View original document

The full text on this page is automatically extracted from the file linked above and may contain errors and inconsistencies.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

pd
papers

NUMBER 21

By O. Emre Ergungor

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPER

On the Resolution of Financial Crises:
The Swedish Experience

JUNE 2007

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

On the Resolution of Financial Crises:
The Swedish Experience

O. Emre Ergungor is an
economist at the Federal
Reserve Bank of Cleveland.

By O. Emre Ergungor
Sweden was one of the Scandinavian countries experiencing a severe financial
crisis In the late 1980s and early 1990s. I review the policy choices and
external factors that pushed the country’s financial system over the edge and
then examine the steps the government took to make its resolution of the crisis
one of the most successful in the past 30 years.
Materials may be
reprinted, provided that
the source is credited.
Please send copies of
reprinted materials to the
editor.

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

Policy Discussion Papers are published by the Research Department of the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland.To receive copies or to be placed on the mailing list, e-mail your request
to 4dsubscriptions@clev.frb.org or fax it to 216-579-3050. Please send your questions
comments, and suggestions to us at editor@clev.frb.org.
Policy Discussion Papers are available on the Cleveland Fed’s site on the World Wide Web:
www.clevelandfed.org/Research.
Views stated in Policy Discussion Papers are those of the authors and not necessarily
those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland or of the Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System.

ISSN 1528-4344

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

Introduction
In the late 1980s and early 1990s, the Scandinavian countries underwent their most
severe financial crisis of the postwar period. While such crises are not rare, what sets
these countries apart is their freedom from the institutional weaknesses that dogged lessdeveloped countries in the 1970s and emerging-market economies in the 1990s (slow
bankruptcy procedures, lax law enforcement, regulators who lacked the power to close
banks, and so forth).This makes the Scandinavian nations an interesting laboratory for examining how crises develop and are ultimately resolved.
In this Policy Discussion Paper, I focus on the experience of Sweden, first reviewing
the policy choices and external factors that pushed this country’s financial system over
the edge, and then discussing what steps the government took to make its crisis resolution process one of the most successful of the past 30 years. The paper emphasizes the
resolution process rather than the way in which the financial crisis unfolded, because
any number of events can lead to crises, but the general principles for resolving crises
successfully are universal.

The Road to Crisis
In the mid-1970s, Sweden was a small, open economy, whose growth depended heavily
on exports. Its economic policies were influenced by the core tenet of its political system:
The government’s primary focus should be keeping unemployment low and promoting
economic equality.At the same time, its policies had to be aligned with the central bank’s
commitment to keeping the exchange rate fixed relative to a basket of Sweden’s trading partners’ currencies (details later), all within the context of a closed-capital-account
environment.
How did these constraints affect the economy? The success of the export-based growth
model is conditional on keeping the tradable goods industries competitive in global markets; this means that production costs cannot grow faster than competitors’ as long as
the exchange rate is fixed.Yet in the 1970s, wage inflation grew out of control.The seeds
of inflation had been sown in the 1960s and early 1970s, when policymakers thought
they faced only a temporary slowdown in productivity growth and in the development
of Sweden’s primary export industries (such as forestry products and ship building), but
in reality, the slowdown had resulted from tougher foreign competition. Although the
natural rate of employment was rising, the government would not back off from the
unsustainable policy of full employment to which it had committed itself. Instead, it
decided to overcome economic weakness by increasing its expenditures on welfare programs (Bosworth and Lawrence, 1987), a further sign that the government thought the
decline in productivity growth was temporary. Workers in export industries who lost
their jobs were retrained and found employment in the white-collar service sector or
1

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 21, JUNE 2007

the public sector.The ensuing growth of public-sector employment was remarkable:The
sector’s share of total employment grew from 20 percent in 1965 to 30 percent in 1975
and 38 percent in 1985.1
In hindsight, this policy seems to have been a costly alternative to higher unemployment. As budget deficits grew, the holes were plugged by foreign borrowing and higher
income taxes (the marginal income tax rate on full-time workers earning the average
hourly wage increased from 35 percent in the second half of the 1960s to 65 percent in

1. This growth is due, in part, to the
entry of women into the labor
force and their taking of jobs in
the public sector. So, in addition
to the switch from the private
to public sector jobs, the public
sector also grew internally.

