View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

pd
papers

NUMBER 60

by Patrick C. Higgins and Owen F. Humpage

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R

Walking on a Fence: Brazil’s
Public-Sector Debt

F E B R UA R Y 2 0 0 4

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Walking on a Fence: Brazil’s
Public-Sector Debt
by Patrick C. Higgins and Owen F. Humpage

Patrick C. Higgins is a research
analyst, and Owen F. Humpage is
an economic advisor at the
Federal Reserve Bank of
Cleveland.

Brazil is walking on a fence between sustainable and unsustainable public-debt dynamics. How it
treads could affect not only its own economic prosperity but that of its neighbors, emerging markets
in general, and U.S. financial institutions in particular. Relatively small improvements in Brazilian
economic conditions and a continuation of that country’s recent fiscal improvements could push
Brazil in the right direction, particularly if the dollar continues to depreciate.

Materials may be reprinted if the
source is credited. Please send
copies of reprinted materials to
the editor.
We invite questions, comments,
and suggestions. E-mail us at
editor@clev.frb.org.

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

Policy Discussion Papers are published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland. To receive copies or to be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to 4d.subscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to 216-579-3050.
Policy Discussion Papers are available electronically through the Cleveland Fed’s site on the World
Wide Web: www.clevelandfed.org/Research.
Views stated in Policy Discussion Papers are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the
Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

ISSN 1528-4344

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Introduction
Since the adoption of its Fiscal Stabilization Program in 1998, Brazil has substantially improved in
fiscal position. Even as economic activity stagnated last year, that country managed to maintain the
momentum of its fiscal reforms. Its primary budget surplus—receipts minus non-interest expenditures—rose, and its debt-to-GDP ratio ticked down. Risk spreads on Brazilian debt narrowed.
Nevertheless, the Achilles’ heel of sustained economic prosperity in Brazil remains that country’s
public-debt burden. High and growing levels of debt increase the chances that Brazil might default
on its obligations, either through an outright repudiation of its contractual commitments to lenders
or through inflation and currency depreciation. These prospects cause investors to demand a risk premium, which raises real interest rates in Brazil and reduces investment, employment, and growth in
that country.
Since Brazil is Latin America’s biggest economy and the world’s twelfth largest, default there could
have serious consequences for the region, for emerging markets in general, and for U.S. financial institutions in particular. Debt problems in one emerging market often spill over into others, particularly
those shouldering large debt burdens, as lenders grow increasingly cautious and attempt to reduce their
exposures. With the emerging-market debt situation growing somewhat more precarious in recent
years, so have the prospects for debt contagion.
According to the IMF (2003, p. 115), the public debt burdens of a broad range of emerging-market
economies increased sharply in the last half of the 1990s after declining during the first part of that
decade. The gross public-debt burden among emerging markets now averages approximately 72 percent
of GDP and exceeds that of developed economies (65 percent). This pattern has raised concern about
the debt’s viability because emerging markets generally have not been able to sustain the same levels of
debt as developed countries. The IMF (2003, p. 118) reports that in 55 percent of all defaults, the gross
debt burden was less than 60 percent of GDP in the year before the default, and in 35 percent of the
cases, the debt burden was less than 40 percent. Brazil’s gross debt burden approached 80 percent of
GDP in September 2003.
Serious debt problems currently affect Argentina, Ecuador, and Uruguay. Bolivia, Paraguay, and
Venezuela face budget problems. A Brazilian default would almost certainly shake investors’ confidence and have serious spillover effects on these Latin American countries, if not the entire region.
The broader the contagion, the more problematic it becomes for the United States.
U.S. banking organizations hold approximately $97.5 billion in total claims on emerging-market
economies.1 Approximately 58 percent of this lending ($56.8 billion) is to Latin American countries.
Next to Mexico, Brazil is our largest Latin American borrowing country. Brazil accounts for nearly
one-third ($18.2 billion) of all U.S. bank claims against Latin America. A default in Brazil, especially one that rippled through other emerging markets, would affect U.S. banking organizations and

1. These data are from the Federal
Financial Institutions Examination
Council (2003) and pertain to the
survey responses of 72 U.S.
banking organizations.

