishments set up exceed those that were broken up, in spite of the continual calls to the front. Disabled soldiers and other men unfit for active servic_e set up households of their own. Women who had married during the war and whose husbands were still at the front took aJ>artments of their own either before or after the birth of children. The result was that in the end the proportion of occupied dwellings increased considerably, and so the proportion of vacant dwelling!:! was again reduced. In 33 of 41 cities tliere were fewer vacant dwellings in the winter of 1916-17 than in that of 1915-16, the total number of vacant apartments having decreased from 97,329 to 86,602. In 1916 the proportion of vacant apartments was higher than at the last census oefore the war in 57 of 75 cities; in 17 1t had decreased below the pre-war ~e. In 31 cities the proportion was higher than in 1910-11 and m 25 it was lower. .Although very_ many large and medium-sized dwellings and dwellings connected with business premises were still vacant, the total supply was about normal. Small apartments for the working class, not connected with business premises, were very scarce in many places. In 1917 accommodations were as scarce as before the war, and at the close of the war there were scarcely any vacant dwellings fit for use available anywhere in Germany. The standard of housing accommodations in the la~e cities became worse and worse during the war. The old infenor a:eartments deteriorated more and more and even the apartments built on the eve of the war became prematurely old and the worse for wear. In peace time inferior apartments were eliminated, not only by pulling down the houses, but by their being declared unfit for use by the authorities. During the war these authorities kept their eyes shut. Where immigration was lively, and this was the case in many towns, they_ even permitted underground dwellin~, whose use had been prohibited, to be reoccupied. Overcrowding was no lo:nger prevented. The demand for lodgings made it necessary ~ lower the standard as to apartments. SITUATION SINCE THE WAR An insufficient supply of dwellings would have been unavoidable in any case at the close of the war, for then the unmarried men and widowers who had had apartments of their own before the war, but had _given them up on entering the army, returned from the front and looked for new apartments. The same is true of a great number of soldiers' wives wlio, in the absence of their husbands, had lived with their parents or with bthers. As might have been expected, a large numoer of new households were set up. The situation was https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 40 CHAPTER II,--STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING still further aggravated by circumstances connected with the issue of the war. After the conclusion of the armistice, a large number of fugitives and returning emigrants flowed into the country and increased the numbers of those looking for accommodation. These peo:ple included Germans from abroad, inhabitants of the ceded territories, and f!).gitives of foreign nationality from the ne~hbotjng countries in the East. The increase in the number of houseliolds due to this immigration was at least 250,000. In the occupied territory the scarcity of accommodation was intensified by the necessity of placing a large number of dwellings at the disposition of the occupymg troops. , - The ouilding of new houses met with the greatest difficulties. In the eourse of the war the production of building materials had been reduced to a minimum. Of about 18,000 brick kilns 8,000 stopped work immediately on the outbreak of the war. In 1915 another 5,500 and in 1916 another 900 followed their example. At the close of the war only 700 kilns were at work. In the years 1919 and 1920 the number increased slowly to about 1,200 or 1,300. The prices of building materials, however rose enormously. At the same time a serious iack of workers was experienced in the building trades. Many- had been killed in the war or had returned with inJuries impairing their work4lg :eower or _preventing them from carrying on thell' trades. A considerable number had clianged their occupations during the war and had gone into the mines or into the war mdustries where they could earn higher wages. Only a few of these men returned to their old trades after the war. In the building trades it was almost impossible to secure a fresh supply of young men, because they preferred to enter other trades where prospects were less uncertain. Tlius the number of workers in the builcling trade fell from about one and three-fourths millions in 1914 to about one million in 1920. The individual workman, moreover, did less work than before the war, because inadeg_uate nourishment reduced his physical ability to work and political excitement interfered with his application to his work. Under these circumstances the Government to remedy as far as possible the most serious grievances connected with the scarcity of accommodation, took measures (1) to regulate the relations between landlord and tenant; (2) to control the a.isposition of existing housing facilities; and (3) to stimulate building enterprise. 1. The legislative measures for the frotection of the tenant materially restrict the landlord's i;ight o givip.g notice and limit the amount of the rent. The basis for the calculation of the rent is that paid on July 1, 1914, and the increases permitted were for a long time very moderate, e. g., in Berlin, at the end of 1920, 30 per cent and early in 1922, 70 per cent, whereas the minimum cost of subsistence at the end of 1920 was 11 times as high as before the war, and in Janu~, 1922, 19 times as high. 2. The legislative measures relat~ to the control of the exis~ housing accommodations authorize tlie communes to forbid the pull= ing down of buildings and the appropriation to other purposes of rooms that up to October 1, 1918, had been used as living rooms. The communes may also allot vacant rooms that are fit to live in to persons in seareli of apartments, and cause unused offices or busi·ness premises to be fitted up as living rooms. Finally, they are https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis HOUSING 41 authorized to seize occupied offices or business _premises and part of occupied apartments. Apartments owned by mdustrial or agricultural concerns, which were built for the accommodation of their salaried employees or workers, and newly erected houses are not subject to seizure, these exemptions being intended to stimulate building enterprise. Some communes waived their right of seizing part of unnecessarily large apartments in case the owner agreed to pay a sum sufficient to provide an equal number of new rooms. 3. It was evident at the outset, however, that all legislative measures for the appropriation of existing house room for living purposes could not bring about a material improvement in the supply of apartments, and that the only: way to achieve this would be to encourage by all possible means the building of new houses. Yet, private builders could not be expected to engage e..""{tensively in building operations so long as a satisfactory return on the invested capital could not be _guaranteed. The situation in 1918 may be described as follows: The cost of erecting an apartment had increased on an average about 200 to 300 per cent as compared with pre-war time, but rents had not risen in proportion. They were in geneyal just sufficient to cover the expense of keeping existing apartments in repair, but not sufficient to insure an adequate return on the capital reg_uired to erect new apartments. But even the raising of rents could liard.ly induce private capital to engage in building, because of the uncertainty as to the future trend of the cost of building. In 1917 and 1918 it was supposed that the rise in the cost of building then experienced would be transitory, and that when the immediate consequences of the war were over it would fall again, though not to the level of pre-war prices. If, after rents had first been raised, a retrograde movement of prices had set in, the cost of building in the following years would have been reducea and rents might have been expected to fall also. In that case rents fixed for newly built houses on the basis of the actual price of building at the time could hardly be maintained. Even if the increased rents had at first insured a satisfactory return on the capital invested in new houses they could not continue to do so. It was the uncertainty re(J'arding the trend of prices and not the control of the disposition of the existing accommodations (as has often been asserted) that prevented private capital from engaging in building to any extent. If, therefore, private building enterprise was to be revived, the only way was to secure out of public funds an adequate return on the capital invested in building operations, public subsidies being paid to cover that part of the cost of building the interest on which tlie prospective rent of the house would not cover. Such subsidies have been granted to a large extent for the building of dwelling houses in general, as well as for miners' houses. The Commonwealth, the States, and the communes have also granted subsidies toward the unremunerative part of the cost of ouilding houses for officials, salaried employees, and workers employed in Government establishments and in public-service enterprises. A part of these funds was raised by a building tax on the old houses. All these and numerous other measures, however, did not stimulate building enterprise greatly. Whereas during the war 250,000 ap:1rtments were erected, in tlie period from 1919 to 1921 ori.ly about the same number were built. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 42 CHAPTER II.-STANDABD AND COST OF LIVING Table 11 shows the net increase in dwellings in German cities of over 100,000 inhabitants for each year from 1913 to 1923. TABLB 11.-NET INCREASE IN DWELLINGS IN GERMAN CITIES OVER 100,000 IN• HABITANTS, 1913 TO 1923, BY YEARS ~ ~lid K• City Aix la Chapelle___________________ Altona ___________________________ 1913 1914 1915 1916 1917 1918 1919 298 938 565 237 587 709 «2 250 170 18 15 54 14 20 28 16 I 13 11 19 138 111 9 13 9 195 635 ~~i!~:::::::::::::::::::::::: Bochum__________________________ 3,096 Berlin•--------------------------- 311 --in" Breslau Bremen___________________________ ___ -··-------------------_ 1,053 1,328 Brunswick _______________________ 445 188 177 ---64,521 445 ------ ------ -----· Chemnltz ________________________ 321 314 377 Cassel __ -------------------------3,745 1,885 412 Cologne _________ .---------------- 2,442 1,813 1,366 Crefeld ___________ ---------------73 Dortmund _______________________ 637 259 1,341 Dresden_------------------------- 2,376 1,001 E:=ii:r:ri----------------------Elberfeld _________________________ a,576 --ozr a,"iii2289 i;5i8- 1,068 305 275 98 Errurt____________________________ 546 298 106 Essen ____________________________ 1,013 11911 869 Frankfort on the Main ___________ Gelsenklrchen ____________________ 2,563 l, 1146 9711 Halle _____________________________ 335 390 217 323 51 Hambom_________________________ 507 448 358 Ham burg ____ ·------ __________ ·-_ 7,402 3,050 1,4511 631 1,311 534 Hanover_--···-·•···------------· Karlsruhe ________________________ l, 677 510 350 42 Kiel ______ ------·--·--·--------·-- 241 180 -·---- 1,726 769 :E:~~~~~~!::::::::::::::::::::::: Lubeck__________________________ • 2,788 2,467 254 313 Magdeburg_______________________ 1,091 Mainz _____________________________ ···-·----------------- 113 --iioMannheim 1,582 1,084 Mulhelm _______ ------· __________ 656 420 Munich __________________________ Munchen-Oladbach______________ 3,445 1,624 118 Nuremberg Munster. _________________________ --------------------·- 363 245 1,260 1,084 Plauen_ ·--------·--·----·--- •____ 754 --389Stuttgart _________________________ 332 Stettin __ .•·---··-·----·---------· 2,104 1,649 1 472 1,147 75 292 26 485 116 577 2 56 262 --i82645 -----1 23 --isii- ---77161 145 75 127 544 3 265 321 1 121 63 1911 874 270 14 100 53 391 64 47 11 177 134 11 95 11211 141 35 63 11 5 79 26 66 409 --iiiii28 304 1,028 1920 1921 1922 1928 71 182 152 341 33 '¥1 200 539 263 3,057 445 480 536 123 «7 «7 3,863 520 626 1,259 85 534 256 232 294 56 ------ 730 1,205 920 756 1,196 950 882 309 87 217 169 169 787 410 4112 23 272 188 276 393 1178 2,750 2,531 l 60 196 330 235 294 1,158 5114 82 183 807 944 715 r,77 49 392 536 ---ii" 6 345 615 869 17• · 3 97 37L 367 ----3- 145 578 415 628 251 603 558 196 511 1,404 1,318 146 27 229 1,171 457 864 18 14 47 306 469 196 67 5 80 280 202 341 1 1 IJ 160 270 313 8 65 452 1,416 2,187 2, 6.10 13 15 193 674 2115 445 19 18 202 339 3911 509 66 125 140 181 272 267 88 136 58 288 386 539 33 39 298 565 518 1,174 7 169 439 934 616 485 32 154 78 196 195 284 167 --223- 230 416 266 --,-iii- 15 684 191 679 211 15 31 436 98 388 18 222 607 1,469 748 1,441 244 306 ---i6- --i23- --iiiii- --939- --600- 1,061 11 122 102 143 ---,-6- ---1T lU, 539 656 275 46 913 852 939 37 378 20 26 65 13 100 4 45 114 5 65 42 9 150 6 96 ---ar ------ ------ ------ ------ ------ 636 432 2,663 554 845 702 1,356 856 176 170 1,095 1,013 6111 501 741 3,065 311 517 258 483 882 370 284 2114 744 450 958 110 268 821 182 547 687 Decrease. • 1913 to 1920, Berlin without suburbs; 1922 and 1923, Greater Berlin. Table 12 shows the cost-of-building index for each month from January, 1921, to June, 1923, covering the prices of materials and the cost of building, and showing also index numbers of the dollar exchange rate of marks. Buildmg materials are divided into three groups: Raw materials (brick, lime, gypsum, cement), lumber, and miscellaneous (rod iron, shaped iron, winclow glass, linoleum). The cost of building is for two factory: buildings (one simple factory building and one factory building with office rooms) and for dwelling houses (from January, 1921, to October, 1922, one small one-family house, one tenement house, one fine apartment house; from November, 1922, to June, 1923, one small one-family house and one tenement house). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 48 HOUSING TABLB lt.-INDEX NUMBERS OF COST OF BUILDING IN GERMANY, JANUARY, 1921, · TO JUNE, 1923, BY MONTHS [July, 1914-1) Building materials Building cost per cubic foot Year and month Mlscel• Raw materlala Lumber laneo118 1921 January•••••••••••••• February••••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••• 14. 71 June ••••••••••••••••• July -·•·············· August••••••••••••••• September••••••••••• October.••••••••••••• November ••••••••••• December•••••••••••• 16.41 15.62 15.47 15.52 16.49 22.48 28.92 }t:· tJ:rll ................. 16.66 15.40 BY ••••••••••••••••• 1922 January ........... February •••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••• tJ:rll. ................ ay ••••••••••••••••• June ••••••••••••••••• July ................. August••••••••••••••• September••••••••••• October•••••••••••••• November ••••••••••• December:··········· 1923 January•••••••••••••• February••••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••• 32.43 42.27 52.65 65.42 88. 72 106. 73 126. 51 155. 88 ?.86.04 452.-13 944. 50 1694.26 2625.6 6649.l 8570.1 7755 ~················· ay ••••••••••••••••• 8102 June ••••••••••••••••• 14697 Total Factories Dwelling .holl8es Total Dollar ex~ marks (11113-14 ~l), . 20.26 19.58 19. 73 21,:H 24.23 25. 73 32.36 36.93 14.68 14.87 14.94 15.40 15.39 15.57 16.02 16.51 17.15 • 18.30 23.58 29,27 11,78 12.40 13.54 18.54 13.23 15.63 17,09 18. 54 ~-42 24.38 26.04 27,09 11.79 18.31 14.14 14.53 14.53 15.40 16.93 18.85 19.89 26.32 26.13 27.17 1L79 18.09 13.99 14.28 14.~ 15.46 16.97 18. 78 20.02 25.09 26.11 27,15 111.46 14.60 14.88 15.13 14.M 16.52 18.27 20.08 24.99 36. 78 62.64 46. 72 32.15 39.50 48. 70 64.35 32.19 37.19 45.32 56.63 37.65 44. 85 61.99 82.15 85.39 88.69 83.34 96.36 29. 70 34.~ 41.39 54.32 69.33 114.09 146.16 ~.89 344. 94 610.9 960.4 2017.5 30.33 34.95 42.37 65. 74 71.62 96.64 142. 86 46.69 49.51 67. 70 69.32 69.11 75.62 117.49 270.26 349.18 767.73 171L08 1807.88 12.07 12.10 12.60 18.:H 13. 73 14.49 15. 45 16. 66 17.49 18.83 22.48 27.30 29.85 33.10 37. 70 73.69 112.13 179.53 405. 63 640. 78 948. 97 2937.53 88114. l 6117.1 6270.4 6278 7660 16256 22.as 23.11 22.01 2i.Oli 117.26 214.69 86L07 S60. 92 135L08 2182.82 8146.5 8902.0 9007.8 8412 10659 26311 98.87 1~.69 170.30 329. 76 627.10 99Ll6 2107.42 2939.6 6722. l 7852. 2 7002 ~5 16396 60.00 78.48 104.30 135.94 178.13 321.36 541.2 9114.8 1833.8 2802.1 4416. 7 5182.3 5703 7109 14063 ' 2796.5 4190.2 5365. 9 5688 6991 14363 200.45 339.04 693.5 969. 1971. 5 2797.9 4246.8 53~ 5692 7021 14288 4281 6650 5048 5826 11355 26202 Table 13 shows the cost-of-building index for each month from July, 1923, to November, 1924. These figures are not exactly comparable with those of the prece<!ing table as the gx:oup of raw materials includes iron and roofing board, the base for the lumber-price indexes has been changed, and "miscellaneous" comprises materials for the inside of the building such as pipes, window glass, etc. The cost of buil~ is computed for an apartment of four living rooms, having a total of 1,200 net square feet, on an upper floor of an apartment house. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 44 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD A.ND COST OF LIVING T.6.BLB 13.-INDEX NUMBERS OF COST OF BUILDING IN GERMANY, 1ULY, 1923, TO NOVEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS (1913-1) Building materials Year and month Raw mat.erials Lumber MiBcellaDeOIJ8 Dollar exchange Building rateofmarb 0081, (1913-1' Total -1) 11123 86937 July ••••••••• 54369 96625 67385 64813 August ••••••••••••••••• 1235760 110803:. ™30t3 1207506 1268512 28131781 261131814 lM3S8021 September•••••••••••••• 23004822 38348326 I 118115 l9899 19031 19183. 113126 October••••••••• ;. ••••••• 1 862.6 1 11.0.s I 790.8 1891.9 1778.6 November•••••••••••••• I Lli6 IL66 I 2.33 I 1.611 11.49 December •••••••••••••• 1924 January •••••••••••••••• February ••••••••••••••• March •••••••••••••••••• tt::.····· . y •••••••••••••••••••• June •••••••••••••••••••• July •••••••••••••••••••• August ..••••••••••••••• September•••••••••••••• October ••••••••••••••••• November •••••••••••••• 11.41 I 1.26 I 1.21 • 1.20 I 1.20 I 1.18 1 1.14 1 1.14 I 1.20 '1.20 I L32 IMllllous. . IL66 IL47 IL41 I 1. 51 I 1.65 1 LM I 1.33 IL28 I 1.49 1 L48 1 L50 • Billlons. 11. 76 11. 411 I 1. 411 1 L51 • 1. 50 I 1.50 I 1.49 I 1.46 I 1.46 I 1.41 I 1.44 11.49 I 1.33 IL29 •1.32 • 1.34 I 1.30 I 1. 23 I 1.22 I 1.30 11.29 •L38 I 1.34 I 1. 27 I 1.2' I 1.27 I 1.32 I 1.33 I 1.25 I L27 I 1.47 I 1.49 I 1.60 8'186 1100632 123.1 16017 1 622.8 11 •1 •1 •1 •1 11 •1 •1 •1 •1 •1 •1 • Based on rentemnarks. Table 14 shows the building cost for 101600 cubic feet (net) of· living room in an apartment house and for a one-family house of 12,400 cubic feet (~oss), containing three living rooms, closets,..cellar, and garret in specilied months, 1914 to 1923. · · 14.-BUILDINO COST FOR ONE-FAMILY HOUSES AND APARTMENTS IN GERMANY, 1ULY, 1914, OCTOBER, 1921, AND 1ANUARY, 1922, TO 1UNE, 1923, BY MONTHS TABLE ment Onetamlly feet) cubic feet) .Mara .Mara Apart- Month 1914 July•••••••••••••••••••••••• ~~ house (12,400 6,700 6,125 144,000 168,000 165,000 195,000 240,000 315,000 410,000 636,000 182,000 210,000 262,000 340,000 '°3,000 682,000 1921 October •••••••••••••••••••• 1922 January .....•.•.•••••••.•.. February••••••••••••••••••• lltr.arch ••••••••••••••••••••• u:·:::::::::::::::::::::: June ••••••••••••••••••••••• ment Onetamlly feet) house (12,400 eubicfeet) Apart- Month ~~ 1922 .Marica July...............•.•••••.. 810,000 August... • •••••• 1,275,000 ~ b e r ••••••••••••••••• 2,065,000 3,675,000 November ..•..•..•.••..•.. 6,000,000 December .........•.•••.••. 11,700,000 1923 24,800,000 t:~·:::::::::::::::::: 31, 600, 000 33, 7SO,OOO tJ>:·:::::::::::::::::::::: 79,000,000 .Marb 823,000 1,226,000 2,066,000 8,618,000 6,600,000 12,260,000 25,200,000 32,400,000 34,125,000 89,300,000 The continuous increase in the cost of building, which on the whole exceeded the increase in the cost of living, was an impediment to building, not only because people could not afford the expense, but also because it rendered anything like a reliable estimate of cost impossible. A building whose cost liad been estimated at 3,000,000 marks might, when completed, have cost 60,000,000 marks or more, and thus meant ruin to its owner. Many buil~ were therefore left unfinished and in this condition sold to persons wnose means enabled them to finish the buildings. To prevent the consequences of this uncertain state of affairs, great efforts were made to provide some https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ROUSING 45 guaranty that the actual cost of erection of a building would not exceed the estimate. This was possible, at least as regards part of the items, if the necessary matenals and fittings were bought as soon as the resolution to build was definitely taken. But so uncertain was the state of the buil~ industry that even this precaution did not protect the builder agamst loss.., unless he took actual possession of the materials and articles J?urchased and warehoused them himself. When this was not done, 1t often happened that purchased goods which had been ke_J>t in stock by the dealer were not forthcoming when called for. This, of course, led to further difficulties and litigation, and in the end the owner had generally to bear the loss. The w~es always remained a variable item, and such variations involved a nsk to the builder that could in no way be avoided. As only about one-half of the estimated cost of a building can be definitely fixedby the purchase of materials, etc.-the other half will always constitute a considerable risk to the builder. It was the varying item of wages that caused the chief difficulties in agreements between owners and contractors. A complete system of scientific calculations was necessary to ascertain, for instance what part of the cost of erecting a cubic foot of masonry was chargeable to materials, to transportation, to wages, to superintendence, to workers' insurance, to general expenses, to the profit of the contractor, etc., and which of these items were to be considered as fixed and which as varyjng. The trouble caused the supervising architect by these various calculations was enormous. The arrangement aimed at in most cases was that only the wages should be considered as variable, and that as regards his profits, the general expens~.., and various other items the contractor should agree to a liberal settlement with the owner. The negotiations on these points were difficult and took a great deal of time; the results differed, depending greatly on the good will of the contractor. In any case the risk run by both contractor and owner was very•great. Generally speaking, only people who were engaged in business, and whose income therefore mcreased more or less m proportion to the depreciation of the money value, could build in the time of inflation. For this class of people the high prices did not make much ., difference, tho~h almost every business undertaking in Germany was on the decline in spite of tlie nominally high figures of sales and profits. The formerly well-to-do classes who had lived on the returns of their capital were hopelessly pauperized. As far as building was concerned, this class of the population was out of the running altogether. On the whole, therefore, only the business men, the manufacturers, the landed proprietors, and foreigners from countries ha'7ing a sound currency could engage in house building. The buildings erected in Germany were, therefore, chiefly office buildings, factories, and agricultural establishments, but included also a considerable number of dwelling houses for the above-mentioned classes. As regards the supply of dwellings for the mass of the people the erection of residences for a few newly rich persons meant nothing. The erection of dwelling houses proper in Germany has virtually ceased. Very few apartment houses have been erected in German cities since tlie war, as the rents were kept so ridiculously low by the law restricting house rents that there was no prospect whatever of 20168°-25t-4 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 46 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND' COST OF LIVING ma~ a profit on a house built under prevailing conditions. Houses built smce the war are not, it is true, subject to the restrictions on rents. But this exemption did not help the owners of new houses, as, if rents of old houses were, say, about 10 times as high as they were in :pre-war time and the cost of building 1,000 times as high, it would be rmpossible to expect tenants to pay a rent for new houses 100 times higher than that for old houses. Under such circumstances it would have been foolish to build houses for rent. Not only was the poi;isibility of erecting new dwelling houses for rent destroyed by the restriction on rents, but practically all the houses for rent in German cities got out of repair, because the rent was insufficient to pay for the most trifling repairs. The renewal of a single kitchen sink re~uired a whofe year's rent of a large Berlin apartment house. This is the reason also that large areas of bare wall from which the plaster has fallen are to be seen on buildings on all streets and that all German towns ·and cities are beginning ~o show a neglected appearance. All this would have been tolerable if the working class had actually profited by the low rents, but this was not the case. In ~ wages, the low rent was fully taken into account, and the main effect of ~he rent restriction law in the long run was that the German emplot!°ghad the benefit of having his employees lodged for practically not · . Conditions in rural districts were on the whole not much better. In the first year after the war the erection of small dwelling houses in the country was carried on actively, being encouraged by considerable grants from the Government. But liere, too, the influence of the depreciation of the currency very soon made itself felt. Even before projected building operations were completed, the means granted by the Government proved to be totally inadequate in consequence of the continuous advance of prices. The situation was further aggravated by the fact that societies formed on cooperative principles for carrying out such projects had only very limited means at their disposal. In consequence, most of the housing projects failed before they were half carried out. Almost all the extensive, carefully prepared, and architecturally promising projects for settling the surplus town population in the country thus came to naught. Only workmen's settlements of the more important industrial works could be carried on. In the last three years the owners of industrial works have received stro~_encouragement and material aid from the Government toward providing houses for their workmen. The owner of an industrial establishment employing more than 20 workmen may escape the special tax which may be imposed on such establishments by 1:iuilding -houses for his workmen, and the law also allows him to deduct the building cost from his taxable income. Besides settlements built by private industrial establishments, a certain number of dwelgng houses have been built by a few progressive municipalities. Dwellirigs for Government employees have also been erected by the Ministry of Labor. But even when all these are considered there still remains an almost absurd discrepancy between the urgent demand for apartments and house room and tlie number of new houses built. According to the estimates of various experts, one and one-half million apartments are now needed in Germany. fie worst feature of this scarcity of available apartments is that there is no possibility of employing the only effectual means of relief https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 47 FUEL AND LIGHT that is, buildine: a sufficient number of new houses. This was not possible when tiie rent restriction laws kept the rents (calculated in aollars) down to one-tenth in 1921, to one-fiftieth in 1922, and to one one-hundredth or less in 1923, but neither is it possible now when the rents are three-fourths of what they were in pre-war times. Table 15 shows index numbers of rent for two rooms and a kitchen from January, 1922, to December, 1924, by months: TABLE 15,-INDEX NUMBERS OF COST OF RENT IN GERMANY, 1922 TO 1924, »Y MONTHS [1913-14-1] On basis of dollar exchange rate of marks Month 1922 1,1924 1923 1922 ;January__________________________________ _ ___________________________________ _ March February··--·---------------------------- tr:ff-::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: July ______________________________________ _ lune_----------·-----------------·-·-·---- August---------------·-·-·····--······---- -····--------------------------_ September. October __________________________________ November __ ····--··-·----------···----·-December-----···--·----·----·-···-···-·-t 2.36 2. 40 2. 50 2. 87 3.00 3.13 3.43 4. 03 4.17 7.95 11.33 16. 52 :tlased on rentenmarks in this year. 38 .'58 113 181 216 301 714 4932 ,3 '54 22 1218 I 0. 29 .34 .38 .53 .55 .57 .68 .70 .70 .73 • 74 .74 2 Mlllion. 0. 05 .05 .04 .04 .04 .04 .03 .015 .012 .010 .007 .009 1923 0.009 .009 .022 .031 .019 .011 .008 .004 .013 .009 .04 .22 11924 0. 29 .34 .38 .53 ,55 .57 .68 .70 ,'10 ,'13 ,'14 .74 •Billion. The reasons why the low rents preclude much building are as follows: 1. .A13 one-third of the rent has to be paid as a special rent tax, the proprietor of the house gets not three-fourths, but only onehalf of the pre-war rent; 2. The cost of building is 60 per cent higher than before the war; 3. The general rate of interest has increased so much that houses can not be built on a sound business basis unless the rents are much higher in proportion to the cost of building than before the war. FUEL AND LIGHT From 1916 to 1921 the coal supply in most German cities was so scarce that, in general, workmen found it impossible to get sufficient fuel adequately to heat their dwellings, ana this condition did not materially improve when coal became more plentiful, as its price was then prohibitive. For the same reason tliey were obliged to be as economical as possible as regards lighting. It became quite customary for workers' families to go to bed early in winter in order to escape freezing in their unheated quarters, and in summer to walk in the streets after dark as they could not afford light in . their dwellings. Table 16 shows all changes in the price of Ruhr coal from April 1, 1914, to December 31, 1924, both in paper marks and in gold marks (calculated on the basis of the exchange rate of the mark m Amsterdam up to the end of 1919 and of the dollar exchange rate of marks in Berlin from and after 1920). Up to September, 1923, the gold-mark prices calculated on the exchange rate of the paper mark · were sometimes higher and sometimes lower than before the war. From and after September 17, 1923, gold prices were introduced, which were at all times considerably higher tlian those before the war. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 48 CHAPTER Il.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING 'l'ABLB 16.-PIT PRICE PER TON OF RUHR COAL, APRIL 1, 11114, TO DECEMBER 31, 1112' Gold marks 1---...-----.---- Paper marks Period Lowest Highest 1L25 1L26 10. 79 11.68 12.29 1L39 11.69 12.56 19,50 18.01 20.98 24.51 Apr. 1 to luly 31, 1914.................................... 11. 26 Aug. 1, 1914, to Mar. 31, 19Ui............................. 11. 211 Apr. 1 to Aug. 3!!_ 1916.................................... 13. 25 Sept. 11 1915, to uec. 31, 1916 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 14. 25 lan. 1 io Apr. 30, 1917 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 16. 25 May 1, to July 31, 1917••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 18. 211 Aug. 1 to Sept. 30, 1917................................... 2L 90 Oct. 1, 1917, to Aug. 31, 1918............................. 24. 30 Sept. 1 to Dec. 31, 1918. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 26. 85 lan. l to Apr. 30, 1919.................................... 41.30 May 1 to 111Dl1 15, 1919 •• • •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 61. 30 111D8 16 to Sept. 301 1919.................................. 67. 40 Oct.1 to Nov. 30, 1919.................................... 77. 90 Dec. 1 to Deo. 81, 1919.................................... 86. 90 lan. 1 to lan. 3:i lll'JO..................................... 106. 90 3i,1~::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Apr. 1 to Apr. ~J lll'JO,................................... 192. 40 May l lll'JO, to M.llr. 81, 1921. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1118. 40 Apr. 1 to Aµg. 311 11121.... ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 227. 40 Sept. 1 to Nov. llU, 1921................................... 268. 90 Dec. 1, 1921, to lan. 31, 1922.............................. 405. 10 Feb. 1 to Feb. 28, 1922.................................... 468. 10 Mar. 1 to Mar. 81, 1922................. •••••••••••••••••• 601. 70 Apr. 1 to Apr. 19, 1922............................ •••••••• 713. 20 Apr. 20 to 111Dl130i 1922................................... 907. 50 luly 1 to July 31, 922.................................... 1,208.00 1, 613. 00 Aug. 1 to Aug. 31, 1922.. ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Sept. 1 to Sept; 30, 1922......................... ••• ••••••• 4, 105. 00 Oct. 1 to Oct. 31_, 1922... ••••••••••••••• •••••••••••••••••• S, OM. 00 Nov. 1 to Nov. 16, 1922................................... 8,114.00 Nov. 16 to Nov. 30, 1922.................................. 14,011.00 Deo. 1, 1922, to lan. 11, 11123.............................. 22,763.00 lan. 12 to lan. 31, 11123..... ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 38,044.00 Feb. 1 to Feb. 8, 11123.. ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 68,411.00 Fob. 9 to Mar. 31, 11123.. ••••••••••••••• ••••••• ••••••••••• 123, 356. 00 Apr. l to May 16, 11123................................... 114,117.00 May 16 to May 31, 11123. •• ••••••••••••••••••••••••• •••••• 143, 510. 00 June 1 to lune 14, 11123.................................... 221,200.00 lune 15 to lune 24, 11123.................................. 836,200.00 lune 26 to luly 8, 11123.................................... 628,000.00 luly 9 to luly 16, 11123.................................... 835,000.00 July 17 to luly 26, 11123................................... 1,361,000.00 July 27 to Aug, 1, 11123.................................... 2,083,000.00 Aug. 2 to Aug. 81, 11123... ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• S, 168,000.00 Aug. 9 to Aug. 111, 11123................................... 23,267,000.00 Aug. 20 to Aug, 26, 11123.................................. 37,IIBf,000.00 Aug. 27 to Sept. 2, 11123.................................... 70,707,000.00 Sept. 3 to Sept. 9, 11123.•••• ~............................. 91,913,000.00 Sept. 10 to Sept. 16, 11123.................................. 168, 700, 000. 00 Sept. 17 to Sept. 23, 11123•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 9.69 11.25 9.36 10.13 9.89 1L73 12.53 11.96 12.30 16. 76 9.95 7.66 7.41 4.53 6.06 i::: -If!:.1t ~- 24. 05 14.39 8.83 9.23 6.90 10.22 16.09 7.05 12.06 9.49 25. 05 10.49 3.44 7.21 8.60 7.46 9.18 10.19 7.57 3.22 10.34 4.72 11.25 10.21 1L44 10. 51> 10.92 10.84 12.29 16. 64 14.63 17.12 19. liS 16.44 10.81 8.06 6.92 6.34 8.41 13.M 14.37 13,40 6.17 8.86 9,46 8.97 9.88 12.60 10.28 5.60 11.76 6.67 4.81 8.07 26.98 7.28 7.38 16.41 12.46 10.28 10. 05 10.98 10.66 16.12 12.61 9.86 13.78 11.69 7.49 9.52 15.66 Ui.43 8.57 27.40 22.78 13.28 14.86 13.11 19,40 19.47 26.21 11,61 19.68 86.17 37.97 52.25 39. 78 13.97 28.08 28.08 28.08 38.46 38.46 38.46 24.92 2G.60 24.92 24.92 3.72 6.70 9.15 8.26 6.80 16.66 10.41 8.67 8.60 9.63 12.60 17.88 7.52 7.95 4.46 20.10 28.99 ti'i\il~f§:;i;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;; ;;;;;;;;;;;;;;;; Average 20.60 16. liO 16.00 16.50 16.00 12.02 7.01 7.48 23.36 16. 39 10.79 11.34 11.01 14.37 18. 72 15.28 8.61 7.114 28.42 32.17 36.37 14.97 8.95 20.60 16. liO 15,00 Table 17 shows the average price of lignite briquets in Greater Berlin each month from January, 1920, to December, 1924. The average price in 1913-14 waa 1.15 marks per 110 pounds. TABLB 17.-AVERAGE PRICE OF 110 POUNDS OF L'IONITE BRIQUETS IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS Month 1920 Jlarb lanuary ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ~~Y·::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: t&r:~·~:::::::::::::. ::::::::, :::::::::::::::: June••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••. luiy•••••• •••••••••••••• ••••••••••••••••••••••• $her.::::,::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: November. _•••••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••••• December •.•••••••.••••••••••••••••••.••••••.• •Millions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis t 7.90 8. 70 13. liO 16.80 16.10 16.10 16.10 14.90 14.90 14.90 11\.20 15. 20 Billions. 1921 Marica 1922 Jlarb - 16. 20 16.10 16.26 16.90 17.60 17.60 17.60 17.60 18.35 19.05 2!.55 27.35 27.80 32.40 40.80 51.10 60.25 64.90 1923 1924 .Marica Juntenmark8 2,267 11,807 7,225 6,446 6,918 15,087 49,329 106.10 1,169,955 131.4 245.80 •7,3M.2 Mo. 50 t 1,030.8 728.15 a 1.88 1,496.25 82.30 I RentenmarkR. 1. 76 1.69 1.66 1.65 1.65 1.58 1,53 L49 1.47 1.45 1.53 1.53 49 FUEL AND LIGHT Table 18 shows the average price of gas in Greater Berlin each month from January, 1920, to December, 1924. The average price in 1913-14 was 0.12 mark per cubic meter. TABLE 18.-AVERAGE PRICE OF 1 CUBIC METER! OF GAS IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS Month 1920 1921 1922 1923 1924 January _• ----- _______________________ -- _________ _ Febmary ________________________________________ _ March __________________ • _________________________ _ .--------------------------. __________________ April___________ -- __ --- ________ -- __________________ May June_ _____________________________________________ _ July ______________________________________________ _ August. ______________ • ___________________________ _ September________________________________________ _ October ______ ·-._ •. _____ • ________ .·- -- • ·- ________ _ N ovembA• •••• _______ • _. ______ • __ • _. ___________ _ December ___________ ._. ____ • -- -- • -- • -- -- ---·- ____ _ Mark8 Marks Mark8 Mark8 Rentenmark8 o. 75 1.10 1.10 1.10 1.10 1.25 1. 25 1.25 1. 25 1.35 1.35 1.60 2. 30 • 75 1 1 1 1 1 1 1.10 1.10 1.10 1.10 0. 21 • 21 . 21 .20 .19 .19 .19 .19 .19 .19 .19 .19 200 3.20 310 700 650 3.50 3.80 4.30 5.20 5.20 650 1,200 6,000 100, 96R 8 22.30 31.65 '3 1414 a 103.3 •. 21 58.50 98 •Billions. •Millions. 1 1 cubic meter=35.3H cubic feet. 2. 50 • Rentenmark. Table 19 shows index numbers of the cost of fuel and light in Germany for each month from January, 1922, to December, 1924. These index numbers were computed from reports of cities to the Federal Statistical Office on the prices of fuel and light of the kind most commonly used by its inhabitants; viz, as to fuef, the price either of 3 centners 3 of coal, of 5 centners of lignite, of 4 centners of lignite briquets, of 3 centners of ~as coke, of 6 centners of peat, of 6 centners of firewood, or of 40 cubic meters 4 of cooking gas, and as to light, the price either of 15 cubic meters of illuminating gas or of 5 kilowatt hours of electricity. TABLE 19.-INDEX NUMBERS OF COST OF FUEL J. -.,D LIGHT IN GERMANY, JANUARY, 1922, TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS [1913-14= 1] 1922 Month 11924 1923 On basis of dollar exchange rate or marks 1922 .Tanuary ·-· ·-- ----. ----- --- ------- ----- ~~~ :::::::::::::::::.::::::::::: ~1-::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: .Tune_. ___ .------- --- -- • -- • - --- -- • •- --- -- --- ----- --- --- --- - • -- --- --_____ .July ________________________________ August t~~~ber ··--·----------------------December __ -------------------------November_____________________________ 1 Based on rentenmarks In this year. 20. 94 23.85 29.65 34. 97 44.11 48.22 59.39 77.16 161.12 251. 72 508. 30 1038. 91 1612 4071 5529 5514 5785 10378 36904 890539 • 23.34 15715 8 834 • 1. 765 •Millions. 1. 63 1.55 1.51 1.48 1.47 1.46 1.43 1.41 1.40 1.36 1. 35 1. 35 a Billions. 0.46 .48 .44 .50 .64 .64 • 51 .29 .46 .33 .30 .57 1923 0.38 .61 1.09 .95 .51 '~' .40 .44 .81 .99 .95 1.60 1. 77 1.63 1.55 1. 51 1.48 1.47 1. 46 1.43 1.41 1.40 1.36 1. 35 1.35 • Based on rentenmarks. The German fuel and light cost index, calculated on the basis of the dollar exchange rate, was generally below 1 until October, 1923. After the mark was stabilized in November, 1923, this index rose to 2 on December 3; it then fell again but still stands at 1.35. 1 1 centner-110.23 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis pounds. ' 1 cubic meter-35.314 cubic feet. 60 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING CLOTHING Since Germany produces only a small proportion of the raw materials (wool, cotton, hides) needed for the manufacture of clothing, the blockade during the war and the monetary depreciation after the war affected the supply of clothes and shoes perliaps more than that of any other necessity of life. Moreover, the necessity of spendim? the greatest part of their wages on food and fuel made it impossible for most workingmen to ~et adequate clothing for themselves and especially for their families. The clothing-cost index is, therefore, less than any other index a gauge to measure what workingmen actually spent; it merely shows what workingmen would have spent if they had satisfied their needs. Table 20 shows index numbers of the cost of clothing for each month from January, 1922, to December, 1924, based on reforts of cities to the Federal Statistical Office on the price of 1 man s suit, 1 boy's suit, 1 girl's dress, 2 ladies' skirts, 2 waists, 6 men's shirts, 6 ladies' shirts, 6 pairs of men's socks, 6 pairs of ladies' stoc~, 1 pair of men's slioes, 1 pair of ladies' shoes, 2 pairs of children's shoes, and 8 pairs of soles and heels for men's shoes. TABLB 2O.-INDEX NUMBERS OF COST OF CLOTHING IN GERMANY, lANUARY, 1922 TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS · (1913-14-1) On basis of dollar exobange rate of marks Month 1922 111124 1923 1922 lanuary ·----------------------------February_ - - -------------------------March_------------------------------- tra:· :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June_----------------. ---------------luJy _-- ------------------------------- = b e r:::::::::::::::::::::::::::: December____________________________ Novembei _---------------------------_ l Based OD rentenmarks in this year. 30. 75 37.21 44.47 48.29 56.88 65.19 80. 16 125. 71 260. 00 386. 64 74L62 1161.13 I Ul.82 4L64 43.23 4L82 57.24 119. 95 664.88 10895. 71 126. 5 16160. 00 I 816. 00 l L66, M11lioDB. L61 L47 L49 LM 1,68 1.55 1.45 1.42 1.44 . 1.46 1.48 1.49 1 Billions. 0.67 .75 .66 .70 .82 .86 .68 .47 .74 .51 .43 ,64 1923 11124 0.39 .63 .86 .72 .50 .46 .79 .99 L13 L02 L56 L66 1.51 1.47 L49 LM 1,68 l.M 1.46 1,42 1,44 1.46 1.48 1.49 'Based OD rentenmarks. The Federal Statistical Office has not published a clothing-cost index for 1920 and 1921, but gives an inaex for the cost of food, housing, fuel, and light, and one for the cost of food, housing, fuel~ light, and clothing. The first index is computed by adding the prices of the food comprised in the food-cost index (see p. 9), tlie monthly rent of two rooms and kitchen, 3 centners of coal or the corresponding quantity of other fuel, and 15 cubic meters of illuminating gas or 5 kilowatt hours of electricity. The second index in(lludes also onethirteenth of the total price of the clotb.4tg comprised in the clo~cost index (see above). Table 21 shows·both indexes for each month from February, 1920, to December, 1924. In each month the second index was higher than the first. This proves that the price of clothing was always comparatively higher than the price of tlie other necessities of life taken together. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 51 CLOTHING TABLE 21.-INDEX NUMBERS 011' COST OF LIVING IN GERMANY, FEBRUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS [1913-14-1) Index numbers Index numbers Month Food, Food, hous- houslngt foe!, ana light light, and 1920 February ,. ............. March ••••••••••••••••••• tf:··::::::::::::::::::: June ••••••••••••••••••••• July •••••••••••••••••••••• August .................... September ••••••••••••••• October •••••••••••••••••• November•••••••••••••••• December •••••••••••••••• 1921 tr~·:::::::::::::::: tra:··::::::::::::::::::: June ••••••••••••••••••••• July•••••••••••••••••••••• August ••••••••••••••••••• September ••••••••••••••• October •••••••••••••••••• November•••••••••••••••• December •••••••••••••••• 7.00 8.17 9.16 D. 75 9.53 9.35 8. 87 8.81 9.45 9.99 10.47 10. 70 10.33 10.28 10.22 10.14 10.48 11.24 11.92 12.12 13.08 15.94 17.46 tr:·:::::::::::::::::::: June ••••••••••••••••••••• July•••••••••••••••••••••• j lMllllons. 1 Billions. 18.25 22.09 26.39 31. 75 34.62 37. 79 49.90 houslngt Food, hous- rurfgh'fa clothing 1922 8.47 9.56 10.42 11.02 10.83 10.65 10.23 10.15 10. 71 11.18 11.58. lL 79 11.47 11.38 11.27 1L20 1L67 12. 50 13. 33 13. 74 15. 04 17. 75 19.28 1922 January •••••••••••••••••• February••••••••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••••••• Food, Month Ing, foe!, 20.41 24.49 28.97 34.36 38.03 41.47 53.92 August ••••••••••••••••••• September ••••••••••••••• October •••••••••••••••••• November•••••••••••••••• December •••••••••••••••• 70.29 113. 76 195.04 400.47 611.56 Ing, foe!, ~:~d 77.65 133.19 220.66 446.10 685.06 1923 January •••••••••••••••••• February••••••••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••••••• April ••••••••••••••••••••• May ••••••••••••••••••••• June ••••••••••••••••••••• July.••••••••••••••••••••• August ••••••••••••••••••• September••••••••••••••• October •••••••••••••••••• November•••••••••••••••• December •••••••••••••••• 1034 2408 2627 2764 3521 6979 33300 508631 113. 2 13265 1120 2643 2854 2954 3816 7650 37651 586045 1633 11.18 1 15. 01 13657 1657 I 1.25 1924• January •••••••••••••••••• February••••••••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••••••• .98 tfr.1·:::::::::::::::::::: JUDA •••••••••••••••••••• July •••••••••••••••••••••• August ••••••••••••••••• September_••••••••••••• October •••••••••••••••••• November-•••••••••••••• December •• ·-··········· • Based on rentenmarks. LlO L04 L07 L12 1.15 Ll2 1.16 1.14 Ll6 1.22 1.23 L2S L04 1.00 1.06 1.08 L05 1.12 1.09 Ll2 1.18 1.19 1.19 • Based on rentenmarks In this year. Table 22 shows the second cost-of-living index for each month from Februa,ry, 1920, to December, 1924, computed on the basis of the dollar exchange rate of marks. TABLE 22.-INDEX NUMBERS OF COST OF LIVING IN GERMANY, FEBRUARY,.1 192!)1 TO DECEMBER, 1924, ON BASIS OF DOLLAR EXOHANUE RATE OF MARKJ:j, Bx MONTHS [1913-14-1) Month 1920 ~~~.::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ·- n·36. March • •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• • 48 M!!: :.:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: l:! i~iust:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ~J:~ber :.:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: November ········----······················ December........................................... https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1: M :: ••61 66 1921 0. 76 • 79 • 76 • 74 • 75 • 71 .68 .66 .55 .42 .28 .42 1922 1923 0.45 .49 0.26 .50 .55 .66 .46 .29 .38 .29 .26 .38 .51 • 43 .40 .55 .34 .29 .45 .53 .64 .61 1.26 1.26 1924 1.lC, 1.04 1.07 1.12 1.15 1.12 1. 16 1. 14 1.16 1.22 1.23 1.23 52 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING TRANSPORTATION The question of transportation of the German worker from his dwelling to the place where he is employed is in many res.P8cts different now from what it used to be before the war. In practically all cities street-car operation has been considerably reduced. There are even large .towns in which no street cars are now ~ - This is true, for instance, of Wurzburg, a Bavarian town of about 90,000 inhabitants, in which the operation of street cars has been stop_ped since April, 1920. Moreover, the street-car fares are so high tliat, with the exception of a few large cities, the use of the street ear has become a luxury which worki.!)gmen generally can not afford. Table 23 shows the price of a single street-ear ride in Berlin, Janua.ry 1, 1901, to December 31, 1924: TABLB 23.-PRIOE OF A SINGLE STREET-OAR FA.RE IN BERLIN, :JANUARY 1, 1901, TO DECEMBER 31, 1924 Period beginning- Fare 1901 :Jan. 1.••••••.....•.•••••••••.•••• Jl11rb Period beginning0.10 t/:y k::::::::::::: ·:::::::::: 1918 May 1 •••••••.••••..••••••••••••• .15 1919 :Jan. 21 ••••••••••••• Sept. 1. •••••.•.....•. - - - - i .20 • 20 ----1 1920 :Jan. 1 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Vil F·::::::::::::::::::::::::: 11121 Mar.8 ••••••••••••· - - - · Dec. 1·-························· .30 .00 t~e g.::::::::::::::::::::::::: :July 28.. •••••••••••••••••••••••••• Aug. 28......................... . 1 1, 00 2 3 4 Ii 8 Dec. 1·-························· 10 20 30 00 1923 , :Jan. 2 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••• :Jan.17 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••• :Jan. 30 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Feb. 12. •••••••••••••••••••••••••• 70 100 100 200 ~Jlt 1r:::::::::::::::::::::::::: Nov, 10 •••••••••••••••••••••••••• I :June 25......................... 11 •• ·-···················· :June :July 2........................... :July 16.......................... :July 25.......................... Aug. 1.......................... Aug. 10......................... Aug. 13......................... Aug. 211......................... :: Sept. tg:: H......................... k:::::::::::::::::::::::: lll'J2 Feb. 4.. •.............•...•........ 1923 Mar. !. .......... _ _ _ _, Sept.18......................... Sept. 22......................... Sept. 28......................... Oct. 10.......................... Oct. 13.......................... Oct. 17•••••••••••••••••••••••••• Oct. 20.......................... Oct. 23.......................... Oct. 25.......................... Oct. 27•••••••••••••••••••••••• •• Nov. I •••••••••••••••••••••••• !. Nov. 3.......................... Nov.11 •••••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov. 8 •••••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov. 12......................... Nov. 14.. ••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov. 16.. ••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov.17 ••••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov. 20 ••••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov. 22......................... Fare Jlarb 260 :! ooo 1,000 1,000 3,000 6,000 10,000 20,000 00,000 100,000 ~:: := 000,000 2,000,000 3,000,000 4,000,000 10,000,000 20,000,000 00, 000, 000 100,000,000 200,000,000 800,000,000 1, 000, 000, 000 2,000,000,000 4,000,000,000 10,000,000,000 15,000,000,000 20,000,000,000 30,000,000, 000 00, 000, 000, 000 70,000,000,000 90,000,000,000 ! .15 Rentenmark. The fare is now 50 per cent higher than before the war. Moreover, on September 10, 1923, commutation tickets, which were 10 times as high as the price for a single fare but entitled the owner to 12 rides d!,lring a week, were abolished. As a eonseq_uenee, street-ear riding for workmen from their dwellings to their places of employ- • ment costs them now 80 per cent more than before the war (1.8 marks a week instead of 1 mark), and they do their utmost to avoid street-car riding. On the other hand, many employees who, because of lack of employment in their places of residence, w01·k at some other place, but on account of the housing shortage have not been able to secure https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 58 TRANSPORTATION dwellings in that place, travel each day long distances to and from their places of employment. Thus, while street-car travel of workingmen has considerably decreased, railway travel has materially increased. In general, ordinary trains in Germany carry second, third, and fourth class cars and express trains first, second, and third class cars. Workingmen use the fourth class in ordinary trains and the third class in express trains. Table 24 shows the price for 1 kilometer 5 in the fourth class of ordinary trains and in the third class of express trains, both in paper and in gold (on the basis of the exchange rate of the mark in Amsterdam l!P to the end of 1919 and of the dollar exchange rate of marks in Berlin from and after the beginning of 1920). The supplementary fare charged on express trains being the same for all distances traveled beyond 150 kilometers, it was necessary, in order to compute the price of 1 kilometer, to choose a definite distance, and therefore a tnp of 300 kilometers was taken as. the basis of the calculation. TABLE 24.-RAILWAY FARE PER KILOMETER ON ORDINARY TRAINS, FOURTH CLASR, AND EXPRESS TRAINS, THIRD CLASS, IN GERMANY, MAY 1, 1907, TO DE· CEMBER 31, 1924, Period beginning- Ordinary trains, fourth class I Express trains, third class Period beginning- Ordinary trains, fourth class Paper currency 1907 May 1. •...•.••••••• Pfennigs 1918 Apr. 1. .•••••••••••• 1919 Apr. 1. .•.•••••••••• Oct. 1. ••••••••••••• Pfennigs 2 3.4 2. 4 6.2 5.81 8. 72 3 4.5 9 17.43 1921 June 1. ..••••••••••. Dec. !. ............. 13 16.9 23.5 30.35 1922 Feb. 1. ••••••••••••• Oct. 1. ••..••••••••• Nov. 1. ••••••••••••• Dec. 1. •••••••••..•• 29.58 45 90 180 52.04 82.5 165 330 Mark8 4 8 16 33 100 330 3,300 13,200 33,000 198,000 440,000 660,000 1,320,000 2,640,000 13,200,000 33,000,000 132, 000, 000 1 Kllometer-0.62137 mile. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Express trains, third class Gold 1920 Mar. 1..•.•••••••••• 1923 Jan. 1. ••••••••••••• Feb. 1. •••.•••••.••• Mar. 1. ••••••••••••• June 1. ••••••••••••• July 1. ••••••••••••• Aug. 1. •••••..•.•••• Aug.20 •.•••.••.••• Sept. 1. •...•••••.•• Sept. 11. ••••••••••• Sept. 18 ...••••••••• Sept. 25 .••••••••••• Oct. 2....•••••••••• Oct. 10••••••••••••• Oct. 13 ••••••••••••• Oct. 18 ••••••••••••• Oct. 25 ••••••••••••• Oct. 29 ••••••••••••• I Mark8 7 14 28 60 180 600 6,000 22,800 57,000 342,000 760,000 1.140,000 2,280,000 4,560,000 22,800,000 57,000,000 228, 000, 000 1907 May 1.•••••••••••• 1914 Aug. 1. •••••••••••• 1918 Apr. 1. ••..••••••••• 1919 Apr. 1. ...•••••.••.• Oct. 1••...••••••••• 1920 Mar. 1.••••••••••••• 1921 June 1. ••.•.•••••••• Dec. 1. •••.••••••••. 1922 Feb. I. •.••....••••. Oct. 1. ••••••••.•••• Nov. 1••••••••••••• Dec. 1•••••••••••••• 1923 Jan. 1••••.••••••••• Feb. 1. ••••••••••••• Mar. I. June 1. ••••••••••••• July 1. --··········· Aug. 1. .•••••••••••• Aug. 20••••••••••••• Sept. 1. •.••••.••••. Sept. 11. ••••••••••• Sept. 18 •••••••••••• Sept. 25 •••••••••••• Oct. 2..•••••••••••• Oct. 10.•••••••••••• Oct. 13 .•••••••••••• Oct. 18.•••••••••••• Oct. 25 .•••••••••••• Oct. 29 ••••••••••••• Nov. 1. ••••••••••••• 1924 Mar. L ••••••••••••• Pfennigs 2 Pfennigs 3.4 1-1.9 LS -3.3 .9 -1. 7 2.3 -4.4 .4 -1.2 .2 -.8 .9 -2.3 ,4 -1. 6 .4 -1.1 .7 -2.2 .2 -.9 .3 -.4 .3 -1.6 .6 - .8 .06.04.04.09- .6 .10 .08 .12 .11-1.1 .08- .2 .08- .2 .16- .2 .03- .2 .08- .2 .10- .3 .09- .2 .04- .3 .03- .13 .13- .3 • 10- .6 .10- .2 .5 - .8 .8-1.5 .2 - .9 .11- .19 .2 - .3 .09-. 7 .2 .8 - .9 2.2 .06- .4 .14- .3 .17- .6 .16- .4 .07- .5 .06- .2 ,2 .•. 6 .18-1. 0 .18- .4 .8 -1. 3 1.3 -2.6 .4-1.5 .19- .3 .3 - .5 .16-1. 2 .4 1.3-1.5 3.8 3.0 5 :54 CH~EB II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING Table 25 shows the average railway fare (in gold) for all classes of cars on both ordinary and express trains. 25.-AVERAGE RAILWAY FARE PER KILOMETER ON ORDINARY TRAINS A.ND EXPRESS TRAINS, A.LL CLASSES, MAY 1, 1907, TO DECEMBER 31, lllM, IN GOLD PFENNIGS TABLE Express trains Ordinary trains Period beginning- 1907 Mayl••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1914 Aug. 1. •••••••••••.•••••••.••••••••••••••• 1918 A.pr. 1•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1919 t:· f·.::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 1920 Mar. l ••••••••••••••.•• ·------1 1921 .Tune 1••••••••••••...•••••••.......•.•...• Dec. 1-••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1922 Feb. 1•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Oct. 1..............................•...... Nov. 1•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Dec. 1••••••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••• 1923 Jan. 1. ••••..•••••.•.•.....••••••••.••••••• Feb. 1•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Mar. 1•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• June 1•••••••...•.•........•...•.••••••••• July 1•••••••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Aug. 1••••••••••.•••.••••••••••••••••••••• Aug 9() ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Sept. 1. •••••••• ••••••••••• •••••••••••••••• Sept. 11 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Sept. 18 •••.•.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• t~t Oct. 225::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 10•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Oct. 13•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Oct. 18•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Oct. 25 .................................... Oct. 29•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov. 1••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Dec. I •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Second class 4. 77 Third class Fonrth cla8s First class Second class Third cla8s 2.0 8.47 5.43 3.4 2.29 L60 6.33 4.06 2.~ 2.03 L32 8.62 5.49 3.41 L33 .56 .83 .36 5. 55 2.32 2. 77 L16 L61 .67 L66 LOO .62 4.17 2.08 L21 LOO .92 .66 .66 .44 .37 2.24 LSS L36 Ll4 .79 .66 .55 .16 .13 .33 .22 .06 • Oil .10 Lll .31 .29 .66 .67 .19 .17 .32 .28 .36 .66 .38 .48 .22 L03 .83 .66 2.43 l!.25 1.89 , .14 .18 .32 .19 .18 .07 .32 .28 .22 .81 L76 .63 .21 .37 .23 .32 1.23 3.3 .09 .12 .22 • 13 .12 .Oil .21 .19 .16 .64 L17 .42 .14 .25 • 16 .21 .33 .42 • 76 .46 .67 .27 L23 a.a .82 2.2 2. 2 .66 .84 Llil .92 L14 • 63 2.43 L92 L50 5. 69 12. 09 36 L43 2. liS L60 2. 21 8. 61 22.8 4.6 3. 0 lLl 8.116 3.13 2. 21 .92 .25 .62 1.12 .70 .97 3. 69 9.9 6. 6 3.07 • 09 .08 .16 4. ll!.2 ,96 • 76 2. 79 6.06 2.18 .72 L29 .80 LIO 4.25 1L4 7.6 .89 .11 . .10 .18 .16 .21 .38 .23 .21 .08 .38 .32 • 211 .93 2.02 .73 .24 .43 .27 .87 L42 3.8 3.8 1924 Mar. 1•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 6. 6 7.6. 5.0 The passenger rates established on May 1, 1907, remained unchanged until the end of' March, 1918. It was only when the transport tax went into effect on April 1, 1918, that the passenger rates (inl,aper marks) were raised. A second change of rates took place on p:ril 1, 1919, and other changes followed on October 1, 1919, March 1, 1920, June 1, and December 1, 1921, February 1 and October 1~ 1922, each month November 1, 1922, to March 1, 1923, June 1, JUly 1, August 1 and 20, September 1, 11, 18, and 25, October 2, 10, 13, 18, 25, and 29, November 1, and December 1, 1923, and March 1, 1924. Between November, 1918, and November, 1923, the rates, calculated in gold, for the third and fourth classes were lower than before the war, while the rates for the second class were higher only in the last week of September, 1923, and for the :first class only in the last week of September./ 1923, and on October 2, 29, and 30l 1923. From· and after Nove.moer 1, 1923-the date when gold prices were introduced-rates in all classes were higher than liefore the war. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis TAXES 55 In former times third-class tickets on ordinary trains were about 50 per cent higher than fourth-dass tickets and second-class tickets 11.bout 50 per cent higher than third-class tickets; the ratio was about the same between first, second, and third class tickets on express trains. The differentiation between the classes was considerably intensified after the war and especially during 1923. In the fall of 1923 third-class tickets in ordinary trains still cost 50 per cent more than fourth-class tickets, but second-class tickets cost three times as much as third-class tickets; in express trains second-class tickets cost three times as much as third-class tick~ts and first-class tickets twice as much as second-class tickets. While in November, 1923, third and fourth class rates were 10 per cent hig~er than before the war, second-class rates were more than twice as .tugh and first-class rates almost three times as high. But on December 1 first and second class rates were reduced by one-third, and on March 1 first-class rates were again reduced by more than one-fourth, while on March 1 third and fourth class rates were raised by about one-third. As a consequence thereof, the ratio between the third and fourth classes is still about the same as before the war, while that between the second and third and especially the first and second classes is lower. Third and fourth class rates at present are about 50 per cent higher than before the war, second-class rates about 40 per cent higher, and fi.'"'Bt-class rates about 30 per cent higher. The recent passenger-rate policy- of the railway constitutes, then, a discrimination ag~t the working class. TAXES Until 1920 direct taxes, in general, were levied only by the States and the municipalities, but not by the Federal Government. Income tax rates were very low for small incomes and the large majority of workers was exempt from the income tax. After the war, when it became apparent that the obligations of the Fe,lcral Government could not be met by indirect taxation alone, a complete change took J>lace. The National Assembly which was elected early in 1919 for the 1>_urpose of drafting a constitution for the Republic conferred on the Federal Government unrestricted control over all forms of taxation and enacted among other fiscal laws the States tax law (Landessteuergesetz) of March 30, 1920, which forbade the States and municipalities to levy taxes similar to those levied by the Federal Government. As a Federal income tax law had been enacted on March 29, 1920, the States and municipalities were thus prevented from imposing income taxes. Under the new law the followix_ig exemptions were allowed: 1,500 marks for the taxpayer; 500 marks for each person belonging to the household of the taxpayer (wife and minor cliildren), this exemption being raised to 700 marks for the second and each additional person under 16 years of age, unless the net income of the taxpayer exceeded 10,000 marks. In computing net income, deductions were allowed for expenses incurred in acquiring and maintaining the income (Werbu:ngslcosten). The total exemption for a married taxpayer with two children who had an income of 9,000 marks and who spent 500 marks in acquiring this income thus amounted to 1,500+500+700+700+500=3,900 marks, and his taxable net income was 5,100 marks. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 56 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING The tax rate was 10 per cent of the amount of the net taxable income up to 1,000 marks; 11 per cent of the amount over 1,000 marks and not exceeding 2,000 marks; 12 per cent of the amount over 2,000 marks and not exceeding 3,000 marks; the rate rising progressively to 60 per cent of the amount of the net taxable income exceeding 500,000 marks. The above taxpayer with a total income of 9,000 marks and a net taxable income of 5,100 marks had, then, to pay an income tax of' 100+110+120+130+140+15=615 marks, or 6.83 per cent of his total income. The income tax was, in general, assessed at the beginning of each year on the income of the })receding year. An important exception, however, was made as to salaries and wages, which were taxed at the source. The employer was requir.ed to deduct 10 per cent from all payments of salaries and wages, buying tax stamps equal in value to the amount deducted and pasting such stamps on the tax card of the· employee. The assessment of the employee by the. fiscal authorities. took place later on. In case the value of the stamps on the employee's tax card exceeded the tax finally assessed according to the normal income tax rates, the tax office refunded him the sur_plus. If t~ taxpayer noted above with a total wage mcome of 9,000 marks had had 900 marks deducted from his wages on pay days for the income tax, he should, as he had to pay only 615 marks, have gotten back 285 marks after his final assessment. But if the cur-rency had depreciated in the meantime (and this was often the case) the 285 marks which were returned to him would not be worth aSmucb at the time of the return as at the time they were deducted from his'wages. The provision as to the deduction of the income tax from salarieSand wages went into effect on June 25, 1920. It meant a great hardship for the workers as compared with other taxpayers and involved greater disadvantages for those with the smaller incomes than for th& higher-salaried employees. A new law, intended to remedy theseabuses, was therefore enacted July 21, 1920, and went into effect August 1. It introduced the allowance of the following exemptions in computing the amount to be deducted from salaries and wages: (a) Five marks per day in case of daily wages; (b) 30 marks per week in case of weekly wages; (c) 125 marks per month in case of monthly wages. This exemption was raised 1.5 marks in the case of daily wages, 10 marks in the case of weekly wages, and 40 marks in the case of monthly wages, for each person belonging to the household of the· employee. On the other hand, the deduction was to be increased beyond 10 per cent in case the taxable wages (total wages minus the exemptions 3ust mentioned) exceeded 15,000 marks per year. The amount to be deducted on pay days was: Fifteen per cent of the amount of the taxable wages over 15,000 marks and not exceeding 30,000 marks; 20 per cent of the amount over 30,000 marks and not exceeding 50,000 marks; the rate rising progressively to 55 per cent of the amount over 1,0001000 marks. This progression was to insure greater returns to the treasury from the higlier employees before their final assessments, while the exemptions mentioned were to relieve the situation of the workingmen. A https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis TAXES 57 great drawback of the new law was that it invohred considerable work for the employer. While under the former law a simple deduction of 10 per cent·was made from each and every salary, under the new law the deduction had to be computed for each employee individually. For the workers, however, the new law provided great relief. The total yearly exemption for a married employee with two children amounted to 1,500+480+480+480=2,940 marks. The taxpayer with an income of 9,000 marks had his yearly income reduced by deductions on pay days amounting to 10 per cent of 6,060 marks, or 606 marks. As his final assessment amounted to 615 marks, he had to pay an additional 9 marks after his final assessment, while under the original law he advanced to the treasury 285 marks which he got 'back after his final assessment, possibly in much depreciated money. The law of July 21, 1920, also introduced differential deductions for married and for single employees and allowed special exemptions for children. But the exemptions for wife and children were so small that the married employees and especially those with children riractjcally had to pay on pay days the whole tax or had even to 'advance" something to the treasury, while the single employees might pay part of their tax after the final assessment m depreciated money. A single worker who earned 9,000 marks paid 750 marks through deductions of the tax from his wages on pay days while (if he spent 500 marks in acquiring his income) he was finally assessed 100+110+120+130+140+150+160=910 marks. This defect of the law of July 21, 1920, was remedied by the law of March 24h1921, which went into effect April 1, 1921. Under the latter law t e following exemptions were allowed in computing the amount to be deducted from salaries and wages: (a) Four marks for the taxpayer, 4 marks for his wife, and 6 marks for each minor child, in case of wages paid daily; (b) 24 marks for the taxpayer, 24 marks for his wife, and 36 marks for each minor child, in case of wages paid weekly; (c) 100 marks for the taxpayer, 100 marks for his wife, and 150 marks for each minor child, in case of wages paid monthly. The exemption for the taxpayer was thus reduced by 20 per cent, while that for his wife and especially those for his children were considerably raised. At the same time the progression introduced by the law of July 21, 1920, was abolished, tlie rate of deduction being again uniformly 10 per cent. The rates of the general income tax (which were still to be applied in the final assessment of the employees) were: Ten per cent of the amount of the net taxable income up to 24,000 marks; 20 per cent of the amount over 24,000 marks and not exceeding 30,000 marks; the rate risi!ig progressively to 60 per cent of the amount over 400,000 marks. Tlie exemptions from the general income tax, which theretofore had been tne same for all incomes, were now restricted to small incomes. The tax was to be reduced (a) in case the taxable income did not exceed 24..,000 marks, by 120 marks for the taxpayer, by 180 marks for eacn. minor child, and by 120 marks for each other person belonging to the household of tlie taxpayer; (b) in case the taxable income was over 24,000 marks but did not exceed 60,000 marks, by 120 marks for the taxpayer and each person belonging to his household; (c) in case the taxable income was over 60,000 marks but did not exceed 100,000 marks, by 60 marks for the taxpayer and each person belonging to his household. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 68 CHAPTER II,-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING A married taxpayer with two children, who had an income of 9,000 marks and who had spent 500 marks in acquiring this income, had thus to pay 850-120-120-180-180 =250 marks. The total yearly exemption for a married employee with two children amounted to 1,200+ 1,200+ 1,800+ 1,800 =6,000 marks. The taxpayer with an income of 9,000 marks had his yearly income reduced by deductions on pay days by 10 per cent of 3,000 marks, or 300 marks. .As he was finally assessed 250 marks, he got back 50. marks. The fact that the income tax from salaries and wages had to be assessed twice-provisionally b_y the employer and finally by the fiscal authorities-became in the long run so cumbersome that a simplification was necessary. A new law was therefore enacted on July 11, 1921, which provided that in case the taxable yearly income did not exceed 24,000 marks and was exclusively a wage income or did not include another income of over 600 marks, the tax should be definitely settled through deductions from the wages by the employer. The exemptions were -to be deducted from the amount of the tax and not from the amount pf the taxable income, but since the exemptions were reduced to one-tenth of what they had theretofore been, this meant only a formal change. It became, however, necessary to introduce an exemption for expenses in acquiring the income, since these expenses had- theretofore been ta.ken mto account only at the final assessment. This exemP.tion was to be the same as for each minor child, viz., in case of daily wages, 0.6 mark per day; in case of weekly wages, 3.6 I)'.lar~~r week; and in case of monthly wages 15 marks per month. While the other provisions of the law went into effect on January 1, 1922, the provisions referring to the exemption for " acquiring expenses" were retroactive to April 1, 1921. The income tax of a married employee with two children, who had a yearly income of 9,000 marks, was thus 900-120-120-180-180180 =120 marks. The law of July 11, 1921.., remained practically in force until the beginning of 1924. The oruy changes which took place d ~ that time referred to the amount of the exemptions, the limit below which no final assessment was to be made, and the ~oups of income to which the general tax rates applied. These changes occurred the more frequently as the depreciation of the money became greater. The most important provisions of the various laws, so far as they refer to the wage tax, can best be seen from Table 26. TABLE 26.-EXEMPTIONS UNDER WAGE-TAX LAWS ENACTED FROM AND AFTER DECEMBER 20, 11121 Exemption forDate of enaotment of law Dec. July Dec. Feb. May lune July Aug. Sept 1 20,11121 20, 1922 23, 1922 15, 11123 1 12, 11123 21, 11123 24, 11123 23, 11123 18, 11123 Date law went Into force Jan. Aug. Jan. Mar. June July Aug. Sept. Sept 1, 1922 1, 1922 1, 11123 1, 1928 1, 11123 1, 11123 1, 11123 1, 11123 16, 11123 Taxpayer and wife, each Weekly Monthly Mara Mara· 4.80 11.60 48 1112 288 1,440 6,760 86,400 172,800 Weekly 20 Marki 7.20 200 800 1,200 6,000 24,000 360,000 720,000 111.20 240 ll60 1, ll20 11,600 38,400 6'16,000 1,162,000 40 ExpeIIS!lS In acquiring Child mcome Monthly Weekly Monthly Mara Mara Mara 30 80 1,000 4,000 8,000 40,000 160,000 2,400,000 . 