1976). The disincentive to invest created by higher income taxes probably cost Sweden
dearly in future private-sector job creation. And the exchange rate risk the government
assumed by borrowing in international markets came back to haunt it in later years, when
rising labor costs and deficits necessitated large devaluations.2
The growth in public-sector and white-collar employment also had an unintended
consequence: It strengthened the unions that represented these workers, which, given
the circumstances, played a significant role in breaking the link between wage growth
and productivity growth.The Social Democrats who ran Sweden from 1932 to 1976 had
a very close relationship with the country’s most powerful union of blue-collar workers,
the Landsorganisationen (Weaver, 1987). Both sides understood that their interest lay
in keeping export industries competitive by holding wage growth in check. The three
white-collar unions, which also participated in the negotiation process, were too small
to dictate wage policy. As public and white-collar employment grew and these workers
gained bargaining power, the unions began to compete with each other for new members. But public-sector and white-collar workers had no incentive to reduce their wage
demands so that export industries could remain competitive, so unions forsook the centrally determined wages and made side deals with employers for higher wages (Flanagan,
1987). Soon thereafter, the link between wage growth and productivity growth broke
down. In addition, Sweden’s generous unemployment benefits may have put the unions
in a heads-we-win-tails-the-government-loses situation. The unions won if they could negotiate higher wages for their members, and if companies failed, their members were still
covered by government insurance (Calmfors, 1987).

The Stage Is Set
High inflation made the fixed-exchange-rate policy untenable, so the krona was devalued
several times. Foreseeing the unsustainability of the fixed exchange rate, the unions demanded higher wages in anticipation of the krona’s decreased purchasing power. When
consumer price inflation hit 15 percent in 1980, the government decided to break the inflationary spiral (i.e., inflation expectations) and promote economic growth through a series of financial reforms, made at intervals throughout the 1980s.The reforms have three
major components that are relevant to our discussion.

2

2. This is similar to the Southeast
Asia crises, in which growing
fiscal deficits rendered the
fixed-exchange rate regime
increasingly unworkable—and
made devaluation imminent.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

First, Sweden lifted restrictions on borrowing in the 1982–85 period. Until then, the
government had tried to control the quantity and price of credit, favoring major exporting companies over smaller enterprises (such as those in property development and real
estate management) and households. As might be expected, a gray market developed to
circumvent these measures (Tranøy, 1999).3 Over time, the Riksbank (and the administration) concluded that these interest rate and credit ceilings were unsustainable and
restricted growth; consequently, the credit market was fully liberalized in 1985. Not sur-