complicate monetary policy.
Since the International Monetary Fund’s extension of a $30 billion loan facility in August 2002,
concerns about Brazil’s debt have waned somewhat, but the situation remains tenuous. The prospects
largely depend on the contours of Brazil’s near-term economic development. In this paper, we assess
the sensitivity of Brazil’s public-debt burden to alternative scenarios for that country’s economic
growth and real interest rates. Under certain combinations of these variables, Brazil’s public-sector
1

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

N U M B E R 6 , F E B R UA R Y 2 0 0 4

debt could become unsustainable; that is, the costs of servicing its public debt would outpace the country’s ability to generate revenues for that purpose. Investors would flee, and Brazil could only hope to
avoid default by undertaking severe austerity measures.
The results of our analysis are cautiously optimistic. Brazil’s past performance indicates that the
necessary economic conditions are attainable, but it also suggests that they may prove difficult to sustain
in a world buffeted by economic shocks. Brazil can, however, improve its chances for debt sustainability by continuing its recent fiscal reforms, especially by maintaining a primary budget surplus near the
current 5.10 percent of GDP. These findings update and echo similar conclusions found in Goldfajn
(2002), Goldfajn and Guardia (2003), and Williamson (2002).2

2. See also Favero and Giavazzi
(2002) and Goldstein (2003).

Brazil’s Public Debt
In September 2003, Brazil’s consolidated net public-sector debt equaled $304.3 billion (equivalent) or
57.7 percent of that country’s GDP (see table 1).3 This consolidated amount includes the net debt
of the general government—that is the federal, state, and local government sectors (including social
security)—plus the net debt of government-owned enterprises and Brazil’s central bank.
This figure, however, may be a somewhat imprecise measure of the overall debt burden. For one thing,
it subtracts from Brazil’s gross debts certain assets held by the government, government-owned enterprises, and the central bank. Such assets should be subtracted only if Brazil can readily use them to service its
debts. According to Banco Central do Brasil (2003, table 37), approximately $124.2 billion (equivalent)
of general government assets—an amount equal to 23.6 percent of Brazil’s GDP—was available to offset
debts in September 2003. The Bank considered slightly more than one-half of these assets to be liquid,
which makes them particularly well suited for redeeming debt on short notice (see Goldfajn, 2002, p.13).
The 23.6 percent figure, however, also includes investments in several constitutional funds, resources in
the Labor Assistance Fund, and credits to public enterprises that are considerably less liquid. They are
TA B L E 1

B R A Z I L’ S P U B L I C - S E C T O R D E B T

R$
(billions)

%
GDP

US$
(billions)

1230.4

79.7

420.2

363.6

23.6

124.2

Net public-sector debt

891.1

57.7

304.3

General government

866.9

56.2

296.1

2.0

0.1

0.7

22.2

1.4

7.6

891.1

57.7

304.3

Domestic

702.7

45.5

240.0

External

188.4

12.2

64.3

Domestic

793.3

62.0

270.9

External

227.2

17.8

77.6

Gross public-sector debt
Assets

Central bank
Government-owned enterprises
Net public-sector debt

Gross public-sector debt

NOTE: GDP = R$1543.6 billion, September 2003; Reais per $ = 2.928, September 30, 2003.
SOURCES: Banco Central do Brasil, September 2003; and Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

2

3. Throughout this paper, we convert
Brazil’s public debt to dollar equivalents at 2.928 reais per dollar,
the exchange rate at the end of
September 2003. Original data
are from the Banco Central do
Brasil (2003).