4,800,000 10.80 21.60 240 ll60 2,400 12,000 48,000 720,000 l,«o,000 415 IIO 1,000 4,000 10,000 60,000 200,000 8,000,000 6,000,000 According to the law of February 15. 11123, no deduction was to be made from the wages for the last six working days of February, 11123. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis TAXES 59 The table reads like this: According to the law enacted December 20, 1921, which went into force on January 1, 1922, a married employee ·with two children, who earned 500 marks per week, had his wages reduced on pay days through the wage tax (10 per cent) by 50-4.80-4.80-7.20-7.20-10.80 =15.20 marks. The necessity of rapid changes to adapt the exemptions to the depreciation of the currency induced the Government and the Reichstag to insert a clause in the law of December 23, 1922, authorizing the Minister of Finance, with the consent of the Federal Council (Reichsrat) and a committee of the Reichstag, to change the exemptions without consulting the Reichstag itself. But finally it was impossible to follow even this informal method and it became necessary to find some way of automatically adapting the exemptions to the depreciation of the currency. The act of September 17, 1923, therefore provided that the exemptions should change each week in proportion to the change in the mdex of the cost of living as determined by the Federal Statistical Office the preceding week. This law was modified by the laws of October 17 and 24, which, however, kept the principle of cha~ the exem1>tions in the same ratio as the index of the cost of livmg changed. It is not necessary to state the details of these laws; it will suffice to state that the exemptions fixed by the law of September 17, 1923, which were in force from September 16 to September 30, 1923, were to be multiplied for the week October 1 to 6, by 6; October 7 to 13, by 8; October 14 to 20, by 32; October 21 to 27, by 210; October 28 to November 3, by 6,000; November 4 to 10, by 20,000; November 11 to 17, by 300,000; November 18 to 24, by 300,000; November 25 to December 1, by 700,000; December 2 to 8, by 850,000; December 9 to 15, by 850,000; December 16 to 22, by 650,000; December 23 to 31, by 600,000. In the last week of 1923, the following exemptions were allowed in computing the amount to be deducted from salaries and wages: 103,680,000,000 marks for both the taxpayer and his wife; 691,200,000,000 marks for each child, and 864,000,000,000 marks for "acqu1ring expenses." A married worker with two children, who earned 27,000,000,000,000 marks (27 gold marks) a week, therefore had his earnings reduced on pay day by 2, 700,000,000,000-103,680,000,000 -103,680,000,000 - 691,200,000,000 - 691;200,000,000 - 864,000,000,000 = 246,240,000,000 marks (0.246 gold. marks). With the stabilization of the mark at the end of 1923, the method of computing the wage tax was put on an entirely new basis. The "second emergency tax act" (Zweite Steuernotverordnung) of December 19, 1923, provided that from and after January 1, 1924, the following exemptions were to be allowed in computing the amount to be deducted from salaries and wages: (a) For the taxpayer, in case of weekly wages, 12 gold marks; in case of monthly wages, 50 gold marks; (b) for each person belonging to the household of the taxpayer, 1 per cent of his taxable wages. No exemption was allowed for '' acquiring expenses.'' A single worker who earned 27 gold marks a week thus had these earnings reduced on pay days by 10 per cent of 15 marks or 1.50 marks. A married worker with two children, who earned the same wages, lost 7 per cent of 15 marks or 1.05 marks. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 60 CHAPTER Il.-STANDARD AND OOST OF LIVING From and after December, 1924, the exemptions are as follows: (a) For the taxpayer, in-case of weekly wages, 15 gold marks; in case of monthly wages; 60 gold marks; (b) for each person belonging to the household of the taxpayer 1 per cent of his taxable wages. Table 27 shows for a married Berlm printer with two children, who earned the wages fixed by collective agreement, his weekly wages .and deductions from wages for income tax from the introduction of the tax up to December, 1924: TA.Bu 27.-WEEKLY WAGES AND DEDUCTIONS FROM WAGES FOR INCOME TAX OF.MARRIED PRINTER WITH TWO CHILDREN, IN BERLIN, AT SPECIFIED TIMES, J'ULY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924 Deduction from wages for inoome tax Weeklywagest-----...--- Period Amount ·-·········----············----1 August to October, 1920 ••••••••·---················· .July, 1920••• November, 1920, to J'anuary, 1921•••••••••••••••••••••••••••• February to March, 1921 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ii€~1~ 921 ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: November, 1921 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Deoember, 1921•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• .January, Ul22•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1~l~~l~~I~f~ll~f:~f:[t~ J'anuary, 1928•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• · ••••••• --~----··-·······-············-··-· August 16 to 81, 1928••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• September 1 to 16, 1928 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• September 16 to 30, 19211••• ; ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• October 1 to 6, 1928 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• October 7 to 13, 1928 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• October 14 to 20, 1928•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• October'21to~,11928 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••. October 28 to .l'IOVember 8, 1928 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• November• to l0r.1928 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• November 11 to 11, 1928 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• November 18 to :M, 1928 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• November 211 to December lll, 1928••••••••••••••••••••••••••• December 18 to 22, 1928•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• December 23 to 31, 1928•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• .January and February, 192f. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• March, 1924 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• tl!.1: 11::-:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::············· .June to October, 1924••• - - - - - - - - · · · · · · · · · · · · · · November, 1m.•••••• - - - - - - · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · · Deoember,1924.--------- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis •BWIOD. Maria 248. 88 250. 50 270. 50 Marta 2U8 19.06 21. OS 28ll. 50 286. 50 296.88 22.llll 12. INI 13.99 18.63 23. 79 28.20 87.78 821.28 893.88 f18 633.M 668 613 M2.68 20. r,o 778 1138 1,093 1,3113 1,838.19 2,822.23 f,Mll.31 7,337.:M 12,773 20,789 f8, 1211 89,806 72,1ft 86,350 199,890 ffl,000 9211, 71f 6,63f,816 311, 7M.M3 - i100.2 1676 11, l!OO 1 .. l!OO 130 126() 28.50 211. f8 f2.50 68.50 74.150 104. r,o M.62 188.02 8M.33 llM.112 1,198.10 1,260.90 2,822.fO 8,698.60 8,950.10 6,371 18,163 10,020 ll8,flll 617, 1ft 8,M2,0M 7,976,200 113,fl0,400 126, f82, 400 f17, 283, 200 12,8611 1211,lfl l f6,f82 1288,208 Percent of wages 10 7.6 7.8 7.9 f.ll .. 7 6.1 8 8.1 7.1 8. 7 ... f.6 6.ll 8.3 8.8 7.6 6.2 7 8.2 8.9 9,4 8.1 8.1 6.B 6. ll 8.2 8.6 2.3 8.3 7.9 9.7 8.0 9.4 8.4 9.3 ll.6 ll.7 8.ll 1700 13, l!OO 7.7 18,333 •• I 1, Ofl, 120 •••• • f. 6 122,680 127 127 l,Of ,2 127 I, 211 •9 127 •LOS 8.9 27.23 L07 3.9 30 L28 f.2 3Lf7 L36 f.3 33.80 Llll f.6 fO L96 f.9 L75 f.4 fO IGoldmarlm. TAXES 61 The final assessment of the same printer (if he ha~ spent 500 marks a year for "acquiring expenses") would have amounted for July, 1920, to ·1,260 marks a year or 9.7 per cent of his income; for August to October, 1920, to 1,279 marks a year, or 9.8 per cent; for November, 1920, to January, 1921, to 1,490 marks a year, or 10.6 per cent; for February to March, 1921, to 1,630 marks, or 10.9 per cent. For April to November, 1921, the final assessment was equal to the deduction from the wages (if in both cases the " acquiring expenses" are placed at the rates fixed by the law of July 11, 1921). For December, 1921, the final assessment would again have been greater than the provisional deduction, since the yearly income exceeded 24,000 marks-it would have been 2,120 marks a year, or 7.6 _per cent. From and after January 1922 the income tax of the prmter was practically always settled by the deduction by the emplo_yer. For some months a :final assessment, it is true, ouglit to have taken place, but such assessments were generally dispensed with in view of the dep:reciation of the currency. The wage tax was thus pretty heavy most all the time. This did not in itself constitute an injustice, but it proved to be unjust because all other taxpayers were benefited by: the depreciation of the money. In so far as the income tax was levied upon salaries and wages before they were paid to the employees, it followed the trend of salaries and wages; but in so far as it was levied on other sources than salaries and wages it was levied in proportion, not to the present income, but to the income of one or two years before. In such cases the taxpayer got the benefit of the depreciation of the mark. Take, for instance, the case of a bank clerk m Berlin earning (on the basis of his income early in 1923), say, $20 a month or $240 a year. The income tax deducted immediately from his sal8.l"y and paid at once into the treasucy totaled, say, $20 a year. Suppose in 1921 his employer earned 50 times as much, and that he so reported to the fiscal authorities. His income, then, in 1921 was $12,000, or 1,000,000 marks. His annual income tax amounted to 380,000 marks, and one-fourth of this amount, or 95,000 marks, was still to be p·aid in the first quarter of 1923. This 95,000 marks in the first quarter of 1923 was equal to $4, as against $5 which his clerk had to pay in this same first quarter of 1923 when he earned one-fiftieth of what his employer had earned. The law which made the employer pay 38 per cent of his income of $12,000 and the em1?loyee 8 per cent of his mcome of $240 was all right, but it worked m an entirely unexpected and unjust way when the mark -J.ost value. The consequences for the treasury, of course, were disastrous. Under the assessments of 1921, not more than 18.6 per cent of the total income tax was expected fr.om deductions from salaries and wages, and 81.4 per cent from all other sources. Instead of 81 per cent, the "other sources"_yielded in September, 1922, 42 per cent; in October!.- 28 per cent; in November, 24 per cent; in December, 16 per cent; in January, 1923, 12 per cent; in February, 6.4 per cent; and in March, 5.1 per cent. The mcome tax on salaries and wages yielded all that could be expected-for instance, in tht:1 first quarter of 1923 almost $17,000,000-but the income tax from other sources, which ought to have yielded more than $70,000,000, brought only $1,300,000. 20168°-25t-6 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 62 CHAPTER II,--STANDARD AND COST 01!' LIVING Official returns for the wage tax and for the other income tax from and after February, 1923, published by the treasury, are as follows: T.A.BLB 28,-AMOUNT RECEIVED FROM THE WAGE AND OTHER INCOME TAXES, FEBRUARY, 1923, TO DECEMBER, 1924 Wage tax Year and month other income tax Per cent wage tu was of total income tu . 1923 f:~ :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: tfa1·:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• July ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• August••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ~':£=ber.::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: November .•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Deoember •••••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••••••••• 1924 ~i:-i::u~y :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: tt:-·:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::· ::::::::::: June•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• March ••••••••••.•.•••••.•••••••••••.•••••••••• July•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• August ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• September .••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• October ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.• November .••.••..••••••••••••••.•.••••••••••. Deoember ••••••••••••••••••••••••••.••••••••••• .llarb '¥1, 218, 980, 406 179, 079, 338, 667 219, 199, 00!, 073 257, 185, 168, 99& 421,683,817, 61K 1, 186, 384, 283, 923 14,619, fNT, OM, 946 2«, 231, 813, 384, 000 I 16,112', 404,670 I 5, 422, 660, 621, 266 l 37, 351, 769, 340, 959 Rffitfflmarka 7f, 716,895 63,869,282 71,230,524 79,494,327 87,889,821 96, 081, 429 108, 468, 6114 107,IK9,658 113,465,799 llf, 873, 063 119, 751, 490 126, 319, 607 .llarb 6, 606, 961, 488 9, 643, 700, 771 a8, 67f, 820, 4118 223, 799, 648, 278 89, '¥17, 682,316 99, U8f, 320, 640 11, 8liO, llf, 40G, 476 28, 483, 787, 132, 000 l l 3, 215, 687, 524 l 609,136,146,919 3, 129, 263, 688, 019 Rentmmarb 90,079,724 66,491,363 88,471,746 70,639,738 73,482,462 Sf, 995,273 83,3«,878 66,808,828 55,481,060 91,849,698 7f,467, 146 59,316,204 114 96 79 M 82 92 55 90 86 92 92 45 49 45 63 M M 67 62 67 54 62 68 1 Mllllon. During the period shown in the table the wage earners contributed between 45 and 95 per cent of the income tax. As a result of the depreciation of the mark, the income tax was not really progressiveas one might conclude from the progressive tax rates-but degressive; the workers paid more in proportion to their income than the wealthy people. Since this anomaly was not compensated by any heavy tax on property, and since the workers had to bear their share of almost all the indITect taxes, it is safe to say that-in contrast to pre-war times-the German wage earners were more heavily taxed after the war than the propertied classes. MINIMUM COST OF SUBSISTENCE The cost-of-living index calculated by the Federal Statistical Office includes only food, rent, fuel, light1 and clothing (see pp. 50 and 51). These expenses, accord.4ig to an mvestigation made by that · office in 1907-08, constituted at that time 73.4 per cent of the total expenses of an average worker's family. It would, therefore, have or 36.4 per cent to the total of the item& been necessary to add mentioned in order to find the total cost of li~. But some items not included in the cost-of-living index of the Federal Statistical Office are not such imperative needs as some that are, for example, food and housing. T.he minim.um cost of subsistence for Greater https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ;::1 • MINIMUM COST OF SUBSISTENCE 63 Berlin, has therefore been computed, by adding to the price of the minimum requirements of food, housing, fuel, light, and Qlothing 20 _per cent and also the income tax deducted from wages. Table 29 shows for Greater Berlin the minimum weekly cost of subsistence of a single man, a married couple, and a married couple with two children from 6 to 10 years of age for each month from January, 1920, to December, 1924. The food requirements considered as absolutely necessary have been described before (see p. 11); the amount for rent refers to one room and kitchen; for fuel and light 110 pounds of briquets and 6 cubic m«;iters of gas have been considered as the weekly minimum; the minimum weekly expense for clothing (including mending) for a man was considered as equivalent to the price of one-thirtieth of a man's suit plus one-thirtieth of a pair of men's shoes, while for a woman two-thirds of this price and for each child one-third of this price was considered as the minimum expense. In computing the mcome tax the wages were assumed to be equal to the minimum cost of subsistence. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 64 • CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING TABLE 29.-MINIMUM WEEKLY COST OF SUBSISTENCE IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS SINGLE HA.N Period Food Housing August, 1913, to July, Marks Marks 3. 6 1914•••••••••••••••• 1920 January•••••••••••••• February •••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••• April .•••••••••••••••• May ••••••••••••••••• June ••••••••••••••••• July•••••••••••••••••• August ..•••••••••••.• September ••••••••••• October•••••••••••••• November .•••••••••• December•.••••.••••• 41 47 59 70 68 51 51 48 48 56 54 56 5. 5 Fuel and light Mark, L9 8 8 8 9 9 11 9 9 9 9 9 9 1921 January.•.•••••.••••• February ••••••••.••• March .•••••••••••••• April ••.••••.••••••••• May ••••••••••••••••• June .•••••••••••••••• July••••••.••••••••••• August..•••.••••••••• September .•••••••••• October ••••.••••••••• November •.••••••••• December•••.•••••••• 63 50 47 46 47 55 58 62 65 70 91 103 9 9 9 9 9 9 10 10 10 10 10 10 Clothing Mfscel• Mark, Jlarka .MCll'u 23 114 2. 6 12 13 20 22 22 22 22 21 22 22 22 22 30 35 45 22 23 23 23 25 25 25 25 26 27 31 30 30 27 27 27 27 27 30 30 36 55 65 ,u 48 42 36 33 30 30 30 30 30 Total Ianeous a., 26 33 37 36 29 39 36 36 39 18.8 . 38 39 38 37 35 32 32 36 36 38 40 44 67 62 129 165 188 177 147 154 144 145 156 163 lli6 152 149 141 137 140 152 156 165 171 187 244 271 1922 January.•••.••••••••• February •••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••• 104 121 138 166 177 189 283 467 742 1,242 2. 647 3,533 tfa':·:::::::::::::::: June._ ••••••••• -·- ••• July_··-··-·-·-····--August ...•..••••••••• September ••••••••••• October···--······--· November ••••••••••• December.••••••••••• 43 62 62 74 86 96 11 11 11 14 14 14 114 14 16 16 32 72 193 65 60 85 go 100 150 154 222 435 1,079 2,084 633 988 2,207 8,683 380 530 63 61 80 96 106 130 196 321 548 894 1,982 3,100 266 306 376 440 483 579 829 1,393 2,311) 8,686 7,987 12,493 1923 January.••••••••••••• 5,799 8,467 4,377 300 5,025 18,968 February ••••.••••••• 9,633 14,653 7,667 9,354 300 41,607 13,988 11,425 8,788 6,475 660 41,336 March.·····-··--·-·· April ••••••••••••••••• 13,807 10,346 660 6,717 8,512 40,042 20,251 10,818 May ••••••••••••••••• 1,010 16,017 13,948 62,044 1,045 31,667 43,697 22,287 127,318 28,622 June.··········-·--·· July..•••••••••••••••• 162,866 111,750 85,329 101,457. 2,400 463,802 August •.••••••••••••• 2,848,204 1,775,761 9,800 2,138,805 2,050,000 S.82;570 147_4 I 73.9 149.2 155. 5 September.•••••••••• 36o, 000 226.4 I 9,838.4 I 24.6 I 15,031.9 October...••••••••••• I 21,126. 7 119,116.7 l 65,138.3 2 4,198.7 1 2,150.0 I 38. 3 I 1,650.9 12,009.5 110,047.4 November.····-····3 3.14 1 3.20 I 1.10 December.••••••••••• I 15. 99 • 5. 95 • 2.00 Renten- 1924 January...••••••••••• February_ ••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••• April ••••••••••••••••• May •••••••••••••.••• June ••••••••••••••••• July._··············· August••••••••••••••• September ••••••••••• October···-··-·- ••••• November_ •••••••••• December•••••••••••• I Millions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis marks 4.88 4.22 4.27 4. 35 4.48 4. 43 4. 49 4. 46 4. 66 4.98 4. 96 4. 95 Rentenmarks 1.10 1. 60 1. 70 2. 70 2.85 2.85 3. 50 3. 50 3. 50 3. 70 3. 70 3. 70 I Renten- marks Billlons. 3.02 2. 95 2. 91 2.85 2. 79 2. 72 2. 67 2.63 2. 61 2. 59 2. 67 2.67 Rentenmarks 2.40 2.45 2. 50 2.50 2. 50 2. 35 2. 20 2.20 2.40 2.40 2.40 2.40 Rentenmarks 2.85 2. 81 2.85 3.10 3.15 3. 09 3.22 3. 20 3.29 3. 55 3.57 3.57 • Rentenmarb. Rentenmarks 14.25 14.03 14.23 15.50 15. 77 15. 44 16.08 15.9G 16.46 17.22 17.30 17.29 . 65 MINIMUM COST OF SUBSISTENCE TABLE 29,-MINIMUM WEEKLY COST OF SUBSISTENCE IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS-Continued MARRIED COUPLE - Periqd Food Housing Fuel and light Clothing Miscellaneous Total August, 1913, to July, 1914 ________________ Mark8 Mark8 Mark8 Mark8 Marks Mark8 6.3 1920 January _____________ 64 73 00 112 112 83 86 82 81 93 February_ -- --------March _______________ April _________________ May_________________ June _________________ July _________________ August _______________ September_._ ••••••• _ October •..•••••••• ___ November.- •••••••• December•• _•••••• ___ 1.9 5.6 8 8 8 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 90 96 9 92 87 83 79 82 9 9 9 9 9 9 10 9 4.2 12 13 20 22 22 22 22 21 22 22 22 22 60 58 75 80 70 60 . 55 60 60 50 50 22 23 23 23 25 25 25 25 26 27 31 41 50 50 45 45 45 45 45 50 43 62 62 92 100 142 150 167 50 4.5 22.3 33 38 48 56 54 43 58 54 54 58 57 59 167 190 241 279 267 21; 230 216 216 232 228 236 58 56 53 48 48 54 55 58 61 66 87 231 225 218 204 1921 January••.••• -•• -•••• Febmary •••••••••••• March •.••••••••••••• April. •••••••••••••••• May·-········-·-···· June.·-·········-···· July ..•••••••••••••• _ August.•••••• ·-······ September •••••.••••• October ••••••••••.••• November ••••••••••• December•••••••••••• 98 102 108 118 128 158 177 1922 January•••••••••••••• Febmary ••••••••.••• March •••• ·-·····-··· April. ••••••••••.••••• May ••••••••••••••••• June.-··········-···· July················· August ••••••••••••••• September••••••••••• October ••.••••••••••. November ••••••••••• December•••••••••••• 181 212 241 200 308 328 493 799 1,261 2,106 4,450 6,962 1923 9,730 January···-·-········ February •••••••••••• 24,459 23,668 March_··-··········· 23,487 April_···-···········May ••••••••.•.••••.. 34,327 June ••••••••••••••••• 73,795 July ••••••••••••••••• 282, 133 August ..••••••••••• -. 4,806,409 September.•••••••••• 1123.8 October •••••••••••••• 136,353. l 1 7,069.4 November •• _•••••••• a 10.13 December•••••••••••• Renten- 1924 January-••••••••••••• Febmary ••• _•••••••• March •••••.•••• -•••. April................. May ••••••••· .•.••••• June ••••••••• ·-····-· July ••••••••••••••••• August_ •••••••••••••• September ••••••••••• October •••••••••••••• November ••••••••••• December.-----······ l marks Millions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 8.49 7.35 7.47 7.67 7.96 7.87 8.02 7.91 8. 18 8. 75 8. 69 8. 66 10 IO 10 10 10 11 11 11 14 14 74 86 14 96 114 154 14 16 16 32 50 60 92 92 250 530 1,079 2,084 370 725 1,055 1,647 3,678 6,972 1,010 1,045 2,400 9,800 360,000 124,6 t 38.3 I 1.10 3,467 7,667 11,425 10,846 10,818 22,287 85,329 I, 775,761 149.2 19,838.4 1 1,650.9 •3.H 8,375 16,056 10,792 11,194 26,694 52,778 186,250 3,416,667 I 79.1 I 31,861.1 1 3,583.3 a 4. 30 Renten- Renten- Renten- 380 72 193 300 300 660 660 mark8 marks 1.10 1.60 1. 70 2. ?O 2.85 2.85 3.50 3.50 3. 50 3. 70 3. 70 3.70 I Billions. 3.02 2. 95 2. 91 2. 85 2. 79 2. 72 2. 67 2. 63 2.61 2. 59 2.67 2.trl marks 4.00 4.10 4.15 4.15 4.15 3.90 3. 65 3.65 4.00 4.00 4.00 4.00 97 81 93 123 148 161 199 307 509 840 1,381 3,062 4,600 209 281 237 251 260 286 378 417 408 468 579 676 736 887 1,298 2,203 3,552 5,696 12,841 18,901 6,562 28,434 14,060 62,542 12,567 59,112 12,336 58,023 21,127 93,976 43,472 193,377 155,711 711,823 3,202,764 13,211,401 182.0 1334.5 123,423.2 I JQ#, 500.4 1 3,085.5 • 15,427.4 3 23.34 14. 67 Rentenmark8 4.15 4.00 4. 06 4.34 4. 44 4. 34 4.46 4.42 4.57 4.~5 4.96 4. 95 a Rentenmarks, Renlenmarks 20. 76 20.00 20.29 21. 71 22.19 21.68 22. 30 22.11 22.86 23.99 24.02 23.98 66 CHAPTER II.-STANDARD AND COST OF LIVING TABLE 29.-MINIMUM WEEKLY COST OF SUBSISTENCE IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS-Concluded MARRIED COUPLE WITH TWO CIIILDBEN Total Period August, 1913, to July, 1914- ___ --- _------1920 January _____________ February____________ March __________ ---April ________________ Food Marki 9.8 May ______ ---------June ________________ July _________________ August_------------September ___________ October _____________ November __________ December ___________ 86 100 125 157 16.1 128 135 131 123 138 136 144 1921 January _____________ February____________ March ____ ---------APril-- ·------------May-----------•••• June ________________ July _________________ August_ _____________ September __________ October _____________ November __________ December ___________ 139 133 129 121 122 142 151 156 162 176 222 249 1922 January _____________ February____________ March ______________ tfariL _______________ June ________________ ay --------------July _________________ August ______________ September___________ October _____________ November___________ December ___________ 1923 January, _____________ February____________ March ______________ ~rn ________________ 257 299 351 417 444 466 700 1,091 1,726 2,820 5,934 8,164 13,098 32,376 31,957 32,198 ay --------------- 45,312 June ________________ 98,579 July _________________ 391,458 August ______________ 6,307,538 September ________ --: October _____________ November___________ December ___________ 1924 January _____________ February____ •••••••• March. _____________ ~rn_ ------------- -June ay_________________ - - - - -----------July _________________ August ______________ September___________ October _____________ November___________ December ___________ I Millions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Housing Marki 5. 5 8 8 8 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 9 Fuel and light Mark, 12 13 20 22 22 22 22 21 22 22 22 22 22 9 9 9 9 9 10 10 10 10 10 10 23 23 23 11 11 11 43 52 14 74 86 96 114 164 380 530 1,079 2,084 300 300 Marki 1. 9 9 14 14 M 16 16 32 72 193 Clothing 25 25 25 25 26 27 31 41 62 5.9 Mlscellaneous Marki 5.8 70 82 44 61 106 112 64 98 75 73 84 77 70 70 70 70 70 61 81 82 77 75 79 79 70 80 63 63 63 63 63 70 70 84 128 128 78 74 65 66 72 75 78 81 89 118 129 128 140 198 210 109 125 167 70 233 350 518 1,015 1,477 2,306 5,149 8,361 200 218 269 417 682 1,115 1,820 4,037 6,202 Index numbers Amount (191314-1) Marki 1 28.8 7.7 220 254 822 8.8 11.2 13.0 12. 7 10.6 11.3 10. 7 10.4 11.0 11.0 11.8 3711 3611 304 324 308 299 318 316 827 320 313 11.1 10.9 10.3 298 281 285 311 324 339 349 9.8 - 9.9 10.8 11.2 11.8 12.1 13.4 17.7 19.3 386 509 557 548 627 789 915 995 1,195 1,763 2,958 4,714 7,508 16,271 24,994 19.0 21.8 27.4 31.8 . 34.5 41.6 61.2 102. 7 163. 7 260. 7 565.0 867.9 3,467 7,667 11,725 8,577 37,167 1,29o. 5 22,478 18,218 81,039 2,813.8 15,108 15,971 75,121 2,608.4 10,346 15,672 15,896 74,772 2,596.3 10. 818 37,372 27,409 121,921 4,233.4 22,287 73,889 56,782 252,582 8,770.2 85,329 260,750 207,182 947,119 32,886.1 1,775,761 4,783,333 4,120,458 16,996,890 690,170 1 162. 2 360,000 149.2 I 110. 7 I 104. 8 1427,3 114.8 151,561.3 I 24. 6 19,838.4 149,606.6 133,309.0 1144,338. 9 111,011.8 I 9,354.3 I 38,3 I 1,650.9 15,016.7 14,015.0 120,075,2 I 697, 1 1 14. 39 I 1,10 16,05 13.14 I 30,85 • 6.17 '1.07 660 660 1,010 1,045 2,400 9,800 11,425 Rente11,mark, luntenmark, Rentenmark, 12. 47 10.89 11.07 11.39 11.94 11. 67 12.10 1. 10 1.60 1. 70 2.70 2. 85 2. 85 3.50 3. 50 11.77 12.10 12. 95 12. 81 12. 74 • Billions. 3.50 3. 70 3. 70 3. 70 Ren/enmarka 3.02 2. 95 2. 91 2.85 2. 79 2. 72 2. 67 2.63 2.61 2.59 2.67 2. 67 • Rentenmarks. 5,60 5.80 5.85 5.85 5.85 5.50 5.15 6.15 5.60 5.60 6. 60 6.60 Rentenmarka 5. 55 6. 31 5.38 5. 70 6. 86 6. 69 5.86 6. 76 5,95 6.46 6.44 6.42 lunte11,marka 27. 74 26. 55 26.91 28.49 29.29 28.43 29.28 28.81 29. 76 31.30 31.22 31.13 , Based on rentenmarks. '.96 '· 92 '.93 '.99 'L02 '.99 '1.02 'I. 00 '1.03 '1.09 '1.08 'LOS 67 MINIMUM COST OF SUBSISTENCE In Table 30 the minimum cost of subsistence of a married couple with two children from 6 to 10 years of age in Greater Berlin is shown in dollars (calculated on the exchange rate of marks in Berlin) and index numbers thereof, with the price in 1913-14 ($6.86) taken as the base. According to this standard the fluctuations were enormous. In January, 1920, the minimum cost of subsistence was one-half of what it was before the war; it dropped to three-eighths in February and increased to one and one-fifth m July. From August, 1920, to October, 1923, it was always below the pre-war cQst. The minimum was reached in November, 1921, when it was only two-sevenths of what it was before the war. In November, 1923, it was one-third higher than 10 years before, but when the mark was stabilized the mmimum cost of subsistence in Greater Berlin dropped again, and since the second half of December, 1923, it has been about the same as before the war. 30.-MINIMUM WEEKLY OOST OF SUBSISTENOE IN DOLLARS, FOR A MAR• RIED OOUPLE WITH TWO OHILDREN IN GREATER BERLIN, AND INDEX NUMBERS THEREOF, JANUARY, 1920, TO DEOEMBER, 1924 TABLB Month January ••••.••••••••••••••••••••••.•.••••• February ...•.•...........•...•........... March. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• tf: ·::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• July •••••.••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••••• ---······················· August ~11:,bRr :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Novemw •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• December·-----············· 1920 1921 $3.40 2. 66 $4.93 6. 29 4.42 4.58 4.48 4. 23 4.02 3.33 2.57 L94 3.01 3. 84 7.85 7.77 8. 21 6.45 II. 16 4.66 4.09 4.48 11.11 4. 77 1922 $2.86 3. 02 2. 78 3.14 3.43 3. 76 3. 57 2.61 3.22 2. 36 2.27 3. 29 1923 $2.07 2.90 3. 55 3. 06 2.66 2.30 2. 68 3. 68 4. 32 II. 71 9.15 7.35 $6. 61 6. 32 6.41 6. 79 6.97 6.77 6.97 6.86 7.09 7.45 7.43 7.41 Index numbers (1013-14=1) January··································· February•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• March. ••••••••••••••••••••••.••••••••••••• tFar:·::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• July ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ~=ber . : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : August •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• NovembRr -•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• December .....••••••...•..........•....... https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 0. 50 ,37 .66 ,91 L15 1.14 L20 .94 .75 .68 .60 .65 0. 72 .75 ,69 .65 .67 ,65 .61 .59 .48 .37 .28 .42 0.42 .44 .41 .46 .50 .55 .52 .38 .47 .34 .33 .48 0.30 .42 .52 .45 .37 .33 .39 .54 .63 .83 L33 1.07 0. 96 .92 .93 .99 1.02 .99 1.02 1.00 1,03 1.00 1.08 1.08 Chapter m.-COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS LEGISLATION Before the World War collective agreements concluded between -employers or organizations of employers on the one hand, and o~• izations of workers or of salaried employees on the other hand, with the object of regulating working conditions and wages, had become of great importance in German economic life. Accoriling to statistics of the Federal Statistical Office there were on Decemlier 31, 1913, 10,885 collective agreements, coveriJ:ig 143,088 establishments and 1,398,597 employees (workers and salaried employees). Yet there was no special law regulating such agreements., the relations between the two parties being r02Ulated by the general principles of the civil law as to contracts. Political parties· in Parliament had repeatedly demanded legal re~ation of collective agreements, but the Government had never yielded to such requests, as it was afraid that legal regulation would hamper the natural and sound development of collective agreements, and employers and employees did not insist. During the war, when the preservation of economic peace was vital, some military authorities tried to guarantee, by military decrees, the strict observance of collective agreements. A comprehensive regulation of collective agreements by law took place, however, only after the war. A few days after the revolution, on November 15, 1918, the large employers' associations stipulated in an ~eement with the tradeunions 1 that "the working conditions of all male and female workers are to be determined, in accordance with conditions in the trade in question, througli collective agreements with the workers' trade organizations. Negotiations relating thereto shall be initiated immediately and concluded as soon as possible:" On December 23, 1918, the Council of People's Commissioners issued a "decree regulating collective agreements, workers' and salaried employees' committees, and arbitration of labor disputes." 3 The main object of the decree was to insure stability of economic life by creating equality in working conditions a.s far as possible. The provisions relating to collective agreements (articles 1 to 6 of the decree) have not since been materiall;y changed or enlarged. While they do not involve a complete regulation of collective agreements, these provisions (1) establish the principle of the obligation of the parties to live up to the agreement (principle of nondeviation) ; (2) determine the parties who are entitled to conclude a collective agreement; and (3) authorize the Minister of Labor, under certain conditions, to declare a collective agreement generally binding beyond the domain of the contracting parties. I See Monthly Lnbor Review, April, 1919, pp. 158-160. • Idem, pp. 160-167. 68 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis . 69 CHAPTER m.-COLI.ECTIVE AGREEMENTS .ACTUAL DEVELOPMENT AB a consequence of the agreement of November 15, 1918, and the decree of December 23, 1918, as well as the enormous increase in the membership of employers' associations and trade-unions, collective agreements became almost universal. Their number, it is true, did not increase-being 10,885 on December 31, 1913, and 10,768 nine years later-but the number of firms and the number of employees covered by them were much greater. The number of collective agreements, with the number of establishments and employees covered, on December 31 of each year from 1912 to 1922 is shown in Table 31. TABLE 31.-NUMBER OF COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS AND NUMBER OF ESTABLISH• MENTS AND EMPLOYEES COVERED, 1912 TO 1922 ... ~.!•• Date Col• Establectlve llsh• agree ments ments covered December 311912•••••••••••••• 10,739 1913-------·-----)914 ____ • _________ 10,885 10,840 1915-----·-------1916 ______________ 10,171 9,435 1911-----·-------- 8,854 159,930 143,088 143,650 121,697 104,179 91,313 Employ• ees covered 1,574,285 1,398,r/¥7 1,39,5, 723 943,442 740,074 905,670 Date December 311918 --------1919 _____ ______________ 1920______________ 192]. _____________ 1922 ------------- Col• Estab- Employ• lecth·e lish· ees agree- ments covered ments covered 7,819 11,000 11,624 107,503 272,251 434,004 697,476 10,768 800,237 11,488 1,127,690 5,986,475 9,561,323 12,882,874 14,261,106 The number of establishments bound by collective agreements, which had decreased from 143,088 at the end of 1913 to 91,313 at the end of 1917, increased to 890,237 at the end of 1922, while the number of employees affected by the agreements, which had dropped from 1,398,597 in 1913 to 905,670 in 1917, increased to 14,261,106 in 1922. AB a consequence thereof, the average number of establishments covered by a collective agreement increased from 13 in 1913 to 83 in 1922, and the average number of employees affected by a collective agreement from 128 to 1,324. The working conditions of salaried employees are not generally regulated by the same collective agreements as those of the workers, only 52 agreements in 1921 having been found covering both groups of employees. The total number of agreements covering salaried employees (included, of course, in the figures of Table 31) was 1,272 at the end of 1920, 1,481 at the end of 1921, and 1,464 at the end of 1922; the number of establishments was 70,958, 145,487, and 172,280, respectively; the number of salaried employees bound by such agree-'ments, 931,357hl,811,300, and 1,970,754, respectively. It must be borne in mind, owever, that all the figures mentioned in this chapter refer only to such agreements as were reported to the Federal Statistical Office or to the Ministry of Labor. In the course of time the reJ>orting of collective agreements, particularly those covering salariea employees, became more complete, which accounts, to a certain extent, for the apparently large increase in collective agreements for salaried employees in 1921.8 • On the other band, the apparent decrease or establishments and employees covered by collective agreements In 1913 and 1914 as compared with 1912 ls due to the fact that In those two years many local collective Blll"eements were concluded In the building trades which were not recognized by the central unions -and therefore were not reported to tne Federal l!tatlstlcal O:tllce. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 70 OH.APTER ID.-OOLLEOTIVE AGREEMENTS The increase in female em{>loyees covered by these agreement.a was especially conspicuous, bemg from 1,665,115 at the end of 1920 to 2,729,788 at the end of 1921, and to 3,161,268 at the end of 1922; th~per cent increasedJrom 17 to 21 and then to 22. The industries in which collective agreements existed at the end of 1922 and the number and_per cent of establishments and employees covered are shown in Table 32: 32.-NUMBER AND PER OENT OF OOLLEOTIVE AGREEMENTS AND ESTAB• LISHMENTS AND EMPLOYEES OOVERED, DEOEMBER 31, 192'l, BY INDUSTRIES TABLII Percent Number IDdustq Estab- Employees covered Agree. llshAgreements meuts ments COV• Total Female ered ~cul=~enlng, and forestry •••• 4411 307,178 1,996,917 Ines, sm works, and salt works. 177 3,688 1,589,992 ilO,SM Sto:t clay, an glass products ••••••••• 695 10,369 Me working and miehlnery ••••••••• 1,326 60,819 2,924,979 Ohemloals ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 92 11,188 396, 7117 Forest by•prodaots, soap and fats •••••• 111 614 29,918 Textiles.......... • ••••••••• 530 19,868 1,038,330 f 115 9,204 6,749 221,586 122,717 413,504 462,855 488,570 32,076 809, li92 186,862 2,923 616,475 r=er :::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 229 Lumber•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 406 28,677 Food, liquors, and tobacco ••••••••••••• 1,556 711,731 843 64,017 223 Lii=::============================ 16,282 986 46 211,891 68,780 Art lndastrles•••••••••••••••••••••••••• 8 656 Oommeroe ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1,000 68,417 IDsaranoe •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 7o,2Ui 6 302 Transportation••••••••••••••••••••••••• 625 22,462 1,095,115 Hotela and restaurants ••••••••••••••••• 115 16,682 102,777 Musical, theatrical, etc., shows••••••••• 168 2,925 46,209 Mlsoellaneoas•••••••••••••••••••••••••• 968 79,758 1,202,384 72,571 346,3311 67,670 7,614 633,784 95,848 29,049 50,869 193,466 289,962 17,002 2,654 48,879 72 4.2 1.6 6.4 12.3 .9 LO 4.9 1.1 2.1 3. 8 14.4 7.8 2.1 9.2 .4 2211, 716 15,068 36,326 48,459 16,171 288,702 .1 10.1 .1 6. 8 1.1 1.6 9.0 Total •••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 10,768 890,237 14,261,106 3,161.268 100.0 ' 1 GlU,146 40,906 Employees covered Establlsh· meuts COV• Feered Total Dlllle 34.11 •• L2 6. 7 1.3 .1 2.2 1.0 .8 3.2 8. 5 7.2 LS 7. 7 2. 9 .1 7.7 14.0 11.2 2. 9 20.11 2.8 20.1 1.3 2.3 lLO 2.1 7.8 L6 20.1 3. 0 ,2 .9 2.9 3.2 3. 4 .2 6. 7 .2 .9 1.6 6.1 9.2 .II 7.7 .7 .3 8.4 .1 L6 (1) 7.1 .II L2 ·Lil .II 9.1 100. 0 ,100. 0 100. 0 L3 ~8 .o .II 2. 5 1.9 .3 9.0 I Less than one-tenth of 1 per cent. The largest number of employees bound by collective agreements in any industry on December 31, 1922, was 2,924,979, in the metal working and machinery industry, followed by agriculture etc., with 1,996,917, mines, etc., with 1,589,992, transportation with 1,095,115 (among which were 593t698 employed by the State railways), textiles with 1,038,330, and bui1di.J!g with 809,592. The building industry, which before the war employed more persons covered by collective agreements than any otlier mdustry, thus occupied only sixth rank in 1922. The largest number of women covered by collective agreements was to be found in agriculture, etc., and the next largest number in the textile industry. Before the war only a small proportion of the collective agreements were enter~d into by emY,loy:ers' associations or by guilds, the large majority being by mdiVIaua.I :firms. After the war, the proportion of a~eements concluded by :firms decreased from year to year, until from 1920 on the majority of the collective agreements were entered into by emplo_yers' associations or guilds. Table 33 shows the per cent of collective agreements concluded by :firms and by organizations from 1912 to 1922. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 71 ACTUAL DEVELOPMENT TOLi: 33,-PER OENT OF OOLLEOTIVE AGREEMENTS OONOLUDED BY FIRMS AND BY ORGANIZATIONS,• 1912 TO 1922 Organizations Date Ffnm Guilds Only on employees' side On both sides Estab- PerEstab• Per• Esteb- PerEstab- Per• lish• sons Agre&- llsh• sons lish• sons Agre&- llsh· sons Agre&- ments Agre&- ments ments COV• ments COV• COV• ments ment.s COV• ment.s COV• ment.s COV• COV· COV• ered ered ered ered ered ered ered ered December 311912•••••••• 1913•••••••• 191'-. ••••••• 19111•••••-.. •• 1916•••••••• 1917•••••••• 1918•••••••• 1919•••••••• 1920.••••••• 1921 •••••••• 1922•••••••• 22.6 18. 11 20. 9 22.3 24.0 26. 5 29.1 39.9 44.0 48.7 49.5 63. 2 118.8 60.5 60.0 60.6 60.4 61.3 73.8 79.2 82. 7 86.1 65. 4 60.8 63. 7 62.3 56.0 62. 11 64. 3 81.0 75. 3 82. 2 83.9 72. 8 33.8 38.4 37.1 37.6 37.0 37.2 36.9 25.9 20.6 17.3 13.9 77.2 75. 2 74.0 72.6 70. 6 68.4 59.8 57. 7 51.1 5o. 0 31.6 35. 9 33.9 35. 3 41.3 35. 5 34.6 19.0 24. 7 17. 7 16.0 s.7 5. 7 5. 5 5. 6 6.1 6.3 6. 7 8. 7 8.9 9.2 9.2 22.0 24. 9 23.5 21.5 24.1 24. 0 25.9 22. 0 16. 9 13.4 11.0 6.8 9.0 8.4 5. 6 6. 8 5. 7 5. 7 3.1 1.7 LIi 1.1 73.6 78. 2 76.1 74.8 72.8 72. 2 69.4 54.0 48. 7 43. 7 42.4 211.8 29.6 28.6 30.8 28.9 34.0 28. 5 12.3 8.4 6.1 4. 9 33.4 37.6 34. 6 38.4 45.2 41.2 36.4 18. 6 ~4 17.3 15. 7 • In some cases agreements were concluded on the employers' side both by an employers' organlzatlon and by firms not belonging to the organization. The increasing number of collective agreements concluded by employers' organizations accounts in part for the increasing "J)oncentration" of agreements, which resulted, as has been shown above, in an ever-increasing average number of establishments covered by one agreement. Thls increase in the. average number of establisliments and in the average number of employees per agreement was further promoted by an increase in the collective agreements concluded for the entire country, for a district, or for a locality, instead offor an individual firm, as shown in Table 34. T.&BLB 34.-PER OENT OF OOLLEOTIVE AGREEMENTS COVERING TERRITORY, 1912 TO 1922 Locality District EstebIEstab• Em• A llsh• ploy• Agree- llsh• m : ments ees ment.s ments COV• COV• COV• ered ered ered Em• Estebploy• Agree- llsh· ees ment.s ments COV• COV• ered ered Em• Estab• Em• ploy• Agree- llsh· plo7• ees ments ments ees COV• COV• COV• ered ered ered 18.0 17.9 17.3 14.3 19.5 18.0 20.6 12. 0 9. 7 7.5 7.8 60. 2 46.1 49.2 46. 9 34.9 39.0 26.8 63.7 56. 5 66.8 71.9 Individual firm" Date S~EOIFIED December 311912.••••••••••• 1913•••••••••••• 1914 .••••••••••• 1915•••••••••••• 1916.••••••••••• 1917.•.•••••••.• 1918••.••••••••• 1919•••••••••••• 1920•••••••••••• 1921. ••••••••••• 1922•••••••••••• 72. 7 77.0 74.8 73.4 7L3 68.8 65.8 62.6 47. 7 42. 7 41.6 18.8 21.8 2L0 21.8 22.3 22.3 14. 9 7.9 4.8 4.1 1.4 12.9 26.6 11.9 30.4 28.0 12.2 28.0 . 12. 7 14.1 36. 5 31.8 15.7 27.2 17.1 16.5 23.3 12. 2 26. 7 29.0 9.4 26. 9· 5. 9 29.1 27.1 26.0 25.2 28. 6 30.0 29. 7 26.1 211. 6 18.1 16.3 14. 3 11.0 12. 9 13.8 14.6 15.3 16. 9 23. 7 24. 9 27.6 30. 7 46.3 44.6 46.6 44.8 43.5 40-1 37.8 56.6 51.5 64. 8 75. 0 Entire country 0. 1 .1 .1 .1 .1 .2 .2 .7 .7 .7 .8 5.8 6.11 6.4 8. 2 5.6 7.6 17.6 9.5 18. l 13.0 7.3 5.2 5.6 5. 5 10.8 9.1 11. 2 25.4 7.8 2L6 16.3 14.4 Before the war collective agreements were generall;y made for comparatively long periods. Iii 1912 and 1913, more than half of the workers covered by collective agreements had their working conditions regulated by agreements running for more than twoJ,ears, while the proportion of such workers at the end of 1922 was o y 0.9 per cent. Tlie main reason for this change was the monetary depreciation, which necessitated a constant change in wages and siuaries. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 72 CHAPTER ID,--OOLLEOTIVE AGREEMENTS When, however, the fall of the mark became more and more rapid. the terms of collective agreements were adapted to such unusual conditions and it again became customary_ to make collective agreements for longer periods but to provide for changes of wages and salaries within the period covered liy the agreement. Of the total agreements concluded in 1920, 1921, and 1922, the following proportions were for fixed periods: In 1920, 58.4 per cent, covering 72 _per cent of the establislii:nents and 75.5 per cent of the employees; m 1921, 57.8 per cent, covering 79.7 per cent of the establishments and 78.1 per cent of the employees; and in 1922, 53.2 per cent, covering 80.3&er cent of the estaolishments and 78. 7 these agreements for fixed periods, the per cent of" the employees. proportion concluaed for certain fixed periods and the p:roportion of tn.e establishments and emplo_yees working under the agreements for such periods, are shown in Table 35. TABLE 36.-PER OENT OF OOLLEOTIVE AGREEMENTS OONOLUDED FOR SPEOIFIED PERIODS AND OF ESTABLISHMENTS AND EMPLOYEES WORKING UNDER OOLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS CONCLUDED FOR SUCH PERIODS, 1920 TO 1922 Dec. 31, 1920 JEstabAgree- lishments ments covered Period covered by agreement Fb:ed period__________________________ 3 months or less___________________ Over 3 to 6 months _______________ Over 6 months to 1 year __________ Over 1 year to 2 years_____________ Over 2 years. _____________________ Dec. 31, 1921 EmEstabploy- Agree- lish• ees ments ments covcovered ered Dec. 31, 1922 EmEstabploy- Agree- Iishees ments ments COV• COV• ered ered Em• ploy- ees COV• ered 58.4 72.0 75.5 67.8 79.7 78.1 53.2 80.3 78. 7 22. 9 12.8 13.5 41.6 21.5 10.6 17.0 25.2 22.5 18.6 10.0 8.4 63.1 24. l 12.5 12. li 23.1 16.8 6.4 28.2 1.1 14.9 LO 9.1 7.8 64.9 24. 6 33. 7 16. 2 2.6 41.3 14. l 2.4 37.8 111.9 1.2 4.4 li0.7 44. 7 4.6 66. 7 20.8 LIi 27.3 .9 The ·proportion of employees affected by agreements concluded for more than six montlis thus increased .during 1921 from 57.8 to 75 per cent, and during 1922 to 83.1 per cent. At the same time, the proportion of employees bound by collective agreements providing for changes of wages or salaries within the period covered by the agreement increased from 38.6 to 51.5 per cent in the course of 1921 and to 53.2 per cent in 1922. Before the war collective agreements regulated mainly hours of work, wages, terms of notice to quit, conditions of apprenticeship, and means of conciliation and arbitration. Provisions as to vacations of employees were to be found in .only a few collective agreements. Nowadays collective aP."eements which do not regulate vacations are an exception. ProV1Sions relating to the use of s_pecified employment agencies are somewhat more frequent than before the . war but still are not usual. The number of collective agreements which are generally binding was 1,297 on December 31, 1924. LEGAL REGULATION The legislation on collective ~_eements has defined the term II collective agreement," the meaning of which had theretofore been strongly contested. It has declared the :princi.P.le of nondeviation from tlie collective agreement, under which mdiviaual labor contracts https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis LEGAL REGULATION 73 between the interested parties shall be ineffective in so far as they do not conform to such agreement. It has also strengthened the idea that in case no other arrangement is made the collective agreement is to be considered as recognized, by expressly stating that collective agreements that have become of predominant importance in the development of working conditions in an occupation within the territory covered by the agreement may be declared generally binding. The procedure for declaring an agreement generally bmding has been regulated in detail, and during the period of inflation simplified Finally, copies of all collective ~eements, including those not de· clared generally binding, are to be filed with the Ministry of LaborDEFINITION A collective agreement, according to article 1 of the decree of December 23, 1918, is an agreement in writing which regulates the conditions under which labor contracts between organizations of employees and individual employers or organizations of employers may be concluded. 1. It must be an agreement, i. e., a voluntary arrangement between several contracting :earties. The collective-agreement legislation thus recogrrizes the prmciple of freedom of contract, and therefore it is not possible to compel an employer or an employee to enter into a collective agreement. The agreement must be made in writing. Verbal agreements or agreements signed by one party only are not considered collective agreements within the meaning of the decree. A collective agreement can be made verbally, but such agreement does not enjoy the legal protection granted to written agreements, is not impressed with the principle of nondeviation, and can not be declared generally binding. Awards made by official arbitration boards or arbitrators in general disputes, i. e., disputes between one or several employers on the one hand and the employees or a part of the employees of an establishment or a trade on tne other hand, are also considered collective agreements, in so far as these awards regulate conditions for making labor contracts. They are so considered, however, only where both parties, i. e., employers and employees, have accepted them or where they have been declared generally binding by an arbitrator under article 6 of the decree of October 30, 1923, relating to the adjustment of labor disputes. In the latter case, the declaration making them generally binding takes the place of the acceptance of the award by the parties. 2. The parties to the collective Rg!"eement must be entitled to enter into such an agreement if it is to be legally effective within the meaning of the decree. On the employers' side the agreement may be made by individual employers or by one or several organizations of employers; on the employees' side it must always be made by one or several ol"§anizations of employees. The term 'organization of employers or employees," as used in the decree regulating collective agreements and also in practically all labor laws, has never been legally defined. In consequence thereof many disputes have sprung up with reference to the definition of "o~anization of employees." Theory and practice, however have at last developed a definite conception of organizations of empioyees entitled to conclude collective agreements. The organization must https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 74 OHA.PTER ID,-COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS be founded as a permanent one. If, then, the employees of an establi.8hment create an organization for the purpose of concluding a collective agreement, such organization is not one entitled to sign a col. lective agreement within the meaning of the decree.' Nor can a works council make a legally effective collective agreement with its employer, since its task 1s not to make ~eements bu.t to carry out existing agreements. Moreoveri the obJects of the organization, which must be shown in its bv- aws, must be along economic lines. Finally, the membership of the organization must be composed entirely either of employers or of employees. Organizations of emJ?loyees, in particular, must receive their financial support exclusively from contributions of their members and not wholly or in part from employers or their representatives. So far as trade-unions are concerned, the free (Social Democratic), the Christian, and the Hirsch-Duncker (liberal) unions have been recognized as organiz'ations entitled to make collective agreements. Only such organizations of employees, indeed, as are willing and able independently to safeguard their mterests can make collective ~ements. This could not be true of organizations includi~ both employers and employe~ as the employers would naturally consider their own interests. The same is true of organizations such as "yellow unions," which in general are influenced by employers and subsidized by them in one way or another. 3. The collective agreement regulates the conditions under which labor contracts may be concluded'. It is not itself a labor contract, but states only the main provisions of future labor contracts. It does not necessarily r~ate all provisions of future labor contractsJ but may confine itself to some of them. As a matter of principle, however, the parties can regulate through a collective agreement anything that can lawfully be included in the individual labor contract. Provisions which would conflict with any law, or which are immoral, are of course ineffective. Generally, collective agreements also contain provisions outside the domain of mdividual labor contracts, such as provisions relating to the restriction of apprenticeship, the use of specified employment agencies, the means of conciliation and arbitration, etc. 4. Collective agreements also contain provisions as to the occupations, t~rritory, and period covered. Such provisions must be particularly accurate because of the principle of nondeviation involved. In respect to territory, the agreement may cover either the whole of Germany, or a district, a locality, or an establishment. A!?reements covering the whole of Germany or a district, i. e.t a State, a1.>rovince, etc., contain as a rule only general provisions; they are basic agreements and are supplemented by local collective ~eements. Such local agreements are, however, frequently concluded indeJ>endently. The agreements for individual establishments are as a rule not restricted to one occupation but cover all the employees of the concern. It may happen, therefore, that an employer is bound by several collective ~reements which are contradictory. In such cases the agreement which is the most favorable to the employees is to govern the working conditions. As tlie decree makes no provision as to the period for which a collective agreement is to run, the parties are free to determine the dura• The same Is tme of all organizations whose membership is con11ned to employees of an Individual eatabllahment. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis LEGAL REGULATION 75 tion of the ~ement; in doubtful cases the civil law rules. As the fa.te of indindua.l labor contracts in case a collective ~eement is eha.nged or terminated is not specified in the decree, the civil law again prevails, and when a collective agreement terminates, individual labor contracts remain in force until explicitly changed. POLICY OF NONDEVIATION The provisions of a oollective agreement can not be deviated from, i. e., tlie_y are binding on the contract~ parties. Article 1 of the decree of December 23hl918, provides that "labor contracts between the interested parties s all be meffective in so far as they_ do not comform '' to the regt]Jations of the collective agreement. The favorable conditions of a collective agreement can not therefore be waived by the employees. The principle of nondeviation applies, however, only to those _provisions of a collective agreement wliich may be contamed in an mdividual labor contractz such as provisions referring to wages, hours of work, vacations, and torm and terms of notice to g_uit, while provisions binding only the contracting parties, such as tliose referrmg to the duration of the agreement, the use of certain employment agencies, and the prohibition as to employing persons not covered by the agreement atlower wages than tliose fixed in the agreement are not subject to this principle. In case an employer or an employee violates such a provision, the contracting parties are entitled to protest to the organization of which that employer or employee is a member, but no direct pressure can be brought upon tlie mdividual employer or em_ployee. The decree allows two exceptions from the principle of nondeviation: (a) Nonconforming contracts shall be effective in so far as the collective agreement permits their conclusion. Collective agreements regulate, for example, the w~es of efficient workers., but a.t the same time may specify that spemal arrangements may t>e m.a.de as to wages of those physically disabled. (b) Nonconforming contracts shall be effective in so far as they provide for working conditions more favorable to the worker and not explicitly excluded by the collective agreement. The working conditions fixed by collective agreements are thus, in general, only minimum conditions for individual labor contracts. The principle of nondeviation, however, a,Pplies only to a. labor contract between the "interested parties.' Interested pa.rties, within the meaning of the decree, are "employers and employees who are parties to the collective agreement or members of the signatory organizations, or who on the conclusion of the labor contract are members of those organizations, or who have concluded a labor contract which refers to the collective agreement." Individual labor contracts between a party not bound by a collective ~eement and a party bound by such agreement are, therefore, not subject to t~e principle of nondeviation unless the parties in the contract have explicitly referred to the collective agreement. AGREEMENTS DECLARED GENERALLY BINDING While the principle of nondeviation applies only to those individual labor contracts which are concluded by the "interested parties," a collective agreement can be extended to include outsid•rs https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 76 CHAPTER m,-COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS by declaring such agreement generally binding. The object of such a declaration is to equalize wor~ conditions in a certain occupation in a certain district. The declaration can be made only upon request and only in the case of a collective agreement whicli has "become of predominant importance in the development of working conditions in an occupation within the territory covered by the agreement" (article 2). In practice, the condition as to predominant importance is considered to have been met if the working conditions of the majority of the persons in the occupation covered by the agreement correspond to tlie provisions of the agreement, whether or not this majority actually belongs to the signatory organizations. . Under the decree of December 23, 1918, the Department of Labor (Reichsarbeitsami,) was authorized to declare collective agreements binding. When this department, in 1919, was made a ministry (Reichsarbeitsministerium), this ministry made such declarations. In June, 1922, the authority to make such declarations was transferred to the Federal Labor Office (Reichsarbeitsverwa1tu'Tlfl).; which is under the supervision of the Ministry of Labor. The Laoor Office is not obliged to declare an agreement generally binding, even if all the conditions are fulfilled but is free to decide as it sees fit. It can reject the request for such a declaration; it can comply with it in full; it can reduce the territory for which it has been asked to issue the declaration; or it can exclude certain provisions of the agree:qient from the declaration. The decision of the Labor Office is final and can not be appealed from. · On such a declaration the collective agreement in question, within the territory in which it is binding, becomes aJso binding on employers or employees or both who are not interested parties to the agreement; they are also bound by the principle of nondeviation as applied to working conditions fixed b_y the agreement. In so far as exISting labor contracts are in conflict with the provisions of a collective agreement which has been declared generally binding, such labor contracts become ineffective and are automatically replaced by the provisions of the collective agreement. Just as the principle of nondeviation applies only to those provisions of collective agreements which may be contained in an individual labor contract, so only such provisions can be affected by the declaration that the agreement is generally binding. Likewise, only those provisions can be affected which do not violate a law or which are not immoral. In practice, the latter provisions are always explicitly excluded from the declaration. The declaration affects only such individual labor contracts as . have been concluded within the territory for which the collective agreement is declared generally binding. In case there exist within the territory several generally binding collective agreements and a labor contract comes under such several agreements, that agreement shall be considered as governing whose provisions cover the largest number of labor contracts in force in the establishment or the subdivision of the establishment-without prejudice, however, to a cont!'My decision by the Labor Office. The beginning of the period for which the agreement is generally binding is fixed by the Labor Office in its declaration, and the perioa . lasts until the Labor Office cancels the declaration. The right of cancellation is not specified in the decree, but since the Labor Office https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis LEGAL REGULATION 77 is authorized to declare an agreement generally binding, it is also entitled to cancel such declaration either because conditions which led to the declaration have materially changed or because the agreement declared generally binding has expired. The signatory parties to a collective agreement may change a collective agreement which has been declared generally binding, but only to the advantage of the employees. Such change, however, a:ffects only the labor contracts of the "interested parties. " Before the change can affect labor contracts of those not parties to the agreement it must first be declared generally binding. Under the law on employment offices, tlie public and the private noncommercial employment offices, in case there is a collective agreement, are to fill vacancies in establishments covered by such agreement only in accordance with conditions corres.1:onding to the agreement. 5 They therefore need to be acquainted with such agreements. Factory mspectors, who take part in the ing_uiry as to the predominant importance of an agreement, and otlier authorities are in a similar position. The "interested" employers and organizations of employers and employees are therefore required, within two weeks of the conclusion of the agreement, to supply free of charge to the following authorities copies or reprints of the agreement, as well as all changes and supplements agreed upon: 1. The Federal Labor Office (Reichsarbeitsverwal:tung), which files the agreements. 2. The district employment offices (Landesamter fur Arbeitsvermitftung) in the territory in which the agreement is valid. On payment of costs, they can demand further copies of the agreements for the use of the public employment offices of their distnct. · 3. The central authority of the district (LandeszentralbihiJrde). 4. The factory inspectors in whose districts establishments covered by the agreement are situated. The Federal Labor Office and the district employment offices are likewise to be informed of the expiration of a collective agreement. fo case of noncompliance with these requirements penalties may be imposed. The Federal Labor Office not only files the collective agreements but also is charged with the publication of information relative thereto. The matter collected and disseminated furnishes the basis for future legislation and for the work of conciliators and arbitrators, and enables the public and especially the representatives of employers and employees engaged in collective bargaining to keep constantly in touch with the development of collective liargaining both in general and :particular trades. Such publication consists of articles on the proVIsions of collective agreements, of reports on collective bargamil!g, and of statistics of collective agreements, printed in the Reiclisarbeitsblatt and its supplements. The great influence of collective agreements upon the development of labor legislation can best be seen from the fact that the law on works councils is based to a great extent on the promions of collective agreements, some of the provisions of the law having been taken literally from collective agreements. L. I Bee Chapter vn, "Unemployment" (pp. 146 to 189), 20168°-25t--6 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Chapter IV.-TRADE-UNIONS The first German trade-unions were founded in 1848, but in the early fifties they were prohibited. A new union movement arose in the sixties but 1t was confined to a few trades and closely connected ~th some of th.e political _parties. I!)- 1878 most of these organi~at1ons were prohibited by the law agamst the "dangerous tendencies of socialism," the only trade-unions surviving this period being the liberal trade-unions, which were rather weaK. New unions organized in the middle of the eighties suffered considerably under the law of 1878. When, in 1890, the interdiction of 1878 was withdrawn, the economic crisis then prevailing hindered quick development of the trade-union movement. From 1891 to 1895 the unions comprised in the General Commission of Trade-Unions (Genera.lkommission der Gewerkschaften), now the General Federation of German TradeUnions (Allgemeiner Deutscher Gewerkschaftsbund), had about 250,000 members. In 1896, its membership began to increase rapidly and steadily so that there were almost 700,000 members at the close of the nineteenth century. The membership exceeded one million in 1904, two millions in 1910, and was two and one-half millions at the outbreak of the war. While the members of these unions belonged largely to the SocialDemocratic Party, there was an_other equally old group of unions called · the Hirsch-Duncker Federation of German Trade-Unions (Verband der Deutschen Hirsch-Dunckerschen Gewerkvereine), which had been founded in 1868 b;r. some liberal politicians, and whose leaders always belonged to the Liberal Party. As this party did not gain much sympathy from the working class, the Hirsch-Duncker tradeunion movement remained weak. These unions had 110,000 members in 1903, which was also their membership at the outbreak of the war. A third group of unions, the Christian trade-unions, composed mainly of Catholic workers belonging to the Center Party, showed much stronger vitality than the liberal unions. The first unions of this kind were founded in the nineties, and their first general congress was held in 1899. At the beginning of this century/2 they formed the General Federation of Christian Trade-Unions (&esamtverband der Ohristlichen Gewerkscha/ten). At the beguiill}lg of the war their membership exceeded 340,000 members. This figure may appear small when compared with the membership of the Social-Democratic unions, but the Christian unions can develo_p only in Catholic districts. Only in one district, Rhineland-Westphalia, have they developed to any extent. Apart from these three federations there was a number of independent trade-unions, having altogether 300,000 members. The only important ones were the Pqlish Trade Association (PoZnische 78 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 79 INTRODUCTION Beru(8'Vert1,nt,g'U,ng_), which comprised about 75,000 workers in Silesia and ·Rhineland-Westphalia, and the unions of hotel and restaurant em_ployees. More tlian one-third ·of the 300,000 members belonging to mdependent unions were railway men and telegraphers in Government service, but it is doubtful whether their umons before the war could be considered genuine trade-unions. The same is true of the salaried employees' unions, which to a very small extent only were imbued with the trade-union spirit. The unions of commercial employees comprised more than half a million em._plo:yees and the unions of. technical employees 140 000. Dunng _the war most trade-unions experienced heavy losses of membership as many of their members enrolled in the army. But as their expenses decreased at the same time, their :financial status was not much weakened, and quite unexpectedly their political strength imJ?roved. On the outbreak of the war the Government did its best to mcorJ.>Orate the unions into the economic war machinery. The trade-umons and the employers' associations at once stopped all labor disputes. On the part of the trade-unions this was necessary as there was a tremendous amount of unemployment during the first three months of the war. But as more and more men entered the army and the war industries employed greater and greater numbers of men, the labor market developed in favor of the trade-unions, and with the increasing cost of living the trade-unions saw again the possibility and even the necessity of starting movements for wage mcreases. Wage disputes were at this time largely settled before the State conciliation boards, which was a great help for the weak unions and especially the salaried employees' unions, which were now able to make collective agreements before such boards. This strengthening of the position of the trade-unions during the war took place in spite of the heavy reduction in the number of officials, especially in those unions having a considerable number of young members, such as unions of building laborers, or barbers, etc. According to the annual statistics of the unions comprised in the General Commission of Trade-Unions, the number of local officials decreased in the sameJroportion as the number of members, while the number of nation officials was much less reduced. In Table 36 the membership and number of officials of Social-Democratic (free) trade-unions for each year from 1913 to 1918 are given: TABLE 36.-MEMBERSHIP AND NUMBER OF OFFICIALS OF THE SOCIAL-DEMOCRATIC (FREE) TRADE-UNIONS, DECEMBER 31, 1913 TO 1918 National officials Year Local unions Membership Pres!- dents, etc. 1913. _ ------------ -··-·····- -um;_ _________________________ 1914- -----------------------1916- - -----------------------1917- - -----------------------1918-- ------------------------ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 11, 7rtl 10,980 9,869 9,308 9,309 10,044 2,498,959 1,485,428 982,863 934,784 1,264,714 2,858,053 • 417 366 297 245 262 368 Editors 75 69 57 M 51 63 District offlcinls Local offlolals 428 370 1,956 1,482 200 860 269 303 369 694 750 1,532 Total officials 2,876 2,287 1,504 1,262 1,366 2,332 80 CHAPTER IV.-TRADE-UNIONS Everywhere work had to be restricted or _postponed, this being most conspicuous~. perhap_s, in regard to tlie trade-union press. The number of ectitors fell from 75 to 51; the number of weekl:y papers decreased from 35 to 30 and their size was generally reducea one-third or even one-half. MEMBERSHIP The German trade-union movement after the war was characterized by the influx of great masses of UJ1organized workers into the unions. The membership of the Social-Democratic (free) unions, which had decreased from two and one-half millions at the outbreak of the war to one million at the end of 1915, and which in October, 1918, was not more than one and one-half millions1 was almost three millions at the end of 1918, exceeded four millions m April, 1919, five millions in June, six millions in August, and seven riiillions at the end of 1919. It rose to eight millions in the second quarter of 1920 and maintained this height until the end of 1922, but as a consequence of the unrest caused by inflation dropped with increasing rapidity in the course of 1923, at the end of which year it was not more than five and three-fourths millions. Table 37 shows the average membership of all Social-Democratic unions from 1891 to 1923. · TABLB37.-AVERAGE MEMBERSHIP OF 8OO1.A.L-DEMOORATIO TRADE•UNIONB, 1891 TO 1923 Year Members 1891......... 1892......... 1893......... 277, 6119 237, OM 223,530 1894••••••••• 2(6,49' 1895......... 1896......... 259, 175 329, 230 1897......... 412,359 11198......... 493, 742 680,473 18119......... Year Members Year Memberi 1900. •••••••••• 680, 427 1909••••••••••• 1, 832, 667 1901........... 677, 510 1910••••••••••• 2,017,298 1902........... 733, 206 1911••••••••••• 2, 339, 785 1903........... 887, 698 1912••••••••••• 2, 553, 162 1904••••••••••• 1, 052, 108 1913••••••••••• 2, 573, 718 1905••••••••••• 1, 344, 803 11914••••••••••• 2, 075, 769 1906••••••••••: 1, 689, 709 1915. •••••••••• 1, 159, 497 1907. •••••••••• 1, 865, 506 1916........... 966, 705 1908••••••••••• 1, 831, 731 11917••••••••••• l, 106,657 Year Members 1918........... 1,664.991 1919........... 5,479,073 1920........... 7,890, 102 1921 •••••••••• 7,667,978 1922.... ••••••• 7, 895, 065 1923........... 7, 063, 158 1 The decrease from 1920 to 1921 ls due to the secession of the union of salaried employees from the General Federation of German Trade-Unions. Table -38 shows the total and female membership of the various unions belonging to the General Federation of German Trade-Unions in 19131 19201 and 1923: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis • 81 MEMBERSHIP TABLE 38.