3. In a “gray” credit market,
noninstitutional lenders and
borrowers interact directly, using
banks as brokers.

prisingly, the formerly credit-constrained Swedish companies and households ran to their
lenders, and a credit boom followed. After the capital account was opened in late 1980s,
these companies gained further freedom to borrow in international markets.
Second, a series of devaluations in 1981 and 1982 had temporarily revitalized Sweden’s
export industries. However, inflation remained out of control despite many ill-advised
attempts to restrain wage inflation through labor negotiations and price and rent freezes.
When those attempts failed, the government gradually lifted restrictions on foreign capital flows between 1986 and 1989 as a commitment to a nonaccomodation policy, thereby
abdicating its discretion over domestic monetary policy to more-credible foreign central
banks.The krona was still anchored to a basket of currencies, primarily the German mark,
based mostly on their trade weights. However, the weight of the U.S. dollar in the basket
was double what it would have been if it had been based solely on the size of its trade with
Sweden. With the decline in the dollar relative to the mark during the 1980s, this weight
gave an advantage on Swedish exports to Germany (Bosworth and Lawrence, 1987b).
Third, the government made a commitment to stop borrowing in international markets and borrow only domestically in kronas. Foreign borrowing had been seen as a way
for the government to keep real krona borrowing rates low by staying out of the domestic money market and thus avoiding the crowding out of private firms (Bosworth and
Lawrence, 1987b). An unintended consequence of this policy, however, was that banks
borrowed in foreign markets and lent to the government in kronas. In essence, this policy
transferred foreign exchange risk from the government to the banks.
Unfortunately, these financial reforms were not enough to overcome rigidities in the
Swedish political system and labor markets (Weaver, 1987). With full-employment targets and the associated incentives to workers and unions still in place, the economy’s
devaluation-induced competitiveness proved to be temporary. Although inflation cooled
initially, it never came down to the levels of Sweden’s trading partners. Consequently, maintaining the currency peg required high domestic real interest rates. The peg must have
seemed credible to the many Swedish companies that borrowed heavily in foreign currencies to escape high domestic real interest rates. In addition to banks’ borrowing abroad
and lending in the domestic market, the real economy also took on large exposure to
exchange rate risk.Before the crisis,more than 50 percent of all corporate debt was foreigncurrency denominated (Drees and Pazarbasioglu, 1998).
3

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 21, JUNE 2007

Borrowing cheap abroad and lending at higher rates domestically helped banks
finance a consumer lending surge.Also, foreign bank entry was allowed in 1986, one year
after interest rate liberalization, so locals may have wanted to move first in a growing
credit market. It is possible that in a new financial environment, bankers did not fully understand the risks they were taking. A statement from the then-Riksbank-Vice-President
Lars Heikensten (head of the Riksbank from 2003 to 2006) supports this view:
When deregulation was a fact, bank managers saw a chance of gaining
market share and increasing revenues by taking new risks, but did not
clearly see the dangers in a lack of the necessary expertise.
As often happens in such cases, the real estate market experienced a speculative boom
parallel to the rapid growth in credit (Ergungor and Thomson, 2006). As figure 1 shows,
home prices more than doubled between 1981 and 1991.4 Heikensten referred to this
sharp increase in home prices as a “speculative bubble.”
The impact of credit growth on household finances is apparent in figure 2. Despite the
rising cost of credit, Swedish households’ outstanding debt increased rapidly after 1986.

The Dominos Fall
The shock that pushed Sweden’s teetering economy over the brink of crisis came from
German unification in 1990, when the mark weakened against the U.S. dollar and Germany’s real interest rates jumped as a result of high unification costs.The fixed exchange
rate obliged Sweden to import the higher German real interest rates, pushing its own alFIGURE 1

HOUSING PRICE-RENT RATIO IN SWEDEN

Index (1981=100) by assessed value and period

Ratio

240

1.6
1.5

220

Home prices
1.4

200

1.3
180
Price/rent (right axis)

1.2

160
1.1

Rents

140

1.0

120

0.9

100

0.8
1981

1983

1985

1987

1989

Note: The shaded bar marks the recession.
Sources: Statistics Sweden; and the Riksbank.

4

1991

1993

1995

4. The price-rent ratio is conceptually similar to the price-earnings
ratio for stocks. However, in
figure 1, the rent index that I use
does not reflect the estimated
rental income stream of the
homes included in the price
data. It is also worth noting that
rents are tightly controlled in
Sweden, which further reduces
their usefulness as a measure
of market fundamentals.
Therefore, the ratio is only for
illustrative purposes.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

ready-high domestic rates even higher. The currency basket’s tilt in favor of the U.S. dollar, which formerly had given Swedish exporters a competitive edge, came back to haunt
them when the krona became overvalued. An attempt to fix the country’s fiscal imbalances dealt a final blow to its weakened economy:A change in tax policy in the late 1980s
abolished the tax-deductible status of interest paid on consumer debt, effectively increasing households’ interest burden.
It is hard to maintain speculative asset price growth when the credit feeding it becomes costlier. From 1990 to 1995, residential real estate prices dropped 25 percent
and commercial real estate prices dropped 42 percent (inflation-adjusted rates). Banks’
nonperforming loans mushroomed from 0.2 percent–0.5 percent of total loans in the
1980s to 5 percent in 1992. Then came George Soros’s infamous 1992 attack on the
European exchange-rate mechanism (ERM). After the krona was floated, domestic banks’
losses increased