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

potentially available over a longer-term horizon. Other illiquid governmental assets, such as state-owned
enterprises and land, are not included in this 23.6 percent, but conceivably Brazil could also use these assets
to meet debt obligations (see Favero and Giavazzi, 2002, and Goldstein, 2003). In the calculations that
follow, we stick with the official estimates of net consolidated debt listed in table 1, as Goldfajn (2002) and
Goldfajn and Guardia (2003) do in their debt-sustainability analysis, but adjustments in our analysis could
be made to reflect alternative assumptions about the liquidity of some assets and the ability to use them
for debt service.
In addition to the difficulty of ascertaining which assets are potentially available to help service
Brazil’s gross debts, the official, publicly announced level of overall debt may understate that country’s
true total. As part of its fiscal reforms, Brazil began adding some heretofore hidden liabilities—
euphemistically called skeletons (as in “skeletons in the closet”)—to the consolidated public-debt totals
in 1996. Goldfajn and Guardia (2003, p. 14) calculate that roughly half of the increase in the debtto-GDP ratio from 1994 to 2002 (30 percent to 56.5 percent) was due to the recognition of these
skeletons. They also suggest that additional hidden liabilities could come to light in the future, and
they augment their debt calculations by 0.65 percent of GDP in 2003 and 0.75 percent of GDP per
year between 2004 and 2007. Again, we stick with the official data and do not make adjustments for
additional skeletons.
Brazil’s net public-debt burden has burgeoned since 1995, despite substantial fiscal reforms,
because of high real interest rates, currency depreciation, slow economic growth, and the inclusion of
the skeletons. Brazil’s net public debt is generally short-term in nature, and sensitive to interest rate
changes. Williamson (2002, p. 5) estimated that roughly 37 percent is linked to Brazil’s overnight
interest rate (SELIC), but this percentage is now probably higher because of changes in the portion of
the debt that is linked to the dollar (see below). In addition, a small portion is tied either to the inflation rate or to other indexes that help protect nominal returns from economic shocks.
Foreigners hold only 21 percent of Brazil’s net public debt, but approximately 26.5 percent of the
total debt is linked to the U.S. dollar and is therefore directly responsive to changes in the exchange value
of the Brazilian real relative to the U.S. dollar. Goldfajn and Guardia (2003, p.14), for example, estimate
that had the Brazilian real not depreciated between 1994 and 2002, the debt burden would have risen
only to 42.5 percent of GDP instead of 56.0 percent.4
The remainder of this paper explores the sensitivity of Brazil’s debt-to-GDP ratio—officially put
at 57.7 percent in September 2003—to changes in real interest rates, economic growth rates, fiscal policy, and exchange rates. The calculations are clearly back-of-envelope in nature. We do not posit a

4. Over the past year, Brazil reduced
the dollar-linked proportion of its
public debt from 40.7 percent to
26.5 percent. Goldfajn and
Guardia (2003) use the older
percentage.

particular type of underlying economic shock, nor do we allow for the intricate real-world interactions
that would take place among these variables. The results, nevertheless, set out a range of alternative
economic and budgetary assumptions that indicate when Brazil’s debt burden will fall or rise, and
therefore, suggest the chances for debt sustainability in Brazil.

3

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

N U M B E R 6 , F E B R UA R Y 2 0 0 4

Debt Dynamics
Brazil’s net public-sector debt is sustainable if that country can meet its obligations without a major
policy change (see International Monetary Fund, 2002a). This implies that the level of debt does not
exceed the country’s ability to routinely service it. Since a country’s capacity to generate revenue for
fulfilling its debt obligations ultimately depends on its economic growth rate, economists typically
assess sustainability in terms of a debt-to-GDP ratio.5 Brazil’s debt-to-GDP ratio—its debt burden—
cannot rise indefinitely and remain sustainable.
Whether Brazil’s debt burden rises or fall depends largely on how that country’s economic growth
rate compares with its real interest rate. The year-to-year change in Brazil’s net public debt is equal to
the interest cost of its outstanding debts from the previous year less any additional surplus revenues
available to reduce that debt; that is:
p
Dt – Dt–1 = rt • Dt–1 – St ,

1)

where Dt is the outstanding government debt in period t, r is the real interest rate on government debt,
p

and S is the primary budget surplus (see Carlson and Stevens 1985). The primary budget surplus
equals public-sector receipts less non-interest expenditures.
Expressing the arguments of equation 1 as ratios to GDP provides an equation for the debt
burden, dt :
dt = 1 + r.t dt–1 – stp.
1 + gt

(

2)

)