-MEMBERSHIP OF SOCIAL-DEMOCRATIC (FREE) TRADE•UNIONS, DECEM• BER 31, 1913, 1920, AND 1923, BY KIND OF TRADE•UNION Total membership Female members Kind of trade-union 1913 Salaried employees............................. 24, 809 Salaried employees, offices..................... 8,414 Asphalt pevers..... •• ••• •••••••••• ••••• •••••••• 1, 275 Babrs and confectioners....................... 28, 754 Building trades workers........................ 310,444 Clothing workers.............................. 48, 712 Miners......................................... 101, 986 Coopers........................................ 8,632 Brewery and flour•mlll workers................ 51,317 Bookbinders.·············--·----···--········· 33,377 1920 363, 521 2, U9 65, 077 465, 744 129,621 467, 339 12,938 73,428 79,549 1923 • 710 55, 121 43o, 904 10!, 807 299, 811 1913 1920 1923 13, 5liO 167, 219 416 •••••••••••••••••• 4, 656 24, 808 8,867 76, 713 2, 524 10,155 •••••••• 69,459 1,436 57,500 16,596 555 5,336 55,241 25, 141 1. llK 61,447 972 157 4,717 39,500 Jffi ~f:f i -·-·-· · :: ~:~: ~i:=ers.:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: :::::. Factory workers ••• ········-···-···-·-·····-··· 208,314 644, 910 522, 294 26, 680 175,496 128,331 Film and moving.picture Industry employees.. ••••••••• 7,400 3,400 Butchers....................................... 6, 567 24, 473 15, 720 397 1, 583 1,007 Barbers and hairdressers....................... 2,491 · 10,076 4,444 3 1,497 774 Gardeners...................................... 7,224 23, 147 13, 2li8 30 4,249 2,848 Hotel, restaurant, andcBfhmployees ••••••••• 16,025 63,379 37,175 1,046 26,911 16,210 Municipal and Government workers........... 53, 925 299,891 211,465 1,547 62,821 38,383 Glass workers.................................. 18, 261 55, 656 30, 116 945 11, 514 3,209 Glaziers••••••••••••••••••••••••• ·-............. 4, 280 4, 186 40 Printing Industry auxiliary workers............ 15,934 39, 993 32, 744 8, 572 26, 557 21,816 Domestlc servants ••• ·············-··-········· 5,816 19, 214 •••••.•••• 5, 792 18,880 ••• Woodworkers •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 193,076 370,840 377,025 7,470 37,400 88,655 Sculptors...................................... 3, 716 Hatters........................................ 11,927 23,206 24,630 6,016 15,395 17,516 Coppersmiths.................................. 5, 337 ti, 971 7,446 Furriers........................................ 3, 962 9, 977 6, 460 1,316 5,953 3,490 Agricultural workers........................... 20,267 68o, 174 101,503 884 170,043 26,723 Leather workers............................... 16,481 35,441 46,634 2,086 6,217 10,194 Lithographers.................................. 16, 533 18, 962 19,520 465 124 MllSic engravers............................... 441 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Wood engravers................................ 422 Painters_...................................... 44,842 54, 181 47,413 20 372 414 Engineers...................................... 26,267 88,818 64,996 •••••••• 116 175 Metal workers................................. 544, 934 1,608,932 1,291, 761 27,373 202, 791 136,326 MllSiclans...................................... 2,086 46, 199 18,004 •••••••• 1, 246 690 Construction work, foremen.................... ••••••••• 10,200 Porcelain workers•••••.•••••••••••••• _......... 16, 972 66, 201 72, 464 3, 679 25, 424 33, 321 Saddlers, upholsterers, leather•bag makers..... 14,865 38, 153 37,500 1,029 6,115 7,592 ,~~~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: :=: ~m··;~=··;~· ==:~= ===~~ Stoneworkers................................... 30, 516 45,476 47, 123 ····200· 778 515 Stone pavers................................... 11,164 11,194 9,519 •••••••••••••••••••• Tobacco workers............................... 31, 713 113,267 81, 934 15,449 88, 918 64,639 Textile workers................................ 138,079 537, 909 608, 168 M, 113 36o, 443 405,961 Potters......................................... 10,166 11,368 •••••••••• •••••••• 604 ••••••••• Transport workers............................. 229,427 678,367 408,240 9,201 77,631 43,838 Carpenters..................................... 59,831 87,024 93,336 •••••••••••••••••••••••••• Firemen....................................... ••••••••• •••••••••• 2, 136 •••••••••••••••••••••••••• https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 82 CHAPTER IV.-TRADE-UNIONS The Christian unions likewise experienced an enormous increase in their membership immediately after the armistice. While their nu:r:µber had drop~d from 340,000 at the outbreak of the war to 160,000 at the end of 1915, it exceeded 500,000 in December, 1918, and amounted to 1,000,000 at the end of 1919 and to ~,100,000 at the end of 1920, but also was considerably reduced with the rapid fall of the mark. The Hirsch-Duncker (liberal) unions did not make as great headway as the free and the Christian unions. During the war they, like the other unions, lost about one-half of their membership, but while the membershi_p of the free and the Christian unions was-l~er at the end of 1918 than before the war, the Hirsch-Duncker unions had at that time only regained their old position (about 110,000 members) and two y.ears later, when other unions had more than three times as many members as before the war, the Hirsch-Duncker unions had only doubled their membershiJ?. While the Hirsch-Duncker group, wliich has never been very important and which was pushed altogether into the bac~ound by the expansion of the free unions in the two decades preceding the war, has not succeeded in ga~ any real ground since the war, the communist and the syndicalist unions have of late had increasing success. The Communist Party, it is true, was not in favor of special communist unions but wanted the communists to stay in the SocialDemocratic (free) unions and conquer them. But when communist members were excluded from the Social-Democratic unions those members created a few unions of their own, and these new o~anizations founded the Federation of Manual and Nonmanual German Workers ( Union der Hand- und ~ f'larbeiter Dru"8chland8), numbering about 160,000 members. U e the Communist Party, the Communist Labor Party is in favor of ~pecial communist unions and backs the· General Federation of German workers (.A.llgemeine .A.rbeiter-llnion Deu"8chland8), which so far, however, has not many adherents. The syndicalist unions, which existed before the war and which in 1919 created the Federation of Free German Workers (Freu Arbeiter-Union Dru"8chland8), have now about 100,000 members. The indElpendent unions (Polish Trade Association, General Railwaymen's Union, etc.) have never exceeded the membership they had before the war (300,000). There are still other organizations which call themselves tradeunions alt~?::"fl~ they are not based on trade-union principles-the yellow (no "tant) unions. They were founded and subsidized by employers and had almost 300,000 members before the war. Mter the revolution the employers' associations pledged themselves not to support or subsidize the yellow unions and m conseq_uence their membersn.ip at the end of 1918 was only about 45,000. These unions were no longer considered by the leading manufacturers' associations as representatives of the workers and were not allowed representation in the National Economie Council and similar bodies. Nevertheless they survived and now have about 250,000 members. While the unions of salaried employees, as has been mentioned, were not very strong before the war, they did have a rather large membership. They natl about one million members then, lost half -their members during the war and now have about one and twotliirds millions. While before the war, unlike the organizations of https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1 :MEMBERSHIP 83 workers, the unions of salaried employees were not combined into federations, after the war these employees and also the civil-service employees (who before the war liad no trade-union whatsoever) organized such federations. The Social-Democratic unions of ·salaried employees formed the General Federation of Free Employees (AUvemeiner Freier .Angestelltenbu,nil), which has now two-thirds of a million members and on April 12, 1921, concluded a working agreement with the General Federation of German Trade-Unions. lriimediately after the revolution the civil-service employees founded the German Federation of Civil-Service Employees (D(!/11,tscher Beamte11r bu,nil), which split in May, 1921, the old federation retaining one million members, while the unions of the left wing, led by the National Trade-Union of German Railway Employees, founded the General German Federation of Civil-Service Employees (.Allgemeiner D(!/11,tscher Beamtenbu,nil), which has about 350,000 members. In March, 1923, this federation concluded a working agreement with the General Federation of German Trade-Unions. While the Social-Democratic trade-unions of workers are rather loosely affiliated with the Social-Democratic .unions of salaried employees and civil-service employees, the Christian and liberal labor unions are much more closely associated with the unions of salaried employees and civil-service emJ>loyees sharing their J>olitical views. The Christian unions organized the Federation of German Trade-Unions (D(!/11,tscher Gewerkschaftsbu,nil), composed of the General Federation of Christian Traae-Unions (Gesamwerbanil der Ohrisaichen Gewerkscha.ften), the General Federation of German Unions of Salaried Emp1oyees (Gesamtverbanil D(!/11,tscher .Angestellte11r g_ewerkscha.ften), with 460,000 members, and the General Federation of German Unions of Civil-Service Employees (Gesamtverbanil Deutscher Beamte11r unil St,aa,tsangestelltengewerkschaften), with 400,000 members. The liberal unions formed the Federation of German Unions of Workers, Salaried Employees, and Civil-Service Employees (Gewerkschaftsring Deutscher ..drbeiter-, .Angestellte11r unil Beamtenverbanile) which consists of the Federation of German Trade-Unions ( Verba;J der D(!/11,tschen Gewerkvereine), the Federation of Unions of Salaried Employees (Gewerkschaftsbu,nil der AftQestellten), having 300,000 membe~ and two federations of civil-service emplo;yees-the Association of \ierman Unions of Civil-Service Employees (Ring Deutscher Beamtenverbande), with 65,000 members, and the General Federation of Railwaymen, with 82,000 members. There are also some yellow unions of salaried employees, with 56,000 members, which with a yellow union of civil-service employees having 6,000 members and the yellow labor unions have founded the National Federation of German Professional Unions (Nationalverbanil Deutscher Berufsverbanile). A most conspicuous feature in the postwar development of the membership of the German trade-unions is the great increase of female members. In the Social-Democratic labor unions, for example, while not more than 9 per cent of the members in 1913 were women, since 1919 the proportion has exceeded 20 per cent. Women constitute the majority of the members in the unions of clothing workers, of bookbinders, of chorus singers, of auxiliary workers in the printing industry, of domestic servants, of hatters, of furriers, of https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 84 CHAPTER IV.-TRADE-UNIONS tobacco workers, and of textile workers. The percentage of women in the Christian labor unions is 25, in the liberal labor unions 10, in the unions of salaried employees 21, and in the unions of civil-service employees 5. FINANCES The sudden influx of new members in 1919 unavoidably weakened the financial strength of the trade-unions, since the reserves had to serve a much larger number of members. Moreover, it was not until the begll!Iling of 1923 that the unions learned to protect their funds against the depreciation in currency. At the end of 1918 their funds (in paper marks) were about the same as at the outbreak of the war, but tlieir real value had, of course, declined. They- increased about one-half in 1919, while the membership and cost of liv4ig doubled or trebled: and they doubled in 1920 and again in 1921, but their real value dwindled from year to year. While before the war the per capita funds of most Social-Democratic unions varied between the equivalent of 50 and 80 hours' wages and in the case of some unions (for example, printers and carpenters) even exceeded 100 hours' wages, at the end of 1922 no union possessed more than the equivalent of 4 hours' wages per capita and many did not own the equivalent of even 2 hours' wages per member. At the end of 1923 the total funds of the Social-Democratic unions were not more than 2,738,712 rentenmarks ($651,813) as compared with 88,110,855 marks($20,970,383) at the end of 1913. At the same time the revenues of the unions did not rise in proportion to their needs. In 1919 they were (in paper marks) only about three times as high as before the war and consequently only about 50 per cent higher J?er member than in 1913. In 1920 they were about three times as ~has in 1919, or about three times as !ugh per member as in 1913. Iri 1921 they were about five times as high as in 1919, or about :five times as high per member as in 1913. There were several reasons for this state of affairs: 1. Real wages were so. low that it was impossible to demand high dues; 2. For technical reasons it was not possible to increase the dues as quickly as wages increased; 3. The loyalty of the membership, which to a large extent was composed of recent additions, was not very strong, many members not paying their dues at all or postponing payment a.nu paying them later m depreciated money; 4. The collectors and cashiers of the local unions frequently postponed the delivery of the dues. The time elapsing from the payment of the dues by the individual member to the receipt thereof by the federation treasury was very long. When the shop steward or collector collected the dues in the shop or in the home of the worker on Saturday, he did not, as a rule, settle accounts with the cashier of the local union before the following Friday. (He may have immediately spent the dues, which were, say, three times as high as his weekly- salary and six days later, when his weekly- sal9!r equaled that, delivered the amount of the dues to the local cashier, thus profiting by the. transaction.) The local cashier himself may not have been anxious to forward dues to the treasurer of the union federation, but waited perha:es one or two weeks and in the meantime speculated with the unions mone_y. The collector and the cashier frequently did not realize that they cheated the unions through such delays, and they https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis INTERNAL ORGANIZATION 85 often had the excuse that the union would suffer a loss anyway by the deterioration of the currency since its funds often lay idle for weeks without protection against inflation. With regard to dues the unions were in a position similar to that of the State which received taxes in depreciated currency; for example, one union which before the war had monthly revenues of 150,000 marks received in September, 1923, only 11,000 gold marks and in October, 1923, only 2,000 gold marks. Dunng 1923 the decline in the real value of their funds and of their current revenues became so rapid that all unions had to discharge a large proportion of their employees because of insufficient means. All otlier expenses had also to be curtailed greatly. More and more the unions had to give up paying strike benefits; other benefits, such as sick and death and unemployment benefits, had to be reduced. Many unions were no longer able to continue publication of their trade papers. These journals, which, almost without exception, were distributed free to members and which in some cases had a larger circulation than any daily paper (the journal of the metal workers reaching a circulation of one and three-fourths million copies) had been reduced in size during the war, and after the war, because of the prohibitive paper prices, were not enlarged to their old size. With increasing inflation their size was still further reduced, in the suinmer of 1923 being only one-fourth or one-sixth of what it had been in pre-war times, and they were not distributed to every member, one copy being assigI_1.ed to two, three, or even more members. Since January, 1924 (with the stabilization of the mark) conditions have somewhat improved, but the union journals, which in former times were a most important means of educating the union members, are still far from what they used to be. INTERNAL ORGANIZATION The first trade-unions in Germany included men of a single occUJ)ation. This trade-union type, which still _predominates in AngloSaxon countries, has almost completely disappeared in Germany, there being in the General Federation of German Trade-Unions only one union comprising a single occupation-the carpenters' union. All other unions include either several skilled occupations, or several unskilled occupations (e. g., the factory laborers' union), or both skilled and unslnlled workers (e. g., the building workers' union), or all the workers of specified concerns (such as the union of State and municipal workers and the railwaymen's union). This consolidation had made great progress before the war but since then the movement has been accentuated. At the Leipzig Trade-Union Congress of June, 1922, where there was much discussion of the question, 12 of the 49 trade-unions there represented comprised five-sixths of the combined membership, and these stronger unions are very anxious to absorb the smaller ones. While in pre-war times it was mainly simplification and economy in administration and in propaganda which induced separate unions to combine, after the war it was, above all, the difficulty in q_uickly adapting wage conditions to changes in cost of living and the high development of collective bargaining which made it desirable to reduce the number of unions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 86 CHAPTER IV.---TRADE-UNIONS At present the organization of practically all German trade-unions is as follows: The elementary umt of the union is always the workshop, or, in case of a large establishment, the section. The male and female workers of this unit who belong to the trade-union elect a shop steward, who guards their interests against both the employer and the gove~ board of the union. The shop stewarrui, in general1 are memliers of the works council and as such enjoy the protection gi-anted by the works council law. In former times this shop steward also collected the union dues in the shop, in case they were not collected at the home of the member, but nowadays the shop steward has so many other duties that the collection of dues is often intrusted to special employees. The next unit is generally the local union, thougli in some large cities between the shop and the local union are committees for boroughs (cover4ig all occupations in the union) or for special occupations (covering the entire territory of the local union). The local union, almost without exce£::n, covers the city and its suburbs, i. e., the entire territory depen · economically upon the city. The local union enjoys considerable indepen<lence, especially in :financial matters, and not only can use for its own pUJ.1>oses (within the limits of the by-laws) a certain percentage of the dues but also can collect special dues for local needs. The whole management, it is true, is closely supervised by the national federation, and in case of strikes it must act in accord with the national board. The administrative bodies of the local union are the presiding board and the general assembly. In case the local union has more than 1 000 members, the management is generally intrusted to members who are relieved from their work for that purpose. The next unit above the local union is that of the district. With a few exceptions it has practically no importance as a selfgoverning body. The management of these districts lies in the hands of salaried district presidents, who safeguard the interests of the union as a whole against the special interests of the local unions and at the same time represent the interests of their respective districts before the national federation. They were originally established mainly for propaganda work and before the war had ample time to devote themselves to educating the unionists and to enro!}ing new members. After the war their work soon became restricted to 1.vage movements. They always had and still have to report to the national board on impendhu? wage movements, and to see that the instructions of this board are :followed. If necessary, they conduct negotiations with the employers' organizations. They are not generally charged with examination of the accounts or funds but are bound to be constantly informed on the management of the local unions within their respective districts. At the head of each union is the national board, the majority of whose memb8l"S actually work at their trades. The main work, however, is done by salaried members, who, like all other trade-tmion officials, are members of the union in question. The national board is charged with the management of the entire union. It has to secure the necess~ revenues-if necessary, by levying special assessments-to con.fuie expenditures within fair limits, to audit the accounts of local unions, and above all to direct the wag_~ policy of the union. Just as wage controversies have superseded all other activities in the districts, the wage policy, in consequence of the money depreciation, has become the paramount task of the https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis INTERNAL DIFFICULTIES 87 national boards. While before the war, when collective agreements were generally concluded for several years, the national boards had only to direct w~e movements and str11g~les for new ~eements or for the inclusion ID agreements of localities and establishments not theretofore covered by an agreement, in such a manner that no one region should be mucli behind in its wages nor the funds of the unions be too much depleted, after the war they had continuously to conduct wa~e movements and to adapt their strike policy to their more limited funds. At the time of the final collapse of the mark, in the fall of 1923, the unions' finances were so impaired that strikes became impossible. This, of course, considerably weakened the position of the national boards of the unions. With the stabilization of the mark, however, they have regained their former decisive influence. INTERNAL DIFFICULTIES The ieneral attitude of the German trade-unions in the period succeeding the revolution is characterized by three changes in their position produced by that event: First, a considerable enhancement of their moral influence; second, as a consequence of their larger membership, an increase in their actual power, which, however, diminished again when the currency depreciat~d; and third, the necessit_y of assimilating large numbers of new members who were politically untrained and ignorant of trade-union principles and at the same time of combating communistic tendencies among them. The loss of power and the impossibility of keeping wages at pre-war levels rendered it esJ>ecially difficult for the unions to combat radical tendencies amon9 their members. The "free ' trade-unions, with the exception of a few organizations, such as that of the printers, have always been intimately connected with the Socialist Party. After the split in the party in the spring of 1917 because of the diverging attitudes of its members with reference to the war, the greater part of the trade-union leaders remained in the old party (so-called majority socialists). On the outbreak of the revolution, the "independent socialists" (the left wing of the old party), being no longer restricted in their political activity, immediately endeavored to gain control of the trade-unions by tlie help of the radical working classes. In all places where they were numerous enough they proceeded to attack those in power and wherever they succeeded in obtaining. a majority they ousted the adherents of the right wing of the Socialist Party not only from the leading positions but even from the lower clerical places, thou~h up to that time officers of trade-unions could not be removed except ID cases of flagrant neglect of duty. This struggle was naturally restricted to the free tradeunions but at the same time another conflict was going on which involved the entire workers' an<l salaried employees' movement. At the outbreak of the revolution, workers' comrmttees patterned after the Russian model~o-called "workers' councils "-were elected. There being no doubt about the moderate political attitude of the trade-unions, the radical elements endeavored to push aside the tradeunions by the help of the workers' councils. They were aided by two circumstances. In the first place the members of workers' councils, a number of whom in the large establishments were exempted from their usual work at the expense of the employer, showed a strong tendency to independence, especially when they had had little voice https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 88 CHAPTER IV,--TRADE-UNIONS in the trade-unions before the revolutionary wave carried them to the top. On the other hand, the solidarity among all classes of workmen was so great that the tjgid organization of tlie trade-unions was not always necessa.ry for tlie· successful prosecution of movements for ~her wages, loose associations formed by a few workers' councils be!!}g as a rule quite sufficient for that purpose. Because of th:eir great experience the trade-unions soon mastered both these diffie11lties. After the enactment of the works councils act they gave the works councils a place within their own organization, assigning to them special functions. The Independent Socia.list Party-although the leaders of the shoemakers' and textile workers' trade-unions were among its members-with the exception of local successes in Berlin, Leipzig, Bremen1 and a few smaller places, gained only one really important VIctory-the conquest of the meta.I workers' union. The communist propaganda was a far more serious danger to the trade-unions. The low level of real wages paid in the period of the great depreciation of the currencY:, when the rate of wages agreed to by th:e trade-unions never reached the level of the index representm~ the actual cost of living, made many workmen discontented and dissatisfied with the management of the unions and led to unauthorized strikes. · This unauthorized striking and disregard of the authority of the union leaders were encouraged both by the easilywon success of indifferently organized and wild or unauthorized strikes and by· the fact that one-half or two-thirds of the members of many of the unions were recent additions and therefore not trained in loyalty to the union. The communists took advant~e of this state of affairs. While immediately after the revolution their idea had been simply to break up th:e trade-unions, they had later become convinced th.at the German trade-unions were too strong to allow of this and therefore restricted their plans to warfare within the trade-unions. While the form and the nature of the weapons used have changed considerably, in essentials this warfare has remained the same. The masses were incited to wild strikes not upheld by the leaders and mass movements were inaugurated whenever a local conflict showed the weakness of the trade-unions. The success of the communists was, however, coma:~~ively trifling. While in a few places they captured the local a · ·stration, they have not been able to gain control of the genera.I management of any union. On the other hand, it can not be denied tliat their attacks have considerably weakened the free trade-unions. The unauthorized strikes of workmen in public services (gas, water, and electric works) in several cases led to such strikes being prohibited by the President of the Republic. Frequent strikes in the Berlin municipal services caused the Government, even before the creation of the Reichswehr, to organize an engineering service in the army to give assistance in such cases. This service was afterwards ta.ken over 1:>y the Minister of the Interior as an emergency engineering corps ( Techn-ische NotMlfe) and further developed. The tradeunions, being in the nature of things obliged to resist scabbing to the utmost, could not possibly agree to the organization by the Government of a corps of professiona.l strike breakers. On the other hand, as they were not able to provide the necessary workers to keep the public services going they could not o_ppose the emergency service and later saw it c~ed into action by Socia.list ministers. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis INTERNAL DIFFICULTIES 89 The communists within the trade-unions soon united in separate organizations with the object of furthering their political views. Tlie trade-unions did not treat this organized opposition in an altogether uniform manner. The view generally taken was that it would not be advisable to exclude members on the score of their political ideas and also that it was extremely improbable that the communists would be able to extend their influence within the union to extent. For these reasons the unions refrained from rigorous measures and excluded only those members who violated the rules and regulations of the unions. Moreover, the importance of the communist movement depends on the amount of employment and the relations of wages to the cost of living. The worse the condition of the workmen the stronger will be the response to communist propaganda. While some unions were especially liberal in their treatment of the communists, and endeavored as far as possible to avoid conflicts between members of closely associated parties, others acted more harshly. Considerable numbers of communist railway men and building workers were excluded from the unions or resignea of their own accord. At first the unions conducted their campaign ~a.inst the C?~unists rather energetically in the~ journals but smce the begmnmg ·of 1924 they seem to have decided on a camp~n by means of ~ements. It had become usual for the national boards to reqmre officials who were known as communists or members who were leaders of the opposition to sign agreements binding them to regulate their conduct exclusively by the decisions of the union and to take no directions concerning their activity within the union from any outside person. Agreements of this tenor are now ~uite generally demanded, not only by the national boards, but also oy local boards. Thus the Berlin local board has refused to act in cooperation with delegates who are also members of the Red Trade-Umons' Association (the local board of the communist tradeunions) and has bound local administrations to require their delegates to sign written agreements that they will be governed by the principles and conform to the by-laws of the General Federation of German Trade-Unions and the International Federation of TradeUnions and that they do not intend to join the Red Trade-Unions' Association. Delegates refusing to sign such agreements are not admitted to the meetings of the boara. The national board is to proceed against local boards which decline to demand agreements of this tenor from their delegates. It is _probable that, in one form or another, such agreements are in use m all unions. Although they are mentioned only occasionally in reports of meej;ings in the papers, they are evidently demanded much more frequently than is publicly known. In the case of appointed officials a clause is frequently added to the effect that they may_ be dismissed without notice in case of violation. The object of this procedure seems to be to keep the organized opposition out of the boards or committees of the union and to limit its activity to the general meetings. In case opposition members interrupt the meetings they are to be excluded. These measures do not appear to have been dictated by any fear of an increase of communist opposition. The consideration influencing the leaders seems rather to· have been that of preventing the opposition from embarrassing the management of future strikes by the national board and of obliging it to form separate organizations. any https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 90 CHAPTER IV,-TRADE-UNIONS As rival organizations formed by secessions of this kind have never had much vitality, this would probably be the shortest way of paralyzing the opposition. In contrast to the Christian trade-unions, which also had to assimilate large numbers of new members and which, moreover, were to a large extent under the influence of the free trade-unions because of their members being in close contact in the workshops and factories, the Hirsch-Duncker trade-unions have been comparatively little affected by the agitation produced by the revolution. Originally the three groups of trade-unions were exceedinidy hostile and tried to ignore eacb other in the struggle for higlier wages. The disadvantages accruing to all parties from this attitude had even before the war induced these gt'OUps to combine in movements for higher wages and to conclude collective agreements jointly. Notwithstanding the very close cooperation often arising therefrom, this did not lead to an understanding definitely limiting the sphere of each group. Each organization had to be continually prepared for sharp struggles with its rivals. In later years the three national organizations have often proceeded jointly in negotiations with the Government on economic and social matters, but on other occasions the three organizations have not been able to come to an understanding or at the outset have _given up joint action as impossible. The only lasting result of this limited joint action of the three associations is an agreement binding each of them not to b ~ economic pressure to bear on members of the rival organizations m order to enlist them on its own side. In the extraordinarily violent struggles of 1923 remarkably little stress was laid on the common cause of the trade-unions against the employers' organizations. This may be due to a resolution passed by a bishops' conference in Fulda in 1923 limiting rather strictly the conditions under which Catholics might belong to the free trade-unions and in consequence thereof the influence of the clergy on Catholic workmen to resigl! from the free trade-unions. The relations of the Christian to the free tradeunions have evidently suffered. in these last years because of the knowledge by the free trade-unions that in a crisis the Christian trade-umons count on being able to attract many of the members who have entered the free trade-unions since the war. With the exception of the engineers' association, none of the organizations of salaried employees and-... civil service employees acquired any great importance or power before the war, and while they have smce changed greatly in numbers as well as in character, they still feel the lack of training and union tradition on the part of theu- members and are therefore more or less in the development stage. ECONOMIC POLICY At the outset, German trade-unions ~onflned themselves to the amelioration of wage and working conditions through negotiations with employers and strikes. The courts prevented them fro;rn extending their activity to political or sociopolitical questions. Those unions which could improve the conditions of their members only by working for protective labor laws did so cautiously through public meetings or congresses. In so far as measures covering the working class as a whole were involved, discussion by unions was also hampered by the fact that such questions were considered to https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ECONOMIC POLICY 91 be within the domain of the political parties and that many union leaders did not consider it fair for the unions to compete with Parliament. Later, however, the unions became convinced that as they had a better knowledge of the actual needs of the workers than the politicians did, it was their duty to fight for an extension of labor legislation./ but they still refrained from taking any deeper interest in genera.I. econormc questions. Their economic policy consisted mainly of studying the condition of the labor marlret. Before the war the textile workers' union was the only German trade-union which had an economic department, its. duty being to study the economic situation of the textile industry. During the war conditions changed because of two reasons: 1. Trade-union leaders, as representatives of the consumers, were called into the offices and committees charged with the food distribution. This protection of the interests of consumers was quite along the lines of the pre-war work, but at the same time it gave union leaders a close insight into price calculation of which they had known very little. 2. The distribution of raw materials and industrial production were controlled by the State. While the unions did not participate in this supervision, they did take part in the State regulation of economic life during the period of demobilization. Wlien in November, 1918, the Imperial Government collapsed, and the newly elected soldiers' and workers' councils proved unable to create a new order, the trade-unions represented the stable portion of the working class and the hope of those who were anxious to kee_p out bolshevism. They thus suddenly gained not only considerable political importance, but also an important place in the reconstruction of the economic life of the nation. Even those employers who had formerly declined all negotiations with the workers and had never recognized the trade-unions as legitimate representatives of labor now associated themselves with tlie union leaders to replace the .planned bureaucratic demobilization by self-government of those engaged in industry, employees and employers being granted equal ri~hts. Twenty-one of the largest employers' associations and all nnportant federations of trade-unions entered into a joint declaration of principles to govern future industrial relations. This declaration provided for the immediate reinstatement of workmen returning from military service in the situations occupied by th!:Pll before the war, for a Joint regulation and equipartisan administration of employment offices, for the conclusion of collective agreements, for the appointment of workers' committees in estaolishments employing at least 50 workers, for the establishment of conciliation and arbitration boards composed of an equal number of employers' and workers' representatives, for the mtroduction of the e~ht-hour day,. and for the establishment of a joint central committee on an equipartisan basis and representing the various trades. This committee was to determine upon further measures necess~ during demobilization to maintain economic life. It was also origmally planned to have a similar committee for each district, and if tbis plan had been carried out, the trade-unions would have had a chance to influence greatly the economic policy of the country. But as the old chambers of commerce and craftsmen's chambers m which the employees were not represented were maintained the employers did not care to establish new equipartisan district organ- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 92 CHAPTER IV.-TRADE-UNIONS izations. The joint central committee therefore became more and more a. debating body. The main product of the joint declaration of the employers' associations and the trade-unions was the conclusion of collective agreements, which soon covered almost the entire country. This by no means diminished the wage controversies, but the percentf!,ge of controversies resulting in strikes or lockouts was considerably reduced. The number of members ·of the Social-Democratic umons affected by wage, etc., controversies was 1,200,000 in 1913, 7,400,000 in 1919, 13,000,000 in 1920, 17,700,000 in 1921 60,100,000 in 1922, and 11,700,000 in 1923; 1 the number of members participating in strikes or lockouts was, in the same years, ~49i000, 764,000, 940,000, 1,159,000, 1,159,000, and 1,093,000, respective y. The actual number of controversies, strikes, and lockouts affecting the Social-Democratic trade-unions in each year from 1913 to 1923 are shown in Table 39. TABLB 39.-CONTROVERSIEB.i. BTRIKEBt.AND LOCKOUTS AFFECTING 8OO1.A.L-DEMO• CRA.·J:IO TRAD.1!.•UNIONS, 11113 TO 1112S Controversies terminating without stoppage of work • Year Controversies resulting In strikes or lockouts Total controversies particl- Controversies Workers partlclControversies Workers patiilg patmg NumNumber 1913.________________ 11114_________________ 7,372 3,467 3,683 6,849 10,336 10,696 22,769 33,001 49,498 126,025 1923••••••••••••••••• 163,147 11115••••••••••••••••• 11116••••••••••••••••• 11117••••••••••••••••• 11118••••••••••••••••. 1919••••••••••••••••• 1920••••••••••••••••• 1921. •••••••••••••••• 111')2 •••••••••••••••• Per Number Per cent Per cent Number Per cent Num• ber cent 73.9 71.0 118.2 118.0 118.2 118.5 86.1 85.6 811. 7 116.2 118.2 79.5 73.4 911. 7 911.0 97.6 911.1 811. 7 112.8 93.0 97.8 IIO. 7 2,600 1,409 66 142 26.1 248, 1186 29.0 116,681 1.8 2,221 2.0 14, 6311 1.8 66,634 1.5 21,733 13.9 764,480 14.4 1140, 081 10. 3 1,159,191 3.8 1,158,906 LS 1,093,174 965,1537 266,359 816,246 1, 400, 1114 2,732,841 2,417,1124 6,671,249 12,103,847 16,446,167 58,806,711 10,801,117 1113 163 3,664 5,546 6,707 4,930 2,766 211.5 26.6 .3 LO 2.4 .II 10.3 7.2 6.6 L9 9.3 ber 9,972 4,886 3, 7411 6, 9111 10,529 10, 8511 26,433 38,547 55, 7n5 130,965 1611,1113 Workers particl- patlng 1,214,523 363,040 818,467 1,464,833 2, 7118,9711 2,439, 6117 7, 4311, 709 13, 043, 1128 17,687,229 80, 1411,466 11, 6114, 2111 • In addition 811881 persons in 1921 and 184,849 persons In 1922 participated In controversies resulting In stoppage of work out their demands were granted before quitting work themselves. There were two other organizations besides the joint central committee which :might have enhanced the influence of the tradeunions on the economic policy of the country-the National Economic Council and the export control boards. The National Economic Council was to be tlie head of a body of district economic councils, but the .employers took no interest in fostering this development. The district councils were never created and the National Economic Council became more and more a debating club. The export control boards gave the trade-union leaders a somewhat better chance. They were founded early in 1920 for the p~ose of preventing the export of German goods in too great.quantities and at too low prices; they served also to secure to the Reichsbank J>art of the foreign currency realized through exports. The union feaders had here an opportunity: to get a certain lilSight into the conditions of industry, although all establishments did their utmost to disclose as little as 1 These figures Include, of course, duplications, the 118Dle trade-union members sometimes being parties to more than one wage controversy. • https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ECONOMIC POLICY 98 possible of their so-called business secrets. These boards, however, were suspended in the fall of 1923. The economic importance of the trade-unions, which immediately after the revolution seemed to become very great, was therefore, really very slight. The unions were not prepared to exercise a strong influence along economic lines, being too much absorbed in their struggles for higher wages. It is necessary to emphasize this point because the r6le which the trade-unions played-for example, at the time of the Kapp revolt-gave the illusion that 'they really had a strong economic influence. After overthrowing the Kapp government by a general strike they made a number of definite economic demands wliich were granted by the government they had restored. Although these pronnses were never fulfilled they led to the catch phrase "the cogovernment of the trade-unions." Similar demands were made at other times by the d,i.fferent federations of tradeunions, which also repeatedly protested against the economic and financial policy of the various governments. But these demands and protests never had any practical result, and the power of the unions m matters of economic policy became negligible when the deprecia- · tion of the mark deprived them of their financial means. The trade-unions are organizations of the sellers of labor. They can exercise power only in so far as they are able to keep labor from the market until the ouyers of labor are compelled to accept their conditions. This requires great financial reserves and strong organizations. Before the war such reserves existed, but strong organizations were to be found onlr in a few occupations and in SO!l).e parts of the country. After the war the influx of large unorganized masses into the unions strengthened the organizations in spite of certain deficiencies of the new members (lack of dis.cipline, etc.), but the monetary depreciation demoralized the financial status of the unions and paralyzed their activity. The practical loss of the eight-hour day at the end of 1923 is the clearest proof of the collapse of the unions. Their organizations, however, still exist, and their membership is still two and a half times as large as before the war. The stabilization of the mark enabled them to recover financially, and the day may not be far distant when they will possess the two things necessary for permanent success-a strong organization and adequate financial reserves. 20168°-25f--1 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Chapter V.-HOURS OF LABOR SITUATION BEFORE DECEMBER, 1923 LEGISLATION Efforts to introduce a. general maximum workday in Germany da.te far back. ·.As early as 1869, when the Industrial Code was under discussion, motions were made for a legal general limitation of the daily hours of labor, but in the Industrial Code aa passed a limitation of the hours of labor was fixed only for children, for young persons, and for female workers, the hours of children being limited to 6 per da.y and those of women and young persons to 10, with certain limits which insured continuous rest periods of at least 10 or 11 hours. Up to 1918 there were no legal general restrictions for adult males, provision being made only for the so-called "h_ygienic 11 maximum working-day in specified industries in which the health of the workers was particularly endangered by excessive working hours. The revolution of 1918 led to a complete change in the law as to hours of labor. Three da.ys after the breakdown of the Imperial Government, the Council of People's Commissioners in a manifesto to the population declared: "The maximum eight-hour workday will go into effect not later than on Janufl.rY 1, 1919." Three days later, on November 15, 1918, the joint declaration of the associations of employers and the trade-unions as to principles to govern future industrial relations stipulated: "The maximum regular daily hours of labor shall be fixed for all establishments at eight hours. Reductions of earnings shall not take place bees.use of th~ shortening of the hours of labor." .As early as November 23, 1918, the National Office for Economic Demobilization issued an order regulatii!g the hours of labor of industrial workers. This order was amended in some minor details by an order of December 17. .As it is generally, tho~h wrongly, believed that these orders established a schematic and melastic eight-hour day, the main provisions of the order of November 23, as amended by the order of December 17, are here reproduced: · ARTICLE 1. This regulation applies to industrial workers in all industrial establishments, inclusive of mining, in Federal, State, communal and communal union establishments, even if they are not operated with a view to profit, and in agricultural subsidiary establishments of an industrial nature. ART. 2. The regular daily hours of labor, exclusive of rest periods, must not exceed eight. If by agreement the working hours are curtailed on the afternoons preceding Sundays and holidays, the time thus lost may be made up on other working-days. ART. 3. In the case of general exceptions to the foregoing regulations made necessary in industries connected with transportation and communication, including the railways and post and telegraph service, and called for by existing conditions, agreements must be arrived at between those in charge of the establishments and the workers' organizations. Should such agreements not be concluded· within two weeks, the right to issue further orders is reserved. ART. 4. In order to in'flroduce a regular weekly change of shifts in establishments whose nature does not admit of any interruption of operation or in which at the present time continuous Sunday labor is necessary in the public interest, male workers over 16 years of age may once within three weeks work a maximum 94 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis SITUATION BEFORE DECEMBER, 1923 95 of 16 hours, inclusive of rest periods, provided that during these three weeks they are twice granted an uninterrupted rest of 24 hours at a time. ART. 5. Notwithstanding the general regulations of the Industrial Code, female workers over 16 years of age in establishments with two or more shifts may be employed up to 10 p. m., provided that, after quitting work, they are given a rest lasting at least 16 hours. In such cases, in place of a noon rest of one hour, there may be a rest period of half an hour or two rest periods of a quarter of an hour which are to be counted as working time. * * * ART. 6. The foregoing regulations shall not be applicable to temporary emergency work, which has to proceed without delat. ART. 7. If, in establishments whose nature does not admit of any interruption, or in which unrestricted operation is necessary in the public interest, the required number of suitable workers is not available, a regulation deviating from the foregoing may be approved provisionally by the competent factory inspection official,· or, in the case of mines, by the district mining inspector. This must be preceded by a request on the part of the employer, and should no agreement have been concluded between the employers' and workers' organizations, a declaration of consent on the part of the workers' committee, or, should no such committee exist, on the part of the workers in the establishment. Should more comprehensive agreements between employers' and workers' organizations with respect to exceptions to the limitations of employment of industrial workers be arrived at in establishments designated in this article, the officials of the factory or mine inspection service are authorized to permit further provisional exceptions from the protective labor regulations. Immediately after giving their approval the said officials shall call the attention of the proper employment offices to the shortage of labor in the establishments in question. The competent commissioner of demobilization must also be informed of the permits granted and he is authorized to call upon the officials to revoke such permits. The commissioners of demobilization are authorized, after having heard the opinion of the factory or mining inspectors, to grant more comprehensive provisional exceptions to the limitations of employment of industrial workers, if such exceptions become urgently necessary in the public interest, particularly for the sake of an orderly demobilization, to avoid unemployment or to insure sufficient food for the population. Copies of the permits granted shall be submitted within two days to the Demobilization Office. ART. 8. The commencement and termination of the daily hours of labor and rest periods are, so far as they have not been regulated by collective agreement, to be fixed in accordance with the foregoing regulations by the employer in agreement with the workers' committee, or should no such committee exist, with the workers in the establishment, and to be published by posting in the establishment. ART. 9. The officials of the factory and mine inspection service are charged with the enforcement of the foregoing regulations. For this purpose they are authorized to negotiate with the workers' committees in the presence of the employer, or with either party alone and to summon the workers' committee. This regulation provided for a general improvement of working conditions, but in one respect it resulted in lowering the standard as to the employment of women. Under the Industrial Code female workers were not to be employed between 8 p. m. and 6 a. m., and on Saturdays and days preceding holidays not after 5 p. m. Under the new regulation they could be employed up to 10 p. m. in establishments liaving two or more shifts. On March 18, 1919, this order relating to industrial workers was supplemented by an order regulating in a similar manner the hours of labor of salaried employees. This new legislation on the hours of labor thus established as a matter of principle the maximum eight-hour workday for all employees without regard to sex or age and fixed fines and imprisonment for violations of this limitation. In cases of violation the employer was punished even if the employee worked more than the eight hours of his own free will, while the employee always went scot-free. In order to avoid economic friction, however, which would have been unavoidable in case of a sudden and rigid enforcement of the eight-hour day, factory and https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 96 OHAPTEB V.-HOUBS OF LABOR mine inspectors, as well as the demobilization commissioner, were authorized to permit exceptions in the case of industrial workers and salaried employees when the public interest demanded it. Aside from the two general orders relati!ig to industrial workers and salaried employees, special orders and laws regulated the hours of labor of certain trades; e. g., (1) bakeries, (2) agriculture, and (3) mines. 1. On November 23, 1918, the day on which the order reirulating the hours of labor of industrial workers was made, the National Office for Economic Demobilization issued an order regulating hours of labor in bakeries and confectioneries. Up to that tune, the hours of labor in these establishments were re~ated by the provisions of the Industrial Code as to trades injurious to the health of the workers, but by the new order, which is still in force, these provisions were nullified as to workers employed in bakeries and confectioneries. The order applies to male and female workers Gourneym.en, helpera, apprentices) in bakeries and confectioneries proper, as well as to workers employed in the manufacture of bakery or confectionery goods in all other establishments (hotels, restaurants, caf~s, boarding houses, hospitals, department stores, flour mills, etc.), but it does not apply to the salaried employees. · The regular workday of such workers shall not exceed eight hours, but the following exemptions are provided for: (a) Workers may be employed more than eight hc,urs a day if such employment is necessary to prevent the decay of raw matenals, or the spoiling of products, m so far as this work can not be done or comJ!.Ieted within the regular working time. (b) Upon request. the factory inspectors may permit, subject to revocation, exceptions from the foregoing regulation in two cases. They may allow an extension of the maximum workday for not more than 20 days a year if urgent necessity has been proved, and they may perm.it the employment of workers more than eight.hours during fairs and public festivals, in both of which cases, before the granting of the request., the workers' committee, or if no such committee exists the wor.k:ers of the establishment, must be given an opportunity to present their views. A copy of the decision, which must be made in writing, is to be posted m the establishment at a place easily accessible to the workers. · The commencement and termination of the daily hours of labor and rest _periods are regulated in a more comprehensive manner for workers m bakeries and confectioneries and establishments manufacturing biscuits, crackers, gingerbread, waffles, and matzoth· than for industrial workers in general. In such establishments all work between 10 p. m. and 6 a. m. is forbidden (as was the case during the war). This applies also to other establishments (hotels, etc.) having work connected with the manufacture of bakery and confectionery_ goods. There are, however, two exceptions to this rule: 1. Upon request the competent authority may allow, subject to revocation, in its district or parts thereof the eight-hour mght rest to begin at 9 or 11 p. m. instead of at 10 p. m. 2. Workers may be employed during the night rest period if on emergency work or if the public interest is involved, and also for keeping watch of the establishment and for repair work which can not be done during regular wor~ hours without considerable inconvenience to the operation of the establishment. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis SITUATION BEFORE DECEMBER, 1923 97 The rest periods within the regular working hours are regulated onll:_ for apprentices and female workers. Work on Sundays and holidays is forbidden in bakeries, confectioneries, and in all bakery and confectionery work of other estab· lishments, such as hotels, etc., the only exemptions granted being of a most limited scope. 2. When the Council of People's Commissioners in their manifesto of November 12, 1918, declared that all laws (mainly restrictive) governing the rights of agricultural laborers were suspended, the mea~er provisions which had protected agricultural laborers automat1caJ11 disappeared. At that time farmers' and agricultural laborers councils were created in the individual communes, and these local councils combined in a national farmers' and agricultural laborers' council, representatives of which and of the Federal Department of Labor and the Prussian Ministey of .Agriculture drew up a bill which on January 24, 1919, received legal force through a provisional order regulating aw.icultural labor. This order, which is still in force, contains proV1Sions as to labor contracts and hours of labor in agriculture. This provisional r021J].ation covers workers and salaried employees in agricultural and lorestral establishments, including suosidiary establishments. Because of the peculiar needs of agriculture, no uniform maximum workday is fixea for the year. The order merely provides that for four months the maximum workday shall average 8 hours, for four months 10 hours, and for four months 11 hours. 'l'he four months with equal working time need not be continuous; e. g., the four months with an average of 10 hours may be spread over the year. In computing hours of labor, the time from the farmhouse to the place of work and back is to be included, but not the rest periods nor the time occupied in feeding draft animals. During the six summer months rest periods of at least two hours :per day must be granted. Female workers with households of then- own must be released from work early enough to arrive at their homes one hour before the main meal. They are to be excused from work on the day preceding Christmas, Easter, and Whitsuntide. Overtime work is allowed, but in order to restrict overtime work, the employer must pay the employee for each hour of overtime at least one-tenth of the customary local daily wages plus 50 per cent. Some States have stipulated that the worker who works overtime is entitled to a corresponding reduction of his hours of labor in the dull season of the/ear. On Sundays an holidays only such work as is by its nature necessary-as for example, feeding and at ten~ the animals-shall be performed. If other work is done, and oruy urgent work is permitted, at least double the customary local wages shall be paid. 3. In the years immediately following the revolution the working time of miners was regulated by the general order of November 23, 1918, regulating the hours of labor of industrial workers. A special law relating to the hours of labor in underground mines, enacted July 17, 1922, brought about no essential change. It stipulated that the length of the shifts as fixed in the collective agreements in force on October 1, 1921, was to constitute the regular daily hours of labor, the shift, within the meaning of this law, beginning for under- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 98 CHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LA.BOB. ground miners with the time of their descent into the mine and ending with their completed ascent from the mine. In establishments in which the hours of labor were not regulated by a collective agreement on October 1, 1921, the daily hours of labor were to be those usual on that day in these establishments. Overtime work could be agreed · upon by means of a generally· binding collective agreement. For mines in which the temperature is in excess of 82° F. collective agreements should provide for shorter hours than the regular hours of labor, and. if a collective agreement failed to make such provision, shorter hours were to be fixed by the competent mining authorities after a hearing of the employers' and workers' organizations interested. This law was suspended when the decree of December 21, 1923, provisionally regulating the hours of labor of industrial workers, went into effect. ACTUAL DEVELOPMENT Pre-war time.-Statistics on collective ~reements for December 31, 1913, compiled by the Imperial Statistical Office, give the percentage of workers working specified hours in summer time as follows: TABLE 4O.-PER OENT OF INDUSTRIAL WORKERS COVERED BY OOLLEOTIVE AGREE· MENTS WORKING EACH CLASSIFIED NUMBER OF HOURS IN SUMMER, DEOMBER 31, 1913. Daily hours of labor Under 8•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 8 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 8!: :~t~............................. 8!: :~mo............................ Over 10 to 10½••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 10½ to 11. •••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over ;u•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• - Per cent of workers 0.3 2.5 3.2 35.4 20-4 34. 5 Ll L2 L4 Weekly hours of labor Under 48•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 48tolill ................................. Over 50 to 52•••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 62 to 54••••••••••••••••••••••••• 8ver M to 56•••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 1511 to 58 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 58 to 60 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 60 to 62•••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 62 to M -·-····················-Over 64••••••• · - · · · · · · · · · · - - - - , Per cent of workers 0. II 3.2 6.6 33.3 1L7 12.2 28.8 .4 .8 2. 5 Three-sevenths (43.6 per cent) of the workers covered by collective agreements had re~lar hours of labor not exceeding 54 a week. In studying these ngures, however, one must bear in mind that in pre-war times only a small fraction of the workers-those who were strongly organized and had comparatively favorable working conditions-were covered by collective agJ:eements. The agricuftural laborers and the other employees working 10 hours or more a day were, in general, not in a position to conclude collective agreements. The same is true of the miners, who on the whole had shorter hours of labor than the average workers. In the Ruhr they worked 8½ hours "bank to. bank," and as generally 1½ hours were consumed in descent and ascent, their actual working time was about 7 hours. In other mining districts hours of labor were much longer; e. g., in Upper Silesia, where the miners worked 10 hours "bank to bank," with an actual wor~ time of about 8½ hours. In the heavy industries (metal works, etc.), where collective agreements were also unknown, the hours of labor, almost without exception, were very long-from 10 to 12 hours a day. The shortest hours were those of the woodworkers, who were strongly organized while their employers were comparatively weak, and who laid special stress upon a short workday. The cabinet makers, for example, had the following weekly hours of labor: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 99 SITUATION BEFORE DECEMBER, 1923 TABLI: 41.-PER OENT OF CABINET MAKERS WORKING EACII OLASSIFIED NUMBER OF HOURS PER WEEK, 1885, 1893, 1902, and 1911. Weekly hours of labor 1885 Ill and under····---············································ •••••••• Over 51 to 54........................................................... ........ Over 54 to 57........................................................... 06 Over 57 to 60........................................................... ~Ji 7 Over 60 to 63........................................................... 22. 8 Over 63 to 66........................................................... ~11 8 Over 66 to 69........................................................... 6.1 Over 1111 ............................................................. 5. 0 Total............................................................ 100. 0 1893 0. 5 8. 8 12. 0 47. 6 12.<l 20. 6 1902 2. 6 28. 0 14.4 44. O 4.3 1. 6 1. 5 6.1 .3 .3 100. 0 100. 0 1911 16. 6 Sl. l 26. 4 22. 6 .9 2. 3 •0 .1 100. 0 In 1911 almost one-half of the cabinet makers worked no longer than 9 hours a day. In contrast may be mentioned the hours of labor of bricklayers and hod carriers, of whom in 1910 72 per cent worked 10 hours or more: Percent 8hours--··-···························-·····----··· 0. 64 • 63 8½hours....................... ·-··--·-----·····-·8¾ hours .......................................... . .02 9hours·-···················---··-··-········--····- 17. 10 g~~~~~=====:=======================:=========:=:== l0hours ............................... ---·······-·· 8. 87 • 63 65.25 1. 85 10½ hours_··-····················-················· 4. 96 11 hours ............................... ·-··········• 02 11½ hours·-······-·-·······--··--·····-·-··-······· • 03 12hour&----·----·····-·-·-···-··-·······-··-------Total.----------··-··---·-----·-------·· 100.00 War time.-Efforts of the workers to reduce their hours of labor, which had been rather successful in the 15 years _preceding the war, ended when the munition industry absorbed all the unemployed and overtime became customary in all establishments. According to data of investigations of the Federal Statistical Office covering the last two weeks of March and of September, 1914 to 1918, and including about 200,000 workers, a workday of 10 hours or more was in effect during the entire period in flour mills (in which even more than 11 hours were worked from 1915 to 1917) and in the paper industry (with the exception of September, 1914), in stone quarries in September, 1916, 1917, and 1918, and in the iron and metal industnes in March, 1916. On the other hand, the industries which suffered from a shortage of raw materials had very short hours of labor. A workday of less than 7 hours was in force in the lingerie and clothing industry in Se_ptember, 1916; in cotton mills in September, 1916; in hosiery mills m September, 1916; and in the passementerie industry in September 1914. A workday of over 7 and under 8 hours was in effect in September, 1914, in iron and metal works, in the precious metals industry, in the lingerie and clothing industry, in shoe factories.., in the manufacture of artificial flowers, and m printing establisnments; in March, 1915, in the precious metals mdustry; in September, 1915, in cotton mills; in March1 1916, in cotton mills and hosiery mills; in September, 1916, in hnen mills and shoe factories; and from March, 1917, on, in chocolate and https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 100 CHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LABOR candy factories and in the lingerie and clothing industry (with the exception of September, 1917). It will hardly be necessary to show in detail how the industries with reduced hours of labor also reduced their personnel, who flocked into the industr,ies with long hours of labor. The establishments in the metal industry covered by the investigation, for instance, increased their J>ersonnel 74 per cent between March, 1914, and September, 1918, while in the same period those of the clothing industry reduced their personnel 54 per cent. Perhaps the worst feature of the extension of hours of labor in war time was the reckless exploitation of children. The war emergency law of August 4, 1914, authorized factory inspectors to suspend during the war, in individual cases, the legal restrictions on child labor, etc. and this was done in numerous cases. Children under 14, for whom the law prescribed a 6-hour day, were frequently allowed to work up to 10 hours daily. The working-day of children between 14 and 16, normally 10 hours, was often extended to 11 and 12 hours. Employment of children under 16 on SUJ!cJ,ay, J;>rohibited by law, was permitted in a number of districts. While m normal times children under 16 could not be employed between 8 p. m. and 6 a. m., during the war many of them were permitted to work until late in the evening or in the early morning, and a very large number were employed on the regular nig_]it_ shifts, which often lasted 12 hours including rest periods. While all these exemptions were explicitly permitteaf there were many more cases in which emplo_yers simply ignored the egal restrictions on the employment of cliildren, not even attem:r>ting to secure permission for such employment. Two examI?les taken from the factory inspectors' reports may serve as illustrations: In the district of Dusseldorf 15-year-old boys were emplo:yed around blast furnaces in loading iron and in other transportat10n processes not only on Sunday and at night, but also on 24-hour sliifts. In two brickyards in Konigsberg, children under 14 years, who under the law could not be employed for more than three hours on school days and four hours on other days, were working up to 11 hours daily. Throughout Germany cliildren 8 and 9 years old were employed in peddling in the early morning and late evening hours. Postwar time.-With the introduction of the maximum 8-hour day in November, 1918, the regular weekly hours of labor became 48 for the majority of the workers and salaried employ:ees. AccordinJ? to statistics on collective agreements compiled by the Federal Statistical Office, more than four-fifths of the a~eements in force on December 31 of the years 1919 to 1922 provided for a week of 48 hours, as will be 1:1een in Table 42. They covered from two-thirds to five-sixths of the establishments and almost two-thirds of the persons whose working conditions were regulated by such agreements. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 101 SITUATION BEFORE DEOEMBER, 1923 TABLB 42~WEEKLY HOURS OF LABOR UNDER COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS IN FORCE DECEMBER 31, 1919 TO 1922· Weekly hours of labor I 1919 1920 I 1921 I 1Q22 Colleclbe agreements Up to 42 ..••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 42 to 45 •.•••••••••••••••.•••.•••..... · ..•...•••••••••••••• Over 45 to 46 ..••..•...•.•.•...••..•.••...•..••..••.•••••••••••• Over 46 to 47.........••...••.•••••.•••••••.•••••••••••••.•••••. Over 47 and under 48 .•......••..•••••••••••••••.••••••••..•..•• 48 ••...•...•..•.......••.•••.•••..•••••••••••••••.•••••••..••... Over 48 ••••••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••••••• Per cent Per cent Per cent 0.5 4.4 7.0 3.6 0.8 3. 5 9.0 3.4 0.5 3.5 8.1 3.2 81.3 80.8 2.0 82.1 2. 3 .7 2. 5 .5 Per cent .3 0.6 3. 0 9.3 3.0 .3 80.6 3.2 Establishments covered Up to 42 .•••••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••••••••••••• · •••••••••• Over 42 to 45 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•••.••.•••••••••••••.• Over 45 to 46 .•••••••••••••••••••••••••••.••..•..••••••••••••••• Over 46 to 41 •...•••••••••••••••••••••••••••.••••.•••••••••••••• Over 47 and under 48•••••••••••••••••••••••..•••••••••••••••••• 48 ..••.•••••••••..••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••••• Over 48 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 0.5 6. 7 11. 9 4.6 .7 73.3 2. 3 0. 7 0.2 5.5 15.3 3.1 4.1 8.9 75.2 .4 82.3 .4 .3 2. 7 .9 0. 2 2. 2 7.2 2. 7 .1 66.1 21.5 Employees covered Up to 42 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 42 to 45 .••••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•••••••••••• Over 45 to 46 .••••••..••••••••••••••••••.•••••••.•••••••.••••••• Over 46 to 47 •••. ·••..••••••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••••.••••••• Over 47 and under 48••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 0.1 8.0 21.2 48 ......... ..................•......•.••••. •·•·•···•••·•• ...••.. 62. l Over 48 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 6. 8 .7 1.1 8.4 6.2 15.8 3.2 .3 65.8 .3 6. 9 7.5 15.6 4. 7 .3 64. 7 .3 5.1 6. 4 13.5 3.0 .1 65. 7 6.2 Female employees covered Up to 42 .