significantly.5

Nonperforming loans hit 11 percent of GDP in 1993. The

institutions that suffered most (especially among the large banks) were those funded by
foreign funds.
The first victims of the economic downturn were two of Sweden’s six largest banks,
Första Sparbanken and Nordbanken.6 After they announced in the fall of 1991 that they
could no longer meet the regulatory capital requirements (8 percent of assets), the state
eventually guaranteed all their existing liabilities, took full ownership of Nordbanken, and

5. Once the fixed exchange rate
was abandoned, the krona
immediately dropped by
11.5 percent against the
reference basket of currencies.
A year later, the decline
exceeded 30 percent.
6. I borrow this description
of events from Calomiris,
Klingebiel, and Laeven (2004)
and Bergstrom, Englund, and
Thorell (2003).

helped Första Sparbanken with a loan guaranty to the owners.Within a year, a third major
institution, Gota Bank, became undercapitalized. When its largest owner refused to provide additional funds, the state guaranteed all its liabilities to prevent a meltdown; Gota
declared bankruptcy the same month. Once again, the state took ownership of the bank.
FIGURE 2

DEBT LOAD OF SWEDISH HOUSEHOLDS

Percent
1.4

Percent
14
Debt/income

12

1.3

10

Interest expenditure
to disposable income
(right axis)

1.2
1.1

8
6
4

1

2

Real after-tax lending rate
(right axis)

0.9

0
–2

0.8

–4
0.7

–6

0.6

–8
1980

1984

1988

1992

1996

Note: The shaded bar marks the recession.
Sources: Statistics Sweden; and the Riksbank.

5

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 21, JUNE 2007

After acquiring Nordbanken, the state owned 22 percent of all banking-system assets.
As a resolution strategy, it elected to divide each bank into two separate entities, one with
its good assets, the other with its bad ones.The entities holding the good assets continued
to operate under their old names and were later merged under the name Nordbanken.
The bad assets were transferred to two asset management companies (AMCs): Securum
for Nordbanken’s assets and Retrieva for Gota’s.7

The Recovery
In creating the AMCs, the legislature gave them a high degree of independence from
political and regulatory constraints. The state never explicitly assumed the role of an
active owner; however, the chairman of Securum’s board resigned when he could not

7. Part of the reason for rehabilitating an existing insolvent bank
by stripping away its bad assets
stems is a desire to protect (or
at least salvage) the value of the
bank’s relationships, particularly
its lending relationships (see
Diamond, 2001).

agree with the Ministry of Finance about compensating the AMC’s leading staff, so the
state seems to have had some say, at least on compensation-related issues. Still, the AMCs,
which were adequately overcapitalized in relation to the expected costs and losses during their expected life-time, held their own purse strings. Securum alone was capitalized
with SEK24 billion, an amount equal to Sweden’s defense budget. This deliberate overcapitalization enabled the AMCs to carry out their salvage operations autonomously; they
did not have to request funding from the legislature, which might have tried to influence
their decisions.
The AMCs were also free of many regulations and activity restrictions that applied to
banks, even though managing the loan portfolio, collecting payments, and possessing collateral in case of bankruptcy might be considered banking activities. The AMCs needed
broad leeway because they had to be more than banks.They injected equity into troubled
borrowers to maintain and restore their values as well as revive the real economy. In
many instances, this meant that they had to take over defaulting companies.They became
responsible for running those companies, much as a private owner would (including
hiring and firing management, rehabilitating neglected property, acquiring supplementary property, changing the focus of companies’ operations, and so on) until liquidation.
A second area in which they were exempt from bank regulation was the timing of collateral liquidations. Swedish banks were required to dispose of any collateral within three
years.8 Because the AMCs’ portfolio was so large, policymakers worried that selling all the
problem assets within a short period would put too much pressure on market prices.To
ease those concerns, the AMCs emphasized from the very beginning that cleaning up the
bad assets would take a long time, more than a decade if necessary (Bergstrom, Englund,
and Thorell, 2003).
In the end, the resolution occurred much more quickly than initially anticipated, thanks
to the rapid growth of the Swedish economy, which paralleled the global economic boom
of the 1990s. Liquidations were completed by 1997 at a smaller cost to the taxpayers than
was anticipated. Securum returned to the state nearly SEK14 billion ($1.8 billion in 1997
6