TA B L E 2

B R A Z I L’ S E C O N O M I C P E R F O R M A N C E

Real GDP
(% change)

Inflation
(%)

Treasury bill rates
Nominal
Real
(%)
(%)

Average 1984–1993

2.8

614.2

NA

NA

1994

5.8

2074.7

NA

NA

1995

4.2

66.0

49.9

–16.1

1996

2.7

15.8

25.7

10.0

1997

3.3

6.9

24.8

17.9

1998

0.1

3.2

28.6

25.4

1999

0.8

4.9

26.4

21.5

2000

4.4

7.1

18.5

11.4

2001

1.3

6.8

20.1

13.2

2002

1.9

8.4

19.4

11.0

2003

0.6

13.6

24.6

11

2004

3.5

6.2

NA

NA

NOTES: GDP for 2003 and 2004 and inflation in 2004 are IMF projections. Interest rate and inflation for 2003 are averages of the first eight
months. Real interest rates equal the nominal interest rate less the inflation rate.
SOURCES: IMF World Economic Outlook, September 2003, Tables 6 and 12; and IMF International Financial Statistics, IMF Press Release
#03/217.

4

5. To the extent that Brazil’s debt is
denominated in dollars, measuring the ability to service these
debts in terms of GDP may be
somewhat misleading. To service
dollar-denominated debt, Brazil
must earn dollars through its
exports. Using GDP, instead of
exports, implicity assumes that
Brazil can potentially direct all of
its GDP into exports. In a later
section we look at the effects of
currency revaluation on Brazil’s
budget situation.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

In equation 2, the lowercase letters designate ratios to GDP for the corresponding uppercase let.
ters from equation 1, and gt is the real growth rate of output in period t.6 As equation 2 indicates,
for any given primary surplus and initial debt burden, the debt will continue to rise relative to GDP
if the average real interest rate on that debt exceeds the growth rate of the economy.
Consistent with equation 2, the real rate on Brazil’s Treasury bills, which we use as a proxy for
the average interest rate on Brazilian public debt, has almost always exceeded that country’s real growth

6. Although the mathematics suggests that equation 2 should
include nominal interest rates and
nominal growth rates, economists
typically employ real variables.
Implicitly, they are holding
inflation constant.

rate since 1995, and Brazil’s debt ratio has risen (see table 2). An increase in Brazil’s primary budget
balance from an average deficit of 0.4 percent of GDP between 1996 and 1998 to a primary surplus
of 5.1 percent of GDP in September 2003 helped limited the rise in Brazil’s debt ratio.
Table 3 shows the change in Brazil’s debt-to-GDP ratio over the next 10 years under a range of
assumptions about real GDP growth and the average real interest rate on this debt. The calculations
start with the September 2003 debt-to-GDP ratio—57.7 percent—and assume that Brazil’s primary
budget surplus as a percent of GDP remains at its current target of 4.25 percent on average over the
next 10 years.
If recent patterns serve as a reliable guide to the future, Brazil is not likely to sustain a rate of economic
growth over the next decade at the high end of our assumptions in table 3. Between 1984 and 2002,
Brazil’s economy expanded at a relatively low 2.8 percent average annual rate. Since 1994, year-to-year
growth has ranged from 0.1 percent in 1998 to 5.8 percent in 1994.7 The International Monetary Fund
(2003a) believes that Brazil only grew 0.6 percent in 2003 but anticipates a 3.5 percent growth rate in
2004. This is substantially below Brazil’s potential growth, which Banco Central do Brasil estimates at
4.5 percent, an estimate that equals the high end of our assumptions.
The range of Brazil’s real interest rates since 1995 is so large as to make the average (11.7 percent)

7. In 1994, Brazil instituted a new
currency, the real, and a crawling
peg exchange rate mechanism.
These changes “proved a turning
point for macroeconomic
policies” (International Monetary
Fund, 2002, Box 1.4).