•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 42 to 45 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Over 45 to 46.••••••••••••••••••••..••••••••••.•••••••••••.•••••••.••••••• Over 46 to 47•••..•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.••••••••.••..••••• Over 47 and under 48•....••.•••.•••••.....•..............•..... .•........ 48 •.... ··•·•••·••••·••· ..•..••..••..•••..•••.•.•••.•••.•••.•••.....•••••.. Over 48 •••••••••••••.••.•••••••••••••..••..•........••••••••••• .••••••••• 0.3 5.1 35.1 4.9 0.2 5.8 31.9 54.1 .1 54. 9 .4 .0 .5 6. 7 0.2 3.9 29.9 3.8 .0 53.2 9.0 Longer hours of labor than 48 were agreed upon mainly in agriculture, where it is customary to limit the hours per year and not per week. This limitation in general is uniform for Provinces and even States. In 1923 the yearly hours agreed upon were: 2,900 in Bavaria, Wurttemberg, Baden, and parts of Pomerania; 2,840 in Eastern Prussia and Silesia; 2,800 in Mecklenburg, Thuringia, Hesse-Nassau, Rhineland, and Waldeck; 2,750 in Hesse, Hanover, and parts of Anhalt; 2,725 in Schleswig-Holstein; 2,700 in Brandenburg; 2,675 in parts of Anhalt; and 2,625 in Brunswick. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 102 CHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LABOR The workday is generally fixed at 10 to 11 hours per day in the summer and harvest months, and at 7, 8, and 9 hours in the other months. Some collective agreements (e. g., in Brandenburg, Eastern Prussia, and Mecklenburg) pr_ovide that in the busiest months there shall be a certain number of "emergency" or "obligatory" overtime hours. Agreements for nonagricultural workers and salaried employees which provide for more tnan 48 hours of labor are rare. An analysis made of the collective agreements in force in Saxony at the end of October, 1921, shows the following: Aside from agriculture, where the workday has been fixed at 8 hours for 3½ to 4 months, at 9 hours for 2 to 4½ months, and at 10 hours for 4 to 6 months, more than 48 hours per week have been fixed for the following occupations: Gardening, only three out of nine collective agreements providing for an 8-hour day. the year round and one for a 9-hour day for four months and five for eight months; engineers and firemen in the textile industry of eastern Saxony who had to work up to 54 hours; barbers and hair dressers, only two collective agreements providing for 48 hours, while one provided for 50, one for 52, and two for 54; cab drivers in Dresden, with a maximum workday of 10 hours; hotels, restaurants, and cafes. two agreements providing for 8 hours, one for 9, one for 10 per day, and one for 60 hours per week; domestic service, where the employees under the agreement of Plauen had a workday of 10 hours and thpse under the agreement of Dresden, "on call" time (presence on duty) of 12 hours; and service in institutions, the municipal hospital of Riesa having agreed upon 10 hours per day and the school for invalid children in Kleinmensdorf upon 60 hours per week for the teachers. In most cases more than 48 hours per week have been agreed upon for work which is not continuous, so that the hours of labor did not actually refer to wor~ t~e but to ~ime of prese~ce on duty. The 46-hour week prevailed m Saxony m the ·metal mdustry and the textile industry. Practically_ all over Germany the textile industry had the 46-hour week, which explains the fact that the percentage of women covered by collective agreements providing for less than 48 hours is larger than that for men. In the metal industry the em:r>loyers in many cases succeeded in 1922 in extending the hours of labor to 48. The percentage of German metal workers covered by collective agreements providing for less than 48 hours decreased from 40 on December 31, 1921, to 25 on December 31, 1922. Shorter hours than 46 were found only in certain trades. The only cases in Saxony in October, 1921, were in the following occupations and industries: Industrial workera Coal mining, underground__________________________________ Potash industry, underground______________________________ Building and construction work: November 15 to December 15__________________________ December 16 to January 15____________________________ January 16 to February 8______________________________ Stove setting (Nov. 1 to Feb. 28)___________________________ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Hours per day 7 7½ 7½ 7 7½ 7 103 SITUATION BEFORE DECEMBER, 1923 Hours perweek Sheet-glass manufacture-glass makers Gourneymen)__________ Bottle manufacture: Bottle makers ___ ------------------------------------Wicker-bottle plaiters__________________________________ Ball makers __________________________________________ Asbestos works (Dresden-Leuben)___________________________ Tallow and grease products (Leipzig)________________________ Slaughtering at home______________________________________ Cigarette industry_________________________________________ Paving (Leipzig) _________________ ------------------------- 42 45 39 33 45 36 36 45 45 Commercial and technical employees and foremen Metal industry (district of Chemnitz, Leipzig)________________ Breweries (Dresden)_______________________________________ Building industry ___________ --'-----------_________________ 45 45 45 !g Architects------------------------------------------------{1 Construction work________________________________________ 45 45 Insurance ________________________________________________ Private schools (Dresden)-teachers_________________________ 32 There are two trades which call for special discussion-(!) mines and (2) railways. I. Immediately after the revolution, the hours of labor for miners all over the country were reduced to 8 per day "bank to bank." This meant for the Ruhr Basin a reduction of only half an hour as compai'ed with pre-war times, and the miners of this district, who were accustomed to work shorter hours than other workingmen, were not satisfied. They demanded a six-hour shift1 went on strike, and succeeded in obtaining (April, 1919) a shift ot 7 hours "bank to bank" (5½ hours of actual work). They insisted, however, on a further reduction of the hours and the Munster of Labor, under the decree of June 18, 1919, appointed a commission to study means of introducing on February 1, 1920, the 6-hour shift "bank to bank." The comnussion1 composed of representatives of the organizations of mine owners 1 mmers, and salaried employees, while unanimous that a shorter shift would be advantageous from the point of view of health, came to the conclusion that the introduction of the 6-hour shift was feasible only through an international convention. It was probably not so much the dislike of long working hours that induced the Ruhr miners to cling to the principle of the 6-hour shift as the desire to have their claim to shorter working hours recognized by the mine owners. In any case, whenever they became convinced that an increase of production was necessary in the public interest, they were willing to do overtime work. Thus on March 8, 1920, they concluded a collective agreement with the mine owners under which, b e ~ with March 15, 1920, all miners, in addition to their regular shifts of 7 hours C;lach, were to work an extra half shift twice a week at double the regular w11ges. They were thus to work 49 hours for 56 hours' pay. The Kapp revolt, which broke out on March 13, 1920, and the ensuing conflicts in the Ruhr District somewhat delayed the actual introduction of the extra half shifts, but they were finally put into effect and were worked for about a year. But when the hopes of the miners for socialiKtion of l J'aclusive of midday rest. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 104 CHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LABOR the mines failed, the extra shifts were suspended. They were again ina~ated under an agreement effective September 1, 1922, and ~inng the middle of December. Because of the dissatisfaction of the miners, who felt the strain of the extra shifts considerably, extra shifts were suspended for four weeks. In the meantime, the French entered the Ruhr Basin, and when passive resistance was decided upon; extra shifts were, of course, out of question. In Lower Silesia the situation was similar to that in the Ruhr Basin. In Upper Silesia, where the length of the shift had been reduced by the collective agreement of January 31, .1920, from 8 to 7½ hours, extra shifts were the exce_ption. The same is true of Saxony where the opposition of the nuners doomed from the outset any attempt to introduce extra shifts. 2. The mtroduction of the eight-hour day caused probably- more inconvenience in railway operation than in any other industry, since men employed on trains can not, of course, quit their "place of work" at a cartain minute, and since working hours, hours of presence on duty, and hours of rest are here particularly difficult to separate. Indeed, the States, after introducing the eight-hour workdaf immediately after the revolution, soon recognized that to adhere stnctly to the maximum workday would hamper efficient operation of the railways. .An agreement was therefore reached under which weekly working hours (48) and monthly working hours (208) were fixed. The daily hours might exceed 8 hours in a particular case, provided the weekly or monthly maximum was not exceeded. • When on April 1, 1920, the State railways were taken over by the Federal Government, the latter wished to introduce a law providip.g special working hours for the railways, but owing to the o_IPOSition of the railway employees such a law was not enacted. The railwa_y administration then entered into negotiations with the employees which resulted in an understandini? that only part of the hours on duty should be considered hours ol work. This understanding was emoodied in the decree of August 5, 1922, which ·also fixed the days of rest at 52, consisting of not less than 32 consecutive hours each, or, as an alternative, 26 days of not less than 32 hours each and 3 days of at least 24 hours each in place of each 2 of the remafoing 26. OPPOSITION TO 8-llOUR DAY The first year after the introduction of the 8-hour day it met with practically no opposition at all. The first noteworthy signs of antagonism to this reduction of hours appeared in the summer of 1920, when the dollar exchange rate dropped from 100 marks in February to 33 marks in June. Some groups of employers, seeing their exports ham£:~ed, became anxious to reduce the cost of prothe wor!mig hours. But the matter became duction· by exten serious only when tlie· first bill for a law regulating hours of labor was published in A1.lg!1St 1921. Up to that time the 8-hour day had been r8'?1]].ated only by the provisional orders heretofore mentioned, which were extended from time to time. The employers who at first wanted only the opportunity of extending the liours of labor for certain periods by collective agreement, were now eager to abolish the 8-hour day thro:ugh 1!~w:~tion restoring their pre-war liberty of action as to pa.id but · · ted overtime work, but the https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis SITUATION BEFORE DECEMBER, 1923 105 power of the trade-unions was still too strong, and the employers contented themselves for the time being by fighting a reduction of hours on Saturday. In the spring of 1922 two sharp controversies took place. Botli in the metal industry and in the textile industry the employers attempted to replace the 46-hour week by a 48-hour week, '6e4tg rather successful in the metal industry, but not in the textile industry. When inflation increased and in consequence thereof trade-unions became absorbed in wage disputes, at the saane time being financially weakened, the :fight against the 8-hour day became more intense. When finally the unions broke down financially, the "conviction" that the 8-hour day was unbearable became universal among employers and the public in general. Arguments of adversaries.-The strongest attack against the 8-hour day was niade by Hug_o Stinnes, who, in a speech in the National Economic Council, November 9, 1922, declared it absolutely necessary to have for 10 or 15 years two hours additional work a day without compensation if Germany was to recover economically. Others advocated the suspension of the 8-hour day for five years. In general, however1 up to the fall of 1923, the employers did not go so far. They derued merely the legal fixation of many exceptions to the 8-hour day, arguing as follows: The introduction of the 8-hour day was necessary for political reasons and for the physical recovery of the workers from their overexertion during the war. It should also be legally maintained as a matter of principle. But it must be adapted to the needs of the industry, it must not reduce the productivity of Germany, and it should be enforced only after industry has been put on a sound basis and production intensified to such a degree that the ma.xi.mum outJ)ut can be secured within 8 hours. Tliey further demanded the exclusion of hours of presence on duty in computing working time, the extension of hours of labor for light work, and liberty to require overtime work. Mr. von Siemens, president of the Siemens concern, and member of the Reichstag and of the National Economic Council, particularly em:phasized that the decrease in German production was even more collSlderable than the reduction of working hours warranted, since a strict application of the 8-hour working-aay made it impossible, he said, to make good the fluctuations and disturbances of every-day occurrence in manufacturing. If even the smallest loss of trme could not be made up, it resulted in a loss in output. The arguments most generally advanced were that the extension of the hours of labor was the quickest means of increasing production and that, with the burdens resulting from the war, it was impossible to expect shorter instead of lo~er hours of labor. Special argllillents advanced by one or the other groups of employers were as follows: 1. Intensification of production is a matter of education of workers and employers and calls for a material change in the operation of the busmess. It is therefore not possible suddenly to reduce hours without hampering _production. Such a reduction can take place only as production 'becomes more intense. Moreover, such education of the workers takes a. long time, and there are numerous workers who are not able or not willing to work intensively and who prefer an unhurried 10-hour workday to an intensive 8-hour workday. Besides, putting industry on a sound business basis can be done only https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 106 CHAPTER V.-HOUBS OF LABOR through increased production, since additional capital can not easily be obtained. • This is the more necessa.ry as the equipment of the factories deteriorated during the wa1 and has not been renewed. 2. The output per man and per hour has dropped, or at lea.st has not increased sufficiently to make up for the reduced wor:kim? time. 3. In the many cases where the mtensity of production aepends upon the machine and not upon the worker, the output per day has, of course, decreased in proportion to the reduction of the workinE? time. A good deal of so-called work consists merely_ of hours ol presence on duty. It is unjust to value light work as bighlY. as hard work, and differentiation of the hours of labor between tight and hard work is urgent. 4. Economically, Germany lives upon her substance, consuming more than she produces. She has an adverse balance of trade, and an increase of exports, which is necessary in order to stabilize the currency, can be obtained only by an extension of the hours of labor. 5. The 8-hour day was introduced under the assumption that the other countries would follow the example of Germany, but this has' not resulted. 6. The 8-hour day has always been advocated as a means for the better intellectual development of the working class. But the number of those who are thus benefited is small and the sudden reduction of hours of labor is a detriment to those who do not seek to improve themselves intellectually, but loaf, or work for other employers in their spare time, or do agricultural work in addition to tlieir main occupation, and in consequence are tired when they go to work in the factory. An extension of the hours of labor was especially demanded for the coal mines, the metal works, the buil~ industry, and the small shops in rural districts. The three-shift system of 8 hours each was denounced as harmful, and, because of the necessary repair work and the time lost in changing shifts, it was declared preferable to return to the pre-war two-shift system of 10 hours. On the wh:ole, the movement ~ainst the eight-hour day, which originated within the heavy industnes, found there the strongest and most united support. More than all other employers, these industrial magnates hoped to be able to crush the trade-umons by an extension of the hours of labor. The manufacturers of finished products were not quite so unanimous. Where the workers were employed on automatic machinery, their employers were in favor of abolisliing the 8-hour day, but where the output de1;>ended on the efficiency of the worker, a good many manufacturers with modern equipment were not anxious to extend hours of labor. But they too found it inconvenient always to negotiate with their employees if they wished overtime work: done and they suffered from the enforcement of the 8-hour day particularly in repair work, cleaning, transport work1 etc. It was, then, more the desire for greater elasticity in the working time which made such employers join the ranks of th:e :fighters against the 8-hour day and not the conviction that they would materially increase their out;put or lower their cost of production by extending hours of labor. The advocates of the 8-hour day declared that overexertion of the workers was detrimental to the general welfare, and argued in favor of the 8-hour day from the standpoint of the worker. Specific arguments advanced by them were as follows: · https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis SITUATION SINCE DECEMBER, 1923 107 1. When work becomes slack, turnover of capital becomes slower and the equipment of the plant is utilized as fully as with intense J>roduction. Overhead expenses are comparatively smaller with a three-shift system of 8 hours than with a two-shift system of 10 hours. 2. The 8-hour day means in the long run increased output. The 8-hour day was not granted in 1918 as a J>Olitical concession but for economic reasons. The employers then aemanded only that other countries follow the example of Germany; this has resulted. 3. Before the war hours had already been reduced, and 10 years ago the 9-hour and even a shorter workday prevailed in many German establishments. 4. The necessity of adapting the maximum workday to the needs of agriculture and of distinguishing between hours of work and hours of presence on duty- in railway service were recognized by the workers immediately after the introduction of the 8-hour day and all justifiable claims of the employers in this respect have been met. 5. The German workers are morally bound to maintain the 8-hour day, since the German trade-unions for decenniums have led the international trade-union movement. 6. For psychological reasons, an extension of the hours of labor, which would be unavoidably accompanied by strong sociopolitical friction, would not result in an increase, but perhaps even in a reduction of out_put. Th.e workers demanded a legal 8-hour day, exceptions to be admissible only if arranged by collective agreement. The employers, on the other hand, demanded a fixing of the exem_ptions in the law itself. This struggle as to the impending 8-hour law was. thus, perhaps without a full knowledge of this fact by the interested parties, a struggle as to the basis of future labor contracts-should they be be.sea on the law, as they had 30 years before, or should the employers, in order to deviate from the 8-hour day, be compelled to conclude collective agreements~ · SITUATION SINCE DECEMBER, 1923 DECREE OF DECEMBER 21, 1928 The orders establishin_g the 8-hour day were extended from time to time, the last occasion being on October 29, 1923, when they were extended to November 17. No further extension being made, the legal 8-hour day for German workers (except miners) and salaried employees ceased to be operative. At first this was of no practical consequence because of tlie fact that working conditions were generally regulated by collective agreement. The Government, however, seeing no possibilitv of the enactment of a law regulating working hours and realizing~ the necessity of some regulation, resorted to the emergency law of December 8, 1923, authorizing it to take such measures as it might consider necessary and urgent, and on December 21, 1923, issued a decree relating to working time, which went into force January 1, 1924. This new decree explicitly reestablishes the legal force of the orders of November 23 and December 17, 1918, regulating the hours of labor of industrial workers, and of March 18, 1919, regulating the hours of labor of salaried employees, in so far as those orders are not amended by the new decree; e. g., since the new decree does not https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 108 CHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LABOR regulate the commencement and the end of the working time and the periods of rest and Sunday work, the provisions of the orders of 1918 and 1919 relating thereto are still in force. The purpose of the new decree, as announced by the Government, was to mcrease production by abolishing impediments to the free exercise of the will to work. It permitted exceptions from the rigid 8-hour day (1) by collective agreements and (2) by permit of the authorities. At the same time tlie decree "maintained the/rinciple of the 8-hour day and refused to abolish all limitations an to deliver the workers to the free play of economic forces. This could not be justified in a period of general distress when the economic organizations of employees were _perhaps not always stron!f eno~h successfully to resist unreasonable demands on the employers side.' The decree re!?Ulated its own scope, the hours of labor, and the means for its enforcement. SCOPB OP DBCRBB The decree of December 21, 1923, applies to persons who are economically dependent u_pon the,ir work for an em_ployer, and does not, therefore, cover_ public officials, nor such workers as prisoners and inmates of workhouses, nor __persons whose occupation is not their principal means of living, such as convalescents who work as an aid to their recovery. The order applies to industrial workers and to salaried employees. · The decree applies, first, to industrial workers in all industrial establishments, mcluding mining, in Federal, State, communal, and conununal union establishments, even if not operated for profit, and in agricultural subsidiary establishments of an industnal nature. The definition of "industrial worker" thus takes into consideration (1) the kind of work and (2) the nature of the establishment in which employed. 1. Industrial workers are all persons who through a labor contract are elnployed as journeymen, helpers, apprentices, supervisory officials, foremen, engineers, or factory hands, or in similar positions. 2. In order to be an industrial worker within the meaning of the decree, the worker must be employed either in an industrial establishment or a public-service ente~rise. Mines are considered to be industrial establishments, and tlie law of July 17, 1922, relating to the hours of labor in mines has, therefore, been explicitly abrogated by the new decree. The following are not to be considered industrial establishments: Fisheries, drug stores, schools, lawyers' offices, insurance companies and the like, railways, and ocean ships. Domestic service is not included, and therefore the hours of labor of domestic servants are not regulated by the decree. It does not apply · · fo bakeries and confectioneries, the hours of labor of which are still regulated by the special order of November 23, 1918. Federal, State, and communal enterprises are covered by the new decree even if not operated for profit, e. g., State mines, municipal gas works, etc., but not the national railways. The regulation applies also to salaried employees engaged in com:m.ercial work, and to those engaged in technical work whose hours of labor differ from those of the industrial workers. Supervisory officials, foremen, and engineers whose work time, for practical reasons, must coincide with that of the industrial workers are not con~ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis SITUATION SINCE DECEMBER, 1003 109 sidered salaried employees within the meaning of this decree. On the other hand, office employees and apprentices learning the work of a salaried employee are regarded as salaried employees. The regulation does not apply to higher emplo:yees such as managers with general or limited power of attorney (Prolcuristen) who are enterea in the commercial register, nor to supervisory employees who direct at lea.st 20 salaried employees or 50 workers, or workers and salaried employees whose yearly income exceeds 4,000 gold marks ($952). Salaried employees in agriculture and forestry, inclucling subsidiary establislurients, and journeymen and a_pprentices in drug stores are also excluded, but not those in the other establishments excepted in the case of industrial workers. The scope of the regulation IS thus much broader as to salaried employees than as to industrial workers. LENGTH: OF WORKIHG-DAY As a matter of principle, the normal workday, i. e., the regular daily wor~ time, consists of 8 hours for tlie above-mentioned persons. The decree, however, allows many exceptions to this rule and, moreover the regular daily working time can be extended beyond 8 hours by collective agreement or by order of the competent authorities. H no regulation of the working time has been made by collective agreement or by official order, the regular daily working time is that fixed in the law. As a. :matter of _principle, regulation by collective agree:ment ranks above the official order, except as otherwise provided in the decree. Overtime work by order of the employer alone is permitted under certain conditions but in other cases an official permit is needed for such work. Because of the numerous deviat!ons from the 8-hour day permitte~, a maximum workday of 10 hours 1s •fixed, but there are also exceptions, as employment beyond 10 hours is permitted if urgently required in the interests of the public weliare or in case of temporary emergency. Aside from this general regulation of the hours of labor, several special regulations are still in force, e.g., the regulations applying to establishments involving special dan~er to health and to underground mining. These special regulations are akin to the provisions m the Industrial Code as to the hygienic maximum workday. Special regulations as to hours of labor also appear in many articles of the decree of December 21, 1923. Normal, worlcday.-The regular daily working time, including the hours of presence on duty, but excluding rest periods, are not to exceed 8 hours. The decree provides not only Ior the 8-hour day but also for the 48-hour weelt and the 96-hour fortnight. In case less than 8 hours has been worked in an establishment or in a subdivision thereof on individual days, this loss of time may be made up, after a hearing of the legal representatives of the e:mployees, by overtime work on other days of the same or the subsequent week. In this manner greater freedom is granted with regard to the distribution of the hours of labor over the individual workdays. The employer may thus reduce the regular working time in his establishment or in a part thereof (but not for individual workers), for example, by two hours on Saturday, and these lost hours may be made up in the course of the next week. No :maximum workday within the 48-hour week or the 96-hour fortnight is fixed for male workers over 16 years nor 20168°-25t--8 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 110 CHAPTER V,-HOURS OF LABOR for salaried employees in general, but for juvenile workers between 14 and 16 years of age and for female workers in establishments emplo:png as a rule at least 10 workers, the maxim.um workday of 10 hours :fixe<l by the Industrial Code still obtains, as does also the .maximum workday of 8 hours ·for females on days preceding Sundays and holidays. Since in transportation and communication the regular 8-hour day causes special mconvenience, the decree provides that for both workers and salaried employees in transportation and communication, including railways and :post and telegra:eh service, general excel>:' tions from the legal regulation of the worlong time may be agreed upon between the management and the employees' organizations. The hours of presence on duty may be re_gu!ated by special arrangement. The 8-liour day may be exceeded m branches of industry (or for groups of employees) wliich regularly and to a considerable extent require mere presence on duty on the part of the employees. In such cases the hours of labor per day, per week, or per fortnight may be. regulated by collective agreement, or, in the absence of such agreement, by the Federal Minister of Labor after a hear:i!).g of the interested organizations of emJ>loyers and employees. This provision applies to such groups as doorkeepers, drivers, office boys, etc. _ The trme by which the 8-hour day may be exceeded in such cases is not limited in the decree, but for juvenile and female employees the limitations of the Industrial Code hold good. In case a collective agreement :provides for an unreasonable extension of the work~ time (including presence on duty) the competent authorities may interpose and themselves reg1ll.ate the hours of labor. Excep_tiom to normal workday.-The normal workday may be deviated from in two waY.8: 1. :r!ie regulai: hours of _labol' ~a:y: be extended; 2. Under certa.m conditions overtrme work 1B permIBsible. 1. The regular workday may be extended by collective &.g!eement, in which case the provisions of the agreement shall be binding upon workers covered by the agreement. ·n sueh an agI"eement contains provisions as to hours of Iabor which are considered harmful by the competent authorities, such authorities may object, and if the objectionable provisions a.re not ultered within the trme limit fixed by the authorities, they may themselves fL"t the hours of labor. On the other hand, on the going into effect of the decree collective agreements which fix shorter holl1'8 of labor than those provided in the decree may be abrogated on 30 days' notice. Collective agreements must not provide for a regular workday in excess of 10 hours, nor, of course, for one not in accordance with the Industrial Code. But in those cases where an employer is for certain reasons allowed to l1mgthen temporarily the regular workday, he shall not be restricted to the hours of labor proviaed for in a collective agreement. The reg1ll.ar workday may- also be extended by order of the competent authorities. In establishments in which the hours of labor are not regulated by collective agreement, a. deviation from the normal 8-hour day may, on application of the employer, be permitted, after a hearing of the legal representatives of the emplorees and subject to revocation by the factory or mine inspector, if considered necessary for technical re21sons, beca.use of interruption of operation due to force majeure, accident, or other unavoidable cause, or for https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis SI1'UATION SINCE DECEMBER, 1003 111 g~neral economic reasons. An appeal from such decision tq the higher authority may be taken at any time, but such appeal does not postpone the enforcement of the decision. In granting an extension of the regular workday, the authorities must observe the maximum 10-hour workday. The extension of the regular workday by the authorities shall take place only if no collective agreement exists. If after a decision of the authorities the hours of labor are regulated by collective agreement, such regulation shall at once supersede tlie decision of the authorities. 2. A temporary extension of the regular workday through overtime work by order of the employer alone is, under certain conditions, permissible; in other cases overtime work requires the approval of the authorities. Overtime work by order of the emplo_yer alone is permissible (a) on 30 days during one year, (b) for the sake of a regular and full operation of the entire _plant, (c) for emergency work, or (d) in case of · establishments with continuous operation. (a) Employers may, after a hearing of the representatives of their employees, have the employees of tlieir establishment or of a subdiVISion thereof work overtime not to exceed two hours per day on 30 days, to be chosen by the employers, during one year. This provision gives the employer a certain freedom of action in cases where a sudden temporary need for longer hours of labor arises, but he is not allowed to have individual employees work overtime, nor can he have all his employees work one hour of overtime on 60 days. (b) After a hearing of the works council, female and juvenile employees may be required to work one hour overtime daily and male employees over 16 years of age two hours overtime daily if employed: 1. In guarding the establishment or in cleaning or in mamtenance work necessary for the regu_lar operation of the employer's or another establishment; 2. In work necessary for the resumption of full operation; 3. In the loading or unloading of vessels m port or of railroad cars, and in the switching of such cars, provided that sueh overtime work is necessary to prevent traffic jams or to observe loading-time limits; 4. In supervising the work mentioned under 1, 2, and 3. This provision, then, refers mainly to work performed outside of the regular working time to mak:e possible the full use of the regular worlring time of the entire plant. (c) The employer may require overtime work in emergencies or to prevent detenoration of raw materials or ~polling of products. In such cases the hours of labor fixed by collective agreement or by official instruction do not apply. There is no limit to the amount of such work other than the restrictions for juvenile and female employees and as to the hygienic maximum workday provided for in the Industrial Code. (d) In establishments whose nature necessitates continuous operation, like blast furnaces and gas works, or in which continuous Sunday labor is necessary in the public interest, e. g., certain food industries, male workers over 16 years of age, if -:-equested by the employer, may each three weeks on the weekly change of shifts work a maximum of 16 hours inclusive of rest penods, provided that during the three weeks they are twice granted an uninterrupted rest of 24 hours. This exception shall, however, apply only to employees necessary for the maintenance of continuous operation. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 112 CHAPTER V.-HOUBS OF LABOR Overtime work may also be authorized by the competent authorities, 'if urgently necessary in the public interest-in particular to prevent unemployn:i.ent or to insure a supply of food to the population. Maximum workday_.-To prevent unreasonable overtime, a maximum workday of 10 hours is established. The employer may, however, without special :permission, demand work beyond the maximum workday in emergencies, provided he does not violate the provisions of the Industrial Code as to the hours of labor of juvenile or female employees and as to the hygienic maximum workday. He may also exceed the maximum workday if urgently necessary for the public welfare. Such reasons must actually prevail, however, or the employer will be liable to punishment. Special reg'Ulations.-Further limitations on the hours of labor are provided by the decree (a) for establishments involving special dangers, (b) for various unhealthful trades, and (c) for juvenile and femiile employees in conformity to the Industrial Code. (a) The order of December 21, 1923, limits the hours of labor in branches of industry or in occupations involving special danger to life or health of the workers, such as underground coal mining, or in which the workers are more than extraordinarily exposed to the effects of heat, poisonous substances, dust, and the like, or to the danger of explosives. The Minister of Labor is to decide to what brandies of industry and to what occupations these limitations (which appJy to workers only and not to salaried employees) are to apply. Under these limitations an extension of the 8-hour day or 48-hour week or 96-hour fortnight by collective agreement or official order shall be permitted only if urgently required in the J>Ublic interest or if shown by long expenence tliat it is not harmful and if it does not exceed half an hour per day. In no case is an extension of the maximum 10-hour day permitted in such branches of industry or occupations. In underground mines, in shafts with a temperature of over 82° F., shorter hours of iabor are to be fixed by collective agreement or by the mine inspection service, after a heanng of the interested economic organizations of employers and of employees, if no agreement is reached. In coal mines the shift, beginning with the time of descent into the mine and ending with the completed ascent from the mine, shall be considered the reguJ.ar workday. The law of July 17, 1922, is explic_ itly suspended by the new decree. (b) A hygienic maximum workday, differing for different industries, had been mtroduced for certain industries, e. g., flour mills (April 26, 1899); hotels and restaurants (January 23, 1902); lead works (June 16, 1905); stone quarries and stone cutting (May 31, 1909, and November 20, 1911); compressed-air work (June 28, 1920); paint work on vessels (February 2, 1921). These 1imitations a.re not affected by the new decree and can not be altered by collective agreement nor by official order. (c) The limitations on the hours of labor of iuvenile and female workers provided by the Industrial Code are explicitly adopted by the new decree. Tn addition it provides that female workers who a.re pregnant or who nurse children shall, if possible, upon request, be exempt from working more than 8 hours a day. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis SITUATION SINCE DECEMBER, 1923 113 ENFORCEMENT OF DECREE ,The enforcement of the provisions of the decree referring to hours of labor of workers and salaried employees is intrusted to the factory and mine inspectors, who are authorized to discuss the hours of labor with committees of the workers and of the salaried employees in the presence of the employer or with either party alone. In case of violation of the new decree, the old orders of 1918 and 1919 (again in force), or the Industrial Code, it is not the employee but the employer exclusively who is punished. Under the new decree the employer who violates its provisions is to be punished by a fine. For a second offense, if the violation is premeditated, the _penalty shall be imprisonment for a term not exceeding six months, or a fine, or both. Under the old orders the employer was punished regardless of whether or not the employee had worked the unlawful overtime voluntarily; but under tlie new decree the employer is not to be punished for allowin~ male workers to work excessive overtime if they work voluntarily, if the overtime is required because of special circumstances and is temJ?orary, if the employer does not exploit the necessity or inexpenence of the employee, and if such overtime does not manifestly injure the employee. HOURS OF LABOR IN HOSPITALS An investigation in 1910 as to the daily hours of labor, periods of rest, vacations, and old-age provision for employees in hospitals disclosed great abuses in working conditions. Before the war unsuccessful attempts were made to regulate such conditions, especially the hours of labor, by law, and during the war of course no progress was made along these lines. When, after the revolution, the working time of industrial workers was regulated, opinions di:ffered as to whether nurses in hospitals were covered by such J>rovisions. The employees themselves were in favor of an 8-bour day, but both private and :rmblic employers, physicians, and the majority of the experts consulted declared that the enforcement of the 8-hour day and the introduction of a three-shift system would be detrimental to the interests of the sick and so the matter was left in abeyance. In Octoberz 1920, however, a national collective agreement was concluded tor female nurses, which established the 8-hour day, to be extended only in emergencies. A day of rest was to be granted each week, twice a month on a Sunday if possible. In general a sufficient rest period was to intervene when night service followed day service or vice versa. The nurses did not enjoy these satisfactory conditions very long, however, as the decree of February 13, 1924, deprived them of the advantages they had gained. Under the new decree the weekly hours of labor, including Sundays and holidays, are 60, exclusive of rest periods. No maximum workday is provided, but the daily hours of labor shall not as a rule exceed 10. The distribution of the hours of work over the week shall be fixed by the management of the hospital, after a hearing of the supervising physicians and representatives of the employees. Overtime work bevond the 60 hours per week shall be done only in emergencies and as a temporary measure. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 114 OHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LABOR ACTUAL DEVELOPJDNT It is not yet possible to judge the ultimate effect of the decree of December, 1923, upon the hours of labor. The tendency of the trade-unions in negotiations with employers' associations was, of course, to maintain the 8-hour dav, while the latter aimed at an extension of the hours of labor. The attitude of the employers was not, however, uniform. The employers in the·india rubber industcy, for example, declared in favor of the 8-hour day, statiilg that before the war the 8-hour day and the IO-hour day had existed simultaneously, and that the unbroken 8-hour day had yielded a better econormc result than the 10-hour day broken by a midda;r rest; that after the revolution the men had done quite as much, and in some cases even more, work in 8 hours with good management than in the 10-hour day of pre-war time; that for uninterrupted operation, which, however, could not be considered in the rubber industry except in periods 01 especially brisk business or in seasonal work, the 8-hour day alone allowed of making the best possible use of the plant and its equipment. It was taken for gi:anted that, in spite of the shorter hours, the present output in the rubber industry exceeds that of pre-wartime. In other cases, the employers attempted to obtain an extension of workin? hours but afterward agreed to the 8-hour day. The employers association in the cigarette industry abrogated their basic agreement stipulating for a 48-hour week, and called on their workmen to enter into negotiations for a new agreement. The application of the employers' association to the Minister of Labor to establish a 56-hour week from and after February 1, 1924, did not, however, meet with approval, and an agreement was coil.eluded between the parties under which the national collective ·agreement and the district collective agreements were to remain in force provisionally. - The employers in the printi!ig trade, in spite of great numbers of unemployed workers, did not show as conciliatory a spirit. Negotiations for a new basic agi:eement to supersede the agreement which was to e;pire on December 23 be~an on December 121 and were conducted with rather vehement d1sI?utes, produced mainly by the following proposals of the German printers' association (employers): The workin~ time is 57 hours per week exclusive of rest periods. Whether the working trme be continuous or interrupted by rest periods, the_ workman must begin and leave his work punctually. The employer has the right of checking the coming and going of the workmen, e. g., by time clocks. The daily working hours may be between 6 a. m. and 10 p. m., according to tbe requirements of the business if there is but one shift. They may vary, that is, be reduced or extended, on individual days in each establishment or department. Notice of changes of this kind will be given to the workmen within a specified time before their going into effect. Notice of the introduction or abolition of shifts need not be given beforehand. The workmen will be assigned to the shifts by the management of the establishment. · These proposals were rejected. On January 10, negotiations were renewed at the instance of the Minister of Labor, and an agreement arrived at establishing the 48-hour week as the normal working time, while 5 hours of overtime-3 hours in the case of linotype, etc., operators-are to be worked at the regular rate. With the altera~1ons agreed upon, the basic agreement of January 1, 1922, was extended to May 31, 1924. Litho~aphers and music engravers have concluded a siinilar agreement, while photo-engravers, copper engravers, and wood engravers, under an agreement effective until December 31, 1924, are to receive 25 per cent additional for overtime https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 115 SITUATION SINCE DECEMBER, 1923 previously announced, 33 ½ per cent additional for overtime notice of which is not given in advance, and 100 per cent additional for Sunday work. In some trades the demands of the employers have been even more excessive. In the chemical industries, they have given notice that they will no longer be bound by the national ha.sic agreement, demanding the 10-hour day o.nd in establisnments with continuous operation a week of 70 hours and for presence on duty a week of 84 hours. In many ca.ses collective agreements could not be concluded, and official arbitrators stepped in, who in their awards generally extended the work4ig time. In case such awards were declared generally binding, the trade-unions had to yield, but many times difficulties a.rose in the practical enforcement of such awards which led to strikes and lockouts. In examining the collective agreements and awards made under the new decree, it is noticeable how greatly the working time varies from one agreement to another. The effect the new decree has already had on collective agreements can be seen in the provisions of such collective agreements on the following points: Maximum working week of over 48 hours; maximum wor~-day of 8 hours, or over; week of 46 or 48 hours, or 48 hours with provisions for maximum; hours of presence on duty of employees whose regular work consists to a considerable extent in readiness to work; pay for extended hours of labor or overtime work; regulation of hours of labor in trades injurious to health; assent of representatives of employees required in extending hours of labor; shorter working time on Saturday; dismissal of employ-ees in consequence of extension of hours of labor. Table 43 shows the agreements containing such provisions: TABLE 43.-PROVISIONS OF COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS AND ARBITRATION AWARDS MADE UNDER DECREE OF DECEMBER 21, 1923, AS TO SPECIFIED POINTS Mazimum working week of over 48 hours Collective agreement or Hours per week arbitration award Industry or occupation Award, Dec. 29, 1923 ____ Banking ·------------··············· Clotblng-Blelefeld.-···-____ ·----- __ Agreement, Feb. 7, 1924_ Agreement ______________ Commercial clerks-Eeatern Prussia_ Hats and mllllnecy (wholesale) _______ Agreement, Jan, 11, 1924_ Iron and steel-Ruhr district: Blast furnaces_ ··- --- -- Otber departments •••••••••••••• _ ............................................. Metals: Lower Silesia _____________________ Award_----··--- ______ •• Wurttemberg and Hohenzollern._ General agreement, Jan. 28, 1924. 64 64 64 Beginning Jan. 2, 1921. 59 6-day week: Exclusive of rest perlod&-day sblft, 68 hours; night shift, 60 hours. 164 I Remarks 67½ Do. FromJan.14to Mar, 14. 64 54 Mining, Ruhr dJstrlct, work above Cl'9Ulld: Mines with 1 hoisting shaft••••••• Acreement_ ••••••••••••• May be extended to 60. For whole or part of establlshment, at order of employer. 69 Mines with 2 hoisting shafts ___ ••• ···--do .....•••••••••.• -. 68 Textllell-Lall88tla: MachiDlsts and --·--do •••••••••••••••••• firemen. 66 6-day week: Exclusive of rest periods-night shift, 68 hours; Saturday morning shift every other week, 8 hours. 6-day week: N~ht sblft, 58 hours; Satur ay mormng shift, 8 hours. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis I Net time, 116 CHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LABOR TABLE 48.-PROVISIONS OF COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS AND ARBITRATION AWA.RDS MADE UNDER DECREE OF DECEMBER 21, 1923, AS TO SPECIFIED POINTS-Contd. Maximum working day of 8 hours or over Industry or occupation Collective agreement or Hours per week arbitration award Coal mining-Underground miners: District of Ibbenbiiren ___________ Agreement, Dec. 11, 1923 _ Agreement ______________ All other__________________________ districts except Bavaria__ _____ Bavaria do. _________________ Lignite minesCentral Germany-Under- Award, Dec. zi, 1923 ____ ground workers. Central Germany-Workers _____do---------·-------above ground. Rhineland __________________ ----SaxonySalaried employees. ______ -- ---------------- --- ----------------------- - O111.ce employees__________ Iron and steelIron works of Upper Silesia _______ ----------------- -- ----- -------------------------- - Leather industry _____________________ Award __________________ Metals: Agreement ______________ District of Dresden-Metal Manufacturers Association plants. District of Bautzen _______________ ...................................................... :Potash salts mining: workers ____________ Underground - Workers above ground ___________ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ------------------ ------- -.................................................. Remarks Length of shift, from beginni~ of descent into mine to beginning of ascent therefrom. Do. 8 Do. 8½ 8 8 10 Closed working; open working, 8½ hours, exclusive of time of descent and ascent and rest periods. Exclusive of rest periods. 10 9 9 10 10 Technical employees same hours as miners under their orders, with same rest c:iods. . 7 urs OD Saturday. No chan~ where ~ants worked ess than 10 ours before or during war. Exelusive of rest iSeriods, beginning Jan. 1, 1 /M, After notice to workmen. 8½ l 8 10 From ~ ~ c e n t into e to · of ascent therefrom. Workers on hoisting work same hours as underground workers. 117 SITUATION SINCE DECEMBER, 1923 43.-PROVISIONS OF COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS AND ARBITRATION AW ARDS MADE UNDER DECREE OF DECEMBER 21, 1923, AS TO SPECIFIED POINTS-Contd. TABLE Week of 46 or 48 hour8, or 48 hour8 with provision for maximum Hours per week Industry or occupation Collective agreement or arbitration award l-----l Agreement ••••.•••.•.... Agreement Jan. 15, 1924. Agreement Jan. 21, 1924. Agreement ••..•••••••••. 48 48 46 46 Engraving and chasing and related National agreement Dec. occupations. 12, 1923. Jute-Welda and Triebes •••••••••••••• Agreement ..••••.••••••• Metals-Dresden and Bautzen .•••••••••••••••..•.••.•••••..•••• Porcelain and related industries........ Award Jan. 26, 1924•..... Printing and bookbinding ••••••••••••• Agreement Jan. 10, 1924. 48 Breweries............................. Corrugated cardboard................. Corset maklng-Wurttemberg.•••••••• Electric works-Saxony............... Sawmills.............................. Salaried employees: Commercial and technical em• ployeesHlrschberg (Silesia) ••••••••••••• Magdeburg ••••••••••••••••••••• Osnabruck................. ••.•• Commercial clerks-Halberstadt, Oschersleben, Seehausen, Nien• hagen and Crottorf. Commercial employees-Wurt• temberg. Commercial establishments and transport trade-Halle and vi• clnity. Steel works-Rhineland and West• phalla. Textiles: Dresden and Plauen •••••••••••••• Bielefeld•••••••••••••••••••••••••• Remarks Regn• Maxi• Jar mum 46 48 48 48 Agreement •••••••••••••• 48 AgreementJan. l, 1924... Agreement Feb. 7, 1924.• 48 48 48 Agreement Jan. 1, 1924•• 48 54 54 48 ------52 ------54 53 Maximum hours for type-sett'lng•machlne operators, 51. 54 54 ------------- ------- Award Jan. 28, 1924••••• 48 Agreement Jan. 4, 1924 .. 48 Agreement Dec.1923•••• 48 54 AwardJan.18, 1924•••.•• Agreement Jan. 23, 1924. 48 48 54 Tobacco (chewing) manufacture- Agreement Jan. 10, 1924. Thurlngia. Wine trade and allied Industries- AwardJan.21, 1924•••••• Treves.. 48 54 48 100 hours overtime per year obligatory. 54 54 ------54 ------- Same In other agreements for textile industry. While hours may be ex• tended if necessary for increased production or better use of equip• ment. etc., award de• nied such necessity tilen existed. Hours of presence on duty of employees whose regular work consists to a considerable extent in readiness for work Industry or occupation Collective agreement or arbitration award Hotels: Berlin ...•••••..•.•••..•.••••••••••••••••••••••.•••••. Dresden ..•..••.•.•••..••••••••..••.. __ ...••......•... Hanover••••••••••••••.•••••..•................•..•... Munich .••••.•.•.•••••.•••••••.•..••.•...•.•... __ . _-·Stettin and vicinity••••••••••••••..•.• Agreement .•.• Metals: Lower Silesia-Guards, doorkeepers, Hours per day 3 57 13 10 11 • 60 Award .•••••• _ 12 Wurttemherg and Hohenzollern- Agreement. .•• Doorkeepers, servants, errand boys, etc. . Mining-Saxony: Salaried employees •••••••.••••••••••••• 160 etc. • Per week. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 12 Remarks Hours of work proper, 10. Hours of work proper, 9. Uninterrupted weekly rest of 36 hours; employees not to take W'ork In 2 establishments at same time. Considered as equivalent of 10 hours' work. 118 OHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LA.BOB TABLE 43.-PROVIBIONB OF COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS AND ARBITRATION A.WA.RDS MADE UNDER DECREE OF DECEMBER 21, 1923, AB TO SPECIFIED POINTS-Contd. Pay for eztended hours of labor or overtime work 1Dd118try or occupation Collective agreement or arbitration award ID- Time for which paid crease over regular rate Remarks P. ct. Of gold value of stipulated District of Ibbenbllren-Un- ---------------- 8th hour______ (') dergronnd work. Lower and Upper Silesia, ---------------- Extended time------ N=pay. Saxony, and Upper Saxony. -----do______________ _ Regular pay (lnoludlng ooat-o1Lignite :mines-Central Germany. 11v1ng bonus) Increased In proportion to extena1on of time. Oorrngated cardboard-Hanover_------- 11th hour _____ ----- Overtime rate; 9th and loth hours regular rate. 10 9th hour_____ Flour mllla-Breslau ______ , Agreement____ { loth hour_____ 20 Over 9 hours to ba worked onl7 If workers agree. After lothhour 2li Government hospitals____________ Agreement, Extended time No extra pay. 1an. 1, 1924. Do. Hats and millinery-Berlin----do Hotels-Stettin-_________________ Agreement____ After 60 hours l Overtime rate. · Iron works-Upper Silesia--_____ Extended time Regularrate. Marble works and stone mason's Agreement, ---- -do_______ _ 1st after rap1ar hours DO& trade-North Germany. J"an. 1, lffl. overtime. Metals: District of Berg ______________ Agreement, A.fter48hours •------ Regular rate. J"an. 28, 19'J4. Berlin.._______________________ Agreement___ _ After limit _____ _ Overtime rate. ftxed In decree. Dresden______________________ ---------------- Extended time _____ _ No extra pay. Mining-Ruhr district: Underground work.__________ _____do ··------ -----Do. Work above ground._________ Agreement____ Extra work____ (I) Do. Porcelain-Berlin---------------- ---------------- Extended time Potash salts :mining ______________ ---------------- -----do ·------ ------ Regular pay (Including J.ost.oflfvlng bonus) Increased In ~ o n to extension of Coal mining: i------ nonr Salaried employees: Halle and vlclnlty-Oommerclal eetabllshments and transport trade. Hlrschberg-Gommerclal and technical employees. Magdeburg __________________ Textiles: Esst Saxony _________________ ---------------. ----.do--------______ No extra pay. Agreement_____ Mith hour•---·------ Overtime rate; one two-hundredth of monthly salary for @th to Mth hours. ---------------- Extended time ______ No extra pay. Award,Feb. 1. ---------------- ------ Monday to Friday, 1 extra hour obligatory, wagee In11124. creased 6 per cent; 3 addlUonal hours, with workers' consent, wagee lncreaaed 16 _ per cent. Saxony______________________ Award-------- Extended time _____ _ wee1r1,- wagee Increased In pro. port.on to extension of time. Wurttembarg and Bielefeld__ ---------------------do_________ ------ No extra pay. Tobacco: Cigars _______ Agreement____ After M hours• 211 6 extra hours per week worked for normal wagee. Ohewlng-Thurlnlia-------- ---------------- Extended tfme ______ No extra pay. Tr~elm-Ooal transport Agreement, and Industrial eetabllsh1an. 28, 19:M ments. Sondershausen and vlcln- ________ lty (German Transport Assn.) Treves---------------------- Agreement---Woolen-Nuremberg_____________________________ I Per week. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis • One-seventh. 11th hour___________ Overtime rate; 9th and 10th hours regular rate. After60hours• Bundayandnf&htworkllOper cent extra 9th and 10th ______ No extra pay. hours. After48honrs • 3 I One-sixth. 2li 1 I Additional pay for each hour. 119 SITUATION SINCE DECEMBER, 1923 TA.BLF: 43.-PROVIBIONS OF COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS AND ARBITRATION AW ARDS MADE UNDER DECREE OF DECEMBER 21, 1923, AS TO SPECIFIED POINTS-Contd. Regulation of hours of labor in trades injurious to health Collective agreement or arbitration award Industry or occupation Provision Iron and steel: Ruhr district........................ Agreement•••• Workmen not to work regularly more than 54 hours in 6 days (exclusive of rest periods and time of presence on duty), classes of workers affected to be determined without delay. Do. Mlnlng ••• ·-··--···------·····-········- Agreement__ ._ Conforms exactly to provisions of decree. Iron works-Upper Silesia.•••••••••• ··-·--·------·-· Assent of representatives of employees required in extending hours of labor Collective agreement or arbitration award Industry or occupation Extra hoursrr wee Body whose BSSent ls necessary Remarks Metals: Dlstriot of Berg _____ ·-······- Agreement, After48th Workers' rep- 8 hours per week. resentatl ves. Jan. 28, 1924. Lower Silesia_ ••••••• -··-···· Award----··-- 54thto60th. Works counoll _ After 9th•. - •••• do--······ 88J'.ODY-···-···-·-·-··--·--·· Arter54th. ···--do •••••••• Wurttemberg and Hobenzollern. Salaried employees: .Association of German Na- Agreement •••• After48th_ Employees' 1 hour dally except Sat• representsurday. tional Commerclal Clerks. tlves . • ____do __ • _____ ___do •••••• ••••• •••••••• do Do. Magdeburg. __ .... -·-······· • •••. do •••••••• In redistribution of hours Osnabruck and vioinity •••••• Agreement, over week. Jan. 7, 1924. emRhineland, West~la, ............... ~8thto54th Salaried p 1 o ye es' Lower Silesia and · chcouncils. berg-Iron and steel works. Employees' Do. SBJ'.ony-Electrio works. ••••• Agreement, May24,192:: represents• tlves. ----·-------··-- ----·----------- ---------- ------------- . ------------ Textiles: Do• Bielefeld ••••••••••••••••••••• Agreement, ....................... Workers' repJan. 23, 1924. resentatives. Eastern SBXony ___ •••••••••• Award •••••••• After 54th. • ••••do •••••••• For 3 hours. Shorter working time on Saturday Industry or occupation Collective Time agreement or Saturarbitration daywork award to end Remarks p.m. Banking .•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••. Award ••••• ___ ····--·-·· Not more than 7 hours on Saturday, 3 Bats and millinery-Berlin. ____________ • ___ ····---·····----·-·Iron and steel works-Northwest Germany____ • Agreement •••.•••••••••• Saturday half holiday recommenae<i. For Saturday day shlft in Lignite coal mines-Central Germany.......... Award._ •••••• 4 continuous-operation con• cerns with 2 shifts. Metals-Wurttemberg and Hohenzollern ••••••. Agreement •••.•••••••••• Saturday half holiday. Textiles: Bielefeld.-•.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Agreement •••• ·····-···· 6 hours• work on Saturday. 1 Wurttemberg --·····-······················ ••••• do........ 2 Tobacco (chewing)-Thuringia •••••••••••••••.. --··--·-·······- lln day. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 120 CHAPTER V.-HOUBS OF LABOB TABL1143.-PBOVIBIONBOFOOLLEOTIVEAGBEEMENTBANDABBITRATIONAWABD8 MADE UNDER DEOREE OF DECEMBER 21, 1923, AB TO BPEOIFIED POINTB-Oonold. Dismissal of employees in consequence of ~tension of hours <>I labor Collective Industry agreement or arbitration Provision award Leather----------·····-·---·--·---·--Award.·-···-- Such discharges forbiddeD. Llgmte mining-···•···•···-·······---- ._ ...do........ Only unavoidable discharges, In case of 8110h discharge age, me of_family, and fixed residence to be CODS!dered and early notice given to em• pl0)'88; discharges to be dfstribuied between Jan. 2 and 1st of February and notice given to l>Ubllo employment exobaugea. Ore mlnlng-Mausfeld Joint Stock Co. • ••••do........ Do. Potash salts m!Dlng •••• -····-·-·-····· •••• _do_ ••••••• Bame provision 88 for lignite mlnee; also, dlscbarged workmen to be i:eengaged 88 soon 88 possible, SPARE-TIME WORK Spare-time work became vecy widespread in Germany after the introduction of the 8-hour day, but, o{ course, it played an important rOle only when overtime work was not abundant. Before the war German workers in general were not opposed to overtime work and even many trade-umon members were ready at any time to increase their e8.l'llings by overtime work. Opposition to overtime work emanated mainly from the most educated workers. In normal times German employers were not anxious for overtime work, because of the extra pay and the inferior quality of the work performed, but in very busy seasons these drawbacks did not count. Mter the war, when the demand for goods was vecy great while the hours of labor and efficiency of the workers were considerably reduced, the desire of employers for overtime work was vsyy keen. Real wages were so low tliat the extra pay for overtime did not cut any figure, and extension of the plants was difficult because of the scarcity of building materials and of machinecy. The workers had become accustomed to lo:ng hours of labor during the war and as they had obtained the 8-hour day suddenly, and more by political ac01dent than through an earnest struggle, those workers who had not previously been organized often did not mind wor~ overtime. Single workers living near their place of work often yieldecfbeca.use at first they did not know what to do with their spare time and married men often yielded because they were anxious to increase their low e ~ . The union leaders were, of course, opposed to overtime work and gradually the opposition to overtime work gained ground. Employers found it more and more difficult to induce their emJ>loyees to work overtime, and this was the main reason, at lea.st in the manufacture of finished products, why employers were anxious to obtain an alteration of the regulation of the hours of labor. Statistics of overtime work are not to be had. A most conspicuous example of the decrease of overtime work, which; however, can not be considered as tYJ)!cal, is furnished by a big electrical machinecy concern in Berlin. The management claims tliat the overtime hours worked in addition to each 100 regular hours were as follows: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 121 SPARE-TIME WORK Plant A Plant B 10.0 1914 ______________________________________________ 11.0 1913---------------------------------------------llO 9.0 20.2 1916 ______________________________________________ lfl3 lfl 7 1915---------------------------------------------1917______________________________________________ 15.2 18. 0 17.0 1918---------------------------------------------- ~• 11 1919______________________________________________ 1920---------------------------------------------.1 1921______________________________________________ .3 13. 8 .1 .2 .4 1922______________________________________________ .4 .7 Wherever there was no overtime work many workers did sparetime work, either in their own trade or in some other, partly for themselves and partly for some other employer. While spare-time work was done before the war, it was then confined mainly to occupations in which work was done· immediately for the consumer and with sim_ple tools. Mter the war, when hours of labor were reduced and real wages dropped, and the consumer, impoverished by inflation, was amnous to save every cent, spare-time work increased greatly. The craft guilds did their utmost to fight it, systematically persecuting spare-time workers and mercilessly denouncing them to the income tax officials, but with little effect. The union of building workers, for example, repeatedly and bitterly complained about the competition of railway men, who not only helped their friends to build cottages but also worked systematically four or :five hours a day for small contractors. Another form of spare-time work was that pe],"formed in order to obtain directly better and more ample food. Millions of workers in the cities rented small bits of land and-raised v~etables,, potatoes, etc., in their spare time. In the small towns, agnculturru work was carried on by industrial workers on a much larger scale, the em~loyers often directly favoring this spare-time work in order that the efficiency of their employees might be improved through better food. VACATIONS Before the revolution1 vacations (annual leave) were not usual for workers and few collective agreements contained a clause regulating this matter. But from 1919 on vacations became quite customary. The progress made since 1913 may perhaps best be gathered from the results of an inves_ti_gation covering_ the German metal industry, made by the German Metal Workers' Union. The number of agreements regulating vacations and the number of establishments and employees affected was as follows: TABLB 44.-NUMBER OF OOLLEOTIVE AGREEMENTS IN THE GERMAN METAL INDUSTRY REGULATING VAOATIONS, 1913 TO 1922 Year 1913 ••• ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• •••••••••• • ••••• • ••• ·- • ••••••• lllH •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• --- -· --•••• -- -- ••••••••• 1916. •••••••••••••••••• ·-·--- -··--····-··---· --- -- -•• -·---•••• • ••••• 1916•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1919•••••••• ·•••••• ··-····· ···--·· ··- ••••••• ··-- -·-·- ••••••• -·. ··- - • 1920••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.• 1921.-•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1922·-········-·-···-······························-················ https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Agree- ments 77 81 '19 73 673 968 1,065 1,079 Establish• Employees =::i covered 306 8,319 328 2411 111,372 10,959 357 24,985 28,474 46,272 7,727 7,725 1,251,200 1,602,976 1,856,337 2,768,814 122 CHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LABOR The Federal Statistical Office, in its analysis of collective agreements in force on December 31, 1920, found that about two-thirds of the agreements regulated vacations. By December 31, 1922, the proportion had increased to four-fifths, and as regulation of vacations was more frequent in agreements covering a large territory than in those concluded for a single establishment, the proportion of employees entitled to vacations through collective agreements. was. even larger than the proportion of agreements containing such provisions. By December 31, 1922, 92.7 per cent of the workers and 93.3 per cent of the salaried employees covered by collective agreements were entitled to vacations. The minimum duration of the .vacations agreed upon was generally less than 3 workdays for workers and between 3 and 6 workdays for salaried employees; the maximum was generally less than 12 workdays for workers and more than 12 workdays for salaried employees. Vacations, as a rule, were somewhat longer for women than for the employees as a wh?le. Table 45 shows the -pe! cent of_ ~reements re~ating vacations and the per cent proVIdmg for mm1mum and maximum vacations of a specified number of days, both for workers and salaried employees, Decembe~ 31, 1922: TABLE 46.-PER CENT OF COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS REGULATING VACATIONS AND PER CENT GRANTING MINIMUM AND MAXIMUM VACATIONS OF SPECI· FIED LENGTH AND OF ESTABLISBMENTSANDEMPLOYEESCOVEREDTHEREBY, DECEMBER 31, 1922 Workers' agreements Length or minimum and maximum vacations Agreements regulating vacations ••••• Minimum vacation: 3 days and under .••••••••••••••• Over 3 to 6 days ••••••••••••••••• Over 6 days •..••••••.•••••••••••• Maximum vacation: 6days and under ••••••••••••••••• Over 6 to 12 days.••...••••••••••• Over 12 to 18 days••••.••.•••••••• Over 18 days ••••••••••••••••••••• Salarled employees' agreements Workers Employees Estab•· Estabcovered. covered Agree- lish• Agree• Jfsh• ments ments ments ments covered Total Female covered Total Femal,e 80.1 90.4 92. 7 93.4 89.9 97.5 93.3 9S. 5 54. 5 38. 0 7.5 54. 3 37. 7 8.0 63.8 38. 6 7.6 49.5 40.1 to.4 1.7 76. 2 22.1 82. 6 0.9 0. 7 72. 9 0.6 74.3 25.1 3L9 42.0 20.1 6.0 4L3 31.1 20. 9 6. 7 29.1 40. 7 35. 3 13. 9 10.1 2.1 11.8 64.1 22.0 3.1 65.4 Ll .1 2.4 48.4 49.1 44. 2 13. 3 13.4 16. 5 4.6 26.9 26.4 3. 5 53. 0 42.4 The granting of vacations is conditioned as a rule on a minimum length of service in the establishment and the vacation is often graded according to the length of this service. In some cases the employee m~t also have reached a definite age (mostly 17 years). Agreements often contain the provision that, in order to avoid inconvenience to the employer, no vacations shall be taken in certain periods of the year. Sometimes, as for example in the collective agreements for the coal mines of Upper Silesia, it is stipulated that not more than 5 per cent of those entitled to vacations shall take them at the same time. A special regulation of vacations is found in the building trades (including stone paving). The requirement of a minimum length of service in the shop, prevailing in the other branches of industry, would in these trades mean too great a hardship for the employee, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 123 VA.CATIONS who because of the nature of the industry must often change employers through no fault of his own. On the other hand, it constitutes a burden on the employer to grant _paid vacations to employees whom he has perhaps employed for onfy a short while. To overcome these difficulties, "vacation funds" have been created for separate district.s, into which each employer of the trade in question pays a contribution. These funds then provide the money for the vacations granted to the workers of that trade, and also sometimes assist the workers in case of unemployment in winter, of sickness, and of leave of absence from an unusual cause. As examples of these vacation funds may be quoted the benefits granted by the following funds of the stone-paving trade: D7!8aeldorf-Bochum agreement of March 7, 1921 1. Six days' vacation. 2. Indemnity equivalent to one day's earnings for working time lost through births and deaths within the family (parents, consort, children, and parentsin-law who belong to the household of the employee). 3. Indemnity in case of sickness of the employee exceeding one week. Hamburg agreement of February 10, 19ee 1. Assistance in winter time. 2. Payment for vacation. The employee can choose either of these two forms of assistance, but can not receive both the same year. Brunswick-Goslar agreement of January 28, wee 1. Six days' vacation. 2. H the worker is unable to work for personal reasons, without his fault, or because of a birth, death, or sickness within his family, he receives indemnity not exceeding one day's wages for the lost working time. Leipzig agreement of June 1, wet 1. In case of sickness, the worker getsanindemnityforthedays (waitingperiod) for which he is not indemnified by the national sick insurance fund. 2. In case of a birt)l or a death within his immediate family, the worker receives an indemnity not exceeding one day's wages. 3. In case of unemployment in winter the worker receives a supplement to his unemployment allowanca for eight weeks. 