8. During the crisis, the Swedish
banks were also exempted from
the three-year rule.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

dollars) of its SEK24 billion ($4.5 billion in 1997 dollars) initial capital—admittedly, in
depreciated kronas.9 That being said, the cost of the crisis to Sweden was not limited to
the capital spent by the AMCs.There have been significant income and output losses as-

9. Constant dollars are calculated
using the GDP deflator.

sociated with the crisis. In the early 1970s, Sweden had one of the highest income levels
in Europe; today, its lead has all but disappeared. Cerra and Saxena (2005) found that the
crisis caused a permanent decline in output that can explain the entire fall in Sweden’s
relative income. So, even well-managed financial crises don’t really have happy endings.

Lessons of 20/20 Hindsight
How much of Sweden’s success in crisis resolution can be credited to its wise policies
and how much to a strong global economic expansion in the years after the crisis? Did
sensible policies pay off, or did the rising tide lift all boats? I suspect it was a bit of both.
As evidence for the rising-tide hypothesis, foreign demand for Swedish goods and services (measured by exports) rose from 0.89 percent of GDP in 1990 to 1.2 percent of
GDP in 1995. Unfortunately, there is no evidence that quantifies each factor’s contribution. Still, we can evaluate the resolution strategy in light of previous crises and those
that followed.
Ergungor and Thomson (2006) point out a number of traits that successful resolution
strategies have in common. I focus here on four: First, the process must be transparent;
expected losses must be recognized early on to preserve the market’s confidence in the
process. Second, crisis resolution is best handled by a politically and financially independent agency. An independent structure is desirable because it shields decision makers from political pressures, which mount as banks are closed and borrowers are pushed
into liquidation.The decision to close a bank or a business must be an economic—not a
political—one. Financial independence is necessary to give credibility to political independence: If a government agency holds the purse strings, it can dictate policy. Financial
independence is also important because it allows rapid response when funding needs
emerge suddenly (as when new losses are discovered in a financial institution) and waiting for the legislature to appropriate funds is impractical.10
A case in point is the Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC), which was founded in 1989
to handle the U.S. savings and loan crisis. With no internal source of funding, it relied on
Congressional appropriations, which made long-term planning difficult. Between March
31, 1992, and December 17, 1993, the RTC had to reduce its crisis-resolution activity for
lack of funds (Spade and Thomas, 1998; also see Kane, 1990).
The third trait of a successful resolution strategy is the maintenance of market discipline.Without it, the stage is set for future crises. For example, extending blanket guaran-

10. As a comparison, in its
financial crisis, Finland
decided on a fixed and
limited amount of funds
for bank resolution, and
when this amount proved
inadequate later, a new
Parliamentary decision had
to be requested and taken
at a significant cost to the
credibility of the resolution
process.

tees during a crisis weakens the market discipline exerted by uninsured creditors in the
postcrisis period. Uninsured depositors and nondeposit creditors have strong incentives