a rather unsure forecast of the future. Nevertheless, it falls in the upper half of our assumptions. Based
on the data in table 2, a range of 10 percent to 13 percent seems conceivable, and 8 percent to
10 percent seems optimistic.
The combinations of economic growth and real interest rates that could achieve a decline in
Brazil’s consolidated net public-debt ratio over the next decade seem to be within that country’s reach,
but lie on the more optimistic end of the assumptions. A 3.5 percent average rate of GDP growth and
a 9 percent real interest rate, which underlie Goldfajn’s and Guardia’s (2003) projections, would lower
the net public-debt ratio from 57.7 percent to 42.6 percent by 2013 according to our estimates. This
TA B L E 3

Interest rate

T H E C H A N G E I N B R A Z I L’ S D E B T-T O - G D P R AT I O U N D E R A LT E R N AT I V E
ECONOMIC ASSUMPTIONS (percentage point change over 10 years)

2.0%

3.0%

GDP Growth
3.5%

4.0%

4.5%

8.0%

–11.2

–18.1

–21.2

–24.2

–27.0

9.0%

–4.0

–11.6

–15.1

–18.4

–21.5

10.0%

4.0

–4.5

–8.4

–12.0

–15.4

11.0%

12.7

3.3

–1.0

–5.0

–8.8

12.0%

22.2

11.9

7.2

2.7

–1.5

13.0%

32.6

21.2

16.0

11.1

6.5

NOTE: The initial debt-to-GDP ratio is 57.7 percent, and the initial primary budget surplus is 4.25 percent of GDP.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

5

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

N U M B E R 6 , F E B R UA R Y 2 0 0 4

scenario clearly implies a sustainable debt burden. Brazil has achieved this rate of economic growth
and has come close to this real interest rate on occasion since 1994, but has not managed to maintain
either rate for very long. A 3.0 percent real economic growth rate and a 12 percent real rate of interest, which corresponds more closely to Brazil’s recent average performance, would push the debt ratio
to 69.6 percent by 2013. All else equal, the debt would ultimately be unsustainable in this case.

Primary Budget Surplus
Brazil’s budget situation has improved substantially since the announcement of the Fiscal Stabilization
Program in 1998 and the Fiscal Responsibility Law of 2000 (see Goldfajn and Guardia, 2003). These
laws introduced far-reaching institutional reforms, which seem to focus on eliminating the moral hazard
problems created when the central government assumes the debts of the state and local governments. In
addition, Brazil now adopts targets—currently 4.25 percent—for its primary surplus.
The projections of Brazil’s debt burden in table 3 assume that the primary budget surplus remains
constant at its current target, 4.25 percent of GDP. But if Brazil can continue to exceed this target, as
it did in 2003 (through September), it could improve its chances for stabilizing its debt ratio. We can
calculate from equation 2 the primary surplus that would keep the debt burden constant under alternative assumptions for the real interest rate and the real growth rate. To do so, we assume a constant
debt ratio (that is, dt = dt-1 = d*) and solve for the primary surplus:
.
3) stp = rt – g.t
1+g

(

)

•

d* .

Table 4 shows the percentage point amount that the primary budget surplus would need to
increase relative to GDP in order to prevent a rise in Brazil’s net public-debt ratio under alternative
economic scenarios. The calculations also assume that Brazil implements the increase immediately and
sustains it over the next 10 years.
As we saw, the previous estimates (table 3) suggested that the debt ratio would increase by
11.9 percentage points (from 57.7 percent to 69.6 percent) over the next 10 years if the average rate
of economic growth is 3.0 percent and the average real interest rate is 12 percent. This 10-year increase
in the debt burden, however, could be offset by an immediate, and sustained, 0.8 percentage point
increase in the primary budget surplus from 4.25 percent to 5.04 percent. In fact, Brazil exceeded this
TA B L E 4

C H A N G E I N B R A Z I L’ S P R I M A R Y D E F I C I T N E E D E D T O S TA B I L I Z E T H E D E B T-T O G D P R AT I O ( p e r c e n t a g e p o i n t c h a n g e o v e r 1 0 y e a r s )

Interest rate

2.0%

3.0%

8.0%

–0.9

–1.4

9.0%

–0.3

10.0%

GDP growth
3.5%

4.0%

4.5%

–1.7

–2.0

–2.3

–0.9

–1.2

–1.5

–1.8

0.3

–0.3

–0.6

–0.9

–1.2

11.0%

0.8

0.2

–0.1

–0.4

–0.7

12.0%

1.4

0.8

0.5

0.2

–0.1

13.0%

2.0

1.4

1.0

0.7

0.4

NOTE: The initial debt-to-GDP ratio is 57.7 percent, and the initial primary budget surplus is 4.25 percent of GDP.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations.