4. Six days' vacation, which, however, is granted only in case the worker does not claim assistance under clause 1, 2, or 3. Special provision is made in the case of an employee who leaves the district covered by a vacation fund without having enjoyed it.s benefits. The by-laws of the vacation funds of the stone-J>aving trade of Bielefeld~ Dusseldorf-Bochum, Hamburg, Lubeck, Bonn, Coblenz, Brunswic.ir-Goslar, and Leipzig stipulate that if an employee leaves the district without having taken his vacation, the unexpended sum shall be transferred to the fund of the district where he finds employment. The by-laws of some funds, moreover, provide that if an employee quits his trade (e. g., on account of complete disabilit:y) without having drawn on the fund, he may receive an indemmty equal to a specified per cent of the benefits to which he was entitlea. Statistics as to the effect of the granting of vacations upon the yearly working time of employees are not available. Two statements, both from employers, may be mentioned for what they are worth. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 124 CHAPTER V.-HOURS OF LABOR At the end of 1920 the German Railway Ministry estimated that on account of the extension of vacations as compared with pre-war times, it had to employ an additional force of 26,517 (with a total force of about 1,000,000). The average yearly days of work per employee in the railway repair shops are stated to have been reduced from 300 to 280 on account of the extension of vacations. The ministry also complained of the increase in sick leave due to the fact that at that time employees, if absent for more than three days, were obliged only to present a physician's certificate. A large electrical machinery concern in 1907 granted a vacation of six days a year to male workers over 30 years old who had been emf)loyed more than eight years in the establishment, and to female workers over 25 years who had over five years' service. The average number of vacat10n days per worker was then 0.86 f9r male workers, 0.14 for female workers, and 0.63 for all workers. The progressive extension of vacations by collective agreement after the war resulted in average vacation days per worker in 1920 of 3.9 and in 1922 of 5.2. The days of sick leave per male emJ>loyee rose from 8.97 in 1913 to 11.57 in 1921 and such days per female employee from 16.64 to 31.31. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Chapter VI.-WAGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LABOR GENERAL TREND OF REAL WAGES Before the war there was no country in continental Europe that had higher nominal or real wages than Germany, only British, American, and Australian workers enjoying a better living than German workers. Immediately after the outbreak of the war nominal wages of many workers, and especially female workers, in Germany decreased, although.cost of living increased-a consequence of the great unemployment which then prevailed. This was the case for workers employed in mines, stone quarries, and the electric, chemical, textile, leather, clothing, and printing industries, while workers employed in metal working, woodworkin~, and the machinery-, paper, and food industries at once received higher wages than m peace times. In the course of the war nominal wages increased in all mdustries, but real wages probably increased only in the war industries proper. There doubtless occurred a decrease of real wages for miners, stonecutters, textile workers, leather workers, printers, and in the food industries, this decrease being on the whole larger for men than for women. It was especially large for Government and municipal employees, whose nommal wages were not raised before 1918 and very little then. It is impossible to give statistics on real wages, as statistics on the cost of living before 1919 are not available. Table 46 shows for Greater Berlin the nominal weekly wages of bricklayers and of printers as fix~d by collective agreement, and the weekly mmimum cost of subsistence for a married couple with two children from 6 to 10 years of age, for 1913-14, and for each month from January, 1920, to December, 1924. From July to December, 1923, when, on account of the depreciation of the currency, wages changed very of ten, fig11res are shown for each fortnight. The bricklayers receive no family allowance, but the printers receive an allowance if they are married. TABLE 46.-WEEKLY WAGES OF BRICKLAYERS AND OF PRINTERS IN BERLIN AND MINIMUM COST OF SUBSISTENCE, AND INDEX NUMBERS THEREOF, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924 (1913-14-1) Wages of bricklayers Wages of printers Month Amount Index numbers Mark8 1913-14..........•.... 41.82 157. 96 185. 09 204. 70 253. 35 265. 03 299 312. 80 312. 80 312. 80 312. 80 312. 80 312. 80 20168"-25t-9 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Index numbers Mark8 1 1920 January.•.••••••••••• February •••••••••••• March ••••••••••••••. April ••••••••••••••••• May ••••••••••••••••• June ••••••••••••••••• July.••••••••••••••••• August••••••••••••••• September ••••••••••• October..••••••.••.•• November ••••••••••• Decemher ••.••••.•••. Amount 3.8 4. 4 4. 9 6.1 6.3 7. 1 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.5 7.11 34.38 160. 50 160.50 160.50 160. 50 210.50 235.50 248. 83 250.50 250. 50 250. 50 270.50 270. 50 Minimum cost of subsist• ence of married couple with two children --Amount Index numbers Marks 1 4. 7 4. 7 4. 7 4. 7 6. 1 6. 8 7.2 7.3 7.3 7.3 7.9 7.9 1 28.80 220 7. 7 8 11. 2 13.0 12. 7 10.6 ll3 10. 7 10.4 ll0 11.0 11.3 s. 254 322 375 365 304 324 308 299 318 316 327 125 126 CHAPTER VI.-WAGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LABOR TABLE 46.-WEEKLY WAGES OF BRICKLAYERS AND OF PRINTERS IN BERLIN AND MINIMUM COST OF SUBSISTENCE, AND INDEX NUMBERS THEREOF, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924-Concluded Wages of bricklayers Wages of printers Minimum cost of subsistence of married couple with two children Month Amount 1921 January ______________ February_ •• _________ March. ______________ April _________________ May _________________ June_--------------July __________________August _______________ September ___________ October ______________ November •• _________ December____________ 1922 January ______________ February. ___________ March. _____________ • April ••••• ____________ May. ________________ June.·------------·-July __________________ August _______________ September ___________ October··-----------November.------·--December•••••.•.•.. _ Marka 312. 80 322. 86 324. 30 324. 30 324.30 324. 30 332. 79 356. 24 377. 38 427. 80 458. 14 547.31 7.5 7. 7 7. 7 7. 7 7. 7 7. 7 8. 0 8. 5 9.0 10. 2 11.0 13.1 586.06 621 715. 56 966 1,196 1,472 1,692 2,008.67 3,552.62 5,052.92 7,985.60 14,950 14. 0 14.8 17.1 23.1 28. 6 35. 2 40. 5 48.0 85.0 ll'JJ.8 191.0 357. 5 1923 January ______________ February_____________ March.·-·------·---April ___________ • _____ May _________________ 22,572 48,300 69,283 78,660 89,634 185,344 June_---------------· July 1-15_____________ 536,443 July 16-31.. •••••••• __ 1,077,852 Aug. 1-15____________ 6,203,813 Aug. 16-31.. _________ !2, 569,207 Sept. 1-15. ___________ 1131. 8 Sept. 16-30___________ 1 998. 2 Oct. 1-15_____________ 18,040.4 Oct. 16-31.. __________ 1 334,213. 7 Nov. 1-15 ____________ 2 5,789.6 Nov. 16-30••• ________ 1 28,116 Dec. 1-15 •.•• ________ • 32. 44 Dec. 16-31.. _________ a 32. 44 Rentenmarka 1924 January______________ 29.20 29.20 29.64 April_ ___ •••••• __ •• ___ 37.19 39.39 May--······--------June _________________ 39.39 July __________________ 39.39 August _______________ 39.39 September ___________ 39. 39 October ______________ 44.49 November ••••.••••.. 44.49 December•••••••••••• 44.49 r:t~":~-_-::::::::::: 1 Millions. Index numbers •Billions. Amount Marka 270.50 285. 50 285. 50 285. 50 285.,'iO 285. 50 285.50 295.88 321. 26 393. 88 418 533. 56 553 613 642. 63 773 933 1,093 1,393 1,638.19 2,622.23 4,345.31 7,337.24 12, 773 537. 7 20,769 1154. 9 43,125 1656. 7 69,606 lSSO. 9 72,141 2143. 3 86,350 4431. 9 199,690 12829. 8 441,000 25773.6 925,714 148346 6,534,615 1017915 39,784,143 1 100. 2 3151129 1 23. 9 1 675 1192.2 17,269.2 17991. 7 13,~m_4 1 138. 4 1 672.3 1 24,200 127 . 78 127 •. 78 • •.70 ••.• 7170 .89 ••.94 ••.94 . 94 •.94 • • 94 • 1.06 • 1. 06 • 1.06 Index numbers 7.9 8. 3 8. 3 8. 3 8. 3 8. 3 8. 3 8. 6 9.3 11. 5 12. 2 15. 5 16.1 17.8 18. 7 22. 5 27.1 31.8 40.5 47. 6 76. 3 126.4 213. 4 371.5 • Rentenmarks. •.79 •. 79 •.79 1 .87 •.92 •.98 .98 •.98 .98 •• 98 '1.16 • 1.16 • • Index numbers Marks 320 313 298 281 285 311 324 339 349 386 . 11.1 10. 9 10. 3 9.8 9.9 557 lo.8 11.2 11.8 12.1 13.4 17. 7 19.3 548 627 789 915 995 1,195 1,.763 2,958 4,714 7,508 16,271 24,994 19.0 21.8 27.4 31.8 34. 5 41. 5 61.2 102. 7 163. 7 260. 7 565.0 867.9 509 604.1 37,167 1254. 4 81,039 71,121 2024.6 74,772 2098. 3 2511. 6 121,921 5808. 3 252,582 12827. 2 688,589 26926 1,201,751 9,245, ()89 190070 1157189 24,622,120 1170.6 2913143 1 683. 3 119.6 1 7,104.9 1211.4 19307.8 1 266,556 • 4,498.8 ' 128. 4 1 703.9 I 35,651.6 •33.04 •. 79 •.79 • 28. 73 Rentenmaru 27 27 27.23 30.00 31.47 33.60 33.60 33.60 33. 60 33.60 40.00 40.00 Amount 129Q. 5 2813. 8 2608.4 2596. 3 4233. 4 8770.2 23909.4 41727. 5 321031 854935 5924323 1 23. 7 1 246. 7 1 9255. 4 I 156. 2 • 1237. 9 '1.15 Rentenmarka 27. 74 26. 55 26. 91 28.49 29.29 28.43 29.28 28. 81 29. 76 31. 30 31. 22 31.13 '1.00 •••• 9692 •.93 •.99 '1.02 •.99 • 1. 02 '1.00 •1.03 • 1.00 •1.os '1.08 • Based on rentenmarks. The weekly wages of the Berlin bricklayers-which have been calculated by taking into account the working time fixed by agreement for the various periods of the year and by multiplying the hourly wages of pre-war time by 51 and those paid after the war by https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis GENERAL TREND OF REAL WAGES 127 46-amounted before the war to $9.96 (41.82 marks). In January, 1920, at the exchange rate they were but $2.44 (157.96 marks), and in February not more than $1.87 (185.09 marks). They then rose to $7.92 in July, but dropped again to $4.05 in November and amounted to $4.29 in December. In 1921 they varied between $1.74 in November and $5.27 in February, in 1922 between $1.11 in November and $4.63 in June, and in the first seven months of 1923 between $1.26 in January and $3.22 in April. From August to November wages and dollar quotations changed so often that no comP.arison seems possible. From November 21, 1923 (after the stabilization of the mark), to January 1, 1924, wages amounted to $7.73; from ,January 2 to March 25, 1924, to $6.95; from March 26 to April 8 to $7.50; from April 9 to September 30 to $9.38; and since October 1, to $10.59. Calculated in dollars, wages in 1920 were from 19 to 80 per cent of what they had been in pre-war times; in 1921 from 18 to 53 })er cent; in 1922 from 11 to 47 per cent; in the first seven months of 1923, from 13 to 32 per cent; in December, 1923, 78 per cent; in January and February, 1924, 70 per cent; in March, 1924, 71 per cent; in April, 1924, 89 per cent; from May to September, 1924, 94 per cent; and since October, 1924, 106 per cent. Before the war the weekly wages of bricklayers were 45 per cent higher than the minimum cost of subsistence of a family of 4 persons. In the year 1920 they were 13 per cent lower than the minimum; in 1921, 4 per cent higher; in the first half of 1922, 10 per cent higher; in the third quarter, 23 per cent lower; in the fourtli quarter, 43 per cent lower; in the first quarter of 1923, 26 per cent lower; and in the second quarter, 21 per cent lower. In the following months fluctuations were so phantastic that a computation of averages would be misleading. In the first half of August, for example, wages were 33 per cent lower and in the second half of August, 73 per cent higher than the minimum cost of subsistence; in the first half of September they were 23 per cent lower and in the second half 46 per cent higher. A clear relation between wages and the minimum cost of subsistence prevailed only toward the end of the year, after the stabilization of the mark. In December, 1923, and in January, 1924, wages were 5 per cent higher than the minimum cost of subsistence, in February and March they were 10 per cent higher, in the second and third quarters 35 per cent higlier, and in the fourth quarter 43 per cent hig!:ler. The weekly wages of married printers over 24 years old-since 1919 the printers receive an allowance for the wife, but no children's allowance-at the exchange rate amounted before the war (with a working time of 53 hours) to $8.19 (34.38 marks), and in January, 1920 (with a working time of 48 hours) to only $2.48 (160.5 marks). Their wages decreased further to $1.62 in February, increased to $6.30 in July, dropped to $3.50 in November, and amounted to $3.71 in December. In 1921 they varied between $1.59 in November and $4.66 in February; in 1922, between $1.02 in November and $3.44 in June; in the first seven months of 1923, between $1.16 in January and $3.28 in March. From August to November a computation of wages in dollars is impossible. From November 21, 1923, to March 28, 1924, the weekly wages amounted to $6.43; from March 29 to May 2, to $7.14; from May 3 to 30, to $7.50; from May 31 to October 31, to $8, and from November 1 on to $9.52. Calculated in dollars, wages https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 128 OHA.PTER VI.-WAGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LABOR in 1920 were from 20 to 77 per cent of what they had been in pre-war times; in 1921 from 19 to 57 per cent; in 1922 from 12 to 42 per cent; in the :first seven months of 1923 from 14 to 40 per cent; from December, 1923, to March, 1924, 79 per cent; in April, 1924, 87 per. cent; in May, 1924, 92 !!._er cent; from June to October, 1924, 98 per cent; in November and December, 1924, 116 per cent. · Before -the war the weekly wages of printers were 19 per cent higher than the minimum cost of subsistence. In the year 1920 they were 30 per cent lower than that minimum; in the year 1921, 8 per cent lower; in the :first half of 1922, 9 per cent lower; in the. third quarter, 40 per cent lower; in the fourth quarter, 50 per cent lower; in the :first quarter of 1923, 31_per cent lower; in the second quarter, 20 per cent lower. In the following months the same tops:r-tµrvy con<litions prevailed as with the bricklayers. In the :first half of August, for example, wages were 29 per cent lower than the minimum cost of subsistence, while in the second half therwere 62 per cent higher. In December, 1923, wages were 12 per cent lower than the mmimum cost of subsistence; in the :first quarter of 1924, they were just as high as the minimum cost of subsistence; in the second quarter, 10 per cent higher; in the third quarter, 15 per cent higher; and in the fourth q_uarter, 21 per cent higher. The wages of bncklayers, which before the war had been 45 per cent ~her than the minimum cost of subsistence, were lower tlian that minimum in 28 of the 60 months under considerti,tion (January, 1920, to December, 1924). The wages of printers, which before the war exceeded the minimum cost of subsistence by 19 per cent, did not reach it in 43 months; they exceeded it only in April, Ma.Y, and October, 1921, January, 1922, August and October, 1923, and February to December, 1924. The real wages of bricklayers were not even half as bkh as before the war in January, Marcli, AJ>ril, and May, 1920, in August, 1922, and from October, 1922, to February,1923.; they were more than.three-fourths as !ugh only in ~pril, May, ana October, 1921, in May and June, 1922, m -August, September, and October 1923, and from February to December, l924. The real wages of printers, which 10 yea.rs ag~ were much lower than those of bricklayers, were not even lialf as high as before the war in March, April, and May, 1920, and from A~t, 1922, to Febru&.rY,, 1923; tliey were more than tbree-fourths as high from February to June, in September, October, and December, 1921, in January, February, ana May, 1922, in April, August, and October, 1923, and since January, 1924. In no month from January, 1920, to October, 1924, were real w~es of bricklayers or printers higher than in pre-war times. · AB a matter of comparison may be quoted the real weekly wages for Germany computed by the Federal Statistical Office, weighted averages of the wages of miners, building workers, woodworkers metal workers, textile workers, and factory workers in the chemicd and paper industries, ·printers, and Government workers being divided by the cost-of-living index. It must, of course, be home in mind that such weighted averages a.re only approximately coITeet, and that the official cost-of-living index includes only cost of food, housing, fuel, light, and· clothing. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 129 GENERAL TREND OF REAL WAGES TAllLB 4.7.-BEAL WEEKLY WAGES OF SKILLED AND UNSKILLED WORKERS IN THE trimt~IflL GERMAN INDUSTRIES, APRIL, 1922, TO SEPTEMBER, 1924, BY [1913-100) Skilled workers Year and month Amount 1913_______________________________________ _ l92'J-tu~-:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: October _________________________________________ _ 1923-J'anuary ---------------------------------------- .Marki 35.02 25.17 25.03 19. 20 17.05 f:~ ::::::::::. ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: tfa1-:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ;rune ____________________________________________ _ luly ·-----------------------------------------Augulll: ---------------------------------------- 22.23 October _________________________________________ _ September_------------------------------------- 21.42 18.22 November __ ------------------------------------192i-1auuary December.• ______________________________________ .--------------------------------------_ 18.66 24.53 25.34 :::r~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: tfat-::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: August. _________________________________________ _ luly -------------------------------------------·September _____________________________ _ lune ____________________________________________ _ 27.57 25.96 22.80 22. 79 16. 80 Zl.52 26.811 27.17 27.93 29.52 31.26 30.86 3L29 30.52 Index numbers UDllkllled workers Amount Index numbers .Marki 100. 0 71.9 7L5 M.8 48. 7 63.6 78. 7 74. 1 65.1 65.1 48.0 67.2 61.2 52.0 53.3 70. 1 73.8 78.3 79.1 8L3 85.9 91.0 89.8 91.1 88.9 24.31 22. 71 22. 79 17.19 16.45 19.98 24. 79 23.34 20.46 20.42 16. 06 2LOO 19.02 16. 74 16.04 20. 66 21.22 22.07 2L65 2L64 22.88 23.90 23.59 23.93 23.32 100.0 93.4 93.8 70. 7 63.6 82.2 102.0 96.0 84.2 84.0 62.0 86.4 78. 2 64.8 66.0 85.0 88.4 92.0 90.2 90.2 116.3 119.6 118.3 99. 7 117. 2 Table 48 shows for Greater Berlin the nominal yearly salaries of bank helpers (Group 1), bank clerks doing simple work (Group 2), and banJr clerks domg responsible work (Group 3), as fixed by collective agi:eement, and the minimum cost of suosistence for a married couple with two children from 6 to 10 years, for 1913-14, and for each month from Febru~, 1920, to December, 1924. AB no collective agreement was in force before August 1, 1920, the figures for 1913 represent aver~e actual e ~ , and those from February to JulyL 1920, the salanes uniformly fixed b~he banks. The salaries 01 the bank employees are graaed accor · to years of service. They receive allowances for wife and each chil , and a bonus at Christmas. The table gives the salaries (including bonuses) in each group for married bank employees in their tenth year of service, with two children of 6 to 10 years. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis CHAPTER VI_.-W AGES AND :SFFICIENCY OF LABOR 130 48-YEARLY SALARIES OF MARRIED BANK EMPLOYEES IN BERLIN, WITlJ TWO CHILDREN, AND MINIMUM COST OF SUBSISTENCE, AND INDEX NUMBERS THEREOF, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924 TABLE [1913-14= lj Minimum cost of subsistence Group 3 Group 2 Group 1 Month Amount Index numbers Index numbers Amount Amount Index numbers Amount Index numbers --1913-14 _______ Marks 2,165 1920 January ______ February ____ March _______ April _________ May--------June _________ July __________ August _______ September ___ October ______ November ___ December ____ Marks Marks 1 3,525 1 3,210 Marks 1 ----------4. 1 1,502 1 7. 7 5. 8 5. 9 5. 9 5.9 5.9 7.5 7. 5 7. 5 7. 5 7. 5 14,000 14,000 14,200 14,200 14,200 14,200 18,120 18,120 18,120 18,120 18,120 4. 4 4. 4 4.4 4. 4 4.4 4.4 5. 6 5. 6 5. 6 5.6 5. 6 14,500 14, 700 14,700 14,700 14, 700 18,620 18,620 18,620 18,620 18,620 4.1 4.2 4.2 4. 2 4.2 5. 3 5. 3 5.3 5.3 5,3 11,500 13,250 16, 750 19,550 19,000 15,850 16,900 16,050 15,550 16,550 16,450 17,050 8. 8 11.2 13.0 12. 7 10.6 11. 3 10. 7 10.4 11.0 11.0 11.3 19,944 19,944 19,944 19,944 19,944 19,944 27, 704 27, 704 27,704 27, 704 27,704 27, 704 9.2 9. 2 9.2 9. 2 9.2 9.2 12. 8 12. 8 12. 8 12.8 12. 8 12. 8 22,248 22,248 22,248 22,248 22,248 22,248 30,008 30,008 30,008 30,008 30,008 30,008 6. 9 6.9 6.9 6. 9 6.9 6. 9 9.3 9.3 9.3 9. 3 9,3 9.3 22,848 22,848 22,848 22,848 22,848 22,848 30,608 30,608 30,608 30, e-os 30,608 30,608 6. 5 6. 5 6.5 6. 5 6. 5 6. 5 8. 7 8. 7 8. 7 8. 7 8. 7 8. 7 16, 700 16,350 15, 550 14,650 14,850 16,250 16,900 17, 700 18,200 20,150 26,550 29,050 11.1 10.9 10. 3 9.8 9.9 10.8 11.2 11.8 12.1 13. 4 17. 7 19.3 January ______ 39,184 February ____ 43,384 March _______ 46,984 April__ _______ 58,804 May _________ 58,804 June _________ 64,358 July __________ 90,577 August__ _____ 176,373 September ___ 217,236 October ______ 370,993 November ___ 612,528 December ____ 1,039,081 18.1 20.0 21. 7 27. 2 27. 2 29. 7 41.8 81. 5 100. 3 171.4 282. 9 479. 9 41,488 45,688 49,288 61, 757 61,757 67,691 94,997 185, 121 230,312 394,295 649,296 1,093,474 12. 9 14. 2 15. 4 19. 2 19. 2 21.1 29.6 57. 7 71.1 122.8 202. 3 340.6 42,088 46,288 49,888 62,522 62,522 68,554 96,137 187,389 233,695 400,321 658,822 1,107,549 11. 9 13.1 14. 2 17. 7 17. 7 19. 4 27.3 53. 2 66.3 113. 6 186. 9 314. 2 28,600 32, 700 41,200 47,700 51,900 62,350 91,950 154,350 245,850 391,650 848,800 1,303,900 12,500 12,500 12, 700 12, 700 12, 700 12, 700 16,200 16,200 16,200 16,200 16,200 1921 January ______ February ____ March _______ u,rn _________ ay _________ June _________ July __________ August_ ______ September ___ October ______ November ___ December ____ 1922 1923 January ______ February _____ March ________ April__ _______ May--------June _________ July __________ August _______ September ___ October ______ November ___ December ____ 1924 January ______ February_____ March _______ April__ _______ May _________ 1une _________ 1,653,060 3,833, 721 4,607,444 4,745,919 7,808, 718 18,346, 114 1115.4 1930.4 I 38,391.6 2 4,930.5 I 996, 777 '1,969 ----------5.8 763, 5 1,750,992 4,064,820 1770. 8 4,874,062 2128. 1 5,019,856 2192. 1 8,362,052 3606. 8 8474. 0 19,689,920 1 124. 4 53284. 5 1 1,003.0 429740 I 46,552.3 I 17. 8 I 6,058.4 I 2272. 8 2 460.4 '1,224,823 '2,484 .82 ' Rentenmarks July __________ August _______ September ___ October ______ November_ __ December____ 2,011 2,011 2,362 2,449 2,449 2,426 2,592 2,592 2,592 2,592 2,592 2,703 I Millions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis - ----------- • .93 • .93 • 1.09 • 1.13 • 1.13 • L 12 • I. 20 '1.20 • 1.20 'l. 20 • 1.20 '1.25 •Billions. 1,874,640 545. 5 4,358,424 1266. 3 5,212,770 1518. 4 5,370,434 1563. 8 9,048,184 2605. 0 6133. 9 21,356, 271 1135. 5 38745. 3 11,093. l 312468 I 54,935.8 I 14. 5 I 1887. 3 '7,190.3 1 1,453,666 2 381.6 3 2,600 • 71 ' 1,938,900 531. 8 4,227,600 1236. 4 3,918,850 1478. 8 1523. 5 3,900,600 6,360,200 2566. 9 6058. 5 13,176,350 38450. 4 49,408,050 1 886. 7 310097 122,291.4 IJ5.6 I 2039, 8 '7,529. 7 21,047,256 I 412. 4 3 1,609 •, 74 Renten- Rentenmarks 2,448 2,448 2,799 2,900 2,900 2,873 3,084 3,084 3,084 3,084 3,084 3,224 14,500 ' ''• •• • • Rentenmurks. 2,906 2,906 3,257 3,409 3,409 3,377 3,639 3,639 3,639 3,639 3,639 3,812 31. 8 34. 5 41.5 61. 2 102. 7 163. 7 260. 7 565.0 867.9 1290. 5 2813. 8 2608. 4 2596. 3 -4233. 4 8770.2 32886. l 590170 Rentenmarks marks •. 76 '. 76 .87 •• 90 •.90 .89 • 96 . 96 . 96 . 96 . 96 '1.00 19.0 21.8 27.4 •.82 •.82 '.92 •. 97 •. 97 .96 '1.03 '1. 03 '1.03 • 1.03 '1.03 • 1. 08 ' 1,447 1,385 1,404 1,486 1,528 1,483 1,527 1,503 1,552 1,633 1,629 1,624 • Based on rentenmarks. 1 14.8 15011.8 2 697.1 • 1.07 • 96 . 92 ••.93 '•. 99 '1.02 ' .99 'l. 02 • 1.00 '1.03 '1.09 '1.08 '1.08 GENERAL TREND OF REAL WAGES 181 The averaie yearly salary- of Berlin bank helpers (in their tenth year of service) amounted, before the war, to $516 (2,165 marks) . .According to the rates fixed by the banks from February, 1920, on, the yearly salary of such helpers (including allowances for wife and two children) at the dollar exchange rate was only $126 in Februa.ry ($10.50 per month). It rose to $325 in June and was $322 in July. At that time the employees succeeded in obtaining a collective agreement by which their yea!'lY nominal wages, wliich had been 12,500 marks in February and March, and 12 700 marks from April to July, were increosed to 16,200 marks for the last five months of the year. But as the dollar exchange had already risen considerably in August and rose still more in the following months, the yearly salary of bank helpers, calculated in dollars, was not more than $339 in August, droppmg in November to $210. In 1921, the yearly salary varied between $105 in November and $361 in July; in 1922 between $85 in November and $209 in February; in 1923 between $92 in January and $469 in December. It was $479 in January and February, 1924, $562 in March, $583 in April and May, $578 in June, $617 from July to November, and $644 in December. Salaries, calculated in dollars1 were thus in 1920 from 24 to 66 per cent of what they had been m pre-war times; in 1921 from 20 to 70 per cent; in 1922 from 16 to 41 per cent; in 1923 from 18 to 91 per cent; in January and February, 1924, 93 per cent; in March, 109 per cent; in April and May, 113 per cent; in June, 112 per cent; from July to November 120 per cent; and in December, 125 per cent. Before the war the average yearly salary of bank helpers was 44 per cent higher than the minimum cost of subsistence of a family of four persons (i. e., their salary was equal to the wages of bricklayers, but they had the advantage of being, as a rule, employed all the year round). In the year 1920 (February to December), their sala:rr was 19 per cent lower than that minimum; in 1921, 28 per cent higher; in the first half of 1922, 18 per cent higher; in the third quarter, 2 per cent lower; in the fourth quarter, 21 per cent lower; in the first quarter of 1923, as high as the minimum cost of subsistence; in the second quarter, 32 per cent higher; in July, 1923, 133 per cent higher; in August, 1923, 5 per cent higher; in September, 1923, 72 per cent higher; in October, 1923, 35 per cent lower; in November, 1923, 5 per cent lower. From December, 1923, on, it always exceeded that minimum-in December, by- 22 per cent, in January, 1924, by 39, in February by 45, in March by 68, in the second quarter of 1924 by 63 per cent, in the third quarter by 70 per cent, and in the fourth quarter by 61 per cent. The average yearly salary of the Berlin bank clerks (in their tenth year of service) doing responsible work (those doing simple work, of course, have a smaller income) amounted before the war to $839 (3,525 marks). According to the rates fixed by the banks from February, 1920, on, the yearly salary of such clerks (including allowances for wife and two children) at the exchange rate was only $146 in Februfl.ry ($12.20 per month). It rose to $376 in June and was $372 in July. The collective agreetnent which went into force on .August 1 did not help these clerks much, as the dollar exchange rate rose at the same time; in November their salary dr~ped to $241. In 1921 their yearly salary varied between $116 in November and $399 in July; in 1922, between $92 in November and $223 in Febru- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 132 CHAPTER VI.-WAGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LABOR ary; in 1923, between $104 in January and $663 in November. It amounted to $619 in December, 1923, $692 in January and February, 1924, $776 in March, $812 in April and May, $807 in June, $886 from July to November, and $908 in December. Salaries calculated in dollars were thus in 1920 from 17 to 45 per cent of what they had been 'in pre-war times; in 1921 from 14 to 48 per cent; in 1922 from 11 to 27 per cent; in 1923 from 12 to 79 per cent; in January and Febru!',ry, 1924, 82 per cent; in March, 92 per cent; and in A_pril and May, 97 per centb·in June, 96 per cent, from J-qly to November, 103 per cent; and in ecember, 108 _per cent. Before the war the average yearly salary of bank clerks doing responsible work was 135 per cent higher than the minimum cost of suosistence for a family of four persons. In 1920, which was one of the most prosperous years German banks ever had, the sal~ of bank clerks doing responsible work did not quite reach the minimum cost of subsistence for a. family of four persons, but lagged a.bout 1 per cent behind. In 1921 theu- salary was 44 per cent liigher than that minimum; in the first half of 1922 it was 25 per cent higher; in the third quarter 5 per cent higher; in the fourth quarter, in spite of a great boom in banking business, it was 15 per cent lower. In the first quarter of 1923 it was 13 per cent higher; in the second _qua.rter 53 per cent higher; in July, 1924, 174 per cent higherj in .August, 24 per cent higher; in September, 146 per cent higher; m October, 5 per cent lower; in November, 39 per cent higher; in December,. 62 per cent higher. In the twelve months of 1924, salaries exceeded the minimum cost of subsistence by 101, 110, 132.z. 129, 123, 128, 138, 142, 134, 123, 123, and 134 per cent, successively. The salary of bank helpers, which before the war had been 44 J>er cent higher than the minimum cost of subsistence, was lower than that minimum in 18 of the 59 months under consideration (Febru&.!"Y, 1920 to December, 1924). The salary of bank clerks doing responsible work, which before the war exceeded the minimum cost of subsistence by 135 per cent, did not even reach this minimum in 10 months (March to July, 1920, September, November,· and De-· cember 1922, January and October, 1923). The real salary of bank helpers was less than half as ~has before the war in April and May, 1920, and in October, 1923; 1t was higher than before the war m July, August, and September, 1921, in July and September, 1923, and from and after February, 1924. The real salary of bank clerks doing responsible work was less than half as }mzh as before the war from February to August, 1920 (in A_pril and 'Ma;y: less than onethird as high): from October to December, 1920, in December, 1921, in June and July, 1922, from September, 1922, to February, 1923 (in November, 1922 less than one-third as high), and in October, 1923; it was higher than before the war in July and September, 1923, and from July, 1924 on. . In conside~ these figures it must always be borne in mind that a computation of real wages in times of rapid inflation can never lead to exact results. When a concern for some reason had no cash on hand on a certain day with which to pay wages-and this happened very often since the Reichsbank was unable to print the necessary notes (whose nominal value always rose) quickly enollf:h-the workers who got their wages a day later than their colleagues m a neighboring concern received real wages perhaps 20 per cent less. Moreonr, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 188 GENERAL TREND OF REAL WAGES monthly, fortnightly, and even weekly indexes of cost of livi~ cover far too long_ periods when cost of livmg doubles or trebles within a week. Real wages therefore changed much more than mi~ht be concluded from Tables 46 and 48. Some light on actual conditions will be thrown by Table 49, which shows the nominal wages and the trend·of real wages of skilled and unskilled workers in tne Berlin chemical industry: from October 1 to November 15, 1923, each pa1, day (that observed by most of the large establishments) being considered separately and the cost-of-living index, ascertained by the Federal Statistical Office on Mondays, being assumed to increase each day within the week by the same percentage. It will be seen that the skilled worker, who before the war received 38.88 marks per week, got on October 1, 1923, 500,000,000 marks and on October 5i 861,000,000 marks. He then had to live on those 500,000,000 marks four days. As the cost-of-living index for those four days was 49228909, the real value of those 500,000,000 marks was then 10.16 marks. As in prewar times he earned 38.88 marks per week and thus had 22.22 marks to spend in four days, his real wages from October 1 to October 4, 1924, were 45. 7 per cent of what they were in pre-war times. In the following three days, from October 5 to October 7, he made 861,000,000 marks, which constituted 61 per cent of his real wages before the war. At other times his real wages were much lower. The billion marks which he received on October 13 and which had to last him three days were worth only 9.2 per cent of his real wages in pre-war times. It is interesting to note that unskilled workers who before the war received 27 marks per week received on pay days when a lump sum was disbursed to the skilled workers (500,000,000, 1,000,000,000, 1001qQO,OOO,OOO, and 500,000,000,000 marks) just as much as those skilled workers, while on other pay days they, of course, got less. This also shows the arbitrary state of wage conditions and the difficulty of reducing them to statistical form. TABLB 49.-NOMINAL WAGES AND INDEX NUMBERS OF REAL WAGES OF CHEMI• CAL WORKERS IN BERLIN, OCTOBER 1 TO NOVEMBER 15, 1923 Index numbers of real wages (1914- Nominal wages Payday 11123 Oct. 1. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Oct. 5 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•••••• Oct. 8•••••••••••••••••••••.••••••••••••• Oct. 10••••••••••••••••••••••..•••.•••••• Oct 13•••••••••••••••••••••••.•••••••••• Oct. 16•••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•••••• Oct. 19•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Oct. 23 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•• Oct. 26 ••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••••.•• Oct llO ••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••..••.• Nov. 2. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov. Ii ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov. 8. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Nov. 13••••••••••••••••.•••••••••.••••••• Nov lJI ············-·-······-········- 100) Cost-of•llvlng Skilled workers .Million maru 500 861 500 1,662 1,000 5,178 7,236 23,000 112,620 100,000 219,800 5()(),000 1,744,640 50D, 000 3,426,800 Unskilled lndex(l 9l3-l4-1) Skilled UDSkllled workers workers workers .Million marka 500 49228009 500 1,470 1,000 4,630 7,126 23,000 109,500 100,000 191,800 5()(),000 1,582,400 5()(),000 3,038,000 142658303 739 84703840 290167223 654973940 1237091762 2905184024 6139164472 12028502200 31790818300 79196610100 136568449000 193598867000 320064868000 587171153000 45. 7 61.0 3L6 34.4 9.2 25.1 11.2 22. 5 42.1 18.9 16. 7 22.0 32.4 14.1 26.3 65.8 76.4 46.5 43.8 13.2 32. 4 16.9 32.4 59.0 27.2 20.9 31.6 42. 4 20.3 33.5 Since the stabilization of the mark real wages have, of course, also become more stable, and as the cost of living in 1924 has been https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 134 CHAPl'ER VI.-WAGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LABOR about as lili?h as in pre-war times, even- nominal wages give quite a good idea ol the trend of wages. Table 50 shows for a number of trades which have not been considered in Tables 46 and 48 the nominal weekly wages for a married worker with one child. It will be seen that in these trades there wa.s, in general, an increase of nominal (and real) wages from January to April, 1924, and that wages in most trades are lower, in some very much lower, than in pre-war times, while in a few others workers enjoy higher wages.than they did 10 yea.rs _ago. TnuSO.-WEEKLY WAGES IN SPECIFIED INDUSTRIES AND OCCUPATIONS IN BERLIN, JANUARY TO APRIL, 1924 Industry and occupation Spring, Jan., 1914 1924 Feb., Mar., Apr., 1924 1921 1924 Per cent of spring, 1914, wagee Jan., Feb., Mar., Apr., 1924 1924 1921 1924 .Marta Marta Marta Marki Marki Chemical factories: Skilled workers _______________________ 3&.88 24.56 24.115 27.00 31.26 63.2 M.2 611. 4 Unskilled workers ____________________ 27.00 22.40 22.40 22.40 23.97 83.0 83.0 83.0 Painting: Painters ______________________________ 3&. 611 Wbltewashers ________________________ 36.M 80.4 88.8 3L88 29.28 30. 72 28.32 30. 72 28.32 33. 73 31.33 8L9 8L2 711.4 78. 6 711.4 78. 6 42.00 35.35 37.35 29. 76 40. 78 46. 80 29. 76 29. 76 36. 72 70. 9 70.9 70.9 87.4 48.13 48.13 48.13 126. 3 115. 5 115. 6 115. ll 38.00 36.50 34.00 33.00 3L21 30.21 3L81 30.81 34.00 33.00 8fl.5 00. 4 82.2 82.8 83. 7 84.4 00.4 42.00 37.80 33.00 26.40 26.40 26.40 27.07 27.07 26. 611 32.·97 32.97 30.68 38.40 88.40 35.M 62. 9 60.8 80.0 M.4 71.6 80.9 78. 6 87.2 92.9 91.4 101.6 106.1 48.00 41.00 Pressers_ - --------------- --------- 38.00 35.00 37.13 31.97 29. 66 38.09 39.42 30.14 27.96 34.00 42.50 30.14 27.96 34.00 42.50 77.3 30.14 78.0 27.96 78. 0 36.22 108.8 82.1 73. 6 73. 7 97.1 88.li 73.5 73. 7 97.1 88.li 73. ll 73. 7 103.5 21.30 32.40 27.40 26.00 19.20 27.40 26.00 19.20 29.80 26.92 21.60 31.00 89.8 89.8 97. 7 27.88 102.9 102.9 110.8 21.60 59. 3 59.3 66. 7 101.6 114. 7 66. 7 42.12 39.96 30. 78 29. 71 24.96 21.84 29. 71 24.96 /dl.84 29.71 24.96 21.84 31.44 Meats: Sausage factories-Journeymen ________ Small abattoirs-Journeymen _________ Butcher shops-Journeymen__________ Bakeries: ~ eltabllsbments-lourneymen ••• establlsbments-Journeymen. __ Men's tailoring: · Custom-made clotblngBusbelers _________________________ Tailors •• ------------------------Repair workers ___________________ Readcfu=e clothing- ______________ Tailors •• ------------- -- -- -------£:.!Wi:~~-Journeymen _________ Skilled workers _______________________ Unskilled laborers. ___________________ Shoe factories-skilled workers ____________ Machine and electrical Industry: Skilled workers.. ______________________ Bemlskilled workers •• ________________ Unskilled laborers·---~--------------- 30. 51 87.2 86.9 40.30 40.30 40.30 115.4 114.0 114.0 114.0 26.06 21.84 70. 5 62. ll 7LO 70. 5 70.li 62. 5 62. ll 7LO 71.0 1111.11 74.6 65.2 71.0 PIECEWORK After the revolution workmen frequently refused to continue to do piecework. Much notice has been given to this refusal, which is hardly merited by its intrinsic importance. The following survey, comprismg all the trades in which piecework is done to any considerable extent except mining, where the pay system is different from that of the general piecework system, shows that piecework has been only temporarily abandoned and that with a sliort break in 1919 the trend is essentially the same as before the war, even be~ accelerated. The aversion of the German workmen to piece.:. worlt, first expressed in a resolution passed by the Socialist congress at Brussels in 1891, appears perfectly intelligible when one considers the practical consequences of the piecework system at that timethe sweating to which it gave rise, the unfairness, and the precariousness of the workmen's income therefrom, especially if we remember that it was only in the second half of the nineties that trade-unions began to exercise a serious influence on wage rates and https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis PIECEWORK 185 conditions of labor md to mitigate the abuses of the piecework system. The increase of power of the trade-unions brouglit about a total ~hange. The workman was no longer a defenseless individual, powerless m the grasp of the employer, but could apply to his organization concerning even the daily differences of opinion on the calculations of piecework Wtlge rates. Of still greater importance was the development of collective bargaining, which was inaugurated by the traae-unions about 1900. The establishment by mutual agreement of principles for the calculation of piecework and frequently also of the wage rates for piecework totally changed the character of the piecework system and at the same time the attitude of the wormen toward it, which had never been uniformly antagonistic. Piecework was regulated in three ways: 1. The rates for piecework which had theretofore been fixed by the employer a.lone were established by agreement and were not to be clianged except by mutual consent; 2. Such changes were to be based on a more or less definitely limited standard hourly wage; 3. For new kinds of piecework, especially in industries in which the types of the work cha~e often, minimum earnings were frequently guaranteed. In addition rules were made for the distribution of wages for gang work. I ; was these gang-work contracts that had, far more than the contracts of single workmen, caused the aversion of the workmen to J>i_ecework generally, because in a gang the strongest and most skillful workman was encouraged for his own interest to set the pace for the rest of the gang. Overtime, Sunday work, and payment for lost time were also regulated. During the war piecework in the war industries was on the whole highly paid and tlie discussion of the question of piecework versus time work ceased altogether. On the outbreak of the revolution large numbers of workmen untrained in trade-union principles joined the trade-unions and under their influence, aided by the general decline in working capacity due to inadequate nourishment during the war, aversion to piecework again became pronounced. But even at that time it was not possible to abolish piecework altogether, such abolition being prevented not only by the employers but by the workmen themselves, b~cause such an attempt would have ended in dissolution of the trade-unions. When stability was restored the workmen soon resumed the attitude toward the piecework system which had been prevalent in the ten_years preceding the war. Let us now consider single trades. The shoemaking trade has two branches-custom slioemaking and the manufacture of shoes on a large scale. In both branches of the trade piecework has always prevailed, and until the union succeeded in concluding collective agreements in the custom branch it was opposed to piecework and desired its abolition. These agreements provided only for negotiating and fixing piece rates, being silent as to abolition of piecework. Before the war collective a~eements had seldom been concluded for shoe factories, but during the war a national collective agreement covering all shoe factories which supplied shoes for the army was concluded through the intervention of the military authorities, and this collective agreement became the pattern for another national collective agreement covering all other boot and shoe factories. In both these agreements piecework was https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 136 CHAPTER VI.-WAGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LABOR regulated, and by fixing minimum wages the employers were prevented from taking advantage of the piecework system to the prejudice of the workm.en. After the war the workers endeavored to conclude a national collective agi-eement cont~ a stipulation that repairs. should be paid for by the hour and that minimum wages should be fixed for a normal output in piecework. While there was no general opposition to piecework in 1919, 17 towns abolished piecework and in others the workmen succeeded in getting repairs paid for by the hour. At the 1920 meeting of the muon a resolution "to refuse piecework under any circumstances as long as the capitalistic system _prevails" was passed. At the same trme however, the prohibition of pieceworlc which had been in the by-iaws since 1894 was revoked. The opposition to piecework soon subsided, and though the union still demands payment by the hour on principle, the work of its members has never been permanently influenced thereby. The clothing trades include a number of trades ha".'ing little or nothing in common-the making of custom clothes, the manufacture of ready-made clothing, of soldiers' uniforms, and of women's ready-made dresses, dressmakil!g, the makinJ? of white goods and ~rie, etc. One peculiarity of all these trad'es, with the exception of clressmaking, is that home work prevails and therefore payment by the J?iece. As the result of tlie extreme distress a.mo~ the workers m a large part of these trades for decades, the workers in with home and piece work and to these trades wislied to do replace it every'1Vhere by wor op or factory work and payment by the hour, but when the trade-unions became strong enough to force the conclusion of collective agreements the practice was different. The establishment of worksho~ was of course promoted, but the fixing of fair terms for piecework was always regarded as the most urgent task. With the exception of dressmaking, collective agreements in all these trades were concluded on the basis of payment by the piece. .It is significant that at the meeting of the union in 1912 a motion to declare in the by-laws "the prohibition of piecework" as an aim of the trade-union was rejected. In spite of the practice of piecework, payment by the hour was not altogether abandoned. After the revolution this system gained in im:{>ortance in connection with the 8-hour day. Wlien, in the ne~otiat1ons for the conclusion of a collective agreement in, the men s custom-cloth.!ng trade in December, 1918z payment by the hour was demanded, the employers refused positive1y, but :finally a national collective a~eement was concluded in which· a standard working time was stipulated for the m ~ of each article of clothes and for each quality, which was to be paia: for at the local rate of wages per hour. Before the war a national collective agreement was concluded for the workers in the manufacture of soldiers' uniforms. Workers who worked on custom uniforms were included under the national collective agreement of the men's custom-clothing trade. For contract tailoring a corresponding agreement was not concluded until 1920. In the read_y-mo.declothing trades collective agreements were made at an early date, but, they were not obset"Ved. Strikes started about 1900 with the object of abolishing piecework had to be given up without result. In the last ten years before the war, therefore the trade-unions concentrated on the regulation of piecework by collective agreement, and as far back https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis .abh PIECEWORK 137 as 1912 admitted that the question of piecework must be decided in each case according to local and business requirements. The regulation of piecework 'by agreement was somewhat slower in the women's ready-made-dress trade than in the men's ready-made-clothing trade, because the workers in that trade were not so well organized. In a meeting of the white goods and lingerie trade in November, 1919 it was stated that not only did piecework _Rrevail in the trade but that the workers applied eagerly for it. The skilled workers in this trade have proceeded along the same line as the workers in other trades, by regulation of piecework rather than P.rohibition thereof. For a lo~ time the unskilled workers desired prohibition of piecework, but as tlieir organization was not strong they were unable to effect such a change and had to be content with regulation of piecework by mutual agreement. In the potters' trade, the stoneware industry, the stove-ma~ trade, and in stove :fitting piecework has always prevailed, and to such a degree that the workers' organizations were unable to collect statistics of hourly rates of wages, because nowhere were they regarded as important. In the nineties, the question of piecework or timework was indeed discussed, but in practice only the regulation of piecework by collective agreement was attempted. At :first efforts were made to fix maximum weekly wages for smgle workmen, but as such stipulations could not be carried out this rough method was abandoned. In the 15 years before the war there was no sign of any movement against piecework, but the war brought about a complete change. Owing to the almost complete cessation of building activity, almost all the available work for stove fitters and makers consisted of repairs, which had always been paid for by the hour. Thus payment by the hour came to be aclopted more and more and the idea of introducin~ it generally cropped up_ again and spread more and more in the time of the revolution. The subject was discussed vehemently in the trade journal and in meetings and formed the principal topic of the debates in the :first general assembly after the war, in July, 1919. The fact that the trade-union had succeeded in introducing pa~ent by the hour in 1918 in Hamburg, and in 1919 in Lubeck and Schleswig was a further inducement to continue the strugile against the piecework system. At a meeting of the union a motion that the union declare itself for the prohibition of piecework and the introduction of payment by the hour was carried unanimously, and a resolution-that a two-thirds vote of the members should decide the system of payment to be adopted was passed. In January, 1920, the required majority voted for payment by the hour in the case of the stove makers, stove fitters, and stoneware potters, but in the case of the crockery makers the required majority was not secured. As in former years, however, it proved to be impossible in practice to abolish/iecework, because of the resistance of the employers, who woul :r;i.ot even grant the minimum wage which had been demanded for a long_ time, and also because of the lack of unanimity among the potters themselves. The result was that the piecework system remained in force with the stove makers and wheel potters or throwers, while part of the stove :fitters were paid by the liour. In the pa.inters' trade we must distinguish between house painters proper or decorators, who belong to the building trade, and the varnishers and other painters employed in the wood and metal https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 138 CHAPTER VI.-WAGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LABOR industries. With the house painters the piecework system has never played an important part. In some large towns it was introduced for work on large tenement houses, in the form of gang contracts for special work, such as windows, doors, floors, and ceil:.. ings, but beyond this it has not been used to any extent. Curiously enough there were in this trade signs of a tendency, not only among the employers but also among the workers, to extend the use of the piecework system after the revolution. On the whole, however, the pos~war period has not brought any changes of importance in this r~pect. With the painters in factories, furniture making, coach building, railway-car works, and machine factories the situation is quite different. In these industries piecework had always prevailed to such an extent (more than half of the total number of workmen working by the piece) that the abolition of the system was out of the question. In regulating piecework in these trades, however, the painters met with some difficulties, because they were generally in the minority in the factories and therefore not strong enough to carry through radical changes. With the revolution, collective agreements were concluded in these trades and piecework was regulated in this manner. The piecework system has caused a good deal of conflict in the bricklayers' trade, which, however, has not been of any great importance in itself. The workers have always declined to do piecework on account of the increase of danger to accident, especially in the jerry work frequently connected with it, and while the employers have tried repeatedly to have the principle of the piecework system ~knowle~ed in the ~o~ective agree~ents t1:1-eY. have not put. it mto practice even within the established lirmts. Some special trades, such as plasterers, stuccoers, and flag or tile layers, have always done piecework to a large extent. In the printers' trade piecework has never played any considerable part except with compositors, but even in their case 1t has been in a great measure abandoned. After the revolution the journeyinen demanded the abandonment of the piecework system without success, but the employers did not succeed in introducing the piecework system generally, and the postwar period has not brought any change of importance. In tlie bookbmding trades piecework has increased in the degree that the craftsman has been replaced by the manufacturing concern. The bookbinders' union soon perceived that the abuses of the piecework system, which were extending, could be combated only by collective agreements. Whereas in the earlier periods only traces of aversion against piecework are to be found, a typical reaction set in after the revolution. In the towns in which collective agreements were in force resolutions prohibiting piecework were passed by general vote of the members . of the union, but attempts to put them into effect were for the most part without success. At the meeting of the union in 1919, it was decided after much debate, to continue the previous policy of regulation by collective agreement, and the principle of the piecework system was thus accepted. In the textile industries the piecework system has always prevailed and has been extended continuously since the introduction of the collective-agreement system. Owing to the weakness of their tradeunion the workers were on principle averse to piecework, but the https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis PIECEWORK 139 number of those favoring the piecework system was growing even before its regulation by collective agreement. While collective agreements were not concluded to any considerable extent before the war, it had become evident even in 1914 that the piecework system could not be abolished very soon, and that the real question was as to how far it could be regulated by collective agreement. After the war this opinion persisted and the demand for prohibition of the piecework system was struck out of the by-laws in 1919, probably because conditions of work and rates of wages in this industry were, as a result of the revolution, regulated to a great extent by collective agreements and a stable rate of wages as well as a minimum wage thus secured. In the woodworking industry piecework has played an important part and has increased continually up to the war. The workers demanded the abandonment of the piecework system as long as they had no voice in the management of the concerns. A.s soon, however, as they were given the opportunity of concluding agreements regulation of piecework began. A. minimum rate of wages and, above all, impartial investigation of new rates for piecework were the characteristic stipulations of such agreements. The war brought an increase of piecework in some branches of the woodworking industry and a decrease in others. In work for the army, supplying it with certain uniform articles on an enormous scale, piecework played an important part. In regular factory work, however, piecework had frequently to be abandoned, as the indifferent quality of the materials (wood, glue, French polish) hampered the workmen too much and caused interruptions and loss of time. The opposition to piecework which set in after the revolution was, in the woodworking industry, felt only here and there, being strongest among the woodworkers employed in the metal industries, but even here it soon declined. In 1920 a national collective agreement for the woodworking industry was concluded, which was renewed in 1921. Like many previous local agreements, this agreement provided that 115 per cent of the wages agreed upon for work by the hour was to be paid as the minimum wage for piecework. By this agreement the piecework system was formally recognized. The metal industries comprise a large number of different trades, and the employers also belong to widely different classes, ranging from the small handicraftsman, locksmith, or fitter to the general works manager of a large concern in the Rhineland or Westphalia industrial district. It can hardly be said, therefore, that in this industry the piecework system has developed uniformly, although there is no doubt that on the whole it has gained ground. Regulation by collective agreements was effective only in the small concerns and with individual tradesmen, as the large works positively declined to enter into collective agreements. During the war the most powerful agent in extending the piecework system was the extensive use of the industry for army supplies. A.s all articles for the army are required to be produced on a large scale, no other branch of industry could be more suitable for piecework, even though the indifferent quality of the materials was to a certain degree an obstacle. Before the war the employers in the metal industry who were opposed to the trade-unions had tried to prevent the training and https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 140 CHAPTER VI.-WAGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LABOR education of the workers in trade-union policies and management, first by prohibiting their employees from joining the unions and, second, oy promoting the so-celled "yellow" organizations. The consequences of this folicy became perceptible a.fter the revolution, when the members o the "yellows' joined the struggle against the piecework system. The struggle, however, did not last long. At the meeting of the union in 1919 motions for the abolition of piecework were rejected. According to statistics of the union for 1920, piecework was prohibited in onl_y six agreements, covering 1:28 establishments and 283 persons. In only .one agreement was piecework excluded altogether, and that was an agreement concluded by_ a. corporation of smiths, where piecework was never customary. In the other five agreements piecework was prohibited for only a. pa.rt of the workers enga..ged or for certain kinds of work. With the change of political conditions collective agreements could be concluded on a. different basis than theretofore. As trade-unions had been universally recognized, the large manufacturing concerns were obliged to acknowledge the right of their workers to participate on a footing of equality in negotiations as to conditions of labor and ra.ies of wages. As a consequence of this not only did the movement for collective agreements spread enormously, but the proportion of afeements concluded between single firms and their workers and o joint collective agreements was reversed. Whereas in 1917 two-thirds of all agreements were concluded by single firms, in 1920 this proportion had decreased to less than one-third. The negotiations between organiz'a.tions carried on since the revolution have gi,ven a different basis to the system of collective bargaining. By 1918 extensive ioint collective agreements and basic agreements for whole districts had been concluded, in which uniform standards in ell matters of principle, including the matter of piecework, were established. Local agreements for single towns and for related trades provided for local and trade requirements. This movement has extended, while national agreements on wages have been concluded only in a few oases. In the standard regulations for piecework issued by the German Meta.I Workers' Union in 1904 the aims of these regulations a.re _defined as follows: Fixing of terms for piecework in cooperation with the workers before the work is entered upon; establishment of a. minimum wage according to the average working ca.pa.city; guaranty of an hourly wage and a. list of rates for piecework protected by agreement. These stipulations have been amplified to suit the requirements of single trades, e. g.1 by regulations for molders in case of failures in casting, additional pay for pipe layers working outside of the city, gang work of smiths, fitters, and smelters, prohibition of overtime, and the middleman or sweater system. They were :finally completed by protective measures against reduction of rates-piecework rates to be altered only in case working methods a.re improved or the types of wholesale articles a.re ~hanged, and the fundamental requirement that a. fair rate of hourly wages shell be ~a.ranteed. To this day the standard stipulations of 1904 contain all that the metal worker considers essential to fair conditions for piecework. These standards a.re still a. matter of discussion, for the ultimate aim is to regulate conditions of labor and rates of wages of meta.I workers satisfactorily ell over Germany. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EFFICIENCY OF LABOR 141 The German trade-unions are not unanimous in their position with regard to _piecework. On the whole, they have allowed their attitude to be mfluenced by the circumstances in each case. The above survey shows however, that the tide of opinion which set against the piecework system after the revolution has left no lasting impression, and that although a large part of the workers are not particularly enthusiastic as to piecework the system has probably gained ground since the war and prevails in all places and establisnments where there are no serious objections due to the peculiarities of .the trade in question. . · EFFICIENCY OF LABOR . Complaints as to inefficiency of workers in Germany were rather frequent even in pre-war times and many examples were shown to prove that the output per hour of the average worker was lower in Germany than in other countries, especially in the United States. Part of this was due to bad management, old-fashioned machinery, long working hours, or 1,>iecework systems with maximum wage per week, which: indirectly mduced the worker to restrict his output. Complaints were much more frequent in small shops than in large establishments with efficient management, up-to-date machinery, short working time, and modern wage systems. Yet there is no doubt that, m general, even in establishments with equally good management and machinery, with equal working time, and equal wage systems with modern American establishments, the average hourly output per worker was smaller than that in the United States. The i:lifference, however, was practically always smaller, and often much smaller, than the difference in real wages, and the cost of production per unit in such plants was generii.lly lower than that in America. After the war complaints as to decrease of efficiency of labor were universal in Germany, both in small shops and in the best managed and best equi_pped establishments. Thls,nowever, in no way crip:pled the competitive power of German goods in the world's market, smce for the same reasons cost of production increased likewise in other countries, although the political unrest and the low standard of living reduced output in Germany after the war probably more than in any other country. Moreover, complaints of a too low hourly outimt per worker have been raised less and less of late. As early as October 27, 1921, the Minister of Railways declared with regard to the railway workshops (and the railway workers were accused even more than others of being inefficient): "The output per man is in general on prewar level"; and the railway official in charge of the workshop department wrote only a few months later: "According to the standard of output in the main and the subsidiary workshops, the output of the individual man in most of the repair shops has reached the pre-war level and in some shops exceeds it." A representative of a big electric concern, in an article entitled "Dearer production-lower production," bitterly complained of the reduction of the yearlJ- output per employee through the increase of unproductive work, the shortening of the regular workin.2: time, the refusal of overtime work, the increase of sickness and of vacations and the frequency of strikes, but explicitly said: "It must be admitted that the pieceworker engaged in productive work is in general, as to 20168°-25t-10 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 142 CHAPTER VI,-WAGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LABOR the output per hour, no longer behind the pre-war output and even partly exceeds it." The decrease of efficiency of labor 1s, then, now only of historical interest, but in itself this should be no reason for eliminating it from a study of postwar labor conditions in Germany, for it shows that even those who were most outspoken in former years now generally admit that severe reduction of output took place only in the first two years after the revolution. An ascertainment of the actual facts is difficult, as no unbiased investigation of efficiency of labor has been made in postwar times. Such an investigation would have shown that even in cases of very low efficiency of labor the wages per unit were ridiculously low in comparison with the selling price of the product. · Aside from political unrest, the main reason mentioned for the reduction of labor efficiency (hourly output) in the first years after the war was that the employers were prevented from paying their employees according to their efficiency, because of: 1. The abolition of piecework; 2. The leveling of wages-almost the same wages being fixed for skilled workers as for unskilled workers; 3. The introductio~ of family allowances. 1. The attitude of the workers of different trades toward piecework is discussed on pages 134 to 141. It may suffice to supplement that discussion at this place by a description of the experience of the German railways. Before the war piecework was quite the rule in the repair shops of the German railways; during the war it became less important, and in the last months before the revolution at least as much timework. was performed as piecework. With the outbreak of the revolution piecework was completely abolished. The number of days worked on timework and on piecework in the Prussian-Hessian railway shops is shown in Table 51: TABLE ol~NUMBER OF DAYS OF TIMEWORK AND PIECEWORK WORKED IN THE PRUSSIAN•HESSIAN ··RAILWAY SHOPS, 1913 TO 1919 Fiscal year beginning- April 1, 1913••••••••••••• April 1, 1914.. ••••••••••• April 1, 1915.••••...•••• April 1, 1916.•••••••••••• Tlmework Piecework Da!IS 6,499,603 6,763,697 7,053, 735 9,473,747 15,999,383 14,290,204 13,347,510 13,639,908 Daya Fiscal year beginning- Tlmework April 1, 1917••••••••.•••• April 1, 1918•••••••••••.• April 1, 1919••••••••••••• Da!IS 14,183,025 28,575,790 51,025,654 Piecework Days 15,958,273 8,553,441 338,239 The hatred of piecework by the workers in the railway shops which induced them immediately to suspend piecework after the outbreak of the revolution was aue to a large extent to mistakes committed by the old administration. The former piecework system in the workshops made it possible for the foremen to handle things as they pleased and to pay the workers not according to their efficiency anct mdustry but according to political or similar consideration. The sudden abolition of piecework resulted in a great reduction in the amount of work done. To quote only one example: In September, 1918, with a staff of 107,000 workers, 870 locomotives were repaired weekly; in September, 1919, only 747 locomotives were repaired within a week, while 164,000 men were employed, and this in spite of the fact that in 1918 many women and war prisoners had been employed, who by 1919 had been replaced by skilled workmen. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EFFICIENCY OF LABOR 148 All attempts to reintroduce piecework by mutual agreement proved unsuccessful. At last, in February, 1920, certain shops were closed for some days, the unnecessary workers were disnussed, and the work taken up with a reduced personnel on the basis of a reasonable piecework wage system. By December, 1920, 70 per cent of the workshops were operated on a piecework system. The output per man increased and in the course of 1921 regained the pre-war level. 2. Before the war there had been in Germany quite a difference between the wages of skilled and of unskilled workers, a skilled worker receiving, in general, from 20 to 50 _per cent more than an unskilled worker. With the outbreak of the revolution the selfconsciousness of the unskilled laborers was, of course, considerably intensified and the tendency to level wages became very strong. Before the war the trade-unions bad to a great extent included within the same union both skilled and unskilled workers in their trade, resulting in a tendency to reduce the difference between their wages, and with the influx of great numbers of laborers into the union after the revolution-the uruon leaders often had to yield to the ambition of the unskilled workers to get the same wages as the skilled workers. On the other hand, real wages of skilled workers remained so low that it was hardly possible to pay the unskilled workers much less than the skilled workers. But whatever may have been the decisive factor in an individual trade the leveling of wages had the effect of reducing the industry of the skilled workers and temporarily of reducing the number of apprentices. But this condition did not last very long. When political unrest subsided, and in consequence thereof the general level of efficiency of labor rose, the scarcity of unskilled labor, which had been augmented by the reduction of the movement from the rural districts to the cities and by the disappearance of alien laborers, was no longer felt so strongly, and the importance and greater worth of skilled workers was once more recognized, the differentiation of salaries and wages increased, and in some cases became what it had been in pre-war times. A few examples will serve to illustrate this development: The wages of German building laborers in 1913 were about 78 per cent of those of the bricklayers; in 1922 the percentage was about 95-or 96; in the first three quarters of 1923, 94 or 95; it then dropped to about 90 in November, 1923, and to 84 in December, 1924. The wages of metal workers' helpers in 1913 were about 68 per cent of those of skilled metal workers; in 1922 the percentage was about 94; in the first three quarters of 1923 it was about 93 or 92; it then dropped to about 85 by the end of the year and to 70 in December, 1924. The wages of woodworkers' helpers in 1913 were about 72 per cent of those of skilled woodworkers. The leveling here was not so great as in most other trades. In 1922 helpers earned about 10 or 11 per cent less than sltllled workers, and in December, 1924, 17 per cent less. In individual cases the relation between the wages of skilled and of unskilled workers changed because the difference in wages in marks remained unchanged. Thus the weekly wages of laborers in chemical factories in Berlin were less by 21.6 marks than those of skilled workers from the beginning of 1920 to October, 1921. But https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 144 CHAPTER VI.-W.AGES AND EFFICIENCY OF LA.BOB. as the wages of skilled workers rose from 148.8 marks in January, 1920, to 391.2 marks in October, 1921, laborers who before the war had ea.med 69 per cent of the wages of skilled workers, received in Janua.ey1 1920, 85 per cent, and in October, 1921, 94 per cent. A similar situation existed for several years with bank clerks. As will be seen from Table 48, bank clerks doing responsible work who in 1913 had earned 315 gold marks ($75) more per year than the bank clerks doing simple work, had their yearly salary fixed in February, 1920, at only 500 marks ($5) more than that of clerks doing simple work. This difference of 500 marks prevailed all the year 1920, being raised to 600 marks in January, 1921 and to 765 marks in April, 1922. In the meantime the wages of clerks do~ simple work had increased from 14,000 to 61,757 marks. The difference between the wages of these two classes of employees, which in 1913 amounted to 10 per cent, was then in February, 1920, 3.6 per cent and only 1.2 ~r cent in April, 1922. The difference became much greater during the course of 1923, amounting to a.bout 18 per cent m September, 1923, and has remained a.bout as great up to the present time. In this exceptional case, the difference between the earnings of trained and of untrained employees, which for some time had practically disappeared, is now much greater than in pre-war times (588 marks, or $140). Government employees also for several years after the war experienced a considerable leveling of th:eir income. A comparison of -four typical grades of employees (excluding the highest and the lowest) shows tlie following: TABLE 31.-INDE:X: NUMBERS OF MONTHLY WAGES OF SPECIFIED GRADES OJI' GOVERNMENT EMPLOYEES ON SPECIFIED DATES (Waps of Grade m-100) Gradel Grade ITT .•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Grade vnr ....•.•..••••.••...••.•.•..•••••••.••.•.. Grade XI.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• _ _ _ , Grade XIIL.