7

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 21, JUNE 2007

to monitor and discipline financial institutions by raising their cost of funding when their
risk increases. At some point, as the probability of default increases, uninsured claimants
will threaten to liquidate their claims. If market discipline is to be effective, these investors must be credibly exposed to loss; that is, they must suffer the consequences of ignoring or failing to detect signs of trouble. An explicit blanket guarantee of all the liabilities
of problem institutions in the throes of a crisis reduces the credibility of claims that de
facto guarantees will not be extended in future bank failures.
Similar incentive problems arise when regulators and policymakers respond to the
crisis by bailing out banks’ creditors through a policy of capital forbearance and unlimited liquidity support. Although bailouts tend to alleviate pressures on the financial system, forbearance and unlimited liquidity support allow uninsured investors to take their
money out of the bank, shielding them from loss and reducing their incentive to monitor
in the future. In essence, capital forbearance and unlimited liquidity support provide an
implicit blanket guarantee and serve as a taxpayer-funded rescue package for sophisticated investors who purposely took on risk and were compensated for bearing it.
The fourth—and final—requirement for successful crisis resolution is a plan to jumpstart credit flows in the financial system by repairing the damaged creditworthiness of
the real economy. Even if banks can be completely restored to health through recapitalization, borrowers may be in no position to repay any new loan they may get. This was
the case in the United States during the Great Depression. The Reconstruction Finance
Corporation (RFC) was founded in 1932 to handle banking crises. Noticing that loan
growth was very slow, in 1934 Congress authorized the RFC to make loans to business
and industry.The RFC invited local bankers, who would have superior knowledge about
borrowers, to participate in the lending. The banks’ response was unenthusiastic. Jesse
Jones, head of the RFC under President Franklin D. Roosevelt, reported (Jones and Angly,
1951):
At one time I sent a letter to every one of the 14,000 banks in the United
States asking their cooperation in making loans to business. Only 1 percent acknowledged receipt of our letter.That seems hardly credible, because more than half of the banks had been directly assisted by the RFC
and all had been indirectly assisted; but it is human to forget.
The RFC was disappointed by the lack of participation and criticized the banks for it.
Jones even admits doing some arm twisting to induce bankers to lend, even when denying the loan might have been the right decision.When they refused to participate despite
such pressure, the RFC made the loans itself. In hindsight, Jones admitted that these were
loans that “no one would have expected a careful banker to make” because businesses’
balance sheets had been severely damaged by the long recession and lack of funding.

8

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

How does Sweden’s experience relate to these four traits of successful crisis resolution?. With respect to transparency, Sweden did particularly well in terms of recognizing the magnitude of the losses, assigning realistic values to seized collateral, and giving
markets a clear picture of how the crisis was being managed (Ingves and Lind, 1996;
Bäckström, 1997).The Swedes also get high marks on the second trait, the independence
of the resolution agencies they created. As Klingebiel (2000) notes, the success of asset
management companies depends greatly on the type of asset that must be disposed of,
professional management, political independence, a skilled resource base, appropriate
funding, adequate bankruptcy and foreclosure laws, good information and management
systems, and transparency in operations and processes. In every category, Sweden is a
success story.
As to the third trait, resolution policies that maintain market discipline, Sweden, to
its credit, refused to go down the path of forbearance and unlimited liquidity support.
However, by guaranteeing all bank liabilities, Sweden is likely to have reduced incentives
to monitor bank risk on the part of uninsured creditors, who would have anticipated
implicit insurance. Such a guarantee, intended to calm markets at the onset of a crisis,
has been governments’ typical response to crisis situations around the globe. However,
being typical does not make it the only alternative. Kane and Klingebiel (2004) argue
that the best response would be a bank holiday long enough to allow bank examiners to
determine the extent of the damage, while also giving insured depositors access to their
funds.This response would solve the problem of market discipline because uninsured depositors could not move out and would be forced to take a haircut if losses were large. It
would also save taxpayers money because banks that were not viable would not receive
liquidity support during the holiday and good money would not be thrown after bad to
keep a nonviable institution operating.
The Swedish experience also demonstrated the fourth trait of a successful resolution,
as the asset management companies showed clearly their ability to repair the creditworthiness of the economy. They moved quickly, making equity injections to revitalize
borrowers who were damaged but still viable, and acquiring a majority of their shares
in most cases. The ones that were deemed beyond repair were liquidated, and their collateral was seized. The efficiency of Sweden’s legal infrastructure was a critical factor in
the country’s speedy resolution process (Klingebiel, 2000).There was some criticism that
the AMCs were trigger-happy in initiating liquidations and too quick to dispose of the
assets (mentioned in Bergstrom, Englund, and Thorell, 2003). If the AMCs had waited a
few years, the quick-disposition argument goes, the government might have recovered
a larger share of its losses by selling the assets at higher prices during the recovery. The
main weakness of such criticism is that the market may never recover if a large inventory
of assets is sitting on the sidelines, ready to be dumped onto buyers when prices go up.