6

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

target in September 2003, when its primary budget surplus reached 5.11 percent. If Brazil were to maintain a primary budget surplus of roughly 5 percent over the next 10 years, the country could lower its debt
burden, even if its economic growth and real interest rates were no better than their past averages.

Exchange Rates
As Goldfajn (2002) and Goldfajn and Guardia (2003) show, movements in the real–dollar exchange
rate have had a major impact on Brazil’s debt burden. During 2002, the U.S. dollar appreciated more
than 50 percent against the Brazilian real. Since then, the dollar has depreciated almost 20 percent.
Over the past year, Brazil lessened the exchange rate impact on its debt burden by reducing the proportion of its net public debt that is linked to the dollar, from 40.7 percent to 26.5 percent.
Table 5 presents rough guesses for the direct effect of a dollar appreciation or depreciation on the
debt burden, given that 26.5 percent of Brazil’s debt remains linked to the dollar. An immediate
20 percent dollar appreciation, for example, would increase the debt ratio almost to 61 percent. Of
course, like all of the calculations presented here, this estimate does not allow for the complicated
interactions that could take place between the exchange rate, real interest rates, and real economic
growth. We assume no other changes.
Goldfajn (2002) and Williamson (2002) correctly anticipated an appreciation in the real, contending that the recent depreciation has left the real—or inflation adjusted—real–dollar exchange rate
too low relative to its average level. An immediate 20 percent depreciation of the dollar would lower
TA B L E 5

T H E C H A N G E I N B R A Z I L’ S D E B T B U R D E N U N D E R A LT E R N AT I V E
E XC H A N G E R AT E A S S U M P T I O N S

Dollar appreciation
20%
30%

Sept. 30, 2003

10%

Exchange rate

2.928

3.221

3.515

3.806

Net public-sector debt

891.1

914.8

938.4

962.0

Dollar-indexed

236.1

259.8

283.4

307.0

Other

655.0

655.0

655.0

655.0

Net public-sector debt

891.1

914.8

938.4

962.0

57.7

59.3

60.8

62.3

Percent of GDP

Dollar depreciation
20%
30%

Sept. 30, 2003

10%

Exchange rate

2.928

2.635

2.342

2.050

Net public-sector debt

891.1

867.5

843.9

820.3

Dollar-indexed

236.1

212.5

188.9

165.3

Other

655.0

655.0

655.0

655.0

Net public-sector debt

891.1

867.5

843.9

820.3

57.7

56.2

54.7

53.1

Percent of GDP

NOTE: Exchange rates are in reais per dollar.
SOURCE: Authors’ calculations, assuming that 26.5 percent of Brazilian debt is indexed to the dollar.

7

P O L I C Y D I S C U S S I O N PA P E R S

N U M B E R 6 , F E B R UA R Y 2 0 0 4

Brazil’s debt burden to 54.7 percent. A continuing dollar depreciation against the Brazilian real should
help Brazil stabilize and reduce its debt burden.