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••, ••••••••••• October, 1913 100 2M 387 63) 1921 100 138 179 289 100 130 174 230 100 14/l 214 847· 100 183 270 3112 1 Grade m mcludes, for emmple, railway conductors; Grade vm, post and telegraph clerks; Grade la, directors of large post and telegraph ol!lces; Grade XIII, chiefs of divlslons In Government departments. The leveling of the salaries of these grades was greatest in August, 1921, when the bkhest grade under consideration drew only 2.3 times as much as the lowest grade (as compared with 6.2 times in 1913). Two months later a new scale went into force which raised the proportion to 3.5. In the following years there was a noticeable increase of the salaries of the employees m middle grades, while those in the bkher grade continued to draw a.bout 3.5 times as much as those in tlie low~r grade. But in the.last week of May, 1924, a. radical change took placeiiJ!1e pre-war relation of the various grades was completely reestab · ed, all single emplo_yees dra:vving from and after June 1, 1924, 80 per cent of the 1913 salaries. Since the revolution empl~ees with families also receive allowances for wife and children. 3. Family allowances, which of course are an infringement upon the principle of paying employees according to their efficiency, were mtroduced on a large scale after the revolution, for workers as well as https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EFFICmNCY OF LABOR 145 for salaried employees and for officials. Employees generally were at first rather suspicious with regard to this reform, bemg afraid that discrimination against workers with many children would result. But real wages were so low that emJ?loyers were always ready to hire married men having children, especially as such men were supposed to be more steady and less inclined to political agitation. Moreover, family allowance funds were created which spread the expenses for family allowances over an entire employers association, thus decreasmg the risk of the individual employer. If these funds have not become of great importance, this is perhaJ?s due partly to the fact that it is almost impossible for the association to prevent frauds. Thus in times of scarcity of labor, when the employers' associations bound their members not to pay higher wages than those fixed bJ collective agreements, it frequently liappened that the employees of a concern were given to understand that no strict examination would be made by the management of the data submitted as to tho number of children, and in such cases unduly high family allowances were granted to many workers at the expense of the fund. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Chapter VIL-UNEMPLOYMENT NUMBER OF UNEMPLOYED WORKERS Immediately before the war unemployment was normal. On the outbreak of war it became enormous, but began to decrease after a few weeks and in the early spring of 1915 was again normal. From the fall of 1916, when the so-callea "Hindenburg munition program" was put into effect,!. until the armistice there was yracticall_y no unemplo~ent in uermany. The sudden return o the soldiers from the front and stoppage of war industries necessarily _made adjustl:µent of supply and aemand·on the labor market very difficult, and in the winter of 1918-19 the rate of unemployment was rather high, but from then until the beginning of 1923 there was no very long period when unemployment was really serious. Conditions took a bad turn, however, when the French entered the Ruhr and passive resistance was inaugurated, and became still worse when passive resistance broke down and inflation reached its peak. In the winter of 1923-24 unemployment in Germany was greater than it has ever been. Table 53 shows the per cent of trade-union members unemployed on the last day of each month from January, 1913, to December, 1924: TABLB 63.-PER CENT OF TRADE-UNION MEMBERS UNEMPLOYED, JANUARY, 1913, TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS Month ! j 1913, 191411915 19UI 1191711918 / 191911~ 192111922 1923 1924 Malta January _________________ -------------- - 3.4 5.0 5.8 February __ ---------------------------- 3.1 3.9 4.5 March __ ----------------------- -- ------ 2.4 2. 9 2.6 tea~-_::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 2.3 2. 5 2. 9 2.8 L9 L7 2.8 2L2 L4 4. 9 L5 June_------------------------ --- -- -- --- 2. 7 2. 6 L4 July ____ ------------------------------- 2. 9 2. 9 L4 August _________________________________ October________________________________ September - ------------------- --------- 2. 7 14. 5 L2 2. 9 9.9 1.0 December November______________________________ __ --------------------------- 3. 2 7.4 1.4 6.4 1.4 L5 LO 1.0 ,9 .9 .9 .7 .7 .6 .6 .7 0. 9 .8 .6 .4 .3 .3 .3 .3 .3 .2 .3 .5 0,5 .5 .4 .3 .3 .2 .2 .2 .2 .2 1.5 5.1 6, 2 5. 6 3. 6 4.8 3. 5 2.1 2.8 2. 6 1. 7 2. 3 2. 7 2.8 3.3 2. 7 1.9 1.9 2. 4 3. 5 5.0 5.2 4.1 4. 0 3. 9 4.3 4. 7 3.8 8.9 4. 9 3.1 4. 8 3. 7 1.2 5.1 3. 8 .9 6, 6 3. 5 .6 5. 9 2. 9 .6 3. 6 2. 6 .5 3.1 2. 2 .5 5. 7 1. 4 .6 9.6 1.1 1.1 19.3 1.4 1.6 24.4 L7 2. 4 30.8 28.6 19.0 11.7 9,:l 11.1 12.9 12. 7 10. 7 8.6 7.6 8.8 3.6 3. 7 8.4 3. 3 9. 7 3. 3 9.5 2. 8 9.5 2. 7 9.5 2. li 8.1 2. 2 7.3 2. 2 6, 3 1.8 5. 0 2.1 2. 5 6.8 2. 2 2.5 5.0 3.8 2.4 3.8 5. 9 2. 2 4. 2 10.0 2. 2 4.8 8. 7 2.2 4.1 5. 9 2.1 3. 9 4. 9 2.8 3.8 3. 8 5.2 3. 6 3. 4 4. 4 4. 4 3. 4 2. 8 2. 3 1. 4 1.4 1.2 1,3 1. 7 L7 .9 .8 .8 1.0 .8 Ll L4 2. 4 3. 4 4. 3 17.1 13. 3 7.9 6.0 5.6 8.1 11.3 11.5 9.8 7.5 5.9 5. 5 2. 6 2.8 2. 2 2. 3 2. 5 2. 5 2. 4 2. 2 2. I 2.0 L7 L6 0. 9 .8 .9 .8 .8 .8 .7 .7 .8 .7 LS 5.1 29.4 Femalea January ________________________________ 1.5 2.4 11.1 8. 2 4. 7 2.0 7.9 February ___ --------------------------- 1.5 2.1 9.4 8. 8 4. 7 L9 8.0 3.6 4.1 March_ ------------------ -- ----- -- ----- 1.4 1.9 8.3 8.1 3. 9 2.1 4.8 2.1 3. 7 tl:::==:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June_---------------- --- ----- -------- -July_ - - -------------------------------August _____ --------- --- _______ -------t':ti~ber::::::::::::::::::: ::::: ::::: November______________________________ __ --------------------------December 1.5 2. 4 2. 5 2. 9 2. 8 2. 4 2.4 2. 4 3. 9 1. 7 2. 6 2. 6 3.4 32.4 24.3 18. 5 14.3 12. 9 9.1 9.1 9. 7 9.9 10.0 10.0 8. 5 7.8 3.2 2. 9 2.3 2. 3 2. 5 2. 7 2. 9 2.8 2. 7 2.8 3.1 4.8 4. 7 3. 7 2. 8 2. 8 2.8 2. s 2. 9 22. 4 15. 7 10. 9 8. 2 7.2 6. 5 5.1 3.3 2. 9 2. 9 2. 5 2. 7 2.8 2. 6 2. 5 2. 5 2. 6 io.o Total ti:t~ _::: -::::::::::::::::::::::::: March __ ---------------------- _________ tl::::=:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June ___________________________________ July - ---------------------------------August ______ ------------ -- --- --------September_------------October________________________________ -- ------------November-_--------------------------December------------------ -- ---------- 146 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis L7 1.6 1.3 1.0 1.0 .9 .8 ,8 .8 .7 .7 .9 6. 6 6.0 3. 9 5. 2 3.8 2. 5 3.1 3.1 2. 2 2. 6 2. 9 2. 9 3. 4 4. 5 2. 9 4. 7 1.9 3. 7 1.9 3. 9 2. 7 3. 7 4.0 3.0 6.0 2.6 5. 9 2. 2 4. 5 1.4 4. 2 1.2 3. 9 1.4 4.1 L6 5. 3 6.4 7.2 8. 5 7.3 5.3 4. 7 7.9 10.8 18.4 20. 1 19. 6 --26.5 3. 3 4. 2 2. 7 5. 2 1.1 5. 6 .9 7.0 ,7 6, 2 .6 4.1 ,6 3. li .7 6, 3 .8 9.9 1.4 19.1 20 23.4 2.S 28.2 25.1 16.6 10.4 8.6 10. 5 12.5 12.4 10.5 8. 4 7. 3 8.1 . 147 NUMBER OF UNEMPLOYED WORKERS The postwar statistics of unemployment, however, do not convey an exact idea of the condition of the labor market, as many workers who had a regular job were employed on short time. This was due mainly to the fact that under tlie decree of January 4, 1919, an employer who wished to reduce his personnel could not, as in prewar times, simply dismiss a number of employees but first had to resort to short-time work. Only when he liad reduced the working week to less than 30 hours (under the decree of March 20, 1919, to less than 24 hours) was he allowed to dismiss workers. Table 54 shows the J>er cent of trade-union members working short time at the end of each month from January, 1921, to December, 1924. TABLB 54.-PER CENT OF TRADE•UNION MEMBERS WORKING SHORT TIME, JAN• UARY, 11121, TO DECEMBER, 1924, BY MONTHS -Males Females Total Month • J921 1922 1923 192( 1921 1922 1923 1924 1921 1922 1923 1924 - . January.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 6. 3 1.1 7.6 24. 3 8. 7 8. 3 25. 6 2Ll 7.0 LS 12.6 23.4 February•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 6.2 LI 9.9 18. 6 12.1 8. 5 27.7 12. 9 7.9 1.9 H.9 17.1 March ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 7.3 .8 19.1 10. 6 lf-9 2. 3 35. 6 7.7 9,5 L3 28. 6 9.9 .5 .4 .4 .6 .6 September ............................. 2.4 1.4 October •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1.5 2.8 November ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ,8 .. 3 December•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• LO S.1 ttar:·:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 7.4 6. 8 June.······················· •.••••••••• 6.1 July •• •••••••••••••••••••·•••·•·••••••• .. 7 August•...•.•.•.....•............••.••. 2. 9 6. 3 19.0 8.6 18.1 17.6 12.4 25. 7 22. 4 26.0 36. 6 16.6 46. 5 11.4 46.1 6.7 42.6 s. 4 25. 4 12. 7 L2 IL 7 .9 10.0 L3 6. 5 L4 8. 8 1.9 .. 2 S.8 .. 8 9.8 2. 0 16.8 2. 6 18.6 37.0 28.6 20. 9 19.8 35.4 47.5 5L8 00. 4 40.2 .. 2 7.2 24.6 35.2 31.8 00-4 14.5 10.0 9.5 8. 9 .7 8.1 .5 7.2 .6 s. 2 .8 8. 2 .9 2. 9 2. 6 2. 5 .. 7 1.1 7.5 L5 8. 7 28. 5 S.8 2L 7 8.2 IS. 3 19.4 lf. 5 28.2 26. 0 27.6 39. 7 17.5 47,3 12.2 47.3 7.5 42.0 6.5 Short-time work, of course, varies greatly as to length. According to the report of the Ministry of Labor for the end of April, 1924, 33 J>er cent of those working short time worked from 1 to 8 hours less than the usual hours; 18 per cent worked from 9 to 16 hours less; 26 per cent, from 17 to 24 hours less; and 23 per cent, more than 24 hours less. When business is very slack and unemployment and short-time work especially wfdespread1 the reduction of hours of labor is naturally also very great. In October, 1923, for example, only 10 per cent of short-time workers worked from 1 to 8 hours less than the normal hours; 20 ~r cent worked 9 to 16 hours less; 47 per cent 17 to 24 hours less; and 23 per cent more than 24 hours less. The distribution of short-time work over the week, of course, also varies greatly. At first, as employers generally hope that short-time work will be only temporary and are loath to change the organization of their establishments, they reduce work daily. When they begin to realize that short-time work will be necessary for some weeks. they attempt a definite arrangement. The employees, especially 'if they live at a distance from their working place, prefer to work full time on some days and to remain away altogether on the other days. The employers are anxious to save overhead charges (heating cost, etc.) and so in some cases yield to the wishes of their employees and SUSJ?,end work altogether on certain days; e.g., from Friday evening until Tuesday morning. In establishments operated continuously, however, employers sometimes prefer to shut down part of the establishment and to reduce the length of each.shift. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 148 CHAPTER VII,-UNEMPLOYM:ENT While, up to the end of 1923, especially in times of slack business, the number of employees working short time was generally larger than the number of totally unemployed, short-time work: in the winter of 1923-24 decreased much more than full unemployment. Thi& was due to the fact that the decree of October 13, 1923, authoriz~s the employer to dismiss workers if he intends to shut down his establish.inent or part thereof. · UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF LEGISLATION IB 1918 Immediately after the conclusion of the armistice the Fedetal Office for Economic Demobilization (Reii/1,sq,mt fur wirtschaftliche Demobilmachung) was created for guiding German economic life into peace channels. Its :first legislative act was an order regulating unemployment relief. The most important provisions of this order were as follows: ARTICLE 1. The Federal Government granlis assistance to communes or commu,nal unions (Gemeinden oder·Gemeindeverbilnde) giving relief to unemployed. ABT. 2. The communes are required to institute unemployment relief, which from a lega! point of view is not to be regarded as poor relief. ABT. 4. Of the total expenses of the commune or communal union for unemployment relief one-half shall be home by the Federal Government and onethird by the State. The Federal Government * * * may increase its share in the case of poorer communes or for certain districts. * * * ABT. 5. The unemployment relief is to be granted by the place of residence of · the unemployed. Demobilized soldiers * * * are to receive relief in the place where they lived before enlisting. . Persons who during the war moved to another place to take up work there shall return, if possible, to their former place of residence, where they are to receive relief. Expenses of the journey to the former place of residence are to be paid by the last place of residence out of the funds of the unemployment relief. ABT. 6. Relief is to be paid only to persons over 14 years of age who are able and willing to work but who owing to unemployment in consequence of the war are indigent. Indigence is presumed * * * only when, as a result of total or partial unemployment, tlie income of the person, together with the income of the members of his family living with him, has been so reduced that he is no longer able to meet his necessary living expenses. ABT. 7. Women are to receive relief only if they are dependent on their own exertions for a living. . . Persons whose former supporters return home able to work are not to receive unemployment relief. ABT. 8. Unemployed persons are bound to accept any suitable work assigned to them, even if outside their own trade and _place of residence, especially in the loeality where they were formerly employed and where they lived before the war, and even if the hours are shorter, provided they are offered ·the customary wages in the locality for the work assigned them, that the work is not injurious to their health, that their lodging is morally unobjectionable, and, in the case of married men, that the maintenance of their family is not impossible. Expenses of the journey to the place of employment are to be paid by the last place of residence out of the funds for unemployment relief. · ABT. 9. The nature and amount of relief, the fixing of a waiting period not longer than one week for unemployed persons (with: the exception of ex-soldiers) and the further payment of their sickness insurance premiums are to be left to the judgment of the commune or communal union. These must, however, see that the relief gran~<! is sufficient and that it at least equals the local wage fixed under the Workmen's Insurance Code, which, for the suP.porter of a family, is to be suitably increased according to the size of the family. In place of money grants, relief in kind may be given (granting of food, partial payment of rent, and the like). * * * Should workers, because of a temporary shutdown or a limitation of their work, fail to work the number of hours p~ week usual in their establishments without overtime, they are to ·receive unemployment nlief for the hours missed, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF 149 provided that 70 per cent of their regular earnings is not equal to twice the sum given as relief for total unemployment. * * * ART. 10. The communes or communal unions may make unemployment relief, especially in the case of juvenile workers, dependent on further considerations (attendance at schools, training courses, workshops, etc.). They may determine causes for the exclusion of persons from the benefits of unemployment relief (misuse of benefits, failure to conform wit\t the regulations, etc.). ART. 11. No regard shall be paid to small amounts of property (small savings, household goods) in defining necessitous cases. ART. 12. Relief which the unemployed may receive through his own providence or that of others, such as a pension, may be taken into account in the relief granted by the commune or communal union only when the unemployment relief, other relief, and the pension taken together are four times the amount of the local wages. Interest on savings is likewise to be taken into account. ART. 13. For the administration of unemployment relief, relief committees are to be established, to which representatives of the employers and of the employees are to be appointed in equal numbers. The relief committees are to decide as to unemployment relief. * * * ART. 14. Upon the demand of a labor organization, the payment of unemployment relief and the control of the unemployed are to be transferred to such organization, (1) if it grants, according to its by-laws, unemployment relief to its members; (2) if it offers sufficient guaranty that the payment of the relief and the control of the unemployed will be orderly done. ART. 18. This order goes into force on the day of its promulgation [November 13, 1918) and is to remain in force for at least one year. Further orders were issued on December 3 and 21, each containing one or two important provisions. The order of December 3 provided: The relief may be regulated by the commissioner of demobilization so that the unemployed will get food and lodging from his former employer in the same way he got them while he was employed. In that case the commune or communal union is to grant to the employer compensation, to be fixed in advance. * * * According to the order of December 21, :Raragraph 2 of article 9 of the original act was thereafter to read as follows: Should workers because of a temporary shutdown or a limitation of their work fail to work the number of hours per week usual in their establishments without overtime and should their wages be reduced on that account, they are to receive unel_Ilployment relief for the wages not received, provided that 70 per cent of the weekly earnings remaining to them is not equal to the sum given as relief for total unemployment; but they shall not receive more in wages and relief taken together than the amount of their regular full-time earnings. The same order extended the payment of unemploJ'lllent relief to unemployed persons during the tune of sickness, as follows: ART. 12a. In case an unemployed person is entitled under the Workmen's Insurance Code to a continuation or maintenance of insurance against sickness with a sick fund * * * , the commune is to attend to his further insurance in the same class or wage group in which he was insured. It is to * * * pay the full fees for the unemployed person. ART. 12b. Unemployed persons wlY.> receive unemployment relief and do not fall under article 12a are also to receive the full unemployment relief in case of sickness. AMOUNT OF UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF The order of November 13, 1918, did not fix the amount of the unemployment relief, each municipality fixing the allowances as it saw fit. In Berlin, for example, the daily benefit in case of total unemployment was fixed for males over 17 years of age at 4 marks, for males between 14 and 17 years and for females over 17 years at 3 marks, and for females between 14 and 17 years at 2.5 marks. In addition, each unemP.loyed worker was to receive 1 mark a day for his wife, for each child under 14 years of age, and for each other https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 150 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT membt,r of his household who was unable to earn a living and whom he was legally obligated to su_pport. These rates are rather moderate. A single worker received probably less than one-third of his regular w!l-Ses and a roamed worker with two-children hardl_y more than half his orc:li!tarY wages. Rates in other towns were at first also rather modest. But the unemployed soon became dissatisfied with this state of affairs and succeeded now and then in forcing up the allowances to such a level that there was gr_eat inducement to abandon work and draw the increased benefits. Moreover, the workers began to flock into those cities which paid the highest benefits and those staying_ _there refused to leave. To counteract such abuses the National Office for Economic Demobilization on January 15, 1919, issued a new order. Article 5, par~aph 2, of the order of November 13, 1918, was supplemented by a new provision, as follows: Pers9ns who during the war moved to another place to take up work there may, however, receive assistance in the district to which they moved for not longer than four weeks in all, even if it has not been possible to assign them suitable work. * '!' * Under article 8, the terms of which were made stricter, the local authorities were require(\ to refuse or withdraw assistance if the unemployed :person declined to accept work assigned to him. But more 1mportant than the change in the r~ations was the fact that the new order fixed maximum benefits liy adding the fol)owing provision to article 9: ' The relief may be granted by the communes and communal unions only for the six week days and may not exceed, exclusive of the famill all9wances, one and one-half times the amount of the local wage nor the JD&XImum rates prescribed for the various localities according to their grouping in the locality classes. Notwithstanding the provisions in paragi:aph 1, sentence 2, of article 9, maximum daily rates were fixed as follows: TABLII 5&-MAXIMUM DAILY RATES OF UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEI' IN LOCALITIES 01' SPECIFIED CLASSES FOR PERSONS IN SPECil'IED AGE GROUPS Place of residence: Localities of olasa- ~==:?::;.;,.is::::::::: ..............:::::::::::::::-: Males over lf to 16 years••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ~==rs t~\,ems..................................... l!'emales over H to 16 yems----····················· A B C DandB Mart, Marti Marti Marti 6.00 f.26 2.1111 3.1111 2.1111 2.00 6.00 8. 50 2.26 3.00 2.26 L75 f.00 3.00 2.00 2.50 2.00 L76 3.60 2.50 1. 76 2.26 L76 LIIII Maximum daily family allowances were also fixed as follows: T4BLB 56.-MAXIMUM DAILY l'AMILY ALLOWANCES IN LOCALITIES OF SPECIFIED CLASSES Placeofresldence:LocalltlesofClasBPersona for whom granted WUe. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Childrenandotherdependents................................. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis A B C DandB Marta Marta Marta Mara 1. liO 1.00 l. liO 1.00 1. 26 1.00 1. 00 • 71 UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF 151 The locality class register established for the granting of housing allowances to Government employees deternnnes the grouping of the various localities in locality Classes A to E. The decree of January 15, 1920, suspended the payment of unemployment benefits to J>ersons under ll>_y~ars of age and increased the allowances to be paid to females. While those over 21 years of age had received from 2.25 to 3.50 marks per day they were thereafter to receive, if they were not living in the liousehold of another person, from 3 to 5 marks and if they were living in the household of another person, from 2.50 to 4.25 marks. Fem~es under 21 years were to get from 2 to 3 marks. The combined family allowances drawn by an unemployed person were not to exceed one and one-half times the amount of the unemployment donation which the unemployed received for himself and in no case more than from 1.75 to 2.50 marks for the wife and from 1.25 to 1.75 marks for each child and other family member he was legally obligated to support. The new regulation went into force on February 1, 1920. As the cost of Jiving was almost three times as high as in February, 1919, and as wages had in the meantime at least doubled, the unemployment benefit, which for males had not been altered, was extremely low. An adult employee with a wife and two children received, for example, in Berlin from February to April a weekly unemployment allowance of 72 marks, while the weekly minimum cost of subsistence for a family of four in the same three months was 254, 322, and 375 marks, and the weekly wages of bricklayers 185, 205, and 253 marks, and those of printers 161 marks. New aecrees increasing the unemployment benefit (in paper marks) were issued on May 6 and October 13, 1920, on November 1 and December 7, 1921, and on February 8, 1922. But with the ever-increasing monetary depreciation it became necessary to simplify the proceedings to change the amount of benefits, and the decree of March 21, 1922, provided that the maximum rates of the unemployment benefits and the family allowances should thereafter be fixed by the Minister of Labor conjoint~ with the Minister of Finances and with the approval of the Reichsrat. Table 57 contains all the changes that occurred from February 1, 1920, until December, 31, 1924. The rates given are for the lowest {D and E) and the highest {A) locality classes. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 152 TABLE CHAPTEll VIl._.:.UNEMPLOYMENT 57.--'MAXIMUM DAILY RATES OF UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF, FEBRUARY 1, 1920, TO DECEMBER 31, 1924 Males Over 21 years of age Period beginning- Not members of another household ;Feb. 1, 1920... --···-··-Apr. 30, 1920___ ·--·-·--Nov .. i, 1920-·---------Aug. 5, 1, 192L 1921----·------Dec. ____________ Feb. 13, lij22__ __________ Aug. 14, 1922.----·--·--Nov. 20, 1922.-"······-" Dec. 25, 1922_·-······-·· Jan. 15, 1923.·--·····-·Jan. --····-·--Feb. 29, 12; 1923 1923_______ , _____ Apr. 16, 1923 ____________ May 14, 1923 ___________ June 4, 1923_____________ June 25, 1923 ____________ July 9, 1923 _____________ July 18, 1923_"---------,July 30, 1923 ____________ Aug. 6,,1923 ____________ Aug. 8, 1923_ .. _________ Aug. 15, 1923, __________ Aug. Aug. 22, 29, 1923-,--------1923 ___________ Sept. 5, 1923------~----Sept. 12, 1923 ___________ Sept. 19, 1923 _-·······-Sept. 1923 _---·-····Oct. 3,26,1923 _____________ Oct. 10, 192lL ___________ Oct. 15, 1923 ____________ Oct. 22, 1923 ____________ Oct. 29, 1923 ____________ -----------Nov. 5, 1923 Nov. 12, 1923 ___________ Nov. 19, 1923 ___________ Dec.District 10, 1923:r_ __________ Under 21 years of age Marks Marks Marks 3.506. 00 8.00 5.0010.00 7.008.2512. 00 11. 2515. 00 18. 00 12. 5028.00 18. 75140 100 255 360 425 600 510 720 1,500 1,200 1,950 2,400 3,200 2,600 5,000 3,950 9,000 7,100 12,800 16,200 16,100 20,000 27,000 33,000 72,000 90,000 225,000 180,000 530,000 650,000 820,000 -1,000, 000 I, 290,000 -1, 570,000 2,000,000 -2, 450,000 6,000,000 -7,500,000 117 21.5 I 33 42 I 48 60 q35 165 1960 1,200 10. 5 '8.4 21 ' 16. 8 2 108 135 2 330 420 2 630 780 3.5o6.00 4.5Q7.00 5.508. 00 7.0010.00 12. r,o 8. 7510.0015. 00 10.0015.00 70 100 175 200 290 415 300 500 1,000 1,300 1,650 2,100 2,200 2,800 3,500 4,400 6,300 7,900 14,200 11,300 17,500 13,900 29,000 23,000 60,000 75,000 155,000 185,000 420,000 540,000 650,000 830,000 I, 020, 000 -1, 300,000 I, 610,000 -2, 030, 000 4,800,000 -6,000, 000 114 17 127.5 33. 5 I 39 48 1100 130 1960 1,200 IO. 5 •s.4 2 16. 8 21 '108 135 '330 420 2 630 780 2.5o4.25 3.005.00 4.006.00 5.007.25 8. r,o 6.257.0010.00 7.0010. 00 r,o 35 125 85 .., 140 210 170 200 750 900 1,150 1,450 1,500 1,950 2,450 3,050 4,400 5,500 7,900 9,900 9,800 .12, 200 16,000 20,500 42,000 M,000 105,000 135,000 300,000 390,000 460,000 - 600,000 720,000 - 940,000 1,100,000 -1, 460,000 3,600,000 -4, 500,000 110 13 1 20.525 1 27 36 170 100 1570 720 2 5.1 6. 3 •10.212. 6 81 '66 I 190 250 470 '380 ------ --- .- -- ---- ·--- 1490 District IL---·---District III.. -- ---M·ayDIBtrict 51 1924:1___________ . 2 550 2 630 -- Rentenmarks IIL-------- 1 610 700 780 -------- ---- '490 I 550 2 630 --- 610 700 780 Rentenmarks o. 60--0. 75 --- -------- 2300 330 '380 I --- Rentenmarks .66- .84 • 72-- . 90 0. 36--0. 44 .41-. 50 .42-. 54 • 72-- . 90 • 79-1. 00 .86-1. 10 • 72-- • 90 .42-- . 54 .48- .60 • 79-1. 00 . 91-1.15 1. 01-1. 25 • 79-1.00 • 91-1.15 1. 01-1. 25 0. 60--0. 75 .66- .84 • 72--. 90 District II.--------District IIL---r··Aug.District 11, 1924:I_ __________ District n __________ District IIL. _______ Dec. 15, 1924: District II L---------District __________ District https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Members of another household Millions. • 79-1. 00 • 86-1.10 I BiIIlons. .54-.66 .48- .60 .54-.69 .60-. 75 360 420 470 153 UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF TABLE 37.-MAXIMUM DAILY RATES OF UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF FEBRUARY 1, 1920, TO DECEMBER 31, 1924-Continued Females Over 21 years of age Period beginning- Not members of another household Members of another household Under 21 years of age .Mark, Marki Marki Feb. 1, 1920_____________ 2. 503. 005. 00 ~26 2. 003.00 ~ - 30, 1920____________ 3. 756. 00 2. 505. 00 2. 003. 00 5. 758. 00 3.506.00 ov. 1, 1, 192L 1920-----------3. 00~00 Aug. ___________ 10.00 5. 007. 007.26 3.25~75 Dec. 5, 1921-____________ 12. 50 6. 258. 758. 50 ~757.00 Feb. 13, 1922____________ 15.00 7. 0010. 0010.00 5.258. 00 Aug. 14, 1922____________ 15. 0022. 50 7.0010.00 5.258. 00 Nov. 20, 1922 ___________ 110 50 80 65 26 40 Dec. 26, 1922____________ 120 165 275 200 70 100 1an. 15, 1923 ____________ 460 200 335 275 115 165 550 240 400 330 140 1an. 200 Feb. 29, 12, 1923-----------1923____________ 1,300 950 1,000 1,100 650 800 ~r.16, 1923 ____________ 2,100 1,450 1,650 1,750 1,000 1,300 ay 14, 1923____________ 2,800 1,900 2,350 2,200 1,450 1,750 1une 4, 1923_____________ 4,400 2,900 3,500 3,650 2,150 2,750 1une 26, 1923____________ 7,900 5,200 6,300 6,600 3,900 5,000 1uly 9, 1923 _____________ 9,400 11,300 14,200 11,900 7,000 9,000 1uly 18, 1923 ____________ 12,000 13,900 17,500 15,000 9,000 11,000 1uly 30, 1923 ____________ 29,000 20,000 23,000 25,000 15,000 18,000 Aug. 6, 1923_____________ 75,000 48,000 60,000 60,000 34,000 43,000 Aug. 8, 1923_____________ 120,000 150,000 155,000 185,000 90,000 105,000 Aug. 15, 1923____________ 540,000 350,000 440,000 420,000 240,000 300,000 Aug. 22, 1923____________ 830,000 540,000 650,000 680,000 370,000 460,000 Aug. 29, 1923____________ 1,020,000 -1,300,000 850,000 -1,070,000 580,000 720,000 Sept. 5, 1923 ____________ 1,610,000 -2, 030, 000 1,300,000 -1,660,000 910, 000 -1, 120, 000 Sept. 12, 1923 ___________ 4,800,000 3,950,000 -6, 000, 000 -6,000,000 2, 750, 000 -3, 500, 000 Sept. 19, 1923 ___________ 111 1 8.5114 17 14 10 Sept. 26, 1923 ___________ 122 33. 5 127.5 28 115 111./l Oct. 3, 1923 _____________ 139 131 122 40 48 28 Oct. 10, 1923 ____________ l 80 160 110 1100 130 75 l 780 1780 1440 960 960 Oct. 15, 1923 -------- ___ 560 Oct. 22, 1923 ____________ 8. 4 • 6. 6 • 6. 6 8. 4 ~9 '4 Oct. 29, 1923 ____________ 16.8 '13. 2 '13.2 16.8 9.8 '8 Nov. 5, 1923 ____________ 108 108 '87 '87 63 '51 Nov. 12, 1923 ___________ • 280 • 280 1 170 340 340 200 Nov. 19, 1923 ___________ • 500 1300 620 620 '500 360 Dec.District 10, 1923; J ___________ 490 490 '400 280 '400 '220 District IL _________ 560 560 '440 '440 '270 330 District III__ _______ 1300 620 620 '500 '500 360 May 5, 1924: District I__ ________ .Rentenmarka .Rentenmarka Rentenmarka District rr __________ 0.48-0. 60 0 .48-0.60 0. 28--0. 34 District III _________ ,55- .67 .55- .67 ,31- .40 Aug, 11, 19'J4: ,56-.71 .56-.71 ,32- .41 District L---------District II_. _________ ,65- .80 ,65- .80 .38- .48 District IIL •• ______ .90 .72-.90 .43- .55 Dec.District 15, 1924:J.. __________ • 79-1.00 • 79-1.00 •.s- .60 District rr___________ .72- .90 .72-.90 .43-. 55 District fil __________ ,83-1.04 .83-1. 04 ,50- .62 • 91-1.12 ,91-1.12 • 53-- • 68 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis -- --------- --------- --- --- --- ---- ------ --------- - -- - - ,.72- I Millions, I Billions. 154 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT TABLE 57.-MAXIMUM DAILY RATES OF UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF, FEBRUARY 1, 1920, TO DECEMBER; 31, 1924-Concluded Family allowance forPeriod beginningChildren and other dependents Consort Feb. 1, 1920 _______________________________________ _ Apr. 30 1920 _______________________________________ _ Nov. 1, 1920_______________________________________ _ Aug. 1, 1921. ______________________________________ _ Dec. 5, 1921. _-------------------------------------Feb. 13, --------------------------------------_ Aug. 14, 1922_ 1922 ______________________________________ Nov. 20, 1922_ -------------------------------------Dec. 15, 25, 1923 1922--------------------------------------_ Jan. _______________________________________ Jan. 29, 1923 _______________________________________ _ Feb. 12, 1923 ______________________________________ _ Apr. 16, --------------------------------------_ May 14, 1923_ 1923 ______________________________________ June 4, 1923 _--------------------------------------June 9, 25,1923 1923 _--------------------------------------_ July ________________________________________ July 18, 1923 _______________________________________ _ July 30, 1923 _______________________________________ _ Aug. 6, 1923 _______________________________________ _ Aug. 8, 1923 _______________________________________ _ Aug. 15, 1923. _____________________________________ _ Aug. 22, 1923 ______________________________________ _ Aug. 29, 1923 ______________________________________ _ Sept. 5, 1923 _______________________________________ _ Marks 1. 75-2. 50 2. 25-3.00 3. 25-4. 00 3. 505. 00 4. 75-7. 00 5. 508. 75 8. 5013. 00 50 65 120 165 200 275 240 330 550 700 700 850 850 1,150 1, 550 1, 850 2, 800 3, 300 5, 000 5, 900 6, 000 7, 500 10, 000 12, 500 27, 000 33, 000 65, 000 80, 000 170, 000 - 230, 000 260, 000 - 350, 000 410, 000 - 550, 000 620, 000 - 860, 000 2, 150,000 -2, 750, 000 16.58 1 12. 5 15. 5 116 22 145 60 1 350 440 '3 3.9 26 7.8 '39 48 2]20 150 '170 200 ~::. g; !t:______________________________________ _ Sept. 26, 1923______________________________________ _ Oct. 3, -----------------------------_ Oct. 10,1923 1923____________ _______________________________________ Oct. 15, 1923 _______________________________________ _ Oct. 22, 1923 _______________________________________ _ Oct. 29, 1923 _______________________________________ _ Nov. 5, 1923 _______________________________________ _ Nov. 12, 1923 ______________________________________ _ Nov. 19, 1923 ______________________________________ _ Dec.District 10, 1923:I ____________________________________ _ DistrictUIll --------------------------_________ __ Disttrict __________________________________ May 5, 1924: District L ___________________ ------------- ----District IL ___ -------------- __________________ _ District UL __________________________________ _ Aug. 11, 1924: District L ____________ ----- ------------ _------District IL __ ----------------------------- ____ _ District UL __ --------------------------------Dec. 15, 1924: District L __ ----------------------------------District ----------------------------------_ District IL UL____________________________________ 1 Millions. '130 2 160 '170 - 160 190 200 Rentenmarks 0. 17--0. 20 .19- . 22 .20- .23 Marks 1. 25-1. 75 1. 25-2. 00 2. 25-3. 00 3. 504. 25 4. 506. 00 5. 507. 00 8. 25-11. 25 35 50 85 125 140 210 170 250 450 600 550 700 800 950 1, 150 1, 450 2, 100 2, 600 3, 800 4, 700 4, 800 6, 000 8, 000 10, 000 21, 000 27, 000 50, 000 65, 000 130, 000 - 190, 000 200, 000 - 290, 000 315, 000 - 455, 000 500, 000 - 710, 000 1, 800, 000 -2, 250, 000 I 5 6.5 19.512.5 115 18 135 50 I 300 360 1 2.5 3.1 25 6.2 134 40 '100 130 2 120 150 '90 '110 2 120 - 120 140 150 Rentenmarks 0. 12--0. 15 .14- .17 .15-- .18 .24- .30 .29- .35 .29- .38 .19-. 22 .19- .25 .21-. 27 .29- .35 .31- .40 .35-- .44 .19- . 25 .23-.29 .25--. 31 •Billions. The decree of May 6, 1920, suspended the provision that the relief should not exceed one and one-half times the amount of the local wage and introduced the distinction for unemployed men over 21 years of those living and those not living in the household of another person, which distinction had formerly prevailed only for women. The decree of October 13, 1920, provided that from and after November 1, 1920, the combined family allowances granted to an unemployed person should not exceed 200 per cent (theretofore 150 per cent) of the benefit he would draw for himself. These family allowances were also graded in a different way, the higher .rates applying to the consort and the children up to 16 years of age and the lower rates applying only to" other dependents." The decree of November 1, 1921, reintroduced the old classes. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF 155 The order of August 1, 1922, provided that the combined family allowances should not exceed 300 per cent of the benefit which the unemployed would draw for himself. The order of June 8, 1923, reduced this to 200 per cent. The order of November 9, 1923, reduced it to 100 per cent, the order of February 14, 1924, raised it to 150 per cent. The order of August 1, 1924, again reduced it to 100 per cent, but only in case the combined fanuly allowances together with the b!lnefit draWI?- b[ the unemployed person would equal the average net mcome of sum ar groups of employees. The same order provided that unemployed females over 21 years of age who prove that other family members depend upon them for a living shall get the same benefits as males over 21 years of age; in such cases, however, the combined family allowances should not exceed 100 per cent of the benefit which the unemployed would draw for herself. By order of October 19, 1923, the distinction between adults living and those not living in the household of another person was eliminated. The order of December 11, 1923, introduced a subdivision into three "economic districts": District I, comprising Eastern Germany; District II, Central Germany; and District III, Western Germany. The locality classes were maintained, so that there were from then on, so to speak, 12 locality classes. Table 58 shows the maximum weekly unemployment benefits, including family allowances, of a man with a wife and two children, living in a city of locality class A, and the minimum cost of subsistence of a family of four (father, mother, and two children from 6 to 10 years) in Greater Berlin: TABLE 58.-MAXIMUM WEEKLY UNEMPLOYMENT BENEFITS AND MINIMUM COST OF SUBSISTENCE FOR A FAMILY OF FOUR IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, 1920, TO DECEMBER, 1924 Period 1920 January••••••........••.•••.•••••••• February ••.•••..•...•.•.••.•••...•. March •••.••.••••••••.•••••• · ••• · · · • April 1 to April 29•••••.•..••.•.••••• April 30 to May 31. ••..•..•••••.••.• lune •••••••••••••.•••••••.••.•.....• July.••••••••••............•.•••••••• August•••..•.••.•••.•..••.•......... September ••••......•..........••.•• October ....••.•.••.•...•..••....•... November •••....•.•......•.•••.•••• December••••••.••.....••••••••••... 1921 January.•••••••.•••••.••.••••••••••. Maximum unemploy• ment beneftts January ..............•..••••••••. 90. 00 90. 00 90.00 90. 00 90. 00 132. 00 132. 00 July•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• August ••••.•..••....•..•........... September••...........•.........•. October.•..•.•.••.•••••.••......... November •....••.•.•••..•••......• December.••.•..•.••••••.••.......• February ..........•..•.••.••••.... March ••.•.•.•••••••••.• · ••••...... ~: ~ tfa~L:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June •......•...•.•..•..•..•••.••..• 132. 00 132. 00 132. 00 July ·•••••••••••••••••••••••• ••••••• August ..•..•..•..................... September •••••••••••••••••.•.•••••• October ••••••••.•..•••.••.•••.••.••. November 1 to December 4 .••....•. December 5 to December 31••••••••• 132. 00 132. 00 153. 00 153. 00 153. 00 153. 00 204. 00 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1920 Marb 57.00 72. oo 72.00 February ••••••..•..........•••••••• March ••••••....••.••..•..•..•.••••• t!!! ::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Period ~~ ~ ••••.••.1.~1•••.•.•••.••..... I January February .•.....•..•..•.•...••.•... March •••.•.•...•.....•.....••..•.. tfar:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June •••..................•..••••••• July•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• August•••••••••••••••••..•••...•... September••.•..•.••••••••.•••.•••• October..••••...............••.•••• November •..••.......•.....•.••.•• December•••••••••••••••••••••••••• Minimum cost of subsistence Marb 220.00 254.00 322.00 375.00 365.00 304.00 324.00 308.00 299.00 318. 00 316.00 327.00 320.00 313.00 298. 00 281. 00 285. 00 311.00 324.00 339.00 349. 00 386. 00 509.00 557.00 156 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT 'l'ABL• 18.-MAXIMUM WEEKLY UNEMPLOYMENT BENEnTS AND MINIMUM COST OJ' SUBSISTENCE FOR A FAMILY OF FOUR IN GREATER BERLIN, JANUARY, 1920. TO DECEMBER, 11124-0onoluded ·.1. Period Maximum unemploy• ment benet\ts l'erlod ·1022 Jlarb 1922 ii BI&11~························~· January 1 to Febroar,- 12••••••••••• February 18 to February 28 ••••••••• March •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 253. 50 263. liO 263. 50 253. 50 tf:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June ••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•••• July 1 to August 13 ••••••••••••••••• Augoat 14' to Augost.31•••••••••••••• Sjlptember•••••••••••••••••••••••••• October 1 to October 16••••••••••••• October JI to October 31 •••••••••••• November 1 to November 19•••••••• November 28 to November 30••••••. December 1 to December 15••••••••• December 16 to December :M..:•••••• December 25 to December 31•••••••• 381. 00 381. 00 381. 00 381. 00 381. 00 1,830.00 1, 830. 00 1, 830. 00 4,,650.00 1923 January 1 to January 14.............. January 15 to January 28............ January 29 to February 11.......... February 12 to February 28. •••••••• March 1 to March 16................ March 16 to March 31............... April 1 to April 16................... Ai>rll 16 to April 30.................. May 1 to May 13................... May H to June 3••••• s.............. June• to June 16.................... June 16 to June 2'.................... June 25 to June 30................... July 1 to July 8 •• ••••••••••••••••••• July 9 to July 15.................... July 16 to July 29................... July 80 to August II................. August 6 to August 7•••••••••••••••• August 8 to August 14................ August 16 to August 21._........... August 22 to August 28.............. August 29-to September 4'........... September 6 to September 11........ September 12 to September 18....... September 19 to September 25....... September 26 to October 2.. •••••••• October 3 to October 9. ••••••••••••• October 10 to October 14'.. •••••••••• 4c, 650. 00 7, 770. 00 9,300.00 20, 400. 00 20, 400. 00 20, 400. 00 20, 400. 00 '.¥1, llOD. 00 '.¥1, llOD. 00 37, 600. 00 58,600.00 68,600.00 105,000.00 105, 000. 00 189,000.00 237,000.00 3113, 000. 00 1, 062, 000. 00 2, 610, 000. 00 7,660,000.00 11, 580, 000. 00 18,180,000.00 28, 380, 000. 00 88, 0001000. 00 255 I 496 g:::= ~: g=: ~:::::::::::: October 29 to November 4........... November 5 to November 11........ November 12 to November 18....... November 19 to November 30....... December 1 to December 9.......... December 10 to December 31........ 1924 ~::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ,April 1 to May 4•••••••••••••••••••• I 708 I I 1, 960 I~ 1, 6 • 24'7. 2 '1,578 1 4c, 980 • 7,680 I 7. 68 I 7. 02 May 5 to May 31 ••••••••••••••••••• June •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• July 1 to August 10•••••••••••••••••• August 11 to August 31••••••••••••~. September•••••••••••••••••••••••••• Octol)Ar •••••••••••••••••••••••••• November 1 to December M•••••••• December 16 to December 31. ••••••• I Millions. ,April••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• May ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• June............................... • July··············---······ August.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••• September••••••••••••••••••••••••• October 1 to October lli••••••••.••·• October 16~ October 81 ••••••••••• November 1 to November 15••••••• November16toNovember80 •••• - . December 1 to December 16•••••••• December 16 to December 31.•••••• 1923 l_K_ __ January 1 to January January 16 to January 31..••••••••• February 1 to February 15•••••••• ~ February 16 to February 28 •••••••• March 1 to March 16 ~ •• March 16 to March 31-•••••••••••• April 1 to April 15•••••••••••••••••• April 16 to April 30••••••••••••••••• May 1 to May 15•••••••••••••••••• May 16 to May 31 ••••••••••••••••• June 1 to June 16••••••••••••••••••• June 16 to June 30•••••••••••••••••• 8.40 uo 8.40 lLl0 lLl0 lLl0 lLl0 12, 78 1 Jlarb 1148.00 6'.¥1.00 789.00 916.00 1)1)6.00 1,196.00 1,763.00 . 2,968.00 . .. 714.l)O 6,136.00 8,871.00 13,238.00 19,303.00 24,,395.00 25,579.00 July 1 to July 15 ••••••••••••••••••• S0,383.00 4,3,821.00 81,671.90 80,350.00 77, 74'1.00 72,483.00 7o,832.00 78, 71LOO 107,821.00 186, .... 00 198,676.00 306, 4'88. eo . 688, li89. 00 July 16 to July 31 •••••••••••••••••• August 1 to August 16•••••••••••••• II, 24'5, 689. 00 August 16 to August 3,.___ _ _ • 24', 822,120.00 1, 201, 761. 00 September 1 to September 15....... 17o, 620,606.00 September 16 to September 30•••••• 1683.3 October 1 to October 16 •••••••••••• 17,184.9 October 16 to October 31 ••••••••••• 1266, liS8 November 1 to November 16••••••• 14,,4'98.8 November 16 to November 30•••••• December 1 to December 15•••••••• December 16 to December 31••••••• 135,ssi.-11 Rmu,unarb 7.02 7.02 7.02 7.02 Minimum OOfit of .. BUblllstence 1924 &11~:::::::::::::::::::::. :::: tFar:·:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: June ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• July ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• August. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••• ~ct~ber::::::::::::::::::::::::: November_ ••••••••••••••••••••••••• December _ _ _ __ Billlons. I •33.M • 28. 73 R,nt,nmort, '.¥1.74' 26. 511 26.91 28.4'9 29.29 28.43 29.28 28.81 29. 78 3L30 3L22 3L18 Bentemnarlm. In comparing the two sets of fu?ures, it must be borne in mind that in the time of rapid monetary a:e_preciation everything depends on the day the benefits were actually paid. Very often tlie decree which raised the benefits for a certain period was issued in the middle https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 157 UNEMPLOYMENT BEL1E1!' of that period, and so the increased benefits were _paid when the money liad lost part of its value. 1 The "real" allowances were thus smaller than one might judge from the table. Most of the time these allowances were, however, very small, even when the day of payment is not taken into account. In general the allowances furnished onlx. between one-fourth and one-third of the minimum cost of subsiste:dce. The proportion was higher only from November, 1920, to October, 1921, from December, 1921, to February, 1922, in the second half of April, 1923, during some days in August and September, 1923, and from August 11, 1924, on. But in certain other periods it was much smaller. From September 1922, tmtil Christmas of that :year the unemployment allowances did not cover even one-tenth of the minimum cost of subsistence, and in the :first half of November, 1922, not even one-thirtieth. Early statistics of the persons receiving unemployment benefits are incomplete. From May to December, 1919, reports are available only for some cities and one must resort to estimates in order to get a notion of the amount of unemployment which then prevailed. From March 1, 1923, to April 15, 1924, no figures are available for the occupied territory. Table 59 shows, for 1918 to 1924, the number of totally unemployed workers receiving unemployment benefits, by sex, the number of dependents of such unemployed for whom an allowance was paid, and the number of short-time workers assisted, so far as data are available. TABLE 59.-NUMBER OF PERSONS RECEIVING UNEMPLOYMENT BENEFITS, DECEMBER 1, 1918, TO DECEMBER 15, lll'l4 Date Totally unemployed workers Number receiving benefits of deShortpendents time i - - - - - , - - - - , - - - - 1 for whom workers allow• receiving Males Females Total benefits made ances 1918 Deo. ,..________________________________ ---------- ---------- liOl, 610 ---------- ---------- 1919 1an. L----------------------------------------------- ---------- ---------- 905,137 ---------- ---------Feb. 1----------------------------------------------- ---------- ---------- 1,076,368 ---------- ---------Mar. 1----------------------------------------------- ---------- ---------- 1,003,854 ---------- ---------- Mi! i-============================================== ========== ========== aa Nov. 1----------------------------------------------- ---------- ---------- liOO, 000 ---------- ---------470,000 ---------- _________ _ ========== ========== iDec. )-:1----------------------------------------------: : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : : :__________ : : : : :__________ : : : : i ffl :::::::::: :::::::::: 1920 1an. 15---------------------------------------------347,783 Feb. 1----------------------------------------------- 333,204 Mar. 1----------------------------------------------- 287,531 tray½::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: =: ~ lune 1----------------------------------------------- 209,930 1uly 1----------------------------------------------- 240,812 Aug. 1----------------------------------------------- 294,747 Sept. 1----------------------------------------------- 309,579 Oct.1----------------------------------------------- 301,809 Nov. 4----------------------------------------------- 282,126 Dec. l ----------------------------------------------- 277,007 106,1192 97,562 82,765 :: ~ 454,775 430, 766 370,296 :i ::~ 271,660 379,071 _________ _ 392,321 ---------- 849,381 ---------- =:256,840:: :::::::::: _________ _ 61,730 82,111 322,923 293,520 ---------109,088 403,835 370,015 _________ _ 105,022 414,601 387, 2M ---------· 91,014 392,823 362,423 ---------79,185 361,311 345,646 _________ _ 73,080 300,087 352,875 ---------1 For e:mmnle, the benefits were raised by order of Aug. 4, 1923, as from Aug. 6, and by order of Aug. 14 for the period beglmrlng Aug. 8 and ending Aug. 14. 20168°-25t-11 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 158 CHAPTER VII.-UNEM:PLOYMENT TABLE 59.-NUMBER OF PERSONS RECEIVING UNEMPLOYMENT BENEFITS. DECEMBER 1, 1918, TO DECEMBER 15, 1924--0oncluded Date Totally unemployed workers Number receiving benefits of deShorlipendents time 1 for whom workers allow• receiving Males Females Total ances benefits -----------1 made 1921 Jan. 1 ...•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Feb. 1 •.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Mar. 1.............................................. . 334,912 347,974 346,532 333,630 f!i~ L:::::·:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 313,653 282,468 244,067 204,185 176,595 11:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 142,759 Nov. 1••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 113,672 Dec. 1 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 114,339 July 1 ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Aug. 4••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• t4;,¥t 1922 Jan.1 ••••••••••••••••••.••••.••••••••••••••••••••••• Feb.1 ••••••.••••••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Mar. 1. ............................................. . 132,223 171,517 182,629 94,711 49,191 June 1 •••.•••••••••.•••.•••..•••....•••.•..•.••••••.. 20,136 July 1 ••••••••••••.••.••••..•...••.••••••..•••••••••• 13,781 10,603 Aug. 1. ............................................. . 7,946 Sept. 1••••••••••••••••.••••••••••...•.•.•••.••••••.•• Oct. 1 .•.......•••..•...........................•.... 12,054 Nov. L ...••••.••••••••••••...•..•.••..•..••.•••••••• 19,297 Dec. 1 •••••••••••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••• 34,463 t/':y l::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: 1923 Jan. 1............................................... 71,429 Feb. 1............................................... 129,405 Mar. 1............................................... 165,089 ~~: t/':y ½.-:.:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: i: June 1............................................... 211,863 June 15.............................................. 181,893 July 1 •• ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 152,081 July 15 •• •••••••••·••••••·······•··•••••••••••••••••• 133,084 Aug. L ••••••••••••.••••••.•••••.•••....••.•••••••••• 111,457 Aug. 15.............................................. 116,323 Sept. 1.. •• • ••• ••••.•• ••• .• • •• • • • ••• •• •• ••• ••••• ••••• 202, 512 m: m ~tit 115 .~::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Oct. 15.. .•••••••.•••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 575,650 NOV. L... ••• •••••. .•• • ••• •. • ... ••••• ••• •. ••• •• •••••. 784, 690 Nov. in ..•••••••••.•••••••••••••••••••••••.•.•.••••• 1,028,563 Dec. L •••••••••.............•..........••••••••.... 1,190,543 Dec. 15•••••••••••.•••••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••• 1,216,639 1924 Jan. l .•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1,2'12,997 Jan.15 ••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••. 1,351,895 Feb.1 •••••••••••••••••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••• 1,258,948 Feb. 15 ••••••••••••.•••••••.•••••••••..•.•••••••••••• 1,162,091 l 75,326 75,190 80,068 79,691 80,609 74,884 70,408 62,923 55,462 43,047 36,432 34,998 410,238 423,164 426,600 413,321 394,262 357,352 314,475 267,108 232,057 185,806 150,104 149,337 458,924 499,140 494,738 468,148 444,357 384,683 339,008 300,856 253,431 208,326 165,194 172,510 33,025 31,077 29,897 21,134 15,517 8,490 5,867 4,534 8,725 4,624 li,516 8,437 165,248 202,594 212,526 115,845 64,708 28,626 19,648 15,137 11,671 16,678 24,813 42,900 210,468 288,030 308,265 157,699 79,855 35,824 25,339 18,611 13,308 21,028 28,068 50,638 13,989 85,418 106,108 20,815 150,220 190,336 24,919 190,008 240,253 33,735 222,410 273,229 43,270 266,966 312,282 41,666 253,529 279,683 38,055 219,948 239,362 33,901 185,982 189,471 30,724 163,808 159,907 27,559 139,016 138,257 31,020 147,343 147,260 46,680 249,192 248,616 70,962 384,439 379,015 94,996 534,360 543,582 121,425 697,075 701,451 169,974 954,664 962,181 236,941 1,265,504 1,257,113 283,145 1,473,688 1,447,644 271,532 1,488,171 1,470,375 260,498 238,155 180,832 145,145 112,555 83,975 159,434 141,362 l 43,558 1 26,720 I 32,127 I o0, 723 I 61,185 :!5:m 1 • ~p~· 0 ~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: tf:Y is:::::::~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: :~ g~ June 1. ••••••••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••••• t 375,238 July L ••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•.••••••••••••••••• l 394,293 Aug. 1............................................... I 475,465 Sept. L... ••• ••••• .•• •• • • • • •• ..•. ••• ••. . •• •..••••••• 1 527, 300 Sept. 15.... •••••••••.•.........•••••.•.....••••••••• 1 517, 704 8~t k::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: :~: ~ Nov.1-•••••••••••••••••••••.....••••.•••...••••••••• •396,193 Nov. 15••••••••••••.........•... ··•·• ... .. . .•••••.... 1 388, 890 E:: k::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ::gg; ;: I 58,886 50,403 145,662 139,128 137,492 135,916 137,416 l t Includes also figures for short-time workers receiving benefit. • Included in figures for totally unemployed workers receiving benefit. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1,533,495 1,590,050 1,439,780 1,307,236 1,167,785 975,885 I 694,559 I 475,988 I 571,783 1401,958 I 426,420 I 526,188 :m;:gg 513,496 1473,023 t 435,321 I 426,382 1436,607 1458, 125 I 1,572,403 1,690,214 1,592,549 1,481,018 1,378,143 1,182,248 865,332 577,945 722,562 659,248 596,888 555,869 550,190 571,582 605,938 125,352 379,620 412,304 300,536 259,875 254,833 191,632 210,774 526,010 934,731 1,158,061 1,476,437 1,719,738 1,816,979 1,795,824 1,227,628 849,162 624,932 363,634 252,328 149,871 90,006 (1) r ~ ~~ ~~ (') ~~ (l~ (I UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF 159 EXPENSES OP UNEM:PLOYIIENT RELID' Originally only such sums were considered unem~loYlll,ent relief ~8!18es as were actually paid to the persons assistea. The decree of March 14, 1919, however, provided that expenses of administration should also be included. Previous to the regulation of October, 1923, the funds for unemployment relief were contributed.z in fixed proportions, by the Federal Government, the States, anc1 the communes concerned, the Federal Government bearing one-half, the State one-third, and the communes the remaining one-sixth. In the case of communes of limited means the proportion borne by the Federal Government could be increased. By decree of October 13, 1923, the method of raising funds for unemployment relief was radically altered. 2 It seemed important that the funds for unemployment relief and for the public employment offices should come from the same source, such institutions being intimately connected and established in the same communes. The principal provisions of this decree are as follows: ARTICLE 1. The funds for carrying on the struggle against the scarcity of employment and for unemployment relief are to be raised, up to the limit fixed in article 2, by contributions of employers and employees and by ~ t s from the commune. In so far as the maximum contributions of employers, employees, and communes fail temporarily to cover the necessary expenditures in districts with extraordinarily serious unemployment, the Federal Government and the States shall make the necessary grants. ART. 2. All employees liable to compulsory sickness insurance under the Workmen's Insurance Code or to sickness insurance in a miners' fund, as well as their employers, are required to make contributions. The amount of such contributions is to be fixed by the administrative committee of the public employment office for its district in fractions of the contributions to sickness insurance. The contributions shall be so fixed as to cover four-fifths of the necessary expenditures for unemployment relief in the district of the employment office and of the necessary cost of the public employment office, but not to exceednotwithstandin!i the provision of article 6, paragraph 2-20 per cent of the contributions for B1ckness insurance. One-half of the contributions shall be paid by the employers and one-half by the emplo;rees. ART. 3. The contributions are to be paid m addition to the contributions for sickness insurance. * * * ART. 4. The commune (communes) which has established a public employment office shall contribute one-fifth of the necessary expenditures for unemployment relief in its district and one-fifth of the necessary cost of the public emplorment office, but not more than one-fourth of the combined contributions paid by the employers and employees under article 2, paragraph 3. * * * ART. 5. On unanimous resolution of the communes concerned, several public employment offices may form an association to bear the common risk of raising the necessary funds. * * * ART. 6. The grants necessary under article 1, paragraph 2, will be borne by the Federal Government and the State in equal parts. · The grants by the Federal Government and the States fall due only when the maximum contributions permissible under article 2, paragraph 3, have been collected for at least two weeks. This decree, which went into force November 1, 1923, was amended in some essential points by the decree of February 13 1 1924. The main changes were: 1. The amount of the contributions shall no longer be fixed in fractions of the contributions to sickness insurance out in fractions 1 Tbls' decree was Issued under the emergency law of the same date granting extraordinary powers to the Government but before the latter was_proclalmed. In order to avoid contests, the decree was reissued Olli. lo, and tbls ls the date which ls ofllolally quoted. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 160 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT of the basic wages (adopted for calculating sickness insurance contributions). This provision was to eliminate the advantages to those employers and employees whose sickness insurance fund did not raise the permissible maximum sickness insurance contributions. 2. The contributions shall be so fixed as to cover two-thirds of the necessary cost of the public employment office and eight-ninths of the necessary expenditures for unemployment relief in the district of the public employment office. They shall not, however, except for a period of two weeks, exceed 3 per cent of the basic wage. The commune shall bear the remaining one-third of the cost of the public employment office and one-ninth of the expenditure for unemployment relief, the Federal Government and the States making grants only in so far as the expenditures for unemployment relief after two. weeks are not covered by the contributions of the employers, the employees, and the communes. The Minister of Labor, moreover, may fix a higher percentage of the basic ·wage than 3 per cent as the contribution of employers and employees, and he may order, as from July 1 1924, that the contribution of the communes shall be increased up to one-sixth of the expenditure for unemrloyment relief. The ob3ect of these provisions was to lighten the financial burden of the communes but especially of the Federal Government and the States. · 3. The State governments and the Minister of Labor may order that the contributions of employers and employees shall be calculated on the total expenditure for unemployment relief in large districts or even in the whole of Germany. The object of this provision is the better distribution of the financial burden of unemployment. 4. The Minister of Labor may exempt certain occupations or groups of persons from contribution or may grade the contributions. In pursuance of the last provision, the Minister of Labor, by order of March 13, 1924, exempted the following persons from the payment of contributions: 1. Persons engaged in agriculture or forestry as workers during part of the year, in case they, at the same time, own or rent agricultural property of such size that it furnishes the principal means of supJ>ort for themselves and their family. 2. The consort and descendants of the persons mentioned in section 1, if they live under the same roof and are employed part of the year as workers in agriculture or forestry. 3. Workers who are engaged by contract of not less than a year's duration or for an indefinite period, in case the time allowed for giving notice without any sufficient reason is at least 6 months. The exemption ceases six months before the expiration of the contract, either by the expiration of the stipulated term or by the giving of regular notice. 13y order of May 24, 1924, persons engaged in river, lake, and offshore :fishery are also exempted, if they own or rent agricultural property of such size that it furnishes the principal means of support for themselves and their family. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis UNEMPLOYMENT RELIBF 161 The total expenses for unemployment relief and public employment offices in the five months from August to December, 1924, were as follows: August, 1924, 20,495,318 marks; September, 1924, 22,456,941 marks; October, 1924, 21,901,132 marks; November, 1924, 19,326,565 marks; December, 1924, 22,810,411 marks. • UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEF WORK Unemployment relief work was provided for by section 16 of the decree of January 15, 1920, authorizing the Minister of Labor, in furtherance of measures calculated to diminish the number of persons depending on unemployment relief, more especially by providing work for the unemployed, to grant loans and contributions out of the funds appropriated for unemployment relief, the amount of such loans and contributions being based on the number of persons thereby becoming independent of unemployment relief. The funds appropriated for unemployment relief work are raised in the same manner as those for unemployment relief-by the Federal Government, the States, and the communes concerned. Measures to be promoted under this section are, first of all, those considered profitable from the standpoint of J?Ublic economy. In such cases an application must be filed in which the nature and extent of the undertaking in question are accurately specified and the number of workmen who will thereby become independent of unemployment relief given, and an estimate of the cost involved presented. In case the commune does not itself intend to carry out the relief work, the application is presented by the commune to the competent department. The conditions under which the Federal Employment Office and the Minister of Finance are authorized to grant loans and contributions are specified in detail. The principal consideration is the saving of expense for unemployment relief by the relief work proposed. In the beginning the undertakings to be promoted were restricted to relief work undertaken by corporations invested with public authori~. Private enterprises expected to yield a profit are not as a rule to be promoted out of public funds and if so o:rily when the commune which supervises the undertaking is in a position to reduce the profit. Grants are to be made only to undertakings which produce goods of general utility. .An employer receiving a subsidy is required to supply the product of his undertaking at cost price. The period for repa_yment of the loans provided in the various decrees was of various lengths, being at first long, but later generally short. The installments and the rate of interest were at first calculated accurately, but as the German currency became more and more depreciated they were calculated in terms of the produce yielded by the undertaking, until finally, on May 16, 1923, the rate of discount used by the Reichsbank was taken as the standard, except in cases where the real value of the produce was taken as a basis, 5 per cent being paid as interest. As a rule loans and subsidies are to be given only for the current fiscal year, and even in case of exception not beyond the end of the current calendar year. Under section 32 of the decree of February 16, 1924, the expense of the unemployment relief work is shared by the Federal Government and the State concerned. More and more the assistance https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 162 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT granted for unemploYJ!l.ent relief work is beiilg extended to private enteryrises. This is done, however, as explained above, only on condition that, under the regulation of January 18, 1924, the product of the undertaking is employed for the public benefit, so that prices may to a. certain extent be artificially lowered. To receive loans or subsidies from the Government a private unde1-taking must employ at least 20 unemployed who have received unemployment relief for not less than two weeks and who could not expect to find other work for some time. They must be employed to such an extent that th~ will not become entitled ·to assistance for short hours. The undertakings started or promoted as unemplo_yment relief work are considered emergency work. An order issued on November 17, 1923, by the Minister of Labor, contains the following regulations regarding relief works: De.finition.-Relief works are undertakings subsidized by the unemplopnent relief fund. The obligatory work done by the unemployed under section 9, paragraph 2, of the decree of October 15, 1923, as an equivalent of the assistance the]' receive, is not regarded as relief work. Cla88ification.-Small relief works are undertakings subsidized by the unemployment relief work fund, the funds being raised by contributions of the employers and workmen. [Road repairs are considered as small relief works according to a circular of the Minister of Labor of February 16, 1924.] Large relief works are undertakings subsidized in addition by the State and the communes. Large relief works are started only in cases of the most urgent need and must give work to 2,000 uneml>!oyed who have received unemployment relief for not less than two weeks. The unemployed assisted must consti · ute at least 2 per cent of the population of the communes, and employers and workmen in the communes concerned must pay the maximum rates. Conditiom.-Workmen who are engaged on relief works nevertheless remain at the disposition of the employment office and may be recalled as soon as they have a chance for profitable work. In order that as many unemployed as possible may find work on the relief works, the working time must be shortened, and, if this is not sufficient, the men must work in shifts. At first (by decree of June 18 1920} fair wages according to the local rate were paid for relief work, but later on the rate was lowered. A low rate of wages is paid in order to make the men em_ployed on relief work anxious to find other employment for which they would receive the w~es customary in the locality or those fixed by collective agreement. For some time also the maximum rate of wages was uniformly fixed (in 1923); generally, however, this was left to the local authorities. • Amo11g relief works which the Minister of Public Works considers especially worth promoting are the following:_ . 1. Buil~ of electric lines and systems (high voltage lines up to 30,000 volts, transformer or converter stations, switching ~tations and low tension s~tems). 2. Building of houses. This does not refer to house building already subsidized by the Federal Government in one way or another. Not until the _grants for this purpose by the Federal Government are exhausted is the buil~ of liouses to be subsidized by the unemployment relief fund, and tlien only in case the available workmen are thereby distributed in a. manner advantageous to the builder or the nUID,ber given employment considerably increased. Concerns engaged exclusively in tlie manufacture of building materials or of doors, window frames, and the like are not to be subsidized except in the case of building enterprises of public utility which manufacture such parts for their own use. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis UNEMPLOYMENT RELIEJ!' 163 The building of residences for Government, etc., employees is also considered as deserving of encouragement by grants from the unemployment relief fund. The building of houses for rural laborers is to be J:>romoted as far as possible and for this purpose noninterestbearing loans are granted. Such houses may be built of wood, provided they are not mere temJ:>orary structures but are built to last for at least 30 years. These frame houses must conform to the building regulation and be well built and habitable in all seasons of the year. '"'.By means of noninterest-bearing loans running for 20 years, about 14,000 houses for rural laborers have thus far been built. Building trades workers are to be prevented, if possible, from leaving their _place of employment during the winter, and therefore their applications for unemployment relief are, as far as possible, to be granted and they are to be given special consideration as to the amount thereof and in the obtaining of employment. The railwa~ are allowed to diminish their force, transferring men to the building trade. Railway employees .who belong to the building trade are to be discharged and sent to the local employment exchange to obtain employment in their trade. Unemployed workers of all trades may be given a course of training for the purpose of transferring them to other trades, but for workers in tlie building trades the procedure is regulated in detail. In 1922 the following regulations were in force: (a) The transfer of unemployed workers to other trades will be carried out by a committee consisting of equal numbers of employers and employees, with the president of the employment office as chairman. The duties of this committee are selection of suitable workmen to be apprenticed to other trades and establishments or workshops in which they can be trained, approval and supervision of the course of training, and arbitration of matters relating to the apprenticeship contract. The committee is to fix the length of the training, distribute the funds granted for the training of apprentices, etc. (b) The workers to be apprenticed are to be selected from the following trades: Building laborers, stove fitters, joiners, and related trades. They must be unemployed or such workers as can be replaced by unemployed workers. Such apprentices are to be from 18 to 30 years of age. (c) Tlie length of the apprenticeship is to be fixed in each case according to circumstances; as a rule, one year for masons and one and one-half to two years for carpenters. (d) On principle apprentices are to be trained in workshops or industrial establishments, this practical training to be supplemented by theoretical instruction. A contract is to be entered into between tlie employer and the apprentices. At the end of the aJ:>prenticeship the aJ:>prentice must pass a test before a committee before being classea. as a journeyman. These conditions may be modified under certain conditions. (e) The apprentice is to receive the wages of a helper in the building trade under the collective agreement. The workshop or concern taking an apprentice is allowed a grant from the unemployment relief fund. One-half of this allowance is due when one-third of the apprenticeship is over, one-third when two-thirds of the term is over, and the remaining one-sixth at the end of the apprenticeship. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 164 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT In exceptional cases the grant may be used for the purchase of tools and working clothes. 3. In order to meet the ~eat demand for rural labor, em_ployment offices are to see that wor.1:anen out of emploYII!ent are directed to places where work is to be had in the countrr.. By decree of March 16, 1919, such workmen are allowed free railroad transportation to the place of work. In Janual'J7', 1922, the following measures were recommended by the Federal Employment Office: Advertisements for work in the country for unemployed city workmen; investigation of vacancies of this kind, especially as to board and lodging; selection of suitable men for such work; arrangements for taking the unemployed workers to the place of wo:rk1 and board and accommodation during the journey; provision of smtable clothing for the workmen (as far as possible), to be paid for by the employer; supervision of the treatment of the workmen in thell' new places of work; payment of traveling expenses on the return journey in case of illness, or illness or deatli in their families, or because the workmen prove unfitted for the work. . A separate fund was appropriated in April, 1923, out of the unemployment relief fund for the expenses incurred in _procuring workers for rural lab,pr. In 1923 a total of 14,000 city workmen were b,v: this means transferred to the country, of which 30 to 35 per cent did not remain because of lack of working clothes, physical mability, dislike of the work, etc. The expenses for this agency dllring 1924 are provided for in the following manner: For every suitable unemployed workman for whom employment is procured in the country from January 1 to December 31, 1924, a sum equal to :five times the amount of the unemploYII!ent benefit due to a single workman over 21 years of age in towns of class A in economic District II, but not exceeding the extra expenses incurred by the State employment office in promoting such labor movement will be 1>_aid. Up to April 1st threefifths of this amount was borne by the Federal Government and twofifths by the State, thereafter the Federal Government and State to contribute equal shares. From April 1, 1920, to August 20, 1923, the number of da_ys worked in the performance of unemployment relief work, was as follows: Days'work Road making and digging _________________________ 27,835, 714 Public improvements _____________________________ 10,294,499 River and canal construction ______________________ 12,350,310 Gas, water, and sewer work_______________________ 5,564,852 Railroadwork ___________________________________ 3,343,084 Electrical plants_________________________________ 867,968 162,369 Gardening______________________________________ House building __________________________________ 4,696,953 Miscellaneous ___________________________________ 8,523,801 Total _________________________________________ 73,639,550 EMPLOYMENT OFFICES Pre-war time.-In pre-war time the conduct of employment ~encies was left to private enterprise. In consequence man;y different kinds of employment agencies were established and flourishe<l side by side without any connection with each other. The earliest form was the employment office of the trade guild, which by the supplement to the Industrial Code of June 18, 1884, was given the https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 165 task of procuring employment for journeymen. With the rise of the trade-union movement the trade-unions established emplo_yment offices for almost all trades, but they did not acquire any considerable importance. The employment offices of the salaried employees' associations were centralized and also served as registration offices. The emplo_yers' associations also established employment offices, some of which attained importance. Other offices managed conjointly by employers and employees were established on the basis of collective agreements, but they were only for certain trades. Public welfare or charitable associations also established employment offices, but they generally restricted their activities to procuring employment for the needy. In addition to all these private agencies there existed public employment offices, established or subsidized by communes or communal unions, which soon acquired greater importance than any of the others. Because of this great variety of employment offices working side b_y side but without a common contro1 or unity of purpose, a sufficiently regular supply oflabor for the vacancies occurring could not be maintained. In order to remedy this and other defects of the employment service, the public employment offices deemed it advisable to cooperate more closely and so formed associations of the employment offices in the Province or State, these associations being united in the Federation of German Employment Offices. In order to secure regular adjustment between su_pply and demand of labor in the different localities, they published regular lists of vacancies and established a journal for emplo_yment agencies. 3 As these associations, however, comprised only the public emP.loyment exchanges, the defects arising from lack of unity and uniformity among private offices could not be entirely eliminated. Legislation regulating comprehensively the organization of employment offices was lacking. The States, especiallym southern Germany, had issued ministerial decrees by which public employment offices were _promoted but whicli did not/rovide for uniform organization. The Federal Government confine its activities to giving financial assistance for the maintenance of the public employment offices. Only the private employment office operated for profit, about which complaints were frequently heard at the time, was strictly regulated by law. Sections 1 to 14 of the law of June 2, 1910, covered private employment offices operated for profit and provided that such agencies were not thereafter to be established ui:iless urgently necessacy-. The management of such em_ployment agencies was made · suliject to the control of the local authonties and the carrying on of certain other business in connection with such employment agencies was forbidden. Employment a_,gencies for female workers were subjected to strict control by tlie police authorities, and it was provided that maximum fees were to be fixed by the authorities. Sections 15 to 18 of the law related to nonprofit employment agencies, authorizing the State governments to prescribe their q_uali:fications and duties, but the States took very little advantage of this permission. War time.-The complete change in economic conditions caused the outbreak of the war made it necessary to adjust the organization o the employment offices to the altered conditions. The Central hr • Der Arbeitsmarkt, later Der Arbeitsnachweis in Deutschland. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 166 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT • Bureau of the Federal Employment Service (Reickszentrale der .Arbeitsnachweise) was thus established on August 6, 1914, within the Ministry of the Interior, with the object of organizing the employment offices throughout the country on a uniform basis, of affording a comprehensive survey of the labor market, and of equalizing the supply and demand of labor. This department, however, did not exert v~ry great ~fl.uence on the orgf!,n~zation of emplo~ent offices. In addition to this the Federal Stat1st1cal Office published a labor market gazette, each employment office reporting twice a week the number of applications for employment still pending and the number of vacancies. Finally, under section 15 of the law on employinent agencies all employment offices were required from and after May, 1915, to report concerning their establishment and organization, and once a month on the number of apJ?lications filed and vacancies registered, with the object of obtammg a survey of the existing employment offices and of the state of the labor market. The decree of the Federal Council (Reichsrat) of June 14, 1916, authorizing the State governments to make it the duty of the communes or communal unions to establish or subsidize _public employment offices and to issue regulations for their orgaruzation and management, did not lead to any important results. Prussia, for instance, merely instructed the presidents of the administrative districts to make use of their powers, "in case the communes or counties should decline to supply an evident want." The first e.ffective step towards unification of the individual employment offices was taken when the national auxiliary service law of December 5, 1916, went into effect. Under the management of the newly-established War Office central information bureaus comprising all the employment offices were established, and attached to the associations of employment offices, with advisory committees composed of equal numbers of employers and of employees. Re~tration offices for the auxiliary service were also established, which were in all cases attached to the public employment offices and to which vacancies and applications for employment were required to be repor.ted. • Postwar period.-The sudden demobilization s~bsequent to the revolution of 1918 and the consequent enormous increase in the number (Jf the unemployed resulted· in a reorganization of the employment offices. The mana_gement of the entire em_ployment service was transferred from the War Office to the Demobilization Office on November 9, 1918. In an attempt to regulate the labor market the new Government issued the decree of December 9, 1918, confining itself, however, to conferring extensive powers on the States. Thus authorized, most of the States issued decrees; e. g., the provisional decree of September 12, 1919, of Prussia requiring on principle every subordinate _government board to establish puolic employment offices in its district and providing that provmcial boards (which later became the State employment offices), composed of all the employment offices in the Province or district, should be established. The growing importance of the employment offices, especially in connection with unemployment relief and unemployment relief work, made it necessary to centralize the employment agency in a Federal Employment Office (Reichsamt fur .Arbeitsvermittlung) https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 167 established by decree of the Federal Government May 6, 1920. Soon after its establishment, the Federal Employment Office was instructed to submit a draft of a comprehensive bill re~ating employirient agencies. On December 7, 1921, this bill was submitted to the Reichstag in the form given it by tne Reichsrath and after numerous amendments was passed almost unanimously, being signed by the President of the Republic, July 22, 1922. OPERATIONS 011' EMPLOYMENT 011'11'ICES The economic importance of the public employment office organization established by the employment office act of July 22, 1922, is evidenced by statistics of vacancies filled through the various employment offices. Up to the passing of the employment office act, as shown above, public (at that time the communal) employment offices had not been promoted to any considerable degree by legislative measures. But in spite of unrestricted competition in the labor market the public employment offices had succeeded in distancing all other emplo_yment offices. This is due mainly to the advantages they offer both to employers and to employees, such as gratuitous services, impartiality and, last but not least, management by boards composed of equal numbers of employers and employees. Of the total vacancies for men 'filled by all employment offices in 1913 the public offices had filled 44 per cent; in 1920 the proportion filled by them was 78 per cent, due mainly to the growth of the communal employment offices during the war. In 1923 the proportion was 90 per cent, which shows that the employment office act has had a favorable influence on the activities of the public employment offices. The proportion of vacancies for women filled by such offices has increasea correspondingly, being in 1913, 86 per cent; in 1920, 89 per cent; and in 1923, 91 per cent. The proportion of vacancies negotiated by the employers' employment offices, whose operations in pre-war time came next in importance to those of the public employment offices, has fallen from 34 per cent in 1913 to 14 per cent in 1920 and in 1923 was only 0.4 per cent. This exceptionally low :figure is due mainly to the fact that the employment office of the port of Hamburg, wliich filled 362,353 vacancies in 1920, was in the beginning of 1921 attached to the State employment service. The vacancies for women filled by the employers' employment offices has never been of importance, being in 1913, 4.5 per cent and in 1920, 0.4 per cent. In 1923 the :figure fell to 0.1 per cent of the total business done by all offices. The proportion of vacancies for men filled by the workers' employment offices has fallen from 11 per cent in 1913 to 3 per cent in 1923. The proportion of vacancies .negotiated by the salaried employees' employirient offices has been maintained at approximately the same level. Vacancies for men filled dropped from 1.4 per cent to· 0.8 per cent and vacancies for women :filled from 2.2 per cent to 1.8 per cent. The offices managed jointly by employers and employees have increased the extent of their operations from 2 J?er cent m 1913 to 4 per cent in 1920 and 1923. Wliereas the proportion of vacancies for men filled by public welfare employment offices fell from 1.6 per cent in 1913 to 0.6 per cent in 1920 and to 0.5 per cent in 1923, the vacancies for women filled has averaged 4 per cent. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 168 CHAPTER VII.-ee-UNEMPLOYMENT Table 60 shows the number of vacancies filled by the various kinds of employment offices in 19i3, 1920, and 1923: TABLB 60.-NUMBER AND PER OENT OF AO.A.NOIES FILLED BY EMPLOYMENT OFFICES IN GERMANY, 1913, 1920, 1923, BY KIND OF OFFICE NlJHBEB Females Males Kind of employment office 1913 1920 1923 1913 1920 1923 Public e~loyment office ••••••••••••••••• 1,086,738 3,0M,103 2,075,360 22,773 10. 940 Public w tare =oyment office ••••••••• 37,845 Equi em oyment office •••••••••• 47,800 162,428 99,710 9,730 Emp~m oyment office •••••••••••• 836,644 575,634 84,401 70,0'a Workers' e~oyment office••••••••••••••• 280,335 19,0'Jo Salaried em oyees' employment office•••• 36,370 42,123 17,007 Guilds, eto., employment office ••••••••••• 127,730 9,862 655,843 1,312,108 25,766 64,946 6,734 66,353 1,006, IIOl 52,586 Total ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 2,%3,462 3,991,SM 2,301, 71K 648,775 1,481,033 1,11M, 7111. 29,018 10,607 14,684 6,133 5,419 15,782 37,294 132 PEB CENT Public e ~ e n t office ••••••••••••••••• Public w emJ:loyment office ••••••••• Equi,::san em oyment office •••••••••• Emp oyers' employment office •••••••••••• Workers' emJ:loyment office••••••••••••••• Salaried em oyees' employment office •••• Guilds, etc., emoloyment office ••••••••••• 44.3 1.6 2.0 34.1 11.4 L4 6. 2 77.5 .6 4.1 14.4 2.1 Ll .2 90.3 ------------ 100.0 100.0 Total ••••• 9,601 1,631 7,7111 20,301 6,380 - •• 88.6 3. 7 3. 7 3.0 .8 .7 85. 7 4.0 LO .. 5 L6 2.2 LO .o 9Ll 4.8 .9 .1 .7 LS .6 100.0 100.0 100.0 100.0 .5 .. 3 •• Ll 2. II On comparing the business transacted by the various kinds of emJ>loyment offices with respect to the occupations followed by the applicants, the difference in importance of the public employment offices and of the other kinds of employment offices becomes evident. In numbers and proportion the figures ft>r communal J>Ublic employment offices are highest for common labor of various kinds and for domestic servants, which classes include the main body of unskilled employees employed on short contracts. The total vacancies filled in these classes in 1923 is 566,764 for men and 608,300 for women. The number of vacancies negotiated. by the communal public employment offices in 1923-546,745 men and 556,653 women-and by the public-welfare employment offices-6,815 men and 46,490 women-are significant in this connection. As regards the skilled occupations, the share of the communal public employment offices in the vacancies filled in agriculture is remarkaole, amounting to 205,401 for men out of a total of 231,663 and 74,217 for women, out of a total of 80,379. In many trades the public employment offices seem almost to have a monopoly, and there are only a few trades in which other employment offices man~e to surpass the public offices, such as the printing trades in which the eqmpartisan employment office has filled 16,359 vacancies for men out of a total of 23,422. In Table 61 are shown the number of vacancies filled oy nonprofit employment offices in 1923, by occupations: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis TABLE 61.-VACANCIES FILLED BY NONPROFIT EMPLOYMENT OFFICES IN GERMANY, 1923, BY OCCUPATIONS Vacancies filled by public employment offices Applications Vacancies Occupation Offices for specific occupations Males Agriculture, gardening, forestry •.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••. 336,546 Mines, smelting works, salt mines .•••••••••••••••••••••••••••. 96,202 Stone, clay, and glass products •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 78,271 Metal working and machinery •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 770,951 Chemicals••••••••••••••.••••••••••••••..•••••••••••••••••••••• 25,032 Textiles •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••••••••• 61,633 Paper .•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 24,632 Leather •••••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••••.•.••••••••••••••••••• 51,995 Lumber and timber.••.••..•••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••••• 225,413 Food, liquors, and tobacco.•••••••••••••••••••.• , ••••••••••••• 143,475 Clothing •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•••••••••••••••••••• 163,627 Cleaning.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••....•••••••••••••••••• . 36,806 Building ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••.•...•.••••••••••••••••••• 472,346 Printing••••••••••••••••••••••.••••••••••••••.•...••••••••••••. 75,105 Art industries.•••••••••••••••..••.•.•••••••••••••••••••.•••••• 4,356 Musical, theatrical, etc., shows••••••••••..•••••••••••••••••••• 184,213 Hotels and restaurants ••••••••••••••••••.•••.•••.••••••••••••• 282,228 580,217 8,918 fi~~Jt~~:!~~fce ••••••••••••••••••••••••••.••••••••••••••••••• Common labor..•.•••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 1,523,467 Firemen and engineers •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••. 53,965 Commercial clerks •••••••••••••••.••.•••...••••••••••••••••••• 179,044 Office clerks .••...•.•••••••••••••••••..•••••••••••••••••••••••• 43,233 40,588 27,567 Not specified •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 12,006 rf~!':.l~i~~/gKs~~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: Females Males Females Males 92,227 2,491 9,681 87,472 15,602 108,948 50,388 9,812 10,498 111,628 167,877 27,371 279,252 34,935 23,546 238,480 14,162 16,172 8,004 16,129 93,616 58,930 36,205 22,906 169,036 24,117 1,324 169,352 243,693 335,634 6,676 578,919 21,135 72,189 20,471 8,555 5,673 3,860 123,658 1,880 3,243 35,985 6,082 38,613 22,430 4,323 4,633 49,740 67,687 20,753 231,663 32,138 21,788 203,000 14,018 15,151 7,626 14,644 84,422 57,139 32,344 18,740 154,340 23,422 870 167,171 235,982 325,478 6,000 560,764 20,598 43,591 15,937 6,754 4,756 3,458 25,761 5.57 6,501 148,467 15,713 683,510 384,008 ---------137,417 59,230 597 8,654 3,908 13,437 303 4,433 143,392 7,279 829,444 98,514 ---------58,796 40,123 160 3,602 2,371 Females Males 80,379 1,682 3,059 31,192 5,912 35,163 21,376 4,004 4,303 48,325 55,402 16,383 12,969 250 4,109 106,166 6,567 515,844 92,456 33,932 21,509 97 2,176 1,501 Total ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 5,501,856 2,168,318 2,502,971 1,580,881 2,301,794 1,104,756 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis State Vacancies filled 4,352 96 67 10 1 Fe• males Males Females Males 3,699 ___1,347 ., ____ 1,385 16 205,401 31,688 20,550 193,874 13,736 14,869 7,157 14,197 74,446 44,675 30,268 10,797 146,467 5,763 836 148,071 206,707 284,673 4,952 541,793 6,758 23,689 13,182 5,685 3,819 3,214 ----------------------- --------------· 3 --------------3 -------3 -------4 -------8 2 4 ---------------6 -------······s· 95 7 457 1 -------- ·····so· 212 ····s3s· ······1· 485 460 299 47 7,251 Communal Branch offices 6 ......7° -------1,662 259 51 879 11 13 33 132 388 228 237 128 550 57 7 144 403 829 61 1,511 123 493 349 68 166 23 10,842 ·····i4· ·····29· 11 4 2 23 385 173 ······r 3 101 261 368 1,630 602 ····373· 254 3 111 -------- 5,749 2,057,267 Females 74,217 1,666 2,828 30,886 5,762 34,811 20,650 3,794 3,895 46,069 52,625 13,385 5,181 246 3,273 100,393 6,169 465,633 91,020 --------20,276 13,251 83 1,635 1,347 999,095 TABLE 61.-VACANCIES FILLED BY NONPROFIT EMPLOYMENT OFFICES IN GERMANY, 1923, BY.OCCUPATIONS-Concluded Vacancfes filled by other employment agencies Guilds' Occupation Males Iles Equipartlsan Males Iles Employers' Salaried employees' Workers' Males Females Males 230 5 8,602 Females Males Females Public welfare Others Males Females Males 2,502 794 178 Females Q Agriculture! prdening, forestr?;i······························ 6,250 2,252 114 •••••••• ~~;~· J~;, ~~ ;i~~r~~~:a.~~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ::::::: ::::::: ······s· :::::::: :::::::: :::::::: Meta1 working and machinery................................ 794 ••••••. 6,434 263 38 •••••••• Chemicals.•.••••••.••••.••.••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Textiles....................................................... ••••••. ••••••• •••••••• •••••••• 51 •••••••• r!riter::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: ·····5• ::::::: 8,121 U: Lumber and timber........................................... 24 Food, liquors, and tobacco.................................... 1,558 8,534 g~;~gt::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: B :i, 7 152402 s~ 250 .·.·.··..·s_·_ 617 •••••••• •••••••• 249 3 •••••••• 20 ••••••.••••••••• ····Mi. 2, 1~g 18! •••••••• 1,868 •••••••• 18_ •••• 10. 16,35~ 6,739 •••••••••••••••• Musical, theatrical, etc., shows................................ ••.•••• .•••••• 718 714 •••••••••••••••• rJni~~tirle.•=················································ .... f~~i~:e~turants .••.••••••••••••••••••••••••.••••••.••..••••••. ·····~·. ~ ~. :::::: ~~!i:::iiSJ:r~~~~:::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::::: : : :~: ::::::: I~! Office clerks................................................... .•••••• ••••••• Technical employees.......................................... ••••••• .•••••• Liberal professions................................................... ••••••• Not specified................................................. ••••••• ••••••• 54 1 1 9 2, ~l :: ~i ·····-r 1 1 • •• •••• 6 ••••••••••••••• : • 892 2,121 54 5 2 50 • •• 47 3 8 1,631 70,022 m······2········· 2 ~~ 53 --i;ooo· i! ·····-r8 259 7 10 J 25 477 24 20 ~ 1:~ ··--ioo· 546 ·····T ..... iii. :::::::: :::::::: .•••..~.••••• T 808 •••••••• •••••••• 133 33 110 •••••••• 16 100 16,873 ·i:f70i" 001 1, 303 449 8 ······r ······r ··--~~~. ·---~~- 233 67 80 6,735 Ji 3,661 25 46,104 386 ····400· 117 218 99 24 176 99 10,940 52,586 8 i:i:l ······is ~ i,:t 86 115 3 1 5 134 55 24 95 3 6218 127 58 92 539 125 57 1 12 27 1,084 4 1,644 71 1,313 1,239 32 260 ·······4 2 .••••. iii 122 1,563 ·······;; 1 .......i 5 1,449 72 ..... iii7 471 --·--i20 136 2 7,711 4,109 1--+--1---+---,'------+---+---,--+--+.---I--+--+---+ Total ••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• 9,296 2,271 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 1:: ~; 2 1,041 374 243 197 225 161 1,264 1,761 1,433 1,309 4,264 1,134 10 18,226 18, 791 7,850 167 335 117 ····231 •• • • •• 14 5 •••••••• 150 •••••••• •••••••• 319 •••••••• •••••••• 96 •••••••• •••••••• 99, 710 9,601 9, 730 7,751 19,025 . 20,301 ii>t,:j ....~ 1 z t.:::! :::: t,:j t"' 0 ~ :::: t.:::! z ~ EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 171 The number of employment offices in 1923 has not yet been ascertained. There are, however, 21 State employment offices distributed over the States and Provinces. On December 1, 1921, the number of registered employment offices of each kind was as follows: Public employment offices ______________________________ 1,332 Public-welfare employment offices_______________________ 168 Equipartisan employment offices-----------------------72 Employers' employment offices__________________________ 35 195 Workers' employment offices____________________________ Salaried employees' employment offices__________________ 314 86 Guilds, etc., employment offices_________________________ Total__________________________________________ 2,202 ORGANIZATION OF EMPLOYMENT OFFICES The employment office act of July 22, 1922, provides for a system of public employment offices based on the eX1Sting communal employment offices. It thus creates a system of free public employment offices under a common management (section 1), m accordance with the principles established in article 2 of the draft convention on unemployment passed at the International Labor Conference at Washington in 1919. The act further provides that in these public employment offices trade departments shall be established. Other provisions regulate the management of the employment offices. Although the act provides a systematic organization of the public employment offices (ojfentliche Arbeitsnachweise), it does not give them a monopoly. On the contrary, the existing private nonprofit employment offices are allowed to carry on business as before and even the establishment of new offices of this kind is not prohibited. They are, however, subject to the supervision of the State employment offices. Private employment offices operated for profit are also permitted to continue in business but their operation will be prohibited after January 1, 1931. The r~ation of the public employment service is based, first, on the principle of systematic organization; second, on the administration of the employment offices by the persons interested. Special provisions of the act relate to the personnel of the employment offices. The procedure in case of complaints and the method of financing the employment offices are also provided for. The systematic organization of the public employment service, in contradistinction to the uncontrolled operation theretofore obtaining, is efiected by providing a complete system of public employment offices (secs. 2-14) under State employment offices for larger districts (secs. 15-25), and by establishing a Federal Employment Office for the entire country (secs. 26-31). OOIIIIUJ.UL PUBLIC Dtl'LOYIIDT OfflOBS Public employment offices form the first class in the organization of the public employment service. In order that the entire country may be covered liy a network of employment offices, the act provides that every commune must be covered by a public employment office. As a rule, a public employment office must be estalilished in every subcrdinate administrative district (sec. 3). In order, however-I that this system of public employment offices may not bf\ distriouted https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 172 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT arbitrarily according to a fixed pattern, which would be the case if the districts were limited by political demarcations, the State government may, in :fixing the distncts for public employment offices, ignore the limits of the subordinate administrative districts and make the districts larger or smaller according to economic needs. The public emplo_yment office is to be established by the communal administration, and several communes may combine to establish a public employment office in_ <;irder that _it may be .m?re efficient. The management of such a Jomt employment office IS mtrusted by the State government to one of the communes concerned (sec. 6). In case the district covered by a public employment office, while extensive, is yet not large enough to render it advisable to divide it and establish a second office, the existing office may establish a branch office within its own district. Branch offices of this. kind, which generally carry on their business independently, are frequently charged with the management of s:peoial departments. Tliey remain, however, a part of the :public employment office and are subordinate to the general administrative committee, unless they happen to be trade departments (seep. 174). The chief work of the public employment service is performed in the communal public employment offices. Their fundamental duty is to procure employment for workers and salaried employees, and in addition they are to assist in carrying out relief measures provided for by law, especially unemployment relief. The decree of the Federal Government of February 16, 1924, relating to unemployment relief regulates in detail the assistance to be rendered by employment o:flfoes, and especially the public employment offices, in carrying out the unemployment relief measures. Besides this, the act provides that employment offices shall undertake, either voluntarily or at the direction of the authorities, vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices. ' The Minister of Labor or the State government may assign to the public employment offices additional duties in the field of r~ating the labor market, such as procutjng employment for and asSISting in the relief of persons of limited earning capacity and itinerant workers' (sec. 2). STATB DIPLOYXBRT omoBS The State employment offices form the second class in the organization of the public employment service, being also established on the basis of existing institutions, for during the war central information bureaus had been established which consolidated a number of employment offices with the object of adjusting the interlocal labor supply and demand. These State employment offices are established in States, Provinces, or other large districts (sec~ 17), either as independent boards or in connection with some other State or communal administrative agency:. The State employment office district are also to be fixed. according to economic needs and without regard to political demarc~ • The public employment offices have not as yet beml charged authoritatively with these additional duties. The gijneral regulations relating to vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices contain only regulations for such.public employment offices as have already assumed these functions. · • According to the law of Dec. 23, 1922, as amended 1an. 12, 1923, regulating the employment of cripples, public employment offices are required to aend repreaentat1vcs to the central relief committees. Under article 1, No. 4, of the decree of Oct. 30, 1923, the employment offices may, with the permission of the Minlllter of Labor, also be charged with fllrther duties. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 173 tions. Thus several State governments may establish a common State employment office if one or more of the States concerned is not able to support an efficient State office because of limited territory. .As it may be expedient for certain work by the State office to be performed in the locality~ the act explicitly provides that branch offices may be established witn the consent of tlie State government (sec. 16). Thus the State office at Munster in Westphalia, which covers Lippe and the Province of Westphalia, has established a branch office for the mining industry. The primary duties of tlie State employment offices consist in the supervision of all employment offices and the rendering of decisions on complaints against them, the observation of the labor market, and the adjustment of supply and demand in the different localities. The supervision of the public employment offices and the rendering of decisions on complaints agamst them are ·confined, however, to their administration, and does not extend to their management, the control of which-is reserved to the competent provincial, etc., authorities. The State employment agency in its supervision of the employment offices has no means of enforcing its orders but may call upon the provincial, etc., authorities in case of disobedience thereof. Subject to the approval of the administrative committee and the State government, the State offices may establish rules for the administration of the employment offices of their districts, in order that such administration may be uniform. The State employment offices shall, on principle refrain from filling vacancies or entertaining applications for em_ployment themselves, but may do so in exc~ptional cases when adjustment of the supply and demand among different localities is urgent. In addition, State offices are authorized to fill vacancies themselves when departments for separate trades are established within a State office, but only in case a similar department does not exist in one of the employment offices of the district (sec. 38). In order to promote interlocal adjustment of supply and demand, the State offices publish weekly reports of vacancies still pending and of the state of the labor market in their districts. They have general authority to demand such information from all institutions engaged in workers' relief, and section 54 of the employment office act provides that any person refusing to give information or J>Urposely giving misleading information may be :fined or imprisoned. The Minister of Labor may, with the approval of the Reichsrat assign to the State employment offices additional duties in the :field of regulating the labor market. 11 By "general directions to the employment offices relating to vocational guidance and the placement of apJ>rentices," dated May 12, 1923, the State offices are directed by the Federal Employment Office to extend their operations to these matters. • 1BDBRAL BJIPLOYJUNT omcB Th~ Federal Employment Office is at the head of the organization of the employment service and is responsible for uniform management and cooperation of the entire service,7 so that it will function • The same restrictions apply here as with the public employment offices. ' The Federal Employment Office, by decree of Sept. 30, 1922, of the Ministry of Labor, was made a department of the Ministry of Labor. 20168°-25t-12 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 174 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT as a single employment organization. It covers the whole of Germ8.ll_y, its headquarters being in Berlin. The Federal Employment Office, conjointly with the State governments, supervises the enforcement of the emplo~ent office a.ct. It exercises technical supervision over the State employment offices and the communal public emrloyment offices. rt also observes the labor market, section 31 o tlie act authorizing it to institute inquiries concerning the state of the labor market, working conditions, strikes, lockouts, etc. Under section 54 of the act any person declining to give information or knowingly giving false information m~ be :fined or imprisoned. The Federal office is to take measures to adjust the supply and demand of labor in different economic districts, and for this purpose publishes weekly a labor market bulletin cont~ reports of· the State offices on the state of the labor market, applications for employment, and vacancies in the country which can not be filled within the district of a State office. It is also required to report regularly on the state of the labor market, the amount of unemployment, the development of collective bargaining, and all matters oonnected therewith. 8 In addition, the Federal office is charged with the duty of regulating and supervising coniointly with the State governments, t:fie recruiting, placing, ana employment of alien workers.• The Federal office is to lay down general principles for vocational guidance and for the. placement of apprentices, not orµy for the public employment offices but also for private concerns engaged m this work. 10 In case of persistent violations of these principles the Federal office may, subject to the approval of the advisory council, demand the closing of the offending private establishments. The Federal Employment Office, as well as communal and State employment offices, ma.y be charged with additional duties relating to the labor market. This has been done in the case of unemployment relief. TBA.DB DBPilTJIBNTS The · organization of the employment service. must be adapted not only to the local but also to the economic requirements of the individual trades. An effective employment agency, one that takes into consideration the special req~rements of ea.ch trade, the requirements of each vacancy to be filled, and the special qualifications of each worker, is possible only on the basis of an organiz11,tion by trade departments. Before the passage of the employment office act many large employment offices had established separate departments for certain trades and this development was promoted by the act. In all classes of the employment service, trade departments may be established, to which a. great measure of independence is given by the act. Trade departments may be established voluntarily or by order of the authorities. A trade department may be formed voluntarily if the employers' and employees' organizations1 after an inquiry, decide that it is needed, the commune as a. rwe having the right 1 These reports are published In the Relchsarbeit.sblatt, the official bulletin of the Ministry of Labor md of the Federal Employment Office. • See pp. 183 8lld 18' for provisions regulating this matter. 11 Such regulations have been issued and are dlscussed In the sections on vocational guidance and pl-. ment of apprentices (pp. 186 to 188). · https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 175 only of contesting such decision. If such trade organizations do not exist, the question is decided by the administrative committees of the employment offices (sec. 32). The State employment office may order the establishment of a trade department ma public emploYJ'.!lent office, and the Federal Employment Office may order the establishment of one in the State employment office (sec. 37), which permits of the creation of a sufficiently broad trade basis in such em]>_loyment offices. • The trade departments are not independent employment offices but rather departments of the employment offices with a large measure of independence. They are under the management of the employment offices in which they are established, the chairman of the administrative committee of the employment office being also chairman of the committee of the trade department. The trade departments are to concern themselves witli conditions in the trades for which they a.re established and especially employment in such trades. The trade departments in the State and '.Federal employment offices may fill vacancies directly if there is no such trade department in a subordinate office (sec. 38). Separate departments for men and women may be established whenever it is deemed advisable for technical or moral reasons to separate male and female workers in the employment office.· In the women's department the manager must be a woman and as far as possible the agents also should be women. These separate departments should not be confounded with the trade departments established for certain trades, such as the metal industry, the building trades, domestic service, and the like. A department for working men or women, unless it is a trade department for a certain trade, is under the administrative committee of the employment office and subject thereto in the conduct of its business. IQ1llPABTlBA1ll BOABDS Another basic principle of the public employment service is that of government by tlie parties concerned-the employers and the em.ploJees.11 This principle :finds expression in the administrative comnuttees of the communal and the State employment offices, the advisory council of the Federal Employment Officet !),Ild the trade committees of the trade departments, on all of which both employers and emJ>.loyees a.re represented. The composition of these equipartisan boards is different in each of the classes of the employment service. In the communal public employment offices, tlie administrative committee consists of the chairman three employers, and three employees. The trade committee, whether belongmg to a communal office, a State office, or the Federal office, is also composed of three employers and three employees. The chairman of the administrative committee is, however, also the chairman of the trade committee. In the administrative committee of the State employment office, one-third of the members a.re employers, one-third employees, and the remain.4tg one-third representatives of the communes in which public employment offices are established. The advisory council of the Federal Employment 11 This is In accordance with the draft convention on unemploYinent adopted by the International Labor Conference at Wlll!hington In 1919: "Committees which shall Include representatives of em~oyers and employees shall be appointed to advise on matters concernlug the carrylng on of these agencies.' -Monthly Labor Review, February, 1920, p. 20. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 176 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT Office is comJ>osed of four representatives of public bodies~ four employers, ana four employees, to whom experts may be adaed as advisers. It is provided that one .of the members of the advisory council must be a woman (sec. 29). Alth01.1gh the principle of equipartisanshi:e is thus followed throughout in the composition of the. administrative committees, parity of voting members is not in all cases considered indispensable, as the by-laws of the employment offices may designate the 8roportions of nly for decivoting members on the administrative committee. sions ori appeals is a parity of voting members on the administrative committee of State offices and the advisory council of the Federal office required (secs. 22, 29). All employer and employee members of these administrative committees must be German citizens at least 24 years of age. They are. appointed for periods of three years,12 and receive no pay (sec. 10). Tlie members of the committees of the public employment offices and of the trade de_partments are proposed by the employers' and e~ployees' organizations (sec. 9)-in the latter case by ~uch organizations of the trades concerned (sec.· 33)-and appomted by the commune in which the employment office is establislied or by which it is managed. The employer and employee members of the administrative committee of the State offices are to be elected by the employers' section· and the workers' section, respectively, of the district economic council; if there is no such council they are appointed by the State government on recommendation of employers' and employees' organizations of the State office district (sec. 65). The members of the advisory council of the Federal office representing the employers and the workers are elected by the employer section and the workers' section, respectively, of the Federal economic council (secs. 29 and 66). The duties of all the equipartisan committees of the employment service are essentially the same. They lay down principles for the administration of the employment offices and issue regulations therefor, supervise the operations of the office, being authorized to demand books, files, and other documents for examination, and receive and render decisions on complaints. The committees have great influence in other ways. The by-laws of the employment offices are formulated after consultation with them (secs. 5 and 18). They are consulted as to the appointment of the heads of the employment offices and may protest against such appointments. The duty of the administrative and trade committees involving the highest responsibility is, however, the selection of the managers and employees of the employment offices, whom they propose (secs. 13 and 23). The committees take a prominent part in t h e ~ of the budget (secs. 14 and 22) .. The trade committee of the trade department is independent of the administrative committee of the employment office, but its authority may be restricted by the general administrative committee and it 1S obliged to follow the general principles laid down by the latter. The advisory council of the Federal Employment Office must approve the .principles laid down for vocational guidance and the u Busoenslon from office ol committee members must be provided for ln the b;y•laws, as the act contains no proilsiona therefor. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 177 placement of apprentices, as well as the general regulations for the management of public employment offices and the State employment offices (sec. 30). KAll'AGBDll'T or DtPLOYJIBNT OrFICBS The communes and the State and the Federal Governments manage the public, State, and Federal employment offices, respectively, through a representative who acts as chairman of the office. As the reJ?resentative of the Government he is also the chairman of the admiriistrative committee or advisory council, and thus acts in a double capacity-as representative of the Government authorities in the management of tlie office and as chairman of the administrative committee or advisory council, but he is primarily the representative of the Government, and is appointed by it, after consultation with the equipartisan boards (secs. 8 and 20). These public employment offices are established by the civil authorities and are therefore public bodies, being departments of the communal or communal umon boards and the State and Federal Governments, respectively. Subject to the approval of the administrative committees the authorities of such governments issue rules governing the employment offices (secs. 5 and 18),13 and in the case of communes ap_point the members of the committees and their alternates; as well as the managers and employees, on approval of the administrative committee. As the budget of the communal public employment office forms part of the budget of the commune in which it 18 established, it is fixed by the latter, but the administrative committee has tho right to suggest alterations and to raise objections (sec. 14). The same is true as to the budgets of the State offices, which are fixed by the · State government, except that if the State office is an independent board or attached to an independent board, the administrative committee is restricted to maKing suggestions and can not raise objections, as in that case the budget forms pa_rt of the general budget of the State. In the Federal Employment Office the advisory council has no part in the fixing of the budget, as it forms part of the Federal budget. · · PBBSOlflfBL or BltPLOYXBNT OrrICES Special provisions concerning the personnel of the employment offices appear in section 13 of tlie employment office act. The liead of the employment office is the chairman of the administrative committee. Of the other ell!ployees in the communal :public employment office and the State office the most important 18 the manager (secs. 13 and 23). The offices of chairman of the committee and manager of the employment office may, however, be united in the same person and this is the rule, especially in the smaller offices. The manager of a communal office 18 appointed, on proposal by the administrative committee, by the commune and of a State office by the State government. As the efficiency of an emploYil!ent office depends on the qualifications of the manager, the act provides n The prl!l!ident of the Federal Labor Office on Nov. 17, 1922, under the authority of section 5, paragraph 4, of the employment office aot issued "regulations concerning the contents of by-laws of public employment offiq," under which the by-laws must set forth the commune estabJlshlug or managing the employment o:fll~1 the name, district, and locality of the employment office, duties, fiscal year, expenditure, the oomposiuon, appointment, and period of service of the administrative committee, dismissal of members of tlie committee, etc. The decree, under seoticftl 11 of the aot, further sets forth model by-laws for a larger public employment office and model business rules for an employment office. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 178 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT that he must be a person possessing "the necessary practical knowledge of employment office work." If a separate manager is a_ppomted for the trade department by the administrative authorities on proposal by the trade committee, he must possess the same qualifications as . the manager of the employment office, and in addition have practical experience of employment office work in the trade concerned (sec. 34). The administrative and trade committees have also the right of prop_o_s~ the other emplo_yees. While as a general rule no special qualifications are required of such employees, those of the trade departments should, as far as p_ossible, belong to the trade concerned. At the head of the Federal Employment Office is a president, who is also chairman of the advisory council. Among the other employees a.re to be women possessing practical experience of employment office work (sec. 29). APPBLLATI PBOCBDVU A written complaint may be lod~ed by any interested per_son with the administrative committee a.gamst decisions of the chairman -of the employment office or with a trade committee if the complaint is against a trade department. If the decision of the chairman is reversed by the committee, he may appeal within two weeks to the administrative or trade committee of the State office. In the case of decisions of the State office, the procedure is similar. Decisions of the administrative or trade committees not rendered on appeal may be appealed to the administrative or trade committee of the State office and such decisions of the State office may be pealed to the advisory council of the Federal office, while decisions o the trade committees of the Federal office may be appealed to the advisory council. af JID'D'SJIS 01' DPLOYJOBT omcBS ' Before the employment office a.et went into effect the necessary funds for the employment offices were raised by the communes, and for the State offices by the States and the provincial unions, but as the communes and the provincial unions were in most cases neither able nor willing to continue to bear the expense, section 67 of the act provides. that until the pass~ of special legislation the expense of the three different classes ·of employment offices is to be home !>Y the establishing communes, the State _governments, and the Federal Government, respectively, but the Federal Government is to grant subsidies of the cost to the State offices and reasonable contributions to the public employment exchanges. By the decree on unemployment relief as am.ended February 16, 19247 the establishing communes are to bear the expense of the public employment exchanges (sec. 37), but may appropriate for this P"!ll'Pose an amount equal to two.:thirds of the necessary expense out of the amounts paid liy employers and employees for unemployment relief. If a pub1ic employment office is established for several communes or by a communal union, the cost is to be divided among them. In the case of the State offices, section 36, paragraph 2, provides that two-thirds of the cost may be paid out of the amounts paid by employers and employees for unemployment relief in the district of the State employment office, the rest to be borne by the body or board establishing the office. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 179 l'U.VMB BJIPLOYIDNT OJ'FICIS Private 'IUYTl,profU empl~m offices.-Under the employment office act private empfoyment offices not operated for profit are permitted to continue their operations, but their authority has been greatly restricted. In the first place, such offices are subject to the supervision of the State employment office in whose district they do business (sec. 44, par. 1), or if their operations extend beyond the district of a State office, by the State office in the district of their location, or the Federal office may decide itself to supervise the private employment office. Il the orders of the supervising authonty are not complied with, the private employment office may be clvsed (sec. 45, par. 2). The Federal office may issue regulations as to the establishment and management of these private offices (sec. 44, par. 3) and this was done by decree of the Federal office, October 26, 1923. The body establishing the employment office must appoint a manager, who is responsible for compliance with the rei?Ulations. Such manager is prohibited from also acting as an independent labor agent. The name of such private employment office must show who established it and for what trades and classes of persons it is operated. The office must be unobjectionable from a moral and sanitary standpoint. Such private employment offices must abide by the regulations governing public employment offices. While not obfu?ed to give gratuitous service the fees charged must not be more tnan enough to cover their expenses. Il the fees charged are higher and are not reduced on demand, the supervising employment office may demand the closing of the private office on tlie ground that it is being operated for profit. Fees may not be charged unless a labor contract has been concluded through the efforts of the employment office. This does not apply, however, to the prepayment of cash expenses incurred. Employnient offices established oy economic organizations of workers, and which by statute negotiate vacancies for members of such organizations only, are permitted to question their clients as to the organization to which they belong (sec. 44, par. 2). By the orders put~ the employment office act into effect, private offices are prohibited from making misleading statements, especially as to the conditions of labor contracts and the number of vacancies, of applications for work, or of placements. They are also forbidden to procure employn'.!ent in other trades or for other groups of persons than those specified by them. In order to adjust supply and demand between the employmen~ offices, the private offices must rE_:lport to the public employment offices all vacancies they can not fill and all applicants they are not able to place. Lists of vacancies published by private emploY!!}ent offices must be submitted to the supervising employment offices. In order to enable the supervising employment offices effectively to control the private offices, the latter are required to keep systematic and up-to-date lists of vacancies and applications, and also to give the supervising office all necessary information concerning the management of the business. The employment office act provides that a private employment office not operated for profit may be converted into a public employment office on application by the body bearing the cost of the pnvate https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 180 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT office. The State office may, with the· approval of the administrative committee, apply to the Federal office for permission either to convert the private office into a public employment office or to close the private office if the former, after repeated demands, does not comply with the requirements of the employment office act and the decrees ·rela~ to private em:J?loyment offices within a reasonable ~e-1 or if its l>usiness is of no unportance to the district, or if twouriras of the administrative committee consent. On the approval of two-thirds · of its advisory council, the Federal Em_ployment Office may then order the conversion or. closing of the pnvate employment office. Appeal from such order may be taken to the Minister of Labor, whose decision is final. The reestablishment of a private employment office not operated for profit, or the restoration of the independence of a private office converted into a public employment office, may be authorized by the State board if it is proved that because of the nature of the trade in question or the special requirements of the interested persons the office can be managed to greater advantage b_y .an economic organization or a trade corporation than by a public employment office. · . Thus, although the competition of private nonprofit employment offices is permitted on principle, the act provides means of prevent~ private einplo)7lllent offices from in any way prejudicing or frustrating the object of the public employment sel'Vlce. Further, the c ~ on of a nonprofit employment office without permission is made punishable by fine or imprisonment on demand of the competent employment office (sec. 56). Private empl<!?f!nent offices operateil, for projit.-Private employment offices operated for profit were regulateaby the law of June 2, 19101 relating to professional employment agents, but the provisions ot this law were from the very first regarded as merely provisional, the end in view being complete abolition of the private employment agency: in favor of communal public employment offices, because of the p.igli fees ch~ed by the private offices, the frequent temp ping of workers and others to change or to leave their positions and to break their contracts, and the consequent injury to the public interest. The employment office act endeavors to put an end to these evils in three ways: (a) The private employment agency operated for p_rofit is prohil>ited altogether from and after January 1, 1931, all licenses to carry on such offices then becoming void. Agents who on that date have been operating a licensed office since June 2, 1910, are to receive reasonable compensation, to be :fixed by a special law. The Minister of Labor may allow exem_ptions from this general prohibition, especially in cases in which the employment service can not be earned on as effectually by the public offices, such as obtaining situations for actors. (b) A gradual reduction in the number of such private employ-: ment agencies is to be brought about under the provision that, from the time of its go~ into effect, licenses to carry on such emploY.ment agencies will no longer be granted and existing licenses will not be extended or transferred. In this case, also, tlie Minister of Labor may allow exemptions. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 181 (c) Such private em.Ployment agencies are placed under the supervision of the public employment offices in whose jurisdiction they are located, tliough witliout pr~judice to the supervision exercised by the police authorities. Under the general regulations, issued by authority of section 69 of the act, technical supervision of the private employment agents doing business for profit is exercised by the chairman of the public employment office in whose jurisdiction such an agency is situated. These agents are required to allow representatives of the competent public office to enter all rooms used for business, to submit all their books and business papers, and to answer all inquiries relating to their bus4iess operations correctly. They are further required to keep a book in wliich all applications and vacancies are registered on the day they are received. (d) The employment office act has included under the definition of "private employment agency operated for profit" the publication, for profit, of lists of vacancrns and also the supplying, for a consideration, of workers to employers for temporary employment where the agent or contractor does not himself supply the necessary tools or assume the employers' share of the insurance, etc., charges on their account. (e) The carrying on of such a private employment office without a license and in contravention of the law is punishable by fine under section 57 of the act and, in cases of previous conviction, by imprisonment. PRINCIPLES GOVBRJIING l:MPLOYJDNT SBRVICB The employment office act relates exclusively to the organization of employment offices. Principles for their business operation are determined by the offices themselves in their rules and regulations and by their officials. The act, however, sets forth (secs. 39-43) a few important principles, which are supplemented by regulations concernin~ foreign workmen, the secu$g of situations for German workmen m foreign countries, and the :filling of vacancies for seamen. These principles apply not only to public employment offices but also, with the exception of the provision as to gratuitous service, to the other nonprofit offices. The fundamental principle of the entire public employment system is gratuitous service (sec. 39) both for employers and for employees. This applies solely, however, to the main function of the employment agency; i.e., the filling of vacancies and/lacement of employees, inclu~ apprentices, but not to ·other ai given by the employment office, especially vocational guidance. The em_plo:yment office service should be impartial and take account of the individual circumstances of the applicant (sec. 40). The act states explicitly that the placing of workers in employment must be effected witliout regard to membership in an organization, ~quiries as to whether the a,licant belongs to an association of any kind ·ous denommation, etc.) being prohibited, (political party, r except in the case o establishments with a pronounced political or religious tendency. Private employment offices earned on by workers' organizations are allowed to ask questions of this nature. Blacklists are explicitly prohibited. In order_ to brmg tlie right man and the right place together, the act provides that vacancies are, as far as possible, to be filled with the most suitable applicants, taking into account, on the one hand, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 182 CHAPTER VII,-UN:ii:MPLOYMENT the nature and conditions of the work, and on the other hand, the trade and physical qualifications, as well as the personal and family circumstanc~, of the workman and the length of time he has been out of work. Placement according to qualification may be supplemented with advantage to employers and employees by information given by the manager and the agent, for it is frequently necess~, especially in filling positions of trust, that the _agent give information concerning the person he wishes to place. Manager and agent are therefore autnorized to give information of the particular conditions of a vacant situation that may be of importance to an applicant as well as of the peculiar qualifications of an apJ>licant whicn may be of importance in an available vacancy. Such information :;1 however, be given only if the particular conditions or special qu · cations have become known to the emP,loyee of the employment office in his official capacity and if justified by special circumstances; e.g., if the applicant is to live under the same roof with the employer (sec. 43). The terms of the offered employip.ent may determine decisively the filling of a vacancy. While employment offices are not to interfere in tli.e guestion of rates of w~es, neither are they to become accessory to infringements of collective agi:eements by filling vacancies where tlie rate of w~es proposed is considerably below the minimum rate customary in the trade and place. If the terms of the labor contract are regulated by collective agreement, the employment office is not to secure employees for employers unless tlie conditions of the contract are in accordance with the collective agreement (sec. 41). The employment offices must therefore be well versed in the terms of collective agreements.• In case the conditions of the contract are not fixed by a collective agreement, the public emplo~ent office must decline to place workers whenever the wages offered are lower than the minimum rates customary in the place. Although the employment· office should, in general refrain from interfering in the fii:ing of the rate of wages, the trade committee may, in case there is no established minimum rate of wages for that trade in the place, fix such a rate and the employment office is then bound by it. The attitude of the employment offices in case of strikes and lockouts is r~ated in detail by the act. Section 42 provides that in case of such economic struggles the employment offices are to take an impartial attitude, and to favor neither side, either by procuri!].g workers for employers or by refusing to supply workers. As the existence of a strike or lockout is of great importance to an apJ>licant in deciding whether or not to take a job, the employment office is bound to gj.ve information on this point. The employers are required and the workers' economic associations are permitted to inform the competent employment office in writi!ig of the outbreak or termination of a strike or lockout. Under the r8'?1llations on this point issued by the Federal office the employment o:flice to receive the notice is the office in whose district the business concerned in the strike is located. The notice should arrive, or at least be in the post, on the workine:-day following the outbreak of the strike or the commencement of the lockout. Failure to send the notice is punishable by :fine or imprisonment (sec. 54). https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis fl, EMPLOYMENT OFFIOES 188 When the written notice has been received, the employment agent is bound to inform an applicant of the strike or lockout, and to place him only in case he requests it after knowledge of the strike. Placement of striking or locked-out workers may be made only in case the employer has been- informed of the strike or lockout, even if such strike or lockout is in a. different trade. OBLIGATORY UPORTING 01' VAOABCIIS An important condition of effective unemployment relief is the adjustment of supply and demand on the labor market, for it is eVIdent that unemployment relief can operate smoothly and effectively only if vacancies are as fo.r as possible reported to such offices. The employment office act has not, however, made the reporting of vacancies to the employment office comJ>ulsory (which would mean that vacancies could not be filled ana no employee could be engaged except through the employment office), as the o:r:ganization of public employment offices in va.nous places and for various trades and professions is not so com_plete as to enable them fully to adjust supply and demand in all branches of the labor market. The reporting of vacancies by employers was thus made optional. The Minister of Labor may, however, after consulting the advisory council of the Federal Employment Office, order that certain employers shall report all vacancies to the competent em:eloyment office (sec. 49), but this authority is subject to four restrictions, viz: The reporting of vacancies may be made obligatory only in the case of workers subject to sickness and old-age insurance; it may not be made ob)katory in agriculture and in domestic service; establishments wit1i less than five employees may not be compelled to report vacancies; and employers can not be compelled to· report vacancies caused by strikes or lockouts. The act provides no means of compulsion m case an employer neglects to report vacancies, which · greatly reduces the value of these provisions.. The obligation to report vacancies :provided in section 49 of the act is extended by other laws. Section 74 of the law on works councils provides that in case of intended dismissal of large numbers of workers in consequence of reorganization of the business the employer shall be obliged, at the instance of the works councils, to report the same to the State employment office or the public employment office designated by the State office, in order that the necessary measures may be taken to place such workers. SPBOIAL DIPilTDJITS The following departments of the employment service are separately regulated by tlie employment office act: (1) The recruiting, placing, and employment of foreigp. workmen; (2) the recruiting and placing of German workmen in other countries; and (3) vocational guidance and the J?lacement of apprentices. ReC'l"Uiting, p'lacing, and employment of foreign workmen.-Under sectidn 26 of the act the recruiting, placing, and em~loyment of foreign workmen has been regulat_ed Dy decrees of the Federal Employment Office. In pre-war time no r~ulations were issued on these points. In the period of sudden growtli of German industry the number of workers available in Germany was not sufficient for the requirements of https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 184 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT industry and foreign workmen were engaged to fill the gn.ps in manufactures and fttrming. The influence of these foreign workers on conditions in German industry may be judged from their number, which was approximately a million. After the war when em;1;>loyment became scarce, the question of how to eliminate the com__petition of these foreign workers became urgent, and the Federal Employment Office, under the authority given it by section 26, regulated the placement of foreign workmen oy the decree of October 19, 1922, amended Januacy- 2, 1923 on the recruiting and plac~ of foreign rural workers, and by the decree of January 2, 1923, on the recruiting and employment of foreign workers. Even before these decrees had gone into effect a perceptible reduction in the number of foreign workers had set m. According to statistics of the Federal Office for the Placement of Foreign Workers their number in 1922 was: Men Manufactures ____________________ 114,910 Farming _________________________ 75,590 Total______________________ 190,500 Women 24,588 72,496 97,084 The leading principle of the decree of October 19, 1922, is that foreign workers shall be engaged only when suitable German workers are not available. The State employment office decides whether the engagement of foreign workers is to be permitted. Certain grc?Ups of foreign workers, however, are excepted from the rule; e. g., workers who have been employed in Germany for many years. To enable the authorities to supervise the employment of foreign workmen, employers are· not permitted to engage foreign workers who do not possess workers' identification cards. These identification cards are 1Ssued by a system of frontier offices organized for that purpose by the Federal Office for the Placement of Foreign Workers, As the foreign workmen are engaged only for certain jobs, measures are taken to prevent then:J. from changing their places of work easily. Such change is permitted only if the contract of the forei_gn workman is in l>erfect order. In case of dispute the public employment office decides. Foreign rural workers may not change from farming to manufacturing work without express permission of the State employment office. Special provision lS made as to wage and working conditions of foreign seasonal workers. Such workers may be employed only on the basis of the standard contract for foreign seasonal workers formulated b;y the agricultural trade. committee . of the Federal Employment Office. Application to employ foreign workers is subject to' the approval of the competent public employment office and of the State office. Violations of these provisions are punished by fine and imprisonment. Under the above-mentioned decree the recruiting and _placing of for~ rural workers is done by the Federal Office for the Plac'eme~t of Foreign Workers but only for concerns that have permission from the competent State empl~ent office to employ foreign workm~n. Recruiti'TUJ and placi1UJ o German workers in forej,gn countries.