9

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 21, JUNE 2007

Whether or not the AMCs were too quick in initiating liquidations is debatable, but there
seems to be no conclusive evidence either way.
Still, there may be room for criticism (again, in hindsight) of the methods used to rescue viable firms. One alternative to injecting equity and assuming ownership of firms is
provided by Mexico’s response to the 1994 Tequila Crisis. After some failed attempts to
revive the economy after the onset of crisis, the Mexican government started the Punto
Final program in December 1998, targeting mortgage holders, agribusiness, and smalland medium-sized enterprises.The program offered debtors a subsidy of up to 60 percent
of a loan’s book value if they began to repay it.The cost of the subsidy was shared by the
banks and the government. Moreover, the government promised to increase its share of
the subsidy by one peso for every three pesos in new loans that the bank made.
This program incorporated some very intelligent incentives. First, borrowers could
get a chunk of their debt erased only if they started to repay it. Because a borrower who
is not hopeful about his business’s prospects is unlikely to throw more money at it, this
subsidy mechanism reveals which borrowers expect to do well in the future, solving the
adverse-selection problem. Second, the program gave banks an incentive to provide new
credit:They could reduce the amount they had to charge off as a part of the subsidy deal
by making new loans. Third, the program got more bang for the buck by targeting small
enterprises, the businesses that depend most heavily on banks for funding and are least
likely to have government connections.11
I am not suggesting that this strategy would have been more successful in Sweden
than the AMCs’ quick-liquidation approach, only that—in hindsight—one can see alternatives to (or steps that might precede) taking possession of a troubled company.

Conclusion
We have analyzed the resolution of the financial crisis that hit Sweden during the 1990s
in terms of four traits that are essential to a successful crisis resolution in a developed
economy: transparency, independence, the maintenance of market discipline, and the
restoration of credit flows. Transparency is necessary to gain credibility in the market.
Independence of the agencies charged with resolving the crisis protects the resolution
process from political pressures, prevents politically connected forbearance, and guarantees that taxpayers’ money is used to save viable banks and borrowers, not the wellconnected ones. Policies that preserve market discipline are critical for reducing the likelihood and severity of future crises. Finally, it may be necessary to rehabilitate the real
sector because the financial sector’s troubles may cause a credit crunch that damages
healthy firms. Without healthy borrowers, bank restructurings will fail to restart credit
flows.The keys to successful rehabilitation are to use incentives that separate viable from
nonviable borrowers and to dispose of seized collateral as quickly as possible.

10

11. Although it incorporated the right
incentives, the program was
impaired by Mexican supervisors’
lack of enforcement authority, an
inefficient bankruptcy system,
and the presence of politically
connected lending (Calomiris,
Klingebiel, and Laeven, 2004).
One would hope that these
problems would be less prevalent
in a developed economy.

FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND

References
Bäckström, Urban, 1997. “What Lessons Can Be Learned from Recent Financial Crises?
The Swedish Experience, “Maintaining Financial Stability in a Global Economy (Federal
Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Jackson Hole,Wyo..).
Bergström, Clas, Peter Englund, and Per Thorell, 2003. “Securum and the Way out of the
Swedish Banking Crisis” (SNS—Center for Business and Policy Studies, Stockholm), translated by Timothy Chamberlain.
Bosworth, Barry P., and Robert Z. Lawrence, 1987a. “Adjusting to Slower Economic
Growth,” in Barry P. Bosworth and Alice M. Rivlin, eds., The Swedish Economy (Brookings
Institution,Washington, D.C.).
Bosworth, Barry P., and Robert Z. Lawrence, 1987b.“Economic Goals and the Policy Mix,”
in Barry P. Bosworth and Alice M. Rivlin, eds.: The Swedish Economy (Brookings Institution,Washington, D.C.).
Calmfors, Lars, 1987. “Comment on Robert J. Flanagan, ‘Efficiency and Equality in Swedish Labor Markets,‘“ in Barry P. Bosworth and Alice M. Rivlin, eds., The Swedish Economy
(The Brookings Institution,Washington, D.C.).
Calomiris, Charles W., Daniela Klingebiel, and Luc Laeven, 2004. “A Taxonomy of Financial Crisis Resolution Mechanisms: Cross-country Experience,”The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series, No. 3379 (Washington, D.C.).
Cerra, Valerie, and Sweta C. Saxena, 2005. “Eurosclerosis or Financial Collapse: Why Did
Swedish Incomes Fall Behind?” IMF working paper 05/29
Diamond, Douglas W., 2001. “Should Banks Be Recapitalized?” Federal Reserve Bank of
Richmond, Economic Quarterly 87, 71–96.
Drees, Burkhard, and Ceyla Pazarbasioglu, 1998.“The Nordic Banking Crisis: Pitfalls in Financial Liberalization,” Occasional Paper, No. 161 (International Monetary Fund,Washington, D.C.).
Ergungor, O. Emre, and James B. Thomson, 2006.“Systemic Banking Crises,” in Andrew H.
Chen, ed.: Research in Finance (Elsevier).
Flanagan, Robert J., 1987. “Efficiency and Equality in Swedish labor Markets,” in Barry P.
Bosworth, and Alice M. Rivlin, eds.: The Swedish Economy (The Brookings Institution,
Washington, D.C.).
11

POLICY DISCUSSION PAPERS

NUMBER 21, JUNE 2007

Ingves, Stefan, and Göran Lind, 1996. “The Management of the Bank Crisis—in Retrospect,” Sweriges Riksbank, Quarterly Review 1, 5–18.
Jones, Jesse H., and Edward Angly, 1951. Fifty Billion Dollars: My Thirteen Years with the
RFC (1932–1945) (The Macmillan Company, New York, NY).
Kane, Edward J., 1990.“Principal-Agent Problems in S&L Salvage,“ Journal of Finance 45,
755–64.
Kane, Edward J., and Daniela Klingebiel, 2004. “Alternatives to Blanket Guarantees for
Containing a Systemic Crisis,” Journal of Financial Stability, September, 31–63.
Klingebiel, Daniela, 2000.“The Use of Asset Management Companies in the Resolution of
Banking Crises: Cross-country Experiences, “ The World Bank, Policy Research Working
Paper Series: 2284 (Washington, D.C.).
Spade, Mike, and Edward D.Thomas, 1998.“Evolution of the RTC’s Resolution Practices,“
in William R. Ostermiller, ed.: Managing the Crisis: The FDIC and RTC Experience (FDIC,
Washington, DC).
Tranøy, Bent Sofus, 1999.“The Swedish Financial Sector 1985–1992: Policy-Assisted Boom,
Bust, and Crash,” ECPR Joint Sessions Workshop, No. 16: Success and Failure in Governance (Mannheim, Germany).
Weaver, R. Kent, 1987.“Political Foundations of Swedish Economic Policy,” in Barry P. Bosworth, and Alice M. Rivlin, eds., The Swedish Economy (The Brookings Institution, Washington, D.C.).

12

pd
papers
Presorted Standard
FEDERAL RESERVE BANK OF CLEVELAND
RESEARCH DEPARTMENT
P.O. BOX 6387

U.S. Postage Paid
Cleveland, OH
Permit no. 385

CLEVELAND, OHIO 44101

Return Service Requested:
Please send corrected mailing
label to the Federal Reserve
Bank of Cleveland, Research
Department, P.O. Box 6387,
Cleveland, Ohio 44101.