Cautious Optimism
Our simple calculations—like those found in Goldfajn (2002), Goldfajn and Guardia (2003), and
Williamson (2002)—suggest that Brazil is walking on a fence between sustainable and unsustainable
public-debt dynamics. Relatively small improvements in economic conditions and a continuation of
that country’s recent fiscal improvements could push Brazil in the right direction, particularly if the
U.S. dollar’s recent depreciation continues.
Merely banking on past economic patterns may not be sufficient to produce a sustained decline in
Brazil’s debt-to-GDP ratio. Although Brazil can attain the economic conditions necessary to sustain
its debt burden without further fiscal consolidation, maintaining them against future economic shocks
seems highly problematic. The key uncertainty is real interest rates. A continuation of recent patterns,
that is, real rates in the 11 percent to 13 percent range, will not lower the debt ratio unless economic
growth is fairly robust. Real interest rates reflect investor confidence, so any step that Brazil can take
to assuage investors’ fears could be particularly helpful in securing debt sustainability. While the recent
IMF loan packages fall into this category, a more fundamental and persistent change in Brazil’s
primary budget deficit could do even more. Brazil’s ability to achieve a 5.11 percent primary budget
surplus this year is especially heartening in that respect. It exceeds the level necessary to prevent a rise
in that country’s debt burden given Brazil’s historical averages for growth and real interest rates. The
U.S. dollar’s recent 20 percent depreciation against the real has also helped stabilize Brazil’s debt ratio;
a further dollar depreciation, which many analysts anticipate, should provide Brazil an added respite
in which to expand its fiscal and economic reforms.

8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

References
Banco Central do Brazil. 2002. “Frequently Asked Questions Regarding Public Debt in Brazil,” Focus
(August 21). <http://www4.bcb.gov.br/gci-i/Focus/F20020821-Frequently%Asked%Questions%
Regarding%Public%Debt%in%Brazil.pdf> (September 12, 2002).
Banco Central do Brasil. 2003. Fiscal Policy Press Release (October 31). <http://www.bcb.gov.br/ftp/
notaecon/n1200310pfi.zip> (January 30, 2004).
Carlson, John B., and E.J. Stevens. 1985. “The National Debt: A Secular Perspective,” Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Economic Review, vol. 21, no. 3, pp. 11–24.
Favero, Carlo A., and Francesco Giavazzi. 2002. “Why Are Brazil’s Interest Rates So High?” Innocenzo
Gasparini Institute for Economic Research Working Paper, no. 224 (July). <http://ideas.repec.org/p/igi/
igierp/224> (January 29, 2004).
Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council. 2003. “Country Exposure Lending Survey”
(September 30). <http://www.ffiec.gov/PDF/E16/E16_200306.pdf> (January 27, 2004).
International Monetary Fund. 2003a. World Economic Outlook (September). <http://www.imf.org/
external/pubs/ft/weo/2003/02/index.htm> (January 27, 2004).
International Monetary Fund, 2003b. Press Release No. 93.217 (December 13). http://www.imf.org/
external/np/sec/pr/2003/pr03217.htm> (January 27, 2004).
International Monetary Fund. 2002a. “Assessing Sustainability,” unpublished manuscript (May 28).
<http://www.imf.org/external/np/pdr/sus.2002.eng/052802.htm> (January 27, 2004).
International Monetary Fund. 2002b. World Economic Outlook (September).
Goldfajn, Ilan. 2002. “Are There Reasons to Doubt Fiscal Sustainability in Brazil?” Central Bank of Brazil
Technical Notes, no. 25 (July). <http://www.bcb.gov.br/htms/public/notastecnicas/2002nt25
fiscalsustainabilityi.pdf> (January 27, 2004).
Goldfajn, Ilan, and Eduardo Refinetti Guardia. 2003. “Fiscal Rules and Debt Sustainability in Brazil,”
Technical Notes, no. 39 (July). <http://www.bcb.gov.br/pec/notastecnicas/ingl/2003nt39regrafi
scsustentdivbrasili.pdf> (January 30, 2004).
Goldstein, Morris. 2003. “Debt Sustainability, Brazil, and the IMF.” Institute for International Economics,
Working Paper, no. 03-1 (February). <http://www.iie.com/publications/wp/2003/03-1.pdf>
(January 27, 2004).
Williamson, John. 2002. “Is Brazil Next?” Institute for International Economics, International Economics
Policy Briefs, no. PB 02-7 (August). <http://www.iie.com/publications/pb/pb02-7.pdf> (January 27,
2004).

9

pd
papers
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND
R E S E A R C H D E PA R T M E N T
P. O. B OX 6 3 8 7

Presorted Standard
U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit No. 385

C L E V E L A N D , O H I O 4 4 10 1

Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing
label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research
Department, P.O. Box 6387,
Cleveland, Ohio 44101.