-As the abuses connected wi the recruiting ana J>lacing of Germ.an workers in foreign countries could not be effectually combated under existing legal regulations and such recruiting and placing directly influences the German labor market, section 60 of the employment https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 185 office act provides that the recruiting and placing of German workers in other countries is to be regulated by the Minister of Labor and the Minister of the Interior conjointly, after consultation with the advisory council of the Federal Employment Office. Under this authority the decree of October 4, 1923, on recruiting and plttcing of workers in foreign countries was issued, going into effect March 1, 1924. The decree provides that private nonprofit employment agencies and employment agencies operated for profit may place workers in foreign countries only when they have a special license therefor. Public employment offices are exceJ>ted from this rule. A license to place workers in foreign countries will be granted only if there is urgent necessity there£or ana the agency in question is proved to be trustworthy. Application for a license must be made to the competent State em_ployment office, but is granted only by tho Federal Employment Office. Certain untrustworthy agencies are prohibited altogether; e. g., itinerant employment agents doing business for gain. Violations are funishable by fine and imprisonment under section 60, paragraJ.>h 2, o the employment office act. Vocational gui<lance ar,li, pl,acement of apprentices.-In the last 10 years there has been a tendency in many communal employment offices to advise applicants as to the choice of a trade, in order to advance the trades requiring training and also the selection of suitable masters for apprentices and of places for the latter when they have :finished their training. A number of communal employment offices had accordingly established departments for this _purpose but a systematic organization was lacking. The decree of December 9, 1918, of the Federal Office for Economic Demobilization relating to emJ>loyment offices provided (sec. 4) that the State governments shoula. require the communes and communal unions to establish departments for general vocational guidance and for placement of apprentices. The decrees issued by the State governments thereunder left it to the communal authorities as to whether they would place such offices under the employment offices or under other communal bodies, such as the office for the protection of juveniles. In September, 1922,1' there existed in the 1,035 subordinate administrative districts 592 public vocational guidance offices. This number, however, includes many offices in which the manager had another main occupation. Of these 592 vocational guidance offices 71 were independent, 397 were departments of public employment offices, 79 of public welfare offices, 14 of offices for the protection of juveniles, 14 of schools, 12 of offices for widows and orphans' relief, and 5 of other public offices. Although the employment office act does not provide that the vocational guidance offices shall be placed under the public employment offices, this will probably become the rule because the communes have to bear the principal part of the expense of such offices unless they are placed under the public employment offices. Of the 592 vocational guidance offices, 17 assisted male youths, 1 assisted girls, and 574 assisted youths of both sexes; 506 of these offices also assisted adults, and 563 partial cripples. 11 That la, before the emploJDU!Dt office act went Into force; later data are not yet available. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 186 CHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT . '· L As men and women generally follow different trades, it has_ proved convenient in practice to have separate offices for them. Thus in 168 offices separate departments for males and for females have been established. That vocational guidance is intimately connected with placement of apprentices is indicated by the fact that in 568 cases the two are combin.ed. Table 62 shows how many of the 592 offices in 1922 had agents who devoted all or a part of their time to vocational guidance work or worked without salary: ' TABLB 69.-NUMBER AND PER CENT OF VOCATIONAL GUIDANCE OFFICES WHOSE AGENTS DID VOCATIONAL GUIDANCE WORK AS REGULAR OR AUXILIARY DUTY OR WITHOUT SAL.A.RY, 1922, BY SEX OF MANAGER Ollicea having agents whose vocational guidance work was done 1111-- !leJ: of manager Male•••• Fmnale. •••••••••••••••••••••••••••••• Regular duty Amlllary duty Without salary Not specified t Num• ber Num• ber 00 49 Per cent 9.li 8.3 433 113 Per cent 73.1 19.1 Number 92 13 Per cent lli.5 12. 2 Number 11 417 Per cent \ L9 70. 4 1 Includes all cases In whioh no special vocational guidance agent was employed but where, for example, the manager of the employment ollice acted as vocational guidance agent. In order that the ,fil~c;:1ent not only of juveniles but also of adults who chqe their c · may be regulated systematically, the Federal Employment Office was, by section 2, No. 4, of the decree of May 5, 1920, charged with the su_pervision of all bodies engaged in vocational gaj.dance work and the placement of apprentices. The provisions of the employment office act charge the Federal Emplo~ent Office with extended duties relating to vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices. Under section26 theFederalofficeisauthorized to lay down principles for the management not only of the public vocational guidance agencies but also of private institutions of this kind, subJect to the approval of the advisory council and after h e ~ of the guilds and economic organizations. It also supervises the management of offices for vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices conjointly with the respective State governments and may, with the approvj!,). of the advisory council, demand the closing of such offices if, by persistent violation of the principles laid down, they endanger the primary purpose of vocational gtridance and the placement of apprentices, in which case the offending office is closed by the State government. The Federal EmploYll!ent Office on May 12, 1923, issued "general regylations for vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices in employment offices" and also "general principles to be followed in vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices in institutions not under the public employment offices." While public emplo~ent offices are not obliged by these orders to establish departments for vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices1 in so far as they have undertaken these duties they are bound by tne rules laid down by the Federal office. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 187 Under these rules the departments for vocational guidance and the filacement of apprentices in the public employment offices are to make 'systematic arrangements for gui~ young people in choos~ a trade or profession and to inform the public as to all matters relatmg to the prospects in trades or ·professions." In this the employment offices are to cooperate closely with the schools, and in most of the States such cooperation is already established by law. It is also the duty of the vocational guidance offices of public employment offices "to give advice to applicants of both sexes in all matters relating to the choosing of a profession, both on entering business life and on changing then- trade or profession, and to training for the same. It is especially desirable in this respect to acquire an influence over the young peor,le under 18 years of age who apply to the public emJ>lOJIIl;ent office. ' Supervising the subsequent career of the persons adVISed or placed may also be included in the sCOJ?e of vocational guidance and placement of apprentices. The vocational ~dance offices shall also direct applicants to suitable training establishments. ApJ?rentices should not be placed in businesses or workshops that are tecbmcally, morally, or hygienically objectionable, and it is therefore the duty of placement agents to investigate a business or workshop taking apprentices, cooperating with the authorities char~ed with that matter. In other matters placement agents are subJect to the provisions of the employment office act for the general employment service. It is, however, emphasized in the "general regulations" that vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices must be impartial and that the interests of a trade must be made subordinate to general economic and social considerations. The pubhc employment offices may not undertake other duties relating to vocational ~idance and the placement of apprentices without the approval of the State employment office. No express regulations have been issued for :putting the vocational guidance agencies and the placement of apprentices under the employment offices, this being a matter to be settled accor<!!ng to the circumstances of each case. In smaller employment offices this work is frequently performed by an employment agent as a subsidiary duty. In the larger public employnient offices in large towns special departments have been created for the J?u.rpose, which are subJect to the management of the general administrative committee. The administrative committee lays down the lines along which vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices are to be administered and settles complaints. A council of experts, whose services are to be gratuitous, may be consulted for advice on pro_posed measures, the size and composition of such council varying with local requirements. The members of such council should be, first, employers and employees of the trades, commerce, manufactures, farming and domestic service, and then representatives of other c ~ , persons with practical knowledge ~f vocation~ guidance and the placement of appr~~ices, representatives of/ublic employment offices and schools, physicians, psychologists, an J>ersons engaged in public welfare work and in factory inspection. The number of representatives of employers and employees must be equal, and women must be included among the members. The term of office of the council should coincide witn that of the administrative committee. The standard rules and regulations https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 188 OHAPTER VII.-UNEMPLOYMENT for a lar~e public employment office, issued by .the Federal Employment Office, provide ~ressly that a council of experts shall be consulted before principles of management and items of the budget relating to vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices are adopted. The council a.ids in ascertaining the state of the labor market and the demand for apprentices, in procuring suitable instructors and traiajng schools, and in establishing cooperation with the schools, especially the technical schools, the juvenile department, the health department, the relief funds for mutilated soldiers, the survivors of soldiers killed in war, and cripples, and the factory ins_J>___ection service. · Wi~ the o~ject of sec~ persons of extended mcperience for this work, mstructions have been issued tha;t only persons at lea.st 28 years qf age with five yea.rs' successful work in a profession or trade, and experience in the treatment of juveniles are to be selected as vocational guidance agents. Teachers in technical schools are especially suitable persons for this work, because their ce,lling b;rings them mto close contact with the trades and professions and gives them, a personal knowledge of the employers who take apprentices. A woman should, if p<>ssible, be appointed in vocational guidance work for women. The employment office act has made vocational guidance and placement of apprentices part of the regular duty of the State employment offices.. This was done so that the local institutions in a district could be organized and their work coordinated and l?romoted. The provisions regulating the management of such agencies by the State· office are similar to those for the public employment offices. The State office must, howeveri form. a council composed of representatives of the principal vocational guidance agencies of the district. The duties of the State offices along these lines are to cooperate in establishing and developing agencies for vocational gajdance and placement of apprentices in the public employment offices of the district to supervise their administration when commissioned by the FederJ Employment Office, to supervise the organization and management of the agencies for vocational guidance and placement of aJ>prentices outside the public employment offices, to observe the suppJy and demand for apprentices in the trades, to adjust interlocally supply and demand, to secure cooperation between public yocational guidance and apprenticeship agencies and the persons and associations interested, to instruct vocational guidance agents, to collect statistics and inform.ation relating to trades and professions, to undertake vocational guidance work for professions or groups of persons not served by the employment offices, and_to promote opportunities for training in agnculture and domestic service, trades, commerce, and manufactures. The State office may not undertake other duties without the approval of the Federal Employment Office. The supervision the State offices exercise over the vocational guidance agencies relates only to their primary work and does not extend to details of management, which are supervised by the general administrative authorities. Vocational guidance and the placement ofi!prentices by agencies not under the public employment offices is re ated by the decree of May 12, 1923. The principles therein set orth a:pply to all such organizations, which are mainly or partly engaged m giving advice and information to applicants as to the choice of a trade or profession https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis EMPLOYMENT OFFICES 189 on entering business life, or on changing their calling, and apprenticeship and additional training, and also to agencies for the placement of apprentices. They do not apply to organizations giving only occasional advice and information, such as trade-unions, organizations for the prot~ction of juveniles, schools, etc. The decree l~ys down the general principle that the free action of individuals or associations along these lines, if really for the public welfare, should not be hampered, but that the State employment offices must have jurisdiction to proceed against such individuals or associations for abuses or incompetency. In order that private organizations engaged in such work may not be used for political purposes, the act prohibits their obtaining members for economic, religious, or political associations. Special regulations provide that it must appear from the name of the agency who is the organizer and for what trade or trades it is established. The management of such agencies must be impartial, and should consider primarily the preferences and the physical qualifications, etc., of its clients. The agents employed must be qualified and have had practical experience. Under the present law, employers having vacancies for apprentices are not obliged to apply for apprentices to the public offices for vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices. The State · employment offices may, however, demand reports from private agencies. The cooperation of private agencies with the public agencies must be arranged according to local circumstances. The State employment office m whose district private agencies are situated has supervision of their activities. Notice of the establishment of new and the closing of existing agencies must be given to the competent State employment office. In case the primary object of vocational guidance and the placement of apprentices is prejudiced by persistent violation of the above regula-tioils and principles, the Federal Employment Office may, with the approval of the advisory council, demand the closing of the offending agencies. The closing is done by the State government. 20168°-25t-13 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Chapter VIII.-COOPERATIVE MOVEMENT CONSUMERS' COOPERATIVE SOCIETIES Consumers' cooperative societies are associations formed for the purpose of purchasiilg at wholesale food and other goods, thus saviilg for the members the retailer's profit. These societies frequently manufacture the goods they deaf in, as soon as their sales warrant it. In Germ.any for the last 30 years they have been organized as registered- limited liability cooperative societies, though some few have kept to their original form of ·joint-stock companies. The law on cooperative societies prescribes their organization-managing committee, board of supervisors, general assembly-and regulates the :financial relations of the members to the society. Every member of the society has to contribute a certain amount of share capital and is also liable for a certain additional amount in case of failure. The law further provides for regular audits of the cooperative societies. These audits are usually carried out by the central unions of cooperative societies, or by special societies-auditing unions-formed for the purpose. . . The consumers' cooperative movement in Germany began in the fifties of the last cent~, such societies being formed by workmen and people of the middle classes. Their business was on a small scale, and it was not till the eighties that the movement received a fresh impetus. At that time the socialist workmen of the Saxon manufacturi!ig district began to join the existing societies in large . numbers and to establish new societies. In the last decade of the century the masses of the workmen, who in consequence of the economic prosperity of Germ.any flocked into the trade-unions in large numbers, took up the idea of consumers' cooperation spontaneously and with enthusiasm. The result wa.s that the movement for the establishment of consumers' societies suddenly assumed great· proportions. As a result of difference of p_olitical opinion between the conservative managers of the General Union of Germ.an Cooperative Societies and the representatives of the modem tendency in the movement, the latter, in 1903, established the Central Union of Germ.an Cooperative Consumers' Societies. A few years later a number of societies established by members of the so-called Christian trade-unions separated from tlie General Union and established the Union of West Germ.an 'Consumers' Cooperative Societies, later called the National Union of Germ.an Consumers' Cooperative Societies. The members of the societies belonging to this union are mainly persons connected with the Christian tradeunion movement. However, the establishment of consumers' retail societies is only the first step; the next is the formation of the cooperative wholesale society, in which may be pooled the purchasing power of the individual retail societies. The consumers' cooperative societies of Saxony had already (1893) established a wholesale purchasing society in Hambm-g. The members of the General Cooperative Union would, for a long time, have nothing to do with this wholesale society. The Nation.al Cooperative Union established its own wholesale society. 190 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis CONSUMERS' COOPERATIVE SOCIETIES 191 POSITION AT OUTBREAK OF Wil In December, 1913, the Central Union of German Consumers' Cooperative Societies comprised 1,157 societies with 4,881 stores and 1,621,195 members. Of their members, 1,220,530 were workmen. These societies had a business for the year of 742,006,215 marks, of which 99,877,629 marks were for goods of their own production. They employed 25,348 persons and their working capital amounted to 31,066,373 marks in share ca1;>ital, 22,503,801 marks in reserve funds, and 67,973,689 marks in savmgs deposits of members. Before the war, 807 cooperative societies were affiliated with the wholesale -purchasing society of the union (the G. E. G.). The wholesale's business amounted to 154,047,316 marks, of which 11,076,578 marks were for goods of its own production (soaJ?, cigars, and matches). The working capital of the wholesale society was 4,000,000 marks and its reserves 6,606,734 marks. This shows that the wholesale had been at pains to increase its capital as far as possible out of the profits and not to make calls on the societies for new capital. To what eJCtent it has worked with capital from other sources does not appear from the balance sheet, as the society also carries on a banking business and makes only one balance sheet for both departments of business. ' At the end of 1913, the membership of the General Union of German Consumers' Cooperative Societies included 287 consumers' cooperative societies liaving 623 stores, 323,228 members, and a turnover of 83,510,509 marks, of which amount 4,272,725 marks were for goods of their own production. The societies' reserves amounted to 4,558,571 marks and members' savings deposits to 2,123,782 marks. The National Union of German Consumers' CooJ>erative Societies comprised in 1913 159 societies, with 143,444 members. The business of these societies amounted to 38,597,252 marks, of which 3,943,540 marks were for articles produced by the societies. These societies employed· 1,877 persons and o:eerated 599 stores. Reserves amounted to 1,369,811 marks and saVIngs deposits of membel"\'I to 579,836 marks. Among its members were 82,715 industrial workers. The· wholesale society of the national union had a turnover for the year of 9,718,670 marks. SITUATION DURING THE WAR The war· affected the development of the German consumers' cooperative societies mainly as regards membership and business. On the outbreak of the war the ban formerly imposed by the Imperial Government, and in many cases also by the communal authorities, upon membership of their employees in consumers' cooperative societies was removed. Also, the prejudice of the middle classes against joining organizations of workmen disappeared. The- membershiJ;> field was tlierefore greatly enlarged and in some cases the societies received such an influx of new members that their requirements could not be satisfied, owing to the limitations on business operations because of the exigencies of war. In a few months, however, things were totally changed. When food became scarce in Germany and was rationed, some cooperative societies were favorably situated because their managers were employed in the commu1;uil https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 192 OHAPTER VIII.-COOPERATIVE MOVEMENT distribution of food, but ·on the whole the societies began to suffer because the authorities favored private business- concerns over the cooperative societies. The central purchasii}g o~anizations of the cooperative societies were ignored by the distriliuting authorities. The more the food-rationing system was developed_, the less completely was it carried out, so that illicit trade flourished and almost every dealer had a double stock-a legal one to sell openly over the counter and an illicit one under tlie counter. Tlie cooperative societies as wholesale dealers could not risk joining this illicit trade. Their members therefore freg_uently preferred to go to the private ·dealers, by whom they were lietter sup_plied. In consequence of the very great loss they thus sustained, the cooperative societies after the revolution were among the first to demand the abolition of the public distribution of food, altho~h the trade-unions and the Socialist Party vehemently opposed the slightest relaxation in the: rigor of the system. . CONDITIOB il'TD THE WAR Data showing the amount of business done since the war are very unsatisfactory, as the figures are comparable with those of previous yeus only if reduced to gold marks on the basis of the weekly or monthl_y mdex of the cost of liv_ing. In the following statistics the number of members is therefore given and the amount of business done stated only_jn a few cases, to allow the turnover of the different groups of societies to .be approximately compared. . The figures seem to show that the consumeril cooperative movement has extended but has made 4ttle gain in vigor, for the business done per member hardly reaches the pre-war figure .. The figures given are, however, taken at random and· may be misleading. · · · . The Central Union of German Cooperative Sc>cieties comprised ·at. the end of 1918, 1,090 societies operating 5,360 stores and having 2,231,917 members. At the end of 1922 the union comprised 1,350 societies running 8,066 stores and having 3,161,794 members. In thE! year 1922 these societies had ·sales of 13,889,3_14,620 marks, of which 2,264,443,400 marks was for goods produced by the union societies themselves. The number of societies affiliated with the cooperative wholesale society increased from 969 in 1918 to 1,030 at the end of 1922. At the end of 1918 the General Union of German Cooperative Societies comprised 253 consumers' societies, with 303,025 members. It had 506 stores and did business to the value of 80,000,000 marks. Since then it has lost a great many of it.s members, these societies. hav~ joined the Central Union of German Cooperative Consumers' Societies. The National Union of Cooperative Consumers' Societies comprised in 1918, 274 societies1 with 354,293 members and annual sales of 73,225,555 .marks, of which 5,492,283 marks were for goods produced by the societies. At the end of 1922, the union comprised 449 societies, with 654.583 members, 1,858 stores, and annual sales of 4,919,900,000 marks, of which 345,200,000 marks were for goods produced by the societies'. union. The most remarkable change occurring in the postwar period in the organization of the consumers' cooperative societies is the estab. ' https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis CONSUMERS' COOPERATIVE SOCIETIES 193 lisbment of a joint committee consisting of representatives of the 'various cooperative unions. ·The mere intimate connections between the unions have not led to business relations of any considerable importance between consumers' and producers' coo:eerative societies but only to joint action on questions of taxation ana legislation. The most important result of this joint action is an amendment to the cooperative societies law b,y which the legal obstacles to the amalgamation of cooperative societies were removed. Under the law in its original form amalgamation of societies could take place only by one of the societies winding up its affairs and its members joining the other society. This method always resulted in a considerable loss of members. By the amendment amalgamation may be effected by a two-thirds vote of the members at general meetings of the societies concerned, by 'virtue of which the members of both societies automatically become members of the new societv from the day on which amalgamation takes ]?lace. In view of the tendency for small cooperative societies in a neighborhood to join the larger and more efficient societies, this amendment is of some importance. The cooperative societies law has further introduced the system of representation by delegates in the general assemblies, making the representation by delegates obligatory for the societies with more than 10,000 members and optional for those of medium size (with more than 3,000 members). By their close cooperaiion the unions, which had drafted the bill of amendments, succeeded in having the new act so formulated that the application of theae provisions of the act was left altogether to the societies. T.he business of the consumers' cooperative societies in the years f ollowi~ the war has suffered because the time of the managers has necessarily been so much occupied by the fluctuations of the market and the depreciation of the money. The need of capital has also been frequently felt to a considerable degree. Finally the reorganization of business after the war had to be carried out with the older generation of managers, who, while having an extended experience, were not always enterprising enough to take up new lines with enthusiasm but preferred a slow rate of evolution. One reason for this may- be that the extension of business has been mainly concentrated on dry goods. Before the war, the tax on department stores made it almost impossible, at least in Prussia, for cooperative societies to deal in dry goods. In other parts of Germany, the dry goods and shoe business wp.s of great importance, but nowhere of the importance it had attained in the cooperative consumers' societies in England at that time. The repeal of the tax on department stores produced a considerable change in this respect. A number of consumers' cooperative societies in l ~ cities have established department goods, boots and shoes, and housestores, and the business in hold articles has on the who e been greatl_y _extended. Here and there furniture departments have been established. It is especially difficult to gain an insight into the financial position of tlie consumers' cooperative societies. The unions 4ave, it is true, published the figures relating to their business operations during the whole period of inflation, but data. for re duet~ these figures to gold value so as to have a stable basis for calculation are not available. On the whole, though the societies sustained some losses, they have not suffered much either by the war or by the revo- https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 194 CHAPTER· VIII.-COOPERATIVE MOVEMENT lution. Their :financial position was, however, decisiveli influenced by the inflation of the currency· and this in two op_posite ·directions. On ~he one hand, the consumers' cooperative societies have1 along with th.e retail business generally, suffered in many ways t>y the legislation against usurious trade practices and the way in which it was administered, and as they were prohibited frotn demanding the cost _price of their goods, they sufferea loss of capital; On the other hand, the food business has, on the whole, flourished during this period. Preferential credits were accorded to food dealers by the Reichsbank and they thus succeeded, though generally wanting_ in business capacity, in profiting by the inflation of the currency. The cooperative consumers' societies also profited by this condition. Though for a few months they lost continually: they then made extraordinarily high profits on their stock through the depreciation of the currency. A survey of the business done and the bills for goods in the periods of relative stability of the currency shows that the societies do not pay as promptly as in pre-war times and demand longer terms. This indicates a certain need of ca:eital, but on the whole they seem to have held their own, with varying success, until the autumn of 1923, when the currency broke down altogether. At this time the cooperative consumers' societies have evidently sustained severe losses of working capital. As soon as the rentenmark was introduced and even before i;he stability of the new currency was recognizable, they proceeded to declare the old shares void ana to sell new shares payable in rentenmarks. The societies had already made a number of increases in the nominal amount of the old shares, which virtually amounted to .assessments on the members, a proceeding which caused a certain amount of discontent. It is tlierefore rather doubtful whether this fresh demand for capital in the form of new shares will be altogether successful. The ability of the consumers' cooperative societies to · compete with private dealers has been c~nsiderably reduced in the last few years by the ~eneral sales tax and by the situation as to wage and working conditions. The changes in working conditions produced b_y the war and the revolution showed themselves most forcibly in the relations of the cooperative societies to their workmen and salaried e!llplorees. Before the war the societies belonging to the Central Union of German Consumers' Cooperative Societies had concluded national collective agreements with the bakers' and transport workers' trade-unions. On the whole the relations of the consumers'.societies . with the bakers' union were excellent and with the transport workers' union rather good. The only serious conflicts were with the head salesmen who had a union of their own. The shop girls as well as the female clerks regarded their occupation with the consumers' societies as transitory and were of little importance as trade-union members. After the revolution there was a tendency, perceptible though short lived, to substitute works' councils for the tradeunions •in negotiations with the· workmen. This tendency was more pronounced with the cooperative societies than with private business as the m~~ement of the cooperative consumers' societies was restricted by various obligations towards their members. The subject of collective agreements next came to the fore. After the rev-0lution1 the managers of the consumers' cooperative societies https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis CONSUMERS 1 COOPERATIVE SOCIETIES 195 attempted to regulate the relations of the societies with their employees . b_y concluding ~eneral collective agreements with - each of the different trade-umons in the same way that the collective agreement in the printers' trade had alw__ttys applied to the printers employed by the consumers' societies. This attempt, however, was a complete failure, the only result being that the trade-unions concernedbegan individually to assail the consumers' societies. Because of these continual conflicts the societies :finally resorted to national collective agreements. The relation between the societies and the bakers' trade-union, the old management of which had been overturned, has become especially bad. During the war night work in the bakers' trade was ·prohibited, in order to prevent the consumption of fresh rolls in the morning and thus to economize wheat flour. This prohibition of baking du.ring the night has remained in force, although the consumers' societies, which worked three shifts, were thereby prevented from utilizing their plant to full advantage. Consumers' cooperative societies and the General Federation of Trade-Unions at fresent unite in the demand for the abrogation of the prohibition o night work in concerns working three shifts, but the bakers oppose this vehemently. The works councils have, with the exception of a short period in 1919, been of little more importance than the workmen's committees in former times. Attempts to give the works councils' delegate a seat on the supervising board came to naught because of the provisions of the cooperative societies act. The cooperative wholesale society has, perhaps, experienced the most remarkable development in the whole cooperative movement. During the war nothing could be done to increase its business, but after the war it began to develop its business in manufactured goods and household articles and created a central office for this department in Saxony. It also greatly increased the number of its industrial works and 110w manufactures soai>, tobacco products, matches, mustard, fish products, macaroni, boxes, clotliing, confectionery, brushes, furniture, etc. It is difficult to give exact figures showing its :financial condition, but comparison of the business reports pf 1913 and 1922 shows that there has been considerable expansion. In general, the progress of German consumers' cooperative societies may be summarized as follows: They have been less crippled by the war than _an_y other economic movement in Germany, and they have not been influenced permanently by the revolution. The war found them in a period of rapid growth and development, for which their :financial resources were not quite adequate, and this was in a great measure interrupted by the war. Since the war they have been hindered by lack of capital and the precarious economic conditions. Their members have increased and they have extended their business considerably in manufactured goods and household articles, but hardly any in foodstuffs. They sustained considerable losses of workim? capital owing to the breakdown of the currency and are now engagea in reo~anizing their business. In spite of their great importance to tlie workmen, before the war tliey took no part in public life, and public opinion took no notice of them; this condition has not been clianged by the disturbances and econoinic and political revolutions which have occurred. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis ·196 CHAPTER VIII.-COOPERATIVE MOVEMENT COOPERATIVE BUILDING SOCIETIES AND BUILDING GUILDS COOPDATIVB BUILDING SOCIETIES The German cooperative building societies, like the consumers' societies, are almost exclusively registered ·societies with · limited liability. Their importance before tlie war lay mostly along educational lines. They departed from the apartment-house system/revailing in many large cities, and again and again demonstrate b7. practical examples that even with rather high building-lot prices 1t was possible for one-family and two-family houses to compete with apartment houses; and they educated public opinion by interesting especially the workers in housing reform. But their activity was not · ·of great importance if measured by the number of their members and the dwellings they erected. According to the last comprehensive pre-war statistics, which refer to January 1, 1912, the number of cooperative building societies was 1,173, with 225,672 members. The number of houses and dwellings erected is reported for only- 494 societies, with 127,377 members; by the end of 1910 these had built 10,678 houses, with 51,086 dwellings. It is therefore safe to say that up to the war these societies had not constructed more than 100,000 dwellings. . During the war the cooperative building societies naturally made little progress. At first they suffered financial losses through the vacating of shops and the mcapacity of many of their members, especially the wives of their enrolled members, to pay the full rent. Later, when industry became more prosperous and the demand for ·dwellings increased, other difficulties-in/articular the scarcity and high cost of building materials-prevente them from erecting houses to any extent. After the war there was a very_ strong trend toward cooperative building societies. Their number increased from 1,391 on January 1, 1918, to 1,485 on January 1, 1919, 2,126 on January 1, 1920, 2,545 on January 1, 1921, 3,118 on January 1, 1922, 3,311 on January 1, 1923, 3,422 on January 1, 1924, and 3,795 on January 1, 1925. But many of the new societies h,.1,d very few membe~, and some of them were not genuinely cooperative societies but so.cieties :financed more or less by employers or contractors. Because of the difficulties encountered in the construction of dwellillgs duri~ the period of inflation (see pages 39 to 47), the record of the activities of the cooperative building societies was small, if measured by the need for housing accommodations, but very large if measured by- the total number of new dwellings. According to data of investigations made by the Federal Statistical Office, the number of houses and dwellings constructed by public welfare buil~ activities (Gemeinnutzige Ba'IJJ,ii,ti,gkfnt) and by other building activities was as follows: https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 197 COOPERATIVE BUILDING SOCIETIES AND BUILDING GUILDS TABLII 63.-NUMB"ER OF HOUSES AND DWELLINGS ERECTED IN GERMAN CITIES, 1929 TO 1923 • Num• Number oflnhabi• berof tants cities Year 1920••••••••••••••••••• --- --------lll'Jl. -····· '···-·- -· ···-·· ••••••••• 1922••••••• -·-·-----------·--------i 1923-··········-···-··············· 35 35 35 42 43 42 44 Public welfare building activities Dwell• Houses Over 100,000____ ••• Over 100,000__ ••••• Over 100,000___ •••• Over 100,000_____ ._ ings 4,497 6,470 5,490 6,612 3,163 6,901 .2, 911 50,000 to 100,000_ ·Over 100,000_______ 50,000 to 100,000 -- 10,468 12,228 12,988 15,619 6,301 18,699 6,922 Other building activitles Houses Dwell• 710 1,139 2,226 3,523 758 3,660 684 ings 8,433 9,045 10,562 14,381 2,711 12,!!68 2,711 In the cities with over 100,000 inhabitants covered by these statistics the per cent of dwelling houses constructed for public welfare amountecl in 1920 to 86.4, in 1921 to 85.0, in 1922 to 65.2, and in 1923 to 65.3, and the per cent of new dwellings in 1920 to 55.4, in 1921 to 57.5, in 1922 to 52.1, and in 1923 to 59.2. The fact that the percent~e of houses built by public welfare activities was in each year larger than the percentage of dwellings so constructed, while the difference between the two percentages decreased each year, is due to the larger size of the houses constructed by' other building activities and the increasing tendency to erect smaller houses, and also to a certain extent to the mcreasing number of villas constructed by the newly rich. Building for _public welfare was carried on during these 7ears in the smaller more than in the larger cities. The percentage o the houses erected for public welfare was in 1922, 80.7 and in 1923, 81.0 in the cities from 50,000 to 100,000 inhabitants, as compared with 65.2 in 1922 and 65.3 in 1923 in the larger cities, and the percentage of dwellings in 1922, 69.9 and in 1923, 71.9, as compared with 52.l m 1922 and 59.2 in 1923. One must, however, bear in mind that these figures include not only dwelling houses erected b_y cooperative building societies but also dwellings constructed by the Federal Government, the municipalities, private employers, foundations, etc. It is possible-I.however, at least for the year 1922, separately to consider the dwellings constructed by cooperative building societies (including foundations) and to add some details about the size of the dwellings. TABLB 64.-NUMBER OF HOUSES AND DWELLINGS ERECTED BY GERMAN COOPER· A TIVE BUILDING SOCIETIES, 1922 Size of city Dwelllnp withNumber Houses 6 of 1 2 3 4 5 rooms cities room rooms rooms rooms rooms and Total more ._···············--1 Over 100,000 lnhabltants __ 80,000 to 100,000 Inhabitants_.-••••••••••••••• 42 43 4,272 2,093 3 ------ 128 ,2,267 4,164 2,008 1,042 77 606 1,572 757 117 I 9,632 3, 1211 Of the total houses erected the per cent erected by cooperative building societies was thus, in the cities over 100,000 inhabitants, 42.2, and in the cities from 50,000 to 100,000 inhabitants 53.41 the per .cent of tota.l·dwellings-was 32.1.and 34.7,-respectively. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis 198 CHAPTER VIlI.-COOPERATIVE MOVEMENT One-third of all the dwellings constructed in German cities with over 50,000 inhabitants were erected by cooperative building societi~1 and yet the building activities of these societies was small, even il: measured by their activity in pre-war times. The cooperative building societies l:iave gained considerable moral ground since the war as the general public has come to see that these societies, which had been so belittled in pre-war times, had after all in a •time of great crisis shown more power of resistance than private business enterprises. It was generally hoped that after the stabilization of the mark the cooperative societies would take up the construction of new dwellings on a very large scale, but as the cost of building is about 60 per cent higher than 10 years ago and the rate of interest on mortgages exceeds the pre-war level by at least 100 per cent, these hopes have so far not been fulfilled. BUILDING GUILDS While the p~ose of cooperative building societies is to supply to their memoers for their own use adequate dwellings at a reasonable price, builders' cooperative societies and building _guilds build for third parties. Builders' cooperative societies existed to some extent before the war, gained some ground during the war, and developed eonsiderabl:y in the first ye~rs. after _the war, but they_ were more and more outstnpped by the buildmg guilds, the first of which was founded in 1919. The objects of building guilds a.re (1) to carry on building work of all kinds and to acce:rt contracts for such work, especiallk:1 connection with workers hous~, and (2) to acquire bull · material establishments. "The ouilding guild," according to its by-laws, "shall aim at relieving the housmg short~e, improving housing conditions, and encouragmg technical progress m the ouildip.g trade. It shall especially attempt to accomplish these aims by means of tryuig and pe:ffect~ the various methods of building and working, by s~tema.tically developing professional skill, and by increasing the willingness of their salaried employees and workers to do efficient work. Its guidini? principle shall always be to construct buildings for the community o1 as good a quality as possible at the lowest practicable cost. " , The advantages of the building guilds over the builders' societies are: (a) The members of the guilds a.re not single individuals but public bodies or public-welfare bodies, and therefore public interest 1s better safeguarded than in the builders' societies. (b) AB the principal shareholders of the building guilds (which are limited-liability companies) are the Federal Government, State governments1 mumcipa.lities, trade-unions, home settlement societies, etc., the building guilds have a more stable :financial foundation than the ,builders' societies, which depend on single individuals, generally of small means. (c) The building guilds are also superior· to the builders' societies in that the latter are subject to ~he decisJons of the majority of the general assembly, the membership of which may ch~e qmckly.From the.very outset the building guilds had considerable practical success in spite of the opposition of vested interests; As they: limited profits to 5 per cent and as the best workers sought employment https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis COOPERATIVE BUILDING SOCIETIES AND BUILDING GUILDS 199 by the guilds, they could easily submit lower bids than those of private contractors and were soon offered more contracts than they could carry out. The building trades-unions soon r~cognized the importance of the building guilds in the slow recovery of the building trades and assisted the guilds in many ways. It was indeed mainly due to their financial help that it was possible to create, as early as September 16, 1920, a Federation of Public Welfare Building Enterprises (Verband sozialer Betriebe), which included both the building guilds and the builders' cooperative societies. The objects of this federation, according to its by-laws, are "to found and encourage public welfare enterprises organized as cooperative or other societies, not working on private capitalistic lines, and to represent such enterprises in negotiations with the authorities of the Federal Government, the State governments, and the municipalities." The number of enterprises affiliated with the federation was 200 on December 31, 1921, 207 on December 31, 1922, and 214 on June 30, 1923. But in the meantime the transformation of builders' cooperative societies into building guilds had made so much progress that the number of affiliated cooperative societies dropped from 140 to 107 and then to 74, while the number of affiliated guilds had increased from 60 to 100 and then to 140. The number of workers employed in the enterprises affiliated with the federation is about 20,000. While this represents only about 2 per cent of the total number of German building trades workers, the enterprises have, according to the reports of the federation, constructed almost 10 per cent of the total number of small dwellings built since the formation of the federation. The paid-in and working capital of the building guilds eix:c;eeds 10,000,000 gold marks and it steadily increases, as the building trades-union has yassed a resolution that 5 per cent of the union contributions shal be placed at the disposal of the building guilds. The ~uilds own works for the production of building materials, such as bnck kilns, sawmills, compo factories, gravel pits, stone quarries, slate quarries, etc. They also own a woodworking factory, and a good deal of land, scaffolding, etc. The guild idea has taken hold of all the branches of the building trade, and the guilds may be expected to grow rapidly as soon as the general impediments to building activity disappear., https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis SERIES OF BULLETINS PUBLISHED BY THE BUREAU OF WOR STATISTICS [The publf.catlon of the annual and apecial report• and of the bimonthly bullstin , _ dllH:ontlnW#l in July, lllJ, and atnce that time a bulletin haa been publt,,hed at irregular inter.,,,,.. Bach number contalna matter der,oted to one of a aeries of general aubjecta. T,._,, bulletina are numbered COlllleCUtir,ely, beginning u,ith No. 101, and up to No. ZII they alao carry co1111eCutir,e numbers under each aerlea. Beginning u,ith No. m the aerial numbering haa been dllH:ontinued. A liat of the- aeries t,, gu,en belou,. Under each i• grouped all the bulletina u,hi.ch contain material relating to the aubject matter of that aerla. A lt,,t of the report• and bulletina of the Bureau "'8ued prior to July 1, 1111, UJill be furnt,,hsd on a,pplf.cation. The bulletina marked thua • are out of print.] Wholeme~. •Bui. 114. Wholesale prices, 1890 to 1912. Bui. 149. Wholesale prices, 1890 to 1913. •Bui. 173. Index numbers of wholesale prices In the United States and foreign ooanbieB. •Bui. 181. Wholesale prices, 1890 to 1914. •Bui. 200. Wholesale prices, 1890 to 1915. •Bui. 226. Wholesale prices, 1890 to 1916. Bui. 269. Wholesale prices, 1890 to 1919. Bui. 284. Index numbers of wholesale prices In the United States and foreign COUIJtrles. [Bevlalcm of Bulletin No. 173.) Bui. 296. Wholesale. prices, 1890 to 1920. Bui. 320. WholesBle prices, 1890 to 1921. Bui. 335. Wholesale prices, 1890 to 1922. Bui. 367. Wholesale prices, 1890 to 1923 ReCaU Prlees and CNt of Lhlna. •Bui. 105. Retail prices, 1890 to 1911: Part I. Retail prices, 1890 to 1911: Part !I-General tables. •Bui. 100. Retail prices, 1890 to J'une. 1912: Part I. Retail prices, 1890 to J'une, 1912: Part II-General tabla Bui. lOII. Retail prices, 1890 to Augost, 1912 Bui. 110. Retail prices, 1890 to October, 1912. Bui. 113. Retail prices, 1890 to December, 1912. Bui. 115. Retail prices, 1890 to February, 1913. •Bui. 121. Sugar prices, from re1lner to consumer. Bui. 125. Retail prices, 1890 to April, 1913. •Bui. 130. Wheat and II.our prices, from farmer to cousllllllr. Bui. 132. Retail prices, 1890 to J'une, 1913. Bui. 136. Retail prices, 1890 to August, 1913. •Bui. 138. Retail prices, 1890 to October, 1913. •Bui. 140. Retail prices, 1890 to Deoember, 1913 Bui. 156. Retail prices, 1907 to Deoember, 1914. Bui. 164. Butter prices, from producer to conaumer. Bui. 170. Foreign food prices as affected by the WIil'. · •Bui. 184. Retail prices, 1907 to J'une, 1915. Bui. 197. Retail prices, 1907 to Deoember, 1915. Bui. 228. Retail prices, 1907 to December, 1916. Bui. 270. Retail prices, 1913 to 1919. Bui 300. Retail prices, 1913 to 1920. Bui. 315. Retail prices, 1913 to 1921. Bui. 334. Retail prices, 1918 to 1922. Bui. 367. Coat of living in the United States. Bui. 366. Retail prices, 1913 to December, 1928, Bui. 369. The use of cost-of-living 11.gures in wage adjustment&. [In p1'8118.) Wases and Boars of Labor. · Bui. 116. Hours, earnings, and duration of employment of -wage-earning women in selected Industries in the District of Columbia. Ten-hour maximum working-day for women and young persons. Working hours of women In the pea 08Dllerles of Wl8consln. Wages and hours oflabor in the cotton, woolen, and silk industries, 1890 to 1912. Wages and hours oflabor in the lumber, millwork, and furniture Industries, 1890 to 1912. Union scB1e of wages and hours oflabor, 1907 to 1912. Wages and hours oflabor in the boot and shoe and hoatery and knit good& industries, l8DO to 1912. •Bnl. 136. W aaea and hours of labor In the cigar and c1othlug Industries, 1911 and 1912. Bul. 137. Wages and hours of labor In the building and repairing of steam railroad cars, 1890 to 19U. •Bui. 118. Bui. 119. •Bui. 128. •Bui. 129. •Bw. 131. •Bui. 134. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (I) Waae• 1111d Ronn of Labol'-Ooncluded. Bui. 143. Union scale of wages and hours of labor, May 15, 1013. •Bui. 146. Wages and regularity of employmant and standardization of P'- rates In the dress and waist industry of New York City. •Bui. 147. Wages and regularity of employment In the cloak, suit, and skirt Industry. •Bui. lliO. Wages and hours oflabor in the cotton, woolen, and silk industries, 1907 to 1913. •Bui. 151. Wages and hours oflabor in the Iron and steel industry In the United States, 1907 to 1912. Bui. 153. Wages and hours of labor in the lumber, mmwork, and furniture industries, 1907 to 1913. 154. Wages and hours of labor in the boot and sboe and hosiery and underwear Industries, 1907 to 1913. . . Bui. 160. Hours, eamlnp, and conditions of labor of women In Indiana mercantile establishments and garment factories. · Bui. 161. Wages and hours oflabor In the clothing and cigar industries, 1911 to 1913. Bui. 163. Wages and hours oflabor in the building and repairing of steam railroad cars, 1907 to 1913. Bui. 168. Wages and hours of labor in the Iron and steel industry, 1907 to 1918. •Bui. 171. Union scale of wages and hours of labor, May 1, 1914. · Bui. 177. Wages and hours oflabor in the hosiery and underwear industry, 1907 to 1914. Bui. 178, Wages and hours of labor in the boot and shoe industry, 1907 to 1914. •Bui. 187. Wages and hours oflabor in the men's clothing Industry, 1911 to 1914. •Bui. 190. Wages and hours oflabor in the cotton, woolen, and silk Industries, 1907 to 191'194. Union scale of wages and hours oflabor, May 1, 1915. Bui. l!M. Street railway employment In the United States. Bui. 214. Union scale of wages and hours oflabor, May 15, 1916. Bui. 218. Wages and hours of labor In the Iron and steel Industry, 1907 to 1914. Bui. 221. Hours, fatigue, and health In British munition fact<lries. Bui. 225. Wages and hours of labor in the lumber, millwork, and furniture Industries, 1915. Bui. 232. Wages and hours of labor in the boot and shoe Industry, 1907 to 1918. Bui. 238. Wages and hours oflallor In woolen and worsted goods manufacturing, 1916. Bui. 239. Wages and hours oflabor In cotton goods manufacturing and ftnlshlng, 1918. Bui. :Mii. Union scale of wages and hours oflabor, May 15, 1917. Bui. 252. Wages and hours of labor hi the slaughtering and meat-packing Industry, 1917. Bui. 259. Union scale of wages and hours of labor, May 15, 1918. Bui. 260. Wages and hours of labor In the boot and shoe industry, 1907 to 1918. Bui. 261. Wages and hours of labor In woolen and worsted goods manufacturing, 1918. Bui. 262. Wages and hours oflabor In cotton gooda manufacturing and tlnishlng, 1918. Bui. ~- Industrial survey In eelected Industries in the United States, 1919. Preliminary report. Bui. 274. Union scale of wages and hours of labor, May 15, 1919. Bui. 278. Wages and hours of labor In the boot and shoe Industry, 1907 to 1930. Bui. 2'19. Hours and earnings In anthracite and bituminous coal mining. Bui. 286. Union scale of wages and hours oflabor, May 111, 1920. Bui. 288. Wages and hours of labor In cotton gooda manufacturing, 1920. Bui. 289. Wages and hours of labor In woolen and worsted goods manufacturing, 1920. Bui. 294. Wages and hours of labor In the Blaugbterlng and meat-packing Industry In Bui. 'NI. Wages and hours of labor in the petroleum industry. . Bui. 302. Union scale of wages and hours of labor, May 15, 1921. Bul. 306. Wages and hours of labor In the Iron and steel industry, 1907 to 1920. Bul. 316. Hours and earnlnga in anthracite and bituminous coal :mlnlng-anthraclte, JanllllrJ', 1922; bituminous, winter of 1921-22. . Bui. 317, Wages and hours of labor in lumber manufacturing, 1921·. Bul. 32'. Wages and hours of labor in the boot and shoe industry, 1907 to 11122. Bul. 325. Union scale of wages and hours oflabor, May 111, 1922. Bul. 327. Wages and hours oflabor In woolen and worsted goods manofaoturlng, 1921. Bui. 328. Wages and hours oflabor in hosiery and underwear Industry, 11121. Bul. 329. Wages and hours oflabor In the men's clothing Industry, 11122. Bul. Mil, Wages and hours of labor In cotton-goods mannfacturlng; 1922. Bui. 348. Wages and hours of labor In the automobile Industry, um. Bui. 353. Wages end hours of labor In the Iron and steel industry, 1907 to 11121, Bui. 354. Union sca1e of wages and hours of labor, May 111, 1923. Bui. 356. Prodwiivity costs In the common-brick Industry, 1922-23. Bui. 3118. Wages and hours of labor In the automobile-tire industry, 1928, Bui. 360. Time and labor costs In manufacturing 100 pairs of shoes. Bui. 362. Wages and hours of labor In foundries and machine shops, 111211. Bui. 363. Wages.and hours of labor In lumber manufacturing, 1923. Bui. 365. Wages and hours of labor In the paper and pulp Industry. Bui. 371. Wages and hours of labor in cotton-goods manufacturing. 19H. Bui. 873. 'Wages and hours of labor in Blaugbtering and meat packing, 11123. Bui. 374. Wages and hours of labor In the boot and shoe Industry, 1907 to ill24. . Bul. 376. Wages and hours of labor in hosiery and underwear Industry, 1907 to 192'. Bul 377. Wages and hours of labor In woolen and worsted goods manufacturlnr, 11126. •:eu1. •:eul. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis um. (D) Bmploymen& and Unemploy1118111•Bul. 109. Statistics of unemployment and the work of employment offices. Bnl, m1. BolllB, earnings, and duration of employment of w ~ women In selected IDdUBtrles In the District of Columbia. Bul. 172. Unemployment In New York City, N. Y. •Bul. 182. Unemployment among women In department and other retail stores of Boston, Mass. -Dul. 183. Regularity of employment In the women's ready-to-wear garment Industries. Bul. 192. Proceedings of the American Association of Public Employment Offices. •Bul. 195. Unemployment In the United States. Bui. 196. Proceedings of the Employment Managers' Conference held at Minneapolis, Minn., January, 1916. •Bui. 202. Prooeedlngs of the confarence of Employment Managers' A.ssoolatlon of Boston, Mass., held May 10, 1916. Bul. 206. The 1'rltlsh system of labor exobanges. Bul. 220. Prooeedlngs of the Fourth Annual Meeting of the American Assoolatlon of Public Employment Offices. Bul. 223. Employment of women and Juveniles In Great Britain during the war. •Bui. '01. Proceedings of the Employment Managers' Confarence, Philadelphia, Pa., April 2 and 3, 1917. Bui. 235. Employment system of the Lake Carrlars' Association. Bul. 241. Public employment offices In the United States. Bul. 247. Proceedings of Employment Managers' Conference, Roobestar, N. Y., May 9-11, 1918. Bul. 310. lndUBtrlal unemployment: A statistical study of Its extent and causes. Bui. 311. Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Meeting of the Intarnational Assoolatlon of Public Em• ployment Sarvioes, Buffalo, N. Y., Septembar 7-9, 1921. Bui. 337. Proceedings of the Tenth Annual Meeting of the lntarnational .Association of Public Em• ployment Services, Washington, D. C., Septembar 11-13, 1922. Bul. 3M, Prooeedlngs of the Eleventh Annual Meeting of the Intarnatlonal A.ssoolatlon of Public Employment Services, September 4-7, 1923. Women In Indu&r,, Bul. 116. BolllB, earnings, and duration of employment of w&gHBrD!ng women In 8eleoted lndUBtrles In the District of Columbia. •Bui. 117. Prohibition of night work of young parsons. •Bul. 118. Ten-hour maximum working-day for women and young persons. Bui. 119. Working hOlllB of women In the pea cannarles of Wisconsin. •Bul. 122. Employment of women In powar laundries In Milwaukee. Bul. 160. llolllB, earnings, and conditions of labor of women In Indiana mercantile establishments and garment factories. •Bul. 167. Minimum-wage legislation in the United States and foreign countries. •Bul. 175. Summary of the report on condition of woman and child wage earners In the United States. •Bui. 176. Effect of minimum-wage detarminatlons In Oregon. •Bul. 180, The boot and shoe lndUBtry In MassachUBetts as a vocation for women. •Bul. 182, Unemployment among women In department and other retail stores of Boston, Mass. Bul. 193. Dressmaking as a trade for women In MassacbUBetts. Bui. 215. Industrial experience of trade-school girls in Massachusetts. Bul. 217. Effect of workmen's compensation laws In diminishing the necessity of lndUBtrial employ. ment of women and children. Bul. 223. Employment of women and Juveniles In Great Britain during the war. Bul. 253. Women In the lead Industries, Wol'kmen'e lneurance·and Compenaadon (lncladlnc laW8 relatlnc thento). •Bul. 101. Care of tubarculoUB wage earners In Germany. •Bul. 102. British National Insurance Act, 1911. Bui. 103. Sickness and accident Insurance law of Switzerland. Bul. 107. Law relating to Insurance of salaried employees In Germany. •Bui. 126. Workmen's compensation laws of the U nlted States and foreign countries• . •Bul. 155. Compensation for accidents to employees· of the United States. •Bui. 185. Compensation legislation of 1914 and 1915. •Bui. 203. Workmen's compensation laws of the United States and foreign countries. Bui. 210, Proceedings of the Third Annual Meeting of the lntarnatlonal Aaioclatlon of IndustrlaJ Accident Boards and Commissions. Bui. 212. Proceedings of the conference on social Insurance called by the International Association of Industrial Accident Boards and Commissions. Bui. 217, Effect of workmen's oompensatlon laws In diminishing the necessity of Industrial employ• ment of women and children. Bul. 240. Comparison of worli:men's compensation laws of the United States. Bul. 243. Workmen's compensation legislation In the United States and foreign oountrles. Bul. MS. Prooeedlngs of the Fourth Annual Meeting of the Intarnatlonal Aaloc1atlon of Industrial Aeoldent Boards and Commissions. • https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Wen:men'•1 - and Compenadlen-Ooncluded. Bui. 26'. Proceedlnp of the• Fifth Annual Meeting of the International Allloclatlon of Indl18trfal Accident Boards and Commissions. Bui. 272. Workmen's compensation legislation of the United States and Canada, 1919. *Bui. 273. Proceedings of the Sixth Annual Meeting of the International Association of Industrial Accident Boards and Commissions. Bui. 275. Comparlson of workmen's compensation laws of the United States and Canada. Bui. 281. Proceedings of the Seventh Annual Meeting of the Intenaatlonal ABSOCiatlon of Industrial Accident Boards and Commissions. Bui. 801. Comparison of workmen's compensation iDsonmce and administration. Bui. 304. Proceedings of the Eighth Annual Meeting of the International ABSOCiation of Industrial Accident Boards and Commissions. Bui. 812. National Health IDSU1'811oe In Great Britain, 1911 to 1920. Bui. 832. Workmen's compensation legislation of the United States and Canada, 1920 to 1922; Bui. 333. Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Meeting of the International ABSOCiatlon of Industrial Accident Boards and Commissions. BDI. 3511. Proceedings of the Tenth Annual Meeting of the International AIIOolatiOD of Industrlal Accident Boards and Commissions. Bui. 379. Comparison of workmen's compensation laws of the United States as of 1an~ 1, 11125. Jaclall<al Aeddent■ and 'R:,.a"Bul. l°'. Lead poisoning In potteries, tile works, and poreeialn enameled 811Ditaty wate faotorlla. BDI. 120. Hygiene of the painters' trade. "BDI. 127. DBDgerS to workers from dust and fumes, and-methods of proteottoa. "BDI..1,1. -Lead pollonlq·ln the smeltADg.and-ftftDinlf of-lead. *Bui. 167. Industrial accident statistics. *Bui. 166. Lead poisoning In the manufacture of storage batteriel. "Bui. 179. Industrial poisons used In the rubber lndasllr,-. Bui. 188. Report of British departmental committee OD the danger In the use of lead In the painting ofbuildings. , *Bui. 201. Report of committee OD statistics and compensation Insurance cost of -the International Association of Industrial Accident Boards and Commissions, [Llmited edition.I Bui. 205. Anthrax as an occupational disease. Bui. 2C11. 01111868 of death by occqpatlon. Bui. 209. Hygiene of the printing trades. "Bui. 216. Accidents and accident prevention In machine building. Bui. 219. Industrial poisons used or produced In the manufacture of explosives. Bui. 221. Hours, fatigue, and health In British munition factories. · Bui. 280. Industrial efficiency and fatigue In British mnnltion factories, *Bui. 281. Mortality from respiratory diseases In dusty trades. . *Bui.~- Safety movement In the Iron and steel Ind~, 1907 to 1917, Bui. 236. Effect of the air hammer OD the hands of stpnecutters. Bui. 2111; .Preventable death In the cotton manufacturing lndwttt7.· Bui. 253. Women In the lead Industries. . Bui. 266. Accidents and accident prevention In machine building. Revlalon of Bui. 118. Bui. 267. Anthrax· as an occupational disease. [Revised.} Bui. 278. Standardization of Industrial accident statistics. BDI, 280. Industrial poisoning in making coal-tar dyes and dye Intermediates. Bui. 291. Carbon monoxide poisoning. Bui. 298. The problem of dust phthlsls In the granite-stone lndnstry. Bui. 298. CBll86S and prevention of accidents In the Iron and steel lndnstry, 1910 to 1919. Bui. 306. Oocopatlon hazards and diagnostic signs: A guide to Impairment to be looked for In haz· ardous occupations. Bui. 889. Statistics of Industrial accidents In the United States. Coadllatlon and AdJltndon (bicladlna lltrlkeB and lockouCll)o "Bui. 124. Conciliation and arbitration In the bulldlpg trades of Greater New York. "Bui. 188. Report of the Industrial counoll of the British Board of Trade OD Its inquiry Into Industrial agreements. *Bui. 189. Michigan copper dlstrlot strike. Bui. l«. lndll!'trlal court of the cloak, salt, and skirt ndnstry of New York City. Bui. 1'5. Conolllatlon, arbitration, and 88Dltat!,on In the dress and waist lndUBtry of New York City. Bul.191. Collective bargaining in the anthracite coal lndnstry., "Bui. 1118. Collective agreements In the men's clothing lndnstry. Bui. 233. Operation of the Industrial Dlspntes Investigation Act of Canada. Bui. am. Use of Federal power In settlement of railway labor disputes. Bui. 8'1. Trade agreement In the silk-ribbon lndnstry of New York Olty, https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (IV) Labor Laws of the United States (Including decisions of courts relating to labor)• .•Bui. 111. Labor legislation of 1912. •Bui. 112. Decisions of courts and opinions affecting labor, 1912. •BuI. 148. Labor laws of the United States, with decisions of courts relating thereto. •Bui. 152. Decisions ol courts and opinions affecting labor, 1013. •Bui. 166. Labor legislation of 1914. •Bui. 169. Decisions of courts affecting labor, 1914. •Bui. 186. Labor legislation of 1915, •Bui. 189. Decisions of courts affecting labor, 1915. Bui. 211. Labor laws and their administration in the Paclftc States. •Bui. 213. Labor legislation of 1916. Bui. 224. Decisions of courts affecting labor, 1916. Bui 22~. Wage-payment legislation in the United States. Bui. 244. Labor legislation of 1917. Bui. 246. Decisions of courts affecting labor, 1917. Bui. 257. Labor legislation of 1918. Bui. 258. Decisions of courts and opinions affecting labor, 1918. 0 Bul. 277. Labor legislation of 1919. Bui. 285. Minimum-wage legislation in the United States. Bui. 290. Decisions of courts and opinions affecting labor, 1919-1920, Bui. 292. Labor legislation of 1920. Bui. 308. Labor legislation of 1921. Bui. 309. Decisions of courts and opinions affecting labor, 1921. Bui. 321. Labor laws that have been declared unconstitutional. Bui. 322. Kansas Court of Industrial Relations. Bui. 330. Labor legislation of 1922. Bui. 343. Laws providing !or bureaus of labor statistics, etc. Bui. 344. Decisions of courts and opinions affecting labor, 1922. Bui. 370. Labor laws of the United States, with decisions of courts relating thereto. [In press.] Foreign Labor Laws, Bui. 142. Administration of labor laws and factory inspection in cert,iin European countries. Vocational EduCDtion, Bui. 145. Conciliation, arbitration, and sanitation in the dress and waist industry of New York City. •Bui. 147. Wages and regularity of employment in the cloak, suit, and skirt industry, *Bui. 159. Short-unit courses for wage earners, and a factory school experiment. *Bul 162. Vocational education survey of Richmond, Va. Bui. 199. Vocational education survey of Minneapolis, Minn. Bui. 271. Adult working class education (Great Britain and the United States). Labor as Affected by the War, Bui. 170. Foreign food prices as affected by the war. Bul. 219. Industrial poisons used or produced in the manufacture of explosives. Bui. 221. Hours, fatigue, and health in British munition factories. Bui. 222. Welfare work in British munition factories. Bui. 223. Employment of women and juveniles in Great Britain during the war. Bui. 230. Industrial efficiency and fatigue in British munition factories. Bul. 237. Industrial unrest in Great Britain. Bui. 249. Industrial health and efficiency. Final report of British Health of Munlti~n Workers Committee. Bui. 255. Joint industrial councils in Great Britain. Bui. 283. History of the Shlpbuilding Labor Adjustment Board, 1917 to 19111. Bui. 287. National War Labor Board. 8afety Codes. · Bui. 331. Code of lighting factories, mills, and other work places. Bui. 336. Safety code !or the protection of industrial workers in foundries. Bui. 338. Safety code for the use, care, and protection of abrasive wheels. Bui. 350. Rules governing the approval of bead-lighting devices for motor vehlcles. Bui. 351. Safety code for the construction, care, and use ofladders. Bui. 364. Safety code for mechanical power-transmission apparatus. Bui. 375. Safety code for laundry machinery and operations. Bui. 378. Safety code for woodworking machinery. 20168°-25t--14 https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (V) Mlaeellaneou11 Sedea. Prohibition of night work of yOUDg persons. Ten-hour maximum working-day for women and YOUDg persons. Employers' welfare work. Government aid to home owning and holl8ing of working people In foreign countnea. Short-unit courses for wage earners and a factory school experiment. 0 :Qul. 167. Minimum-wage legislation in the United States and foreign countries. Bui. 170. Foreign food prices as affected by the war. •Bui. 174. Subject index of the publications of the United States Bureau of Labor Statlatics up to May 1, 1916. Bui. 208. Profit sharing In the United States. Bui. 222. Welfare work in British munition factories. Bui. 242. Food situation in central Europe, 1917. •Bui. 260. Welfare work for employees In indll8trlal establishments In the United States, Bui. 254. International labor legislation and the society of nations. · Bui. 263. HOW!lng by employers in the United States. Bui. 266. Proceedings of Seventh Annual Convention of Governmental Labor Olllolals of the United States and Canada, Bui. 268. Historical survey of International action affecting labor. Bui, 271. Adult working-class education In Great Britain and the United States. Bui. 282. Mutual relief associations among Government employees In Washington, D. C. Bui. 2911. Building operations In representative cities in 1920. Bui. 2911. Personnel research agencies. A guide to organized research In employment management, indll8trial relations, tralnlng, and working conditions. Bui. 313. Consumers' cooperative societies in the United States in 1920, Bui. 314. Cooperative oredit societies In America and foreign eountries. Bui. 318. Building permits In the principal cities of the United States. Bui. 320. The Bureau of Labor Statistics, Its history, activities, and organization. Bui. 323. Proceedings of the Ninth Annual Convention of the All8oclatloli. of Governmental Labor Officials of the United States and Canada, held at Hanlsburg, Pa., May 22-26, 1922. Bui. 326. Methods of procuring and computing statlstloal information of the Bureau of Labor Statistics. Bui. MO. Chinese migrations, with speola1 reference to labor conditions. Bui. 342. International Seamen's Union of America. A study ofits history and problems. Bui. 346. Humanity In government. Bui. 347. Building permits In the principal cities of the United States In 1922. Bui. 349. Indll8trial relations In the West Coast lumber lndmtry. · Bui. 362. Proceedings of the Tenth Annual Convention of Governmental Labor Officials or the United States and Canada. Bui. 861. Labor relations in the Fslrmont (W. Va.) bltumin01l8 coal fl.eld. Bui. 868. Building permits In the principal cities of the United States In 11123, Bui. 872. Convict labor In 1923. •Bui. 117. •Bui. 118. •Bui. 123. •Bui. 158. "Bui. 159. SPECIAL PUBLICATIONS ISSUED BY THE BUREAU OF LABOR STATISTICS o-dpdon of oeeapaClou, prepared for the United States Bmploy-i Senke, 1918-19. •Boots and shoes, harness and saddlery, and tanning. •cllllHUglll' refl.ning and llour milling. Coal and water gas, paint and varnish, paper, printing trades, and rubber good& •Electrical manufacturing, distribution, and maintenance. Glass. Hotels and restaurants. •Logging camps and sawmDJs. Medicinal manilfacturlng. Metal working, building and general oonstractlon, railroad transportation, and shipbuilding, •Mines and mining. •office employees. Slaughtering and meat paoklnc. Street railways. •Textiles and clothing. -Water transportation. https://fraser.stlouisfed.org Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis (VI) 0